25
Doc. #48881 Agricultural Development Bank Reform: The Case of Unit Banking System of Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI) by Klaus Maurer & Hans Dieter Seibel Rural Finance Adviser, IFAD ([email protected]) February 2001 α IFAD – INTERNATIONAL FUND FOR AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT

Agricultural Development Bank Reform: The Case of Unit Banking System of Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Doc. #48881

Agricultural Development Bank Reform:

The Case of Unit Banking System ofBank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI)

by

Klaus Maurer

&

Hans Dieter SeibelRural Finance Adviser, IFAD

([email protected])

February 2001

αIFAD – INTERNATIONAL FUND FOR AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT

Disclaimer: IFAD's thematic working papers disseminate the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas. The authors are IFAD staff, consultants, and members of IFAD projects or partner organizations. The papers are unofficial documents which carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in these papers are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of IFAD, its Executive Directors, or member countries .

Table of contents

THE CASE OF UNIT BANKING SYSTEM OF................................................................................................1

BANK RAKYAT INDONESIA (BRI)..................................................................................................................1

1. INTRODUCTION..............................................................................................................................................1

2.THE REFORM OF THE BRI UNITS...............................................................................................................2

2.1 THE ERA OF SUPPLY-LEADING FINANCE (1969 TO 1983): BRI AS AGENT OF AGRICULTURAL ......................................2DEVELOPMENT..................................................................................................................................................22.2 THE BIG BANG REFORM IN 1983....................................................................................................................22.3 THE EVOLUTION OF THE NEW BRI UNIT BANKING SYSTEM (1984 TO 2000).........................................................2

3. LESSONS LEARNED FROM BRI’S REFORM EXPERIENCE..............................................................10

3.1 PREREQUISITES FOR THE BIG-BANG REFORM IN 1983........................................................................................103.2 SAFE-GUARDING THE UNITS’ OPERATIONAL AUTONOMY......................................................................................103.3 SUCCESS FACTORS AND LESSONS LEARNED FROM BRI’S OWN PERSPECTIVE...........................................................12

4. FUTURE CHALLENGES AND REFORM AGENDA AHEAD................................................................13

4.1 EXPANSION OF LENDING.............................................................................................................................134.2 THE UNIT BANKING SYSTEM AS „BANK“ WITHIN THE BANK BRI........................................................................134.3 LACK OF COMPETITION..............................................................................................................................15

i

Abstract:The case of BRI is evidence that, in a deregulated policy environment, a government-owned agricultural development bank can (a) be transformed into a highly profitable, self-reliant financial intermediary, and (b) turn into a major microfinance provider, offering carefully crafted microsavings and microcredit products to low-income people at market rates of interest. Making good use of government seed money and a World Bank loan during an initial phase, it has now fully substituted savings deposits for external loans as its source of funds. With an outreach to 25 million saving accounts and 2.7 million borrowers through a network of over 3,700 banking units operating as profit centers, BRI covers its costs from the interest rate margin and finances its expansion from its profits. With non-targeted loans from $5 to $5000 at rural market rates of interest and unrestricted deposit services, the BRI Microbanking Division has weathered the Asian financial crisis well, making BRI the only profitable government bank in Indonesia.

Several lessons can be drawn from BRI's experience:• Financial sector policies work and are conducive to financial innovations• With attractive savings and credit products, appropriate staff incentives, and an effective system

of internal regulation and supervision, rural microfinance can be profitable• The poor can save; rural financial institutions can mobilize their savings cost-effectively• If financial services are offered without a credit bias, demand for savings deposit services exceeds

the demand for credit by a wide margin• Incentives for timely repayment work• Outreach of a financial institution to vast numbers of low-income people and profitability are

compatible

After a big-bang-type of reform in 1983/84, the BRI Units soon became a model case in Asia of the transformation of an ailing government-owned agricultural development bank into a viable and self-sufficient financial intermediary with ever-increasing financial resources and numbers of customers, competing successfully with an array of other local financial institutions. Further strength was added to BRI’s microfinance operations during the Asian financial crisis: When the Indonesian banking system collapsed, BRI’s Unit Banking System remained profitable, the loan repayment high, and the deposit volume more than doubled. The BRI Units emerged from the crisis stronger than before.

ii

BRI Unit Banking SystemPerformance Indicators 2000

OUTREACH Loans outreachNumber of active borrowers 2.7 million% of households %Loan amount outstanding US$ 816 millionAverage loan size (disbursement) US$ 425

Savings outreachNumber of deposit accounts 25.8 millionDeposit volume US$ 1,992 millionAverage deposit size US$ 77Market share rural deposits (1998) 86 %

SUSTAINABILITY

Portfolio quality (Past dues/Loans outstanding) 2.5 %Operational self-sustainability (Income/Operational cost) 413 %Financial self-sustainability (Income/Operational cost and Cost of funds) 135 %Profitability Return on Assets 5.4 %Self-sufficiency in funds (Deposit to loans ratio) 244 %Efficiency (Administrative cost/Average loans outstanding) 8.4 %Productivity (Number of active borrowers/Credit officer) 534

iii

AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT BANK REFORM:The Case of Unit Banking System of Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI)

1. INTRODUCTION

Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI) is a state-owned commercial bank in Indonesia. For the past thirty years, BRI’s mandate has been the provision of banking services to the rural and agricultural sector. BRI's physical network is the most extensive of all banks in Indonesia and effectively covers the entire nation. BRI has 318 branches that are located in the district capitals and municipalities. Furthermore, the bank has an even more extensive network of 3,724 retail outlets at the sub-district level, known as the BRI Units1. Although both branches and Units are part of the same bank, the Unit Banking System can be clearly distinguished from the branch network in terms of target groups, services and mode of operation.

It is the BRI Unit Banking System that won the international reputation as a successful rural financial institution and more recently as the developing world’s largest microfinance institution. The Unit Banking System underwent a substantial reform in 1983. In subsequent years, it was transformed from a chronic loss maker to a highly profitable rural banking network. Most surprisingly, the BRI Unit Banking System weathered the severe financial crisis in the late 1990s better than any other financial institution.

The experience of the BRI Unit Banking System, the success factors and lessons learned have been extensively documented elsewhere.2 This paper focuses on the reform process and reform steps, and the lessons which can be learned by other banks in Asia and elsewhere. Section two presents a review of the various phases in the evolution of the new BRI Unit System and an analysis of the impact of the financial crisis on Unit operations, deposit mobilization and lending. Section three draws some of the lessons learned from BRI’s experience. Finally, the fourth section identifies and outlines a few critical areas for future reform.

1Formerly the Units were called Unit Desa (desa = village). However, the Units are actually not located at the village level but mostly in sub-district capital towns. More recently, many units have been opened in urban areas as well. 2Among others: Patten and Rosengard (1991), Robinson (1992, 1994), Yaron (1992), GTZ (1997), BRI (1997)

1

2. THE REFORM OF THE BRI UNITS

2.1 The era of supply-leading finance (1969 to 1983): BRI as agent of agriculturaldevelopment

Established more than 100 years ago during the Dutch colonial period in 1895 as De Poerwokertosche Hulp-en Spaarbank der Inlandsche Hoofden, the bank underwent several changes in its subsequent evolution. Following the independence of Indonesia, the bank was named Bank Rakyat Indonesia - Indonesian People’s Bank - and became the first government bank covering the entire country. Under the New Order Government of former president Suharto and the first Five-Year Development Plan which commenced in 1969, BRI was assigned an active role as agent of development with primary responsibility for the agricultural sector. In the spirit of the Green Revolution, a large credit program with subsidized interest rates for rice farmers - called BIMAS - was designed to promote national rice self-sufficiency. As BIMAS was to be implemented by BRI, the bank prepared itself by establishing more than 3,600 field units - then called Unit Desa - all over Indonesia in the early 1970s. The primary function of the Unit Desa was to channel cheap credit to farmers. The operating costs of the program were high, and as the interest rates were fixed by the government at low levels, BRI was saddled with annual operational losses. Hence, the implementation of BIMAS could only be sustained through administrative subsidies from the Ministry of Finance. Furthermore, the loan recovery gradually deteriorated and the capital stock eroded which required frequent injections of fresh funds. In the early 1980s, the BIMAS lending volume declined, loan defaults climbed above 50% and the program was rapidly approaching its collapse.

2.2 The big bang reform in 1983

BIMAS’ deterioration coincided with important events in the overall economic and political fields in early 1983. On the macroeconomic front, oil prices collapsed and the sharp decline in oil revenues put heavy strains on the government budget. On the political front, a new cabinet and most important a new finance minister took office. Under this new constellation, the government launched some major economic reforms. A major financial sector reform package was announced in June 1983. After decades of financial repression, the measures were a decisive step towards deregulation of Indonesia’s financial system. The most important element of the package was the liberalization of interest rates on both deposits and commercial loans.

In the light of the new policies it also became clear that the massive support to the BIMAS program cannot and will not be sustained by the government. When BIMAS was phased out at the end of 1983, and with it the subsidies to unit operations, BRI was faced with a difficult choice: either introduce drastic measures to increase the viability of the units, or close them down. With the encouragement of the Ministry of Finance, BRI decided to convert the Unit Desa into a rural banking network that would meet a wide range of financial needs in a flexible and financially viable way.

2.3 The evolution of the new BRI Unit Banking System (1984 to 2000)

Phase 1 (1984 to 1986): Establishing the new system

The task was enormous: 3,626 BRI Units had to be converted from loss-making BIMAS conduits to profitable, full-service rural banking units. A massive restructuring of the entire Units was necessary. Almost one third of the Units did not have the potential of reaching viability within a foreseeable period of time. However, they were not closed down, but were designated village service posts (PPD), kept open for one to six days a week depending on the volume of customers and transactions. Today, many of the PPDs have been upgraded to full units and the number of units is roughly the same as it was at the outset. Furthermore, many Units were physically relocated from out-of town field sites to town centers and close to the markets.

2

One of the first steps taken was the reorganization of the Units into profit centers and the creation of separate balance sheets and profit and loss statements for each Unit. A new accounting system, focusing on transparency, allowed each Unit’s performance to be evaluated. A standardized management information system centered around few but significant performance indicators was to provide timely information to managers and supervisors at all levels. It was on this foundation that a staff incentive system were built.

In February 1984, a single loan product for general rural credit (KUPEDES) was introduced. KUPEDES is non-targeted and non-subsidized, and is available to any creditworthy customer for any kind of productive enterprise. Loan terms are up to 24 months for working capital and up to 36 months for investment capital. KUPEDES interest rates were set at 1.5% flat per month for working capital loans and 1% for investment loans. The flat rates are calculated on the borrower's original balance and work out to annual effective rates of 33% and 22% respectively,3 if loans are paid on time. KUPEDES borrowers must provide sufficient collateral to cover the value of the loan, usually in the form of land titles, but also by the pledging of buildings, motorcycles or other property. The maximum loan size has gradually been raised over the years from US$ 1,000 at the start to around US$ 5,000 (Rp 50 million) today.

Savings mobilization has been an integral part of the Unit banking philosophy and strategy since the beginning. The objective of creating a viable and financially self-sufficient network of financial in-termediaries was based on the belief that the large demand for loans can be financed by locally-mo-bilized savings. In November 1984, BRI introduced SIMPEDES, a rural savings product, on a pilot basis. The pilot project quickly showed evidence of massive demand for a liquid, convenient and safe deposit facility. After some modifications and refinements, the facility was successively expan-ded to all Units by September 1986. Since then, SIMPEDES has developed into the main product accounting for about two thirds of total deposits. In addition, the BRI Units offer demand and time deposits, as well as TABANAS, another passbook savings product originating from the pre-deregu-lation era, which is mainly used by school children and students.

3Based on a twelve month loan with monthly installments of equal principal amounts according to the following formula: [i x 2 x t/(n+1)]x 12, where i=monthly flat rate, t=loan term in months, n=number of monthly installments.

3

Table 1: Deposits and loans in BRI Units, 1984-2000 (Amount in Rp billion)

Deposits Loans outstanding Deposit to loanYear Accounts Amount Number Amount ratio1984 2,655 42 640,746 111 38%1985 36,563 85 1,034,532 229 37%1986 418,945 176 1,231,723 334 53%1987 4,183,983 288 1,314,780 430 67%1988 4,998,038 493 1,386,035 542 91%1989 6,261,988 959 1,643,980 847 113%1990 7,262,509 1,695 1,893,138 1,382 122%1991 8,587,872 2,541 1,837,549 1,456 174%1992 9,953,294 3,399 1,831,732 1,649 206%1993 11,431,078 4,325 1,895,965 1,957 220%1994 13,066,854 5,232 2,053,919 2,458 213%1995 14,482,763 6,016 2,263,767 3,191 189%1996 16,147,260 7,092 2,488,135 4,076 174%1997 18,143,316 8,837 2,615,679 4,685 188%1998 21,698,594 16,146 2,457,652 4,697 344%1999 24,235,889 17,061 2,473,923 5,957 286%2000 25,823,228 19,115 2,715,609 7,827 244%

Both KUPEDES and SIMPEDES had a successful start, and after three years of operation it became clear that the BRI unit system could be financially viable. In 1984, only 14% of the Units were profitable, two years later this share had increased to 72%.

Phase 2 (1987 to 1991): Big surge in savings and manifestation as the player in rural finance

The next five years saw a major expansion of outreach and a big surge in savings mobilization as illustrated in Table 1. During this period, the number of savings accounts grew rapidly to almost 8.6 million and - at a slower pace - the number of borrowers to almost 1.5 million. This dimension of outreach clearly established the BRI Unit system as the major player in rural finance in Indonesia.

The development of the BRI Units during the second phase received support from a conducive policy environment. In October 1988, the government announced a set of reform measures known under the acronym PAKTO which opened entry in the financial markets to new participants and aimed at deliberate promotion of competition among banks. New financial services such as factoring, consumer credit, venture capital, and securities dealing and underwriting were opened up to commercial banks. Banks were allowed to introduce their own savings products, and the minimum reserve requirement was lowered to a uniform 2% on all deposits. This caused a fierce competition among banks and resulted in an outright explosion of bank deposits in the following years.4

The BRI Units particularly benefited during the boom years. The Units added one million new depositors every year and the deposit volume increased annually by 80% on average. In the sixth year of operation in 1989, the BRI Unit system achieved self-sufficiency in funding when the volume of deposits was equal to the loan amount outstanding. As deposits continued to rise and lending operations did not expand at the same pace, the BRI Units soon experienced a situation of ever increasing excess liquidity - a situation which has prevailed for the past ten years in varying degrees until today. The excess liquidity was transferred from the Units to the BRI branch system

4 Total bank deposits in Indonesia increased from US$16 billion in 1987 (before the reform) to US$118 bil-lion in 1996.

4

Another reform package came in January 1990, when the Central Bank announced the immediate termination of 34 government-sponsored credit programs, and with it, the phasing out of refinance facilities which put increased pressure on banks, especially state banks, to search for their own funds. The situation was further aggravated in February 1991 when the finance minister withdrew an amount of US$ 4.2 billion in deposits from the banking system (so-called Sumarlin-shock) to curb the growth in money supply and counter the danger of overheating of the economy.

BRI as a whole suddenly faced a liquidity problem. The management reacted swiftly and imposed a general credit stop. This policy decision had considerable consequences for the BRI Units. For two years, the Units did not accept any new borrowers, in fact, the number of borrowers with loans outstanding dropped in 1991 and 1992 (see Table 1). Furthermore, the credit crunch led to a deterioration of the loan repayment. The repayment rate dropped to 95% in 1991, the arrears climbed over 9% in 1992 (see Table ), a level not seen in the entire history. The BRI management learned an important lesson from this unexpected reaction. The reliability of financial services, in particular the availability of future loans, is an important incentive for borrowers to repay their loans. Any restriction and disruption may have an immediate effect on the borrowers’ motivation and discipline.

Table 2: KUPEDES repayment performance

Year 12-monthRepayment rate

Arrears ratio

1984 99.0% 5.4%1985 98.2% 2.1%1986 97.3% 4.5%1987 97.0% 5.8%1988 95.4% 7.4%1989 97.7% 5.4%1990 98.0% 4.1%1991 95.1% 8.6%1992 96.6% 9.1%1993 97.8% 6.5%1994 99.3% 4.5%1995 98.9% 3.5%1996 98.4% 3.7%1997 97.8% 4.7%1998 98.1% 5.7%1999 98.3% 3.1%2000 98.9% 2.5%

Phase 3 (1992 to 1997): Stable growth in a conducive environment, improving systems and increasing efficiency

Growth continued throughout the 1990s, albeit at a slower pace than in the first decade. Every year, the Units added an average of 100,000 borrowers and 1.5 million deposits. Deposits continued to outstrip loans both in terms of number of accounts and volume. At the end of the third phase, the Unit Banking System recorded more than 18 million deposit accounts against 2.6 million borrowers, a ratio of 7:1. BRI’s experience has shown that most rural households are net savers most of the time.

In terms of volume, the deposit-to-loan ratio has been about 2:1. In other words, only half of the funds mobilized by the Units were recycled as KUPEDES loans, the other half was transferred to the branch system. For the Units, the fund transfer was attractive as they were paid an interest rate - the so-called transfer price - which was normally set slightly above the interest rate paid on time deposits. The

5

branches easily absorbed the Units’ excess liquidity and channeled the funds into large corporate loans which were rapidly expanded during this period.

The third phase also saw a considerable progress in productivity and efficiency. Staff productivity was raised significantly. Nowadays, a credit officer is responsible for more than 500 borrowers and a teller handles about 6,000 deposit accounts on average. As a consequence, administrative efficiency increased. Administrative expenses as percent of average loans outstanding were brought down from 10% to 8% (see Table below). The gains in productivity and efficiency were partly due to the computerization of the Units which was completed during this period. Another reason may have been the staffing standards which were consistently applied and ensured maximum performance: one credit officer for every 400 borrowers (excluding fixed income loans), one teller for every 200 daily cash transactions, and one bookkeeper for 150 daily transactions.

Table 3: Staff productivity and efficiency

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000Staff productivity:# active borrowers per credit officer 440 466 503 541 527 478 490 534# deposit accounts per teller 3,008 3,320 3,598 3,887 4,220 4,962 5,614 6,181

Efficiency: Administrative expenses/average loan portfolio

n.a. 10.1% 9.7% 9.4% 9.4% 8.4% 8.1% 8.4%

Source: Own calculations on the basis of data from BRI Monthly Report February 2001

Phase 4 (1998 to 2000): The financial and economic crisis: challenges and opportunities

What started as a currency crisis in Thailand in July 1997, unfolded as the worst financial and economic crisis for Southeast Asian countries in decades. Indonesia has probably been the country hit most hardest. The major onslaught of the crisis came in late 1997 and early 1998. Within a few months, the country's currency - the Rupiah - experienced a dramatic 80% plunge in its value against the US dollar, followed by sharp increases in inflation (77% in 1998) and interest rates. The ensuing political crisis mounted in May 1998 with the downfall of president Suharto. The banking system was on the brink of collapse when the government stepped in and provided a blanket guarantee cover for all bank deposits. Many private banks were closed down, major state banks merged and non-performing assets transferred to the newly-created Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency (IBRA).

It is hard to believe but the BRI Unit Banking System remained largely unaffected by the severe crisis! Rather the opposite was the case as BRI benefited from its status as government-owned bank and safe haven for depositors. From early 1998 onwards, the Units experienced a tremendous influx of deposits as illustrated in Chart 1 below. Within little over a year, time deposits shot up from Rp 1 trillion to Rp 7 trillion. Savings - mainly SIMEPDES/SIMASKOT - continued to grow steadily and their volume more than doubled in the course of two years. A slight friction was felt in the second half of 1998 when some depositors shifted from savings to time deposits due to comparatively higher time deposit rates.

Loans stagnated for about two years. During 1998, the number of loans even declined by 6% from 2.61 million to 2.46 million accounts. However, most surprisingly loan repayment was affected only marginally. The 12-months repayment rate remained at about 98% throughout the crisis years (see Table 2 above). The arrears increased to a high of 6% for a few months in late 1998 but has come down to 2.5% at the end of 2000, an extremely low level for the BRI Units in a historical perspective. However, BRI had to pay its tribute in form of higher loan loss provisions.

Apparently, the micro business sector was not hit as hard by the crisis as medium and large enterprises. Micro and small enterprises utilize family labor and capital to large extent, and can thus more flexibly

6

and easily adjust to changes. Furthermore, the agricultural sector, especially tree crops, performed well during and after the crisis. And finally, the borrowers’ repayment discipline remained strong despite the hardships of the crisis.

Chart 1: BRI Units during and after the crisis

0

2.000

4.000

6.000

8.000

10.000

12.000

14.000

16.000

Jan

97

Jul 9

7

Jan

98

Jul 9

8

Jan

99

Jul 9

9

Jan

00

Jul 0

0

Jan

01

Savings Time deposits Loans

In mid-1999, the crisis was effectively over for the BRI Units. Time deposits returned to normal levels as ‘fugitive’ deposits were gradually withdrawn with the stabilization of the financial sector. KUPEDES lending picked up again and the loan portfolio almost doubled from mid-1999 until end-2000. However, the crisis has left its scars. The surge of inflation to a rate of 77.6% in 1998 has dampened the performance in real terms, i.e. after taking into account inflation. Chart 2 presents the development of deposits and loans in BRI Units in real terms, i.e. in constant prices of 1984. Deposits exhibit a steady growth path, albeit at a slightly lower rate since the outbreak of the crisis. Loans marked a sharp decline in real terms in the crisis year. If the current growth continues, the loan portfolio will likely reach the pre-crisis level at the end of 2001.

7

Chart 2: Deposits and loans in real terms, 1984 to 2000(Rp billion in constant prices of 1984)

0

500

1.000

1.500

2.000

2.500

3.000

3.500

4.0001

98

5

19

90

19

95

20

00

Deposits Loans

The impact of the crisis on the viability of BRI Unit operations was only marginal. The profitability suffered slightly in 1998 and 1999 due to (a) increased loan loss provisions and (b) higher cost of funds which reduced the financial spread. The income and cost structure of the Unit Banking System is presented in Table 4 below as percent of average loans outstanding. While the cost of funds move with the market, the interest rates on KUPEDES loans have remained unchanged since inception. The only exception was during the crisis when inflation and interest rates shot up and KUPEDES rates were increased for a period of nine months. BRI Units operate with a comfortable spread of around 20% of average loans outstanding. Operating costs have moved at around 11% on average, leaving a considerable profit.

8

Table 4: Income and cost structure of the BRI Unit Banking System, 1994 to 2000

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000(% of average loans outstanding)

Interest income from lending 32.4% 31.6% 30.3% 30.3% 30.9% 35.4% 33.2%less: Cost of funds 8.5% 9.6% 10.7% 11.6% 12.7% 16.0% 8.0% = Financial spread 23.8% 22.0% 19.7% 18.7% 18.2% 19.4% 25.2%

Administrative cost 10.1% 9.7% 9.4% 9.4% 8.4% 8.1% 8.4%add: Loan loss provisions 1.8% 1.3% 1.3% 1.4% 2.9% 5.0% 2.8% = Operating cost 12.0% 10.9% 10.6% 10.7% 11.3% 13.1% 11.1%

Profit 11.9% 11.1% 9.1% 8.0% 6.9% 6.3% 14.1%Source: Own calculations on the basis of data from BRI Monthly Report February 2001. Note: The calculation assumes KUPEDES lending as profit center and uses weighted cost of funds and administrative cost.

The Unit Banking System as a whole has been profitable since 1986. During the 1990s, the profitability increased steadily and the Return on Assets (RoA) reached more than 6% as illustrated in Table 5. Return on Assets includes interest earned on excess funds held with BRI branches which explains the slightly different profitability pattern compared to Table 4.

Table 5: Profitability of BRI Units

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000Net income (Rp billion) 140 265 403 423 417 861 1,190 1,160Average annual assets (Rp billion) 3,344 5,401 6,482 7,680 9,224 14,068 19,487 21,676Return on Assets (RoA) 3.1% 4.9% 6.2% 5.5% 4.5% 6.1% 6.1% 5.4%Source: Own calculations on the basis of data from BRI Monthly Report February 2001.

A number of rural financial institutions have reported adequate financial returns in terms of Return on Assets (ROA) and Return on Equity (RoE), but they depended heavily on subsidies. The favorable financial ratios of the BRI units are not a result of subsidies but of efficient rural financial intermediation. Since 1987, Yaron’s subsidy dependency index (SDI) has been negative, reaching –48% in 1995 (Charitonenko et al.1998)5.

However, the rest of BRI fared much worse during the crisis. Due to heavy loan losses in the corporate business unit, BRI almost collapsed (see section IV.3 below).

5 Positive values indicate subsidy dependency: the higher the value, the higher the dependency. Some comparative SDI figures from donor-driven programs in Nepal, 1991/92: ADBN‘s Small Farmers Development Programme 135%; Intensive Banking Programme 180%; Production Credit for Rural Women 366%. (Seibel, Pant and Dhungel 1998:4)

9

3. LESSONS LEARNED FROM BRI’S REFORM EXPERIENCE

A little more than a decade of KUPEDES and SIMPEDES has made the BRI unit system one of the most successful rural financial institutions in the developing world. Some of the features are certainly unique and relate to the specific context of rural Indonesia and/or to BRI as an institution, but there are many others that can be generalized and applied in other countries. The BRI experience has become a learning ground for policy makers and practitioners from institutions and countries around the world.6

3.1 Prerequisites for the big-bang reform in 1983

The timing of the reform was favorable. The timing of the introduction of a savings-based rural banking system in early 1984 was appropriate as several events coincided. This included among others: the financial sector deregulation in June 1983 allowing banks to set their own interest rates, the choice forced by the collapse of the BIMAS credit program, and the declining acceptability of subsidized programs in general, as well as key personnel changes in the government (new finance minister) and in BRI (new president director) in 1983. Even after the big-bang reform in 1983, stable macroeconomic conditions and a further reform of the financial sector provided a favorable and conducive environment in which the new Unit Banking System could develop and prosper.

The political will to reform the BRI Units was strong. The political will to reform the BRI Units originated primarily from economic pressures. The oil price collapse in 1983 and the decline in oil revenues forced the government to impose austerity on budgetary expenses. The government simply could not afford to continue funding the BIMAS credit program and the continuous losses it created for BRI. Moreover, the political goal of achieving self-sufficiency in rice production - the rationale of BIMAS - had been achieved, thus adding pressure to terminate the program. Furthermore, the blueprint for reform was perfectly in line with the overall financial reforms announced in June 1983, thus winning the support of the architects of the reform in the Ministry of Finance and the Central Bank. The following period of transformation and development of the Unit Banking System, too, saw strong support from the government, there was little or no interference in the Unit operations. Section 2 below explores how the Units managed to maintain operational autonomy.

A farsighted blueprint for a new Unit Banking System was on the table. The big-bang type of reform which followed required a clear vision of the restructuring and transformation of 3,600 Units and its 14,000 staff into a fundamentally different system. There was not much time for trial and error. The blueprint for a sustainable rural banking system had been put on the table by a team of local bankers and international rural finance experts in 1983. The essential components which today are regarded as the success factors of the Unit Banking System were already included in the initial blueprint. The concept was partly based on the positive experience of BRI with two non-agricultural loan programs (Kredit Mini and Kredit Midi) and to a large extent on the inputs from the team of international consultants who supported the design and implementation of the new system. Given the success of the BRI Unit Banking System and given the fact that little was changed in the design for almost two decades, the original blueprint was farsighted and the choice a right one. An overview of the main components is presented in Section 3 below.

3.2 Safe-guarding the Units’ operational autonomy

With BRI being a government-owned bank, the issue of operational autonomy gains particular relevance. As mentioned above, the government has maintained a hands-off position since the re-design of the Unit Banking System in 1983. How was it possible to keep the Units free from typical interventions such as credit targeting, interest rate restrictions, provision of cheap funds, etc. or from interference in lending decisions? Several reasons may account for this:

• BRI’s self-reliance in terms of fund mobilization and profitability has created the material base for its autonomy and freedom from political interference which has so severely afflicted the rest of the banking system. The Unit Banking System was profitable from the third year (1986) and self-

6BRI’s International Visitors Program receives study groups from all over the world.

10

sufficient in funding from the sixth year (1989) onwards. Except for the initial injection of seed capital at the tune of US$ 20 million in 1984, there were no further government funds needed. A World Bank loan of US$ 97 million for onlending was provided at a time when the BRI Unit Banking System no longer needed outside funds.

• Strong leadership has proven a crucial factor. BRI's president director from 1983 to 1992 took personal initiative and responsibility for the development of the Unit Banking System. Jointly with the other members of the Board he protected the Units from interference and led the development of what they called BRI's new culture and Indonesia's new rural banking system.7

• The only targeting device applied in the Unit Banking System was a ceiling for KUPEDES loans in order to focus the Unit operations on the micro business segment. Initially the maximum loan size was fixed at about US$ 1,000 and was successively raised to US$ 5,000. The relatively small loan sizes have effectively kept large and politically influential borrowers out of the system, thereby reducing the probability of interference.

• However, it would be naive to assume that BRI as a government-owned bank were free of

government influence and intervention. As agent of development, BRI has always played a role in the implementation of rural credit programs designed by the government for priority sectors and target groups until today. However, all these programs are administered by the BRI branches and are overseen by a ‘political’ division for program credit in the head office. This way, BRI has always accommodated specific requests and special programs from the government (and from donors) without disturbing the development of the Unit Banking System. For example, BRI branches continue to provide subsidized loans to farmers - successor programs to BIMAS - and to politically-favored village cooperatives, however, strictly separated from the mainstream of Unit operations. The lesson to be learned by government-owned banks is clear: As government intervention cannot be avoided the bank could (and should) accommodate such programs in a special unit, but keep the mainstream free from intervention.

7Robinson 1992, pp.48-49.

11

3.3 Success factors and lessons learned from BRI’s own perspective

Key principles of the success of the Unit Banking System and Lessons Learned

During the past decade and a half, BRI has learned many valuable lessons in moving away from a targeted, subsidized rural finance program into a full-service, fully commercial microfinance institution. Some of the most important of these lessons are:

• In order to minimize overhead costs, credit should be made available to all creditworthy microcredit customers. If a bank can serve only one particular segment, such as agriculture, staff and other overhead costs are too high. The bank should be able to lend for any productive enterprise.

• Credit decisions should be based solely on a borrower’s willingness and ability to repay - and this decision should be left to the bank. The amount of the loan should be directly related to need and the assessed repayment capacity of the enterprise and borrower. If the decision is made by agricultural extension workers of other government officials, the creditworthiness criterion is diluted. The borrower should know that loan decisions are based solely on the bank officer’s judgement of creditworthiness, and that additional credits will be available if earlier loans are repaid according to agreed terms.

• Access to credit on a long term basis is more important than cheap credit . Interest rates should be set to cover the costs of the bank so that the bank is financially viable, and can therefore provide credit over the long term as needed. Consistency and sustainability are far more important to borrowers than cheap credit programs which fade away when the government’s budget is tight or donor fashions change.

• Almost all households want to and are able to save, and serving their need to save is just as important as serving their demand for credit. There is a large potential for savings among relatively low-income people. However, savings instruments must be designed to meet the needs of savers. People need a safe place to keep their savings. They need liquid savings instruments for their routine enterprise and household financial requirements. They need to have funds available to meet unforeseen emergencies as well as to meet regular, relatively large expenses such as school fees and uniforms.

• Operating a large network of small banks efficiently requires a combination of simplicity and transparency, standardization, and delegation of authority and responsibility. The cornerstone of the Unit Banking System’s transparency leis in the simplicity of the credit and savings instruments offered and the Units’ financial statements. Savings and loan terms, interest rates, reporting, training, and procedures are all standardized. With this simplicity and standardization, it’s possible to create an efficient well-supervised system which delegates authority to the local level. Thus, both the responsibility and the authority for amking good loans and earning a profit lie at the local level.

Adopted from: Bank Rakyat Indonesia (1997): Introduction to BRI’s Unit Banking System, page 19

12

4. FUTURE CHALLENGES AND REFORM AGENDA AHEAD

Despite the overall success with the reform of the BRI Unit banking System over the past one and a half decades, some challenges remain to be tackled in the near future. Three critical issues remain to be addressed in the following.

4.1 Expansion of lending

A critical issue is the financial drain occurring within the BRI unit system. Since 1989, savings mobilization has exceeded KUPEDES lending, which has led to a considerable transfer of funds to the urban BRI branch network. Throughout the 1990s, more than half of the savings mobilized by the units were deposited in the branches. The financial crisis has widened the gap even further in 1998 when 70 % of the deposits were channeled off to the BRI branches.

Despite BRI’s achievements in lending outreach, there is still a large unmet demand for loans in rural Indonesia. With 2.7 million borrowers out of a population of more than 200 million - with the majority living and working in rural areas, BRI so far has likely reached the smaller part of the potential customers in all sectors of the economy. The distribution of KUPEDES loans outstanding by economic sector show a clear concentration of loans in small trade (42%) and for fixed salary employees (30%). Only 22% of the loans were provided for agriculture and just 2% for small industry.

Table 6: Distribution of KUPEDES loans by economic sector (December 2000)

Economic sector Number of borrowers

Loan amount(US$ million)

Share

Agriculture 589,834 177.0 22 %Industry 66,329 19.2 2 %Trade 1,154,838 338.6 42 %Fixed salary employees 817,041 242.9 30 %Other 87,566 38.1 5 %Total 2,715,608 815.8 100 %

Source: BRI Microbanking Division

Given the potential of Indonesia’s rural economy and the likely credit demand of micro and small businesses, the number of borrowers could probably double or triple, especially in agriculture and agriculture-related activities. BRI Units may also consider to enter new segments such as housing and consumer finance. Also, the time will come when a single loan product - KUPEDES - may no longer be adequate to serve an increasingly diversified and heterogeneous clientele, when new products and services are needed. The planned introduction of online banking services is an important step towards the integration of the Units and their customers into the wider payments system.

However, on the supply side the expansion of lending is primarily a function of number of staff, especially loan officers. The number of loan officers has not risen substantially over the past decade and has remained almost unchanged since 1997. At the end of 2000, there were 5,082 loan officers each serving an average of 534 borrowers (374 microenterprises and 160 fixed salary employee loans). Hence, they have reached a productivity ceiling and there is not much scope to increase the number of borrowers any further without sacrificing the service quality and loan quality. An expansion of borrower outreach can therefore only be achieved with additional staff. A significant increase in the number of loan officers would be an important step to reduce the financial drain, to narrow the gap between deposits and loans and to strengthen local financial intermediation.

4.2 The Unit Banking System as „bank“ within the bank BRI

13

Another critical point relates to the role of the Unit Banking System within the overall organization of BRI as a commercial bank. The transformation of the Units from a chronic loss-maker to a highly profitable entity has also changed its role within BRI. In the 1970s and 1980s, the Units were totally dependent on the mother institution in terms funding and operational subsidies. Within little more than a decade, this has changed to the opposite. In the 1990s, the Units and the microbanking business were generating the profits to sustain the rest of BRI! The rest of BRI, i.e. the branch network, has been running losses since several years - a fact well hidden in consolidated figures.8 It was solely due to the Units’ performance that, on a consolidated basis, BRI posted a positive net income until 1997 (see Table 7). Needless to mention that the bill was paid by the Unit customers, the micro borrowers and savers.

Table 7: Profitability of BRI Units versus BRI branches (Net income in US$ million)

1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000BRI (consolidated before tax) 57 67 111 145 30 -3,308 -243 n.a. of which: a. Branch network -10 -54 -64 -33 -60 -3,397 -411 n.a. b. Unit Banking System 66 121 174 178 90 89 168 121

The bomb exploded in 1998 when BRI was hit by the financial crisis. 56% of the branches’ loan portfolio - large corporate loans for the major part - turned sour and had to be written off. This resulted in a loss of US$ 3.3 billion against a capital base of only US$ 215 million. In 1998, the consolidated BRI - including the Unit banking System! - was technically insolvent and effectively bankrupt, like many other banks in Indonesia at the time. Being an integral part of BRI suddenly turned into a major risk for the BRI Unit Banking System, the risk of being dragged into bankruptcy by the ailing mother organization. However, the government stepped in to recapitalize BRI; the non-performing loans were transferred to the Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency (IBRA).

Table 8: Microbanking „market shares“ within BRI

1997 1998 1999Savings Deposits 69 % 73 % 70 %Total Deposits 37 % 40 % 43 %Net Loans 14 % 21 % 25 %Assets 25 % 53 % 67 %

Source: Own calculations on the basis of data from BRI Monthly Report February 2001and BRI Annual Reports 1998 and 1999

Until 1997, the microbanking section had grown into a substantial business unit of BRI already but the crisis and the faltering corporate business gave it major boost. At the end of 1999, the Unit Banking System accounted for the major share in savings deposit volume (70%), almost half of all deposits (43%) and micro loans (KUPEDES) made up one quarter of BRI’s net loans. The Units brought in two thirds of BRI’s assets, although this ratio declined in 2000 when the recapitalization bonds were issued and fresh money came in.

Adopted as a sick baby in 1984, the Unit System recovered quickly with the right medicine and developed into a healthy child. Today, the child has grown up and matured. The microbanking business is not only able to stand on its own feet but has nurtured the mother organization for most of the past decade. And when BRI was severely affected by the financial crisis, the very existence and success of the Unit Banking System has convinced policy makers to save and recapitalize BRI.9 Now the responsibility lies with the rest of BRI, the branch network, to carry out fundamental reforms. In this regard, much can be learned from the child, i.e. the Unit Banking System.

8 See also GTZ (1997) for critical comments on this issue.9 Other state commercial banks were merged into one, i.e. Bank Mandiri.

14

4.3 Lack of Competition

A third critical point relates to BRI’s market position in rural finance. The BRI Unit Banking System has operated under little or no competition and has thus manifested a monopolist position in the rural areas of Indonesia. The concern is that this may result in distortions of the market with negative consequences for the customers and other market participants.

The financial reforms in Indonesia over the past two decades have resulted in a tremendous expansion of financial institutions and services. Following the financial sector reform package of 1988, more than 2,000 small, private rural banks (BPR) were established at the sub-district level, often close to the BRI Unit. However, the private BPRs had to struggle hard to compete with the government-owned BRI Unit in deposit mobilization as the latter offered government-guaranteed safety of deposits.10 Hence, BPRs are forced to offer higher returns on deposits11 and better service, e.g., doorstep collection of savings, in order to attract depositors. Furthermore, most BPR are independent unit banks with no recourse to vertical risk diversification and with no access to a liquidity pool like the BRI, exposing them to much higher risks and costs. This situation has placed the BPRs at a comparative disadvantage vis-a-vis the BRI Units.

Despite growing competition in some areas, the BRI Unit Banking System has retained its dominant position in the rural financial system in Indonesia. In terms of rural deposits, BRI is clearly a monopolist accounting for almost 80% of the accounts and 86% of the deposit volume (see Table 9). In the rural credit market, the BPRs were able to gain ground achieving a market share of more than 30% while BRI’s position with more than half of all borrowers has remained strong. In terms of number of borrowers, the village credit institutions (BKD) emerge as a strong third player. The fact that they account for just 2% of the loan amount is an indication of the very small loan sizes of BKDs. It should be mentioned, however, that the BKDs are supervised and therefore effectively controlled by BRI which puts BRI in an even stronger position.

Table 9: Market shares of rural financial institutions (June 1998)

Rural financial institutions Savings Deposits Loans outstandingType of institution Number Accounts Amount2 Number AmountBRI Units1 4,085 78 % 86 % 52 % 69 %Rural banks (BPR) 2,227 19 % 13 % 32 % 30 %Village credit institutions (BKD) 5,345 3 % 1 % 16 % 2 %Total 11,657 100 % 100 % 100 % 100 %

Sources: BRI: Monthly monitoring data; BPR and BKD: Bank Indonesia 10/19981 Data for the number of BRI units include village posts2 Deposit amount includes savings and time deposits; for BPR and BKD includes equity.The market shares presented in Table 9 are based on mid-1998 data and, hence, do not yet reflect the impact of the crisis. While the crisis has strengthened the BRI Unit Banking System even further as outlined earlier, it has badly affected the private rural banks. Many BPRs have already been closed and many more will have to be liquidated in the near future. The sad consequence from a market policy viewpoint is that the crisis has stifled the slowly emerging competition in the rural financial markets of Indonesia.

From the BRI Units’ viewpoint, this dominant position is undoubtedly beneficial - the profit margins are a clear indication. However, in the medium and long run the exposure to competition is a necessary prerequisite to maintain and continuously improve the quality of the financial services and the efficiency of the Unit operations. Competition ensures that efficiency gains are passed on to the customers and are not used for cross-subsidizing bad performance and inefficiency in other parts of the organization as it

10 The BRI Units clearly demonstrated their competitive advantage as government-owned bank by posting the national flag in front of every Unit.11The deposit rates of BPR are frequently 3-5 percentage points above SIMPEDES rates.

15

happens in BRI. In this regard, policy makers and regulators have a responsibility for creating the enabling environment.

Finally, competition is the driving force for innovations - an aspect which may need to be addressed by the BRI Unit Banking System. The initial blueprint which has been the centerpiece of the success story of the BRI Unit Banking System may require innovative modifications and adaptations to the rapidly changing environment in Indonesia, in Asia and in the global economy.

16

References

Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI), Annual Reports, Jakarta 1994, 1995, 1998, 1999

BRI (1997): Introduction to BRI’s Unit Banking System. Jakarta

BRI Head Office, Laporan Bulanan BRI Unit, February 2001. Jakarta

Charitonenko, Stephanie, Richard H Patten, and Jacob Yaron (1998): Indonesia: Bank Rakyat Indonesia – Unit Desa 1970-1996. Sustainable Banking with the Poor - Case Studies in Microfinance. Washington DC, The World Bank

Deutsche Gesellschaft fuer technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ). (1997). Comparative Analysis of Sav-ings Mobilization Strategies - Case Study of Bank Rakyat Indonesia.

Robinson, M., Rural Financial Intermediation: Lessons from Indonesia, Part One: The Bank Rakyat Indonesia: Rural Banking 1970-91, Development Discussion Paper 434, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Institute for International Development 1992.

Robinson, M., Savings Mobilization and Microenterprise Finance: The Indonesian Experience, in: M. Otero and E. Rhyne (eds), The New World of Microenterprise Finance, West Hartford: Kumarian 1994.

Patten, R.H. and J.K. Rosengard, Progress with Profits - The Development of Rural Banking in Indonesia, San Francisco, International Center for Economic Growth 1991.

Seibel, H.D. (1989): Finance with the Poor, by the Poor, for the Poor. Financial Technologies for the Informal Sector, with Case Studies from Indonesia. Social Strategies vol. 3 no. 2. Basel University

Seibel, H.D., & Uben Parhusip (1998):Microfinance in Indonesia. An Assessment of Microfinance Institutions Banking with the Poor. Economics & Sociology Occasional Paper No. 2365. Rural Finance Program, Dept. of Agricultural Economics, The Ohio State University, Columbus

World Bank, KUPEDES: Indonesia's Model Small Credit Program, Operations Evaluation Department, OED Précis, Number 104, February 1996.

Yaron, J., Successful Rural Financial Institutions. World Bank Discussion Paper 150. Washington, D.C. 1992.

17