24
What Is European Integration Really About? A Political Guide for Economists* Enrico Spolaore Tufts University and NBER June 2013 Abstract Europe’s monetary union is part of a broader process of integration that started in the aftermath of World War II. In this “political guide for economists” we look at the creation of the euro within the bigger picture of European integration. How and why were European institutions established? What are the goals and determinants of European Integration? What is European integration really about? We address these questions from a political-economy perspective, building on ideas and results from the economic literature on the formation of states and political unions. Specifically, we look at the motivations, assumptions, and limitations of the European strategy, initiated by Jean Monnet and his collaborators, of partially integrating policy functions in a few areas, with the expectation that more integration will follow in other areas, in a sort of chain reaction towards an “ever-closer union.” The euro with its current problems is a child of that strategy and its limits. *Acknowledgements: I am grateful to Jeff Frieden, Yannis Ioannides, Deborah Menegotto, Stelios Michalopoulos, Romain Wacziarg, and the editors of the Journal of Economic Perspectives (David Autor, Chang-Tai Hseih, and Tim Taylor) for their detailed comments. I also benefited from helpful feedback and conversations with many people, including Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi, Giancarlo Corsetti, Henrik Enderlein, Kai Konrad, Athanasios Orphanides, Lucas Papademos, and Daniela Schwarzer, and participants in the political economy discussion group at Harvard and a conference at the Condorcet Center for Political Economy in Rennes. Of course I am the only one responsible for all opinions and errors in this paper.

What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

What Is European Integration Really About?

A Political Guide for Economists*

Enrico Spolaore

Tufts University and NBER

June 2013

Abstract

Europe’s monetary union is part of a broader process of integration that started in the aftermath

of World War II. In this “political guide for economists” we look at the creation of the euro

within the bigger picture of European integration. How and why were European institutions

established? What are the goals and determinants of European Integration? What is European

integration really about? We address these questions from a political-economy perspective,

building on ideas and results from the economic literature on the formation of states and

political unions. Specifically, we look at the motivations, assumptions, and limitations of the

European strategy, initiated by Jean Monnet and his collaborators, of partially integrating

policy functions in a few areas, with the expectation that more integration will follow in other

areas, in a sort of chain reaction towards an “ever-closer union.” The euro with its current

problems is a child of that strategy and its limits.

*Acknowledgements: I am grateful to Jeff Frieden, Yannis Ioannides, Deborah Menegotto,

Stelios Michalopoulos, Romain Wacziarg, and the editors of the Journal of Economic

Perspectives (David Autor, Chang-Tai Hseih, and Tim Taylor) for their detailed comments. I

also benefited from helpful feedback and conversations with many people, including Lorenzo

Bini-Smaghi, Giancarlo Corsetti, Henrik Enderlein, Kai Konrad, Athanasios Orphanides, Lucas

Papademos, and Daniela Schwarzer, and participants in the political economy discussion group

at Harvard and a conference at the Condorcet Center for Political Economy in Rennes. Of course

I am the only one responsible for all opinions and errors in this paper.

Page 2: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

1

As an economic and financial crisis unfolds across the European Union, critics argue that

European institutional integration has gone too far, blame misguided political motivations, and

assert that the monetary union has failed (for example, Feldstein 2012). On the other side,

supporters of European integration attribute the euro crisis to institutional incompleteness—

what Bergsten (2011) called a “half-built house.” They argue that the solution to Europe’s woes

should be sought in additional integration: a banking union, a fiscal union, or perhaps even a

full political union and the formation of a federation.

Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa (2004, p. 1), the economist and central banker who played a key role

in the birth of the euro, wrote: “[T]he euro was the result of a long-term development that

started in the aftermath of World War II. After experiencing political oppression and war in the

first half of the twentieth century, Europe undertook to build a new order for peace, freedom,

and prosperity. Despite its predominantly economic content, the European Union is an

eminently political construct. Even readers primarily interested in economics would hardly

understand the euro if they ignored its political dimension.”

This political guide for economists takes a step back and looks at the creation of the euro within

the bigger picture of European integration. How and why were European institutions

established? What is European integration really about?

The history of European integration is complicated, with a big cast of actors including

governments, technocrats, interest groups, and voters, who in turn pursue a range of economic

and political goals. This complexity is reflected in a variety of interpretations by political

scientists and political economists (for overviews, see Gilpin 2001, chapter 13; Eichengreen

2006; and Sadeh and Verdun 2009). This article discusses facts and theories about European

integration from a political-economy perspective, building on ideas and results from the

economic literature on the formation of states and political union (for overviews, see Spolaore

2006, 2012). Specifically, we look at the motivations, assumptions, and limitations of the

European strategy of partially integrating policy functions in a few areas, with the expectation

that more integration will follow in other areas, in a sort of chain reaction towards an “ever-

closer union.” The euro with its current problems is a child of that strategy and its limits.

A European Federation?

The idea of a new sovereign federation across Europe goes back a long time, but it received a

big push from the first half of the twentieth century. At the end of World War II, the promoters

of European integration looked back at the previous decades and saw a continent fragmented in

independent and unconstrained nation states, which had pursed costly beggar-thy-neighbor

policies during the Great Depression and engaged in two major wars. The goal of European

Page 3: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

2

integration was to create a system where nation states would no longer follow such unilateral

and destructive policies.

In 1943 a group led by Altiero Spinelli founded the European Federalist Movement. In 1946,

Winston Churchill argued for the creation of “the United States of Europe” (which in his view

did not include Britain). By definition, a federation would have eliminated national borders and

international conflict (but not civil conflict) among Europeans. However, no European

federation was created immediately after World War II.

Instead, the founding document of European integration is the Schuman declaration of May 9,

1950, named after France’s foreign minister Robert Schuman and inspired by Jean Monnet, a

businessman and civil servant who played a crucial role in starting European institutions in the

following years. The declaration proposed that “Franco-German production of coal and steel as

a whole be placed under a common High Authority, within the framework of an organization

open to the participation of the other countries of Europe.” The plan was motivated by security,

as a way “to make it plain that any war between France and Germany becomes not merely

unthinkable, but materially impossible.” The pooling of coal and steel production was

ambitiously defined as “a first step in the federation of Europe.”

The Schumann declaration led in 1951 to the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC)

among six countries.1 The ECSC was then used as the institutional template for two proposed

communities: the European Defense Community and the European Political Community, which

included the formation of a common army, a common budget, and common institutions with

significant legislative and executive powers. It would have basically amounted to a European

federation (Moravcsik 1998; Rector 2009). A treaty was signed among the six countries in 1952

but failed to obtain ratification in the French parliament, and never took effect. In 1955 several

politicians, including Jean Monnet, created an “Action Committee for the United States of

Europe.” But, again, no United States of Europe actually formed.2

The fundamental reasons behind these failures to form a federation have bedeviled the

supporters of a United States of Europe, then and since. There are two issues which are key to

understanding the beginning of the integration process, its setbacks, and the following path of

European integration. One issue is a general problem in political economy: the trade-off

between costs and benefits when heterogeneous groups are politically integrated under a

common authority. The other issue involves the particular role of Germany, the country that

played a central role in World Wars I and II.

1 France, West Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Belgium, and Luxembourg. 2 Subsequent less ambitious attempts to integrate European defense and foreign policy have not been very successful either. For

instance, see Alesina and Perotti (2004) for a critical discussion of the more recent experience of the European Union in these and

other areas.

Page 4: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

3

The Political Economy of Heterogeneous Populations

The formation of a European federation across heterogeneous populations, which share diverse

social and economic structures, languages, cultures and identities, would come with several

benefits but also with high costs. The trade-off between such costs and benefits is central to the

political feasibility and stability of institutional integration among those populations (Alesina

and Spolaore 1997, 2003).

Potential benefits from full political unification include economies of scale in the provision of

federal public goods, such as defense and security, and the ability to internalize positive and

negative externalities over a large area. A European federation with its own budget and

redistribution policies could also provide insurance against asymmetric shocks that only affect

some of its regions, whether natural, like an earthquake, or man-made, like the bursting of a

housing bubble. These benefits from fiscal federalism are often stressed when comparing

Europe to the United States (for example, Sachs and Sala-i-Martin 1992; Krugman 2012), and

are now at the forefront of the debate about the European sovereign debt crisis (Lane 2012).

However, political unification comes with significant costs when various groups speak different

languages, share different cultural norms and identities, and have different preferences for

public policies and institutions that cannot be decentralized at the sub-federal level (Alesina and

Spolaore 1997, 2003). Among those institutions is the ultimate “public good”: the federal

government itself, with all its constitutional and legal traits, policies, official language(s), and so

on, about which German or Dutch people may have very different views from those prevalent in

France or Italy.

A growing literature has explored the links between measures of heterogeneity and political

outcomes, such as the provision of public goods, the extent of redistribution, the quality of

government, and the likelihood of civil and international conflict. Microeconomic evidence

links ethnic heterogeneity to underprovision of public goods at the local level (Alesina and La

Ferrara 2005). There is also macroeconomic evidence of negative correlations between

ethnolinguistic fractionalization and government performance, although causality and

robustness are less clear-cut (Alesina et al. 2003). In addition, Montalvo and Reynal-Querol

(2005) and Esteban, Mayoral and Ray (2012) find that ethnolinguistic polarization is associated

with civil conflict. Desmet, Ortuño-Ortín and Weber (2009) show that once distances between

languages are accounted for, linguistic diversity has a significant negative effect on

redistribution. Desmet, Ortuño-Ortín and Wacziarg (2012) find that deep linguistic distances are

good predictors of civil conflict and redistribution, while even finer distinctions between

languages, such as those among different dialects, matter for economic growth and public goods

provision. The bottom line of this literature is that measures of ethnic, linguistic, and cultural

diversity have significant effects on policy outcomes, redistribution, and the provision of public

Page 5: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

4

goods. A European federation would be quite heterogeneous by most of these measures, and

likely to face significant political costs when choosing common public goods and policies at the

federal level.3

The example of defense and security – which played a fundamental role in Europe’s early

attempts to integrate - can serve to illustrate these issues. These are public goods with high

economies of scale, but also high heterogeneity costs stemming from diverse preferences across

populations. Military power has historically been a central tool to ensure a government’s

monopoly of legitimate use of coercion over a territory. Integration of defense and security

under one authority usually goes hand in hand with the centralization of this monopoly of

coercion – that is, with the formation of a sovereign state or federation (Alesina and Spolaore

2003). However, different populations with different histories, cultures and identities are likely

to disagree over the type of government in charge of such a federation. Moreover, coercion can

then be used to finance a larger set of other public goods and redistribute resources across

different groups. This redistribution is more likely to be resisted when groups are different not

only economically but also along ethnic and linguistic lines. For instance, Western Germans

may be more willing (or less unwilling) to redistribute resources to Eastern Germans than to

Greeks or Italians. Consequently, centralized provision of defense and security across large and

diverse populations usually takes place when dictatorial rulers are able to ignore the

heterogeneity costs of the populations they conquer, and/or when there are overwhelming

benefits of scale from defense that offset high heterogeneity costs (Alesina and Spolaore 2005,

2006). The two most successful federal republics, Switzerland and the United States, emerged

in response to external security threats, and the unification of Germany in the nineteenth century

resulted from conquest by Prussia (Riker 1964; Gilpin 2001).

Military and political union is not the only way to deal with security threats. Heterogeneous

sovereign states can benefit from economies of scale in defense by forming military alliances,

while still maintaining their political and fiscal independence. But military alliances, where

each state can autonomously decide its own level of military spending and pay for it, can lead to

undersupply of defense from the perspective of the whole alliance because of free riding (for a

discussion, Spolaore 2012). Western Europeans failed to form a federation even when faced

with an existential threat from the Soviet Union, and relied instead on an international alliance

(NATO), where issues of undersupply and free riding were in part addressed by the dominant

role of the United States.

If heterogeneity can explain failures to integrate in the past, does it need to be an obstacle to

future political integration? Over time, couldn’t a federal Europe change political and social

3Fractionalization is maximized when each individual belongs to a different group, while polarization is maximized when there are

only two large groups of equal size. A larger European federation formed by many groups would be more fractionalized but less

polarized than a smaller federation dominated by a couple of groups (e.g., Germans and French).

Page 6: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

5

interactions and affect cultures and identities among Europeans, leading to a shared identity

within a “European nation”? After all, nineteenth century France famously turned “peasants into

Frenchmen” through public policies and modernization (Weber 1976).

This question is part of the broader debate on the persistent political and economic effects of

historical and cultural traits, and the extent that culture itself can be changed by policies and

institutions (for recent discussions, Bisin and Verdier 2010; Spolaore and Wacziarg 2013).4 In

the long run, people can learn new languages, modify their cultural traits and identities, and

transmit different traits to their children in response to changing incentives, including public

policies. However, it is at best a gamble to hope that political integration of modern democratic

nations will lead to cultural integration. Historically, nation-building and attempts to

“homogenize” populations were implemented by rulers of undemocratic societies who had an

interest at reducing heterogeneity costs in order to maximize their own rents (Alesina and

Spolaore 2003, pp. 76-78) or pursue their own preferences (Alesina and Reich 2013). Realistic

supporters of European integration understand that convergence of political preferences through

reduction of linguistic and cultural barriers, if it is going to occur at all, will be a slow and

gradual process, which should take place naturally and consensually.

For Europeans, heterogeneity has been a source of benefits as well as of costs. When people

have different preferences and traits, societies can benefit economically and culturally through

specialization, learning, and exchange of goods and services, as well as ideas and innovations.

Benefits from heterogeneity, however, are mostly about interactions over rival goods, not public

goods. Similar preferences over the same rival goods can lead closely related groups to conflict

and war (Spolaore and Wacziarg, 2012), while different preferences over rival goods can

facilitate peaceful exchanges and a better allocation of resources. In contrast, diverse

preferences over public goods are much harder to reconcile, because public goods are non-rival

by definition: all citizens of a federation must share that federation’s government, laws and

public policies, whether they like them or not. As a result, heterogeneity of preferences is

mostly beneficial when people interact about rival goods but costly when sharing non-rival

goods. This is an important reason why, as we will see, the European project has been much

more successful when fostering economic exchanges and a common market, while it has stalled

when attempting to pool “federal” public goods, such as defense and security.

The Role of Germany

In hindsight, as we look back at the 1952 treaty that would have established a European Defense

Community and a European Political Community, what’s perhaps more surprising is not that

France rejected it, but that the other states ratified the treaty. A reason is that the other two

4 There is also an extensive political literature debating whether the social and political relevance of ethnic and linguistic divisions

can be altered by politics and institutional change (for a discussion, Fearon 2006).

Page 7: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

6

largest states at that time, West Germany and Italy, had just emerged from a severe military

defeat, and faced significant constraints to their own defense and foreign policy. West Germany

was the more extreme case: a divided country, technically under military occupation until 1955.

In those circumstances, the costs of constraints on German sovereignty by pooling defense and

security were low and could be traded against other political and economic benefits. As

Germany’s status as a sovereign state “normalized” over time, its incentives to join a security-

based federal union decreased.

The agreement for a European Coal and Steel Community is often interpreted from a similar

perspective. According to Milward (1984), France proposed the coal and steel community to

constrain German control of its own industry, in response to U.S. plans in 1949 to allow a

Germany relatively free of allied supervision. Germany agreed to the Schuman plan because, by

sharing management of its coal and steel, it could obtain important concessions, such as “the

removal of ceilings on permissible levels of industrial production” (Eichengreen 2006, p, 802).

According to Berger and Ritschl (1995), French access to German coal was “the most important

element of the Monnet Plan for France's reconstruction.”

These examples illustrate a continuing issue in the history and politics of European integration:

the extent to which European supranational institutions can be interpreted as tools to constrain

German power in the interest of its neighbors, especially France. This theme has come to the

forefront again with the creation of the euro. A popular view is that giving up its currency was

the price that Germany had to pay to overcome France’s opposition to German reunification

(Garrett, 1993; Marsh 2011), a deal summarized by the witticism quoted by Garton Ash (2012,

p. 6): “[T]he whole of Deutschland for Kohl, half the deutsche mark for Mitterrand.” Literally

taken, as a quid pro quo, this interpretation is not held by most scholars (Sadeh and Verdun

2009). It is questionable that a French threat to veto the reunification of Germany could be

credible. Moreover, key decisions about the single currency had already been taken before the

fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989, and German politicians and interest groups (like exporters) had

other strong reasons to favor a monetary union (Moravcsik 1998; Frieden 2002).

However, it is not fully coincidental that the implementation of the euro took place during and

right after German reunification and the opening of political and economic relations between

Western and Eastern Europe. Germany’s chancellor at that time, Helmut Kohl, viewed the euro

as a big step in the broader process of European integration, which he considered essential to

reassure Germany’s neighbors about his enlarged country’s commitments to peace, security,

and economic cooperation (Garton Ash 2012). And even though the process leading to

economic and monetary union had started before the fall of the Berlin Wall, a detailed analysis

of the interactions among key participants in the negotiations show that German reunification

Page 8: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

7

led to a reassessment of the relative payoffs from economic and monetary union, and was

“use[d] to reshape […] negotiations” (Dyson and Featherstone 1999, p. 16).

The increase in Germany’s potential power might also have affected the borders of the future

euro area, making it much larger than predicted by efficiency criteria, such as the theory of

Optimum Currency Areas. For example, Eichengreen (2012, p. 125) mentions the view that

France and others pushed for the inclusion of many countries at the “periphery,” like Southern

Mediterranean countries, to “balance” Germany’s larger size and influence within the monetary

union.

Whether these Realpolitik interpretations are fully persuasive, the French government saw a

close link between German reunification and European integration. According to an adviser to

the French President, "Mitterrand did not want [German] reunification without advances toward

greater European integration, and the currency was the only topic that was open to debate"

(Spiegel, 2010).

How had a monetary issue become “the next step” in the process of European integration? What

was (and is) such a process about? To answer these questions we need to go back to what

happened after the rejection of the defense and political communities in the mid-1950s.

From the Common Market to Economic and Monetary Union: Jean Monnet’s Chain

Reaction?

From the successful creation of the European Coal and Steel Community and the rejection of

the European Defense Community, Jean Monnet and the other supporters of European

integration learned a lesson in political realism (Duchêne 1992). Partial integration in narrowly

defined areas, such as coal and steel, was feasible, while more ambitious integration in broader

areas such as defense and policy coordination would meet too much political opposition. Their

next step was the creation in 1957 of a community similar to ECSC for civilian atomic energy

(EURATOM), and, more importantly, a European Economic Community (EEC) to set up a

customs union: the “common market.” The institutions of the three communities were later

merged and became known as the European Community. The treaties of Maastricht (1992) and

Lisbon (2009) reorganized and replaced the European Community with the European Union.

The Treaty of Rome of 1957 establishing the European common market no longer referred to

steps “toward a federation,” but included the vaguer objective of laying the “foundations of an

ever-closer union among the peoples of Europe.” The signatories’ main stated goal was “to

ensure the economic and social progress of their countries by common action to eliminate the

barriers which divide Europe,” while claiming that this would strengthen peace and security. To

foster those goals, European states created two sets of institutions: supranational institutions

Page 9: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

8

such as the European Commission, Parliament, and Court of Justice, and intergovernmental

institutions, such as the Council of Ministers and, later, the European Council, formed by the

heads of state or government of the member states.

Over time, policy functions have been delegated to European institutions in an increasing range

of areas. Nonetheless, national governments have kept control over fundamental decisions, and

must decide unanimously on all changes to the international treaties that set Europe’s informal

“constitution.” An attempt to establish a formal “Constitution for Europe” failed when it was

rejected by French and Dutch voters in 2005.

The history of European integration reflects this tension between the role of supranational

institutions and the power of national governments. The conflict is also mirrored by the two

most influential political theories about European integration: functionalism and

intergovernmentalism. This terminology is rather confusing for the uninitiated.5 In a nutshell,

the theories are distinguished by how they answer the question: who is in charge of European

integration?

Intergovernmentalists believe that national governments are in charge, and that supranational

institutions are tools of the national states, which use them to pursue their own goals. Moravcsik

(1993, 1998), an influential proponent of this theory, believes that national governments have

built European institutions in order to pursue the economic interests of their domestic

constituencies. In this spirit, Moravcsik (2012) views the euro as an economic gamble, mostly

reflecting the interests of powerful national producers. This interpretation fits within a broader

literature emphasizing the link from domestic economic interests to national attitudes and

policies towards European integration (for example, Frieden 1998, 2002). The political-

economy approach to regional integration based on domestic economic interests is familiar to

the economics profession, and therefore I will not say more here. I will focus instead on the

alternative theory of functionalism, which is much less known among economists, even though

it has played a significant role in the ideology and practice of European integration and the

creation of the euro.

Functionalists believe that European integration is not primarily driven by national governments

and their voters, but mostly pushed by elites and interest groups that transcend national

boundaries. They stress the role of supranational entrepreneurs and civil servants like Jean

Monnet in the 1950s and Jacques Delors in the 1980s and 1990s. The theory is called

“functionalism” because it is about the dynamic effects of transferring specific “functions” to

5 The jargon is furthermore complicated by “neo” prefixes and other qualifications. Haas (1957,1964), the father of the functionalist

approach to European integration, called his theory “neo-functionalism,” to distinguish it from a previous theory of international

cooperation developed by David Mitrany. Moravcsik (1993, 1998) calls his approach “liberal intergovernmentalism” to distinguish it

from “realist” theories that also place national states at the center of the analysis, but emphasize power and interstate rivalry rather

than domestic economic interests. In this article I only use the simpler terms.

Page 10: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

9

supranational institutions – for example, regulation of coal and steel production to the European

Coal and Steel Community or monetary policy to the European Central Bank. Although this

integration starts in economic areas, integration in one area may well lead to further integration

in many other areas, not only economic but also political (Haas 1957, 1964; Pierson 1996;

Sandholtz and Stone Sweet 1998). In sum, while intergovernmentalists believe that European

integration is rooted in the pursuit of national economic interests, functionalists believe that it is

about economic integration as a path towards political integration.

The theory of functionalism was directly inspired by Jean Monnet’s strategy to delegate specific

functions to supranational institutions in relatively narrow areas, mostly technical and

economic, with the expectation that it would lead to more institutional integration in other areas

over time. Functionalists believe that moving only some policy functions to the supranational

level, while leaving other functions at the national level, creates pressure for more integration

through positive and negative mechanisms. A positive mechanism would work through

learning: as politicians and interest groups observe the benefits of integrating a few functions,

they will want more. This idea is implicit in the Schumann declaration, stating “Europe will not

be made all at once, or according to a single plan. It will be built through concrete

achievements.” Another positive mechanism is assumed to work by changing people’s

preferences. As groups cooperate on specific functions, barriers to communication and

interaction would decline, which would bring an “endogenous” convergence of values and

norms and a demand for more integration. This rather optimistic outlook was inspired by Karl

Deutsch’s (1964) influential research on communication theory and political integration.

A darker mechanism through which partial integration could lead to more integration is,

paradoxically, by generating problems and crises. Because integration is only partial, important

complementary functions are missing at each step. For the functionalists, such incompleteness

is not a bug but a feature, because it creates pressure for further integration. Monnet’s method

was explained by his collaborator George Ball (1994, p. 10):

“There was a well-conceived method in this apparent madness. All of us working with

Jean Monnet well understood how irrational it was to carve a limited economic sector

out of the jurisdiction of national governments and subject that sector to the sovereign

control of supranational institutions. Yet, with his usual perspicacity, Monnet recognized

that the very irrationality of this scheme might provide the pressure to achieve exactly

what he wanted - the triggering of a chain reaction. The awkwardness and complexity

resulting from the singling out of coal and steel would drive member governments to

accept the idea of pooling other production as well.”

Page 11: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

10

A challenge for this story is to explain why national politicians don’t anticipate Monnet’s chain

reaction. Implicit assumptions here are that integration is irreversible, and that national

politicians or voters would prefer limited integration to either more integration or no

integration. But then, if politicians see that limited integration will lead to more integration, they

should either agree to the outcome of more integration right away, or they should object to

starting the process at all. What factors could allow elites and supranational technocrats to move

ahead with initiatives leading to outcomes that national politicians or voters would not have

approved in advance? A first possible explanation proposed by functionalists is that national

politicians have short horizons: they approve the first step, but do not care about the next steps.

A second explanation is asymmetric information. The initial steps of functional integration are

taken in narrow and technical areas, such as coal and steel in the 1950s or, later, anti-trust

regulations and monetary issues. In those matters, national politicians and voters are much less

informed than technocrats, political elites, and supranational entrepreneurs. Hence, it is difficult

for them to monitor these agents and anticipate the consequences of their actions (Pierson 1996;

see Eichengreen 2006 for a discussion). A third, even less flattering reason why the mechanism

may work is that European supranational institutions and bureaucracies have been set up (on

purpose?) with little democratic accountability—the so-called “democratic deficit”—reducing

the opportunities of national voters to monitor the technocrats (for a discussion, Alesina and

Spolaore 2003, chapter 12).

Functionalism was the dominant theory of European integration in the 1950s and 1960s, then

came to seem less plausible (Haas 1975) following a series of political setbacks to integration.

A major setback was the “Empty Chair Crisis,” when French President Charles de Gaulle

boycotted European institutions because he objected to their plans for more supranational

integration. The crisis was resolved in a truly “intergovernmentalist” way with the Luxembourg

compromise of 1966, in which de facto veto power was given to every member state on issues

of “very important national interest.” However, the functionalist view returned in fashion with

the revival of European integration in the 1980s and 1990s when Jacques Delors was head of

the European Commission. Functionalism continues to be very influential not only

academically but also among European policy-makers and supranational civil servants (perhaps

not surprisingly, given that they play the main role according to the theory).

In 1992 the members of the European Community signed a Treaty on European Union at

Maastricht, which reorganized European institutions and designed an Economic and Monetary

Union (EMU),6 establishing the institutional foundations for the euro. Jacques Delors and his

6 “EMU” is a confusing acronym. It does not stay for “European Monetary Union” (a widespread and understandable confusion).

Instead, it means “Economic and Monetary Union,” including both the monetary union and the single market (for the official

definition, http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/euro/emu/). In the 1990s, some even referred to EMU as short-hand for the whole

Maastricht agreement, which included several other provisions besides those about economic and monetary union. In contrast, many

now use EMU in a narrower sense, only for the monetary union. Given such ambiguities, I avoid the acronym EMU and spell out

“economic and monetary union” whenever possible in this article.

Page 12: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

11

Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, also known as the “Delors

Committee,” played a crucial role, as documented in a detailed analysis of the negotiations

leading to the economic and monetary union (Dyson and Featherstone, 1999). The design and

rationale for the European economic and monetary union, as laid out in official documents and

studies (Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, 1989; Commission of the

European Communities, 1990), was deeply influenced by the functionalist view of European

integration (Sadeh and Verdun 2009, p. 283).

An important functionalist argument was based on the “inconsistent quartet:” the mutual

incompatibility of free trade, mobility of capital, fixed exchange rates, and independence of

national monetary policies (Padoa-Schioppa 2004). Assuming that fixed exchange rates were

essential for Europe’s single market, then moving from commercial integration to liberalization

of capital movements had to lead to the loss of national monetary autonomy.7 In fact, Padoa-

Schioppa (2004, p. 14), one of the architects of the economic and monetary union and key

member of the Delors Committee, explained the path to the euro in terms that explicitly echoed

the chain-reaction metaphor:

“[T]he road toward the single currency looks like a chain reaction in which each step

resolved a preexisting contradiction and generated a new one that in turn required a

further step forward. The steps were the start of the EMS [European monetary system]

(1979), the re-launching of the single market (1985), the decision to accelerate the

liberalization of capital movements (1986), the launching of the project of monetary

union (1988), the agreement of Maastricht (1992), and the final adoption of the euro

(1998).”

Also, in the functionalist tradition, each step in this chain reaction was viewed as irreversible. A

joke attributed to Padoa-Schioppa refers to how EMU, the economic and monetary union, like

the Australian bird with the same name, could not walk backward.

Not only was the path to the euro explained in functionalist terms from a technical perspective,

but was also viewed, in Schumann and Monnet’s tradition, as “a further step—and as a

prerequisite for yet other steps—in the political unification of Europe” (Padoa-Schioppa 2004,

p. 6). Wim Duisenberg, the first President of the European Central Bank, said (as quoted in Van

Overtveldt 2011, p. 63): “EMU is, and was always meant to be a stepping stone on the way to a

united Europe.” German Chancellor Helmut Kohl famously said in 1991 (as quoted in Marsh

2011, p. 301): "It is absurd to expect in the long run that you can maintain economic and

monetary union without political union."

7 Fixed exchange rates were viewed as essential for free trade within Europe not only for economic reasons, but also and perhaps

chiefly for political reasons, because of the fear that competitive devaluations could trigger a protectionist policy reaction by other

member states, leading to the eventual unraveling of the single market (Eichengreen and Frieden 2001, pp. 12-13).

Page 13: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

12

From the perspective of Monnet’s method, such an “absurd” economic and monetary union

without political union should create pressures for still more integration. The euro area lacked

many institutions historically associated with a successful monetary union: for example, a

central bank that could really act as market maker and lender of last resort, a banking union, and

a fiscal union. But this incompleteness could be rationalized as a natural and unavoidable

feature of partial integration in the functionalist tradition. Even though present political

constraints prevented the immediate implementation of a more comprehensive design, the

launching of an “incomplete” monetary union would set the steps for further integration in due

course, as predicted by functionalist theories. For example, people would learn with time about

the large benefits from economic and monetary union and ask for more integration in other

areas. Also, supporters of the euro embraced two arguments mirroring the long-standing

functionalist view that preferences and behavior endogenously converge following integration.

One argument was that regions become economically more homogeneous after they share a

common currency (Frankel and Rose 1998).8 Secondly, the economic and monetary union was

supposed to provide discipline to governments, including those that used to pursue erratic

policies. As a result, all member states would eventually converge to common values and

policies emphasizing macroeconomic stability. Supranational institutions could provide the

necessary sanctions if national governments deviated from agreed rules of stability. No-bailout

rules would also be enforced. If, in spite of these positive effects and precautions, future crises

were to occur, they could be resolved with more institutional integration.

Assuming that such logic could really work – and events of the last few years certainly sound a

skeptical note - where would Monnet’s chain reaction lead to in the long run? Jean Monnet

himself was ambiguous about his long-term vision of European integration (Hoffmann 1966;

Duchêne 1992). He oscillated between two visions. One was the original federalist dream of the

United States of Europe, in which Europe was an “incomplete federation” to be completed. The

other vision was of a “post-modern” world where traditional sovereign states, including classic

federations like the United States of America, would play a marginal role compared to

supranational institutions and norms, which would represent a novel way to organize

interdependence among individuals and groups: Europe as a “post-federation.” This same

ambiguity is present in the conflicting views about the euro among its supporters: is it a

currency without a state yet, or is it a currency without a state ever?

The Limits to Monnet’s Chain Reaction

Since the Schumann declaration of 1950 which launched the Monnet strategy of partial

integration, European institutions have grown from a coal and steel community of six countries

to a European Union of 28 countries (as of summer 2013), building along the way a customs

8 In contrast, the anti-functionalist argument that integration can lead to specialization and more heterogeneity (Krugman and

Venables, 1996) received much less attention in Brussels.

Page 14: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

13

union, a single market, an economic and monetary union, and much more. This list of

achievements has brought several benefits, to which we will return. Nonetheless, the

“functionalist” view, deeply embodied in the ideology and practice of the European Union, that

each step is part of a chain reaction leading to ever closer integration has serious limitations.

As a starting point, the functionalist emphasis on the rising power and autonomy of

supranational institutions compared to national governments must be taken with a grain of salt.

National governments do agree to delegate responsibilities to supranational institutions as

commitment devices to achieve collective goals which are in each government’s long-term

interest. To be credible, those institutions must have some autonomous power and

independence; the rules for the autonomy of the European Central Bank come to mind. In

addition, as in all complex organizations, supranational agents cannot be perfectly monitored by

their principals (in this case, national governments and voters), and some principal-agent slack

always exist. However, none of this means that Europe’s supranational institutions can go very

far against the ultimate interests of national governments. While supranational institutions and

procedures are important in the day-by-day working of Europe, they “could not work for a week

in the absence of the will to cooperate of the member states, especially the largest ones –

Germany and France above all” (Gilbert 2012, p. 3).

A well-known illustration of how centralized discipline does not work when ultimate power is

in the hands of sovereign governments is the spectacular failure of the Stability and Growth

Pact, which came into force in the late 1990s and included mechanisms to ensure that member

states would hold their annual budget deficits below 3 percent of GDP and their accumulated

government debt below 60 percent of GDP. The Stability and Growth Pact was never credible,

and became moot after 2003, when France and Germany used their political power to prevent

sanctions against their own violation of the pact’s fiscal rules. In general, the success of

supranational agents’ ability to take autonomous decisions can only be sustained in matters

where the extent of disagreement among national governments over policy outcomes is

relatively low, like the enforcement of trade liberalization agreements. But success in those

areas does not imply that supranational institutions and rules could also trump national

institutions and rules in other areas with much higher heterogeneity of preferences and interests,

like fiscal policies.

The role of the European Court of Justice is instructive. In a series of landmark cases, the Court

enunciated the doctrine that European Community norms have direct effect in member states

and trump domestic law, and that individuals can directly invoke European law before national

and European courts. For example, the 1963 case of Van Gend en Loos v Nederlandse

Administratie der Belastingen (26/62) was decided in favor of a Dutch importer of German

chemical products that had objected to a tariff charged by the Dutch authorities in violation of

article 12 of the Treaty of Rome, which forbids member states from raising customs duties

Page 15: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

14

between themselves or introducing new ones. The aggressive interpretation of its role by the

European Court of Justice in this and other cases went beyond the legal framework that had

been formally agreed with the Treaty of Rome, and, according to some scholars, brought

Europe close to a federal system from a legal perspective (Weiler 1991; Krasner 1999),

expanding supranational powers beyond the control of national governments (Pierson 1996;

Stone Sweet 2000). However, these new legal doctrines were established to enforce norms

consistent with national governments’ own collective objectives, such as trade liberalization.

The acceptance of these decisions by national governments and courts did not imply that any

European norms would be as easily accepted in the future. In more recent years the German

Constitutional Court has elaborated the legal theory of conditional acceptance of European

Union norms, according to which Germany only accepts the supremacy of EU law insofar as it

is consistent with fundamental German rights. In a famous decision on the constitutionality of

the Maastricht Treaty (BVerfGE 89,155 of October 12, 1993), the German Court ruled that

there is a legal limit to the powers of EU norms, defined by their effects on national democratic

sovereignty. In a landmark ruling on the Lisbon Treaty (BVerfG, 2 BvE 2/08 of June 6, 2009),

the German Court explicitly stated that the national states are “the masters of the treaties,” and

"therefore must see to it that there are no uncontrolled, independent centralization dynamics"

within the EU (quoted in Spiegel, 2009), a clear and explicit brake on functionalist dynamics.

In general, the central problem with the chain-reaction method is the unwarranted expectation

that gradual integration, which has been successful in low-heterogeneity-costs areas, can

continue unabated when moving to areas with much higher heterogeneity costs. This problem

stems from the lack of a realistic assessment of the increasing costs and constraints imposed by

heterogeneity of preferences. Successful integration is more likely to take off in areas such as

commercial integration, where heterogeneity costs are relatively low, and partly offset by the

benefits from diversity. As integration proceeds to other areas, after low-hanging fruits are

picked, heterogeneity costs continue to increase along a convex curve. At some point, those

high costs become politically prohibitive, and the pressure from spillovers, inefficiencies and

crises will no longer lead to further integration, but just to losses, and possibly even the collapse

of the whole system. The chain-reaction approach does not anticipate that heterogeneity costs

and constraints will eventually become binding and stop the process for good. Followers of this

approach are therefore prone to setting up incomplete and inefficient arrangements, relying on

the overoptimistic expectation that such inefficiencies can always be addressed at a later stage

through additional integration.

For these reasons, there is no guarantee that regional integration in economic areas, such as a

common market, should lead to political unification down the road. The example of the German

customs union (Zollverein) in the nineteenth century, often mentioned in this respect, is

misleading, because the main force behind commercial integration was political integration

Page 16: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

15

pushed by Prussia’s military power (Gilpin 2001). In fact, international cooperation and

political unification can be viewed as substitute ways to lower barriers to trade. If two regions

can already agree to reduce their trade barriers with each other while remaining independent,

they are going to obtain smaller additional gains from trade if they also form a political union

with a unified domestic market. Empirically, this direct negative effect of economic integration

on the incentives to form a political union is likely to be larger than possible indirect effects of

economic integration on the costs of political integration, such as those stressed by Monnet and

his followers (for example, a possible reduction of communication and coordination costs). The

historical record up to now indeed suggests that international economic integration is more

likely to go hand in hand with political disintegration (Alesina and Spolaore 1997, 2003;

Alesina, Spolaore, and Wacziarg 2000).

The euro is a child of the functionalist method. The method of partial integration provided the

institutional framework and rationale for monetary integration. Without Monnet’s idea of

delegating specific policy functions and prerogatives to supranational institutions, the euro

would not have come into existence. Of course this does not mean that the euro was created

exclusively for “functionalist” reasons and goals, or that the decision-makers were only

supranational civil servants and elites. There would be no euro without the actions of powerful

national politicians pursuing their own geopolitical and domestic objectives or without the

backing of powerful economic interests (like German exporters). However, statesmen with

political goals and producers with economic interests exist elsewhere, but do not end up with a

“currency without a state.” Such a currency was only possible — politically, technically, and

intellectually — in the exceptional institutional framework provided by European integration.

By creating the euro, the chain reaction crossed the border between “pure” economic integration

which can be achieved through international cooperation, in the form of liberalization of trade

and capital flows, and the form of monetary integration that, historically, had only been

obtained by a sovereign state using its power of coercion to establish one currency within its

borders.

The exceptional nature of the euro does not mean that Europe’s monetary union is unsustainable

in the long run, or only sustainable if Europe becomes a sovereign federation. The parameters of

the questions have been well stated by Mario Draghi (2012), the head of the European Central

Bank, who said that “those who claim only a full federation can be sustainable set the bar too

high.” Instead, Draghi focuses on the “minimum requirements to complete economic and

monetary union.” In such framework, the future of the euro depends on a key political variable:

the heterogeneity costs associated with the minimum set of functions that must be pooled or

delegated for a currency union to work.

Page 17: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

16

If heterogeneity costs were small, the euro area crisis of the last few years could perhaps be

addressed with deep fiscal and political integration. This outcome seems out of reach at present

given the historical experience of European integration. In principle, monetary union could lead

to a fiscal and political union even if heterogeneity remains high, if the costs from leaving the

euro are even higher, and fiscal and political integration are perceived by national governments

and voters as the only solution. That outcome could be seen as a vindication of the darker

version of Monnet’s chain reaction: heterogeneous Europeans would have been “trapped” in a

fiscal and political union because they took an irreversible decision to enter a monetary union

without anticipating the spillover to further integration. However, political union on such

grounds would hardly be a solid start for a European federation, and unlikely to trigger positive

cultural changes that would be the only sustainable foundation for a cohesive federation in the

long run.

A more promising way to ensure the stability of monetary union in Europe is to focus on a

narrower set of minimum requirements, as suggested by Draghi (2012). High priority is likely

to be given to banking and financial integration. Those gains could in part be secured with tools

and institutions similar to those already profitably employed in areas where the European Union

has been most successful, like commercial integration, antitrust regulation, and the formation of

a single market (for instance, Enderlein et al. 2012). At the same time, though, the close links

between banks and sovereign states in Europe can create dangerous spillovers, crises, and

clashes between supranational authorities and national governments.

Back Where We Started: The Benefits from European Integration

European integration in the aftermath of World War II started to counteract war and

protectionism. We saw the timid beginnings with coal and steel, the defeat of the ambitious plan

to pool defense, the establishment of a common market, and the building of ever more complex

and ambitious supranational institutions—eventually including monetary union. We discussed

the serious problems with the expectation that this would necessarily be a chain reaction

towards ever closer political integration. Now, it is time to offer a few final comments on the

sources of strengths of the European integration project.

While the chain-reaction method can be carried too far, key aspects of Monnet’s strategy have

in fact contributed to the concrete successes of the European project, when the tools of

integration have been applied to the appropriate areas: those with lower heterogeneity costs and

higher economies of scale. These aspects include: partial integration with a focus on economic

areas; deep “institutionalization,” with the delegation of substantial prerogatives to

supranational institutions, going well beyond the institutional framework of more traditional

international organization; and integration of several functions, creating useful “linkages.”

Page 18: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

17

Trade integration is a good example of the effectiveness of partial integration in economic

areas. Trade is an area where costs of heterogeneity are offset by benefits from heterogeneity

and large economies of scale. The removal of trade barriers was in the general interest of

Europeans, even though specific sectors and groups within each country benefited from

protectionist policies. European supranational institutions provided a way to coordinate trade

liberalization and to lock in the commitment not to raise barriers unilaterally when faced with

domestic political pressure. In this respect, European integration was one of the earliest and

most successful examples of regional arrangements set up to solve coordination problems and to

provide credible commitments (Eichengreen 2006). Partial institutional integration in different

areas also allowed “linkages” between issues and provision of credible side-payments to

potential losers from commercial integration. For instance, the notoriously wasteful Common

Agricultural Policy has been often explained as a political compromise between France and

Germany: German manufacturers gained access to the French market, and German taxpayers

helped subsidize French farmers.

Trade integration within Europe has also benefited peace and security. The view that

international trade can reduce the risk of war goes back to Montesquieu and Kant, and has

spurred a large empirical literature. Multilateral openness (or “globalization”) does not reduce

the risk of war between pairs of countries. However, bilateral trade, by increasing the

opportunity cost of conflicts between two partners, reduces the probability of conflict between

that pair of countries (Martin, Mayer and Thoenig 2008), even when controlling for historical,

linguistic and cultural similarities between populations (Spolaore and Wacziarg 2012). In fact,

Martin, Mayer and Thoenig (2010) find that country pairs with a high frequency of old wars are

more likely to sign regional trade agreements, which can be explained as a consequence of the

complementarity between economic and political gains from trade. They also show that

multilateral trade openness, by reducing the opportunity cost of a bilateral conflict, increases the

political incentive to sign regional agreements for security reasons.

This interaction between economic and political factors can explain important aspects of

European integration. For instance, it can shed light on why Konrad Adenauer, the Chancellor

of West Germany from 1949 to 1963, pushed for a geographically narrower but institutionally

deeper customs union with France, Germany’s old enemy. Adenauer overruled his economic

minister Ludwig Erhard, who was primarily interested in economic benefits and would have

preferred a broader free-trade area, which France would have been unlikely to join given its

own commercial and political interests (Garton Ash 1993; Moravcsik 1998).

An open question is whether European integration has played a central or only a marginal role

in securing peace in Europe. Skeptics of the “pacifying” effect of European institutions stress

the crucial involvement of the United States and NATO in Europe during the Cold War and

Page 19: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

18

afterwards, and the Europeans’ failure to deal with the breakup of Yugoslavia on their own.

Moreover, peace has also held between Japan, the other loser of World War II, and its

neighbors, and trade has prospered among them in the absence of Asian institutions analogous

to the European Union. However, the Cold War ended in Europe with the fall of the Berlin

Wall, Germany is now unified, and European institutions have played a very significant role in

the process of democratization and integration of Eastern and Central Europe. In contrast, the

relation between a still formally communist China and Taiwan remains tense and unresolved,

and Korea is still divided and even at risk of a nuclear war, which could spread to Japan and

other neighboring countries. On balance, whether because of European integration or other

factors, in recent decades Europe has fared quite well in terms of peace and democracy relative

to other areas of the world

In general, pooling and delegating functions and policies to supranational institutions to take

advantage of economies of scale and scope, while maintaining other prerogatives at the national

(or sub-national) level, has brought substantial benefits to Europeans when appropriately

implemented in areas with relatively low heterogeneity costs. Those benefits have been

obtained while keeping ultimate sovereign control and the monopoly of the legitimate use of

coercion at the national state level. A centralized European authority could provide a broader

range of public goods with large economies of scale and scope, while using coercion to prevent

free riding. But that would come with much higher heterogeneity costs. Europeans have

probably been wise not to travel all the way to a sovereign federation so far, given their existing

differences in preferences and cultures. If those preferences change, Europe may benefit from a

reorganization in a federal direction, but of course that should be decided only through broad

and democratically expressed consensus.

At the moment, Europeans are sticking to the current system of cooperation among sovereign

states within a supranational organization. Within those boundaries, and in spite of the serious

limitations that we discussed, European institutions have provided useful commitments to

overcome some (but not all) problems from free riding and beggar-thy-neighbor policies.

European cooperation has at least turned out better than the alternative system of destructive

unilateral national policies plaguing European history until 1945. In this respect, Moravcsik

(2012), a leading “intergovernmentalist” scholar of European Integration, is hopefully not far

from the truth when he writes: “Whatever the outcome of the crisis, the EU will remain without

rival the most ambitious and successful example of voluntary international cooperation in world

history.”

Page 20: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

19

REFERENCES

Alesina, Alberto, Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat and Romain Wacziarg

(2003), “Fractionalization,” Journal of Economic Growth, 8(2): 155-94.

Alesina, Alberto and Eliana La Ferrara (2005), "Ethnic Diversity and Economic Performance."

Journal of Economic Literature, 43(3): 762-800.

Alesina, Alberto and Roberto Perotti (2004), “The European Union: A Politically Incorrect View,"

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(4): 27-48.

Alesina, Alberto and Bryony Reich (2013), “Nation Building,” NBER Working paper 18839.

Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (1997), “On the Number and Size of Nations,” Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 112 (4), 1027-56.

Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (2003), The Size of Nations, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (2005), "War, Peace, and the Size of Countries," Journal of

Public Economics, 89(7): 1333-54.

Alesina, Alberto and Enrico Spolaore (2006), “"Conflict, Defense Spending, and the Number of

Nations," European Economic Review, 50(1): 91-120.

Alesina, Alberto, Enrico Spolaore and Romain Wacziarg (2000), “Economic Integration and

Political Disintegration,” American Economic Review, 90(5), 1276-96.

Ball, George W. (1994), Forward to François Duchêne, Jean Monnet. The First Statesman of

Interdependence, New York: Norton

Berger, Helge and Albrecht Ritschl (1995), “Germany and the Political Economy of the Marshall

Plan, 1947-52: A Re-revisionist View,” in Barry Eichengreen (ed.), Europe’s Postwar Recovery,

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 199-245.

Bergsten, C. Fred (2012), "Why the Euro Will Survive Completing the Continent's Half-Built

House," Foreign Affairs, September/October.

Bisin, Alberto and Thierry Verdier (2010), “The Economics of Cultural Transmission and

Socialization,” in Jess Benhabib, Alberto Bisin, and Matt Jackson (eds.), Handbook of Social

Economics, Elsevier.

Commission of the European Communities, (1990), One Market, One Money. An Evaluation of the

Potential Benefits and Costs of Forming an Economic and Monetary Union, European Economy,

44.

Page 21: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

20

Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union (1989), Report on Economic and

Monetary Union in the European Community [also known as the Delors Report], Luxembourg:

European Communities.

Desmet, Klaus, Ignacio Ortuño-Ortín and Romain Wacziarg (2012), "The Political Economy of

Linguistic Cleavages," Journal of Development Economics, 97(2): 322-38.

Desmet, Klaus , Ignacio Ortuño-Ortín and Shlomo Weber (2009), "Linguistic Diversity and

Redistribution," Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6): 1291-318.

Deutsch, Karl W (1964), “Communication Theory and Political Integration,” in Philip E. Jacob and

James V. Toscano, The Integration of Political Communities, Philadelphia: J. B. Lippincott.

Dyson, Kenneth and Kevin Featherstone (1999), The Road to Maastricht. Negotiating Economic

and Monetary Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Draghi, Mario (2012), “The Future of the Euro: Stability through Change, published in German in

Die Zeit, August 29, 2012, English version:

http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120829.en.html

Duchêne, François (1994), Jean Monnet. The First Statesman of Interdependence, New York:

Norton

Eichengreen, Barry (2006), “European Integration,” in Barry R. Weingast and Donald A. Wittman

(eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 799-813.

Eichengreen, Barry (2012), “European Monetary Integration with Benefit of Hindsight,” Journal of

Common Market Studies, 50 (S1) 123-36.

Eichengreen, Barry and Jeffry A. Frieden (2001), “The Political Economy of European Monetary

Unification: An Analytical Introduction,” in Barry Eichengreen and Jeffry Frieden, (eds.), The

Political Economy of European Monetary Unification, Boulder: Westview Press.

Enderlein, Henrik, Peter Bofinger, Jean-Claude Piris, Paul de Grauwe, Maria Joao Rodrigues, Jean

Pisani-Ferry, Andrés Sapir, and Antonio Vitorino (2012), Completing the Euro – A Roadmap

towards Fiscal Union in Europe. Report by the Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa Group. Paris: Notre

Europe.

Esteban, Joan, Laura Mayoral and Debraj Ray (2012),"Ethnicity and Conflict: An Empirical Study,"

American Economic Review, 102(4): 1310-42.

Fearon, James (2006), “Ethnic Mobilization and Ethnic Violence,” in Barry R. Weingast and

Donald A. Wittman (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 852-68.

Page 22: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

21

Feldstein, Martin (2012), "The Failure of the Euro. The Little Currency That Couldn't," Foreign

Affairs, January/February.

Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Andrew K. Rose (1998), "The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area

Criteria," Economic Journal, 108(449): 1009-25.

Frieden, Jeffry A. (1998), “The Euro: Who Wins? Who Loses?" Foreign Policy, 112: 24-40.

Frieden, Jeffry A. (2002), "Real Sources of European Currency Policy: Sectoral Interests and

European Monetary Integration." International Organization 56(4): 831-60.

Garrett, Geoffrey (1993), “The Politics of Maastricht,” Economics and Politics, 5(2): 105–23.

Gilpin, Robert (2001), Global Political Economy. Understanding the international Economic

Order, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Garton Ash, Timothy (1993), In Europe's Name: Germany and the Divided Continent, New York:

Random House.

Garton Ash, Timothy (2012), “The Crisis of Europe,” Foreign Affairs, September/October.

Gilbert, Mark (2012), European Integration. A Concise History. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.

Haas, Ernst B. (1958), The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social, and Economic Forces, 1950-1957,

London: Stevens.

Haas, Ernst B. (1964), Beyond the Nation State, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Haas, Ernst B. (1975), The Obsolence of Regional Integration Theory, Institute of International

Studies, University of California.

Hoffmann, Stanley (1966), “Obsolete or Obstinate? The Fate of the Nation-State and the Case of

Western Europe,” Daedalus, 95 (3): 862-915.

Krasner, Stephen D. (1999), Sovereignty. Organized Hypocrisy, Princeton: Princeton University

Press.

Krugman, Paul and Anthony Venables (1996), “Integration, Specialization, and Adjustment,”

European Economic Review, 40(3): 959-67.

Krugman, Paul (2012), "Revenge of the Optimum Currency Area," in Daron Acemoglu, Jonathan

Parker, and Michael Woodford (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2012, Volume 27, Chicago:

University of Chicago Press.

Lane, Philip R. (2012), "The European Sovereign Debt Crisis," Journal of Economic Perspectives,

26(3): 49-68.

Page 23: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

22

Martin, Philippe, Thierry Mayer and Mathias Thoenig (2008), "Make Trade Not War?", Review of

Economic Studies, 75(3): 865-900

Martin, Philippe, Thierry Mayer and Mathias Thoenig (2010), "The Geography of Conflicts and

Free Trade Agreements," CEPR Discussion Papers 7740.

Milward, Alan R. (1984), The Reconstruction of Western Europe, 1945-51, York: Methuen.

Montalvo, Jose G. and Marta Reynal-Querol (2005), “Ethnic Polarization, Potential Conflict and

Civil War,” American Economic Review, 95 (3): 796-816.

Moravcsik, Andrew (1993), "Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal

Intergovernmentalist Approach," Journal of Common Market Studies, 31 (4): 473–524.

Moravcsik, Andrew (1998), The Choice for Europe. Social Purpose and State Power from Messina

to Maastricht, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Moravcsik, Andrew (2012), "Europe After the Crisis," Foreign Affairs, May/June

Marsh, David (2011), The Euro. The Battle for the New Global Currency, New Haven: Yale

University Press.

Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso (2004), The Euro and Its Central Bank. Getting United After the Union,

Cambridge (MA): MIT Press.

Pierson, Paul (1996), “The Path to European Integration: a Historical Institutionalist Analysis,”

Comparative Political Studies, 29: 123-63.

Rector, David (2009), Federations. The Political Dynamics of Cooperation, Ithaca: Cornell

University Press.

Riker, William (1964), Federalism, New York: Little Brown.

Sadeh, Tel and Amy Verdun (2009), “Explaining Europe’s Monetary Union: A Survey of the

Literature,” International Studies Review, 11: 277-301.

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier and Jeffrey Sachs (1992), “Fiscal Federalism and Optimum Currency Areas:

Evidence for Europe from the United States,” in Matthew Canzoneri, Vittorio Grilli, and Paul

Masson (eds.), Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the U.S.,

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Sandholtz, Wayne and Alec Stone Sweet (eds.) (1998), European Integration and Supranational

Governance, Oxford University Press.

Page 24: What Is European Integration Really About? A Political ...sites.tufts.edu/enricospolaore/files/2012/08/Euro-June-2013.pdf · What Is European Integration Really About? ... 2 integration

23

Spiegel (2009), “Germany's Lisbon Treaty Ruling: Brussels Put Firmly in the Back Seat,” July 6,

online version in English: http://www.spiegel.de/international/germany/germany-s-lisbon-treaty-

ruling-brussels-put-firmly-in-the-back-seat-a-634506.html

Spiegel (2010), “The Price of Unity: Was the Deutsche Mark Sacrificed for Reunification?”,

September 30, online version in English: http://www.spiegel.de/international/germany/the-price-of-

unity-was-the-deutsche-mark-sacrificed-for-reunification-a-719940.html

Spolaore, Enrico (2006), “National Borders and the Size of Nations,” in Barry R. Weingast and

Donald A. Wittman (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 778-98.

Spolaore, Enrico (2012), “National Borders, Conflict and Peace,” in Michelle R. Garfinkel and

Stergios Skaperdas (eds), Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Peace and Conflict, Oxford:

Oxford University Press, 763-86.

Spolaore, Enrico and Romain Wacziarg (2012), “War and Relatedness,” Tufts and UCLA Anderson

School.

Spolaore, Enrico and Romain Wacziarg (2013), “How Deep Are the Roots of Economic

Development?” Journal of Economic Literature, 51(2): 1-45.

Stone Sweet, Alec (2000), Governing with Judges: Constitutional Politics in Europe, Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

Van Overtveldt, Johan (2011), The End of the Euro, Chicago: Agate Publishing.

Weber, Eugen (1976), Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural France, 1870-1914,

Stanford: Stanford University Press.

Weiler, Jospeh H. H. (1991), “The Transformation of Europe,” Yale Law Journal, 100: 2403-83.