37
Journal of Environmental and Public Health Law Page | 159 ISSN 2164-7976 (online) DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission Congestion Alexander K. Obrecht * ABSTRACT Increasing federal involvement in the wholesale electricity market, and the ever-important emphasis on renewable energy resources, exposed the inadequacies of the existing transmission infrastructure. The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005) attempted to address the transmission problems but failed to adequately consolidate federal power over transmission siting. The resulting atmosphere presents an unsustainable dichotomy in which federal involvement encourages generation dependent upon transmission access, while state control over transmission siting impedes the necessary investment and capital improvement. Despite the efforts of EPAct 2005, a coherent and effective national energy policy remains unobtainable without the ability to incentivize generation and guarantee access to transmission by facilitating its development across state lines. This note proceeds in two sections. First, the background section provides a brief history of federally mandated deregulation in the wholesale electricity market. A brief summary of EPAct 2005 then explains Congress's attempt to encourage transmission investment by allowing limited federal jurisdiction over the siting process. Second, the note analyzes the current pressures exerted on the transmission grid by renewable energy and inadequate state siting processes. The analysis then addresses the judicial interpretations of EPAct 2005 and how the United States Courts of Appeals * Candidate for J.D., University of Wyoming, 2013. Editor-in-Chief, Wyoming Law Review, 2012–13. I would like to thank Alexandra Malatesta and the fantastic Editorial Board and Staff at the Pittsburgh Journal for Environmental and Public Health Law for their help throughout the publication process, Professor Sam Kalen for his guidance, and Rachel Ryckman for her patience.

Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 159

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission Congestion

Alexander K. Obrecht*

ABSTRACT

Increasing federal involvement in the wholesale electricity market, and the ever-important emphasis on renewable energy resources, exposed the inadequacies of the existing transmission infrastructure. The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005) attempted to address the transmission problems but failed to adequately consolidate federal power over transmission siting. The resulting atmosphere presents an unsustainable dichotomy in which federal involvement encourages generation dependent upon transmission access, while state control over transmission siting impedes the necessary investment and capital improvement. Despite the efforts of EPAct 2005, a coherent and effective national energy policy remains unobtainable without the ability to incentivize generation and guarantee access to transmission by facilitating its development across state lines.

This note proceeds in two sections. First, the background section provides a brief history of federally mandated deregulation in the wholesale electricity market. A brief summary of EPAct 2005 then explains Congress's attempt to encourage transmission investment by allowing limited federal jurisdiction over the siting process. Second, the note analyzes the current pressures exerted on the transmission grid by renewable energy and inadequate state siting processes. The analysis then addresses the judicial interpretations of EPAct 2005 and how the United States Courts of Appeals

* Candidate for J.D., University of Wyoming, 2013. Editor-in-Chief, Wyoming Law Review, 2012–13. I would like to thank Alexandra Malatesta and the fantastic Editorial Board and Staff at the Pittsburgh Journal for Environmental and Public Health Law for their help throughout the publication process, Professor Sam Kalen for his guidance, and Rachel Ryckman for her patience.

Page 2: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 160

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

delayed federal jurisdiction over transmission siting for the foreseeable future.

Page 3: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 161

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

I. INTRODUCTION

Historically, the electricity market consisted of vertically integrated monopolistic utilities regulated at the state level.1 The Federal Government took the first steps in wresting control of the electricity market from the states with the deregulation of the wholesale electricity market. 2 Deregulation resulted in clashes between monopolistic utilities restricting access to existing transmission networks and new non-utility wholesale generators seeking access to transmission infrastructure.3 Congress attempted to alleviate the clash by passing legislation mandating equal access to transmission capacity.4 The new transmission capacity demands of the deregulated wholesale electricity market exposed the inadequacies and dilapidated condition of the existing transmission infrastructure.5 An increasing emphasis on renewable energy resources further strains transmission due to the long distances electricity must travel from generation to consumption.6

1 See infra notes 12–19 and accompanying text (discussing the early development of the electricity industry).

2 See infra notes 31–50 and accompanying text (describing federal intervention in the wholesale electricity markets).

3 See infra notes 38–54 and accompanying text (outlining federal attempts to mandate open access to transmission).

4 See infra notes 38–54 and accompanying text (discussing federal statutes and policies aimed at reducing discrimination in transmission access to merchant power producers).

5 See infra notes 73–101 and accompanying text (describing pressures on the transmission infrastructure created by an increase in merchant power generator and renewable energy resources).

6 See infra notes 76–101 and accompanying text (discussing the unique pressures of renewable energy resources on the existing transmission infrastructure).

Page 4: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 162

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

Federal deregulation of the wholesale electricity market and renewable energy development create the need for investment in a nationally focused transmission infrastructure. Unfortunately, localities and states retain primary control over permitting transmission lines.7 The state siting process impedes potential investment by allowing parochial and protectionist policies to pander to local concerns, effectively trumping larger regional and national benefits of new transmission lines. 8 The dichotomy between federal deregulation of the wholesale electricity market and state control of transmission siting starved the transmission infrastructure of the necessary investment. Accordingly, without federal control of both the wholesale market and transmission siting the infrastructure languished under increasing congestion, reliability, and security strains.

Congress passed the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005), in part, to alleviate the increasing congestion in existing infrastructure by creating potential federal authority over transmission line siting.9 However, the attempt failed to adequately address the substantial barriers state control creates.10 Furthermore, judicial interpretations limit EPAct 2005's effectiveness going forward.11 Although EPAct 2005 took the correct step to increase federal control over the siting process, the program proved woefully inadequate to

7 See infra notes 102–54 and accompanying text (detailing the problems with traditional state siting processes for transmission lines).

8 See infra notes 109–51 and accompanying text (analyzing the inadequacies with the state system for transmission line siting and the possibility for abuse by state authorities).

9 See infra notes 55–72 and accompanying text (outlining the provisions of EPAct 2005).

10 See infra notes 102–54 and accompanying text (detailing the problems with traditional state siting processes for transmission lines).

11 See infra notes 160–214 and accompanying text (following the judicial interpretations of EPAct 2005 and how the courts have limited any potential federal authority).

Page 5: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 163

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

consolidate federal power to modernize the United States' transmission grid. The increasingly regional and national electricity marketplace requires federal jurisdiction over both wholesale generation and sales and the necessary means to modernize the American transmission infrastructure.

This note proceeds in two sections. First, the background section provides a brief history of federally mandated deregulation in the wholesale electricity market. A summary of EPAct 2005 explains Congress's attempt to encourage transmission investment by allowing limited federal jurisdiction over the siting process. Second, the note analyzes the current pressures exerted on the transmission grid by renewable energy and inadequate state siting processes. The analysis also addresses the judicial interpretations of EPAct 2005 and how the United States Courts of Appeals delayed federal jurisdiction over transmission siting for the foreseeable future.

II. BACKGROUND

A. THE ADVENT OF FEDERAL REGULATION IN THE

ELECTRICITY SECTOR

Throughout the twentieth century, the American electric grid developed around privately-owned and vertically integrated utilities.12 Locally based utilities faced large upfront capital costs to construct generation and transmission infrastructure, but after completion, the facilities' operated at low cost.13 The inhibitive capital costs made the utility business risky from the outset, but provided the potential for rewarding cash flow after the

12 Jim Rossi, The Trojan Horse of Electric Power Transmission Line Siting Authority, 39 ENVTL. L. 1015, 1018 (2009).

13 THE ELEC. ENERGY MKT. COMPETITION TASK FORCE, REPORT TO

CONGRESS ON COMPETITION IN WHOLESALE AND RETAIL MARKETS FOR

ELECTRIC ENERGY, at 17 (2007), available at http://www.ferc.gov/legal/fed-sta/ene-pol-act/epact-final-rpt.pdf [hereinafter FERC Competition Study].

Page 6: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 164

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

infrastructure came online.14 Due to the upfront risks, investors sought assurances the utility would operate long enough to repay the debt.15 The resulting market structure closely resembled a regulated monopoly, in which the state granted exclusive generation and transmission rights and assurances of an adequate return on investment.16 In return for the exclusive rights, the state imposed a duty to serve the customers within the utility's territory.17 The model incentivized the utility to expand its transmission network to market its own electricity generation, rather than to allow other producers access to the grid.18 The monopolistic model provided ninety-five percent of America's power needs until problems arose in the 1970s.19

Changes during the 1970s and 80s created a veritable "perfect storm" of economic, political and societal pressure on Congress and individual states to question the regulated utility model.20 First, American electricity demand in-creased 7.5% per year through the end of the 1960s, but costly generation improvements gradually began to erode the economies of scale enjoyed throughout the early twentieth century.21 The periods of rising inflation and interest rates increased the cost of capital to add generation capacity.22 The larger generation facilities no longer produced significant decreases in the

14 See id. 15 Id. 16 See id. 17 Id. at 18; see also Transmission Access Policy Study Group v.

F.E.R.C., 225 F.3d 667, 681 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (addressing the historical nature of public utilities and the pressure from current market trends), aff’d sub nom. New York v. F.E.R.C., 535 U.S. 1 (2002).

18 Rossi, supra note 12, at 1018. 19 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 10. 20 Id. at 19–23. 21 See id. at 19. 22 Id.

Page 7: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 165

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

marginal cost of electricity.23 Opponents of the regulated utility model criticized the ability of monopolistic utilities to pass inefficient costs to the consumer.24 Second, the reliability of the traditional generation model faced serious questions. The Arab Oil Embargo inflated fossil fuel prices, which squeezed generation margins and raised questions about the availability of inputs.25 The 1965 Northeast blackout highlighted the inadequacies of bulk power agreements between utilities.26 New environmental regulation threat-ened traditional methods of generation.27 The Three Mile Island incident in 1979 created significant regulation of the nuclear sector.28 Finally, social sentiment favored a decrease in foreign energy reliance and an increase in environmental awareness.29 This "perfect storm," culminated in congressional attempts to address the underlying issues.

Congress reacted to the turmoil of the 1970s and 1980s by increasing federal involvement in the energy sector.30 The increased involvement led to numerous pieces of legislation addressing energy inputs, wholesale electricity generation and industry competition. However, the electricity market did not morph dramatically until after the Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act of

23 Id. at 19–20. 24 Id. at 19. 25 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 20. 26 Id. 27 See id. at 19. 28 Id. at 20. 29 See id. 30 Id.; see Sam Kalen, Replacing a National Energy Policy with a

National Resource Policy, 19 NAT. RESOURCES & ENV’T No. 3, at 12–13 (Winter 2005) (discussing the federal government's attempts to coordinate a national energy policy, which seemingly caught traction in the 1970s).

Page 8: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 166

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

1978 (PURPA).31 PURPA attempted to increase energy conservation and alternative energy sources, while simultaneously decreasing the demand for foreign energy.32 PURPA required regulated utilities to interconnect with, and potentially purchase power from, nontraditional generation facilities classified as qualifying facilities (QFs).33 This provision unintentionally opened the door for non-utility owned generators to enter the wholesale electricity market.34 Applications for QF status with the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) increased from just twenty-nine in 1980, representing 704MW, to 979 in 1986, representing roughly 18,000MW, and the trend only increased through 1990.35 By 1991, non-utilities owned six percent of the electricity generation capacity in the United States.36 PURPA marked the beginning of federal involvement in the electricity market challenging the traditional state regulated monopoly model.

Congress took PURPA's authorization of nontraditional generation facilities further in passing the Energy Policy Act of 1992 (EPAct 1992).37 EPAct 1992 established a new category of generation facilities completely exempt from the regulated monopoly model.38 Entities owning generation facilities selling power exclusively in the wholesale market qualified for classification as an exempt wholesale generator (EWG).39 The creation of

31 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 20; Public Utilities Regulatory Policies Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-617, 92 Stat. 3117 (1978).

32 See FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 20–21. 33 Id. at 20. 34 Id. at 21. 35 Id. 36 Id. at 22. 37 Energy Policy Act of 1992, Pub. L. No. 102-486, §§ 721–26, 106 Stat.

2776 (1992) [hereinafter EPAct 1992]. 38 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 23–24. 39 Id. at 23.

Page 9: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 167

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

EWGs significantly reduced barriers to non-utilities entering the wholesale power market and the advent of non-utilities created a major challenge to the existing transmission system.40 The traditional regulated utilities controlled access to the transmission infrastructure, effectively blocking the growth of EWGs.41 EPAct 1992 established FERC's power to order transmitting utilities to carry non-utilities' wholesale power sales, subject to certain conditions.42 FERC attempted to implement the expanded federal power over wholesale transmission, but faced serious procedural constraints to the program's effectiveness.43

Unsatisfied with the effectiveness of EPAct 1992, FERC issued Order No. 888 to prevent regulated utilities from abusing their transmission facility monopoly.44 FERC cited discrimination and anti-competitive practices from

40 Id. at 23–24; see Debbie Swanstrom & Meredith M. Jolivert, DOE Transmission Corridor Designations & FERC Backstop Siting Authority: Has the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Succeeded in Stimulating the Development of New Transmission Facilities?, 30 ENERGY L.J. 415, 422 (2009) (discussing the regulatory changes in 1992 allowing FERC to control some transmission decisions on regulated utilities’ infrastructure).

41 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 23. 42 Id. at 24; EPAct 1992, supra note 37, at §§ 721–26. EPAct 1992

sought to ensure that FERC would only issue an order to accommodate wholesale transactions if the utility could do so under the conditions that the “rates, charges, terms, and conditions” are economically feasible, not inconsistent with retail marketing areas, and not a “sham.” EPAct 1992, supra note 37, at § 722.

43 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 24. In general, the orders were only on a case-by-case application forcing FERC to engage in a cumbersome process without broad application. Id.

44 Id.; see Promoting Wholesale Competition Through Open Access Non-Discriminatory Transmission Services by Public Utilities; Recovery of Stranded Costs by Public Utilities and Transmitting Utilities, 18 C.F.R. §§ 35

Page 10: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 168

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

the regulated monopolies as the most significant barriers to a competitive wholesale electricity market.45 They also initiated further federal intervention to advance the deregulation started under PURPA.46 Order No. 888 required transmission owners transmitting electricity in interstate commerce to file open access transmission tariffs (OATTs) with FERC, thereby forcing public utilities to treat wholesale power generators the same as traditional customers for transmission access.47 FERC's intervention in electricity generation eroded powers to regulate monopolistic utilities that were traditionally delegated to the states, but the ineffectiveness of EPAct 1992, Order No. 888 and changing market conditions necessitated further federal involvement to best serve the ultimate consumers of the electricity.48

Facing continuing complaints of discrimination in transmission access, FERC further attempted to consolidate power over transmission with Order No. 2000.49 Order No. 2000 authorized the creation of regional transmission organizations (RTOs) to eliminate transmission rate differentials between territories, increase regional stability and eradicate any discriminatory practices still employed by regulated public utilities.50 Although a step in the

& 385 (1996), 61 Fed. Reg. 21540–01 (May 10, 1996) [hereinafter Order No. 888].

45 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 24; Order No. 888 at 21540–01.

46 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 2, 20, 24. 47 Id. 48 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 418–20 (addressing the

unprecedented power grab by FERC in Order No. 888). 49 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 30; see Regional

Transmission Organizations, Order No. 2000, 65 Fed. Reg. 810 (Jan. 6, 2000), order on reh’g, Order No. 2000-A, 65 Fed. Reg. 12,088 (Mar. 8, 2000), 18 C.F.R. § 35 (2000), aff’d, Public Utility District No. 1 v. FERC, 272 F.3d 607 (D.C. Cir. 2001) [hereinafter Order No. 2000].

50 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 30.

Page 11: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 169

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

right direction, RTOs are voluntary organizations and do not actually own any transmission facilities.51 Accordingly, RTOs only reach those markets willing to participate. Much of the Southeast, West (excluding California) and Midwest appear hesitant to relinquish local control over the process.52

B. ENERGY POLICY ACT OF 2005

Upset with the continued frustration of investment and improvement of the transmission infrastructure, Congress attempted to further consolidate federal authority through the enactment of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct 2005). Congress passed EPAct 2005 to provide a comprehensive national energy policy emphasizing domestic energy production, conservation and efficiency to enhance energy security and decrease demand for foreign energy.53 To improve efficiency and energy security, EPAct 2005 sought to enhance electricity transmission, especially the deteriorating condition of the transmission infrastructure and the inefficiencies in the current siting process.54 The outdated transmission infrastructure required billions in investment dollars to ensure adequate reliability, security and capacity for the rapidly evolving electricity market.55 Congress found that inefficiencies in the traditional state level siting process often led to delays and outright rejections of vital interstate transmission projects.56 EPAct 2005

51 Id. at 31. 52 Id. at 32. 53 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 1 (2005); see generally Energy Policy Act of

2005, Pub. L. No. 109-58, 119 Stat. 594 (2005) [hereinafter EPAct 2005]. 54 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 5 (2005); H.R. REP. NO. 109-215, at 171

(2005). 55 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 7 (2005); H.R. REP. NO. 109-215, at 171

(2005). 56 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 7 (2005); H.R. REP. NO. 109-215, at 171

(2005).

Page 12: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 170

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

attacked the problem by attempting to increase federal jurisdiction in the transmission siting process.57

Congress recognized the need to assess the capacity, operation and reliability of the current transmission grid, highlighted by the massive blackouts that struck the Northeast and Midwest in 2003.58 EPAct 2005 mandated the Department of Energy (DOE), in consultation with states, to perform electric transmission congestion studies.59 After considering input from the interested parties, DOE may create a national interest electric transmission corridor (NIETC) in any geographic area with transmission capacity constraints or congestion adversely impacting consumers.60 The designation of a NIETC depends on DOE's determination of five factors: 1) the negative economic effects of overpriced power in the corridor; 2) the constraints on growth due to a lack of diversity in electricity supply; 3) it serves the energy independence of the United States; 4) it is in the interest of national energy policy; and, 5) it furthers national defense.61

Once DOE designates a NIETC, the potential exists for increased federal involvement in the transmission line siting process by creating a federal backstop.62 If the state process fails to permit a transmission line project, the developer may petition FERC to permit the project in certain limited

57 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 48 (2005); see Michael Diamond, Note, “Energized” Negotiations: Mediating Disputes Over the Siting of Interstate Electric Transmission Lines, 26 OHIO ST. J. ON DISP. RESOL. 217, 227 (2011) (discussing the increase in potential federal jurisdiction over the siting process after EPAct 2005).

58 H.R. REP. NO. 109-215, pt. 1, at 171 (2005). 59 16 U.S.C. § 824p(a)(1) (2010). 60 Id. at § 824p(a)(2). 61 Id. at § 824p(a)(4). 62 See generally id. at § 824p(b) (listing the requirements for FERC

siting authority); see Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 422.

Page 13: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 171

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

conditions.63 A transmission line developer may petition FERC in five circumstances: 1) the state process lacks the authority to permit the project; 2) the state authority cannot consider the interstate benefits of the project; 3) the developer is a transmitting utility according to federal law, but does not qualify for the same status under state law because the developer does not serve end-use customers in the state; 4) the state authority has withheld approval for more than one year; or, 5) the state has conditioned its approval upon unduly burdensome requirements.64 The FERC permitting process creates a federal backstop to the traditional state transmission line siting process.65 A federal permit authorizes the use of eminent domain on private land to facilitate the construction of the project.66

In sum, EPAct 2005 created a potential, but limited, federal backstop authority to site transmission lines.67 First, the DOE must designate a congested area as a NIETC.68 Second, if the state permitting process fails to approve a transmission project within a NIETC, the developer may petition FERC to permit the project.69 Since the enactment of EPAct 2005, FERC has

63 Id. at § 824p(b)(1). 64 Id. at §§ 824p(b)(1)(A)–(C). The FERC must also find that: 1) the

transmission project will be used in interstate commerce; 2) the proposed project is consistent with the public interest; 3) the project will significantly reduce transmission congestion in interstate commerce and protects or benefits consumers; 4) the construction is consistent with sound energy policy and will enhance energy independence; and, 5) the project will maximize the transmission capabilities of existing towers. Id. at §§ 824p(b)(2)–(6).

65 S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 48 (2005). 66 16 U.S.C. § 824p(e); see also S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 48 (2005). 67 See S. REP. NO. 109-78, at 49; see generally 16 U.S.C. § 824p. 68 Id. at § 824p(a). 69 See generally id. at § 824p(b).

Page 14: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 172

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

received only one siting request, which the company subsequently withdrew.70

III. ANALYSIS

Increasing federal involvement in the wholesale market and the ever-important emphasis on renewable energy resources exposed the inadequacy of the capacity, security and reliability of the existing transmission infrastructure. While EPAct 2005 attempted to address the transmission problems, it failed to adequately consolidate federal jurisdiction over transmission siting. The resulting atmosphere has presented an unsustainable dichotomy in which federal involvement encourages transmission dependent generation, while state control over transmission siting impedes the necessary development. In sum, a coherent and effective national energy policy remains unobtainable without the ability to incentivize generation and guarantee access to transmission by facilitating its development across state lines.

The analysis proceeds by first articulating why the electricity market no longer supports state authority over transmission line siting. In particular, this note highlights renewable energy resources strain the transmission infrastructure more than traditional fossil fuels. Second, the note discusses the inefficiencies inherent to the state siting process and its impediment to the development of new transmission infrastructure. Finally, the analysis explains the judicial limitations placed on EPAct 2005's attempt to expand federal authority over transmission siting.

70 See, e.g., Diamond, supra note 57, at 235 (referencing Southern California Edison’s (SCE) withdrawn application for FERC siting authority). The proposed SCE line only connected two states, but still faced restraints to its completion. See notes 108–30 and accompanying text (discussing the details of the SCE proposal).

Page 15: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 173

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

A. THE TRANSMISSION SECTOR NO LONGER SUPPORTS STATE

AUTHORITY

The 1970s to 2000s were a turbulent time for the electricity sector, with significant changes in the regulatory and economic aspects of the marketplace. The Federal Government consolidated its power in the traditionally state regulated model in an attempt to ensure the functionality of a holistic, nationally focused electricity market.71 Federal involvement in the wholesale power markets increased electricity generation from non-utilities to 28.2% of total generation capacity in 2004, while regulated utilities decreased from a peak of 97% in 1979 to 63.1% in 2004.72 The increase in non-utility wholesale generators dramatically expanded the demand for transmission access.73 The now competitive wholesale market, coupled with new pressures from renewable energy resources, highlights the inadequacies of the existing transmission infrastructure. In order to develop interstate transmission infrastructure, the federal government must consolidate federal regulation, not only over competition, but over transmission siting as well.

1. RENEWABLE ENERGY PRESSURES ON THE CURRENT

TRANSMISSION INFRASTRUCTURE

Although not necessarily new, renewable energy resources sit at the forefront of electricity generation movements.74 Initiatives from the Obama Administration and individual states encourage the development and use of

71 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 419–20 (addressing changes in the electricity sector and the beginnings of FERC’s consolidation of regulatory power).

72 FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 35 (major federal involvement in the electricity sector was implemented through PURPA, EPAct 1992 and Order Nos. 888 and 2000).

73 Id. at 24–31. 74 See Diamond, supra note 57, at 217–18 (acknowledging America's

four decades of struggle for clean, reliable energy).

Page 16: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 174

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

renewable resources to diversify energy dependence and clean energy profiles.75 Unfortunately, two major systematic issues with large-scale renewable generation prevent its effective use in the marketplace.76 First, the geographic locations of the states demanding renewable generation are generally distant from the isolated parts of the nation generating the power.77 Second, due to the distance between supply and demand, the nation requires new interstate transmission infrastructure to adequately handle the increase in production.78 In effect, the renewable energy mandates create demands upon transmission infrastructure, which directly clash with the traditional regulated utility model. Increased federal jurisdiction over transmission siting best facilitates the infrastructure renewable energy development requires.

As of January 2012, thirty states and the District of Columbia had adopted renewable portfolio standards (RPSs) mandating a certain amount of energy generated from renewable resources.79 California sets the trend with an ambitious rule requiring electric utilities to derive thirty-three percent of generation from renewable resources.80 California's population demands an

75 See id. (discussing various initiatives of the Obama Administration); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1017.

76 See Diamond, supra note 57, at 217–18 (highlighting the geographic location of renewable resources generation compared to the location of demand); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1017.

77 See Diamond, supra note 57, at 217–18 (highlighting the geographic location of renewable resources generation compared to the location of demand); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1017.

78 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 421–22 (addressing the need for further investment in the nation’s transmission infrastructure).

79 Id. at 462–63; U.S. ENERGY INFORMATION ADMINISTRATION, MOST

STATES HAVE RENEWABLE PORTFOLIO STANDARDS (Feb. 3, 2012), http:// www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=4850.

80 See generally U.S. ENERGY INFORMATION ADMINISTRATION, MOST

STATES HAVE RENEWABLE PORTFOLIO STANDARDS (Feb. 3, 2012), http://

Page 17: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 175

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

enormous amount of energy, nearly 8.5% of the total consumption in the United States.81 Other large metropolitan areas face similar constraints as renewable energy resources are located in geographically remote and sparsely populated areas.82 Although most transmission of renewable energy must cross state lines, intrastate transmission inefficiencies impede renewable development as well.83 For example, oil tycoon T. Boone Pickens scaled down ambitious plans for the world's largest wind farm in the Texas Panhandle because the existing transmission infrastructure made the sale to Dallas and Houston economically unfeasible.84 The primary consumers of renewable energy are in states and metropolitan markets far from geographically remote generation facilities, without new transmission infrastructure clean energy cannot reach consumers.

In addition to the geographic location of renewable energy, the stationary characteristics of renewable energy resources further complicate the issue.85 Renewable resources, unlike coal and natural gas, depend entirely

www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=4850 (listing the progressive renewable portfolio standards set by California).

81 U.S. ENERGY INFORMATION ADMINISTRATION, CALIFORNIA (Mar. 15, 2012), http://www.eia.gov/state/state-energy-profiles-data.cfm?sid=CA# Consumption.

82 Sandeep Vaheesan, Preempting Parochialism and Protectionism in Power, 49 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 87, 96–98 (2012) (listing various metropolitan areas that face transmission restrictions to renewable energy resources); see also Diamond, supra note 57, at 218 (highlighting the geographic location of renewable resources generation compared to the location of demand); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1017.

83 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 97 (discussing the lack of transmission within Texas).

84 Id. 85 Id.

Page 18: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 176

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

upon the geographic location for their generation capabilities.86 Generators may transport fossil fuels in raw form to power plants close to the load demand; but wind turbines cannot be transported to metro San Francisco or Chicago in mass scale.87 The best prospects for wind energy generally fall in the corridor spanning the Dakotas to North Texas and parts of the Mountain West, with attractive offshore potential off the Atlantic and Pacific Coasts.88 Solar and geothermal potential similarly exists in the Mountain West and Southwest.89 The fundamental characteristics of renewable energy resources create an exigent need for transmission lines to facilitate their development.90 Conservatively, the United States requires hundreds of miles of interstate transmission infrastructure.91

86 Id. 87 Id.; see Rossi, supra note 12, at 1029 (discussing the need for extra

transmission infrastructure for North Dakota wind generation to power Chicago).

88 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 97; U.S. DEPT. OF ENERGY NATIONAL

RENEWABLE ENERGY LABORATORY, WIND RESOURCES AND TRANSMISSION

LINES (Apr. 19, 2007), http://www.nrel.gov/wind/systemsintegration/images/ home_usmap.jpg.

89 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 97; U.S. DEPT. OF ENERGY NATIONAL

RENEWABLE ENERGY LABORATORY, GEOTHERMAL RESOURCE OF THE

UNITED STATES (Oct. 13, 2009), http://www.nrel.gov/gis/images/geothermal_ resource2009-final.jpg; U.S. DEPT. OF ENERGY NATIONAL RENEWABLE

ENERGY LABORATORY, PHOTOVOLTAIC SOLAR RESOURCE OF THE UNITED

STATES (Oct. 20, 2008), http://www.nrel.gov/gis/images/map_pv_national_ lo-res.jpg.

90 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 97 (discussing the pressures on the transmission grid).

91 See id. (declaring that hundreds of miles of interstate transmission lines will need to be constructed to service RPSs).

Page 19: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 177

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

Improving transmission infrastructure requires capital investment.92 Unfortunately, investment decreased from roughly $5 billion per year between 1974 and 1983 (in 2005 dollars), to a low of $2.5 billion from 1993 to 1994.93 Investment ticked up to $5.8 billion in 2005, and estimates project an increase to $8 billion in the coming years.94 Even if the investment projections prove true, these numbers make up a miniscule component of an industry with $800 billion in capital and estimations of a further $200 billion to be raised between 2009 and 2012.95

The current market landscape presents an interesting conundrum. Federal deregulatory efforts spurred the advent of wholesale power markets, which allowed non-utility generators to sell bulk power into a traditionally monopolistic market place regulated by the states.96 The increase in wholesale power necessitated access to existing transmission lines, which FERC addressed by mandating open access.97 Now non-utility generators face incentives to invest in renewable energy resources but lack the necessary

92 See ELECTRICITY ADVISORY COMMITTEE, KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON IN

A NEW WORLD 16 (Jan. 2009), http://energy.gov/sites/prod/files/oeprod/ DocumentsandMedia/adequacy_report_01-09-09.pdf (discussing the lagging investment in the transmission) [hereinafter KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON]; Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 115 (referencing the stagnation in transmission investment).

93 KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON, supra note 92, at 16; see Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 421 (discussing boom and bust in transmission investment).

94 KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON, supra note 92, at 16. 95 Id. 96 See FERC Competition Study, supra note 13, at 23–35 (outlining

federal moves in the electricity markets that have consolidated federal jurisdiction).

97 See id. (discussing EPAct 1992 and Order Nos. 888 and 2000).

Page 20: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 178

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

infrastructure to use the clean energy.98 The state siting process forms the primary barrier forcing capital to remain on the sideline.99 Since state control impedes interstate transmission infrastructure investment and development, increased federal jurisdiction over wholesale markets exposed a major flaw with state control over transmission siting.

2. FUNDAMENTAL PROBLEMS WITH STATE TRANSMISSION

SITING

Congress took a much needed, but wholly inadequate step to consolidate federal power over transmission siting with EPAct 2005.100 The electricity market has morphed into a national patchwork of competitive wholesale generators demanding access to and investment in new transmission lines.101 Investors appear willing to fund new transmission projects, but the state siting process creates arbitrary obstacles to interstate investment.102 Three funda-

98 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 96–98 (listing various metropolitan areas that face transmission restrictions to renewable energy resources); see also Diamond, supra note 57, at 217–18 (highlighting the geographic location of renewable resources generation compared to the location of demand); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1017.

99 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 115 (discussing state barriers to transmission investment); KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON, supra note 92, at 16–17 (listing interstate concerns in the siting process).

100 See generally Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 123–24 (highlighting the inadequacies of EPAct 2005).

101 See generally Drew Thornley, The Federal Government's Authority to Site Interstate Electric Transmission Lines: How the Meaning of “Withheld” is Withholding Clarity for Transmission Development, 6 TEX. J. OIL GAS & ENERGY L. 385, 385 (2010–2011) (discussing the aging network of transmission lines and the inadequacy of patchwork system).

102 KEEPING THE LIGHTS ON, supra note 92, at 16)17 (listing interstate concerns in the siting process); see, e.g., Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 115 (discussing state barriers to transmission investment).

Page 21: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 179

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

mental problems exist with the state siting process for transmission lines. First, most state siting processes include a need determination based on the in-state benefits of a transmission project.103 Unfortunately, the geographic nature of renewable energy resources and power exporting states in general, force transmission lines to cross numerous state lines.104 Second, political pressures force state officials to skew a cost-benefit balancing test in a way that favors their constituents, often ignoring the greater regional and national benefits.105 Finally, the overall state system remains grounded on an outdated regulatory model that frustrates innovative and necessary market participation from key non-utility players.106

State siting processes and eminent domain need determinations rarely allow state officials to consider regional or national benefits to new transmission projects.107 Although some states allow the consideration of out-of-state benefits, it only takes one intrastate focused siting authority to

103 See, e.g., Rossi, supra note 12, at 1019–20 (discussing the basis for state need determinations).

104 See generally Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 96–98 (listing various metropolitan areas that face transmission restrictions to renewable energy resources); see also Diamond, supra note 57, at 218 (highlighting the geographic location of renewable resources generation compared to the location of demand).

105 See generally Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 115–23 (describing the various pressures on state officials that are not balanced against the overall benefit of the transmission project).

106 See Matthew J. Agen, Transmission Tug-of-War, PUB. UTIL. FORT. 46, 50–51 (Nov. 2011) (describing the problems the Maryland Public Service Commission faced in permitting the Potomac-Appalachian Transmission Highline (PATH)).

107 See Ashley C. Brown & Damon Daniels, Vision Without Site; Site Without Vision, 16 ELECTRICITY J. 23, at 26–27 (Oct. 2003) (specifically referencing Mississippi code as forbidding the state PSC from considering out-of-state benefits).

Page 22: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 180

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

impede development.108 The inconsistencies in the individual state siting processes effectively Balkanizes a national transmission program.109 For example, in 2005, Southern California Edison (SCE) began the process of permitting a 225-mile high voltage transmission line from Arizona into California.110 The majority of the transmission line was located on existing rights-of-way in federally approved corridors, but approval from both the California and Arizona Public Service Commissions (PSC) were necessary to move forward with the project.111 California approved the line in 2007, but Arizona denied the permit.112 The lack of in-state benefits proved key to Arizona's denial of the project.113 SCE estimated the project would have resulted in $650 million in costs to California ratepayers, but cumulative savings of $1.1 billion over the life of the line.114 Arizona ratepayers would incur $242 million in costs over the life of the line and an approximate five percent increase in spot prices at the Palo Verde hub.115 Arguably, the five to one ratio of benefits to the region, compared to the local costs to Arizona,

108 Id. at 26–28; see Thornley, supra note 101, at 385. 109 See Brown & Daniels, supra note 107, at 26–28; see Thornley, supra

note 101, at 385 (referencing the patchwork transmission system as an effective Balkanization of the grid).

110 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 450–52 (discussing SCE’s efforts to permit the Devers-Palo Verde 2 line (Devers PV2)); Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 116–17 (referencing the SCE line).

111 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 450–52 (referencing the approvals necessary to permit the project, although SCE claimed the majority of it ran through federal rights-of-way).

112 See Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 451. 113 See S. Cal. Edison Co., 2007 WL 2126365 1–3 (Ariz. Corp. Comm’n

June 6, 2007) (listing the Arizona PSC’s concerns about the economic, reliability and environmental impacts of the new transmission lines).

114 Id. at 2. 115 Id.

Page 23: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 181

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

supports the construction of the power line, but the Arizona PSC focused on the detriment to their rate base almost irrespective of the regional benefits.116

In addition to costs, SCE presented estimates of $213 million in net benefits to the Arizona ratepayers through increased construction jobs, better access to renewable energy and an improvement in the investment climate in the area.117 The Arizona PSC dismissed the possible benefits as speculative and irrelevant to the factors PSC can weigh under its governing statute.118 The Arizona PSC might have made the "best" decision for its ratepayers, but it did so in a way that completely discounted and ignored the regional benefits to the electricity market.119 The attitude of the Arizona PSC can be summed up by one commissioner's comment that the Devers-PV2 line amounted to nothing more than an "extension cord" to the California power sink.120

Arguably the Arizona PSC made the correct decision, assuming the only thing to be considered is the cost of a new transmission line to in-state ratepayers.121 The nature of transmission projects produces large benefits to regional markets, but creates large costs and negative externalities for states and localities.122 The typical economic costs consist of the recovery of the upfront investment and a reasonable return on investment, which are borne by

116 Id. 117 Id. 118 Id. 119 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 116. 120 Id.; Paul Davenport, Arizona Regulators Reject New Electric Line to

California, SAN DIEGO UNION-TRIBUNE, May 30, 2007, http://legacy .signonsandiego.com/news/state/20070530-1728-wst-sharingpower.html.

121 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 110 (describing the problems with often regional benefits and local costs of transmission lines).

122 Id.

Page 24: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 182

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

local ratepayers.123 Continuing with the SCE example, Arizona ratepayers faced a substantial increase in their electricity costs, even though the savings were predominantly in California.124 A larger emphasis may be placed on intrastate environmental and aesthetic concerns.125 High voltage transmission lines require a large right-of-way and often stand over 100-feet tall.126 Understandably, landowners that oppose the construction of transmission lines refer to them as aerial junkyards.127 These concerns are not unfounded as transmission rights-of-way can result in decreased property values, interfere with existing uses and potentially harm local tourism.128 Thus, the local costs vest state residents with an interest in combating almost any transmission line project, especially ones with predominantly regional benefits.129

123 Id. 124 See S. Cal. Edison Co., 2007 WL 2126365 1–3 (Ariz. Corp. Comm’n

June 6, 2007) (listing the Arizona PSC’s concerns about the economic, reliability and environmental impacts of the new transmission lines).

125 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 111–13 (discussing the eye sore transmission lines create and the possible noise disturbances).

126 Id. at 111. 127 Id. 128 See Diamond, supra note 57, at 225–26 (referencing the negative

impact of transmission lines on property may top a 15% decrease in extreme circumstances); Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 112 (stating that affected parties are often willing to pay for improved transmission towers with lower profiles).

129 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 118–20 (discussing the political pressures that can be exerted on state siting officials).

Page 25: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 183

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

The political arena provides the logical outlet for public outcry in the state transmission line siting process.130 Elected state officials recognize they answer only to their constituents, the very same people facing increased costs due to a transmission project.131 The affected local groups generally bear a higher per capita cost in comparison to the regionally dispersed per capita gain.132 The disparity in the per capita allocation creates a situation in which local cost bearers are more likely to organize and lobby their political representatives than the beneficiaries.133 Even if the regional beneficiaries were to organize, no proper political venue exists for their voice to be heard, because they cannot vote in the opposing state.134 The current political system skews any cost-benefit analysis at the state siting level against the regional benefits.135

These political pressures even arise in intrastate transmission siting.136 For example, the New York Regional Interconnection (NYRI) sought to carry power from upstate New York to the New York City Metropolitan Area.137 Due to significant congestion in transmission capacity to New York City,

130 See id. (describing political pressures exerted on local and state officials).

131 Id. at 118. 132 Id. 133 Id. 134 See generally id. (recognizing that “Not in My Backyard”

movements arise at the local and state levels, generally the locations at which political control over transmission sittingexists); see Diamond, supra note 57, at 226 (referencing NIMBY movements blocking transmission line development).

135 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 119. 136 See id. at 117–120 (outlining the struggle to site the New York

Regional Interconnection). 137 Id. at 118.

Page 26: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 184

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

millions of consumers were forced to purchase higher priced electricity from localized generators.138 The project seemingly had considerable intrastate benefits to millions of people, but it faced staunch opposition from certain residents along the proposed route.139 Prominent New York politicians including Senator Schumer and former Senator Clinton vowed to fight against the NYRI project at multiple levels.140 Ultimately, the centralized political opposition concentrated among the minority bearing the loss overcame the massive benefit to millions of New York residents. 141 Therefore, even if states have the possibility to consider regional benefits in the siting process, the political process coupled with parochial and "not in my backyard" (NIMBY) concerns often outweigh the aggregate benefits.142

Assuming states may properly consider the interstate benefits of transmission lines and are not subject to political pressures, many states still implement archaic definitions of what type of entity may apply for a permit.143 In general, states limit the entities that may apply for transmission development to "public utilities," which creates problems for non-utilities attempting to site a transmission project through the state.144 For example, various entities attempted to permit the Potomac-Appalachian Transmission Highline (PATH) carrying power from Pennsylvania and West Virginia to the suburbs of Washington D.C. 145 The proposed project spanned 275 miles

138 Id. 139 Id. at 119. 140 Id. 141 Id. 142 Id. 143 See Agen, supra note 106, at 50 (acknowledging that many states

face constraints on what type of entity may apply for transmission permits). 144 Id. at 150. 145 See generally id.; Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 117.

Page 27: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 185

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

through the former Mid-Atlantic Area NIETC.146 The Maryland PSC refused to consider the portion of the project running through the state, because the PSC could only issue a certificate of public convenience and necessity to an "electric company."147 The definition of "electric company" reaches back to the outdated concepts of regulated monopolies. In order to qualify the company must be "a person who physically transmits or distributes electricity in the State to a retail electric customer."148 The Maryland PSC found that PATH Allegheny Transmission did not qualify as an electric company and refused to rule on the permit.149

The PATH example further highlights the clashing nature of FERC's deregulated wholesale market and the traditional state siting process.150 Non-

146 Agen, supra note 106, at 50; Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 117; see generally California Wilderness Coalition v. U.S. Dept. of Energy, 631 F.3d 1072 (9th Cir. 2011) (throwing out NIETC designations in the Southwest and Mid-Atlantic for failures to consult with local governments and lacking environmental analysis).

147 Agen, supra note 106, at 50; MD. CODE ANN., PUB. UTIL. COS. § 1-101(h) (West 2012).

148 MD. CODE ANN., PUB. UTIL. COS. § 1-101(h). 149 Agen, supra note 106, at 50; see Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 117

(discussing resistance to transmission line construction projects). Potomac Edison later re-submitted a permit to the Maryland PSC to permit the project, which the Maryland PSC accepted because Potomac Edison qualified as an electric company while its subsidiary PATH Allegheny Transmission did not. Agen, supra note 106, at 50.

150 As of February 28, 2011 the PATH project was suspended indefinitely due to the Mid-Atlantic RTO’s (PJM) desire to further study the need for the transmission project. PATH Seeks to Withdraw Application for Electric Transmission Project: Regional Grid Operator Directs Suspension of PATH Project (Feb. 28, 2011), http://www.pathtransmission.com. Notably, this suspension came a few days after the Mid-Atlantic NIETC was dissolved

Page 28: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 186

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

utility entities are encouraged to provide competition in the wholesale power market and guaranteed access to the woefully inadequate transmission infrastructure, but they cannot expeditiously build extra infrastructure to improve the problem. The inability for the state transmission siting process to consider regional and national benefits, the political pressures to favor localized costs and the outdated regulatory models employed by states all support the case for stronger federal jurisdiction in the transmission siting process.151 Congress attempted to alleviate these concerns with EPAct 2005, but failed to effect any meaningful change.152

B. JUDICIAL LIMITATIONS OF FERC'S AUTHORITY UNDER

EPACT 2005

FERC's potential backstop authority to site transmission lines occurs only within a limited geographic area, and even then, only pursuant to overly specific conditions.153 First, DOE must conduct an electric transmission congestion study.154 In areas subject to congestion, DOE may designate the geographic region as a NIETC.155 If transmission projects in a NIETC are unable to obtain the required state siting permits because of undue delay, onerous conditions or a lack of authority, then transmission developers can

by the Ninth Circuit, but the press release does not mention a connection between the two events.

151 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 124–28 (calling for complete federal control over transmission line siting).

152 See id. at 123–24 (acknowledging the woeful inadequacies of EPAct 2005’s transmission authority); Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 455–56 (discussing the failure of EPAct 2005 to spur investment in transmission); Rossi, supra note 12, at 1033 (questioning how much authority FERC actually has under EPAct 2005 after judicial limitations).

153 See 16 U.S.C. §§ 824p(a)-(b) (2012) (listing the requirements in order to invoke FERC backstop authority).

154 See id. at § 824p(a)(1). 155 See id. at § 824p(a)(2).

Page 29: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 187

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

apply for FERC permitting.156 These overly limiting conditions coined the term "backstop" authority for FERC's jurisdiction.157 Nevertheless, EPAct 2005 attempted to increase, at least the threat of, federal preemption to the state siting process.158

Unfortunately, the judiciary exhibited reluctance to accept FERC's newly created authority.159 In California Wilderness Coalition v. United States Department of Energy, the Ninth Circuit invalidated DOE's two electricity congestion studies, upon which the only NIETCs were based.160 The rejection of the NIETC designations calls into question DOE's ability to designate a geographic area for federal transmission siting authority.161 The Fourth Circuit further complicated the issue in Piedmont Environmental Council v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission by limiting FERC's

156 See id. at § 824p(b). 157 Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 415 (referring to FERC’s

transmission siting authority as “backstop”); Diamond, supra note 57, at 219 (taking the “backstop” reference to its obvious metaphor, with the comparison to the backstop on a baseball diamond).

158 Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 123–24. 159 See California Wilderness Coalition v. U.S. Dept. of Energy, 631

F.3d 1072 (9th Cir. 2011) (throwing out NIETC designations in the Southwest and Mid-Atlantic for failures to consult with local governments and lacking environmental analysis); Piedmont Envtl. Council v. F.E.R.C., 558 F.3d 304 (4th Cir. 2009) (rejecting FERC authority if a state lawfully denies a transmission line project).

160 See Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1095–96 (vacating congestion studies and accordingly, the NIETCs that based upon them).

161 See Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (noting that the Wilderness Coalition case has placed FERC’s jurisdiction in limbo); Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 436–40 (referring to the then pending litigation in Wilderness Coalition and its potential impacts to any FERC authority).

Page 30: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 188

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

ability to site transmission lines if a state denies approval.162 The practical result of the Fourth Circuit's holding severely hinders FERC's potential authority.163 Judicial challenges and the courts' opinions dealt EPAct 2005 a serious setback by limiting DOE's ability to designate NIETCs and further gutting any threat of FERC's "backstop" authority by allowing states to circumvent triggering FERC's jurisdiction.164

1. CONGESTION STUDIES, NIETC DESIGNATIONS, AND

THE NINTH CIRCUIT'S WILDERNESS COALITION

DECISION

The factual background in the Ninth Circuit's Wilderness Coalition decision dates back to the enactment of EPAct 2005. In response to EPAct 2005 DOE began studying transmission line congestion.165 Pursuant to the statutory mandate, DOE was required to "consult with the affected States" in completing the congestion study and allow the affected states to comment before designating a NIETC.166 To accomplish this end, DOE sought

162 Piedmont, 558 F.3d at 320 (holding that a state’s legal denial of a transmission permit does not trigger FERC jurisdiction).

163 See Thornley, supra note 101, at 396–97 (stating that FERC's authority remains an open question).

164 See Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (noting that the Wilderness Coalition case has placed FERC’s jurisdiction in limbo); Swanstrom & Jolivert, supra note 40, at 436–40 (referring to the then pending litigation in Wilderness Coalition and its potential impacts to any FERC authority); Thornley, supra note 101, at 396–97 (stating that FERC’s authority remains an open question).

165 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1080–81; 16 U.S.C. § 824p(a) (2012).

166 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1080–81; see 16 U.S.C. § 824p(a)(1)–(2) (2012) (requiring consultation with the affected States in the congestion study and an opportunity to comment as to the possible alternatives and recommendations to the designation of a NIETC).

Page 31: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 189

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

comments from the public through a notice on February 2, 2006 and held an open technical conference in March 2006.167 No states received an invitation to the closed list conference in May 2006.168 The underlying data behind the congestion studies was not provided to the states.169 DOE published the final congestion study in August 2006 and requested comments on the study and the ensuing designation of NIETCs.170 Two major concerns emerged among the comments.171 The first category expressed concern that DOE failed to "consult" with the states during the congestion studies, contrary to the heightened mandate required.172 The second concern addressed DOE's failure to conduct the environmental review required by the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA).173 DOE formally designated two NIETCs on October 5, 2007, the Mid Atlantic and Southwest Corridors, despite the negative comments.174 Unhappy with the procedural aspects of the congestion study and both NIETC designations, various environmental groups and states filed thirteen petitions for review, which the Ninth Circuit consolidated into one case.175

Petitioners advanced the fundamental arguments expressed in the comments, that DOE failed to consult with the affected states and completely

167 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1080–81. 168 Id. 169 Id. at 1089–90. 170 Id. at 1080–81. 171 See generally id. at 1081–83 (expressing the comments’ concern that

DOE did not “consult” with the states and did not conduct the appropriate NEPA review).

172 Id. at 1081–82; 16 U.S.C. § 824p(a)(1) (requiring consultation). 173 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1082–83; see generally 42 U.S.C.

§§ 4321–35 (2012) (codifying NEPA). 174 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1083. 175 Id.

Page 32: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 190

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

skipped any NEPA analysis.176 DOE countered they solicited comments multiple times and held an open conference for additional conversation.177 The Ninth Circuit settled on the first prong of the Chevron deference, claiming the statutory language unambiguously expressed congressional intent that DOE consult with the affected states.178 The court weighed DOE's opportunities to comment against the plain meaning and case law interpretations of "consultation," coupled with the withheld data underlying the congestion studies.179 Ultimately, the Ninth Circuit held DOE failed to meet the heightened standard of consultation, by allowing only an opportunity to comment.180

The court then turned to the crucial issue of whether the failure to consult amounted to more than a harmless error.181 The opinion explained DOE's conduct adversely affected the congestion study and NIETC designations in three ways.182 First, "consultation requires an exchange of ideas and opinions before an agency makes a decision" and the comment periods failed to allow the same opportunity.183 Second, due to the

176 See generally id. at 1085–107 (following the court’s analysis through the consultation and environmental arguments).

177 Id. at 1085–86. 178 Id. at 1083–85 (applying Chevron USA, Inc. v. Natural Resources

Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984)); see 16 U.S.C. § 824p(a)(1) (2012) (“the Secretary of Energy . . . in consultation with affected States, shall conduct a study of electric transmission congestion”).

179 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1087–90. 180 Id. at 1086. 181 Id. at 1090–95. According to Ninth Circuit precedent, a harmless

error requires a finding that an error had no impact on the procedure followed or the determination’s substance. Id. at 1092.

182 Id. at 1093–95. 183 Id. at 1093.

Page 33: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 191

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

discretionary nature of DOE's decision, consultation would have provided an effective tool for lobbying by the affected states.184 Third, the court reasoned "that consultation would likely have resulted in a different study."185 The combination of the three adverse effects resulting from the failure to consult culminated in the court's holding that DOE's actions amounted to more than harmless error.186 To remedy DOE's failure to consult, the court vacated the congestion studies and consequently the NIETC designations for the Southwest and Mid-Atlantic Corridors.187 Thus, DOE and FERC were thrown back to square one in implementing siting authority under EPAct 2005; the Wilderness Coalition decision destroyed nearly six years of work.188

The Wilderness Coalition court took its holding one step further in addressing the petitioner's environmental claims.189 Even though the inade-quate congestion studies nullified the NIETC designations, the studies would have been vacated because of DOE's failure to conduct the proper environmental analysis.190 DOE attempted to argue the NIETC designations were too speculative to warrant NEPA analysis.191 However, the Ninth Circuit rejected DOE's assertions because the conclusory analysis performed by the department failed to provide a "hard look" at the potential environmental impacts of NIETC designation.192 The court's decision effectively mandated

184 California Wilderness Coal. v. U.S. Dep’t of Energy, 631 F.3d 1072, 1093-95 (9th Cir. 2011).

185 Id. at 1094–95. 186 Id. at 1095. 187 Id. at 1095–96. 188 Id.; Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (recognizing that Wilderness

Coalition returned DOE and FERC to the enactment of EPAct 2005). 189 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1096. 190 Id. 191 Id. at 1098. 192 Id.

Page 34: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 192

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

the completion of an environmental analysis (EA) or environmental impact statement (EIS) for every NIETC designation.193

Wilderness Coalition returns any potential FERC authority over transmission siting back to square one.194 DOE must conduct congestion studies with a heightened standard of consultation, the contours of which re-main uncertain.195 FERC's potential authority erodes further because NIETC designations require the completion of time consuming NEPA analysis.196 Thus, the trigger for potential FERC authority will be delayed, possibly by years.197 Even if a NIETC were to be designated, it is doubtful that FERC will be able to assert jurisdiction contrary to the state's wishes.198

2. DENIAL OF STATE PERMITTING REQUESTS, CIRCUMVENTING FERC JURISDICTION, AND THE

FOURTH CIRCUIT'S PIEDMONT DECISION

The Fourth Circuit dealt EPAct 2005 another fatal blow by severely limiting the potential for FERC backstop authority over transmission siting.

193 Id. at 1098–106 (finding that NIETC designations are major federal actions that raise significant environmental impacts).

194 See Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (recognizing that Wilderness Coalition “returned DOE and FERC to the enactment of EPAct 2005”).

195 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1081–106; Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (analogizing Wilderness Coalition to a complete rejection of DOE/FERC authority).

196 Wilderness Coalition, 631 F.3d at 1081–106; Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (stating that FERC authority is in limbo).

197 See Agen, supra note 106, at 49 (questioning the applicability of EPAct 2005 to any transmission line that was before a state PSC before the Wilderness Coalition decision).

198 See id. at 48 (recognizing that FERC authority can be circumvented by the state process).

Page 35: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 193

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

Transmission line developers may petition for FERC backstop authority within a NIETC if the state PSC lacks the authority to permit the project, withholds a decision for more than one year or conditions its approval upon overly onerous conditions.199 FERC interpreted a state's denial of a permit to trigger the one year withholding period for potential FERC authority.200 Unhappy with FERC's interpretation, various PSCs and community interest groups petitioned for review, with the case being consolidated in the Fourth Circuit.201 In Piedmont, the petitioners challenged Order No. 689's interpreta-tion of "withheld approval" as including the lawful denial of a transmission siting request.202 The Fourth Circuit held the plain meaning of "withhold" did not include a denial, as withholding implied a continuous act while denial was definite and final.203 The court bolstered its adherence to the plain meaning of "withhold" in the context of the statute by interpreting FERC's potential authority to only be in limited circumstances.204 If the court accepted FERC's interpretation, it thought that PSCs would lose jurisdiction, unless they approved every siting permit.205 The court could not accept such a sweeping grant of federal jurisdiction and overturned FERC's interpretation.206

199 16 U.S.C. § 824p(b) (2010). 200 See, e.g., Regulations for Filing Applications for Permits to Site

Interstate Electric Transmission Facilities, Order No. 689, 18 C.F.R. § 50 (2006); Agen, supra note 106, at 48 (interpreting FERC Order No. 689).

201 See generally 558 F.3d 304 (4th Cir. 2009) (rejecting FERC authority if a state lawfully denies a transmission line project).

202 Id. at 311. 203 Id. at 313. 204 Id. at 313–14. 205 Id. at 314. 206 Id. at 315.

Page 36: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 194

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

In his dissent, Judge Traxler emphasized the overarching goal of EPAct 2005 to allow FERC intervention to site transmission lines.207 The dissent claimed not equating a denial to withholding approval allows one state to derail a multistate line, which EPAct 2005 sought to prevent.208 Under Judge Traxler's interpretation, approval of a permit is withheld every day a permit is not issued, which continues to run after denial as approval is still withheld.209 The dissent would accept FERC's interpretation and give effect to the underlying congressional intent to expedite transmission line siting.210

Piedmont created a loophole in FERC's potential jurisdiction.211 If the denial of a transmission siting permit does not trigger the one-year withholding provision, then a state only needs to legally deny a permit to avoid the threat of FERC jurisdiction.212 The Fourth Circuit essentially gutted any potential threat of FERC jurisdiction and nullified EPAct 2005's reach to only the dullest of PSCs who cannot find a valid reason to deny a transmission line siting permit.213 Judicial challenges in the Ninth and Fourth Circuits severely limited any potential for EPAct 2005 to have a meaningful impact on the transmission line siting process.

207 558 F.3d at 323–26 (Traxler, J., dissenting). 208 Id. at 324. 209 Id. at 323. 210 Id. at 325–26. 211 See Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 124 (recognizing that a state only

needs to deny approval to circumvent FERC authority). 212 See, e.g., id.; Agen, supra note 106, at 48; Thornley, supra note 101,

at 396. 213 See, e.g., Vaheesan, supra note 82, at 124; Agen, supra note 106, at

48; Thornley, supra note 101, at 396.

Page 37: Energy Policy Act of 2005: Pseudo-Fed for Transmission

J o u r n a l o f E n v i r o n m e n t a l a n d P u b l i c H e a l t h L a w

P a g e | 195

ISSN 2164-7976 (online) ● DOI 10.5195/pjephl.2013.43 http://pjephl.law.pitt.edu

IV. CONCLUSION

Although the threat of federal transmission siting authority may remain on the books, this aspect of EPAct 2005 lacks any potential for use in the near future. Federal intervention created the first and largest strains on the existing transmission infrastructure. Renewable energy resources further burden an outdated transmission grid. State control over transmission line siting forms the primary obstacle to investment and construction of new lines. To ensure regional and national coordination, the federal government must consolidate its power over not only transmission access, but transmission siting as well. EPAct 2005 attempted to take a step in the right direction, but ultimately proved ineffective. As long as the individual states control interstate transmission siting, congestion, poor reliability and security, and a dearth of investment will plague the United States' transmission grid.