Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    1/121

     

    The determinants of capital structure: evidence

    from selected ASEAN countries

     Ng Chin Huat

    Bachelor of Accountancy (Hons)The Northern University of Malaysia

    Sintok, KedahMalaysia

    1995 

    Submitted to the Graduate School of Business

    Faculty of Business and Accountancy

    University of Malaya in partial fulfillment

    of the requirements for the Degree of

    Master of Business Administration

    December 2008

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    2/121

      ii

    The determinants of capital structure: evidence from selectedASEAN countries

    By Ng Chin Huat

    Abstract

    Corporate structure is an important research area in corporate finance and it remains

    the core of literature studies for academicians. However studies had focused on firms

    in developed countries and little attention on how firms in developing and emerging

    market decide on their capital structure strategy. Therefore this study attempts to fill

    the gap by analyzing the capital structure for listed firms in the ASEAN region.

    The sample comprises 155 listed companies from four selected ASEAN main stock

    exchange index-links components for the period from 2003 to 2007.

    The study found profitability and growth opportunities for all selected ASEAN

    countries exhibit statistical significant of inverse relationship with leverage whereas

    non-debt tax shield has significant negative impact on leverage as for Malaysia index

    link companies only. Firm size gave a positive significant relationship for Indonesia

    and Philippine index link companies. As for the four country-effect factors; stock

    market capitalization and GDP growth rate show significant relationship with

    leverage while bank size and inflation indicate insignificant impacts on leverage.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    3/121

      iii

    Acknowledgements

    To my beloved family and friends, who have constantly been supportive and

    understanding throughout my MBA study, I owe great thanks. Specifically, I owe the

    greatest debt to my parents who have been an important motivation for this thesis and

    who continually provide role models. This work is devoted to them.

    It has also been an enormous challenge to maintain motivation, quality and innovation

    within a balanced research dissertation. I would like to record my sincere thanks and

    appreciation to my supervisor, Mr. Gurcharan Singh A/L Pritam Singh, for his prompt,

    constructive guidance, and continued support given to me during my dissertation

    work. Special thank to Dr. Rubi binti Ahmad, my second examiner for her positive

    comments.

    Finally, I also wish to extend my gratitude and special thanks to the lecturers and staff

    of Graduate Business School, University of Malaya for their valuable coaching and

    insights throughout my MBA course.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    4/121

      iv

    Table of Contents

    Abstract ..........................................................................................................................ii

    Acknowledgements.......................................................................................................iii

    List of Tables ...............................................................................................................vii

    List of Symbols and Abbreviations ............................................................................viii

    CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION..................................................................................1

    1.1 Background....................................................................................................1

    1.1.1 Overview of ASEAN.................................................................................3

    1.2 Problem Statement .........................................................................................4

    1.3 Research Questions/Objectives of the Study .................................................6

    1.4 Purpose and Significance of the Study ..........................................................8

    1.5 Scope of the Study .........................................................................................9

    1.6 Limitations of the Study ..............................................................................11

    1.7 Organization of the Study ............................................................................12

    CHAPTER 2 : LITERATURE REVIEW ..................................................................13

    2.0 Chapter Overview ........................................................................................13

    2.1 Introduction..................................................................................................13

    2.2 Capital structure in a perfect market............................................................15

    2.2.1 The Modigliani and Miller Propositions..................................................15

    2.3 Capital structure in the real world................................................................16

    2.3.1 Trade-off theory .......................................................................................16

    2.3.2 Asymmetric information..........................................................................18

    2.4.3 Agency Costs ...........................................................................................22

    2.4 New development in capital structure .........................................................24

    2.4.1 Shocks to the capital structure and adjusting behavior ............................24

    2.4.2 Dynamic adjustment to target leverage and adjustment speed ................25

    2.4.3 Major real investments.............................................................................26

    2.4.4 Macroeconomic shocks............................................................................27

    2.4.5 Rating.......................................................................................................27

    2.4.6 Behavioral corporate finance ...................................................................28

    2.5 Related literature on the international capital structure ...............................30

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    5/121

      v

    2.5.1 Capital structure around the world: The roles of firm- and country-

    specific determinants by De Jong et al. (2008)....................................................30

    2.5.2 The determinants of capital structure: evidence from the Asia Pacific

    region by Deesomsak et al. (2004). .....................................................................31

    2.5.3 Determinants of Capital Structure: Evidence from the G-7 Countries byAggarwal and Jamdee (2003). .............................................................................32

    2.5.4 Capital structure in developing countries by Booth et al. (2001). ...........34

    2.6 Determinants of capital structure .................................................................35

    2.6.1 Country-specific determinants .................................................................36

    2.6.2 Firm-specific determinants ......................................................................40

    2.7 Chapter Summary ........................................................................................45

    CHAPTER 3 : RESEARCH METHODOLOGY ......................................................46

    3.0 Chapter Overview ........................................................................................46

    3.1 Development of Hypotheses ........................................................................46

    3.1.1 Profitability ..............................................................................................46

    3.1.2 Growth opportunities ...............................................................................47

    3.1.3 Non-debt Tax Shield ................................................................................48

    3.1.4 Firm size ..................................................................................................48

    3.1.5 The size of the banking industry and stock market development. ...........48

    3.1.6 GDP growth rate. .....................................................................................49

    3.1.7 Inflation....................................................................................................49

    3.2 Selection Measures ......................................................................................50

    3.2.1 Leverage...................................................................................................50

    3.2.2 Size of the banking industry and stock market ........................................51

    3.2.3 GDP growth rate ......................................................................................52

    3.2.4 Inflation....................................................................................................52

    3.2.5 Profitability ..............................................................................................52

    3.2.6 Firm growth .............................................................................................52

    3.2.7 Non-debt Tax Shield ................................................................................53

    3.2.8 Firm size ..................................................................................................53

    3.3 Sampling Design..........................................................................................53

    3.4 Data Collection Procedure ...........................................................................56

    3.5 Data Analysis Techniques ...........................................................................57

    3.6 Chapter Summary ........................................................................................58

    CHAPTER 4 : RESEARCH RESULTS....................................................................59

    4.0 Chapter Overview ........................................................................................59

    4.1 Summary Statistics ......................................................................................59

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    6/121

      vi

    4.1.1 Dependent variable (Leverage)................................................................59

    4.1.2 Firm-specific independent variables ........................................................60

    4.1.3 Fixed country effects analysis of the determinants of leverage in the

    selected ASEAN ..................................................................................................62

    4.2 Analyses of Measures ..................................................................................634.2.1 Test of non-stationary ..............................................................................63

    4.2.2 Test of multicollinearity...........................................................................65

    4.2.3 Test of autocorrelation .............................................................................66

    4.2.4 Test of heteroskedasticity ........................................................................67

    4.3 Testing of Hypotheses .................................................................................68

    4.3.1 Cross-sectional results for individual countries and firm-specific effects

    over the whole sample period ..............................................................................68

    4.4 Chapter Summary ........................................................................................74

    CHAPTER 5 : CONCLUSION..................................................................................75

    5.0 Chapter overview .........................................................................................75

    5.1 Discussion and Conclusion ..........................................................................75

    5.1.1 Summary of findings ...............................................................................75

    5.2 Suggestions for Future Research .................................................................79

    5.3 Policy implication ........................................................................................80

    5.4 Chapter Summary ........................................................................................81

    References....................................................................................................................82

    Appendix 1: List of Companies Selected ....................................................................91

    Appendix 2: Description of Variables and Data Sources ............................................94

    Appendix 3: Unit Root Test.........................................................................................95

    Appendix 4: Autocorrelaton Test ..............................................................................102

    Appendix 5: Decision Rules of Durbin-Watson d Test .............................................105

    Appendix 6: Multicollinearity Test............................................................................106

    Appendix 7: White’s Heteroskedasticity Test (With Cross Terms) ..........................108

    Appendix 8: Final Multiple Regression Results........................................................109

    Appendix 9: Summary of Predictions........................................................................112

    Appendix 10: Summary of Hypotheses Testing Results ...........................................113

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    7/121

      vii

    List of Tables

    Table 1.1 Selected Basic ASEAN Indicators 3

    Table 3.1 List of Stock Exchanges in Selected ASEAN Countries 53

    Table 4.1 Statistics of Leverage Ratio 59

    Table 4.2 Statistics of Firm-specific Independent Variables 60

    Table 4.3 Statistic of Country-specific Determinants 62

    Table 4.4 Summary Result of Unit Root Test Using ADF 64

    Table 4.5 Pairwise Correlation Matrix Between Explanatory Variables 65

    Table 4.6 Summary of Durbin-Watson Test 66

    Table 4.7 Summary of White’s Test (Cross Terms) 67

    Table 4.8 Firm Specific Analysis of Determinants of Leverage 69

    Table 4.9 Country Effects Analysis of Determinants of Leverage 72

    Table 5.1 Summary of Firm-specific Determinants 75

    Table 5.2 Summary of Country-specific Determinants 77

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    8/121

      viii

    List of Symbols and Abbreviations

    ADF Augmented Dickey-Fuller

    ASEAN Association of South-East Asian Nations

    BANK Private credit by deposit bank over GDP

    BLUE Best linear unbiased estimator

    CEO Chief executive officer

    CFO Chief financial officer

    EBIT Earnings before income tax

    EBITDA Earnings before income tax, depreciation and amortization

    G-7 Group of Seven (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan,

    United Kingdom and United States of America)

    GDP Gross Domestic Product

    GDPRATE Gross Domestic Product growth rate

    GROWTH Firm’s growth opportunities

    LEVRATIO Leverage ratio

    MM Modigliani and Miller

     NDTS Non-debt tax shield

    INF Annual inflation rate

    OECD Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development

    OLS Ordinary least square

     NPV Net present value

    PROFIT ProfitabilityR&D Research and development

    ROA Return on assets

    SIZE Firm size

    STKMKT Stock market capitalization over GDP

    U.S. United States of America

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    9/121

      1

    CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION

    1.1 

    Background

    For the past fifty years after the influential irrelevance theory of Modigliani and

    Miller (1958) on capital structure, academicians have debated rigorously on this

    capital structure theory through many empirical studies (example in Harris and Raviv,

    1991 in their article “The theory of capital structure”). In order to approve or dispel

    the irrelevance theory, others have studied the determinants of firms’ capital structure

    choices with frictions such as agency signaling costs (Heinkel, 1982; Poitevin, 1989),

     bankruptcy (Ross, 1977), taxes (Leland and Toft, 1996), institutional and historical

    characteristics of national financial systems (La Porta et al., 1997, 2006; Rajan and

    Zingales, 2003), but the understanding of the determinants of national and

    international capital structure is still limited and vague (Aggarwal and Jamdee, 2003).

    In the early years, firms in United States were the primary source of these research

    studies and the coverage was extended to Europe and Japan in mid of 1980s (Kester,

    1986; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Cornelli et al., 1996). In the aftermath of the Asian

    financial crisis in 1997, efforts were focused on emerging countries to shed some light

    on the factors that caused the turmoil in the region. Despite of this attempt, however,

    there have been only a few studies thus far because of the constraints on corporate

    financial data in the region (Fan and Wong, 2002; Deesomsak et al., 2004; Driffield et

    al., 2007). Moreover, still very little is understood about the determinants of the

    firm’s financial structure outside the United States and major developed countries,

    with only a few researches analyzing international data (Rajan and Zingales, 1995;

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    10/121

      2

    Booth et al., 2001; Antoniou et al., 2002; De Jong et al., 2008). Undoubtedly, there

    is not enough evidence on how theories formulated for firms operating in the major

    developed markets can be applied to firms outside these markets coupled with

    differential in institutional and legal frameworks. Consequently, incomprehensive

    conclusions and puzzling questions are left either partially or completely unanswered

    in the area of international capital structure. With the pressing globalization trend,

    managers of today need to be readily equipped with in-depth knowledge of

    international capital structure in strategizing crucial capital structure decisions and

    this remains one of the key success factors of their firms’ survival.

    The knowledge of capital structures has mostly been derived from data from

    developed economies that have many institutional similarities. The purpose of this

     paper is to analyze the capital structure choices made by companies from developing

    countries that have different institutional structures. The prevailing view, for example

    Mayer (1990) seems to be that financial decisions in developing countries are

    somehow different. For example, Mayer (1990) is the most recent researcher to use

    aggregate flow of funds data to differentiate between financial systems based on the

    "Anglo-Saxon" capital markets model and those based on a "Continental-German-

    Japanese" banking model. However, because Mayer’s data comes from aggregate

    flow of funds data and not from individual firms there is a problem with this

    approach. The differences between private, public, and foreign ownership structures

    have a profound influence on such data, but tell nothing about how profit-oriented

    groups make their individual financial decisions.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    11/121

      3

    1.1.1  Overview of ASEAN

    The Association of South-East Asian Nations (commonly known as ASEAN) is a

    geopolitical and economic organization of ten countries located in South-East Asia,

    which was formed on 8 August 1967 by five founding members, namely Indonesia,

    Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore and Thailand. Subsequently other member states

     joined ASEAN - Brunei (1984), Vietnam (1995), Laos and Myanmar (1997) and

    Cambodia (1999). Its main objectives are to accelerate economic growth, social

     progress and cultural development in the region; and promote regional peace and

    stability. As of 2007, the ASEAN has a population of about 575 million, a total area

    of 4.5 million square kilometers, a combined gross domestic product of almost

    US$1,282 billion, and a total trade of about US$1,405 billion as shown in Table 1.1.

    Table 1.1Selected Basic ASEAN Indicators

    Growthrate ofGDP GDP Merchandise trade

    Total landarea

    Totalpopulation

    Atconstant

    pricesat current

    prices Exports Imports Total trade

    km2  Thousand Percent US$ million US$ million US$ million US$ million

    Country 2007 2007 2007 2007 2006 2006 2006

    Brunei 5,765 396 0.6 12,317.00 7,619.40 1,488.90 9,108.30

    Cambodia 181,035 14,475 10.1 8,662.30 3,514.40 2,923.00 6,437.40

    Indonesia 1,890,754 224,905 6.3 431,717.70 100,798.60 61,065.50 161,864.10

    Lao PDR 236,800 5,608 6 4,128.10 402.7 587.5 990.2

    Malaysia 330,252 27,174 6.3 186,960.70 157,226.90 128,316.10 285,543.00Myanmar 676,577 58,605 5.6 12,632.70 3,514.80 2,115.50 5,630.30

    Philippines 300,000 88,875 7.4 146,894.80 47,410.10 51,773.70 99,183.80

    Singapore 704 4,589 9.3 161,546.60 271,607.90 238,482.00 510,089.90

    Thailand 513,120 65,694 4.8 245,701.90 121,579.50 127,108.80 248,688.30

    Viet Nam 329,315 85,205 8.5 71,292.10 37,033.70 40,236.80 77,270.50

    ASEAN 4,464,322 575,525 6.5 1,281,853.90 750,708.00 654,097.80 1,404,805.80

    (Sources: ASEAN Finance and Macro-economic Surveillance Unit Database and ASEAN Statistical Yearbook 2006, ASEANTrade Database as of 18 July 2007, IMF World Economic Outlook Database as of October 2007)

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    12/121

      4

    1.2  Problem Statement

    Capital structure decision remains one of the important strategies to corporate

    manager because it affects firm’s value. For instance, Damodaran (2001) states that if

    the objective in corporate finance is to maximize firm value, then firm value must be

    linked to the three decisions: investment, financing and dividend.

    Ross (1977)’s model suggests that the values of firms will rise with leverage, since

    increasing leverage increases the market’s perception of value. Suppose there is no

    agency problem, i.e. management acts in the interest of all shareholders, the manager

    will maximize company value by choosing the optimal capital structure: highest

     possible debt ratio. High-quality firms need to signal their quality to the market, while

    the low-quality firms’ managers will try to imitate. According to this argument, the

    debt level should be positively related to the value of the firm.

    McConnell and Servaes (1995) find that high-growth firms’ corporate value is

    negatively correlated with leverage, whereas for low–growth firms’ corporate value is

     positively correlated with leverage.

    Stulz (1990) argues that debt can have both a positive and negative effect on the value

    of the firm. He develops a model in which debt financing can both alleviate the over-

    investment problem and the under-investment problem and assumes that managers

    have no equity ownership in the firm and receive utility by managing a larger firm.

    The power of manage may motivate the self-interest managers to undertake negative

     present value projects. To solve this problem, shareholders force firms to issue debt.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    13/121

      5

    But if firms are forced to pay out funds, they may have to forgo positive present value

     projects. Therefore, the optimal debt structure is determined by balancing the optimal

    agency cost of debt and the agency cost of managerial discretion.

    From the above discussion, it is proven that capital structure is one of the main drivers

    for firm’s value. However many empirical studies are done in the developed

    countries such as United States, Europe and Japan (Rajan and Zingales, 1995;

    Cornelli et al., 1996) and only a few research are in the Asia region (Fan and Wong,

    2002; Deesomsak et al., 2004; Driffield et al., 2007). Hence the question whether the

    capital structure determinants in the developed countries could also be replicated to

    developing countries remains ambiguous due to differences in institutional and

    historical environments (Jack and Ajit, 2003). No study has been done using

    specifically the ASEAN’s firms to analyze the capital structure and its determinants.

    Even though there are studies focused on national level [Wiwattanakantang (1999) for

    Thailand; Suto (2003) for Malaysia; Prasad et al. (2003) for Thailand and Malaysia],

    there is no study on cross-country comparison between ASEAN countries.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    14/121

      6

    1.3  Research Questions/Objectives of the Study

    In this research, in line with the problem statement as above, a few objectives are

    outlined as the guiding principle to this study. The focus of this paper is to on

    answering the three questions:

    1.  Do corporate leverage decisions differ significantly between developing and

    developed countries?

    Previous studies have mainly focused on the developed countries in analyzing the

    capital structure decision but researches in the developing countries are limited. Thus

    one of the objectives of this study is to analyze corporate leverage decisions in

    ASEAN region as they are in the emerging and developing market. Thereafter the

    comparison between developed and developing countries will be done to examine any

    significant different in their corporate leverage decisions.

    2.  Are the factors that affect individual countries’ capital structures similar between

    developed and developing countries?

    In this objective, the factors that influence the capital structure in the developed

    countries are extended to the developing countries in order to observe any significant

    differences among them (Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Booth et al.,  2001). In this

    context, comprehension of the linkages between both categories will benefit managers

    in deciding capital structure strategy in era of globalization.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    15/121

      7

    3.  Are the predictions of conventional capital structure models improved by knowing

    the nationality of the company?

    In this objective, this study tries to determine whether the predictions of capital

    structure decisions can be improved by linking the nationality of the company with

    the conventional capital structure models. With this knowledge, managers will have a

    competitive advantage in formulating their capital structure strategy by knowing the

    nationality of the company, particularly in ASEAN members.

    In order to answer the above questions, the objectives are geared toward the

    following:

    (a)  To examine the country-specific determinants such as size of banking

    industry, stock market, and GDP growth and inflation in relation to the capital

    structure.

    (b)  To examine the firm-specific determinants such as profitability, growth

    opportunities, non-debt tax shield and size in relation to the capital structure.

    (c)  To determine which of the capital structure theories are pertinent to ASEAN

    listed companies in order to adopt a more efficient financing mix.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    16/121

      8

    1.4  Purpose and Significance of the Study

    The purpose of this study is to examine the determinants of capital structure at both

    country and firm levels to further the understanding of the different characteristics of

    capital structure in the selected ASEAN countries (Malaysia, Indonesia, Philippines

    and Thailand). As each country has its own uniqueness, the results of this study will

     be useful in understanding which theories of capital structure are robust to such

    differences.

    The main contribution of this study is to provide valuable knowledge of cross border

    comparison of the capital structure determinants in the context of developing and

    emerging markets, in general; and specifically ASEAN to academicians and

     practitioners. This is to complement the abundant literatures of capital structure done

    in developed countries such as United States and Europe (Auerbach, 1985; Titman

    and Wessels, 1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Cornelli et al., 1996; Wald, 1999; Hall

    et al., 2004).

    In addition, with the most recent data available in this study, the development of

    capital structure after the Asian financial crisis could also be evaluated in view of the

    changing in financial markets and economic conditions.

    Previous studies using Asia Pacific companies are limited and almost none

    concentrating in ASEAN countries (published studies include Wiwattanakantang,

    1999 for Thailand; Fan and Wong, 2002 and Driffield et al., 2007 for East Asia; Suto,

    2003 for Malaysia; Prasad et al., 2003 for Thailand and Malaysia; Cassar and Holmes,

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    17/121

      9

    2003 and Zoppa and McMahon, 2002 for Australia; Deesomsak et al., 2004 for Asia

    Pacific region; Fattouh et al., 2005 for South Korea). Hence this study intends to fill

    this gap by analyzing capital structure determinants based on ASEAN countries.

    Lastly, the findings of this study may provide valuable insights in term of the

    complexity and robustness of capital structure decisions to the corporate managers in

    the global market.

    1.5  Scope of the Study

    In the area of any study, it’s expected to encounter numerous issues such as the

    concentration of field study, data collection and others which are constraint by

    available resources like timeframe, monetary and availability of information. This

    study is of no exceptions where the scope is limited to the study of capital structure in

    the corporate finance field, the sample size and lastly the time period of study. The

    detailed of the scope of this study are as follows:

    (a)  The sample companies will be selected from the main stock indexes from four

    Stock Exchanges in the ASEAN region. The entire population of listed companies in

    the four Stock Exchange is 2,131 with total market capitalization of US$837,119

    million as at 31 December 2007 (World Federation of Exchanges 2007). However the

    sampling is from 275 companies, merely a 13 percent of population but representing

    over 70 percent of total capitalization except for Philippine being only 54 percent.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    18/121

      10

    (b)  Four countries representing ASEAN are selected, namely Malaysia, Indonesia,

    Philippines and Thailand out of ten countries. The choice of countries is motivated by

    several factors. Firstly, they are all being the emerging market where the literature on

    determinants of capital structure is limited. Secondly, they are hit severely in the

    Asian financial crisis in 1997. Thirdly, they share the common attributes in

    accounting practices, corporate governance and corporate control.

    (c)  As for companies selected, only non-financial firms were used. This is due to

    the reasons that financial firms such as banks and insurance companies’ leverage are

    strongly influenced by investor insurance schemes. Furthermore, their debt-like

    liabilities are not strictly comparable to the debt issued by non-financial firms.

    Finally, regulations such as minimum capital requirements may directly affect capital

    structure.

    (d)  The sample companies are not categorized into industry classification due to

    the small sample size. However as the listed companies are index-linked stocks,

    there is requirement for sector representation; hence no further work is performed on

    the industry classification effect.

    (e)  The study period for the study is five years from year 2003 to 2007. They

    represent the most current data available and are obtained from the Bloomberg,

    Financial Times and Reuters database. The financial information for last five years

    will be extracted for the 155 index link companies from selected ASEAN countries.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    19/121

      11

    1.6  Limitations of the Study

    As for the limitation, the following are expected:

    (a)  The study is restricted to the sampling from stock indexes of the Stock

    Exchanges in the four ASEAN countries; the result may be biased towards big and

    well established firms and may not be a good representative for the population of the

    firms in ASEAN countries taking into account of the fact that there are many small

    and medium-sized companies. However this reflects a better representation as having

    high percentage in asset capitalization of the firms listed.

    (b)  This study has not taken into account the difference in accounting policy

    adopted by various countries, in particular the depreciation charges (proxy for non-

    debt tax shield variable). However as the companies are public listed companies,

    they generally follow the internationally accepted accounting standard in their

    accounting policy as required by their reporting country authorities.

    (c)  This study has not employed country dummy variables when analyzing the

    country-specific factors as to reduce the complexity of the multiple regression

    equation as there are four countries involved and to mitigate this problem, pooling of

    all listed companies in four countries is used.

    (d)  The study period may be too short, i.e. from the year 2003 to 2007.

     Nevertheless, this study is to see the immediate effect of the capital structure

    decisions after the Asian financial crisis.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    20/121

      12

    1.7  Organization of the Study

    The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Chapter Two will review the main

    theoretical framework such as country-specific factors (macroeconomics); and firm-

    specific determinants affecting capital structure. Chapter Three provides the research

    methodology along with the description of the database, data structure, hypotheses

    and analysis techniques. In Chapter Four, the results and analysis of this study are

     presented. Chapter Five concludes this dissertation as well as suggestions for future

    study and policy implementation.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    21/121

      13

    CHAPTER 2 : LITERATURE REVIEW

    2.0 Chapter Overview

    This chapter will introduce the literature on capital structure. Various theories

    associated with capital structure in the perfect market and real world such as

    Modigliani and Miller Propositions, Trade-off, Asymmetric Information and Agency

    Costs theories will be presented. New developments in the capital structure are also

    discussed. Furthermore, two types of determinants of capital structure: country-

    specific and firm-specific variables are later discussed.

    2.1 

    Introduction

    In corporate finance, capital structure refers to the way a firm finances its investments

    through some combination of equity, debt, or hybrid securities (Ross et al.,  2007,

     page 426). A firm's capital structure is then the composition or the structure of its

    liabilities. For example, a firm that sells RM20 million in equity and RM80 million in

    debts is said to be 20% equity-financed and 80% debt-financed. The firm's ratio of

    debt to total financing is 80% and is referred to as the firm's leverage. In reality,

    capital structure may be highly complex and comprises of many sources (Frecka,

    2005). A firm's capital structure has an important influence on the financial

     performance and firm efficiency (Ghosh, 2008; Margaritis and Psillaki, 2007).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    22/121

      14

    Well, then how should a firm choose its debt to equity ratio? And, what is the optimal

    capital structure for a firm? Whether or not an optimal capital structure do exists is an

    issue in corporate finance (Myers, 1984; Hatfield et al., 1994).

    A  firm can choose any capital structure as it wishes. It is the result of deliberate

    choice on the corporate management, investors’ attitudes and market conditions for

    long-term funds. A firm  could increase or decrease its debt/equity ratio by either

    issuing more debt to buy back stock or issuing stock to pay debt. The objective of

    managing capital structure is to mix  the financial sources used by the firm in a way

    that will maximize the shareholders' wealth and   minimize the firm's cost of capital.

    This proper mix  of funds sources is called optimal capital structure (Ross, et al.,

    2005).

    Haugen and Senbet (1988) argue that capital structure is strongly related to the choice

     between internal and external financial instruments. Thus, optimal capital structure

    will be impacted by the expected costs of financial distress either direct cost, such as

    the costs in the case of bankruptcy, or indirect costs, such as lost of sales. Therefore,

    financial distress is an important criterion for capital structure decisions

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    23/121

      15

    2.2 Capital structure in a perfect market

    2.2.1 The Modigliani and Miller Propositions

    The Modigliani-Miller (“MM”) theorem (1958) formed the basis for modern thinking

    on capital structure. Assuming in a perfect capital market (no transaction or

     bankruptcy costs; perfect information); firms and individuals can borrow at the same

    interest rate; no taxes; and investment decisions aren't affected by financing decisions.

    It does not matter if the firm's capital is raised by issuing stock or selling debt and

    what the firm's dividend policy is. Therefore, the MM theorem is also often called the

    capital structure irrelevance principle.

    Modigliani and Miller made two findings under these conditions. Their first

     proposition was that the value of a company is independent of its capital structure.

    Their second proposition stated that the cost of equity for a leveraged firm is equal to

    the cost of equity for an unleveraged firm, plus an added premium for financial risk.

    This implies that the firm's debt to equity ratio does not influence its cost of capital. A

    firm’s  value is only determined by its real assets, and it cannot be changed by pure

    capital structure management. Consequently, it means that there is no optimal capital

    structure exists (Ross et al. 2007, pp. 433-440)

    However, there is a fundamental difference between debt financing and equity

    financing in the real world with corporate taxes as dividends paid to shareholders

    derive from the after-tax profits and interest paid to bondholders is out of the before-

    tax profits – commonly recognized as interest tax shield (Graham, 2000; MacKie-

    Mason, 1990). Moreover, firms (or their managers) themselves do not believe in the

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    24/121

      16

    irrelevance of capital structure. For instance, in Graham and Harvey (2001) and

    Brounen et al. (2006)’s survey on chief financial officers of U.S. and Europe firms

    illustrate that the majority of firm managers consider capital structure decisions

    important for firm value and that firms have some target debt-equity ratio.

    2.3  Capital structure in the real world

    The theories below try to address some of the imperfections by relaxing assumptions

    made in the MM model such as no taxes, no transactions or distress costs, common

    objectives among decision-makers (value maximization) and perfect information.

    2.3.1 Trade-off theory

    The trade-off theory of capital structure refers to the idea that a company chooses how

    much debt finance and how much equity finance to use by balancing the costs and

     benefits. It states that there is an advantage to financing with debt, the tax benefit of

    debt and there is a cost of financing with debt, the costs of financial distress including

     bankruptcy costs of debt and non-bankruptcy costs (e.g. staff leaving, suppliers

    demanding disadvantageous payment terms, bondholder/stockholder infighting, etc).

    The marginal benefit of further increases in debt declines as debt increases, while the

    marginal cost increases, so that a firm that is optimizing its overall value will focus on

    this trade-off when choosing how much debt and equity to use for financing (Ross et

    al., 2007; Barnea et al., 1981).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    25/121

      17

    The empirical relevance of the trade-off theory has often been questioned (Frank and

    Goyal, 2003). Miller (1977) and Graham (2000) argue that the tax savings seem large

    and certain while the deadweight bankruptcy costs seem minor. This implies that

    many firms should be more highly levered than they really are.  Myers (1984) was a

     particularly fierce critic to trade-off theory because it seemed to rule out conservative

    debt ratio by taxpaying firms. Welch (2002) has argued that firms do not undo the

    impact of stock price shocks as they should under the basic trade-off theory and so the

    mechanical change in asset prices that makes up for most of the variation in capital

    structure.

    Empirical evidences in the tradeoff theory are extensive. For instance, Bradley et al. 

    (1984) find that firms’ optimal leverage is inversely related to the expected costs of

    financial distress and to the amount of non-debt tax shields. They also find the highly

    significant inverse relation between firm leverage and earnings volatility. According

    to Myers (1993), the evidence against the tradeoff theory is the inverse correlation

     between profitability and financial leverage and the same finding is substantiated by

    Rajan and Zingales (1995) for G7 countries. Titman and Wessels (1988) find a

    significant negative relationship between profitability and debt ratios. However, the

    tradeoff theory predicts the opposite relationship unless profitable firms incur more

    agency costs than less profitable firms as the debt ratio increases. Titman and Wessels

    (1988) find no relationship between debt ratios and a firm’s expected growth, non-

    debt tax shields, volatility, or the collateral value of its assets.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    26/121

      18

    2.3.2  Asymmetric information

    Firm managers or insiders are assumed to possess private information about the

    characteristics of the firm's return stream or investment opportunities. In one set of

    approaches, capital structure is designed to mitigate inefficiencies in the firm's

    investment decisions that are caused by the information asymmetry. This branch of

    the literature starts with Myers and Majluf (1984) and Myers (1984). In another,

    choice of the firm's capital structure signals to outside investors the information of

    insiders. This stream of research began with the work of Ross (1977) and Leland and

    Pyle (1977). Various approaches to the asymmetric information are discussed in the

    following subsections.

    2.3.2.1 Pecking order theory

    Myers and Majluf (1984) showed that, if investors were less well-informed than

    current firm insiders about the value of the firm's assets, then equity may be mispriced

     by the market. This underinvestment could be avoided if the firm could finance the

    new project using a security that was not so severely undervalued by the market. For

    example, internal funds and/or riskless debt involve no undervaluation, and, therefore,

    would be preferred to equity by firms in this situation. In addition, Myers (1984)

    stated that companies prioritized their sources of financing according to the law of

    least effort or resistance. This pecking order theory maintained that businesses adhere

    to a hierarchy of financing sources and prefer internal financing when available, and

    debt was preferred over equity if external financing was required (Myers, 1984).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    27/121

      19

    Pecking order theory tries to capture the costs of asymmetric information. Hence

    internal debt is used first, and when that is depleted debt is issued, and when it is not

    sensible to issue any more debt, equity is issued. Thus, the form of debt a firm

    chooses can act as a signal of its need for external finance. The pecking order theory

    was popularized by Myers (1984) when he argued that equity is a less preferred

    means to raise capital because when managers (who are assumed to know better about

    true condition of the firm than investors) issue new equity, investors believe that

    managers think that the firm is overvalued and managers are taking advantage of this

    over-valuation. As a result, investors will place a lower value to the equity issuance

    as evidenced by equity issue announcements are met with a negative market reaction

    (Asquith and Mullins, 1986) and the markets reaction to security issue announcements

    are more negative for issues of riskier securities (Hadlock and James, 2002).

    The evidences of pecking order theory are as follow. Kester (1986), in his study of

    debt policy in U.S. and Japanese manufacturing corporations, finds that the return on

    assets is the most significant explanatory variable for actual debt ratios. MacKie-

    Mason’s (1990) result suggests that the importance of asymmetric information gives a

    reason for firms to care about who provides the funds (e.g., between public and

     private debt) because different fund providers have different access to information

    about the firm and different ability to monitor firm behavior. This is consistent with

    the pecking order theory implied by Myers and Majluf (1984) since private debt will

    require better information about the firm than public debt. Shyam-Sunder and Myers

    (1999) show that firms follow the pecking order in their financing decisions where

    firms with a positive financial deficit (a function of dividend payments, net capital

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    28/121

      20

    expenditure, net changes of working capital and operating cash flows after interest

    and taxes) are more likely to issue debt.

    The pecking order is found to be much more binding force for small firms and non-

    dividend paying firms, supporting the hypothesis that small firms are more likely to

    follow the pecking order because of the difficulty in accessing external financing

    sources (Byoun and Rhim 2003).

    Tests of the pecking order theory have not been able to show that it is of first-order

    importance in determining a firm's capital structure. However, several authors have

    found that there are instances where it is a good approximation of reality. Fama and

    French (2002) found that some features of the data were better explained by the

    Pecking Order than by the Trade-Off Theory. Frank and Goyal (2000) showed, among

    other things, that Pecking Order theory fails where it should hold, namely for small

    firms where information asymmetry is presumably an important problem.

    2.4.2.2 

    Signaling model

    The seminal contribution in this area is that of Ross (1977). In Ross' model, managers

    know the true distribution of firm returns, but investors do not. The main empirical

    result was that firm value (or profitability) and the debt-equity ratios are positively

    related. Managers benefit if the firm's securities are more highly valued by the market

     but are penalized if the firm goes bankrupt. Investors take larger debt levels as a

    signal of higher quality. Since lower quality firms have higher marginal expected

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    29/121

      21

     bankruptcy costs for any debt level, managers of low quality firms do not imitate

    higher quality firms by issuing more debt.

    Heinkel (1982) considered a model on return distribution is assumed to be such that

    "higher" quality firms have higher overall value but lower quality bonds (lower

    market value for given face value), hence higher equity value and therefore high value

    firms issue more debt. Since higher quality firms have higher total value, the result

    that they issue more debt is consistent with Ross (1977) result. Another model that

    uses debt as a signal is that of Poitevin (1989) which involves potential competition

     between an incumbent firm and an entrant. The benefit of debt is that the financial

    market places a higher value on the debt financed firm since it believes such a firm to

     be low cost. The main result is that issuance of debt is good news to the financial

    market.

    Several studies exploit managerial risk aversion to obtain a signaling equilibrium in

    which capital structure is determined. The basic idea is that increases in firm leverage

    allow managers to retain a larger fraction of the (risky) equity. The larger equity share

    reduces managerial welfare due to risk aversion, but the decrease is smaller for

    managers of higher quality projects. Thus managers of higher quality firms can signal

    this fact by having more debt in equilibrium (Leland and Pyle, 1977; Blazenko, 1987).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    30/121

      22

    2.4.3  Agency Costs

    Corporate managers are the agents of shareholders, a relationship form with

    conflicting interests. The separation of management and ownership in a firm causes

    the agency problems. Because management and shareholders each attempt to act in

    their own self- interests, managers may make decisions that are not in line with the

    goal of maximization of shareholders' wealth.

    Agency theory, the analysis of such conflicts, is now a major part of the finance

    literature. The payout of cash to shareholders creates major conflicts that have

    received little attention. Payouts to shareholders reduce the resources under

    managers’ control, thereby reducing managers’ power, and making it more likely they

    will incur the monitoring of the capital markets which occurs when the firm must

    obtain new capital (Easterbrook, 1984; Rozeff, 1982). Financing projects internally

    avoids this monitoring and the possibility the funds will be unavailable or available

    only at high explicit prices.

    Managers have incentives to cause their firms to grow beyond the optimal size.

    Growth increases managers’ power by increasing the resources under their control. It

    is also associated with increases in managers’ compensation, because changes in

    compensation are positively related to the growth in sales (Murphy, 1985).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    31/121

      23

    There are three types of agency costs which can help explain the relevance of capital

    structure as discussed by Smith and Warner (1979):

    2.3.3.1 

    Asset substitution effect

    As Debt to Equity increases, management has an increased incentive to undertake

    risky (even negative Net Present Value, NPV) projects. This is because if the project

    is successful, share holders will receive all the upside, whereas if it is unsuccessful,

    then debt holders will receive all the downside. If the projects are undertaken, there is

    a chance of firm value decreasing and a wealth transfer from debt holders to share

    holders (Zhang, 2006; Gavish and Kalay, 1983).

    2.3.3.2  Underinvestment problem

    If debt is risky (e.g. in a growth company), the gain from the project will accrue to

    debt holders rather than shareholders. Thus, management has an incentive to reject

     positive NPV projects, even though they have the potential to increase firm value

    (Hirth and Uhrig-Homburg, 2007).

    2.3.3.3 

    Free cash flow

    Unless free cash flow is given back to investors, management has an incentive to

    destroy firm value through empire building and perks (Jensen, 1986).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    32/121

      24

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that these relationships between the agency costs

    of debt and the amount of the debt may result in an optima1 capital structure. This

    optimal capital structure can be achieved in two distinct ways. First, agency costs of

    debt may offset the tax advantage of debt financing. There is a trade-off between the

    tax  benefits and agency costs since both the tax benefits and agency costs of debt are

     positively related to the amount of the debt employed. Secondly, an optimum

     proportion of outside debt and equity may be chosen in order to minimize total agency

    costs. This is the trade-off between agency costs of debt and agency costs of equity,

    even in a world without taxes.

    2.4 

    New development in capital structure

    After reviewing the above major theoretical ideas of capital structure from MM

    Propositions to the three famous alternative theories, Trade-Off, Pecking Order and

    Agency Costs, a brief discussion on the new development in capital structure is

    outlined in subsection below.

    2.4.1  Shocks to the capital structure and adjusting behavior

    Since the existence of firm adjustment behavior to capital structure shocks appears as

    the main feature that allows for testing the trade-off versus other theories (Myers,

    1984), one important way to learn about capital structure issues is to examine firm

     behavior after exogenous shocks. The inherent difficulty is to decide on the

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    33/121

      25

    exogeneity of economic events. One particularly interesting attempt in the literature to

    test for adjustment behavior by Welch (2004) relies on market-value-based leverage

    shocks due to stock price changes. The market-value based capital structure changes

    with the market price of equity, and therefore at almost any given point in time, given

    the volatility of today’s equity markets. Welch (2004) examines, whether firms adjust

    their capital structures after these shocks to maintain some target debt ratio by issuing

    and repurchasing debt and equity. The analysis is based on data of publicly traded U.S.

    corporations from the period 1962 to 2000. The Welch (2004) study exemplifies the

     basic idea of using exogenous shocks to capital structures to test for firm adjustment

     behavior.

    2.4.2 

    Dynamic adjustment to target leverage and adjustment speed

    In the dynamic version of the classic trade-off theory, target leverage can be time-

    varying. If there are deviations from the optimal capital structure, the theory states

    that there will be adjustment toward the “optimal” target. Depending on the costs of

    adjustment, target leverage will be adjusted at a different pace (Frank and Goyal,

    2008; Titman and Tsyplakov, 2007). The major objective of capital structure research

    using dynamic partial adjustment models is then to estimate the speed of adjustment.

    Flannery and Rangan (2006) analyze whether U.S. firms indeed have long-run target

    capital structures and if so, how fast they adjust to this target. In comparison to prior

    studies, they put special emphasis on the econometric methods and the model

    specification, emphasizing the need to take the panel nature of the data into account.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    34/121

      26

    2.4.3  Major real investments

    Another strand of the literature analyzes a fundamentally different shock to capital

    structures of firms, but in a dynamic context as well. The studies by Mayer and

    Sussman (2005) and Elsas et al.  (2007) examine dynamic financing patterns of U.S.

    firms when undertake major real investments. Mayer and Sussman (2005) consider

    equity and debt issues following spikes in firms’ investment expenditures, while Elsas

    et al. (2007) examine jumps (rather than spikes) in capital expenditures. Both studies

     pursue the idea that the exercise of very large real investment options allows to

    observe major financing decisions by firms. Moreover, if the major real investment is

    more driven by the availability of the investment opportunities rather than the

    availability of investment funding, it will constitute an exogenous shock to the sample

    firms’ capital structure.

    Another novelty of the above studies is that they rely on an event driven framework

    that is particularly suited to analyze adjustment behavior. Also, as pointed out by

    Leary and Roberts (2005) and Hovakimian et al. (2004), if adjusting capital structures

    entails some fixed cost, firms should be closest to their desired capital structure after

    major recapitalizations. Mayer and Sussman (2005) show that external funds are used

     before internal funds are exhausted, contradicting a strict pecking order of financing,

    though the observed debt preference is consistent. Elsas et al. (2007) show in addition,

    that even in the event year, the financing of the major investment moves the firm

    strongly towards its target capital structure, in the frequent case, where financing is

     predominantly based on debt financing Elsas et al. (2007) also show that stock-price

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    35/121

      27

    run-ups preceding the major investment strongly increase the likelihood of equity

    issues, consistent with market timing behavior.

    2.4.4 

    Macroeconomic shocks

    One stream of literature is concerned the impact of macroeconomic conditions on

    corporate leverage. Macroeconomic shocks are highly exogenous to the single firm in

    the economy. Within their analysis, Hackbarth et al.  (2006) provide an overview of

    recent theoretical works in this area. In an empirical study, Campello (2003) analyzes

    the influence of exogenous shocks in the product market environment on capital

    structure, using aggregate demand shocks as a proxy. Campello (2003) finds that debt

    financing and relative-to-industry sales growth have a negative relationship in

    industries with low industry leverage during recessions, but not during booms. This

    effect cannot be observed in industries with high industry leverage. In a further

    empirical analysis, Korajczyk and Levy (2003) also examine the impact of

    macroeconomic conditions on leverage, controlling for firm-specific variables. They

    find financially unconstrained firms issue equity pro-cyclically and debt counter-

    cyclically, although the underlying economic rationale remains somewhat unclear.

    2.4.5  Rating

    The study by Kisgen (2006) emphasizes a determinant of capital structure decisions

    that has received only little attention before – the rating of companies by external

    rating agencies like Moody’s or S&P. Kisgen (2006) tries to analyze how the

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    36/121

      28

    financing behavior of firms is affected if firms are near credit rating upgrades or

    downgrades. The basic idea is that under both the trade-off and the pecking order

    theory the capital structure depends on the (marginal) costs of debt and equity. Since

    rating changes might affect the costs of capital, potential rating changes through

    financing decisions can alter the target debt level or the marginal benefit of debt over

    equity, rendering the corporate rating a potentially important determinant. Arguably,

    this effect will increase when a firm is closer to a rating change. Correspondingly,

    Kisgen (2006) analyzes firm financing decisions, when firms are close to rating

    changes and finds that these firms issue significantly less debt than other comparable

    firms. This finding is robust even if one controls for several differing approaches to

    take “standard” capital structure determinants into account

    .

    2.4.6 

    Behavioral corporate finance

    In behavioral corporate finance, the assumption of fully rational investors (fully

    rational behavior means that all agents in the market have rational expectations and

    are expected utility maximizers) and managers is abandoned. Beliefs and preferences

    may be non-standard and thus allow for irrational behavior, and theories taking this

    into account might lead to new determinants that help improving the understanding of

    capital structure determinants (Barberis and Thaler, 2003; Baker et al., 2007). In the

     behavioral corporate finance literature, two salient approaches have emerged (Neus

    and Walter, 2008). In the irrational investors approach, rational managers are facing

    irrational investors. The associated literature basically deals with inefficient markets

    and rational managers exploiting mispricing, such as the market timing story of Baker

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    37/121

      29

    and Wurgler (2002). In the irrational managers’ approach, it is assumed that not fully

    rational managers are operating in efficient markets, i.e. facing rational investors. 

    Most of the literature in the irrational managers’ approach focuses on deviations from

    rational expectations. There is some evidence from social psychology that individuals

    and especially managers have biased beliefs. Some possible distortions in managerial

     beliefs emphasized in the behavioral corporate finance literature are optimism and

    overconfidence (Barberis and Thaler, 2003).

    Ben-David et al.  (2007) analyze whether CFOs are overconfident and whether this

    has an impact on corporate policies, including capital structure issues. The authors

    measure managerial overconfidence based upon stock market predictions made by

    CFOs. They use a survey of S&P 500 return forecasts of CFOs between 2001 and

    2007. They derive several hypotheses on corporate policies that the financing-related

    hypotheses state that overconfident managers perceive their firms’ equity to be

    undervalued by the market, that leverage increases with managerial overconfidence,

    and that overconfident managers repurchase shares more often. They find that CFOs

    are overconfident, i.e. they underestimate the variance of market returns, because

    realized market returns are within the estimated 80 percent confidence intervals only

    38 percent of the time.

    Malmendier et al.  (2007) test capital structure-related hypotheses using two

    alternative measures of managerial irrationality. The first hypothesis by Malmendier

    et al.  (2007) is that overconfident managers prefer debt to equity conditional upon

    using external financing, because managers perceive the price of newly issued equity

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    38/121

      30

    as too low in their model. Their second hypothesis is that managers prefer internal to

    external financing unconditionally, which might result in using debt too

    conservatively, thus not exploiting the tax benefits optimally. Testing the first

    hypothesis, the evidence implies that overconfident CEOs are less likely to issue

    equity in comparison to their peers, which supports pecking order financing due to

    overconfidence. Malmendier et al. (2007) also find support for their second

    hypothesis that overconfident CEOs rely more heavily on internal financing.

    Furthermore, they find that the longer a firm is managed by overconfident managers,

    the higher is the firm's leverage in the long term.

    2.5 

    Related literature on the international capital structure

    This section will discuss in summary on the most recent literatures on capital structure

    from the international perspective.

    2.5.1 

    Capital structure around the world: The roles of firm- and country-

    specific determinants by De Jong et al. (2008).

    The study analyzes the importance of firm-specific and country-specific factors in the

    leverage choice of firms from forty two countries around the world for the period

    from 1997 to 2001. Their analysis yields two new results. First, they find that firm-

    specific determinants of leverage differ across countries, while prior studies implicitly

    assume equal impact of these determinants. Second, although they concur with the

    conventional direct impact of country-specific factors on the capital structure of firms,

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    39/121

      31

    they show that there is an indirect impact because country-specific factors also

    influence the roles of firm-specific determinants of leverage.

    The standard firm-specific determinants of leverage like firm size (natural logarithm

    of total sales), asset tangibility (net fixed assets over book value of total assets),

     profitability (operating income over book value of total assets), firm risk (standard

    deviation of operating income over book value of total assets) and growth

    opportunities (market value of total assets over book value of total assets) are chosen.

    Besides that, large number of country-specific variables in their analysis, including

    legal enforcement, shareholder/creditor right protection, market/bank-based financial

    system, stock/bond market development and growth rate in a country’s gross domestic

     product (GDP). One leverage ratio is used as proxy to capital structure: book value of

    long-term debt over market value of total assets calculated as book value of total

    assets minus book value of equity plus market value of equity. Two ordinary least

    squares (OLS) regression analysis techniques are used in this study, i.e. simple pooled

    OLS and weighted least squares regression.

    2.5.2  The determinants of capital structure: evidence from the Asia Pacific

    region by Deesomsak et al. (2004).

    The paper contributes to the capital structure literature by investigating the

    determinants of capital structure of firms operating in the Asia Pacific region, in four

    countries with different legal, financial and institutional environments, namely

    Thailand, Malaysia, Singapore and Australia. The results suggest that the capital

    structure decision of firms is influenced by the environment in which they operate, as

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    40/121

      32

    well as firm-specific factors identified in the extant literature. The financial crisis of

    1997 is also found to have had a significant but diverse impact on firm’s capital

    structure decision across the region.

    The leverage ratio used in this study is debt to capital ratio as calculated by total debts

    over total capital (total debts plus market value of equity plus book value of

     preference shares). The determinants are tangibility (total fixed assets over total

    assets), profitability (EBITDA over total assets), firm size (natural log of assets),

    growth opportunities (book value of total assets less the book value of equity plus the

    market value of equity divided by the book value of total assets), non-debt tax shield

    (depreciation over total assets), liquidity (ratio of current assets to current liabilities),

    earnings volatility (absolute difference between the annual percentage change in

    earnings before interest and taxes), and share price performance (the first difference

    of the logs of annual share prices, matched to the month of firms’ fiscal year-end).

    Seven country-specific variables, namely the degree of stock market’s activity, the

    level of interest rates, the legal protection of creditor’s rights, ownership

    concentration, and three country dummies are used. The fixed effect panel and

     pooled OLS procedures were used to analyze the relationships with leverage.

    2.5.3  Determinants of Capital Structure: Evidence from the G-7 Countries by

    Aggarwal and Jamdee (2003).

    This study builds on the seminal work of Rajan and Zingales (1995) on the

    determinants of capital structure in an international setting. Using the same database

    with more recent data, an expanded set of leverage determinants, and improved

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    41/121

      33

    methodology (panel analysis allowing for time-series and cross-sectional analysis),

    this study re-examines both country- and firm-level determinants of capital structure

    choices across the G7 countries (US, Japan, UK, Germany, France, Italy, Canada).

    First, the overall average leverage in 2001 is lower than in 1991. Second, the

    determinants of capital structure traditionally found useful in the U.S. lose some of

    their explanatory power overseas. Third, book debt ratios seem on average to depend

     positively on tangibility of assets, company size, R&D expenses, and protection of

    control rights and negatively on the market to book ratio, profitability, bankruptcy

     probability, and market access. These findings should be of much interest to

    managers, investors, and policy makers.

    Two measures of leverage based on the adjusted debt to capitalization ratio are used

    as the dependent variables, i.e., book and market leverages, which are the ratios of

    adjusted debt to adjusted debt plus book or market value. For book leverage equity is

    measured at book value and for market leverage it is measured at market value.

    This paper examines the time series-cross-sectional regression of debt to book and

    debt to market equity against fixed assets (Tangibility), investment opportunities

    (Market-to-book ratio), firm size (Log of Sales), Profitability (ROA), the probability

    of bankruptcy (Z-Score), uniqueness of product (R&D), equity and/or bond market

    accessibility (Market Accessibility), measures of investor protection (Legal origin,

    Anti-director), and measures of controlling shareholder rights (Cash-flow rights,

    Control rights).

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    42/121

      34

    2.5.4  Capital structure in developing countries by Booth et al. (2001).

    The study analyzes capital structure choices in ten developing countries: India,

    Pakistan, Thailand, Malaysia, Turkey, Zimbabwe, Mexico, Brazil, Jordan, and Korea;

    for the largest companies in each country from 1980 to 1990. As for the debt ratio,

    three ratios are used:

    i.  Total debt ratio = Total liabilities / (Total liabilities + Net worth)

    ii.  Long-term book-debt ratio = (Total liabilities – Current liabilities) / (Totalliabilities - Current liabilities + Net worth)

    iii.  Long-term market-debt ratio = (Total liabilities – Current liabilities) / (Totalliabilities – Current liabilities + Equity marketvalue)

    The macroeconomic variables used are: stock market value/GDP, liquid

    liabilities/GDP, real GDP growth rate, inflation rate and Miller tax term. As for the

    firm-specific variables are as follow: tax rate (average tax rate), business risk

    (standard deviation of ROA), asset tangibility (total assets less current asset divided

     by total assets), size (natural logarithm of sales), return on assets (earnings before tax

    divided by total assets) and market-to-book ratio (market value of equity divided by

     book value of equity). For data analysis, they use the regression analysis with simple

     pooling and fixed-effects model.

    They find that the variables that are relevant for explaining capital structures in the

    United States and European countries are also relevant in developing countries,

    despite the profound differences in institutional factors across these developing

    countries. By knowing these factors helps predict the financial structure of a firm

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    43/121

      35

     better than knowing only its nationality. Their finding is consistent with the Pecking-

    Order Hypothesis and also supports the existence of significant information

    asymmetries.

    2.6  Determinants of capital structure

    A lot of discussion whether or not an optimal capital structure even exists is raised

    among academicians. An important concern for researchers is to investigate the

    factors that influence the capital structure position of a firm. If analysts have the

    ability to find the major determinants of capital structure, managers can make a sound

    decision about the  capital structure of the firm with  the information of those

    determinants (Prasad et al. 1997).

    In most previous studies, a firm’s capital structure was usually represented by

    financial leverage. According to Rajan and Zingales (1995), there is no clear-cut

    definition of leverage in the academic literature and the specific choice depends on

    the objective of the analysis. For instance, the agency problems associated with debt

    (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Myers 1977) largely relate to how the firm has been

    financed in the past, and thus on the relative claims on firm value held by equity and

    debt - the relevant measure is probably the stock of debt relative to firm value. Aghion

    and Bolton (1992) have focused on leverage as a means of transferring control when

    the firm is economically distressed, from shareholders to bondholders. Here, the

    important question is whether the firm can meet its fixed payments, and consequently,

    a flow measure like the interest coverage ratio is more relevant.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    44/121

      36

    As for the definition of leverage, the ratio of total liabilities to total assets is the

     broadest one and is used in many empirical studies (Ross et al. 2007). However,

    Rajan and Zingales (1995) point out that this definition is inappropriate for financial

    leverage since total liabilities include items used for transaction purposes (e.g.,

    accounts payable) rather than for financing.

    In this study, two major types of variables are looked into: country-specific and firm-

    specific determinants, in analyzing the impacts on firms’ leverage choice.

    2.6.1  Country-specific determinants

    The following literatures specifically examine only the direct impact of country

    characteristics on leverage. In an analysis of ten developing countries, Booth et al. 

    (2001) find that there are differences in the way leverage is affected by country-

    specific factors such as GDP growth and capital market development. They conclude

    that more research needs to be done to understand the impact of institutional factors

    on firms’ capital structure choices. The importance of country-specific factors in

    determining cross-country capital structure choice of firms is also acknowledged by

    Fan et al.  (2006) who analyze a larger sample of thirty nine countries. They find a

    significant impact of a few additional country-specific factors such as the degree of

    development in the banking sector, and equity and bond markets.

    In another study of thirty OECD countries, Song and Philippatos (2004) report that

    most cross-sectional variation in international capital structure is caused by the

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    45/121

      37

    heterogeneity of firm-specific, industry-specific, and country-specific determinants.

    However, they do not find evidence to support the importance of cross-country legal

    institutional differences in affecting corporate leverage. Giannetti (2003) argues that

    the failure to find a significant impact of country-specific variables may be due to the

     bias induced in many studies by including only large listed companies. She analyzes

    a large sample of unlisted firms from eight European countries and finds a significant

    influence on the leverage of individual firms of a few institutional variables such as

    creditor protection, stock market development and legal enforcement. Similarly, Hall

    et al. (2004) analyze a large sample of unlisted firms from eight European countries.

    They observe cross-country variation in the determinants of capital structure and

    suggest that this variation could be due to different country-specific variables.

    2.6.1.1 Size of the Banking Industry and Stock Market

    The difference in the development of banks versus financial markets has long been

     perceived as a possible determinant of capital structure (Mayer, 1990; and Rajan and

    Zingales, 1995). This indicator of banking or market development may cause

    differences in the accessibility to external financing by firms in that the monitoring

    activities and controls of firms by financial institutions are more available in bank-

    oriented countries where the weight of the banking sector is heavier than that in the

    market-oriented countries. This implies that as equity markets become more

    developed, they become a viable option for corporate financing and firms make less

    use of debt financing. Similarly, countries with a relatively large banking sector are

    more likely to be associated with higher private sector debt ratios.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    46/121

      38

    The two indicators are credible measures of the overall ability of the private sector to

    access capital. Previous studies appear to agree on the negative relation between the

    size of stock market and leverage level (Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic, 1998 and

    1999; Booth, et al. (2001); and Giannetti, 2003). In the article by Demirguc-Kunt,

    and Maksimovic (1999), they reported a positive sign for the relation between the

     banking sector/GDP and debt to asset ratios (long term debt and short term debt)

    when leverages were regressed on the banking sector/GDP variable alone. However,

    negative signs are generated once other institutional variables are added in their

    models. 

    2.6.1.2 

    Gross Domestic Product Growth Rate

    The growth rate of GDP is an important macroeconomic variable. If investment

    opportunities in an economy are correlated, there should be a relationship between the

    growth rate of individual firms and the growth rate of the economy. Thus, the

    aggregate growth rate may serve as a control variable in cross-country comparisons of

    firm financing choices. As in the case of the variable of the size of the banking sector,

    the relation between GDP growth rate and leverage ratios does not seem clear.

    Interestingly, contrary to Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic (1998), La Porta et al.,

    (1997) argue that although GDP growth rate are positively related to indebtedness of a

    country, the statistical significances of these results do not carry over once the legal

    system is accounted for.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    47/121

      39

    Since economy-wide growth opportunities (GDP growth rate) are closely correlated

    with firms’ growth opportunities, firms with large growth opportunities tend to use

    less debt in optimality as argue by Myers’ hypothesis (1977). An alternative

    explanation is that mature firms with large economy-wide opportunities may not

    require large amounts of external funds, and thus turn out to have lower leverage

    levels. This is consistent with the pecking order theory propagated by Myers (1984).

    In the contrast, Booth et al. (2001) find that in developing countries, higher economic

    growth tends to cause the increase of total book value of debt and long-term book

    value of debt ratios whereas higher inflation causes them to decrease.

    2.6.1.3 Inflation

    Another important factor to be considered is the effect of inflation on the capital

    structure because debt contracts are generally nominal contracts and high inflation is

    likely to discourage lenders from providing long-term debt (Fan et al., 2006).

    DeAngelo and Masulis (1980) argue that inflation leads to more debt since inflation

    lowers the real cost of debt, the demand for corporate bonds increases during

    inflationary periods. On the other hand, if corporate bonds’ return becomes higher

    relative to stocks’ return as inflation decreases, the aggregate demand of corporate

     bonds increases.

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    48/121

      40

    2.6.2 Firm-specific determinants

    A large number of studies on capital structure have concentrated on figuring out the

    determinants affecting the optimality of capital structure and providing theoretical

    explanations of the relationships between firm characteristics and capital structure

    (Titman and Wessel, 1988; Harris and Rajiv, 1991; Welch, 2002; Frank and Goyal,

    2008). Theories developed to explain the optimality of capital structure have been

    mainly driven on the basis of bankruptcy costs, agency costs, asymmetric information

    as well as debt tax shield effects (Ross, 1977; Myers and Majluf, 1984; Graham,

    2000). If the empirical implications of firm-specific determinants of capital structures

    differ across countries, they should result in different features of international capital

    structure (Fan et al., 2006). Three possibilities are explained as the reasons for the

    variations of international capital structure.

    First, the theories underlying capital structure could be applicable only to some

    countries. For example, agency theory predicts that leverage increases with a decrease

    in profitability (negative relationship) (e.g., Kester, 1986; Friend and Hasbrouck,

    1988; Titman and Wessels, 1988), whereas asymmetric information theory posits the

    reverse relationship (e.g., Heinkel, 1982; Blazenko, 1987; Poitevin, 1989). Therefore,

    the effects of firm-specific determinants of capital structure could be different across

    countries, and therefore cause variations in international capital structures.

    Second, the variations in international capital structure could be caused by differences

    in the levels of the determinants of capital structure. Even though the effects of the

    determinants on capital structure work more or less in similar ways across countries,

    the observed capital structures would differ across countries if the magnitudes of the

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    49/121

      41

    determinants differ from country to country. For instance, if the average size of firms

    in a country is small relative to another country, the mean leverage of firms may differ

    across countries (De Jong et al., 2008).

    Third, even if the heterogeneities at the level of firm-specific determinants are

    controlled for, the cross-country variations in international capital structure could

    survive only if the sensitivities of leverage to the changes in the determinants differ

    across countries. In fact, this possibility appears to be closely related to institutional

    determinants, especially in legal systems (La Porta et al.,  1997). For example, if

    agency problem, as mentioned above, is not serious in civil-law countries, where

    ownership by large shareholders is more common, this legal environment may affect

    the sensitivities of leverage to changes in several firm-specific determinants, and

    thereby cause variation in international capital structure. In other words, it should be

    noted that firm characteristics could be influenced by legal environments; therefore,

    the extent to which firm characteristics affect capital structure choice could vary with

    legal systems (Gonzales, 2002).

    2.6.2.1 Profitability

    Corporate performance has also been identified as a potential determinant of capital

    structure. The tax trade-off models predict that profitable companies will employ

    more debt since they are more likely to have a high tax burden and low bankruptcy

    risk. On the other hand, the pecking order theory of finance proposed by Myers (1984)

     prescribes a negative relationship between debt and profitability on the basis that

    successful companies do not need to depend so much on external funding. They can,

  • 8/17/2019 Final Draft - Capital Structure in ASEAN

    50/121

      42

    instead, rely on their internal reserves accumulated from past profits. The validity of

    the two opposing hypotheses is, thus, another issue that needs to be resolved

    empirically.

    Profitability is measured by normalizing the firm's earnings before interest and taxes

    (EBIT) with total assets. Since retained earnings of companies are expected to be

    highly correlated with their past profits, the preceding year's EBIT to measure

     profitability is chosen. In this way, the proxy also enables the testing of pecking order

    hypothesis.

    2.6.2.2 

    Growth opportunities

    Higher growth opportunities provide incentives to invest sub-optimally, or to accept

    risky projects th