43
1 Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles in the market for corporate directors Changmin Lee Hanyang University Business School 222 Wangsimni-ro, Seongdong-gu Seoul, Korea, 133-791 [email protected] Jihong Jeon Hanyang University Business School 222 Wangsimni-ro, Seongdong-gu Seoul, Korea, 133-791 [email protected] Woonam Seok Korea Corporate Governance Service 76, Yeouinaru-ro, Yeongdeungpo-gu Seoul, Korea, 07329 [email protected] We would like to thank John J. Moon and other seminar participants at ESG Seminar, Korea Exchange at Seoul (March 2017), Dep’t of Econ, SKKU University, Seoul (Nov 2017), for helpful comments and suggestions.

Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

1

Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last?

Political cycles in the market for corporate directors

Changmin Lee

Hanyang University Business School

222 Wangsimni-ro, Seongdong-gu

Seoul, Korea, 133-791

[email protected]

Jihong Jeon

Hanyang University Business School

222 Wangsimni-ro, Seongdong-gu

Seoul, Korea, 133-791

[email protected]

Woonam Seok

Korea Corporate Governance Service

76, Yeouinaru-ro, Yeongdeungpo-gu

Seoul, Korea, 07329

[email protected]

We would like to thank John J. Moon and other seminar participants at ESG Seminar, Korea

Exchange at Seoul (March 2017), Dep’t of Econ, SKKU University, Seoul (Nov 2017), for helpful

comments and suggestions.

Page 2: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

2

Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last?

Political cycles in the market for corporate directors

Ji-hong Jeon, Woo-nam Seok, Chang-min Lee*

Abstract

In this paper, we explore the relationship between CEO’s political preference and post-retirement

directorship holding by individual CEOs. We use a data set on the political donations of CEOs to major

political parties during from 2003-2014 in the USA. Firstly, our empirical evidence suggests that the

political donations of CEOs are more likely to reveal a preference, not strategic behavior. Seventy-one

point three percent of CEOs do not change the pattern of donation according to the ruling party. Second,

the success in the market for corporate director depends on the ruling party. Republican partisan CEOs

hold larger outside directorships than Democratic partisan CEOs only under a Republican regime. These

regressions results are robust for controlling the endogeneity problem. Thirdly, Democratic CEOs have

more variations on outside directorships across political regimes. Democratic CEOs hold 0.72

directorships two years after retirement and 0.71 directorships three years after retirement under a

Democratic regime, which are statistically larger than 0.35 and 0.13 under a Republican regime.

However, Republican CEOs hold stable outside directorships across different ruling parties. Finally, the

political cycle in the market for corporate director could be partially explained by the connection value

in the regulated industry. Democratic partisans hold more outside directorships in the regulated industry

than Republican partisans for two years after retirement under a Democratic regime.

Keywords: Political Preference, Political Connections, Boards of Director, CEO, Career Concern

JEL classification: G30

Page 3: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

3

Ι. Introduction

“Political connection” or “political preference” of CEOs or boards of director is a popular research topic.

Many studies provide theoretical discussions and empirical evidence at the corporate level, for instance,

the effect of those on the value or policy of a firm. The first trend is for the political connection.1

Examples are: Fisman (2001) for the value of political connections with a president, Faccio (2006) for

the value when officers or large shareholders involved in business enter politics, Leuz and Oberholzer-

Gee (2006) for the effect of connections on long-run performance, Goldman, Rocholl and So (2008)

for the abnormal stock return following the announcement of the nomination of a politically connected

individual to the board, Cooper, Gulen and Ovtchinnikov (2010) for the effect of the corporate

political contributions on the abnormal stock returns, Yu and Xiaoyun (2011) for the effect of lobbying

on fraud detection by regulators, Kim, Pantzalis and Park (2012) for the effect of political geography

on the stock returns, and Akey (2015) for the value of donating to winning candidates.

The second trend is for the political preference. Examples are: Gordon, Hafer and Landa (2007) for

investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky (2012) and

Borghesi, Houston, and Naranjo (2014) for the relationship between the political preference and the

policy, Lee, Lee, and Nagarajan (2014) for the effects of alignment in political orientation between

the chief executive officer (CEO) and independent directors, Hutton, Jiang, and Kumar (2014) for

the effects of personal political preferences on the levels of corporate debt, capital and R&D

expenditures, and profitability, Christensen, Dhaliwal, Boivie, and Graffin (2015) and Francis,

Hasan, Sun and Wu (2016) for the relationship between personal political orientation and tax

avoidance, and Unsal, Hassan and Pantaleoni (2016) for the relationship among the political

preference, lobbying efforts, and performances.

In this paper, we analyze the relationship between CEO’s political preferences and the number of post-

retirement directorships CEO holds. Previous literature focuses on the effect of “political connection”

1. A good example for the political connection is shown in Goldman, Rocholl and So (2008). A company is classified as

politically connected if it has at least one board member with one of the following former positions: president (Gerald R. Ford),

presidential (vice-presidential) candidate, senator, member of the House of Representatives, (assistant) secretary, deputy

secretary, deputy assistant secretary, undersecretary, associate director, governor, director (CIA, FEMA), deputy director (CIA,

OMB), commissioner (IRS, NRC, SSA, CRC, FDA, SEC), representative to the United Nations, ambassador, mayor, staff

(White House, president, presidential campaign), chairman of the Party Caucus, chairman or staff of the presidential election

campaign, and chairman or member of the president's committee/council.

Page 4: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

4

or “political preference” on the firm. We, however, shed new light on “political preference” in the

market for corporate directors. We tackle whether the political preference of a CEO matters or not for

his individual life and career path after retirements. It naturally follows a question. Why “market for

corporate directors?” Brickley, Linck, and Coles (1999), Linck, Netter, and Yang (2008) and Lee

(2011) show that main players in the market for corporate directors are retired CEOs. Put simply, “CEO”

is not the end of career path in the professional labor market. Moreover, Brickley, Linck, and Coles

(1999) study the evidence about the CEO post-retirement. Ongoing CEOs can get incentives for

acquiring the directorship on his or her own board and an outside directorship on other boards after

retirement. CEOs holding the directorship position after retirement strongly create higher annual

abnormal stock returns and annual accounting returns than CEOs who do not keep the directorships

during their CEO tenure. This means that the market for corporate director functions well when it finds

talented CEOs. We could ask a question. Would the CEO’s political preference be valued in the market

for corporate directors? In this sense, our paper is very close to Goldman, Rocholl and So (2008). They

analyze the stock-price response to the Republican win of the 2000 presidential election and finds that

companies with boards connected to the Republican Party increase in value, and companies connected

to the Democratic Party decrease in value. They show the value of boards’ political connection at the

firm. We test the value of boards’ political preference for their career.

For that purpose, we use a data set on the political donations of CEOs to major political parties from

2003-2014 in the USA: George Walker Bush, 2003~2008, a Republican and Barack Hussein Obama,

Jr. 2009~2014, a Democrat. We measure the political preference as the contribution amounts to

Republicans minus Democrats divided both parties’ contributions from 2003-2014, which are similar

as Borghesi, Houston, and Naranjo (2014) and Lee, Lee, and Nagarajan (2014).

Our main findings follow. We, firstly, address a possibility that the individual donation is driven by

strategic incentives as in Ovtchinnikov and Pantaleoni (2012). Our empirical evidence supports that

the political donations of CEOs are more likely to reveal preference, not strategic behavior. Seventy-

one point three percent of CEOs do not change the pattern of donation according to the ruling party.

Second, we find that CEO’s political preference does not have effect on outside directorships, in general.

Republican partisan CEOs, who donate only to a Republican Party, hold 0.69 and 0.73 post-retirement

outside directorships for two and three years after retirement compared to 0.66 and 0.64 for Democratic

partisan CEOs who donate only to the Democratic Party. There is no statistically significant difference

between Republican partisans and Democratic partisans. The regression results also show that the

Page 5: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

5

number of post-retirement outside directorships is not associated with the political preference. Thirdly,

however, the success in the market for corporate director depends on the ruling party. Republican

partisan CEOs hold more outside directorships under a Republican regime than Democratic partisan

CEOs. Republican partisan CEOs hold 0.82 and 0.83 post-retirement outside directorships for two and

three years after retirement, which is statistically larger than 0.35 and 0.13 for Democratic partisan

CEOs under a Republican regime. Meanwhile, Republican partisan CEOs hold 0.65 and 0.70 post-

retirement outside directorships for two and three years after retirement, which is not statistically

different from 0.72 and 0.71 for Democratic partisan CEOs under a Democratic regime. The regression

results also show that the number of post-retirement outside directorships is positively correlated with

the political preference under a Republican regime. These regressions results are robust for controlling

the endogeneity problem. Fourth, Democratic CEOs have more variations on outside directorships

across political regimes. Democratic CEOs hold 0.72 and 0.71 directorships under a Democratic regime,

which is statistically larger than 0.35 and 0.13 under a Republican regime. However, Republican CEOs

hold 0.65 and 0.70 directorships under a Democratic regime, which is not statistically different with

0.82 and 0.83 under a Republican regime. Finally, the political cycle in the market for corporate director

could be partially explained by the connection value in the regulated industry. Democratic partisans

hold 0.12 and 0.23 outside directorships in unregulated industry under a Republican regime. It increases

to 0.26 and 0.46 under a Democratic regime. Democratic partisans hold 0.26 outside directorships in

the regulated industry, which is significantly larger than Republican partisans 0.19. For three years after

retirement, Democratic partisans hold 0.24 outside directorships in the regulated industry, which is

higher than Republican partisans under a Democratic regime, even though not significant.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section ΙΙ describes the data and descriptive statistics.

Section ΙII explores the main result. Section ΙV suggests the possible explanations. Section V concludes.

ΙI. Sample

We collect the contribution data of the retired CEOs, financial data during their CEOs tenure and post-

retirement number of outside directorship to find out the relationship between the political preference

and outside directorship.

A. Political Preference

Page 6: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

6

CEO’s contribution to committee

We collect the political contribution of the retired CEOs to parties in the USA from the Federal Election

Commission (FEC) website. The collected data is composed mainly of the contribution amounts and

numbers for retired CEOs contributing to both the Republican and Democratic Parties for 12 years. In

detail, we use three different datasets among the contributions by individuals, committee and candidate

master files in FEC web referred the contribution of CEOs from 2003 to 2014 to two parties both the

Republic and Democratic Parties. In the individuals file, the contribution amount by individuals is

specified in the FEC site as $200 or more during data period in FEC site. It contains contributions by

individuals filed, including the contributor names, addresses, the contribution amount, date, and the

identification number which enables matching to two other different committee and candidate datasets.

The committee master file contains committee names registered in FEC, addresses, committee party

and committee identification. The candidate file contains candidates who have campaign committees

irrespective of the election year and are involved as a member of a draft committee or a non-connected

committee which registers as supporting or opposing a candidate. Also, it includes candidate

information such as identification number, party affiliation, candidates’ election year, office address,

email. Originally, we have the observation number about 38,000 CEOs of 1,094 companies during the

period for this study from FEC website. However, we limited it to 555 CEOs who retired between 2003

and 2014 within S&P (Standard and Poor) 1,500 companies.

Page 7: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

7

B. Data during their CEO position

CEOs' firm

We use the financial data for their CEO company from Wharton Research whether the performance of

CEO might influence to get a position of the outside director after retired or not. We expect a good

performance for the company during their tenure might guarantee the outside director after retired CEOs

based on Brickley, Linck, and Coles (1999), and Lee (2011). We collect the financial data for the

company of CEOs in office to explain the performance of CEO. There are various data as independent

variables such as assets, abnormal stock return, and the return of assets related to dependent variable as

the number of the outside director. We calculate the average assets of a CEO’s company as the

explanatory variables for four years before retirement and then take the natural logarithm of total assets.

We collect the abnormal stock return (ASR), the compound average annual return minus the Center for

Research in Security Prices (CRSP) value-weighted index for stock markets from Compustat in WRDS.

The Industry Adjusted Return of Assets (ROAJ) is ROA the CEO’ company for four years minus the

average value of ROAJ of the same industry before retirement. Finally, we have the regulation dummy

variable that equals one when the CEO company is a utility, depository institution or insurance sector

of Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code from ExecuComp data in WRDS.

C. Post-retirement directorships

We collect the retired CEOs’ directorship data from 2003-20142 from ISS (Institutional Shareholder

Services, formerly RiskMetrics). ISS director data contains information about board members in S&P

major index firms, including individual characteristics. “Outside directorship” means that the director

did not hold the CEO position in the director firm. We match the retired CEO’s name and age to find

the number of directorships in the post-retirement period. Because of the data availability our dataset

2. Using the data from 2003 is mainly due to the enactment of Sarbanes-Oxley(SOX) act in 2002. There is a significant impact

of SOX on director market. Section 101 recommends a full-time director and Section 301 gives more responsibility and stricter

independency standards to the audit committee of a board. There are several studies about the impact of SOX on the director

market. Linck et al. (2009) examine the effects of SOX on the demand for and the supply of corporate directors. They find an

increased workload because of more frequent board meetings and increased risks as measured by higher Director & Officer

Insurance premiums. Jiraporn et al. (2009) find that the U-shaped relation between number of outside board memberships

and committee memberships changed to the negative relation after SOX. Thus, it fails to reject the busyness hypothesis2 for

directors due to the SOX enactment. The busyness hypothesis argues that the more the board seat a director holds, the fewer

committee is assigned. Cashman et al. (2012) analyze the relationship between director busyness and firm value and they find

that the negative relationship between board busyness and firm value has weakened during post-SOX period. Thus, they argue

that directors have felt pressure to behave in a more responsible manner by SOX.

Page 8: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

8

only counts the retired CEO’s directorships in the S&P major index firms.

ΙII. Descriptive Statistics

<Table 1>

<Table 1> shows the definition of main variables. For instance, Dn2, and Dn3 stand for number of

outside directorships for two and three years after leaving office, respectively. Rel is an individual

CEO’s political preference index; contribution amounts to Republicans minus Democrats divided both

parties’ contributions during 2003-2014. CEO characteristics and Financial characteristics are

explanatory variables to be used in the regression analysis.

<Table 2>

<Table 2> shows the summary statistics for main variables. The total number of observations is 555

retired CEOs. The mean number of outside directorships for two3 and three years after leaving office,

Dn2 and Dn3, is 0.71, and 0.72, respectively. Rel is an individual CEO’s political preference index,

contribution amounts to Republicans minus Democrats divided both parties’ contributions during 2003-

2014. The averaged Rel is 0.14, which is larger than 0. It implies that retired CEOs are more oriented

to the Republican Party.

<Figure 1 and Table 3>

3. Using board seats two year after retirement is the conventional way to examine the number of post-retirement directorships

established in previous literatures by Brickley et al. (1999), Fahlenbrach et al. (2011), Lee (2011), Harford and Schonlau

(2013), Liu (2014), Liu et al. (2017). Additionally, analyzing directorships three year after retirement is worth considering the

process of CEO succession. Typically, the retired CEO remains in a firm as a chairman during one or two subsequent year of

his retirement (Naveen, 2006). Thus, it is possible that not his own human capital, but his chairmanship affects the board seat

during the second year following his retirement.

Page 9: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

9

<Figure 1 and Table 3> show the distribution of retired CEOs’ political preference. <Table 3. Panel A>

shows that Republican partisans, Rel is 1, are 227 out of 555 retired CEOs. It consists of 40.9%.

Democratic partisans, Rel is -1, are 163 out of 555 retired CEOs, 29.4% in the full sample. In <Table 3.

Panel B>, Republican partisans who retired during Republican regime (2003-2008) are 99 out of 213,

46.5% and Democratic partisans who retired during Republican regime (2003-2008) are 54 out of 213,

25.4%. Likewise, Republican partisans who retired during Democratic regime are 128 out of 342, and

Democratic partisans who retired during Democratic regime are 109 out of 342, 31.9%.

ΙV. Empirical Results

A. Political Preference or Strategic Behavior

We, firstly, address a question as follows. Would the individual donation behavior really reflect the

political preference? Is there a possibility that the individual donation is driven by strategic incentives?

Much previous literature supports the political preference argument, but it is hard to rule out the strategic

behavior hypothesis completely. For instance, Ovtchinnikov and Pantaleoni (2012) present evidence

that individuals make political contributions strategically by targeting politicians with the power to

affect their economic well-being. Individuals in Congressional districts with greater industry clustering

choose to support politicians with jurisdiction over the industry. Importantly, individual political

contributions are associated with improvements in operating performance of firms in industry clusters.

The relation between contributions and firm performance is strongest for poorly performing firms, firms

closer to financial distress, and for contributions in close elections.

<Table 4>

<Table 4> measures the amount of political contribution relative to CEO compensation. Convpay shows

the proportion of the one year averaged political contributions amount to one year averaged CEO

Compensation during CEO tenure for each retired CEO. The political contribution amounts to only 0.03%

of CEO compensation.

<Table 5>

Page 10: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

10

<Table 5> shows the pattern of donation behavior under different political regimes. Rel Republican

Regime is an individual CEO’s Rel during Republican regime (2003-2008) and Rel Democratic Regime

is an individual CEO’s Rel during Democratic regime (2009-2014). In the unpaired sample, Rel

Republican Regime is 0.18 and Rel Democratic Regime 0.09. For the paired sample, Rel Republican

Regime is 0.20, which is higher than Rel Democratic Regime 0.09, but not statistically significant. There

is no strong evidence that retired CEOs donate strategically according to the ruling party.

<Table 6>

<Table 6> shows the pattern of donation behavior under different ruling party in a different way.

Seventy-four out of 164 retired CEOs, 45.1%, donate more to the Republican Party whatever the ruling

party is. Forty-three out of 164 retired CEOs, 26.2%, donate more to the Democratic Party whatever

the ruling party is. In sum, 71.3% of retired CEOs do not change donation behavior across different

political regimes. 47 out of 88 partisan CEOs, 53.4%, allocate all to Republican Party whatever the

ruling party is. 24 out of 88 partisan CEOs, 27.3%, allocate all to Democratic Party whatever the ruling

party is. In sum, 80.7% of partisan CEOs hold their pattern of donation across different political regimes.

These findings also support the political preference argument.

B. Regression results in the full sample

<Table 7>

<Table 7> shows the post-retirement outside directorships. Dn2 and Dn3 represent the number of

outside directorships for two and three years after leaving office. Republican partisan CEOs hold 0.69

and 0.73 post-retirement outside directorships for two and three years after retirement, on average.

Democratic partisan CEOs hold 0.66 and 0.64 post-retirement outside directorships, on average. There

is no statistically significant difference.

<Table 8 and 9>

<Table 8 and 9> reports ordered logit estimates on post-retirement outside directorships for two and

three years after retirement, respectively. The specification is based on Brickley, Linck, and Coles

Page 11: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

11

(1999), and Lee (2011). They show that the number of post-retirement outside directorships depends

on the characteristics of the firm where they work as CEO. Our empirical evidence shows that the

political preferences of retired CEOs are not associated with the number of post-retirement outside

directorships. Rel and Rel_Dummy, the index of political preference, do not have effects on the success

in the market for corporate directors.

C. Regression results: Republican regime vs Democratic regime

<Figure 2 and 3>

<Figure 2 and 3> report the fitted line between the number of outside directorships two and three years

after retirement, Dn2 and Dn3 for Republican and Democratic partisans and political regime. George

Walker Bush, 2003~2008, is a Republican and Barack Hussein Obama, Jr. 2009~2014, is a Democratic.

Republican partisans have more outside directorships under a Republican regime than Democratic

partisans. However, this pattern is reversed under a Democratic regime.

<Table 10>

<Table 10> shows the mean difference between the number of outside directorships two and three years

after retirement, Dn2 and Dn3 for Republican and Democratic partisans across political regime. For

instance, Republican partisans hold 0.82 and 0.83 outside directorship two years and three years after

retirement, which is statistically larger than 0.35 and 0.13 compared to Democratic partisans under a

Republican regime. However, Republican partisans hold 0.65 and 0.70 outside directorship two and

three years after retirement under a Democratic regime, which is lower than 0.72 and 0.71 of Democratic

partisans even though statistically insignificant.

<Table 11 and 12>

<Table 11 and 12> reports regression results on the number of outside directorships two and three years

after retirement. The specification (1) and (4) in all tables are baseline regression results, ordered logit

estimates in the full sample. An interaction term, Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy, is positive and

significant in <Table 11 and 12>, which implies that partisan Republican CEOs hold more outside

Page 12: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

12

directorships under a Republican regime.

For robustness checks, we, firstly, use a zero-inflated Poisson distribution model in the full sample. One

concern in our sample is retired CEOs who hold zero outside directorships after retirement. It is possible

that there are two different kinds of retired CEOs holding zero outside directorships: one who

participates in the market and one who voluntarily exits the market for corporate directors. To address

this excess zero-count data problem, we adopt a zero-inflated Poisson model based on Greene (1994).4

We assume that zero outcome is due to two different processes. The two processes are that a retired

CEO has not participated vs. participated in the director market. If they have not participated in the

director market, the only outcome possible is zero. If they have participated in the director market, it is

then a count process. The specification (2) and (5) are zero-inflated Poisson models in the full sample.

An interaction term, Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy, is positive and significant in <Table 11 and 12>.

Secondly, the specification (3) and (6) are ordered logit estimates in the sub-sample. Specification (3)

and (6) use only the sample which has at least one directorships including outside or inside (employee)

directorships. We try to exclude retired CEOs who voluntarily leave the market for corporate directors.

An interaction term, Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy, is positive and significant in <Table 11 and 12>,

too.

D. Regression results: Endogeneity problem

Now, we address potential concerns about the endogeneity problem between success in the market for

corporate directors and political preference of a retired CEO. We use the presidential election result as

the instrumental variable. The presidential election result of the state where the HQ is located can affect

the political preference. However, there is no direct connection between the regional political preference

and post-retirement directorships. During our sample period, the presidential elections conducted three

times in year 2004, 2008, and 2012. Based on the majority results (Republican vs Democrat) of the

presidential elections, we decide the regional political preference. An individual political preference can

be affected by the social influences (regional effect). Tam Cho (2003) and Gimpel, Lee, and

Kaminsky (2006) analyze how the geographic pattern affects the individual campaign contributions

and they find that geographical distribution is related to the individual campaign contribution.

4 Currently, Ahern and Sosyura (2014) used a zero-inflated Poisson model.

Page 13: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

13

<Table 13>

<Table 13> shows the strong correlation between individual preference and regional preference. Rel

Republican Win State is a Rel of CEO who works at a firm where a headquarters is located in a state a

Republican candidate wins in the 2004, 2008 and 2012 president elections. Rel Democratic Win State

is a Rel of CEO who works at a firm where a headquarters is located in a state a Democratic candidate

wins in the 2004, 2008, and 2012 presidential elections. For instance, Rel Republican Win State is 0.41

in <Panel B>, which is statistically higher than Rel Democratic Win State, 0.04. A CEO who works in

a Republican-friendly state prefers the Republican party more.

<Table 14>

<Table 14> estimates 2-stage regression models by using an instrumental variable to address the

endogeneity problem. We instrument Rep_Dummy with the regional political preference. The

specification (1) and (5) are 2-stage ordered logit estimates in the full sample. The specification (2) and

(6) are 2-stage zero-inflated Poisson model in the full sample. The specification (3) and (7) are 2-stage

ordered logit estimates in the sub-sample. The specification (4) and (8) are 2-stage OLS estimates in

the sub-sample. An interaction term, Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy, is positive and significant in many

specifications. Our results are robust.

V. Possible Explanations

What would explain the political cycle in the market for corporate director? We suggest two possible

theories. The first one is to demand “(potential) political connection” as a lobbyist for the ruling party.

Republican partisans are more likely to have a political connection with a Republican government and

vice versa.

<Table 15>

We test the first theory to decompose the number of outside directorship into regulated and unregulated

Page 14: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

14

industry holdings by retired CEOs. There is a possibility that the political connections value more in

the regulated industry (Goldman, Rocholl and So, 2008; Babenko, Fedaseyeu and Zhang, 2017).

<Table 15> partially supports this. Democratic partisans hold 0.12 outside directorships in regulated

industry and 0.23 outside directorships in the unregulated industry for two years after retirement under

a Republican regime. This increases to 0.26 in the regulated industry and 0.46 in the unregulated

industry under a Democratic regime. The value of political connection exists not only in the regulated

industry, but also in the unregulated industry. However, the point is that Democratic partisans hold 0.26

outside directorships in regulated industry, which is significantly larger than Republican partisans 0.19.

For three years after retirement, Democratic partisans hold 0.24 outside directorships in regulated

industry, which is higher than Republican partisans under a Democratic regime, even though not

significant.

The second possible theory is “birds of a feather” explanations. Fracassi and Tate (2012) find that

powerful CEOs hire directors that are more socially connected with them, leading to weaker monitoring,

and more value-destroying mergers. Fahlenbrach, Low and Stulz (2010) show that appointments

outside CEOs to their boards have a certification benefit for the appointing firm. CEOs are more likely

to join boards of large established firms that are geographically close, pursue similar financial and

investment policies, and have comparable governance to their own firms. Lee, Lee, and Nagarajan

(2014) show the alignment in political orientation between the chief executive officer (CEO) and

independent directors. In this sense, partisan Republican CEOs prefer more Republican partisan outside

directors and vice versa.

<Table 16 and 17>

<Table 16 and 17> test a “birds of a feather” theory. <Table 16> shows that there is no significant

political preference difference between newly appointed CEOs across ruling parties. New CEO Rel

Republican Regime, the political preference of newly appointed CEOs under a republican regime, is

0.128 and New CEO Rel Democratic Regime, the political preference of newly appointed CEOs under

a Democratic regime, is 0.124. <Table 17> reports a similar result. The proportion of Republican

partisans on newly appointed CEOs under a Republican regime is 39.1% and 40.6% under a Democratic

regime. The proportion of Democratic partisans on newly appointed CEOs under a Republican regime

is 28.9% and 29.1% under a Democratic regime. All results are not statistically significant. There is no

evidence supporting a “birds of a feather” theory.

Page 15: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

15

VI. Conclusions

In this paper, we study the relationship between CEO’s political preferences and the number of post-

retirement directorships CEO holds. Firstly, we provide evidence that the political donations of CEOs

reveal preference, not strategic behavior. Second, the number of post-retirement outside directorships

is not associated with the political preference. Thirdly, however, the effects of political preference in

the market for corporate director depends on the ruling party. Republican partisan CEOs are more

popular under a Republican regime than Democratic partisan CEOs. Republican partisan CEOs hold

less post-retirement outside directorships than Democratic partisan CEOs under a Republican regime,

which are not statistically significant. These results are robust for controlling the endogeneity problem.

Fourth, Democratic CEOs have larger fluctuations in the number of outside directorships across

political regimes. The number of post-retirement outside directorships for Democratic CEOs increases

significantly under a Democratic regime, but Republican CEOs hold a similar number of post-

retirement outside directorships across ruling parties. Finally, the political cycle in the market for

corporate director could be partially explained by the connection value in the regulated industry.

Democratic partisans hold significantly larger outside directorships in the regulated industry than

Republican partisans under a Democratic regime for two years after retirement.

Page 16: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

16

References

Ahern, K. R., & Sosyura, D. (2014). Who writes the news? Corporate press releases during merger

negotiations. The Journal of Finance, 69(1), 241-291.

Akey, P. (2015). Valuing changes in political networks: Evidence from campaign contributions to close

congressional elections. The Review of Financial Studies, 28(11), 3188-3223.

Alexei V. Ovtchinnikov, Eva Pantaleoni, 2012, Individual political contributions and firm performance,

Journal of Financial Economics, 105, 367-392.

Babenko, I., Fedaseyeu, V., & Zhang, S. (2017). Do CEOs Affect Employees' Political Choices.

Borghesi, R., Houston, J. F., & Naranjo, A. (2014). Corporate socially responsible investments: CEO

altruism, reputation, and shareholder interests. Journal of Corporate Finance, 26, 164-181.

Brickley, J. A., Linck, J. S., & Coles, J. L. (1999). What happens to CEOs after they retire? New

evidence on career concerns, horizon problems, and CEO incentives. Journal of Financial

Economics, 52(3), 341-377.

Cashman, G. D., S. L. Gillan and C. Jun (2012). Going overboard? On busy directors and firm value,

Journal of Banking & Finance, 36, 3248–3259.

Christensen, D. M., Dhaliwal, D. S., Boivie, S., & Graffin, S. D. (2015). Top management conservatism

and corporate risk strategies: Evidence from managers' personal political orientation and

corporate tax avoidance. Strategic Management Journal, 36(12), 1918-1938.

Cooper, M. J., Gulen, H., & Ovtchinnikov, A. V. (2010). Corporate political contributions and stock

returns. The Journal of Finance, 65(2), 687-724.

Faccio, M. (2006). Politically connected firms. The American economic review, 96(1), 369-386.

Fahlenbrach, R., Low, A., & Stulz, R. M. (2010). Why do firms appoint CEOs as outside

directors?. Journal of Financial Economics, 97(1), 12-32.

Fahlenbrach, R., B.A. Minton and C.H. Pan (2011). Former CEO directors: lingering CEOs or valuable

resources? Review of Financial Studies, 24(10), 3486–3518.

Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. The American economic review, 91(4),

1095-1102.

Fracassi, C., & Tate, G. (2012). External networking and internal firm governance. the Journal of

finance, 67(1), 153-194.

Francis, B. B., Hasan, I., Sun, X., & Wu, Q. (2016). CEO political preference and corporate tax

Page 17: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

17

sheltering. Journal of Corporate Finance, 38, 37-53.

Gimpel, J. G., Lee, F. E., & Kaminski, J. (2006). The political geography of campaign contributions in

American politics. Journal of Politics, 68(3), 626-639.

Gordon, S. C., Hafer, C., & Landa, D. (2007). Consumption or investment? On motivations for political

giving. Journal of Politics, 69(4), 1057-1072.

Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., & So, J. (2008). Do politically connected boards affect firm value?. The

Review of Financial Studies, 22(6), 2331-2360.

Greene, W. H. (1994). Accounting for excess zeros and sample selection in Poisson and negative

binomial regression models.

Harford, J. and R.J. Schonlau (2013). Does the director labor market offer ex post settling-up for CEOs?

The case of acquisitions, Journal of Financial Economics, 110, 18–36.

Hong, H., & Kostovetsky, L. (2012). Red and blue investing: Values and finance. Journal of Financial

Economics, 103(1), 1-19.

Hutton, I., Jiang, D., & Kumar, A. (2014). Corporate policies of Republican managers. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 49(5-6), 1279-1310.

Jiraporn, P., M. Singh and C. Lee (2009). Ineffective corporate governance. Director

busyness and board committee memberships, Journal of Banking and Finance, 33, 819–828.

Kim, C. F., Pantzalis, C., & Park, J. C. (2012). Political geography and stock returns: The value and

risk implications of proximity to political power. Journal of Financial Economics, 106(1), 196-

228.

Lee, C. (2011). New evidence on what happens to CEOs after they retire. Journal of Corporate

Finance, 17(3), 474-482.

Lee, J., Lee, K. J., & Nagarajan, N. J. (2014). Birds of a feather: Value implications of political

alignment between top management and directors. Journal of Financial Economics, 112(2), 232-

250.

Leuz, C., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (2006). Political relationships, global financing, and corporate

transparency: Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of financial economics, 81(2), 411-439.

Linck, J. S., Netter, J. M., & Yang, T. (2008). The effects and unintended consequences of the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act on the supply and demand for directors. The Review of Financial Studies, 22(8), 3287-

3328.

Liu, Y. (2014). Outside options and CEO turnover: The network effect, 28, 201–217.

Page 18: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

18

Liu, B., J. J. McConnell and W. Xu (2017). The power of the pen reconsidered: The media, CEO human

capital, and corporate governance, Journal of Banking and Finance, 76, 175–188.

Naveen, L. (2006). Organizational Complexity and Succession Planning, Journal Of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 41(3), 661-683.

Ovtchinnikov, A. V., & Pantaleoni, E. (2012). Individual political contributions and firm

performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(2), 367-392.

Tam Cho, W. K. (2003). Contagion effects and ethnic contribution networks. American Journal of

Political Science, 47(2), 368-387.

Unsal, O., Hassan, M. K., & Zirek, D. (2016). Corporate lobbying, CEO political ideology and firm

performance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 38, 126-149.

Yu, F., & Yu, X. (2011). Corporate lobbying and fraud detection. Journal of Financial and Quantitative

Analysis, 46(6), 1865-1891.

Page 19: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

19

Table I.

Description of Variables

This table shows the definition of main variables in our paper. For instance, Dn2, and Dn3 stand for number of

outside directorships for 1, 2 and 3 years after leaving office. Dnr2, and Dnr3 stand for number of outside

directorships in the regulated industries, SIC 2-digit code is 49 (utility), 60 (depository institution), and 63

(insurance), for 1, 2 and 3 years after leaving office. Dner2, and Dner3 stand for No. of outside directorships in

the extended regulated industries, financial (44, 45, 47) / utilities (31) as well as pharmaceutical (12, 13) /

communication (32) / defense based on Fama-French 48 industrial code, for 1, 2 and 3 years after leaving office.

Rel is an individual CEO’s political preference index, contribution amounts to Republicans minus Democrats

divided both parties’ contributions during 2003-2014. Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel=1. Rep_Dummy takes

value 0 if Rel=-1. If Rel is 1, we consider “Republican Partisan”. If Rel is -1, we consider “Democratic Partisan”.

Rea is an individual CEO’s total contribution amount to Republican Party ($) during 2003-2014, and Dea is an

individual CEO’s total contribution amount to Democratic Party ($) during 2003-2014. CEO characteristics are

tenure period of CEO in office (yrs.), CEO compensation for averaged 4 years before retired (thousands), and age

when CEO retired. Financial characteristics are assets of firm for averaged 4 years before retired (millions),

abnormal stock return for averaged 4 years (%), return of assets of CEO company for averaged 4 years before

retired (%), and dummy, one for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance) of SIC code at the firm

of CEO. Variable Symbol

Political Contribution:

No. of outside directorships for 2 years after leaving office Dn2

No. of outside directorships for 3 years after leaving office Dn3

No. of outside directorships in regulated industries for 2 years after leaving office Dnr2

No. of outside directorships in regulated industries for 3 years after leaving office Dnr3

No. of outside directorships in extended regulated industries for 2 years after leaving Dner2

No. of outside directorships in extended regulated industries for 3 years after leaving Dner3

Contribution amounts to Republicans minus Democrats divided both parties’ contributions Rel

Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel=1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel=-1. Rep_Dummy

Contribution amount to Republican party ($) Rea

Contribution amount to Democratic party ($) Dea

CEO characteristics:

Tenure period of CEO in office (yrs.) Tenure

CEO compensation for averaged 4 years before retired (thousands) Pay

Age when CEO retired Age

Firm characteristics:

Assets of firm for averaged 4 years before retired (millions) Ast

Ln (assets): natural log value of assets Lna

Abnormal stock return for averaged 4 years before retired (%) Asr

Return of assets of CEO company averaged 4 years before retired (%) Roa

Adjusted Roa = return of assets of company - average of return of assets for SIC industry Roaj

Dummy, one for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance) of SIC code Dmi

Page 20: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

20

Table II

Summary Statistics

This table shows the summary statistics for main variables. For instance, Dn1, Dn2, and Dn3 stand for No. of

outside directorships for 1, 2 and 3 years after leaving office. The mean of Dn1, Dn2, and Dn3 is 0.64, 0.71,

and 0.72, respectively. Rel is an individual CEO’s political preference index, contribution amounts to

Republicans minus Democrats divided both parties’ contributions during 2003-2014. The mean of Rel is 0.14,

which is larger than 0. Rea is an individual CEO’s total contribution amount to Republican Party ($) during

2003-2014, and Dea is an individual CEO’s total contribution amount to Democratic Party ($) during 2003-

2014. The mean of Rea and Dea is ($) 3,912.83 and ($) 2,912.50, respectively.

Variable Mean Median Min Max Std.Dev. N

Dn2 0.71 0.00 0.00 5.00 0.91 555

Dn3 0.72 0.00 0.00 4.00 0.92 499

Rel 0.14 0.37 -1.00 1.00 0.87 555

Rea($) 3,912.83 1,500.00 0.00 62,250.00 6,883.90 555

Dea($) 2,912.50 1,000.00 0.00 80,100.00 6,188.91 555

Tenure 12.26 10.00 2.00 46.00 7.94 555

Ast($Millions) 39,166.58 3,233.05 80.76 1,878,618.00 169,866.40 553

Asr(%) 24.98 3.77 -98.39 4773.28 232.22 545

Roa(%) 4.15 3.80 -42.89 38.53 7.07 553

Pay($Millions) 7,351.25 4,814.85 217.89 77,068.88 7,876.79 542

Age 60.30 61.00 35.00 90.00 7.39 555

Dmi 0.18 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.38 555

Page 21: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

21

Figure 1. Distribution of Political Preference.

Figure 1 shows the retired CEOs’ Rel distribution. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans -

Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties).

Page 22: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

22

Table III

Distribution of Political Preference

Panel A presents the retired CEOs’ Rel distribution. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans -

Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties). If Rel is 1, we consider “Republican Partisan”. If Rel is -1,

we consider “Democratic Partisan”.

Panel A Mean Median Std.Dev N

Rel 0.14 0.37 0.87 555

Distribution Republican

Partisan

Democratic

Partisan In-between N

227

(40.90%)

163

(29.37%)

165

(29.73%)

555

Panel B presents the retired CEOs’ Rel distribution under Republican regime or Democratic regime. Rel means

as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties). If Rel is 1, we

consider “Republican Partisan”. If Rel is -1, we consider “Democratic Partisan”.

No. of Retired CEOs by Rel

distribution

Total

Republican Regime

based on the retired

year

Democratic Regime

based on the retired

year

N % N % N %

-1 ≤ REL ≤ 1 555 100.00% 213 100.00% 342 100.00%

REL = 1 227 40.90% 99 46.48% 128 37.43%

0 < REL ≤ 1 317 57.12% 130 61.03% 187 54.68%

0.25 ≤ REL ≤ 1 294 52.97% 119 55.87% 175 51.17%

REL = 0 9 1.62% 7 3.29% 2 0.58%

-0.25 < REL < 0.25 53 9.55% 24 11.27% 29 8.48%

-1 ≤ REL ≤ -0.25 208 37.48% 70 32.86% 138 40.35%

-1 ≤ REL < 0 229 41.26% 76 35.68% 153 44.74%

REL = -1 163 29.37% 54 25.35% 109 31.87%

Page 23: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

23

Table IV

Political Preference or Strategic Behavior: Political Contribution Relative

to CEO Compensation

Convpay means the 1-year averaged political contribution amount divided by 1-year averaged CEO Compensation

during CEO tenure for each retired CEO. For instance, a retired CEO from Wal-Mart contributed $1,000 per year

and his CEO compensation during Wal-Mart CEO position was $1,000,000 per year. Then, Convpay is 0.1%. The

averaged portion of political contribution on CEO Compensation is 0.03% in the full sample.

Mean Median Min Max Std.Dev. N

Convpay (%) 0.03 0.01 0.00 2.10 0.10 542

Page 24: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

24

Table V

Political Preference or Strategic Behavior: Donation Behavior Changes

Under Different Ruling Parties

Table V presents the donation behavior under different political regimes. Rel Republican Regime is an individual

CEO’s Rel during Republican regime (2003-2008) and Rel Democratic Regime is an individual CEO’s Rel during

Democratic regime (2009-2014). Rel Republican Regime is calculated by (Donation to Republicans - Donation

to Democrats) during Republican regime / (Donation to Both Parties) Republican regime. Rel Democratic Regime

is calculated by (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) during Democratic regime / (Donation to

Both Parties) Democratic regime. The unpaired sample is for the full sample and paired sample for the same

retired CEOs on Republican regime and Democratic regime, respectively. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%,

and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Mean Std.Dev. N

Unpaired Sample

Rel Republican Regime 0.18* 0.88 398

Rel Democratic Regime 0.09 0.90 326

Mean Difference 0.09

Paired Sample

Rel Republican Regime 0.20 0.84 169

Rel Democratic Regime 0.14 0.86 169

Mean Difference 0.06

Page 25: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

25

Table VI

Political Preference or Strategic Behavior: Donation Behavior Changes

Under Different Ruling Parties

Table VI presents the number of retired CEO who changed political preference across the ruling party. Rel means

as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties). Significant

differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

No. of Retired CEO who changed political preference across

the ruling party N %

Republican Regime: Rel > 0

(2003 ~ 2008)

Democratic Regime

(2009~2014)

Rel > 0 74 45.12

Rel < 0 26 15.85

Republican Regime: Rel < 0

(2003 ~ 2008)

Democratic Regime

(2009~2014)

Rel < 0 43 26.22

Rel > 0 21 12.80

Total 164 100.00

No. of Retired Partisan CEO who changed political preference based

on the ruling party N %

Republican Regime: Rel = 1

(2003 ~ 2008)

Democratic Regime

(2009~2014)

Rel = 1 47 53.41

Rel = -1 11 12.50

Republican Regime: Rel = -1

(2003 ~ 2008)

Democratic Regime

(2009~2014)

Rel = -1 24 27.27

Rel = 1 6 6.82

Total 88 100.00

Page 26: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

26

Table VII

Post-Retirement Outside Directorships

This table shows the post-retirement outside directorships. Dn2, and Dn3 stand for No. of outside directorships

for 2 and 3 years after leaving office. In the full sample, the mean of Dn2, and Dn3 is 0.71, and 0.72, respectively.

Republican partisan CEOs hold 0.69, and 0.73 post-retirement outside directorships, on average. Democratic

partisan CEOs 0.66 and 0.64 post-retirement outside directorships, on average. There is no statistically significant

mean-difference between Republican partisan and Democratic partisan.

Mean in the

full sample

Republican

partisan

sample

N

Democratic

partisan

sample

N Mean

Difference

Dn2 0.71 0.69 227 0.66 163 0.03

Dn3 0.72 0.73 206 0.64 143 0.08

Page 27: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

27

Table VIII

Regression Results for Post-Retirement outside Directorships: 2 Years After

Retirement

This table reports ordered logit estimates. The dependent variable is Dn2, No. of outside directorships for 2 years

after leaving office. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation

to Both Parties). Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel is 1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel is -1. Lna is the log

value of average assets of firm for 4 years before retired. Asr is averaged abnormal stock return for 4 years. Roaj

is averaged adjusted Roa for 4 years, which is return of assets of company minus average of return of assets for

SIC industry. Dmi is a dummy variable taking value 1 for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance)

of SIC code, otherwise, 0. P-values are in parentheses. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are

indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Rel 0.073 0.082

(0.452) (0.401)

Rep_Dummy 0.107 0.124

(0.611) (0.554)

Lna 0.211*** 0.212*** 0.247*** 0.247***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Asr -0.000* -0.000* -0.000* -0.000**

(0.067) (0.063) (0.051) (0.050)

Roaj 0.007 0.007 -0.004 -0.004

(0.573) (0.574) (0.766) (0.752)

Dmi -0.115 -0.084 -0.238 -0.214

(0.626) (0.724) (0.402) (0.451)

Time Trend 0.040 0.032

(0.145) (0.334)

Obs 546 546 384 384

Pseudo R2 0.019 0.021 0.023 0.024

Page 28: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

28

Table IX

Regression Results for Post-Retirement outside Directorships: 3 Years After

Retirement

This table reports ordered logit estimates. The dependent variable is Dn3, No. of outside directorships for 3 years

after leaving office. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation

to Both Parties). Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel is 1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel is -1. Lna is the log

value of average assets of firm for four years before retired. Asr is averaged abnormal stock return for four years.

Roaj is averaged adjusted Roa for four years, which is return of assets of company minus average of return of

assets for SIC industry. Dmi is a dummy variable taking value 1 for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and

63(insurance) of SIC code, otherwise, 0. P-values are in parentheses. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%, and

10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Rel 0.128 0.142

(0.214) (0.170)

Rep_Dummy 0.313 0.338

(0.173) (0.139)

Lna 0.216*** 0.221*** 0.267*** 0.271***

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Asr -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000

(0.368) (0.329) (0.375) (0.359)

Roaj 0.006 0.006 -0.010 -0.010

(0.691) (0.656) (0.497) (0.516)

Dmi 0.223 0.242 0.064 0.080

(0.315) (0.277) (0.814) (0.769)

Time Trend 0.050 0.044

(0.110) (0.233)

Obs 491 491 344 344

Pseudo R2 0.025 0.027 0.033 0.035

Page 29: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

29

Figure 2. Post-Retirement outside Directorships. It shows a fitted line: the outside directorships 2 years after retirement (Dn2) for Republican and Democratic

partisans under Republican regime and Democratic regime.

Page 30: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

30

Figure 3. Post-Retirement outside Directorships. It shows a fitted line: the outside directorships 3 years after retirement (Dn3) for Republican and Democratic

partisans under Republican regime and Democratic regime.

Page 31: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

31

Table X

Post-Retirement outside Directorships:

Republican Regime vs. Democratic Regime

This table shows the mean of outside directorships 2 and 3 years after retirement, Dn2, and Dn3 for Republican

and Democratic partisans under Republican regime and Democratic regime. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%,

and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Republican Regime Democratic Regime

(George Walker Bush,

2003~2008) N

(Barack Hussein

Obama, Jr.

2009~2014)

N

Panel A: 2 Years after

Retirement (Dn2)

Republican Partisan 0.82** 57 0.65 170

Democratic Partisan 0.35 26 0.72 137

Mean Difference 0.48 -0.08

Panel B: 3 Years after

Retirement (Dn3)

Republican Partisan 0.83*** 40 0.70 166

Democratic Partisan 0.13 16 0.71 127

Mean Difference 0.70 0.00

Page 32: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

32

Table XI

Regression Results for Post-Retirement Outside Directorships: 2 Years After Retirement under

Republican vs. Democratic Regime This table reports regression results. The specification (1) and (4) are ordered logit estimates in the full sample. The specification (2) and (5) are zero-inflated

passion model in the full sample. The specification (3) and (6) are ordered logit estimates in the sub-sample. The dependent variable is Dn2, No. of outside

directorships for 2 years after leaving office. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties).

Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel is 1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel is -1. Rep_reg_Dummy takes value 1 if a year of holding outside directorship is

under a Republican regime, otherwise, 0. Lna is the log value of average assets of firm for 4 years before retired. Asr is averaged abnormal stock return for 4

years. Roaj is averaged adjusted Roa for 4 years, which is return of assets of company minus average of return of assets for SIC industry. Dmi is a dummy

variable taking value 1 for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance) of SIC code, otherwise, 0. P-values are in parentheses. Significant

differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: Dn2 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Ologit ZIP Ologit Ologit ZIP Ologit

Rel 0.023 -0.019 -0.301**

(0.828) (0.787) (0.026)

Rep_Dummy -0.076 -0.108 -0.803** (0.738) (0.465) (0.012)

Rep_reg_Dummy 0.057 0.079 0.560 -0.756 -0.625 -1.064 (0.865) (0.710) (0.206) (0.188) (0.136) (0.202)

Rel*Rep_reg_Dummy 0.323 0.255 0.716**

(0.233) (0.134) (0.050)

Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy 1.140* 0.911** 2.243** (0.057) (0.029) (0.011)

Lna 0.209*** 0.066* 0.235*** 0.238*** 0.099** 0.269*** (0.000) (0.059) (0.001) (0.000) (0.027) (0.004)

Asr -0.000** -0.000** -0.001*** -0.000** -0.000** -0.001*** (0.047) (0.033) (0.000) (0.032) (0.023) (0.000)

Roaj 0.008 0.006 -0.008 -0.002 -0.001 -0.018 (0.528) (0.473) (0.561) (0.865) (0.893) (0.271)

Dmi -0.073 0.018 0.495 -0.201 -0.085 0.238

Page 33: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

33

(0.760) (0.898) (0.097) (0.486) (0.617) (0.518)

Time Trend 0.054 0.030 0.081 0.034 0.015 0.023 (0.156) (0.211) (0.087) (0.471) (0.613) (0.719)

Inflate

Lna -0.697** -0.725**

(0.014) (0.030)

Obs 546 546 315 384 384 212

R2 0.022 0.048 0.040 0.029 0.065 0.058

Page 34: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

34

Table XII

Regression Results for Post-Retirement Outside Directorships: 3 Years After Retirement under

Republican vs. Democratic Regime

This table reports regression results. The specification (1) and (4) are ordered logit estimates in the full sample. The specification (2) and (5) are zero-inflated

passion model in the full sample. The specification (3) and (6) are ordered logit estimates in the sub-sample. The dependent variable is Dn3, No. of outside

directorships for 3 years after leaving office. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties).

Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel is 1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel is -1. Rep_reg_Dummy takes value 1 if a year of holding outside directorship is

under a Republican regime, otherwise, 0. Lna is the log value of average assets of firm for 4 years before retired. Asr is averaged abnormal stock return for 4

years. Roaj is averaged adjusted Roa for 4 years, which is return of assets of company minus average of return of assets for SIC industry. Dmi is a dummy

variable taking value 1 for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance) of SIC code, otherwise, 0. P-values are in parentheses. Significant

differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Dependent variable: Dn3 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Ologit ZIP Ologit Ologit ZIP Ologit

Rel 0.060 -0.011 -0.318**

(0.587) (0.876) (0.024)

Rep_Dummy 0.120 -0.050 -0.808** (0.623) (0.741) (0.016)

Rep_reg_Dummy -0.471 -0.298 -0.456 -1.781** -1.721** -2.761*** (0.255) (0.298) (0.399) (0.040) (0.014) (0.005)

Rel*Rep_reg_Dummy 0.728** 0.524** 1.220**

(0.038) (0.032) (0.011)

Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy 2.065** 1.917*** 3.525*** (0.019) (0.006) (0.001)

Lna 0.219*** 0.050 0.297*** 0.272*** 0.076* 0.313*** (0.000) (0.162) (0.000) (0.000) (0.094) (0.002)

Asr -0.000 -0.000 -0.001 -0.000 -0.000 -0.001 (0.305) (0.329) (0.441) (0.351) (0.293) (0.308)

Roaj 0.008 0.010 0.007 -0.007 0.002 -0.006 (0.571) (0.263) (0.672) (0.635) (0.828) (0.782)

Dmi 0.233 0.128 0.285 0.051 -0.021 -0.013 (0.308) (0.329) (0.290) (0.857) (0.894) (0.969)

Page 35: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

35

Time Trend 0.035 0.020 0.053 0.027 0.013 0.043 (0.395) (0.458) (0.310) (0.584) (0.679) (0.532)

Inflate

Lna -0.881*** -0.947***

(0.002) (0.001)

Obs 491 491 279 344 344 187

R2 0.031 0.068 0.050 0.044 0.101 0.065

Page 36: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

36

Table XIII

Instrument Variable: Republican Win State vs. Democratic Win State where HQ are located

Rel Republican Win State is a Rel of CEO who works at a firm where a headquarters is located in a state a Republican candidate wins in the 2004, 2008 and

2012 president election. Rel Democratic Win State is a Rel of CEO who works at a firm where a headquarters is located in a state a Democratic candidate

wins in the 2004, 2008 and 2012 president election. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Mean Std. Dev. N

Panel A: 2004 President Election

Rel Republican Win State 0.38*** 0.79 269

Rel Democratic Win State -0.10 0.88 283

Mean Difference 0.48

Panel B: 2008 President Election

Rel Republican Win State 0.41*** 0.79 146

Rel Democratic Win State 0.04 0.88 406

Mean Difference 0.38

Panel C: 2012 President Election

Rel Republican Win State 0.44*** 0.78 169

Rel Democratic Win State 0.00 0.88 383

Mean Difference 0.43

Page 37: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

37

Table XIV

2-Stage Regression with Instrumental Variable

This table estimates 2-stage regression models by using an instrumental variable to address potential concerns about endogeneity problem. We instrument

“Rep_Dummy” with the regional political preference. The specification (1) and (5) are 2-stage ordered logit estimates in the full sample. The specification

(2) and (6) are 2-stage zero-inflated possion model in the full sample. The specification (3) and (7) are 2-stage ordered logit estimates in the sub-sample. The

specification (4) and (8) are 2-stage OLS estimates in the sub-sample. The dependent variables are No. of outside directorships for 1, 2, and 3 years after

leaving office. Rep_Dummy takes value 1 if Rel is 1. Rep_Dummy takes value 0 if Rel is -1. Rep_reg_Dummy takes value 1 if a year of holding outside

directorship is under a Republican regime, otherwise, 0. Lna is the log value of average assets of firm for 4 years before retired. Asr is averaged abnormal

stock return for 4 years. Roaj is averaged adjusted Roa for 4 years, which is return of assets of company minus average of return of assets for SIC industry.

Dmi is a dummy variable taking value 1 for 49(utility), 60(depository institution), and 63(insurance) of SIC code, otherwise, 0. P-values are in parentheses.

Significant differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

(5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Dn2

2s-Ologit 2s-ZIP 2s-Ologit 2s-OLS 2s-Ologit 2s-ZIP 2s-Ologit 2s-OLS

Rep_Dummy -0.457 -0.559 -1.475 -0.602 -0.572 -0.631 -2.067* -0.820*

(0.533) (0.246) (0.132) (0.126) (0.475) (0.224) (0.070) (0.074)

Rep_reg_Dummy -0.655 -0.959 -2.711 -1.425* -2.669 -1.697* -4.593** -1.921**

(0.665) (0.299) (0.135) (0.098) (0.128) (0.078) (0.029) (0.025)

Rep_Dummy*Rep_reg_Dummy 1.043 1.550 4.848* 2.386* 3.726 2.381* 6.754** 2.789**

(0.638) (0.249) (0.068) (0.067) (0.137) (0.072) (0.017) (0.019)

Lna 0.243*** 0.103** 0.286*** 0.120*** 0.277*** 0.078* 0.340*** 0.143***

(0.000) (0.018) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.084) (0.001) (0.000)

Asr -0.000** -0.000** -0.001*** -0.000*** -0.000 -0.000 0.000 0.000

(0.043) (0.022) (0.005) (0.006) (0.240) (0.305) (0.639) (0.828)

Roaj -0.003 -0.002 -0.024 -0.011 -0.007 0.002 -0.010 -0.003

(0.824) (0.789) (0.147) (0.121) (0.670) (0.858) (0.650) (0.659)

Dmi -0.202 -0.083 0.230 0.112 0.101 0.015 -0.024 -0.009

Page 38: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

38

(0.477) (0.622) (0.541) (0.485) (0.712) (0.925) (0.944) (0.949)

Time Trend 0.028 0.009 0.003 0.002 0.021 0.007 0.026 0.009

(0.563) (0.758) (0.959) (0.927) (0.669) (0.829) (0.699) (0.738)

Inflate

Lna -0.685** -0.911***

(0.039) (0.001)

Obs 384 384 212 212 344 344 187 187

Page 39: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

39

Table XV

Post-Retirement Outside Directorships in Regulated Industries

Regulated industries related to the political regulation to financial (44, 45, 47) / utilities (31) as well as pharmaceutical (12, 13) / communication (32) / defense

based on Fama-French 48 industrial code. Significant differences at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels are indicated by ***, **, and *, respectively.

Republican Regime Democratic Regime

(George Walker Bush, 2003~2008) (Barack Hussein Obama, Jr. 2009~2014)

Regulated

Industry

Unregulated

Industry

Regulated

Industry

Unregulated

Industry

Regulated

Industry

Unregulated

Industry

Mean N Mean N Mean N Mean N Mean Difference

Panel A: 2 Years after

Retirement (Dn2)

Republican Partisan 0.19 57 0.63** 57 0.19 170 0.46 170 0.00 0.17*

Democratic Partisan 0.12 26 0.23 26 0.26** 137 0.46 137 -0.15* -0.23*

Mean Difference 0.08 0.40 -0.07 0.00

Panel B: 3 Years after

Retirement (Dn3)

Republican Partisan 0.23** 40 0.60*** 40 0.20 166 0.50 166 0.02 0.10

Democratic Partisan 0.00 16 0.13 16 0.24 127 0.47 127 -0.24** -0.35**

Mean Difference 0.23 0.48 -0.03 0.03

Page 40: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

40

Table XVI

Political Preference Difference: Newly Appointed CEOs Across Ruling

Parties

This table summarizes the political preference of newly appointed 1, 292 CEOs under Republican or Democratic

party across 2003-2014 sample period from the CEOs’ contribution data in FEC. From this database, we extract

the political preference for newly appointed CEOs by the contribution pattern. New CEO Rel Republican Regime

is Rel of 698 newly appointed CEOs under a Republican regime. New CEO Rel Democratic Regime is Rel of 594

newly appointed CEOs under a Democratic regime. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans -

Donation to Democrats) / (Donation to Both Parties).

Mean Std.Dev. N

New CEO Rel Republican

Regime 0.128 0.033 698

New CEO Rel Democratic

Regime 0.124 0.036 594

Mean Difference 0.004

Page 41: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

41

Table XVII

Political Preference Difference: Newly Appointed CEOs Across Ruling Parties

Panel A summarizes the political preference of newly appointed 1, 292 CEOs under Republican or Democratic Party across 2003-2014 sample period from

the CEOs’ contribution data in FEC. From this database, we extract the political preference for newly appointed CEOs by the contribution pattern. Panel A

presents the newly appointed CEOs’ Rel during 2003 to 2014. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation

to Both Parties).

Panel A

Total REL=1 0<REL≤1 0.25≤REL≤1 -0.25<REL<0.25 -1≤REL≤-0.25 -1≤REL<0 REL=-1

CEO No. 1,292 514 729 685 103 504 549 375

% 0.398 0.564 0.530 0.080 0.390 0.425 0.290

Panel B summarizes the political preference of newly appointed 698 CEOs under Republican Party across 2003-2008 sample period from the CEOs’

contribution data in FEC. From this database, we extract the political preference for newly appointed CEOs by the contribution pattern. Panel B presents the

newly appointed CEOs’ Rel when ruling party is a republic party. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) / (Donation

to Both Parties).

Panel B

Total REL=1 0<REL≤1 0.25≤REL≤1 -0.25<REL<0.25 -1≤REL≤-0.25 -1≤REL<0 REL=-1

CEO No. 698 273 394 373 58 267 295 202

% 0.391 0.564 0.534 0.083 0.383 0.423 0.289

Panel C summarizes the political preference of newly appointed 594 CEOs under Democratic Party across 2008-2014 sample period from the CEOs’

contribution data in FEC. From this database, we extract the political preference for newly appointed CEOs by the contribution pattern. Panel C presents the

newly appointed CEOs’ Rel when ruling party is a Democratic party. Rel means as follows. Rel = (Donation to Republicans - Donation to Democrats) /

(Donation to Both Parties).

Page 42: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

42

Panel C

Total REL=1 0<REL≤1 0.25≤REL≤1 -0.25<REL<0.25 -1≤REL≤-0.25 -1≤REL<0 REL=-1

CEO No. 594 241 335 312 45 237 254 173

% 0.406 0.564 0.525 0.076 0.397 0.428 0.291

Page 43: Who, Republican or Democrat CEOs, laughs last? Political cycles … ANNUAL MEETINGS/2018-Milan... · investment and consumption motives for political contributions, Hong and Kostovetsky

43