35
International Studies Program International Studies Program Working Paper 08-04 December 2008 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M Bird Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

  • Upload
    phungtu

  • View
    215

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

International Studies ProgramInternational Studies ProgramWorking Paper 08-04December 2008

The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformThe BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries

Richard M BirdRichard M. Bird

Page 2: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird
Page 3: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

International Studies Program Andrew Young School of Policy Studies Georgia State University Atlanta, Georgia 30303 United States of America Phone: (404) 651-1144 Fax: (404) 651-4449 Email: [email protected] Internet: http://isp-aysps.gsu.edu Copyright 2006, the Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University. No part of the material protected by this copyright notice may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means without prior written permission from the copyright owner.

International Studies Program Working Paper 08-04

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird December 2008

Page 4: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

International Studies Program Andrew Young School of Policy Studies The Andrew Young School of Policy Studies was established at Georgia State University with the objective of promoting excellence in the design, implementation, and evaluation of public policy. In addition to two academic departments (economics and public administration), the Andrew Young School houses seven leading research centers and policy programs, including the International Studies Program. The mission of the International Studies Program is to provide academic and professional training, applied research, and technical assistance in support of sound public policy and sustainable economic growth in developing and transitional economies. The International Studies Program at the Andrew Young School of Policy Studies is recognized worldwide for its efforts in support of economic and public policy reforms through technical assistance and training around the world. This reputation has been built serving a diverse client base, including the World Bank, the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID), the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), finance ministries, government organizations, legislative bodies and private sector institutions. The success of the International Studies Program reflects the breadth and depth of the in-house technical expertise that the International Studies Program can draw upon. The Andrew Young School's faculty are leading experts in economics and public policy and have authored books, published in major academic and technical journals, and have extensive experience in designing and implementing technical assistance and training programs. Andrew Young School faculty have been active in policy reform in over 40countries around the world. Our technical assistance strategy is not to merely provide technical prescriptions for policy reform, but to engage in a collaborative effort with the host government and donor agency to identify and analyze the issues at hand, arrive at policy solutions and implement reforms. The International Studies Program specializes in four broad policy areas: Fiscal policy, including tax reforms, public expenditure reviews, tax administration reform Fiscal decentralization, including fiscal decentralization reforms, design of intergovernmental

transfer systems, urban government finance Budgeting and fiscal management, including local government budgeting, performance-

based budgeting, capital budgeting, multi-year budgeting Economic analysis and revenue forecasting, including micro-simulation, time series

forecasting, For more information about our technical assistance activities and training programs, please visit our website at http://isp-aysps.gsu.edu or contact us by email at [email protected].

Page 5: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

1

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries

Richard M. Bird University of Toronto

Abstract

Fiscal experts have years proposed a holy trinity of tax reform options for developing countries: broader bases, lower rates, and better administration. The review in this paper of fifty years of experience auggests that what might be called the BBLR approach-- broader bases and lower rates -- to tax structure reform holds up fairly well. Nonetheless, some qualifications to the basic BBLR approach are suggested and the continuing fundamental importance of understanding and improving tax administration is stressed.

Keywords: tax reform, tax bases, tax rates, tax administration JEL classification: H20, O23, P41

Page 6: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

2 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

Introduction

No one likes taxes. People do not like to pay them. Governments do not like to

impose them. Unfortunately, taxes are necessary both to finance desired public spending

in a non-inflationary way and to ensure that the burden of paying for such spending is

fairly distributed. Since even necessary taxes impose real costs on society, good tax

policy seeks to minimize those costs. Tax policy is not just about economics, however.

It is also about justice and hence reflects such political factors as the degree of concern

about fairness. In many countries, the increased economic growth of recent years has

increased disparities between the rich and the poor. How people see the distributive

effects of tax systems matters. In the end, however, no matter what any country may want

to do with its tax system, or what it should do from one perspective or another (ethical,

political, or developmental), in reality what it does do is always constrained by what it

can do. A country’s economic structure and its administrative capacity as well as its

political institutions all tend to reduce the tax policy options available. Nonetheless,

some options almost always exist. The holy trinity of tax reform options proposed by

most fiscal experts for developing countries are broader bases, lower rates, and better

administration. I begin the review of these options by considering what gets taxed – the

tax base.

Page 7: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 3

Broadening Tax Bases1

Developing countries face many difficult challenges in designing and implementing

suitable tax systems. Many countries (like India) have large traditional agriculture

sectors that are difficult to tax. Other significant components of the potential tax base

lurk in other equally “hard-to-tax” sectors ranging from small business and the informal

economy to cross-border investments. The traditional tax base afforded by international

trade has also become increasingly hard to exploit in the face of pressures for trade

liberalization. On the other hand, economic growth generally expands tax bases and such

growth is often encouraged by (and usually results in) closer involvement with the

international economy.

As countries develop, the mass modern production and consumption activities on

which the tax systems of developed countries rest -- taxes on wages and personal income,

on corporate profits, on value-added – expand. This base needs to be reached without

either overstraining administrative capacity or unduly discouraging the expansion of such

activities. However, the leading edge of growth – outward-oriented development -- may

become the bleeding edge of the fiscal system as it becomes more and more difficult to

levy taxes effectively on capital income, thus potentially exacerbating internal

inequalities and political pressures on the tax system. Life is not easy for tax people in

developing countries, and it is not becoming any easier.

As World Bank (1991) argues one important aspect of good tax policy is to

minimize unnecessary costs of taxation and one important way to do so is to make tax

bases as broad as possible. A broad-based consumption tax, for example, will still 1 Some of the ideas contained in this paper were also discussed in my recent NIPFP lecture (Bird 2008), although the focus of that lecture on the political economy aspects of the process of tax reform was very different from the more substantive focus of the present paper.

Page 8: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

4 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

discourage work effort, but such a tax will minimize distortions in the consumption of

goods if all or most goods and services are subject to tax.2 It has also been long argued

that the tax base for income tax should also be as broad as possible, treating all incomes,

no matter from what source, as uniformly as possible, although some recent discussion is

beginning to cast increasing doubt on this once conventional piece of wisdom.3

Growing Tax Bases

Much discussion of taxation in developing countries seems to assume, as it were,

that “unto each a base (or bases) is given.” If the tax base is indeed ‘given’ then the only

policy issue to be addressed is how it can be best exploited -- for example, by reducing

exemptions and by bringing non-payers into the tax net. In reality, however, tax bases

are not simply ‘given’: they can be ‘grown’ – or destroyed – through the manner in which

a given tax burden is collected. Taxes may, for example, discourage, or encourage, the

‘formalization’ of the economy, they may foster or discourage the growth of such ‘tax

handles’ as imports, or they may be used to shape and direct economic growth into

particular channels in a variety of ways and for a variety of purposes. As Emran and

Stiglitz (2005) have recently reminded us, in the long run the manner in which (and from

whom) taxes are collected may affect not only growth and distribution but also the future

2 In theory, in order to minimize efficiency losses different tax rates should be imposed on each commodity, with higher rates imposed on those goods and services where the changes in behavior are the smallest. To do so, however, requires much more information about how taxes alter behavior than is available in most countries. Moreover, this approach does not take administrative and equity concerns into account. For these reasons, in practice it seems generally advisable to impose a uniform tax rate to the extent possible. A few items, such as gasoline, tobacco products and alcohol, may be taxed at a relatively higher rates, either because of regulatory reasons or because the demand for these products is relatively unresponsive to taxation Such taxes can be designed to avoid excessive regressivity. 3 See e.g. Boadway (2005) and Barreix and Roca (2007). I explore this question in more detail in a forthcoming paper with Eric Zolt.

Page 9: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 5

level and mix of revenues itself.4 The long-run ‘fiscal impact’ (or ‘revenue productivity’)

effect of tax policy and administration decisions needs careful attention.

Consider, for example, four questions often raised with respect to the challenges

facing tax policy in developing countries:

1. Should more reliance be put on consumption than on income taxes?

2. Are broader tax bases always better than narrower bases?

3. Should tax policy be designed to reduce the size of the ‘informal economy’?

4. What should be done with tax incentives?

Until recently, the answers of most fiscal experts to these questions were more or

less that: (1) consumption taxes are better; (2) so are broader bases; (3) every effort

should be made to tax the informal sector; (4) and, finally, tax incentives are almost

always a bad idea. How do these answers hold up in light of recent analysis and

experience?

Taxes and Growth

Over the past 50 years, there have been many policy prescriptions for economic

growth (Easterly 2002). Policy advisors have (in rough chronological order) urged

increased capital investment, improvements in education, population control, reduction of

government controls on market activities, and loan forgiveness programs as “silver

bullets” that would result in improved economic performance in developing countries.

Unfortunately, none of these cures has worked as advertised. Similarly, there is no magic

tax strategy to encourage economic growth. Some countries with high tax burdens have

4 Much the same inference can be drawn from such other recent papers as Auriol and Warlters (2005) and Gordon and Li (2005). For a slightly different take on this issue, see the recent survey by Bahl and Bird (2008).

Page 10: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

6 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

high growth rates and some countries with low tax burdens have low growth rates.

Looking at the relationship between growth rates and tax rates in the United States over

the last 50 years, for instance, reveals that the U.S. had its greatest periods of economic

growth during those years where the tax rates were the highest (Slemrod and Bakija

1996). This does not mean that high tax rates are the key to economic growth since

growth rates might have been even higher in those years with high tax rates if the rates

had been lower. But it does suggest that there is still much that we do not understand

about the relation between taxes and growth.

Nonetheless, if one tried to visualize a purely growth-oriented tax system it might

perhaps be one would be one with a relatively low and stable tax on profits and some

taxation of the traditional agricultural and informal sectors, but with major fiscal reliance

being placed on a broad-based consumption tax that makes some allowance for necessary

consumption. What would likely be conspicuously missing in any such design is any

explicit concern for fairness in taxation. I return to this point later.

Consumption or income? Even from a growth perspective, however, some

modifications to the conventional answers summarized above seem required. First,

should taxation focus more on consumption than income? In general, Yes: but there is not

all that much difference between the two in the context of most developing countries, and

some “consumption” in national accounting terms is really “investment” from the growth

perspective and hence should not be taxed.5 Moreover, even though many emerging

countries get little or no revenue from taxing capital income, their tax systems may

nonetheless have high adverse effects on investment and growth owing to the high

5 The careful early work of Carl Shoup (1965) on this subject deserves more attention than it has received.

Page 11: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 7

effective tax rates imposed at the margin (Mintz 2006). Nonetheless, as discussed below,

income taxes also have a distinctive role to play in a "good" tax mix.

Broader base? Should bases be broader rather than narrower? Often the answer is

again Yes. Sometimes, however, as in the productive consumption case and perhaps also

in the capital income case broader may be worse.6 If people lack food to eat or basic

clothing and shelter and they are not sufficiently healthy and educated to engage in

productive work, they are unlikely to be economically productive. For example,

sometimes excluding items that constitute a significant fraction of the consumption of

poor people from the VAT base may be a perfectly sensible growth-facilitating policy,

although developing and implementing a finely nuanced VAT structure along these lines

is a tricky exercise (as Bird and Gendron 2007 discuss in some detail).

Growth in the sense of enhancing the productivity of the labor force and equity in

the sense of not taxing the poor may thus sometimes be fully compatible objectives. In

addition, from a broader perspective societal disaffection with the inequities

accompanying growth may sometimes require a degree of visible fiscal correction in

order to make growth-facilitating policies politically feasible. Poverty alleviation is more

a task for expenditures than for taxes. At the very least, however, heavy taxes on items

that constitute major consumption expenditures for the poor should be avoided.

Tax informality? Should taxes be used to punish the informal economy? Yes, but

again great care is needed in both design and administration. While even a bad tax on a

6 There is also a strong case for heavy narrow excise taxes on a small range of products both in economic and revenue terms. Essentially, a good excise tax system is one that (1) taxes few products, (2) taxes those products correctly, and (3) is administered well. Most excise systems in developing countries fall well short of this standard. Excises are imposed on too many products; the rate structure is not logical; and administration leaves much to be desired. The result is all too often a complex structure that produces less revenue and more distortions than it should and is not well administered: see Cnossen (2006).

Page 12: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

8 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

good base may sometimes be a good idea (Auriol and Warlters 2005), care must be taken

to ensure that the "good" does not become the enemy of the better, as Sally Wallace and I

have elsewhere discussed in detail (Bird and Wallace 2004). An easier task than taxing

those in the informal sector is to remove the many barriers created by tax and regulatory

systems discouraging people from entering entering the formal sector. A recent World

Bank (2008) publication, for example, places India near the bottom of the list with

respect to the costs to formal business of complying with tax system: this is obviously not

conducive to economic growth.

Tax incentives? What should be done with tax incentives? In this case, there is no

reason to add a ‘but’ to the conventional answer: eliminate them. Despite their

continuing popularity, the evidence is -- as these things go in the social sciences --

virtually overwhelming: tax incentives are usually redundant and ineffective: They

reduce revenue and complicate the fiscal system without achieving their stated objectives

efficiently or effectively. Excessive use of tax incentives complicates administration,

facilitating evasion and corruption. Once created, concessions usually prove hard to

remove and are often enlarged at the initiative of taxpayers who lobby for more

concessions or simply redefine existing concessions in unforeseen and presumably

undesired ways.

Elsewhere (Bird 2000) I have suggested that to maximize the likelihood of

beneficial results from tax concessions and to reduce the damage that may be caused by

poorly-designed and implemented incentives, countries should at the very least stick to

three simple rules:

Page 13: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 9

(1) Keep it simple: incentives should be as few in number and as simple in

structure as possible.

(2) Keep records on who receives what concessions and at what cost in revenue

forgone and also, if the incentive is intended to achieve some particular objective,

on the measurable results. In the absence of such information, government is

simply throwing money away.

(3) Evaluate the the numbers at regular intervals to determine whether the

incentive is achieving results worth its estimated cost and, if it is not, eliminate it.

Unfortunately, almost no country follows these simple prescriptions, presumably because

the political advantages of ambiguity outweigh the potential social gains from

transparency. Developing countries cannot waste public money like this.7 Much more

needs to be done to assess and evaluate tax incentives on the basis of evidence instead of

relying on the largely unwarranted faith in their efficacy evidenced by their proliferation

around the world.

Lowering Tax Rates

Countries can increase revenues in only three ways: raise rates, expand bases,

and improve administration. Raising rates within the existing system is the most obvious

approach. It is also often the most politically acceptable approach. On the other hand, it

is generally the least economically desirable solution. Raising rates when traditional tax

bases are not expanding, when new bases can shift abroad, and when administration is

weak is unlikely to increase revenue much. Even if revenues do increase, so may 7 Of course, in some instances as Bates (2007) emphasizes, such ways of putting public money into private pockets may be a pay-off required to keep the current politicians in power so from their point of view it may not be a waste of money – it’s not their money, after all. But it is still a social waste.

Page 14: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

10 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

inequity and inefficiency. Distortions associated with taxation increase (broadly) with

the square of the tax rate, so inefficiency increases with rate increases, especially those

affecting economically mobile sectors such as foreign investors. Horizontal inequity may

also increase because only those few unfortunates trapped within the tax system bear the

burden. When those who comply are penalized and those who cheat escape, a country is

not on the path to building a sustainable state revenue system. Moreover, if as seems

often to be the case, it turns out to be most expedient to increase taxes most on the

politically weaker segments of society, vertical inequity may also be exacerbated.

While as noted earlier statutory rates do not necessarily tell the tale -- effective

rates are what matters for many purposes -- the experience of recent years suggests that

many countries have been listening to the conventional BBLR advice or, more likely,

emulating the neighbors. Statutory income tax rates have in general declined strikingly

around the world in recent decades. Although in most countries VAT revenues have

replaced declining trade taxes (and excises) and not income taxes, concern has been

expressed over this trend by those who view income taxes as the only flag under which

tax progressivity sails.

I have some sympathy with this proposition. Historically, reliance on the income

tax has indeed been seen as “a mirror of democracy” (Webber and Wildavsky 1986, 526).

However, I do not agree that the reduction of nominal income tax rates is always or

necessarily a politically and socially retrogressive move. Taxes impose real costs on

society as a whole. Developing countries (in which resources are by definition scarce)

should strive to keep such costs as low as possible in order to free resources for socially

desired objectives.

Page 15: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 11

The Costs of Taxes

Of course, taxes are not themselves a cost but simply a means of transferring

resources from private to public use. Economic costs arise only when total resources

available for society’s use, whether for public or private purposes, are reduced by taxes.

There are several ways taxes can reduce the size of the economic pot from which all

must draw.

Administrative costs. To begin with, it obviously costs something to collect taxes.

The actual cost of collecting taxes in developed countries is (very) roughly 1 percent of

tax revenues. In developing countries, the costs of tax collection may be substantially

higher: Gallagher (2004) reports administrative costs ranging from 0.9 to 3.9 percent for

six developing countries; Warlters and Auriol (2005) report results for an additional nine

countries in the range of 1.1 to 3.6 percent.

Compliance costs. Taxpayers also incur compliance costs over and above the actual

payment of tax. Third parties also incur compliance costs. One of the few reported

studies of compliance costs in developing countries (by Chattopadhyay and Das Gupta

2002, for the Indian personal income tax) found compliance costs to be more than ten

times higher than in developed countries. Similarly, Shekidele (1999) found compliance

costs for excises in Tanzania to be more than 15 times higher than similar costs in more

developed countries. Costs of paying taxes are generally considerably higher in poor

than in rich countries for several reasons. One is the sheer complexity of their tax

structures and the cumbersome administrative methods employed. Another is because

compliance costs are sensitive to the stability of tax legislation as well as to such changes in

Page 16: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

12 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

the external environment as inflation, and such factors are more prominent in developing

countries.8

Efficiency costs. Finally – and the major concern of most economists -- taxes

impose “deadweight” (distortionary) costs that alter decisions made by businesses and

individuals as the relative prices they confront are changed. In most circumstances, the

resulting changes in behavior reduce the efficiency with which resources are used and

hence lower output and potential well being.9

Virtually all taxes affect resource decisions at the margin. Consumption taxes,

such as the value- added tax, may discourage the consumption of taxed as opposed to

untaxed goods (e.g. housing). Taxes on gasoline, alcohol, and cigarettes may reduce the

consumption of these items.10 Income taxes, because they tax the return to savings, may

alter the amount of savings or the form in which savings are held. Failure to tax capital

gains until they are realized (when the asset is sold) encourages the holding of assets

(lock-in effect). Taxes may also affect investment, and such effects may be especially

important when economies are more open to trade and investment. Foreign investors

may choose to locate their activities in a particular country for many reasons -- the

8 Compliance and administrative costs may sometimes be substitutes to some extent – e.g. when taxpayers are required to provide more information, thus increasing their costs while presumably reducing the administrative costs that would otherwise be incurred to secure that information. On the other hand, administrative and compliance costs may also be complementary, as when a more sophisticated administration both requires more information and makes use of it to undertake audits and other actions. 9 There are exceptions. First, when taxes are ‘lump sum’ – i.e. the tax burden is the same regardless of behavioral responses – there are no distortionary effects. But such taxes are of no importance in the real world. Second, to the extent that taxes fall on economic rents – payments to factors above those needed to induce them into the activity concerned -- they may not affect economic activity. Well-designed taxes on natural resources and land, for example, may thus to some extent produce revenue without economic distortion. Finally, some taxes may not only create no distortions in economic behaviour but may even induce desirable behaviour. Certain environmental levies, for example (even such crude proxies such as taxes on fuel), may to some extent have such effects. “Good” taxes – those with no bad economic effects – should of course be exploited as fully as possible, but most revenue needed to finance government inevitably gives rise to efficiency costs. 10 As noted earlier, not all such effects need be bad: for instance, if tobacco consumption falls, people may live longer, healthier and more productive lives.

Page 17: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 13

relative costs of production, access to markets, and sound infrastructure -- but taxes may

also influence their choice. When taxes lower the after-tax return on investments, the

level of investment and hence growth is lower than it would otherwise be. Corporate

income taxes may also influence the decision to incorporate, the composition of a firm’s

capital structure (use of debt or equity financing) and dividend policy.

The importance of such tax effects is a matter of considerable debate, but the

current consensus is that they are much more important than was earlier thought.

Efficiency costs of taxation in developed countries are usually estimated to be some

multiple of the administrative and compliance costs mentioned above. The lowest

estimates of the efficiency costs of taxes for developed countries are at least 20-30

percent of revenues collected, and much higher estimates (ranging well over 100 percent)

are common in the literature (Auerbach and Hines 2002).

Such estimates are both hard to make and controversial. Nonetheless, unless

public expenditures produce social benefits at least equal to the ‘marginal cost of public

funds’ (MCF), they are by definition not worth what they cost. A recent study found the

average MCF in 38 African countries to be close to those found in a number of developed

countries, namely, around 1.2 (Warlters and Auriol 2005).11 This implies that the last

(marginal) dollar spent by the public sector would have to yield at least $1.20 in public

benefits – more if compliance costs were taken into account – in order to be worthwhile.

11 Warlters and Auriol (2005) do not take compliance costs explicitly into account. They suggest that the similarity observed between developed and developing countries may result from two offsetting factors. First, developed countries tend to have higher taxes and heavier reliance on income taxes, both of which are associated with higher MCFs; second, developing countries tend to have higher administrative costs and larger informal sectors, both of which are again associated with higher MCFs. An additional factor, which also cannot easily be taken into account in the CGE framework used for MCF estimates, is that, as Shah and Whalley (1990) argue, since economic rents are more prevalent in the fragmented economies of developing countries, many taxes that might in more integrated market systems impact economic margins may fall on such rents and hence create less distortion.

Page 18: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

14 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

Whatever their size, efficiency losses from taxation are real. However, they are

not directly visible: they arise essentially because something does not happen -- some

activity did not occur or occurred in some other form than it would have in the absence of

the distortionary tax. Output that is not produced is nonetheless output (and potential

welfare) lost, so poor countries need to design taxes to minimize such possible adverse

consequence. Unfortunately, the absence of visible concrete evidence means that there is

seldom much political weight behind this concern.

One way to reduce the costs of taxation is to shift to consumption taxes (VAT)

instead of income taxes, since this will reduce the extent to which taxes affect the

location of businesses, alter the production techniques, or change the forms in which

business is conducted. However, as I emphasize shortly, personal income taxes are often

politically essential as the primary indicator of the importance governments attach to

fairness. Moreover, countries with personal income taxes need to tax corporate income

also to prevent tax avoidance by individuals as well as to collect taxes from foreign-

owned firms.

To the extent that efficiency costs of taxation result from rational policy

decisions (for example, to redistribute income through the fiscal system), they may be

worth incurring. A key question is thus whether the income tax is in fact an effective

redistributor. If it is, the efficiency cost of taxation may be worth paying – though one

should of course still strive to reduce administrative and compliance costs. But if

progressive income taxes do not do much for distribution, and are unlikely to do so

except by incurring very high costs, then presumably countries can reduce rates to reduce

their marginal distortionary effect at little loss in terms of distribution.

Page 19: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 15

Progressivity and Fairness

Fairness is a key issue in designing any tax regime. Indeed, from one perspective,

taxes exist primarily to secure equity. National governments do not need taxes to secure

funds: they can simply print the money required to fund operations. The tax system may

be viewed as a mechanism designed to take money away from the private sector in as

efficient, equitable, and administratively inexpensive way as possible. Of course, what is

considered equitable or fair by one person may differ from the conceptions held by

others. Some may stress horizontal over vertical equity, for example, as OECD (2006)

argues is increasingly true in developed countries. Others may tilt the balance the other

way, as ‘progressive’ thinkers have long done.

Broadly, horizontal equity requires those in similar circumstances to pay the same

amount of taxes, while vertical equity requires appropriate differences among taxpayers

in different economic circumstances. Those who have the same ability to pay should of

course bear the same tax liability; equally, fairness would seem to require those taxpayers

with greater ability to pay to pay relatively higher taxes. Both concepts have appeal.

Unfortunately, neither is very useful in actually setting up a tax system.

I consider here only the question of whether ‘growing’ governments in developing

countries on the basis of VATs rather than income taxes is an inherently bad idea.12 First,

I ask whether even progressive income taxes in developing countries are very

redistributive: the answer is – not much. Second, I then ask whether VATs in such

countries are regressive: the answer is – not necessarily. And finally, I ask whether in

12 For further discussion of a few of the many complex points touched on (or skipped over) in this section, see Bird and Zolt (2005).

Page 20: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

16 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

some circumstances a ‘good’ VAT may not be better than a ‘bad’ income tax; the answer

is, of course it may, depending upon the details of both the country and the two taxes.

Are income taxes progressive? Chu, Davoodi, and Gupta (2000) surveyed 36

studies of tax incidence in 19 different developing countries: 13 found the tax system

progressive, and 7 each found the tax system proportional and regressive; the others had

mixed findings or insignificant effects. Most of the reported progressivity came from

income taxes. So the answer to the first question is that income taxes in most developing

countries are likely somewhat progressive. Indeed, to the extent income taxes do not

impinge on the poorest – those outside the market sector – they are bound to be

progressive. Even within the taxed sector, progressive rates mean that the impact of the

tax is progressive at least within the group of those who must pay tax on all (most) of

their income-- for example because they receive it in the form of wages from a public

sector employer. In most developing countries, however, little if any tax is collected

from either capital income or self-employment (mixed) income and that little is most

unlikely to be distributed very progressively.

Income taxes may thus help share the burden of government a bit more fairly, but

they are unlikely have any significant influence on distributional outcomes (Harberger

2006). As Lindert (2003) shows, it was not by taxing the rich but by taxing the growing

middle class that developed countries ‘grew’ large states. Big states may – if those who

control them wish to do so – help the poor more than small states; but they do so through

expenditures much more than through taxes. In fact, such well-known ‘welfare states’ as

Sweden have been very careful not to kill the golden goose of private investment that

largely (if indirectly) finances their big public sectors.

Page 21: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 17

Is VAT regressive? Three types of taxes are levied on consumption in most

developing countries: import taxes, excise taxes, and VATs. For the most part, the

growth in VAT replaced the other two types of consumption tax. This change has almost

certainly made the tax system more progressive (Gemmell and Morrissey 2003), for a

number of reasons. First, the impact of trade taxes (especially including the ‘burden’

imposed by their protective effect) is likely regressive in the context of most developing

countries. Second, excise taxes (even those justified by good economic arguments such

as external effects) are also generally -- with the notable exception of those affecting

motor transport -- regressive. Third, VAT in most developing countries is not

particularly regressive and may indeed in some be slightly progressive.13

Can a good VAT be better than a bad income tax? In some circumstances it can,

even if one sets aside the more favorable ‘tax-base’ effects discussed above. Consider the

case of a country with a large shadow economy. Income taxes do not reach this sector –

and indeed appear to be associated with its expansion (Schneider and Klingmaier 2004).

On the other hand, to some extent a VAT functions like a presumptive tax on the

informal sector since credits are available only to registered firms and those earning

income in the shadow sector are taxed when they purchase formal-sector commodities

(Glenday and Hollinrake 2005). Increasing income tax rates in such countries generally

impinges primarily on two limited groups. The first consists of government employees,

who often soon receive counterbalancing wage increases that eat up any revenue gains.

The second are employees of large, formal market firms, which tends to discourage the

expansion of the formal sector. Increasing VAT may, on the other hand, to some extent

tend to make life in the formal sector relatively more attractive. Such a substitition is not 13 The evidence for this conclusion is reviewed in Bird and Gendron (2007).

Page 22: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

18 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

only preferable in terms of growth but may even in some cases increase the horizontal

equity of the tax system by imposing more tax on the informal sector. Indeed, if a VAT

is combined with, say, increased excises on such important higher-income consumption

goods as motor vehicles, then increasing indirect taxes may in some countries is

significantly more progressive than just raising the rate of a personal income tax that

affects only a limited group of formal sector wage earners

Of course, there are also good reasons for keeping direct taxes on both income and

property in the tax mix as well. Corporate income taxes are needed to buttress personal

income taxes, to ensure an equitable share of the returns on cross-border investment, and

to tap economic rents to some extent (Bird 2002). Moreover, to maintain and grow the

state, the tax system must tap into those sectors that grow and since growth usually

results in the growth of the employed middle class, a mildly progressive personal income

tax (like a VAT) can be an important way to ensure that state revenues share in the

prosperity. Perhaps most importantly, only by visibly taxing the better-off through both

income and property taxes can countries use the tax system as a ‘state-building’ tool.14

Similarly, since sustainable tax policy needs to be accepted as fair by those affected, and

automobiles and big houses are much more visible than income, the more taxation can

effectively imposed on such items, the better.

Improving Tax Administration

To this point, I have generally supported, in a qualified way, both prongs of the tax

reform fork – BB and LR -- set out in the World Bank (1991) study that I took as my

14 The case for property taxes is developed at length in Bird and Slack (2004). On taxation and state-building in general, see Brautigam, Fjeldstad and Moore (2007).

Page 23: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 19

starting point. However, an important lesson that has been learned time and time again in

the last few decades is that to get reform not only under way but under way in a

sustainable fashion a third horse needs to be harnessed to the BBLR chariot -- better tax

administration. This ‘third horseman’ of tax reform has received much less attention from

analysts than it warrants.15 Reaping revenues from tax rate changes (in any direction)

requires effective tax administration. Raising revenues through base expansion requires

even better tax administration. New taxpayers must be identified and brought into the tax

net and new collection techniques developed. Such changes take time to implement. The

best tax policy in the world is worth little if it cannot be implemented effectively. Tax

policy design must take into account the administrative dimension of taxation. What can

be done to a considerable extent inevitably determines what is done.

The importance of good administration has long been as obvious to all concerned with

tax policy in developing countries as its absence in practice. One cannot assume that

whatever policy designers can think up can be done or that any administrative problems

encountered can be easily and quickly remedied. How a tax system is administered affects

its yield, its incidence, and its efficiency. Administration that is unfair and capricious may

bring the tax system into disrepute and weaken the legitimacy of state actions

Assessing Tax Administration

Tax administration is a difficult task even at the best of time and in the best of

places, and conditions in few emerging countries match these specifications. Revenue

outcomes are not always the most appropriate basis for assessing administrative

15 Not so incidentally, much of what I have learned about tax administration I learned from Amaresh Bagchi and Arindam Das-Gupta when I had the pleasure of working with them some years ago on a paper reviewing the then scanty literature on the subject (Bagchi, Bird and Das-Gupta 1995).

Page 24: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

20 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

performance.16 How revenue is raised - the effect of revenue-generation effort on equity, the

political fortunes of the government, and the level of economic welfare - may be equally (or

more) important as how much revenue is raised. Private as well as public costs of tax

administration must be taken into account, and due attention must be paid to the extent to

which revenue is attributable to enforcement (the active intervention of the administration)

rather than compliance (the relatively passive role of the administration as the recipient of

revenues generated by other features of the system).17 Assessing the relation between

administrative effort and revenue outcome is by no means a simple task. Neither is

improving administrative efforts and outcomes.

It is useful to think of the problem of tax administration at three levels – architecture,

engineering, and management (Shoup 1991). The first level concerns the design of the

general legal framework - not only the substance of the tax laws to be administered but also

a wide range of important procedural features. Once the general architectural design has

been determined, the engineer takes over and sets up the specific organizational structure

and operating rules for the tax administration. Finally, once the critical institutional

infrastructure has been erected, the tax managers charged with actually administering the tax

system can do their jobs. One cannot assess how well a tax administration is functioning, let

alone suggest how to improve it, without taking into account not only the environment in

which it has to function but also the laws it is supposed to administer and the institutional

infrastructure with which it has been equipped. 16.For example, even if it costs only $1 to collect $1000, it does not follow that to get another $100 in revenue one simply needs to spend an additional dollar on tax administration. Not only are such figures sensitive to tax rates but the marginal revenue yield equals the average only under very special circumstances (Vazquez-Caro et al., 1992). More importantly as Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002) show, the optimal size of a tax administration is likely to be where marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost, perhaps by a wide margin. 17.In one of the few books on how tax administrations actually function in developing countries, Radian (1980) stresses the extent to which officials tend to be passive recipients of funds rather than active collectors of them.

Page 25: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 21

To appraise the efficiency or effectiveness of tax administration one thus needs to

take into account both the degree of complexity of the tax structure and the extent to which

that structure remains stable over time. Complexity and its implications for tax

administration has long been a concern even in the most developed countries. Even the

most sophisticated tax administration can easily be overloaded with impossible tasks (Hood

1976). Such concerns are obviously critical in countries in which less well-equipped

administrators are asked to tackle inherently complex tasks in a generally hostile and often

information-poor environment. The life of the tax administrator is made even more

complicated by the propensity of many governments, reflecting in part the unstable political

and economic environment, to alter tax legislation annually, or even more frequently. Both

the complexity of the tax structure and its stability are thus important factors to be weighed

in assessing tax administration.

Disaggregation of the ‘black box’ of tax administration along such lines is

particularly important since the main ways to improve administrative outcomes are either

to alter the tasks with which the administration is charged or to strengthen the tools with

which it is equipped. Simple exhortations to "do better" are of little use to resource-

strapped administrators faced with impossible tasks. Experience around the world

demonstrates that the single most important ingredient for effective tax administration is

clear recognition at high political levels of politics of the importance of the task and

willingness to support good administrative practices -- even if political friends are hurt.

Few developing countries have been able to leap this initial hurdle.18 The widespread

18 See, for instance, the telling comparison in Bergman (2003) of Argentina, which conspicuously has not leaped the hurdle, and Chile, which has. As IDB (2006) notes, there is still much we do not understand about why Chile has been able to do so much: however, as Bergman (2003) shows, the willingness of Chile’s leaders – of very different political persuasions – to support effective administration stands out.

Page 26: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

22 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

reluctance to collect taxes efficiently and effectively without fear or favor may be

understandable in countries which are fragile politically, but without such efforts no

viable long-term tax system can possibly be put into place. If the political will is there,

the techniques needed for effective tax administration are not a secret.

How to Fix Tax Administration

Indeed, the basic recipe for effective tax administration has only three ingredients:

political will to administer the tax system effectively, a clear strategy for achieving this

goal and adequate resources for the task. It helps, of course, if the tax system is well

designed, appropriate for the country in question, and relatively simple. But even the

best designed tax system will not be properly implemented unless these three conditions

are fulfilled.

If the political will exists, the blueprint for effective tax administration is relatively

straightforward. The tax administration should be given an appropriate institutional

form, adequately staffed with trained officials, and properly organized, which usually

means an organizational structure based on function or client groups. Computerization

and appropriate use of modern information technology are important (Bird and Zolt

2007), but technology alone is not sufficient and must be carefully integrated into the tax

administration. Putting all this into place takes time, resources, direction and effort. But

it can be done, as countries from Singapore to Chile have shown.

In addition to giving the administration simpler and more enforceable laws to

administer, experience suggests that the best approach to improving tax administration

begins by assuming that the taxpayer is a client (albeit probably not a willing one) to be

Page 27: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 23

served and not a thief to be caught. Studies on taxpayer behavior around the world

suggest that services to taxpayers that facilitate reporting, filing and paying taxes, or that

impart education or information among citizens about their obligations under the tax

laws, are often as or more cost-effective in securing compliance than measures (auditing,

penalties) more directly designed to counter non-compliance.

Improving tax compliance is not the same as discouraging noncompliance (Slemrod

1992). Low compliance may to some extent be a function of high compliance costs, as well

as of such more basic problems as lack of state legitimacy, inadequate connection between

taxes and benefits, and perceptions of tax fairness. As a rule, in most countries some

taxpayers always pay (often because they have no choice); some always cheat; and some

cheat when they think they can get away with it. An important task of tax administration is

to prevent the mix from tipping in the direction of pervasive non-compliance. To do so, life

must not only be made more difficult for non-compliers but also easier for compliers

(Torgler 2007). It is thus important to simplify procedures for taxpayers, for example by

eliminating demands for superfluous information in tax returns and consolidating return and

payment forms. Once procedures are simplified, the tax administration can then concentrate

on its main tasks: facilitating compliance, monitoring and enforcing compliance, and

controlling corruption.

Facilitating compliance. The first task of any tax administration is to facilitate

compliance -- to make sure that those who should be in the system are in the system and

that they comply with the rules. To do so:

1. Taxpayers must be found. If they are required to register, the registration

process should be as easy as possible. Systems must be in place to identify

Page 28: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

24 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

those who do not register voluntarily. An appropriate unique taxpayer

identification system is needed to facilitate compliance and enforcement.19

2. The administration needs a process to determine tax liabilities. This may be

done administratively (as with most property taxes) or by some self-

assessment procedure (as with most income taxes and VATs).

3. Taxes must be collected. In many countries, this is best done through the

banking system. It is seldom appropriate for tax administration officials to

handle money directly.

4. The authorities should provide adequate taxpayer service in the form of

information, pamphlets, forms, advice agencies, payment facilities,

telephone and electronic filing, and so on, to make taxpayer compliance

with the system as easy as possible. There should also be a clear and

functioning system of review and appeal.

Monitoring and enforcing compliance. Since some taxpayers are not honest, a

second important task is to enforce compliance and reduce tax evasion. To do so, the

administration needs to understand the extent and nature of the potential tax base in order

to estimate the “tax gap.” Without some knowledge of the unreported base, and its

determinants, no administration can properly allocate its resources to improve tax

collection and ensure everyone bears at least a roughly fair share of the tax burden. Close

attention must also be paid to ensuring that those who are in the system file on time and

pay the amounts due. Adequate interest charges must be imposed on late payments to

ensure that non-payment of taxes does not become a cheap source of finance. Similarly, 19 Manglik (2008) suggests that India’s PAN system falls short in this respect.

Page 29: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 25

an adequate penalty structure is needed to ensure that those who should register do so,

that those who should file do so, and that those who under-report their tax bases are

sufficiently penalized to increase the costs of evading tax. All in all, as Harberger (1989)

once noted, good tax administration is not rocket science: it’s more like being a good

accountant. Unfortunately, in many countries good accountants are scarce – not least in

the tax department.

Controlling corruption. A third major task is to keep not just taxpayers but tax

collectors honest. Corruption undermines confidence in the tax system, affects

willingness to pay taxes, and reduces a country’s capacity to finance government

expenditures (Fjeldstad 2005). No government can expect taxpayers to comply willingly

if taxpayers believe the tax structure is unfair or that the revenue collected is not

effectively used. But even sound tax structure and sound expenditure policy can be

vitiated by capricious and corrupt tax administration. Developed countries took centuries

to develop and implement systems to prevent dishonest tax officials from corrupt

practices (Webber and Wildavsky 1986). Tax officials must be adequately compensated

so that they do not need to steal to live. Ideally, they should be professionally trained,

promoted on the basis of merit, and judged by their adherence to the strictest standards of

legality and morality. Temptation should be reduced by reducing direct contacts between

officials and taxpayers and reducing discretion (and increasing supervision) when they do

have such contact. Developing countries trying to sustain relatively large governments

on precarious fiscal foundations find it hard to deal with such problems.

There is no single prescription - no secret recipe - that, once adopted, will ensure

improved tax administration in any country. Countries exhibit a wide variety of tax

Page 30: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

26 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

compliance levels, reflecting not only the effectiveness of their tax administrations but also

taxpayer attitudes toward taxation and toward government in general. Attitudes affect

intentions and intentions affect behavior. Attitudes are formed in a social context by such

factors as the perceived level of evasion, the perceived fairness of the tax structure, its

complexity and stability, how it is administered, the value attached to government activities,

and the legitimacy of government. Government policies affecting any of these factors may

influence taxpayer attitudes and hence the observed level of taxpayer compliance. Measures

sometimes advisable in countries with very low compliance levels such as the massive

application of administrative penalties may be inappropriate and even have perverse effects

in countries with higher compliance levels.

The Resource Problem

The scarcity of tax administration resources is a constant in most countries. Despite

the high potential pay-off in terms of increased revenue, it is usually difficult, and often

impossible, for tax departments to obtain and retain qualified staff or even to meet such

basic material needs as office space and computers. Tax administrators are civil servants

and hence subject to all the constraints affecting civil services. Reform strategies that

require substantial additional administrative resources - particularly staff - are hence usually

doomed to failure, because the needed resources will not materialize fully or in a timely

fashion.20 Good administrative reform strategies are usually based more on the better

allocation of available resources rather than on accretions of major additional resources.

20 Salvation through reorganization is not likely to solve the problem. For example, setting up more independent revenue authorities that are to some extent freed from civil service restrictions on hiring and pay may sometimes help, but on the whole the evidence seems to suggest that any country that has the will, strategy, and resources to reform tax administration probably does not need an independent revenue

Page 31: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 27

One important improvement may simply be to reduce unproductive tasks such as

processing reams of information of which no uses is made. Another may be to create

specialized offices to deal with particular groups of taxpayers (e.g. by size or industry). Yet

another approach in some countries has been to privatize certain tax administration activities

traditionally performed by government. For example, tax collection can be out-sourced to

banks, which are specialized in the handling and control of payments. Of course, simply

entrusting banks with the task of receiving payments or returns (and even, in some countries,

processing returns) does not assure success. Proper systems must be designed, the tax

department must exercise adequate supervision and the remuneration paid to the banks must

be appropriate. Much time and effort has been spent on such matters in countries in which

collection through the banking system operates successfully.

Most recent attempts to reform tax administration center on information technology

(IT). No modern tax administration can perform its tasks efficiently without using IT, but in

some countries the expectation of greater effectiveness from computerization has not

materialized. Successful modernization efforts do not simply computerize antiquated

processes but re-engineer the whole system - for example, consolidating return and payment

forms, eliminating unnecessary and unused information required from taxpayers, and so on.

Successful computerization requires a fundamental reorganization in both systems and

procedures; it is not a way to side-step such reforms. Moreover, even the best computerized

system will not produce useful results unless there are real incentives for tax administrators

to utilize the system properly.

authority -- and a country in which these critical ingredients are lacking is unlikely to be successful even if it creates such an authority.

Page 32: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

28 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

Still, the large-scale information processing and coordination problems facing tax

administrations usually require the adoption of effective computerized processes in even

the poorest countries in such areas as (1) taxpayer records and tax collection (taxpayer

compliance); (2) internal management and control over resources; (3) legal structure and

procedures; and (4) systems to lower taxpayer compliance costs. Another reason why tax

administrations need IT expertise is simply because some of their most important clients -

- multinational companies and, increasingly, large domestic firms -- employ sophisticated

computer systems which are beyond the investigative capacity of technologically

backward tax administrations. IT is thus in a sense a ‘double-edged’ tool: in the hands of

taxpayers, it may make tax administration more difficult (especially in an open

economy); but in the hands of the administration it may enable a more robust response to

such challenges (Bird and Zolt 2007).

Conclusion

In the end, as I have recently argued elsewhere (Bird 2008), what countries do to

reform their tax systems and how successful they are generally depends less on the

economics of taxation than on the politics of taxation. Nonetheless, what we have

learned from 50 years of experience and reflection on fiscal issues in developing

countries is that what might be called the "Washington fiscal consensus" discussed in this

paper -- broader bases and lower rates -- holds up fairly well. Of course, as Alfred

Marshall once said "every short sentence about economics is inherently false."21 In the

spirit of trying to get a bit closer to what may be true, I have therefore noted some

21 The Marshall sentence – which, it should be noted, is itself short – is cited in Gardner (2006, p.7).

Page 33: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 29

qualifications to and questions about the basic BBLR approach. In addition, I have

emphasized the fundamental importance of understanding and improving tax

administration. No one can work in this field without recognizing the importance of the

administrative dimension of tax reform; too often, however, inadequate attention has

been paid to this critical aspect of the problem when thinking about tax policy in

emerging countries.

References

Auriol, E. and M.Warlters (2005) “Taxation Base in Developing Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, 89: 625-46.

Auerbach, A. J. and J.R. Hines, Jr. (2002) “Taxation and Economic Efficiency,” in A.J. Auerbach and M.Feldstein, eds., Handbook of Public Economics, 3 ( Amsterdam: North-Holland).

Bagchi, A., R.M. Bird, and A. Das-Gupta (1995) “An Economic Approach to Tax Administration Reform,” Discussion Paper No. 3, International Centre for Tax Studies, University of Toronto, November.

Bahl, R.W. and R.M. Bird (2008) “Tax Policy in Developing Countries: Looking Back – and Forward,” National Tax Journal, 61 (2): 279-301. With Roy Bahl.

Barreix, A. and J. Roca (2008)”Strengthening a Fiscal Pillar: The Uruguayan Dual Income Tax,” CEPAL Review, 92 (August): 121-40.

Bates, R.H. (2007) When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Africa (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press).

Bergman, Marcelo (2003) “Tax Reforms and Tax Compliance: The Divergent Paths of Chile and Argentina,” Journal of Latin American Studies, 35:593-624.

Bird, R. M. (2000) “Tax Incentives for Investment in Developing Countries,” in G. Perry, J. Whalley, and G. McMahon, eds., Fiscal Reform and Structural Change in Developing Countries (2 vols.; London: Macmillan for International Development Research Centre), 1, 201-21.

Bird, R.M. (2002) “Why Tax Corporations?” Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, 56 (5): 194-203.

Bird, R.M. (2008) “Tax Challenges Facing Developing Countries,” National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi, March.

Bird, R.M. and P-P. Gendron (2007) The VAT in Developing and Transitional Countries (Cambridge University Press).

Bird, R.M. and E. Slack (2004) International Handbook of Land and Property Taxation (Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar).

Bird, R.M. and S.Wallace (2004) “Is It Really so Hard to tax the Hard-to-Tax? The Context and Role of Presumptive Taxes,” in J. Alm, J.Martinez-Vazquez and S. Wallace, eds., Taxing the Hard-to-Tax: Lessons from Theory and Practice (Amsterdam: North-Holland)

Bird, R.M. and E.M. Zolt (2005) “Redistribution via Taxation: The Limited Role of the Personal Income Tax in Developing Countries,” UCLA Law Review, 52 (6, 2005): 1627-95

Bird, R.M. and E.M. Zolt (2007) “Technology and Taxation in Developing Countries: From Hand to Mouse,” Paper presented at Conference on Technology, Privacy and the Future of Taxation, Washington, D.C.

Boadway, R.W. (2005) “Income Tax Reform for a Globalized World: The Case for a Dual Income Tax,” Journal of Asian Economics, 16: 910-27.

Page 34: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

30 International Studies Program Working Paper Series

Brautigam, D., O. Fjeldstad, and M. Moore (2007) Taxation and State-Building in Developing Countries (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press).

Chattopadhyay, S. and A. Das Gupta, “The Compliance Cost of the Personal Income Tax and its Determinants,” National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi, 2002

Chu, K., H. Davoodi, and S. Gupta (2000) “Income Distribution and Tax and Government Social Spending Policies in Developing Countries,” Working Papers No. 214, UNU/WIDER, December.

Cnossen, S. ed., (2006) Excise Tax Policy and Administration (Pretoria: UNISA Press) Easterly, W. (2002) The Elusive Quest for Growth (Cambridge MA: MIT Press). Emran, M. S. and J.E. Stiglitz (2005) “On Selective Indirect Tax Reform in Developing Countries,”

Journal of Public Economics, 89: 599-623. Fjeldstad, O-H. (2005) “Corruption in Tax Administration: Lessons from Institutional Reforms in Uganda,”

WP 2005:10, CMI Working Paper, Bergen. Gallagher, M. (2004) “Benchmarking Tax Systems,” Public Administration and Development, 25 : 125-44. Gardner, M. (2006) Aha! A Two Volume Collection: Aha! Gotcha. Aha! Insight (Washington DC:

Mathematical Association of America). Gemmell, N. and O. Morrissey (2003) “Tax Structure and the Incidence on the Poor in Developing

Countries,” Centre for Research on Economic Development and International Trade Research paper No. 03/18, University of Nottingham, October

Glenday, G. and D. Hollinrake (2005) “Assessment of the Current State of VAT Implementation in SADC Member States,” November.

Gordon, R. and W. Li (2005) “Tax Structure in Developing Countries: Many Puzzles and A Possible Explanation,” Working Paper 11267, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA, April.

Harberger, A.C. (1989) “Lessons of Tax Reform from the Experiences of Uruguay, Indonesia, and Chile,” in M. Gillis, ed., Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Durham NC: Duke University Press).

Harberger, A.C. (2006) “Taxation and Income Distribution: Myths and Realities,” in J. Alm, J. Martinez-Vazquez and M.Rider, eds., The Challenges of Tax Reform in a Global Economy (New York: Springer)

Hood, C. (1976) The Limits of Administration (New York: Wiley). Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) (2006) The Politics of Policies (Washington) Lindert, P.H. (2003) Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth Since the Eighteenth Century

(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Manglik, G. (2008) “Using Technology to Reduce Income Tax Evasion in India.” Tax Notes

International, 50 (8, May 26): 705-714.. Mintz, Jack M. (2006) The 2006 Tax Competitiveness Report: Proposals for Pro-Growth Tax Reform.

(Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute). OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2006) “Reforming Personal Income

Tax,” Policy Brief, March. Radian, A. (1980) Resource Mobilization in Poor Countries: Implementing Tax Reform (New Brunswick

NJ: Transaction Books) Schneider, F. and R. Klinglmair (2004) “Shadow Economies Around the World: What Do We Know?”

Working Paper No. 0408, Department of Economics, Johannes Kepler University of Linz, April. Shah, A. and J. Whalley (1990) “Tax Incidence Analysis of Developing Countries: An Alternative View,”

World Bank Economic Review, 5: 535-52. Shoup, C.S. (1965) “Production from Consumption,” Public Finance, 20 (2): 175-202. Shoup, C.S. (1991) “Melding Architecture and Engineering: A Personal Retrospective on Designing Tax

Systems,” in Lorraine. Eden, ed., Retrospectives on Public Finance (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 1991)

Shekidele, C. (1999) “Measuring the Compliance Cost of Taxation. Excise Duties 1995-96,” African Journal of Finance and Management, 7 (2): 72-84

Slemrod, J. (1992) Why People Pay Taxes (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press) Slemrod, J. and E. Bakija (1996) Taxing Ourselves: A Citizen’s Guide to the Great Debate on Tax Reform

(Cambridge MA: MIT Press) Slemrod, J. and S. Yitzhaki (2002) “ Tax Avoidance, Evasion, and Administration,” in Alan J. Auerbach

and Martin Feldstein, eds., Handbook of Public Economics, vol. 3 (New York: Elsevier Science) Torgler, B. (2007) Tax Compliance and Tax Morale: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis (Cheltenham,

UK and Northampton MA: Edward Elgar).

Page 35: The BBLR Approach to Tax ReformBBLR Approach to Tax Reform ...icepp.gsu.edu/files/2015/03/ispwp0804.pdf · 1 The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries Richard M. Bird

The BBLR Approach to Tax Reform in Emerging Countries 31

Vazquez-Caro, J., G. Reid and R.M. Bird (1992) Tax Administration Assessment in Latin America. Latin America and Caribbean Technical Department, Regional Studies Program, Report No. 13. (Washington: World Bank).

Warlters, Michael and Emmanuelle Auriol (2005) “The Marginal Cost of Public Funds in Africa,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3679, August.

Webber, C. and A. Wildavsky (1986) A History of Taxation and Expenditure in the Western World (New York: Simon and Shuster)

World Bank (1991) Lessons of Tax Reform (Washington). World Bank and International Finance Corporation (2008) Paying Taxes 2008. Washington, DC.