29
International Shocks on Australia - The Japanese E ect Mardi Dungey Research School of Pacic and Asian Studies The Australian National University Canberra, ACT, 0200 [email protected] Renée Fry Department of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology, Brisbane, QLD, 4001 [email protected] December 2001 Abstract Although Australia has an equivalently large trading relationship with Japan and the US, current macro models often incorporate only US variables in the external sector of Australia. This paper explores the consequences of including both US and Japanese eects in the international sector of an SVAR model of Australia. The results indicate the signicance of the Japanese eects. Excluding Japan results in an overstatement of the impact of US based shocks on the Australian economy. When Japan is included, US based shocks remain dominant in explaining Australian outcomes, but the responses are moderated compared with a model incorporating only a US based external sector. This has important implications for domestic policy responses to international shocks. Without the inuence of Japan, domestic monetary policy will over-react to a US based shock. Keywords: Structural VAR, unied framework, monetary policy. JEL Classications: C51, F41. We would like to thank Ron Bewley, Stan Hurn, Warwick McKibbin, Vance Martin and Adrian Pagan for their helpful comments. 1

International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

International Shocks on Australia - The Japanese Effect∗

Mardi DungeyResearch School of Pacific and Asian Studies

The Australian National UniversityCanberra, ACT, 0200

[email protected]

Renée FryDepartment of Economics and Finance,Queensland University of Technology,

Brisbane, QLD, [email protected]

December 2001

Abstract

Although Australia has an equivalently large trading relationship with Japan and the US,current macro models often incorporate only US variables in the external sector of Australia. Thispaper explores the consequences of including both US and Japanese effects in the internationalsector of an SVAR model of Australia. The results indicate the significance of the Japanese effects.Excluding Japan results in an overstatement of the impact of US based shocks on the Australianeconomy. When Japan is included, US based shocks remain dominant in explaining Australianoutcomes, but the responses are moderated compared with a model incorporating only a US basedexternal sector. This has important implications for domestic policy responses to internationalshocks. Without the influence of Japan, domestic monetary policy will over-react to a US basedshock.

Keywords: Structural VAR, unified framework, monetary policy.

JEL Classifications: C51, F41.

∗We would like to thank Ron Bewley, Stan Hurn, Warwick McKibbin, Vance Martin and

Adrian Pagan for their helpful comments.

1

Page 2: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

1 Introduction

Although Australia has an equivalently large trading relationship with Japan and the US, current

macro models often incorporate only US variables in the external sector of Australia; for example

Gruen and Sheutrim (1994), Brischetto and Voss (1999), Summers (1999) and Beechey et al (2000).

There are some exceptions to this, but these generally impose the international sectors exogenously.1

This paper explores the consequences of including Japanese effects in the international sector, by

extending the Dungey and Pagan (2000) SVAR model of the US and Australia.

Three main results are evident from this model. First, the Japanese effects, whilst small in mag-

nitude, should be included to avoid model misspecification. The exclusion of Japan results in an

overstatement of the impact of US shocks on Australia. This implies that models with US only based

external sectors may lead to over compensating policy decisions. Second, international shocks have a

larger impact on Australia than similarly sized domestic shocks. Third, the inclusion of Japan in the

model is important for Australia, as the impact of the US sourced shocks are amplified by the impact

of the US shocks on Japanese variables, which has subsequent indirect effects on Australian variables.

The literature on international VAR models is relatively small. Some examples include Pesaran,

Schuermann and Weiner (2001), Monticelli and Tristani (1999), and the Minneapolis World VAR

of Litterman and Sims (1988). The Minneapolis World VAR attempts to link three regional blocks

consisting of the US, Japan and Europe, where Europe is proxied by aggregating Germany, France

and the United Kingdom. Each equation in this system is estimated separately. In contrast to the

Minneapolis World VAR and Pesaran et al, the approach adopted here is to estimate a SVAR of

interdependent economies simultaneously. Monticelli and Tristani examine interactions between the

countries involved in the EMU currency block. Germany anchors the system whereas Austria, Belgium,

France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands and Spain are aggregated into a single region. Analysis of

this system proceeds as in a two country model. The main problem with this approach is that the

effects of shocks to Germany on the individual small economies cannot be determined, thereby making

appropriate policy responses on a country basis difficult.

The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the model specification for the

SVAR, including an outline of the contemporaneous and dynamic structures of the model, as well

as an overview of the key equations. This section also includes a discussion of a multicollinearity

correction adopted to circumvent problems arising from the simultaneous inclusion of the US and

Japanese output variables in the Australian output equation. Section 3 contains the empirical results

for shocks to both the domestic and international economies. Although the emphasis of this paper

is on the impact of international shocks on Australia, the section begins with an overview of the1See Adams, Dixon, McDonald, Meagher, and Parmenter (1994), Commonwealth Treasury (1996) and Powell and

Murphy (1997). An important exception is the suite of models maintained by McKibbin, where there are multiple linksto interdependent country models, see McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1998) for example.

2

Page 3: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Table 1: Key variables in the international SVAR.

Variable Definition(a) Abbreviation

Commodity Prices World commodity price index, logs PCUSOutput GDP (SA), logs GDPUInflation Inflation (SA), percent INFUInterest Rate Federal funds rate, percent RUJapanOutput Industrial production (SA), logs IPJInflation Inflation, percent INFJInterest Rate Call rate, percent RJExchange Rate USD/Yen exchange rate, logs EJAustraliaDemand GNE, SA, logs GNEAOutput (SA) GDP, SA, logs GDPAInflation Inflation, percent INFAInterest Rate Cash rate, percent RAExchange Rate Nominal trade weighted index EA

(a)All variables are detrended.

dynamics of the Australian module to ensure that sensible results are obtained. International policy

shocks to output and foreign monetary policy are then analysed, along with the impact of commodity

price shocks. Section 4 provides an insight into the conduct of monetary policy in Australia. Some

concluding comments appear in Section 5.

2 SVAR Model Specification

The selection of variables for the SVAR model is motivated by policy interest and a need for a

parsimonious specification. Each of the US, Japan and Australia includes domestic variables consisting

of output, inflation and the interest rate. Additional variables in the Australian module include the

exchange rate and a measure of demand, whilst for Japan the exchange rate is also included. No

exchange rate variable is included in the US module as the US is the numeraire. Commodity prices

also enter the system. Table 1 presents a summary of the key variables, their filters and abbreviations.

The measure of output chosen is real GDP for both the US (GDPU) and Australia (GDPA), and

industrial production for Japan(IPJ).2 Dungey and Pagan (2000) find that the inclusion of both GNE

(GNEA) and GDP in an Australian SVAR improves its performance, and this is also the case in this

paper. GDP is interpreted as an output variable and GNE as domestic demand.

Inflation (INFU, INFJ, INFA) is used to represent prices in the model, as this is the target of2The use of GDP initially results in instability in the Japanese component of the SVAR model. An examination

of the industrial production index and GDP for Japan suggests that GDP exhibits little cyclical fluctuation. Horiye,

Naniwa and Ishihara (1987) find that the lack of cyclical variation in Japanese GNP is due to the negative correlation

between Government expenditure and domestic demand.

3

Page 4: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

monetary policy conducted by the RBA. The use of inflation is increasing in the VAR literature; see

Dungey and Pagan (2000), and Garratt, Lee, Pesaran and Shin (2001). This is in contrast to the use

of the price level, as in Sims (1992). The interest rate (RU, RJ, RA) represents the monetary policy

instrument in each national VAR model. Although the monetary aggregate M1 is included as an

additional monetary policy instrument in the Sims (1992) model, it is not included here to preserve

degrees of freedom. The exclusion of the monetary aggregate from such models is a contentious area of

the literature; see the debate between Sims (1998) and Rudebusch (1998a,b), and also Leeper and Zha

(2001), Sack (2000), McCallum (1999), and Brischetto and Voss (1999). The exchange rate for Japan

is given by the Yen per USD rate (EJ), and the nominal trade weighted index is chosen for Australia

(EA). Existing Australian VARs use either the nominal or real trade weighted index, although the

choice between the two produces little difference in the results; see Dungey (1997) and Eichenbaum

and Evans (1995).

The commodity price index (PC) traditionally enters VAR and SVAR models to capture inflation-

ary expectations. It also represents the terms of trade effect when used in models of Australia; see

Sims (1992), Gruen and Wilkinson (1994) and Brischetto and Voss (1999). Sims (1992) also finds that

the inclusion of commodity prices helps to alleviate problems in estimating closed economy VARs. In

particular, the incorporation of the commodity price index into Sims’ national VARs solves the price

puzzle, where prices rise in response to an exogenous increase in the interest rate.

The key variables in the model, Yt are

Yt =hPCt YU,t YJ,t YA,t

i, (1)

where

YU,t =hGDPU,t INFU,t RU,t

i, (2)

YJ,t =hIPJ,t INFJ,t RJ,t EJ,t

i, (3)

YA,t =hGNEA,t GDPA,t INFA,t RA,t EA,t

i. (4)

The level of each variable is expressed in natural logarithms with the exceptions of the interest rates

and the inflation rates for each country, which are expressed in percentage terms. Data sources and

codes are contained in Appendix A. All variables are detrended against a constant and a time trend

and thus represent deviations around deterministic trends. An alternative approach follows Garratt,

Lee, Pesaran and Shin (2001) where stochastic long run relationships in the form of cointegration

are embedded in a SVAR model of the UK. Two dummy variables are included in the equation for

the Australian exchange rate to allow for outliers.3 The international SVAR model is estimated with

p = 2 lags.4 The sample period begins in Quarter 3, 1979 and ends in Quarter 2, 1999. The starting

date is chosen to avoid structural breaks in the Australian economy.3The first occurs in Quarter 2, 1985 when the cash rate jumped 300 basis points. The second occurs in Quarter

3, 1986 to account for the effects of the Banana Republic statement made by the then Treasurer of Australia, PaulKeating; see Dungey and Pagan (2000).

4Given the degrees of freedom limitations here, a lag length of 2 quarters is considered optimal.

4

Page 5: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Table 2: Contemporaneous structure of the international SVAR.

Dep. Explanatory VariablesVar.

US Japan Australia

PC GDPU INFU RU IPJ INFJ RJ EJ GNEA GDPA INFA RA EA

PC

GDPU *

INFU * *

RU * *

IPJ * *

INFJ * *

RJ * *

EJ * * * * * * *

GNEA

GDPA * * *

INFA *

RA * *

EA * * * * * * * * * * * *

A * represents the inclusion of an explanatory variable.

2.1 Contemporaneous and Dynamic Structures

The inclusion of both the US and Japanese economies requires the imposition of restrictions on

the contemporaneous and dynamic structures of the model due to degrees of freedom limitations. To

alleviate this problem, block exogeneity between economies in both the contemporaneous and dynamic

structures of the model is imposed. The US as a large economy, is an ‘anchor’ for the system, making

it block exogenous to both Japan and Australia. The Japanese economy is influenced by the US

economy, but is block exogenous to the Australian economy, while Australia as a small open economy,

does not feedback into either the US or Japanese economies. This structure is supported in existing

empirical literature. The placement of Japan in the centre of the system is consistent with evidence

that US shocks are transmitted to Japan and Japanese shocks are transmitted to Australia, but that

Japanese shocks do not transmit to the US, and Australian shocks do not transmit to Japan; see

Selover and Round (1996), Selover (1997) and Horiye, Naniwa and Ishihara (1987). These block

exogeneity restriction have become relatively common in two country open economy SVAR models

recently, following the work of Cushman and Zha (1997) and Zha (1999).

The variables entering into each equation are summarised in Tables 2 and 3, where Table 2 high-

lights the contemporaneous structure whilst Table 3 highlights the lag structure of the model. The

rows correspond to the dependent variable of each equation, whilst the inclusion of explanatory vari-

5

Page 6: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Table 3: Lag structure of the international SVAR.

Dep. Explanatory VariablesVar.

US Japan Australia

PC GDPU INFU RU IPJ INFJ RJ EJ GNEA GDPA INFA RA EA

PC *

GDPU * * * **

INFU * * * **

RU * * * *

IPJ * * * * ** *

INFJ * * * ** *

RJ * * *

EJ * * * * * * * *

GNEA * * * ** *

GDPA * * * * * ** *

INFA * * ** *

RA * * * *

EA * * * * * * * * * * * * *

A * represents the inclusion of lags 1 and 2, while a ** represents the inclusion of just lag 2.

ables in each equation are indicated by a *. In Table 3, a blank corresponds to a variable not entering

an equation, if all lags of a variable enter an equation, a * is recorded. In some equations only the

second lag of a variable enters, this is denoted by **; the reasons for this are given in our discussion

of the key equations below.

2.2 The Commodity Price Equation

Commodity prices (PCt) are exogenous to each of the three economies and are specified as an AR(2)

process

PCt = f1(PCt−1, PCt−2). (5)

2.3 Output and Demand Equations

The US output equation is specified as

GDPU,t = f2(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2, GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2,

INFU,t−1, INFU,t−2, RU,t−2). (6)

6

Page 7: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

US output is a function of lagged values of US output, inflation, the second lag of the interest rate

and contemporaneous and lagged commodity prices. Interest rate effects are delayed to reflect the

gap between the implementation and impact of domestic monetary policy; see Gruen and Shuetrim

(1994) and Dungey and Pagan (2000).

The Japanese output equation is as follows

IPJ,t = f3(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2, GDPU,t,GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2,

IPJ,t−1,IPJ,t−2, INFJ,t−1, INFJ,t−2, RJ,t−2, EJ,t−1, EJ,t−2), (7)

and has a similar structure to that of the US GDP equation with the addition of some international

variables. Included are contemporaneous and lagged effects from US output and commodity prices, as

well as the Japanese variables of lagged industrial production, inflation, the second lag of the interest

rate and all lags of the exchange rate.

Both demand and output are included in the Australian module of the SVAR. Australian demand

depends only on lagged Australian domestic variables, including lags of demand, output, inflation,

the second lag of the interest rate, and all lags of the exchange rate as specified below

GNEA,t = f5(GNEA,t−1, GNEA,t−2,GDPA,t−1, GDPA,t−2,

INFA,t−1, INFA,t−2, RA,t−2, EA,t−1, EA,t−2). (8)

The Australian output equation is specified as

GDPA,t = f4(GDPU,t, GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2, IPJ,t,IPJ,t−1,IPJ,t−2,

GNEA,t, GNEA,t−1, GNEA,t−2, GDPA,t−1, GDPA,t−2,

INFA,t−1, INFA,t−2, RA,t, EA,t−1, EA,t−2). (9)

and contains contemporaneous and lagged US and Japanese outputs, and Australian demand, as well

as lagged Australian output, inflation, the second lag of the interest rate, and all lags of the exchange

rate. The inclusion of Australian demand and output in the model introduces a balance of payments

type relationship into the Australian module. However, analytical and policy interest clearly lies with

demand and output shocks and responses, which is why both are retained in the model.

Shocks from the US filter through to Japan and Australia via the relationship between output

variables. The total impact of a US shock on Australia will be composed of a direct impact from

the US and an indirect impact from the effect of the US shock on the Japanese economy and its

subsequent transmission to Australia.

2.3.1 Multicollinearity Correction

Models estimating Australian output, such as in Gruen and Sheutrim (1994), generally contain some

measure of total international output as an independent variable. The inclusion of output for both

Japan and the US in (9) raises the possibility of multicollinearity due to some form of common

international business cycle. This is solved by placing a further constraint on the system. A weighted

7

Page 8: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

sum of an index of US and Japanese outputs is constructed to replace the individual variables in the

Australian component of the model,

GDPTOT,t = w1GDPU,t + w2IPJ,t, (10)

where the weights represent the relative common currency values of US and Japanese GDP in 1990.

Here, w1 = 0.729 and w2 = 0.271. GDPTOT,t is scaled to take the value 100 in the base year, 1990.5

The effect of this constraint on the system is to alter the form of the resulting impulse response

functions. The impulse response function representing the change in Australian output to a shock to

US output (εUS,t), in the original system can be expressed as

∂GDPA,t∂εUS,t

=∂GDPU,t∂εUS,t

+∂IPJ,t∂εUS,t

, (11)

whilst in the newly restricted system accounting for multicollinearity, this change is

∂GDPA,t∂εUS,t

=∂GDPA,t

∂GDPTOT ,t

µw1∂GDPU,t

∂εUS,t+w2∂IPJ,t∂εUS,t

¶. (12)

In the instance where multicollinearity is non-existent, these two expressions will give the same result.

It is not necessary to consider this issue between other variables such as US and Japanese interest

rates, as in no instance do they simultaneously enter an equation as independent variables in the

SVAR.

2.4 The Inflation Rate Equations

US inflation is modelled as dependent on the contemporaneous and lagged impact of commodity prices

and domestic output, and lagged inflation,

INFU,t = f6(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2, GDPU,t,GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2,

INFU,t−1, INFU,t−2, RU,t−2). (13)

The restriction on the timing of the impact of interest rate changes also applies, as it does in the

output equations.

The Japanese inflation rate is specified as

INFJ,t = f7(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2, IPJ,t, IPJ,t−1, IPJ,t−2, INFJ,t−1, INFJ,t−2,

RJ,t−2, EJ,t−1, EJ,t−2), (14)

and is a function of contemporaneous and lagged commodity prices and Japanese output, as well

as the domestic variables of lagged inflation, the second lag of the interest rate, and all lags of the

exchange rate.5To implement this restriction the identity GDPTOT = w1GDPU +w2IPJ is constructed and the SVAR estimated

with GDPA dependent on GDPTOT with loading β, say. Hence a shock to GDPU is transmitted through GDPTOTwith weight w1. To assess the impact of this shock on GDPA requires the replacement of the coefficient on GDPU asshown in Tables 2 and 3 with the coefficient βw1. Similarly the coefficient for IPJ in the GDPA equation is replacedwith βw2 in calculating impulse response functions. This is a manipulation to produce impulse response functions, notthe method of estimation.

8

Page 9: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

For Australia, the inflation rate equation is

INFA,t = f8(GNEA,t, GNEA,t−1, GNEA,t−2, INFA,t−1, INFA,t−2,

RA,t−2, EA,t−1, EA,t−2), (15)

which is a function of contemporaneous and lagged demand, lagged inflation and the exchange rate,

as well as the second lag of the Australian interest rate.

The inclusion of lagged exchange rates in the inflation equation for Australia and Japan represent

the impact of import prices; see Dungey and Pitchford (2000) and Beechey et al (2000) for recent

Australian examples. Commodity prices are restricted to enter the Japanese inflation equation but

not the Australian inflation equation. This restriction is motivated by the fact that commodity prices

represent import prices to Japan and export prices to Australia, and export price inflation is generally

not found to be empirically important for Australia; see de Brouwer and Ericsson (1998).

2.5 The Interest Rate Equations

Here, the interest rate represents the monetary policy instrument. This is a contentious area of the

literature; see the debate between Sims (1998) and Rudebusch (1998a,b) for example. A common

world interest rate is not imposed on the model directly, although there remain linkages between

international interest rates via the links between output in each economy.

The interest rate equation for each economy in (16) to (18) is generally determined by domestic

economic conditions. The interest rate in each case depends on contemporaneous and lagged domestic

output (demand for Australia) and inflation, and lagged domestic interest rates. For the US and

Australia, commodity prices enter into this equation as a lag, as monetary policy adjusts to the effects

of export prices on output after a lag.

RU,t = f9(PCt−1, PCt−2, GDPU,t,GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2,

INFU,t, INFU,t−1, INFU,t−2, RU,t−1, RU,t−2), (16)

RJ,t = f10(IPJ,t, IPJ,t−1, IPJ,t−2, INFJ,t, INFJ,t−1, INFJ,t−2,

RJ,t−1, RJ,t−2), (17)

RA,t = f11(PCt−1, PCt−2, GNEA,t,GNEA,t−1,GNEA,t−2,

INFA,t, INFA,t−1, INFA,t−2, RA,t−1, RA,t−2). (18)

2.6 The Exchange Rate Equations

Each of the exchange rates is modelled to include all available information in the system. The Yen

exchange rate equation includes all US and Japanese variables in the model as well as commodity

9

Page 10: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

prices as follows

EJ,t = f12(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2, GDPU,t,GDPU,t−1, GDPU,t−2,

INFU,t, INFU,t−1, INFU,t−2, RU,t, RU,t−1, RU,t−2,

IPJ,t, IPJ,t−1, IPJ,t−2, INFJ,t, INFJ,t−1, INFJ,t−2,

RJ,t, RJ,t−1, RJ,t−2, EJ,t−1, EJ,t−2). (19)

All foreign and domestic variables also enter into the Australian exchange rate equation,

EA,t = f13(PCt, PCt−1, PCt−2,GDPU,t, GDPU,t−1,GDPU,t−2,

INFU,t, INFU,t−1, INFU,t−2, RU,t, RU,t−1, RU,t−2,

IPJ,t, IPJ,t−1, IPJ,t−2, INFJ,t, INFJ,t−1, INFJ,t−2,

RJ,t, RJ,t−1, RJ,t−2, EJ,t, EJ,t−1, EJ,t−2,

GNEA,t, GNEA,t−1,GNEA,t−2, GDPA,t,GDPA,t−1, GDPA,t−2,

INFA,t, INFA,t−1, INFA,t−2, RA,t, RA,t−1, RA,t−2, EA,t−1, EA,t−2), (20)

as the Australian exchange rate is assumed to be responsive to all information in the system.

3 Empirical Results

The set of equations for the variables in (1) of Section 2 can be conveniently combined into the

following SVAR system

B0Yt = B1Yt−1 +B2Yt−2 + εt, (21)

where εt is a multivariate white noise process with zero mean and constant diagonal variance-

covariance matrix, D. The parameter matrix B0, has unit diagonal elements and off diagonal terms

given in Table 2. The parameter matrices B1 and B2 correspond to the lag variables and are sum-

marised in Table 3.

The parameters of the SVAR are estimated in two parts. The first part consists of deriving the

corresponding VAR model associated with (21)

Yt = Φ1Yt−1 +Φ2Yt−2 + vt, (22)

where

Φi = B−10 Bi, i = 1, 2, (23)

vt = B−10 εt. (24)

Each equation of the VAR is estimated by OLS, and the VAR residuals vt, extracted. Single equation

estimation of the VAR in (22) yields consistent, but asymptotically inefficient parameter estimates.

The loss in efficiency arises from the zero restrictions given in Table 3.

10

Page 11: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Table 4: Standard deviations of the international SVAR.

US Japan Australia

GNEA,t 0.011GDPU,t 0.004 IPJ,t 0.004 GDPA,t 0.005INFU,t 0.546 INFJ,t 0.676 INFA,t 0.589RU,t 0.876 RJ,t 0.555 RA,t 1.120

EJ,t 0.040 EA,t 0.032

PCt 0.038

The second part of the estimation consists of choosing B0 andD to maximise the likelihood function

conditional on the parameter estimates of the VAR in the previous step. Formally, this amounts to

defining the following likelihood function at the tth observation

lnLt = −12ln (2π)− 1

2ln¯̄B−10 DB−100

¯̄− 12v0t¡B−10 DB−100

¢−1vt, (25)

where vt is taken as the residuals from the VAR in the first step. The log of the likelihood function

for a sample of t = 1, 2, ...T observations, is given by

lnL =TXt=1

lnLt, (26)

which is maximised using the procedure MAXLIK in GAUSS. The BFGS iterative gradient algorithm

is used with derivatives computed numerically.

A selection of the key impulse response functions obtained from shocking the SVAR model are

discussed in this section.6 The size of the shocks are given by the standard deviations of the errors

which are presented in Table 4. As in most VAR applications, the confidence intervals for the impulse

response functions are wide. A selection are presented in an earlier working paper; see Dungey and

Fry (2001).

3.1 Australian Domestic Economy Shocks

Although the focus of this paper is on the effect of the international shocks on Australia, an analysis

of the Australian module of the SVAR model ensures that the dynamics of the Australian sub-system

are sensible. Overall, the behaviour of the SVAR model in response to Australian domestic shocks is

very similar to the results reported in Dungey and Pagan (2000). Some specific examples follow.

Figure 1 shows the impact of shocks to Australian output (GDPA) and aggregate demand (GNEA)

on inflation (INFA) and interest rates (RA). The qualitative impact of the shocks on inflation and the

interest rate are as anticipated, with both shocks resulting in increases in inflation and higher interest

rates within the first year.6The full set of responses are available from the authors on request.

11

Page 12: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 1: Response of Australian inflation and the interest rate to shocks in Australian output and

aggregate demand. Shock in GDPA (solid line), shock in GNEA (dashed line).

Monetary policy shocks are represented by interest rate shocks in this model. A monetary policy

shock has the expected contractionary effect on domestic output and inflation although there is some

brief evidence of the price puzzle as inflation initially rises, but this is quickly reversed; see Figure 2.

Alternative specifications based on the inclusion of commodity prices and a money supply variable

did not solve the price puzzle; for contrary empirical results see Cochrane (1998) and McCallum

(1999). A similar short-lived price puzzle is found by Dungey and Pagan (2000) who are able to

overcome the problem by including international capital markets in the form of deflated share market

prices. However, Brooks and Henry (2000) show that equity market links between the three countries

considered are not causal. This line of investigation is not pursued here due to degrees of freedom

constraints.

3.2 International Output Shocks

Output shocks originating in the US and Japan demonstrate the anticipated responses in terms of own

economy impacts and impacts from cross country transmissions. Figure 3 shows that a US output

shock leads to expansions in US, Japanese and Australian outputs. The expansion in outputs, in turn,

results in higher inflation in all economies. Monetary policy responds in each case by contracting. The

rise in US output increases the inflation rate in Australia, primarily through import prices, proxied

by exchange rate effects as outlined in Section 2.4. Figure 3d also shows that aggregate demand in

Australia (GNEA) increases in response to the US output shock.

Similarly, a Japanese output shock results in theoretically correct responses in both Japan and

12

Page 13: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 2: Response of Australian output and inflation to a shock in the Australian interest rate.

Australia. Figure 4 presents the expansionary effects of a Japanese output shock on Australian output

(GDPA) and Australian demand (GNEA). Inflation rates in each economy subsequently rise, although

the response in Japan is quite volatile. This is followed by contractionary monetary policy in each

economy in reaction to the Japanese output expansion.

The Australian responses to US output shocks are augmented by their transmission through the

Japanese economy. To decompose the effect of a US output shock on Australia into the direct effect

from the US and the indirect effect from Japan, the following procedure is adopted. First, the full

model is shocked to yield the total effect of the US shocks on Australia. Second, the causal linkages

from Japan to Australia are set to zero whilst the remaining parameter estimates are based on the

full system results. The system is then shocked to yield the direct effect of a US sourced shock on

Australia. The indirect effect of the shock is given as the difference between the total and direct

effects.7

The results of this decomposition are shown in Figure 5 for the effects of a shock to US output on

Australian output. It is evident that the direct effect of the US shock is dominant, with about two

thirds of the magnitude of the shock at the time of the peak being the result of the direct linkage,

and the remaining one third arising from the indirect transmission mechanisms through the Japanese

economy. Selover and Round (1996) obtain a similar result.

An alternative approach for uncovering the contribution of Japan to model outcomes is to reesti-

mate the model as a two country model between the US and Australia, and to then perform impulse

analysis based on the reestimated parameter estimates. This experiment provides insights into po-7The same results are obtained if the model is decomposed into direct and indirect effects by imposing zero restrictions

on the US parameter estimates in the Australian impulse response functions, to obtain the indirect effect of the US onAustralia via Japan.

13

Page 14: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 3: US, Japanese and Australian responses to a US output shock. US responses (solid line),

Japanese responses (dashed line), Australian responses (dotted line).

14

Page 15: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 4: Responses of Japanese and Australian variables to a Japanese output shock. Response of

Japanese variables (solid line), response of Australian variables (dashed line).

15

Page 16: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 5: Decomposition of the response of Australian output to a US output shock. Total effect

(solid line), direct effect of US output on Australian output (dashed line), indirect effect of US output

on Australian output via Japanese output (dotted line).

tential misspecification problems from the exclusion of Japan in constructing an international SVAR

model for Australia.

The results of this experiment are contained in Figure 6 which compares the US output shock on

Australian output for both the two country SVAR and the full SVAR. These results show that the

inclusion of the Japanese economy reduces the amplitude of the responses of Australian output and

aggregate demand and inflation to a US output shock; see Figures 6a to 6d. Figure 6b shows that the

longer term inflationary effect of an international shock is overstated if the Japanese economy is not

included. Consequently, the amplitude of the monetary policy response is lower in a model including

Japan than a model which does not; see Figure 6c.

As a further test of the relative importance of Japan in the model, a likelihood ratio test of the

joint hypothesis that the Japanese variables in the Australian component of the model are significant

is given in Table 5. The test amounts to a joint test of 15 zero restrictions. The null hypothesis is

rejected at the 5% level of significance, and is nearly rejected at the 1% level. Thus, the inclusion of

Japan is significant.

Further evidence on the relative importance of Japanese shocks on the Australia economy is ob-

tained by comparing the relative effect of a Japanese output shock on Australian variables, to a direct

Australian output shock of the same magnitude. The result in Figure 7 shows that the Japanese out-

put shock has a relatively greater impact on Australian inflation than does an equivalent Australian

output shock.

16

Page 17: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 6: Comparison of models of Australian responses to a US output shock. International SVAR

model (solid line), two country model (dashed line).

17

Page 18: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Table 5: Likelihood ratio test that Japan is jointly significant in Australia.

Statistic p-value

Joint significance of 29. 822 0. 012*Japan in Australia(15 restrictions)

* denotes significance at the 0.05 level** denotes significance at the 0.01 level

Figure 7: Response of Australian inflation to equivalent sized shocks in Japanese (solid line) and

Australian outputs (dashed line).

18

Page 19: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

3.3 International Monetary Policy Shocks

Inspection of Figure 8 reveals that a contractionary shock to US monetary policy induces a reduction

in US inflation and a contraction in US output. The contraction in the US economy subsequently

results in lower output in Japan and Australia; see Figure 8a. This is followed by eventual falls in

Australian demand (GNEA) and inflation (INFA).

The price puzzle is evident for Japan in response to a Japanese monetary policy shock, as shown

in Figure 9b. Despite this, the remainder of the Japanese and Australian responses to the Japanese

interest rate shock are as anticipated. Japanese and Australian outputs (IPJ and GDPA) contract,

followed by falling inflation, and eventually a reduction in aggregate demand (GNEA) in Australia,

along with a reduction in interest rates (RJ and RA). Shioji (1997) finds some reduction in the Japanese

price puzzle using oil prices in place of commodity prices. The results suggest that commodity prices

do not consistently solve the price puzzle; see also Hanson (2000).

In general, the model has difficulty in capturing the behaviour of Japanese inflation. The inflation

series for Japan is very noisy, making sensible estimation difficult.8 McCallum (1999) argues that the

money base needs to be included in macroeconomic models for Japan to provide a better indication

of the overall status of Japan’s economy. This proved not to be the case here.

Figure 10 compares the two country model of the US and Australia with the international SVAR

model for a US interest rate shock. Again inclusion of the Japanese economy reduces the amplitude

of the Australian responses; see Figures 10a and d. Inflation has a deeper and longer response to the

interest rate shock in the model which includes Japan. A similar result is observed for US output

shocks. The policy implications of these result are explored further in Section 4.

3.4 Commodity Price Shocks

Figure 11 presents the responses of selected variables in the system to a shock in commodity prices. An

increase in commodity prices causes an initial increase in US output and subsequently US inflation.

This results in an increase in Japanese and Australian output, but given that commodities are an

important import for Japan, the initial inflationary effect is greater for Japan. Japanese inflation

continues above trend for between 5 and 6 years, compared with about 4 years for the US. The

Australian exchange rate appreciates strongly in response to the higher commodity prices. This is

consistent with the existing literature; see de Brouwer and O’Reagan (1997) and Gruen and Wilkinson

(1994).

One unexpected result from this model as shown in Figure 11 is that higher commodity prices are

not reflected in higher Australian inflation. This may reflect that commodity prices are not a good

indicator of inflationary expectations in Australia. Further, although Australia is a large commodity

exporter, it is also generally a price taker on international markets, where contracts are primarily

written in USD or Yen terms. Thus in this instance, the addition of commodity prices has not solved

the price puzzle, but has instead transferred it to another segment of the model.8 Several experiments with different data sources were conducted with no improvement over the current version.

19

Page 20: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 8: US, Japanese and Australian responses to a US interest rate shock. US responses (solid

line), Japanese responses (dashed line), Australian responses (dotted line).

20

Page 21: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 9: Response of Japanese and Australian variables to a Japanese interest rate shock. Japanese

responses (solid line), Australian responses (dashed line).

21

Page 22: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 10: Comparison of models of Australian responses to a US interest rate shock. International

SVAR model (solid line), two country model (dashed line).

22

Page 23: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 11: Responses to a commodity price shock. Figure (a) commodity price response. For Figures

(b), (c) and (d), the representation is: US responses (solid line), Japanese responses (dashed line),

Australian responses (dotted line).

23

Page 24: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 12: Comparison of models of Australian responses to a commodity price shock. Multi-country

model (solid line), two country model (dashed line).

24

Page 25: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Figure 13: Response of Australian interest rate to output shocks. Response of Australian interest rate

to a US output shock (solid line), response of Australian interest rate to an equivalent sized Australian

output shock (dashed line).

The inclusion of Japan in the model with the US also moderates impulse response functions for

Australia in response to a shock in commodity prices. Figure 12 shows that the inclusion of Japan

in the system mutes the effect of a commodity price shock compared with the results from the US-

Australia only system. These results may help explain the better than expected inflationary outcomes

from such shocks as commodity price shocks in the late 1990s. An implication of this result is that

monetary policy reactions may be overstated if the effect of the Japanese economy is not considered

in conjunction with the US in an Australian SVAR model.

4 Understanding Australian Monetary Policy

At various times speculation has arisen that Australian monetary policy is mainly reactive to US

monetary policy, see for example discussion in the Australian popular press in May and June 2000,

but this model shows clearly that this is not the case. Figures 3c and 9c present the response of

the Australian interest rate to US and Japanese interest rate shocks respectively. Figures 4c and 8c

present the same comparison for output shocks. These results suggest that the RBA places greater

weight on international output movements than it does on interest rate movements in the US and

Japan whilst conducting monetary policy.

The RBA states that monetary policy is formed in light of domestic economic conditions; see

Fraser (1995). Figure 13 compares the response of Australian monetary policy to an international

output shock with an Australian output shock. For comparative purposes, the size of the shock

to Australian output is scaled to be the same size as the initial impact of a US output shock on

25

Page 26: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

Australian output. The difference in the responses is indicative of the contemporaneous and feedback

effects of the international shocks in the model, and can be interpreted as the impact of international

conditions on monetary policy. This is not the same as stating that the international economy directly

increases Australian interest rates. Instead, the decomposition gives a taste of the relative importance

of the flow on effects of the international conditions to the domestic economy and hence to domestic

monetary policy.

5 Conclusions

The strong influence of the US on Australia is recognized in empirical models of the Australian

economy. However, despite Japan’s status as an equal trading partner, it is usually excluded. This

paper has constructed and estimated a SVARmodel of the Australian economy, where the international

sector is represented by both the US and Japan. This represents both an extension to the general

VAR literature, which concentrates on two region models, and complements analysis of the nature of

international shocks on the Australian economy.

The model comprises three inter-related modules, representing the US, Japan and Australia aug-

mented by commodity price effects. The US represents an ‘anchor’ for the system and is exogenous

to the other economies. Japan is placed in the center reflecting evidence that US based shocks are

transmitted to Japan and Japanese shocks transmitted to Australia but not vice versa. A small open

economy assumption is applied to Australia, excluding it from influencing the other economies.

The Japanese economy makes a statistically significant contribution to the results of the model.

Excluding Japan results in a model misspecification. In total the US based shocks are dominant in

explaining impulse responses in the model. However, although the impact of the Japanese effects

are relatively small in magnitude, they have an important role in amplifying the effects of US based

shocks, through indirect transmission via Japan.

The importance of these results are highlighted by comparison with a two country model. If Japan

is not included in the model, the impulse responses to US based shocks will be overstated. Monetary

policy responses in Australia will overcompensate if the magnitude of the impulse responses is smaller.

This means that correct model specification is important in formulating appropriate policy responses.

26

Page 27: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

A Data Sources and Codes

Table 6: Data sources, codes and abbreviations.

Variable Source Code Abbreviation

Commodity Price Index Datastream WDI76AXDF PCUSAReal GDP (SA) Datastream USGDP...D GDPUInflation (SA) Datastream USI64...F PUFederal Funds Rate Datastream USI60B.. RUJapanIndustrial Production (SA) Datastream JPI66..IF IPJInflation dX IOEJPCPI PJCall Rate Datastream JPI60..B RJUSD/YEN dX EJAustraliaGNE (SA) Datastream AUGNE...D GNEAReal GDP (SA) Datastream AUGDP...D GDPAInflation dX GCPIAGU PACash Rate Datastream AUCASH11F RANominal Trade Weighted Index dX A8.119aH EA

References[1] Adams, P.D., Dixon, P.B., McDonald, D., Meagher, G.A. and Parmenter, B.R. (1994), “Forecasts

for the Australian Economy Using the MONASH Model”, International Journal of Forecasting,10(4), 557-71.

[2] Beechey, M., Bharucha, N., Cagliarini, A., Gruen, D. and Thompson, C. (2000), “A Small Modelof the Australian Macroeconomy”, Reserve Bank of Australia, Research Discussion Paper #2000-05.

[3] Brischetto, A. and Voss, G. (1999), “A Structural Vector Autoregression Model of MonetaryPolicy in Australia”, Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper #1999-11.

[4] Brooks, C. and Henry, Ó. (2000), “Linear and Non-linear Transmission of Equity Return Volatil-ity: Evidence from the US, Japan and Australia”, Economic Modelling, 17(4), 497-513.

[5] Cochrane, J.H. (1998), “What do the VARs Mean? Measuring the Output Effects of MonetaryPolicy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(2), 277-300.

[6] Commonwealth Treasury (1996), “The Macroeconomics of the TRYM Model of the AustralianEconomy” mimeo, Modelling Section, Macroeconomic Analysis Branch.

[7] Cushman, D.O. and Zha, T.A. (1997), “Identifying Monetary Policy in a Small Open EconomyUnder Flexible Exchange Rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 39, 433-48.

[8] de Brouwer, G. and Ericsson, N. (1998), “Modelling Inflation in Australia”, Journal of Businessand Economic Statistics, 16, 433-449.

[9] de Brouwer, G. and O’Reagan, J. (1997), “Evaluating Simple Monetary Policy Rules for Aus-tralia”, in Lowe, P. (ed), Monetary Policy and Inflation Targeting, Proceedings of a Conference,Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, 244-76.

27

Page 28: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

[10] Dungey, M. (1997), International Influences on the Australian Economy”, unpublished PhDthesis, Australian National University.

[11] Dungey, M. and Fry, R. (2001), A Multi-Country Structural VAR Model”, ANU Working Papersin Trade and Development, 2001/04.

[12] Dungey, M. and Pagan, A.R. (2000), “A Structural VAR Model of the Australian Economy”,The Economic Record, 76(235), 321-43.

[13] Dungey, M. and Pitchford, J. (2000), “The Steady Inflation Rate of Growth”, The EconomicRecord, 76(235), 386-401.

[14] Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C.L. (1995), “Some Empirical Evidence of the Effects of Shocks toMonetary Policy on Exchange Rates”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(4), 975-1009.

[15] Fraser, B. (1995), “Economic Trends Downunder”, Reserve Bank Bulletin, July, 25-33.

[16] Garratt, A., Lee, K., Pesaran, H.M. and Shin, Y. (2001), “A Long Run Structural Macroecono-metric Model of the UK”, mimeo, University of Cambridge.

[17] Gruen, D. and Shuetrim, G. (1994), “Internationalisation and the Macroeconomy”, in Lowe,P. and Dwyer, J. (eds), International Integration of the Australian Economy, Reserve Bank ofAustralia, Sydney, 309-63.

[18] Gruen, D. and Wilkinson, J. (1994), “Australia’s Real Exchange Rate - Is it Explained by theTerms of Trade or Real Interest Differentials”, The Economic Record, 70(209), 204-19.

[19] Hanson, M.S. (2000), “The “Price Puzzle” Reconsidered”, mimeo, Wesleyan University.

[20] Horiye, Y., Naniwa, S. and Ishihara, S. (1987), “The Changes of Japanese Business Cycles”, BOJMonetary and Economic Studies, 5(3), 49-100.

[21] Leeper, E.M. and Zha, T. (2001), “Assessing Simple Policy Rules: A View from a CompleteMacroeconomic Model”, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 83(4), 83-110.

[22] Litterman, R.B. and Sims, C. (1988) in Bryant, R.C., Henderson, D.W., Holtham, G., Hooper, P.and Symansky, S.A. (eds), Empirical Macroeconomics for Interdependent Economies, BrookingsInstitute, Washington D.C.

[23] McCallum, B.T. (1999), “Recent Developments in the Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules”, Re-view: Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis, 81(6), 3-11.

[24] McKibbin, W.J. and Wilcoxen, P.J. (1998), “The Theoretical and Empirical Structure of theG-Cubed Model”, Economic Modelling, 16(1), 123-48.

[25] Monticelli, C. and Tristani, O. (1999), “What Does the Single Monetary Policy Do? A SVARBenchmark for the European Central Bank”, European Central Bank Working Paper #2.

[26] Pesaran, M.H., Schuermann, T. and Weiner, S.M. (2001), Modelling Regional Interdependenciesusing a Global Error-Correcting Macroeconometric Model, mimeo, University of Cambridge.

[27] Powell, A. and Murphy, C. (1997), Inside a Modern Macroeconometric Model: A Guide to theMurphy Model, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg.

[28] Rudebusch, G.D. (1998a), “Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a VARMake Sense”, InternationalEconomic Review, 39(4), 907-31.

[29] Rudebusch, G.D. (1998b), “Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a VAR Make Sense: A Reply”,International Economic Review, 39(4), 943-48.

[30] Sack, B. (2000), “Does the Fed Act Gradually? A VAR Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics, 46(1), 229-56.

[31] Selover, D. (1997), “Business Cycle Transmission between the United States and Japan: A VectorError Correction Approach”, Japan and the World Economy, 9(3), 385-411.

28

Page 29: International Shocks on Australia-The Japanese Effect

[32] Selover, D. and Round, D.K. (1996), “Business Cycle Transmission and Interdependence BetweenJapan and Australia”, Journal of Asian Economics, 7(4), 569-602.

[33] Shioji, E. (1997), “Identifying Monetary Policy Shocks in Japan”, CEPR Discussion Paper #1733.

[34] Sims, C.A. (1992), “Interpreting the Macroeconomic Time Series Facts: The Effects of MonetaryPolicy”, European Economic Review, 36(5), 975-1000.

[35] Sims, C.A. (1998), “Comment on Glenn Rudebuschs “Do Measures of Monetary Policy in A VARMake Sense?””, International Economic Review, 39(4), 932-42.

[36] Summers, P.M. (1999), “For the Student: Macroeconomic Forecasting of the Melbourne Insti-tute”, Australian Economic Review, 32(2), 197-205.

[37] Zha, T. (1999), “Block Recursion and Structural Vector Autoregressions”, Journal of Economet-rics, 90(2), 291-316.

29