8
Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment Mary Kathryn Hamman Published online: 13 August 2010 Ó Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010 Abstract The American Academy of Pediatrics recom- mends children receive six well-baby visits between ages 1 month and 1 year, yet by age 14 months less than 10% of infants have received all six visits. Cost sharing under public and private insurance is very low. Low compliance rates despite the low cost of care suggest other factors, such as time costs, may be important. This paper examines the relationship between maternal employment and receipt of well-baby care. The Medical Expenditure Panel Survey contains rich information on use of preventive care, maternal employment, and other economic and non- economic factors that may influence care decisions. Several approaches, including a proxy variable strategy and instrumental variables analysis, are used to attempt to address the potential endogeneity of maternal employment and examine the sensitivity of findings. Findings indicate mothers who work full-time take their children to 0.18 fewer visits (or 9% fewer at the mean) than those who have quit their jobs. Mothers with employer provided paid vacation leave take their children to 0.20 more visits (or 9% more at the mean) than other working mothers. Time appears to be an important factor in determining well-baby care receipt. Policies that extend paid leave to more employed women may improve compliance with pre- ventive care recommendations. Keywords Well-baby care Á Preventive care Á Maternal employment Á Paid leave Introduction The American Academy of Pediatrics (AAP) recommends children receive six well-baby visits by age 12 months, in addition to a newborn and a 3–5 day follow-up visit after hospital discharge [1]. However, fewer than 10% of infants meet recommendations. Visits require both time and monetary resources. Yet, out of pocket costs are very low for the insured, and insurance coverage rates are high among infants. The fact that so few infants receive all recommended care despite low costs suggests parents may have trouble finding the time for visits. One-third of mothers return to work within 3 months of giving birth [2]. For these mothers, visits must either be scheduled around work, or during paid or unpaid time off. Therefore employed mothers, especially those working full-time, have less time available for visits. Furthermore, employed mothers without access to paid or unpaid leave may have less control over their time than those who have leave. Yet, additional household income may increase the ability to pay for visits. Also, if time is scarce employed mothers may actually find preventive care to be more beneficial because it reduces the risk of time lost due to illness in the future. This paper examines the following questions: First, does maternal employment compete with receipt of recom- mended well-baby visits? Second, does access to employer provided paid leave or unpaid leave under the Family and Medical Leave Act (FMLA) increase receipt of recom- mended visits? To address these questions, data from the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) are analyzed. Results indicate employment, and full-time employment in particular, may compete with receipt of care but the neg- ative relationship is at least partially offset if mothers have access to paid vacation. This paper contributes to the M. K. Hamman (&) School of Human Resources and Labor Relations, Michigan State University, 431 S. Kedzie Hall, East Lansing, MI 48824, USA e-mail: [email protected] 123 Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036 DOI 10.1007/s10995-010-0657-9

Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of MaternalEmployment

Mary Kathryn Hamman

Published online: 13 August 2010

� Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Abstract The American Academy of Pediatrics recom-

mends children receive six well-baby visits between ages

1 month and 1 year, yet by age 14 months less than 10% of

infants have received all six visits. Cost sharing under

public and private insurance is very low. Low compliance

rates despite the low cost of care suggest other factors, such

as time costs, may be important. This paper examines the

relationship between maternal employment and receipt of

well-baby care. The Medical Expenditure Panel Survey

contains rich information on use of preventive care,

maternal employment, and other economic and non-

economic factors that may influence care decisions. Several

approaches, including a proxy variable strategy and

instrumental variables analysis, are used to attempt to

address the potential endogeneity of maternal employment

and examine the sensitivity of findings. Findings indicate

mothers who work full-time take their children to 0.18

fewer visits (or 9% fewer at the mean) than those who have

quit their jobs. Mothers with employer provided paid

vacation leave take their children to 0.20 more visits (or

9% more at the mean) than other working mothers. Time

appears to be an important factor in determining well-baby

care receipt. Policies that extend paid leave to more

employed women may improve compliance with pre-

ventive care recommendations.

Keywords Well-baby care � Preventive care � Maternal

employment � Paid leave

Introduction

The American Academy of Pediatrics (AAP) recommends

children receive six well-baby visits by age 12 months, in

addition to a newborn and a 3–5 day follow-up visit after

hospital discharge [1]. However, fewer than 10% of infants

meet recommendations. Visits require both time and

monetary resources. Yet, out of pocket costs are very low

for the insured, and insurance coverage rates are high

among infants. The fact that so few infants receive all

recommended care despite low costs suggests parents may

have trouble finding the time for visits.

One-third of mothers return to work within 3 months of

giving birth [2]. For these mothers, visits must either be

scheduled around work, or during paid or unpaid time off.

Therefore employed mothers, especially those working

full-time, have less time available for visits. Furthermore,

employed mothers without access to paid or unpaid leave

may have less control over their time than those who have

leave. Yet, additional household income may increase the

ability to pay for visits. Also, if time is scarce employed

mothers may actually find preventive care to be more

beneficial because it reduces the risk of time lost due to

illness in the future.

This paper examines the following questions: First, does

maternal employment compete with receipt of recom-

mended well-baby visits? Second, does access to employer

provided paid leave or unpaid leave under the Family and

Medical Leave Act (FMLA) increase receipt of recom-

mended visits? To address these questions, data from the

Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) are analyzed.

Results indicate employment, and full-time employment in

particular, may compete with receipt of care but the neg-

ative relationship is at least partially offset if mothers have

access to paid vacation. This paper contributes to the

M. K. Hamman (&)

School of Human Resources and Labor Relations,

Michigan State University, 431 S. Kedzie Hall,

East Lansing, MI 48824, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

123

Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036

DOI 10.1007/s10995-010-0657-9

Page 2: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

understanding of preventive care receipt at a particularly

important point in the human developmental lifecycle.

The goals of well-baby care are to prevent infant mor-

tality and promote health. The anticipatory guidance pro-

vided during visits targets avoidable risks common in early

infancy and childhood. For example, in 1990 the Sudden

Infant Death Syndrome rate was 1.30 per 1,000 live births

[3]. Since proper sleep position guidance was publicized in

1992, the percentage of infants placed on their backs to

sleep increased from 13 to 72.8%, and the rate of SIDS fell

by over 50% [4]. Although parents could have received sleep

position guidance from many sources, a portion of each well-

baby visit is specifically devoted to age-appropriate pre-

ventive guidance, such as proper sleep position.

Well-baby visits also include health screenings. Early

diagnosis of existing conditions can improve prognosis.

For example, children who receive screening for strabis-

mus (commonly known as ‘‘lazy eye’’) or other sources of

limited visual acuity (amblyomia) and are diagnosed before

age 3 years have better long run visual acuity than children

diagnosed at age 3 years [5, 6]. Similarly, infants who are

diagnosed with congenital hearing loss have a higher

likelihood of developing speech than those whose hearing

loss goes undetected in infancy [7]. Screenings can occur in

other medical settings, but well-baby visits are specifically

designed to include screening. The visit schedule is set to

target critical points in a child’s development.

In 2003, 8.9% of infant deaths that occurred after the

perinatal period and were not associated with congenital

abnormalities were the result of infectious, endocrine,

nutritional, or metabolic diseases [8]. Vaccines are available

for many infectious diseases. For some, treatment can be as

simple as administering vitamin supplements and maintain-

ing routine follow-up care. Well-baby visits include screen-

ings for many of these conditions, and routine physical

examinations may aid early diagnosis and treatment.

Despite the importance of these visits, most studies find

babies receive significantly less than the recommended

amount of care [9–11]. The literature includes many pos-

sible explanations for underutilization including inadequate

insurance coverage, racial disparities, lack of parental

education, and limited access to care [12–14]. Three pre-

vious studies examine the impact of maternal employment

on receipt of care. Colle and Grossman [15] find time costs

reduce the likelihood of receiving pediatric preventive

care, and the estimated effect is largest among children

whose mothers work. Their study also highlights the

importance of the price of care and household income.

Among children ages 0–15, Vistnes and Hamilton [16] find

the number of visits a child receives decreases as mother’s

hours worked per week and weeks worked per year

increase. Berger et al. [17] find mothers who return to work

early (within the first 12 weeks after giving birth) are 2.4%

points less likely to take their babies for any well-baby care

in the first year of life and their babies receive 0.20 fewer

visits on average. Findings on the impact of paid leave are

more mixed; Vistnes and Hamilton [16] find no evidence of

an effect of sick leave but Berger et al. [17] find positive

relationships between paid maternity leave duration and

well-baby care use. No previous study has considered the

influence of FMLA leave eligibility.

In summary, previous studies provide some evidence of

a negative relationship between maternal employment and

well-baby care. However, given the complex nature of

care-giving and maternal employment decisions, these

studies and the present study face challenges to identify

causal effects. The methods used to address these chal-

lenges can materially influence the results. For example, in

the broader literature, Blau et al. [18] show that after

accounting for endogeneity of maternal employment, there

is no evidence of a negative relationship between maternal

employment and child health. Of the well-baby care stud-

ies, Berger et al. [17] is the only study that attempts to

address the endogeneity problem. They use propensity

score matching to model mother’s return to work behavior.

Their propensity score matching technique yields results

that are very similar to their OLS estimates. The relevance

of this problem to the present study is discussed in the

results section alongside three new approaches to it.

Methods

This study investigates the following two hypotheses:

1. Maternal employment creates time constraints that

reduce the amount of well-baby care received.

2. Access to employer provided paid leave or FMLA

leave (at least partially) mitigates any negative rela-

tionship between maternal employment and receipt of

care.

It is possible that the true relationships are exactly the

opposite of those proposed here. Maternal employment

increases household income, which may in turn increase

the family’s ability to pay for well-baby care. Employed

mothers who have access to paid leave may see less value

in preventive care because they have time available to care

for a sick child. Alternatively, if paid time off is rationed,

employed mothers may feel it is better to save that time for

occasions when their child is sick. Given these competing

explanations, the significance of all estimated relationships

is evaluated using conventional two tail hypothesis tests.

The data used in the analysis are drawn from the 1996

through 2005 Household Component, Event Files, and

Conditions Files of the MEPS. Although the MEPS con-

sists of 2 year panels, the panel data structure was not

1030 Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036

123

Page 3: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

exploited because survey waves do not occur frequently

enough to match time varying covariates to specific visits.

Survey waves occur five times over 2 years; there are six

recommended well-baby visits in the first year of life alone

(not including the first visit which should occur within

1 week of the birth). So, the sample consists of all children

14 months and younger in the 1996 through 2005 MEPS

surveys (N = 3,536). Each child contributes one observa-

tion. Time varying covariates are measured as means

across all survey waves a child is observed.

Respondents (generally the mother) identify well-baby

visits when asked the main purpose of a visit. However,

even sick visits may include some well-baby care compo-

nents. Therefore, the analysis begins with an examination

of substitution between well-baby visits and other office

based visits.

Throughout the analysis, the dependent variable is a

count of on-time well-baby visits received. Both the number

and timing of visits are important. To incorporate both

aspects in the dependent variable measure, all visits are

assigned to recommended care intervals (RCI). An RCI is a

time period defined to contain the age at which a visit is

supposed to occur under the AAP guidelines. To illustrate

the construction of RCIs for each visit, Fig. 1 displays a

histogram of the ages at which well-baby visits were

received among infants in the MEPS sample. The horizontal

axis highlights the ages at which the AAP recommends

visits. The peaks indicate actual timing of visits corresponds

closely with recommendations. When the recommended

ages for visits are more than 1 month apart, the bins to the

right of each recommended age generally contain more

visits than the bins to the left. Thus, each RCI is defined to

begin with the month in which the visit is recommended and

continue until the month of the next recommended visit.

The only exception to this coding rule is the 1 month visit;

infants who receive a visit before 1 month are considered to

have received an on-time 1 month visit even if they do not

receive another visit at age 1 month. An infant can receive

future on-time visits even if he did not receive on-time visits

in the past. Given the construction of the dependent vari-

able, throughout the analysis regression coefficients can be

interpreted as an estimated marginal change in the number

of on-time visits received.

Not all children in the sample are observed for all rec-

ommended visits in the first year. Since some children are

born during the survey they exit the survey before they

reach age 14 months; others are born before and enter the

survey after age 0 months. The dependent variable is

defined so that children can only contribute on-time visits

for whole RCIs observed. For example, if a child exits the

survey at age 13 months, the dependent variable will not

count any visits he received during the RCI corresponding

to the 12 month visit because he exited the survey before

that RCI was completed. All specifications control for the

first RCI observed and the length of time (in months)

encompassed by the first and last RCI observed.

Throughout the analysis, maternal wages proxy for the

monetary value of time. Yet, wages are unobserved for non-

employed mothers. To address this issue, past observed

wages for mothers who worked at any time during the survey

are used in place of actual wages. Wages are predicted for

mothers who are non-employed throughout the survey.

Similarly, out of pocket cost data is missing for visits

not received. Missing costs are predicted using the average

cost of all previous office based visits and insurance cov-

erage information. Cost sharing for well-baby care under

Medicaid was eliminated in 1996. Thus, any missing prices

for Medicaid recipients are coded as 0.

All regressions control for whether or not the child has a

usual care provider and the child’s insurance coverage,

race, and subjective health status reported by the household

respondent (usually the mother). Mother’s education,

marital status, and age are included, as are the number of

children in the household by age group, the presence of

adults other than the parents, the region of residence, and

urban or rural residence.

Results

Before analyzing the relationships of interest, it is neces-

sary to confirm the well-baby care measure includes all

care received. As stated previously, households identify the

main purpose of each doctor visit received. Yet a child may

receive some components of well-baby care during a visit

where the main purpose is to treat an illness. If the measure

used in the analysis includes only visits identified as

Fig. 1 Distribution of ages at which visits were received. Note The

x-axis denotes the ages at which the AAP recommends visits. SourceAuthor’s calculation using Medical Expenditure Panel Survey

1996–2005

Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036 1031

123

Page 4: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

well-baby care and less healthy infants actually receive a

non negligible amount of well care during sick visits, the

measure will systematically underestimate care received

for this group. Among the 647 infants observed for all six

RCIs, the correlation between well-baby visits and sick

visits is 0.15. So it seems even if infants do receive some

well care during sick visits, it is not enough to supplant

routine well-baby visits.

The MEPS also allows parents to identify the main

purpose of a visit as a general check-up, immunization, or

postnatal care visit. All of these designations could be

construed by the parent as equivalent to well-baby care. In

the data, the correlation between well-baby visits and these

other types of preventive care is -0.49. So, there is some

evidence of substitution between well-baby visits and these

other types of preventive care visits. Thus, the remainder of

the analysis will include visits identified as general check-

ups, immunizations, or postnatal care delivered to the child

as well-baby visits.

Figure 2 presents a histogram of the total number of on-

time well-baby visits received among the 647 infants

observed for all six recommended care intervals. The

majority of the sample received less than the recommended

6 visits, and approximately half received fewer than 3

visits. The population weighted mean number of visits

received is 3.68.

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics and cross-

tabulations for key variables. In these simple descriptive

statistics, average household income and mother’s hourly

wage are higher among infants who receive more visits.

Furthermore, 61% of mothers who took their children to 4

or more visits are employed as compared to 53% of all

mothers. There are no notable differences in usual hours of

work between the mothers in each group, but those who

took their children to more visits seem to be more likely to

have paid vacation or sick leave offered through their

employer. This may be because the leave enables mothers

to take their babies to visits, or simply because mothers in

more advantaged households are more likely to have jobs

with better leave policies. Multivariate analysis is needed

to distinguish between these two explanations.

Table 2 contains the baseline results of multivariate

analysis. Out of pocket cost of care, mother’s wage, and

household income variables all have the predicted signs.

Yet, the estimated relationship between mother’s wages

and visits received is small and not statistically significant.

Therefore, this estimate does not support or refute

Hypothesis 1. The own-price elasticity indicates a 1%

increase in the monetary cost of a visit would lead to a

0.1% reduction in visits received. At the mean of 3.68, this

would be a reduction of 0.04 visits.

Fig. 2 Distribution of total on-time visits received. Note Includes

infants ages 0–14 months and observed across all RCIs only.

SourceAuthor’s calculation using Medical Expenditure Panel Survey

1996–2005

Table 1 Descriptive statistics and cross tabulations for key variables

Sample mean Sample mean conditional

on 4 or more visits received

Out of pocket cost $8.69 (19.23) $11.81 (20.88)

Wage $11.49 (8.08) $13.27 (8.83)

Income (thousands) $38.36 (33.77) $43.52 (35.63)

Employed 0.53 (0.47) 0.61 (0.45)

Usual weekly hours worked (conditional on working) 34.75 (11.38) 35.08 (12.34)

Access to paid sick leave (conditional on working) 0.56 (0.49) 0.63 (0.47)

Access to paid vacation (conditional on working) 0.63 (0.47) 0.67 (0.46)

Access to FMLA leave (conditional on working) 0.36 (0.47) 0.36 (0.46)

N 3,536 656

N employed 1,654 336

Standard deviations in parentheses

1032 Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036

123

Page 5: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

Rather than relying on wages to measure the time cost of

care, it may be better to directly enter measures of maternal

employment into the regression equation. These specifi-

cations are presented in Table 3. One prefers these speci-

fications if we believe mothers have difficulty taking the

marginal hour off work or incur costs other than the lost

wages, such as animosity from a supervisor or coworkers.

Adding employment status to the model yields a negative,

but insignificant, coefficient. However, this estimate is

likely biased due to endogeneity.

To address the endogeneity problem, three approaches

are employed. The first is a proxy variable strategy.

Whether or not a mother has ever worked for pay is used as

a proxy for unobserved maternal tastes for paid employ-

ment. These unobserved tastes may also correlate with

factors that lead a woman to take her child to well-baby

visits such as diligence, ambition, and an ability to

understand medical guidelines. The results in Column II

indicate that women who have ever worked outside the

home take their children to 0.38 more visits than those who

have never worked outside the home, but those who are

currently working take their children to 0.13 fewer visits

than those who had worked but quit their jobs.

The second strategy used to address potential endoge-

neity is instrumental variables (IV) estimation. The instru-

ment for maternal employment is a binary indicator for

health insurance held in the mother’s own name before the

baby was born. Controlling for the baby’s current health

insurance coverage and health status, mother’s previous use

of employer provided insurance should have no impact on

current receipt of care. It should, however, relate to the

opportunity cost of returning to work. Indeed, in the first

stage regression mothers who held employer provided

insurance in their own name before the birth worked during

36% more RCIs (P = .00). Unfortunately this instrument is

missing for children who enter the sample after birth, so

observations fall from 3,529 to 1,122. Column III of

Table 3 shows the IV estimate is negative and large relative

to Columns I and II, but not statistically significant

(P = .35). However, if the proxy variable strategy is used

with the limited sample of 1,122, the sign pattern is the

same as in Column II, but maternal employment is insig-

nificant. Therefore, it seems lack of statistical power is a

larger problem than inefficiency of the IV estimate.

The third and final technique for addressing endogeneity

requires fewer assumptions but is more descriptive. If

Table 2 Maternal employment and well-baby visits: derived demand

specification

Out of pocket cost -0.005? (0.003)

Out of pocket cost2 0.000* (0.000)

Ln (full income in 10 thousands) 0.094? (0.055)

Ln (wage) -0.027 (0.048)

Constant 0.474 (0.557)

Observations 3,536

R2 0.496

Own price elasticity -0.001? (0.001)

Income elasticity 0.002? (0.001)

Cross-price elasticity -0.001 (0.001)

Regressions control for usual care provider, insurance coverage by

type, race, subjective health status, mother’s education, mother’s

marital status, quadratic in mother’s age, number of children by age

group, presence of other adults in the household, region of residence,

urban, first RCI observed, and number of months in the sample

** Significant at 1%; * Significant at 5%; ? Significant at 10%

Robust standard errors in parentheses

Table 3 Maternal employment and well-baby visits: alternative specifications

(I) (II) (III) (IV)

Out of pocket cost -0.005? (0.003) -0.005? (0.003) -0.001 (0.005) -0.005? (0.003)

Out of pocket cost2 0.000* (0.000) 0.000* (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000* (0.000)

Ln (full income in 10 thousands) 0.090 (0.056) 0.072 (0.056) 0.112 (0.098) 0.067 (0.056)

Ln (wage) -0.026 (0.05) -0.020 (0.049) -0.088 (0.080) -0.009 (0.050)

Mother employed -0.028 (0.057) -0.134* (0.063) -0.285 (0.302)

Mother has ever worked for pay 0.377** (0.087) 0.374** (0.085)

Mother works part-time -0.061 (0.073)

Mother works full-time -0.180** (0.065)

Constant 0.421 (0.549) 0.774 (0.974) 0.380 (0.548)

Observations 3,529 1,122 3,529

R-Squared 0.500 0.357 0.501

Regressions control for usual care provider, insurance coverage by type, race, subjective health status, mother’s education, mother’s marital

status, quadratic in mother’s age, number of children by age group, presence of other adults in the household, region of residence, urban, first RCI

observed, and number of months in the sample

** Significant at 1%; * Significant at 5%; ? Significant at 10% Robust standard errors in parentheses

Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036 1033

123

Page 6: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

Hypothesis 1 is true, then we should find the relationship is

larger (in absolute value) for mothers working full time.

Importantly, these estimates are likely biased for reasons

explained. This technique is descriptive; it does not reduce

any bias. Yet, it does provide a different test of the

hypothesis of interest that relies on the relative magnitudes

of coefficients rather than the absolute magnitude. If biases

are similar in direction and magnitude, this technique may

be more valid than simple OLS or the other methods used.

Column IV presents the results. Estimates do indicate the

negative relationship is larger for mothers who worked

full-time than for those who worked part-time or did not

work.

Hypothesis 2 predicts that among continuously employed

mothers, those with access to paid or unpaid leave will take

their children to more visits. In addition to the control

variables used thus far, mother’s occupation, salaried or

hourly pay status, and job tenure are added to these

regressions. Instead of using part-time or full-time indictor

variables, usual hours worked per week is used because

leave policies are concentrated among full-time employees

and using a full-time indicator results in multicolinearity.

Column I of Table 4 indicates employed mothers with

continuous access to paid vacation leave take their children

to 0.21 more visits than those who do not have any access

to paid vacation leave. Although sick leave does not appear

to have a statistically significant separate effect, access to

paid vacation and to paid sick leave are highly correlated in

the sample (q = .65). Further analysis reveals they are

jointly significant (F = 3.68, P = .03). There is no evi-

dence of a positive relationship between access to FMLA

leave and receipt of care.

One concern with the foregoing results is paid leave

variables may be capturing the advantages of having a

‘‘good job’’ rather than easing of time constraints. As a

sensitivity check, offer of a pension plan was added to the

regression. A pension plan is also an attribute of a good job

but it should have no significant impact on well-baby care

otherwise. Column II presents the results. The point esti-

mate on pension is very small and insignificant, and the

coefficient estimate for paid vacation is relatively

unchanged. So the ‘‘good jobs’’ explanation is unlikely to

be the sole reason for the positive relationship between

paid leave and visits received.

Discussion

The driving question behind this analysis is: does maternal

employment compete with well-baby care? Most specifi-

cations indicate the relationship between full-time maternal

employment and receipt of care is negative and significant,

and the negative relationship holds across specifications

used to account for endogeneity. Mothers who work full-

time take their children to an estimated 0.18 fewer visits

than those who have quit their jobs. Each additional hour of

work is estimated to reduce visits received by -0.006

(P = .07). This implies children whose mothers work 30

hours per week receive approximately 0.06 fewer visits

than those whose mothers work 40 hours per week, which

is in keeping with the estimates for part-time and full-time

work in the full sample presented in Table 3.

Yet, the findings indicate the negative impact of full-

time work may be at least partially offset if the job pro-

vides paid leave. FMLA leave, however, does not appear to

offset any of the negative relationship. This is likely

because very few women are both eligible for FMLA leave

and work for covered employers when they have a child. In

the MEPS sample, only 36% of women were both eligible

for FMLA and working for covered employers. Among

those women, the fact that the law does not require any

remuneration may further limit its use.

In all, a difference of 0.18 visits between mothers

working full-time and those who have quit their jobs seems

quite small given that the average child receives only 3.68

Table 4 Impact of access to paid and unpaid leave among employed

mothers

(I) (II)

Out of pocket cost -0.002 (0.004) -0.002 (0.004)

Out of pocket cost2 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000)

Ln (full income in 10

thousands)

0.136? (0.076) 0.133? (0.077)

Ln (wage) -0.051 (0.054) -0.051 (0.054)

Mother’s usual hours

of work

-0.006? (0.004) -0.006? (0.004)

Mother’s employer offers

paid vacation

0.206* (0.101) 0.200* (0.102)

Mother’s employer offers

paid sick days

0.072 (0.096) 0.082 (0.099)

Mother is eligible for

FMLA leave

-0.100 (0.084) -0.104 (0.085)

Mother’s employer offers

a pension plan

0.018 (0.089)

Constant 0.493 (1.003) 0.466 (1.004)

N 1,474 1,461

R-Squared 0.550 0.550

Regressions control for usual care provider, insurance coverage by

type, race, subjective health status, mother’s education, mother’s

marital status, quadratic in mother’s age, number of children by age

group, presence of other adults in the household, region of residence,

urban, first RCI observed, and number of months in the sample.

Benchmark occupational category is other occupations

** Significant at 1%; * Significant at 5%; ? Significant at 10%

Robust standard errors in parentheses

1034 Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036

123

Page 7: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

of 6 recommended visits. However, if mothers who quit

their jobs to care for their families are also those who

experience the greatest employment related constraints

then this figure may underestimate conflicts between work

and care. Unfortunately this data contains too few obser-

vations to rigorously analyze systematic attrition, but as a

first step Table 5 contains descriptive characteristics of

jobs among mothers who quit to care for their family.

The differences in access to leave between women

who quit and those who did not are quite striking. Only

43.21% of mothers who quit have access to paid vaca-

tion time across all RCIs employed as compared to

64.61% of mothers who did not quit. Similarly, 33.09%

of mothers who quit had paid sick leave as compared to

57.56% of those who did not. Thus, it seems women

with the worst jobs are no longer working after their

children are born. This possibility deserves further con-

sideration; it not only means that the estimates in this

study likely understate the true extent of conflict between

maternal employment and care but also that any study of

maternal employment and child outcomes is subject to

this systematic attrition.

The analysis in this study should be considered in light

of the following limitations. First, as illustrated in the

descriptive statistics in Table 5 and discussed above, there

appears to be systematic attrition from the labor force that

is not accounted for in the analysis. The attrition likely

positively biases the reported estimates and thus the esti-

mates understate the true negative relationship between

maternal employment and receipt of well-baby care. Sec-

ond, given the infrequency of survey waves in the MEPS,

analysis was based on cross-sectional variation and time

varying covariates were averaged across RCIs. Thus, the

timing of changes in paid or unpaid leave access could not

be precisely tied to specific RCIs. Clearly the ability to use

longitudinal variation of this sort, provided there are

enough changes in leave eligibility for identification, would

be helpful. Third, the paid leave measures available in the

MEPS are quite blunt; they simply indicate whether or not

the mother’s employer provides either paid vacation or sick

leave but do not measure how much leave she has per year

or how much remains. Since many women must use their

paid leave as part of their maternity leave, it is possible

those who say their employer provides leave actually have

no leave left to use. This should negatively bias the

reported coefficients; the true impact of paid leave is likely

larger than the estimates imply. Finally, although three

approaches were used to address the likely endogeneity of

maternal employment, the first two approaches require

fairly strong assumptions to arrive at unbiased estimates

and the third is purely descriptive. Thus, the magnitude of

point estimates should be extrapolated to underlying causal

relationships with caution. Nonetheless, it is encouraging

that these approaches do yield similar results.

Acknowledgments The author gratefully acknowledges helpful

comments from Peter Berg, Steven Haider, Stacy Dickert-Conlin,

Dale Belman, Mark Roehling, Stuart Low, and participants at the

2009 Midwest Economics Association and Population Association of

America conferences.

References

1. Committee on Practice and Ambulatory Medicine, Bright Futures

Steering Committee. (2007). Recommendations for preventive

pediatric health care. Pediatrics, 120, 1376.

2. Klerman, J. A., & Leibowitz, A. (1990). Child care and women’s

return to work after childbirth. The American Economic Review,80, 284–288.

3. Hauck, F. R., & Tanabe, K. O. (2008). International trends in

sudden infant death syndrome: Stabilization of rates requires

further action. Pediatrics, 122, 660–666.

4. National Institute of Child Health and Human Development.

(2009). SIDS: ‘Back to Sleep’ Campaign. http://www.nichd.nih.

gov/sids/. Accessed: 10 July 2009.

5. Williams, C. K. N., Harrad, R. A., Sparrow, J. M., & Harvey, I.

(2002). Amblyopia treatment outcomes after screening before or

at age 3 years: Follow up from randomized trial. British MedicalJournal, 324, 1549–1551.

6. Daw, N. W. (1998). Critical periods and amblyopia. Archives ofOphthalmology, 116, 502–505.

7. Kaye, C. I. (2006). Newborn screening fact sheets. Pediatrics,118, 934–963.

8. Hoyert, D. L., Kung, H., & Smith, B. L. (2005). Deaths:

Preliminary data for 2003. National Vital Statistics Reports, 53, 15.

9. Byrd, R. S., Hoekelman, R. A., & Auinger, P. (1999). Adherence

to AAP guidelines for well-child care under managed care.

Pediatrics, 104, 536–540.

10. Maisels, M. J., & Kring, E. (1997). Early discharge from the

newborn nursery–effect on scheduling of follow-up visits by

pediatricians. Pediatrics, 100, 72–74.

11. Ronsaville, D. S., & Hakim, R. B. (2000). Well child care in the

United States: Racial differences in compliance with guidelines.

American Journal of Public Health, 90, 1436–1443.

12. Yu, S. M., Bellamy, H. A., Kogan, M. D., Dunbar, J. L.,

Schwalberg, R. H., & Schuster, M. A. (2002). Factors that

influence receipt of recommended preventive pediatric health and

dental care. Pediatrics, 110.6:1–8.

Table 5 Descriptive analysis of jobs held by mothers who quit work

to care for family

Quit to care

for family

Continuously

employed

% Had paid vacation

in all RCIs employed

43.21% (4.59) 64.61% (1.20)

% Had paid sick leave

in all RCIs employed

33.09% (4.45) 57.56% (1.25)

% FMLA eligible in all

RCIs employed

7.70% (2.69) 35.94% (1.24)

N 172 2,344

Survey weights used to obtain population estimates. Standard errors

in parentheses

Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036 1035

123

Page 8: Making Time for Well-Baby Care: The Role of Maternal Employment

13. Mustin, H. D., Holt, V. L., & Connell, F. A. (1994). Adequacy

of well-child care and immunizations in U.S. infants born in

1988. The Journal of the American Medical Association, 272,

1111–1115.

14. Moore, P., & Hepworth, J. T. (1994). Use of perinatal and infant

health services by Mexican-American medicaid enrollees. TheJournal of the American Medical Association, 27, 297–304.

15. Colle, A. D., & Grossman, M. (1978). Determinants of pediatric

care utilization. The Journal of Human Resources, 13, 115–158.

16. Vistnes, J. P., & Hamilton, V. (1995). The time and monetary

costs of outpatient care for children. The American EconomicReview, 85, 117–121.

17. Berger, L. M., Hill, J., & Waldfogel, J. (2005). Maternity leave,

early maternal employment and child health and development in

the US. The Economic Journal, 115, F29–F47.

18. Blau, D. M., Guilkey, D. K., & Popkin, B. M. (1996). Infant

health and the labor supply of mothers. The Journal of HumanResources, 31, 90–139.

1036 Matern Child Health J (2011) 15:1029–1036

123