Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    1/16

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/Peace Science

    Conflict Management and

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354

    The online version of this article can be foundat:

    DOI: 10.1177/07388942134913582013 30: 354 originally published online 9 July 2013Conflict Management and Peace Science

    Molly M. Melin, Scott Sigmund Gartner and Jacob Bercovitchear of rejection: The puzzle of unaccepted mediation offers in international conflict

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    On behalf of:

    Peace Science Society (International)

    can be found at:Conflict Management and Peace ScienceAdditional services and information for

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.refs.htmlCitations:

    What is This?

    - Jul 9, 2013OnlineFirst Version of Record

    - Aug 28, 2013Version of Record>>

    by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from by Minodora Mancas on October 5, 2013cmp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354http://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354http://www.sagepublications.com/http://www.sagepublications.com/http://pss.la.psu.edu/http://cmp.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://cmp.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://cmp.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://cmp.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.refs.htmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/early/2013/07/09/0738894213491358.full.pdfhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.full.pdfhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.full.pdfhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/http://online.sagepub.com/site/sphelp/vorhelp.xhtmlhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/early/2013/07/09/0738894213491358.full.pdfhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.full.pdfhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354.refs.htmlhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://cmp.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://cmp.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://pss.la.psu.edu/http://www.sagepublications.com/http://cmp.sagepub.com/content/30/4/354http://cmp.sagepub.com/
  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    2/16

    Conflict Management and Peace Science

    30(4) 354368

    The Author(s) 2013

    Reprints and permissions:

    sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav

    DOI: 10.1177/0738894213491358

    cmp.sagepub.com

    Fear of rejection: The puzzle of

    unaccepted mediation offers ininternational conflict

    Molly M. MelinLoyola University, USA

    Scott Sigmund Gartner

    Pennsylvania State University, USA

    Jacob Bercovitch

    The University of Canterbury, UK

    Abstract

    How do factors that influence mediation offers affect belligerent behavior? The circumstances

    that attract potential mediators are not the same as those that make mediation desirable tobelligerents. Third parties offer mediation when the conflict is intense, generation of an agreementis likely and they have ties to the conflict. However, mediation is less acceptable to belligerents in

    these circumstances. This dynamic creates a dilemma; the characteristics that make third partiesmore forthcoming with mediation offers simultaneously make disputants more likely to rejectmediation proposals. A better understanding of this strategic process can help scholars and

    policy-makers better determine how to supply mediation where it is needed most.

    Keywords

    Conflict resolution, expected utility, mediation

    The rejection of offers to mediate international disputes presents a puzzle. Why would disputants

    reject third-party offers when many of the costs of mediation are borne by the mediator? Despite

    To our great sadness, Professor Jacob Bercovitch passed away during the preparation of this manuscript. We very much

    miss his leadership on the study of international dispute mediation, his valuable contributions as a coauthor and his

    wonderful friendship

    Corresponding author:Molly M. Melin, Department of Political Science, 1032 W. Sheridan Road, Coffey Hall, 3rd Floor, Chicago, IL 60660, USA.

    Email: [email protected]

    CMP30410.1177/0738894213491358Conflict Management and PeaceScienceMelin et al.

    Article

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    3/16

    Melin et al. 355

    the high likelihood of failure, dispute mediators contribute time and resources, and risk their repu-

    tation as peacemakers. Rejection of mediation offers can be costly to disputants in an international

    environment that strongly disapproves of violent conflict. The reality is that the occurrence of

    mediation may itself be an achievement, but the chances of further success are far from assured.

    We examine why mediation occurs in some conflicts and not in others by asking how the factors

    that influence mediation offers affect belligerent behavior. We argue that the circumstances that

    make a conflict attractive to a potential mediator differ from those that make mediation attractive

    to belligerents. Third parties offer mediation when the conflict is intense, when generation of an

    agreement is likely and when they have ties to the conflict. Mediation is less acceptable, however,

    for belligerents under these conditions. Both mediators and disputants act strategically, but this

    strategic behavior leads them to react to similar factors differently. While existing research dis-

    cusses mediation occurrence, we offer a more complete picture of those conflicts that go without

    mediation. Exploring rejected mediation offers creates an understanding of variation in conflict

    management behavior with important implications for how best to encourage mediation.

    Understanding international mediation

    Mediation is a method of international conflict management whereby a third party assists the dis-

    puting parties in negotiating their conflict. Mediation differs from other forms of conflict manage-

    ment in several important ways. First, unlike military intervention, which uses force to help one

    side win (Melin and Koch, 2010), or economic sanctions, which encourage peace through limiting

    financial interactions (Drury and Chan, 2000), mediation must be voluntarily acceptable to both

    disputants (Beardsley, 2011). Second, unlike binding arbitration, mediation does not require an

    advance commitment to accept an outcome (Gent and Shannon, 2010; Mitchell and Powell, 2011).

    While we focus on the puzzle of mediation rejection, an informative body of research that

    addresses mediation occurrence more generally has developed. This scholarship helps us under-

    stand the types of conflicts that are likely to be mediated. For example, Greig (2005) examined the

    incidence of mediation in enduring rivalries, finding that mediation is likely when the costs of

    inaction are high and the likelihood of peace is low. Mediation is more likely in interstate, as com-

    pared with civil, wars (Melin and Svensson, 2009). Third parties avoid mediating intractable con-

    flicts and account for previous mediation efforts and their outcomes (Rost and Greig, 2011). More

    generally, this literature finds that mediators act strategically and try to maximize the expected

    benefits and minimize the anticipated costs of mediation (Bercovitch and Gartner, 2006; Leng,

    2000; Greig, 2005; Regan and Stam, 2000).

    Some third parties are more likely to act as mediators. Biases and ties are likely to draw in third

    parties, increasing the likelihood that actors will become involved since they have interests at stake

    (Favretto, 2009; Maundi et al., 2006; Melin, 2011) and are seen as more committed to peacemak-

    ing (Crescenzi et al., 2011; Kydd, 2003). Bercovitch and Schneider (2000) show that a third partys

    reputation as an effective mediator plays an important role in the number of mandates they receive.

    We build on this mediation incidence research theoretically, empirically and analytically.

    Theoretically, we develop arguments for when disputants reject the presence of a mediator, provid-

    ing an understanding of the circumstances when mediation does not occur. The underlying causal

    mechanisms that lead to the rejection of mediation offers will differ from those that prompt media-

    tion offers. Empirically, we examine the potential for state mediation in all violent disputes since

    the Second World War, helping to identify the roles that state relationships, the mediation environ-

    ment and conflict characteristics play in mediation offers and rejections. Finally, analytically, we

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    4/16

    356 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    directly address the selection effects. Factors motivating third parties and disputants to partake in

    mediation activities will affect the outcomes of their efforts, creating a selection bias (Gartner

    and Bercovitch, 2006; Svensson, 2006). Selection bias is likely to be an important issue in the

    study of international mediation because it is reasonable to expect that, rather than selecting cases

    for mediation randomly, disputants and third-parties tie their decision to mediate to the chances forits success (Greig, 2005: 249). While scholars have studied the question of Who mediates?as

    a precursor to mediation success and an element of the selection processthey have not explicitly

    modeled the selection process they identified as critical. We offer that extension here.

    For mediation to occur, three conditions must be met: (1) the disputants must agree to work with

    a mediator; (2) the disputants must find a mutually acceptable third party; and (3) the third party

    must be willing to become involved in the conflict (Beardsley, 2011: 18). Rarely are all of these

    conditions met. As a result, the mediation process exhibits variation at all stages. While particular

    actors may be more or less likely to offer mediation, the occurrence of mediation varies both abso-

    lutely (the number of mediators or mediation efforts per year) and relatively (the ratio of mediation

    or mediators to conflicts per year). Mediation is neither automatic (not every dispute is mediated),nor in constant supply (mediators are not always mediating). Mediation is the result of strategic

    choices by disputants and third parties that cause the allocation of mediators to be asymmetrical.

    Some conflicts attract more mediators than others (Svensson and Wallensteen, 2010), creating

    under-provision of mediation even when the combatants desire it (Beardsley, 2011: 50).

    We assume that third parties anticipate costs and benefits prior to offering mediation, as do

    disputants when considering mediation offers (Mitchell, 1993). While we observe either

    Mediation or No-Mediationempirically, there are three different possible No-Mediation out-

    comes (see Figure 1). In Cell 1, there is neither mediation supply nor demand. Cell 2 represents

    instances that lack mediator supply, wherein the disputants might have been amenable to work-

    ing with a third-party mediator had one been available. Cell 3 represents instances lacking medi-ation demand as one or both disputants were unwilling to work with a third party. The literature

    generally treats these different outcomes identically. While scholars have examined the request

    for, offer of and occurrence of mediation (Greig, 2005), we have little theoretical or empirical

    understanding of variation in disputants rejection of mediation offers. Ignoring the variation in

    conflicts that go without mediation risks generating an incomplete understanding of mediation

    decisions.

    States, regional and international organizations, and individuals all mediate violent disputes

    (Aall, 2007; Chigas, 2007; Touval, 2003). We expect that mediation works differently across medi-

    ator types (Gartner, 2011). For example, belligerents are less likely to turn down mediation offers

    from an organization to which they aspire to gain membership (Svensson and Wallensteen, 2010).The current literature includes many studies of international organization/UN mediation (Hansen

    Figure 1. Disaggregating the occurrence and nonoccurrence of mediation.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    5/16

    Melin et al. 357

    et al., 2008; Shannon, 2009) and an increasing amount of research on regional governmental

    organization mediation (Gartner, 2011; Olson and Pearson, 2002; Wehr and Lederach, 1991), but

    few studies of state mediation (exceptions include Aydin, 2010; Melin, 2011; Rost and Greig,

    2011). The comparative lack of analyses of state mediation is especially troubling because states

    are the most common type of mediator.

    State mediators differ from other types of mediators in both the reason for offering mediation

    and the belligerents reason for acceptance or rejection. In contrast to states, international organiza-

    tions are frequently tasked with peacemaking as a part of their charter (e.g. the African Union and

    Organization of American States; Gartner, 2013). Despite this, international organizations must

    overcome individualism and political struggles between members to build consensus before carry-

    ing out a mission (Abbott and Snidal, 1998). In contrast, state mediators are less able to demon-

    strate impartiality and more likely to have a stake in the conflicts outcome. National interests and

    potential domestic ramifications of failed efforts mean states are more constrained than intergov-

    ernmental organizations and must be more strategic in choosing to intervene (Aydin, 2010). States

    may therefore have a lower baseline likelihood of acceptance as mediators than nonstate actors.

    Additionally, states have more policy instruments at their disposal than international organizations.

    This allows them to select one or more methods by which they can react to external conflict (includ-

    ing support of one side, see Melin and Koch, 2010; Siverson and Starr, 1991; Werner and Lemke,

    1997).

    Empirically, the operationalization of interests, ties and probability of success for nonstate third

    parties entails a vastly different set of variables than those of state actors. For example, the interests

    of potential mediators are frequently analyzed using trade ties (Kathman, 2010). Capturing the

    interests of international organizations using this metric without treating them simply as a sum of

    their parts proves challenging.

    Theory

    How do the factors that influence mediation offers affect belligerents behavior? Third-party medi-

    ators are dependent upon the belligerents acceptance of their offer to mediate. Sometimes third

    parties wish to be involved but are not wanted by the disputants. Rejection is likely, however, in

    any conflict environment where suspicion and mistrust abound (Svensson and Wallensteen, 2010).

    For example, when the conflict between the USA and Iraq escalated in February 1998, several

    states volunteered to act as mediators, but the disputants rejected these offers. At the last minute,

    when a confrontation seemed inevitable, UN Secretary-General Kofi Annan offered his services,

    and his offer was accepted (Wedgwood, 1998: 725). The elective nature of mediation indicates that

    the offer itself is only a part of the process.

    Disputants consider the costs and benefits of mediation and will agree to mediation if they

    expect it to generate a more favorable outcome for themselves compared with continued conflict

    (Wilkenfeld et al., 2003; Zartman and Touval, 1992). Disputants consider the costs of a conflict

    when deciding to work with a mediator (Greig and Regan, 2008; Melin, 2011). Mediation can be

    used to gain time or to avoid the choice between escalation and making concessions (Kleiboer,

    1996). This was probably the reason why Iran and Iraq agreed to mediation in 1975 (Lieb, 1985).

    Mediation can also help policy-makers save face internationally and domestically when making

    concessions, as was probably the motivation behind Irans acceptance of Algerian mediation dur-

    ing the US hostage crisis (Sick, 1985). Agreeing to mediation can be costly for disputants in certain

    circumstances, as openness to mediation can send a signal of low resolve to ones adversary. When

    the costs of involving a mediator outweigh the benefits of doing so, third parties will reject

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    6/16

    358 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    mediation offers. Rejected offers may reflect either a rejection of mediation more generally or a

    rejection of the specific mediator.

    Mediationrejection occurs when one of the disputants deems mediation activities undesirable.

    Belligerents preferences for continued fighting over mediation depends on conflict factors. The

    intensity and potential for escalation that attract mediation offers have an inverse effect on accept-

    ance offers. While the difficulty of resolving territorial disputes indicates these conflicts are the

    ones that need mediation, they involve disputants that are the most likely to turn it down. This

    rejection is due to the importance of signaling resolve and a willingness to continue fighting in

    territorial disputes (Huth, 1998). Wiegand (2011: 110) writes that, because territorial disputes are

    the most salient type of interstate disputes and the most likely to escalate to war, it is logical that

    states involved in territorial disputes would be particularly concerned with signaling resolve to

    adversaries. One way to signal resolve is to reject mediation.

    These same high-stakes disputes are more likely to attract third-party mediation offers.

    Reputation building requires that mediators take on disputes seen as both important and hard to

    resolve. Bercovitch and Jackson (2001) find that mediation tends to occur in disputes that are com-

    plex, intense and long. Third parties are more likely to mediate conflicts that are less likely to be

    resolved bilaterally between the two disputing parties and will lead to deadly combat. Research

    shows that territorial disputes are especially likely to escalate (Huth, 2000) and lead to costly fight-

    ing (Wiegand, 2011). This potential for escalation and cost will probably increase both the visibil-

    ity of the conflict and the probability that it attracts mediation offers (Allee and Huth, 2006;

    Chiozza and Choi, 2003; Hensel et al., 2008; Huth, 1996; Huth and Allee, 2002).

    Hypothesis 1.Territorial disputes are more likely to lead to mediation offers and rejection.

    An ongoing war attracts mediation offers while also increasing the likelihood of their rejection.

    States are most interested in mediating disputes that have escalated to violence and involve casual-ties since these conflicts are most likely to gain international attention. Research shows that high-

    cost conflicts increase mediation occurrence (Beardsley, 2010). Positive reputation gains from

    stopping a war exceed those of resolving a more peaceful conflict. However, wars are the result of

    mutual optimism: the sides have conflicting estimates of their bargaining power and an inability to

    agree on a peaceful reconciliation (Blainey, 1988; Slantchev and Tarar, 2010). Belligerents that

    have decided to fight a war clearly demonstrate a lack of interest in pursuing peaceful means of

    conflict resolution. Disputants are also unlikely to see the need for a mediator as long as conflict

    costs and estimates of the likelihood of success remain unclear (Regan and Aydin, 2006). All of

    these factors indicate that disputes that escalate to war involve a particular pair of disputants who

    are unlikely to voluntarily accept a cooperative and peaceful process of reconciliation.

    Hypothesis 2.Violent disputes are more likely to lead to mediation offers and rejection.

    Mediatorrejection occurs when one of the disputants deems the mediator unacceptable. There are

    instances where the states in a conflict may be open to third-party mediation but are not willing to

    work with the actor that has offered mediation. Trust is necessary for third parties to be deemed

    acceptable as mediators. Trust is a belief that the other side is trustworthy, that is, willing to recip-

    rocate cooperation, and mistrust is a belief that the other side is untrustworthy, or prefers to exploit

    ones cooperation (Kydd, 2005: 3). Disputants will only work with and share strategic informa-

    tion with third parties they consider trustworthy. Dyadic relationships help to reassure disputantsthat a third party can be trusted.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    7/16

    Melin et al. 359

    Ties between the third party and disputants may also reflect the strategic interests of the third

    party that may be at stake, thereby increasing the benefits of involvement. Actors are more likely

    to offer to mediate when there are third-party interests (Greig and Regan, 2008) and an expectation

    of future interactions with disputants (Rauchhaus, 2006). Ties play an important role in the occur-

    rence of civil war mediation (Favretto, 2009) and international conflict management (Melin, 2011).

    Hypothesis 3.Third partydisputant ties increase mediation offers and acceptances.

    This hypothesis may seem counter-intuitive. Theoretically, network dynamics suggest that those

    states with closer ties to disputants are more likely to support one or the other with arms, funding,

    sanctuary and support. This bias would greatly limit their appeal to the disputant whose efforts they

    oppose (Rauchhaus, 2006; Terris and Maoz, 2005), making them less likely to be seen as a media-

    tor and more likely as an ally or enemy. Thus, ties cut both ways: connectivity simultaneously

    increases the probability of a mediation offer (given the higher levels of strategic interests in the

    dispute) and increases the probability of being seen as biased (increasing the chances of rejection

    of the mediation offer). We explore these competing effects directly by examining the influence ofdifferent types of connections on mediation offers and rejections.

    Belligerents, especially those involved in highly visible conflicts, often have multiple mediation

    offers. It is therefore important to account for the conflict management options that disputants face

    when deciding to accept a mediation offer. This is especially vital since disputants have been

    shown to forum shop, looking for the most favorable method of peaceful resolution before agree-

    ing (Wiegand and Powell, 2001). Conflicting actors want to obtain the best deal possible for them-

    selves in mediation (Terris and Maoz, 2005). Disputes thus potentially create mediation markets

    where disputants can choose among competing offers. Belligerents who prefer peacemaking to

    conflict might reject one offer of mediation for another. We anticipate that evidence of other media-

    tion options makes mediation offers more likely to be rejected.

    Hypothesis 4.The presence of mediation alternatives increases the likelihood of mediation rejection.

    Finally, third parties will take into account the likely outcome of their efforts before offering to

    mediate. Research shows that mediators assess their ability to transform a conflict prior to becom-

    ing involved and only make offers if they believe that their efforts will be effective (Touval and

    Zartman, 1996). Mediators take the likelihood of success into account and avoid intractable con-

    flicts that are likely to persist, as actors are more sensitive to risks in these cases (Bercovitch and

    Gartner, 2006; Rost and Greig, 2011). Mediators anticipate that dyads previously engaged in dis-

    putes are less likely to reach a settlement. Therefore, we expect these dyads to be less likely toreceive mediation offers.

    Hypothesis 5.A history of conflict between the disputants decreases the likelihood of mediation offers.

    When a third party perceives that they can help to generate an agreement, it is then that they are the

    most likely to offer their services. This expectation seems to be in contradiction to findings that

    mediated disputes are less likely to result in peace. However, this argument only claims that dispu-

    tants will pay the costs of mediation for the more intractable disputes that are harder to resolve

    (Bercovitch and Gartner, 2006; Gartner and Bercovitch, 2006). These studies only analyze the

    observed strategic interaction of mediation once it is offered, accepted and acted upon. In contrast,

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    8/16

    360 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    our expectation speaks strictly to the likelihood that a mediator will offer their services, and that

    this will happen only if a mediator perceives that an agreement is possible.

    Rejecting offers to mediate is a way for disputants to signal their resolve to fight and optimism

    about their chances for success. We therefore expect to observe rejected offers more often in

    intensely violent and territorial-based disputes. Disputants in these conditions are less open to

    third-party mediation, regardless of the offering party; they are rejecting mediation rather than the

    mediator. In other circumstances, third parties may not appear trustworthy to the disputants owing

    to their relationship to one of the disputants, or other offers may be more appealing, in which case

    the disputants are rejecting the mediator rather than mediation. We therefore expect mediation

    offers to be more likely to be rejected in violent conflicts over territory, when the disputants have

    reason not to trust the offering state, and when other offers are present. However, we expect similar

    circumstances to simultaneously increase the likelihood that states will offer to mediate. We test

    our expectations in the following section.

    Research designWe employed a dataset of post-Second World War third-party conflict mediation efforts that

    includes allDyadic Militarized Interstate Disputes(Maoz, 2005). For every year in which a con-

    flict is ongoing, we constructed an observation of each disputant and a potential mediator. We

    defined a population of potential mediators based on theoretical arguments about likely mediators.

    To be included, potential mediators must be at least one of the following (according to thePolitically

    Relevant Dyadsdata; Maoz, 1996): (1) a major or regional power with both the resources and the

    responsibility to manage conflicts; (2) a geographically contiguous state, regularly interacting with

    the disputants and disproportionately affected by a neighboring conflict; or (3) a reputational

    manager, having exhibited both the willingness and opportunity for mediation in previous dis-

    putes. It is important to note that, since we used these variables in our data selection process, they

    are not included in the analyses. Examination of all violent disputes since the Second World War

    resulted in over 64,000 observations, allowing us to expand beyond the 35 enduring rivalries previ-

    ously studied (Greig, 2005; Greig and Diehl, 2006). This empirical expansion also has theoretical

    importance, as [e]nduring rivalries are unique phenomen[a] (Greig, 2005: 265), making it criti-

    cal that we enlarge the empirical domain to capture other conflict dynamics.

    Selection effects

    States that offer to mediate and are accepted for mediation are not randomly selected. Selection

    effects result when systematic factors reduce the population of potential observations. We identi-

    fied and controlled for two types of selection. First, it is likely that third parties take into account

    the probability that the disputants will accept mediation before offering their services (Greig and

    Regan, 2008; Melin and Svensson, 2009). On the one hand, we know that this knowledge is not

    perfect, as we observe disputants refusing mediation offers. On the other hand, we are unlikely to

    identify the variables that completely reflect such knowledge. As a result of these Entry Effects,

    only select mediation offers are observable.

    Second, the cases requiring outside involvement are those that disputants are unable to resolve

    on their own. Third parties therefore become involved in conflicts that are difficult to manage and

    unlikely to lead to peace (Bercovitch and Gartner, 2006; Greig, 2005). As a result of theseDispute

    Effects, mediation is more likely to be observed among highly intractable conflicts.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    9/16

    Melin et al. 361

    We addressedEntryandDisputeselection effects in three ways: (1) theoretically, by specifying

    factors that we think affect mediator offers; (2) empirically, by identifying a pool of available

    mediators; and (3) methodologically, by employing a censored Probit estimation procedure that

    takes into account dispute characteristics (an alternative method could involve matching; see

    Gilligan and Sergenti, 2008). The censored Probit method allowed us to simultaneously model the

    selection variables that explain mediation offers and acceptances (Nooruddin, 2002). Scholars

    employ selection models to study conflict termination (Lemke and Regan, 2004), mediation (Greig

    and Regan, 2008; Melin and Svensson, 2009) and peacekeeping (Greig and Diehl, 2005).

    Specifically, the method has been used to address selection in the type of mediation study con-

    ducted here (Gartner and Bercovitch, 2006; Savun, 2008).

    Mediation offers

    The unit of analysis is the disputantthird partyyear. This unit of analysis enabled us to explore

    the factors that influence outside states to offer mediation and disputants to accept it. Annual exam-

    ination of each potential mediator prevented us from excluding cases of multiple offers to mediate,

    and allowed for annual variation in the explanatory variables. The first stage of the model predicts

    whether or not the potential third party makes an offer to mediate (Offer=1, 0 otherwise). There

    are 101 state mediation offers. The second stage predicts whether or not the disputants reject or

    accept the offer (Reject=1, 0 otherwise; 34% are rejected). We cluster the models by dispute, since

    not all cases are independent of one another. Information on mediation offers and acceptances is

    from the Third Party Interventiondata (Frazier and Dixon, 2006) and the International Conflict

    Managementdata (Bercovitch, 1999).

    To measure third parties expectations that the benefits of their efforts will outweigh the costs of

    involvement, we examine the role of the dispute environment and the ties between disputants and

    potential mediators. Mediators account for the likelihood of success and want to avoid intractable

    conflicts (Bercovitch and Gartner, 2006; Rost and Greig, 2011). Mediators anticipate that dyads

    previously engaged in disputes are less likely to reach a settlement. Therefore, we expect these

    dyads to be less likely to receive mediation offers. We created the variablePrevious Dispute, and

    it is coded 1 if the disputants have previously engaged in a militarized interstate dispute (83%), and

    0 otherwise.

    Given the costs of mediation, mediators want to work on salient disputes whose resolution is

    meaningful. We captured important disputes by looking at conflicts involving current and future

    potential loss of life. First, we employed the variable War(1 if currently coded as a war (6%), 0

    otherwise). Second, using the Third Party Interventionand International Conflict Management

    data we coded for the territorial nature of the issue (Territorial Conflictis 1 if applicable (9%), 0

    otherwise), since territorial disputes have long been shown to be the most deadly (Huth, 1996).

    We hypothesize that a third party is more likely to mediate if it has cooperative ties to the dis-

    putants. To account for these relationships, we examined the presence of historic, alliance and

    regime ties (Altfeld and Bueno de Mesquita, 1979). Colonial powers may be more likely to manage

    conflicts in their former colonies (Bercovitch and Schneider, 2000), and such links increase the

    probability of mediation offers in civil wars (Greig and Regan, 2008; Melin and Svensson, 2009).

    The variableHistoric Tiesis coded 1 if at least one of the disputants was a former colony of the

    potential intermediary (0.9%; 0 otherwise; The Correlates of War 2 Project, n.d.). Alliances increase

    third-party efforts to resolve international conflicts (Melin, 2011). We measured the presence of a

    defensiveAlliance Tiesbetween the third party and at least one disputant (Alliance Ties= 1 (5%);0 otherwise) using the Alliance Treaty Obligations and Provisions data (Leeds et al., 2002).Regime

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    10/16

    362 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    Tiesshared by the third party and at least one disputant suggest ideological ties. Evidence shows

    that a strong democratic community increases the probability of third-party mediation and its suc-

    cess (Mitchell, 2002; Mitchell et al., 2008).Regime Tiesis coded 1 if the third party and one/both

    disputant(s) are mature democracies, 0 otherwise; democracy requires a Polity IV score of 6

    (Marshall and Jaggers, 2002).

    Explanatory variables for mediation rejections

    We expect that mediation behavior and the nature of the dispute influence the focus of our analysis:

    mediation offer rejection. First, we examined Other Mediation. We anticipate that ongoing media-

    tion identifies the availability of conflict management alternatives, and as a result, increases the

    chances ofRejection. In the face of competing mediation offers, rejection is not necessarily a repu-

    diation of peacemaking; rather, it may be an effort to attract more prominent mediators.

    We used War, Power Differenceand Territorial Conflictto capture our hypothesized effects of

    dispute characteristics and account for the presence of mutual optimism. We anticipate that those

    disputants who are actively engaged in violent conflict are less likely to want to make peace. We

    expect that fights over territory, seen by many as the most salient dispute issue, are less likely to

    lead to voluntary peacemaking. Extensive research suggests that, the greater the power differences

    between disputants, the higher the likelihood of mediation offer rejection (Bercovitch and Houston,

    1993; Melin and Svensson, 2009). Large power asymmetries provide the strong state with confi-

    dence in battlefield victory, making it less likely to seek compromise (Beardsley et al., 2006). Each

    disputant state has a power capacity measured by its Composite Index of National Capability score

    (Bennett and Stam, 2004), which creates an index of measures such as population, steel production

    and military capability. We subtracted the Index scores of the two disputants to create the variable

    Power Difference, which has a mean of 0.09, a standard deviation of 0.07 and ranges from near 0

    to 0.36.

    To test the role of ties between the third party and disputants, we examined the presence of

    historic, alliance and regime ties (Altfeld and Bueno de Mesquita, 1979). The above variables are

    summarized in Table 1. The results of our analysis are discussed below.

    Results and discussion

    We begin with a standard Probit analysis of actors rejecting mediation (results not shown). As we

    expected, disputants are more likely to reject mediation when they anticipate success. Greater dif-

    ferences in power increase the likelihood of mediation rejection. All measures of tiesalliance,

    historic and regimehave no effect on the likelihood of the disputants rejecting a mediation offer,

    suggesting that perhaps disputants are rejecting the involvement of any third party and not just the

    offering third party. Jointly modeling mediation offers and rejections provides further support for

    this theory, and combining these processes to capture the selection effects that mediation offers

    have on rejections yields much stronger and more robust results.

    Results from a censored Probit analysis, clustered by dispute, are shown in Table 2. As the table

    shows, mediators are more likely to offer their services when a conflict is intense, but under these

    conditions, disputants are also less willing to accept offers. War and Territorial Conflict both

    increase the likelihood of mediation offers, but when accounting for selection effects, also increase

    the probability disputants reject mediation. A dispute over salient objectives signals that disputants

    are less likely to seek peace voluntarily.Previous disputes, which signal to third parties the diffi-

    culty of resolving the conflict, decrease mediation offers. Overall, these conflict factors show that

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    11/16

    Melin et al. 363

    third parties account for not only the visibility of the conflict but also the probability of resolving

    it, and that disputants are unlikely to be open to mediation under these circumstances. This ten-

    dency reveals a new pattern concerning disputant willingness to work with third parties. While

    Greig (2005) shows that so-called triage factors increase bothmediation offers and occurrence,

    we find that these factors also contain information about disputants openness to mediation.

    Disputants are less willing to work with the international community while simultaneously absorb-

    ing high costs and casualties, as mediation rejection signals an adversarys resolve and mutual

    optimism.

    As we hypothesized,Power Differenceincreases the likelihood of mediation rejection. At first,the positive relationship of power differences might seem counter-intuitive, as one might think that

    large power differences should make it clear that the stronger state will win and the weaker one will

    lose, making a peaceful alternative more desired. The problem with this line of thinking is that the

    weaker state chose to fight recognizing the clear advantage of the stronger state (Sullivan, 2007).

    As a result, when factors such as dispute characteristics and cooperative behavior are taken into

    account, power no longer has a systematic influence, a result consistent with Sullivans findings

    that major powers lose almost 40% of all wars with minor powers (Sullivan, 2007: 498).

    Other Mediationis not correlated withRejection. This offers a first signal that disputants are not

    shopping for the right mediator. That disputants are no more or less likely to agree to mediation

    based upon the presence of other mediators offers evidence that disputants reject mediation basedon conflict characteristics and not mediation and relationship characteristics. Taking the mediation

    environment and conflict intensity into account, relationships play a minor role in mediation deci-

    sions. Cooperative relationships, such asHistoric Ties, Regime TiesandAlliance Ties, do not play

    a part in third-party calculations. When tested as explanations for disputants rejections of media-

    tion (results not shown), relationship ties were not significant predictors of disputant choices. The

    lack of correlation offers further evidence that disputants reject mediation offers because they are

    not open to mediation, rather than because they disapprove of the mediator. This result challenges

    findings on the importance of trust in mediation occurrence (Kydd, 2003, 2005; Touval, 1975).

    Overall, we find robust support for the inverse effects that conditions have on mediation offers

    and their acceptance. Third parties appear to be more forthcoming with mediation offers when theconflict is intense; however, disputants are less willing to work with a third party when in a territo-

    rial conflict or when the dispute has escalated to a war. Similarly, while third parties view the

    Table 1.Summary statistics

    Variable Mean standard deviation Minimum Maximum

    Outcome variable

    Rejection 0.3366337 0.4749153 0 1

    Offer 0.0015689 0.0395784 0 1

    Explanatory variable

    Other Mediation 0.0129083 0.1128801 0 1

    War 0.0552527 0.2284745 0 1

    Territorial Conflict 0.0856206 0.2798052 0 1

    Power Difference 0.0858299 0.0728291 0 0.3586476

    Previous Dispute 0.8293335 0.3762202 0 1

    Historic Ties 0.0089007 0.0939234 0 1

    Regime Ties 0.0486509 0.2151388 0 1Alliance Ties 0.134924 0.341645 0 1

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    12/16

    364 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    presence of other mediators as an opportunity to burden-share or as a sign of compliant belliger-

    ents, other mediators give the disputants alternatives and make rejection more likely.

    In addition, we find substantial evidence that, when disputants reject mediation offers, they doso because they are not open to the mediation process at all and not because they do not approve of

    the mediator. This finding supports the arguments of the ripeness literature, which argues media-

    tion occurs when the disputants sense a conflict stalemate and see the improbability of winning

    (Zartman, 2000). In such cases, mediation is acceptable since it offers a viable alternative to con-

    tinued conflict. It seems that disputants are not as concerned with finding an acceptable and trust-

    worthy mediator.

    There is strong evidence that selection exerts powerful statistical effects (is significant, con-

    firming the need for a censored approach), suggesting that unobserved factors, such as dispute

    intensity, military stalemate and the inability of the belligerents to negotiate bilaterally, probably

    affect both mediation offers and rejections. More importantly, controlling for selection reveals the

    influence of key factors on mediation rejection, such as the presence of armed conflict, the nature

    of the dispute and the presence of ongoing mediation. Neglecting to control for selection effects

    leads to incorrect inferences about the mediation process. Modeling selection directly leads to

    drastic variation between our findings and those presented by other scholars (e.g. Greig (2005),

    who found that conditions jointly increase mediation offers and acceptance but did not employ a

    selection approach).

    Conclusion

    Mediation is a voluntary process. As a result, the occurrence of mediation is a symbol of success.It signals openness to options beyond conflict. Indeed, often a back-and-forth takes place before

    mediation can even begin. The act of accepting a mediator might be seen as a concession, requiring

    Table 2. Censored Probit model of mediation offers and rejections 19461999

    Rejection Offer

    Mediation characteristics

    Other Mediation 0.0247 (0.1581)

    Conflict characteristicsTerritorial Conflict 0.6335*** (0.1470) 0.5210*** (0.1325)

    War 0.5537*** (0.1723) 0.6404*** (0.1636)

    Previous Dispute 0.3292*** (0.1032)

    Power Difference 1.4870* (0.8848)

    Relationship characteristics

    Historic Ties 0.3555 (0.3268)

    Regime Ties 0.1359 (0.1432)

    Alliance Ties 0.1301 (0.1945)

    Constant 3.4987*** (0.1417) 2.8717*** (0.0891)

    2.2786** (0.9302)Total observations 64,377

    Uncensored observations 101Log-likelihood 756.3251

    Robust standard errors in parentheses.*** p< 0.01, ** p< 0.05, * p< 0.1.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    13/16

    Melin et al. 365

    discussion regarding what the mediator is allowed to do, what resources the mediator will have and

    who will mediate. Disputants and mediators both deal with mediation strategically, but their stra-

    tegic behavior pulls them in opposing directions. Although severe conflicts signal possible gains in

    reputation for mediators, they also reflect that belligerents are less likely to work for peace. Thus,

    the very characteristics that make third parties more forthcoming with offers of mediation are also

    those that make disputants more likely to reject them.

    Our research offers important insights into the complexities of the mediation environment.

    While the empirical literature focuses on mediation offers and occurrence, our findings suggest

    that this process is more dynamic. Observing the absence of dispute mediation suggests critical

    implications. It might mean that no third party offered to mediate or that an offer was made and

    rejected. Examination of these separate, but related, choices helps us to generate an improved

    theoretical and practical understanding of mediation. The challenge for third parties, who undoubt-

    edly would prefer to resolve conflicts before they become costly, is to convey to disputants the

    potential for high costs should the conflict continue. By clarifying the likely costs of conflict, a

    third party can help belligerents see the advantages of a mediator. Such information will probably

    increase the acceptability of mediation. These implications will not only generate circumstances

    under which disputants bring in a third-party mediator, but will probably also affect the outcomes

    of such mediation efforts. Mediation represents a complex, strategic process that integrates the

    preferences and interests of warring parties and potential peacemakers. This study contributes to

    our understanding of how this complicated and important mechanism works.

    AcknowledgementsA previous version of tis paper was presented to the Folke Bernadotte Academys Working Group on Conflict

    Prevention Workshop at Emory University in Atlanta, GA, December 5th2008. The authors would like to

    thank the members of the working group for their valuable feedback

    Funding

    This research was supported with funding from the Folke Bernadotte Academy.

    References

    Aall PR (2007) The power of nonofficial actors in conflict management. In: Crocker CA, Hampson FO and

    Aall PR (eds)Leashing the Dogs of War: Conflict Management in a Divided World. Washington, DC:

    United States Institute of Peace Press, pp. 477494.

    Abbott KW and Snidal D (1998) Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal ofConflict Resolution42 (1): 332.

    Allee TL and Huth PK (2006) Legitimizing dispute settlement: International legal rulings as domestic politi-

    cal cover.American Political Science Review100(2): 219234.

    Altfeld MF and Bueno de Mesquita B (1979) Choosing sides in war. International Studies Quarterly23(1):

    87112.

    Aydin A (2010) Where do states go? Strategy in civil war intervention. Conflict Management and Peace

    Science27(1): 4766.

    Beardsley K (2010) Pain, pressure, and political cover: Explaining mediation incidence. Journal of Peace

    Research47(4): 395406.

    Beardsley K (2011) The Mediation Dilemma. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Beardsley KC, Quinn DM, Biswas B and Wilkenfeld J (2006) Mediation style and crisis outcomes.Journalof Conflict Resolution50(1): 5886.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    14/16

    366 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    Bennett DS and Stam AC (2004) The Behavioral Origins of War. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan

    Press.

    Bercovitch J (1999) The International Conflict Management Dataset Codebook. Available from: http://www.

    posc.canterbury.ac.nz/jbercovitch/mediation.html

    Bercovitch J and Gartner SS (2006) Is there method in the madness of mediation: Some lessons for mediators

    from quantitative studies of mediation.International Interactions32: 329354.Bercovitch J and Houston A (1993) Influence of mediator characteristics and behavior on the success

    of mediation in international relations. The International Journal of Conflict Management 4(4):

    297321.

    Bercovitch J and Jackson R (2001) Negotiation or mediation? An exploration of factors affecting the choice

    of conflict management in international conflict.Negotiation Journal17(1): 5977.

    Bercovitch J and Schneider G (2000) Who mediates? The political economy of international conflict manage-

    ment.Journal of Peace Research37(2): 14565.

    Blainey G (1988) The Causes of War. Melbourne: Macmillan.

    Chigas D (2007) The capacities and limits of NGOs as conflict managers. In: Crocker CA, Hampson FO and

    Aall PR (eds) Leashing the Dogs of War: Conflict Management in a Divided World. Washington, DC:

    United States Institute of Peace Press, pp. 553581.Chiozza G and Choi A (2003) Guess who did what: Political leaders and the management of territorial dis-

    putes, 19501990.Journal of Conflict Resolution47(3): 251278.

    Crescenzi MJC, Kadera KM, Mitchell SM and Thyne CL (2011) A supply side theory of mediation.

    International Studies Quarterly55(4): 10691094.

    Drury C and Chan S (eds) (2000) Sanctions as Economic Statecraft: Theory and Practice. London: Palgrave

    Macmillan.

    Favretto K (2009) Should peacemakers take sides? Major power mediation, coercion and bias. American

    Political Science Review103(2): 248263.

    Frazier D and Dixon WJ (2006) Third-party intermediaries and negotiated settlements, 19462000.

    International Interactions32(4): 385408.

    Gartner SS (2011) Signs of trouble: Regional organization mediation and civil war agreement durability.Journal of Politics73(2): 380390.

    Gartner SS (2013) Deceptive results: Why mediation appears to fail but actually succeeds. The Penn State

    Journal of Law and International Affairs2(1): 2737.

    Gartner SS and Bercovitch J (2006) Overcoming obstacles to peace: The contributions of mediation to short-

    lived conflict settlements.International Studies Quarterly50(4): 819840.

    Gent S and Shannon M (2010) The effectiveness of international arbitration and adjudication: Getting into a

    bind.Journal of Politics72(2): 366380.

    Gilligan MJ and Sergenti EJ (2008) Do UN interventions cause peace? Using matching to improve causal

    inference. Quarterly Journal of Political Science3: 89122.

    Greig JM (2005) Stepping into the fray: When do mediators mediate?American Journal of Political Science

    49(2): 249266.Greig JM and Diehl PF (2005) The peacekeepingpeacemaking dilemma. International Studies Quarterly

    49(4): 621645.

    Greig JM and Diehl PF (2006) Softening up: Making conflicts more amenable to diplomacy.International

    Interactions32(4): 355384.

    Greig JM and Regan P (2008) When do they say yes? An analysis of the willingness to offer and accept

    mediation in civil wars.International Studies Quarterly52(4): 759781.

    Hansen HE, Mitchell SM and Nemeth SM (2008) IO mediation of interstate conflicts: Moving beyond the

    global vs. regional dichotomy.Journal of Conflict Resolution52(2): 295325.

    Hensel PR, Mitchell SM, Sowers TE and Thyne CL (2008) Bones of contention.Journal of Conflict Resolution

    52(1): 117143.

    Huth PK (1996) Enduring rivalries and territorial disputes, 19501990. Conflict Management and PeaceScience15(1): 741.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    15/16

    Melin et al. 367

    Huth PK (1998) Standing Your Ground: Territorial Disputes and International Conflict. Ann Arbor, MI:

    University of Michigan

    Huth PK (2000) Territory: Why are territorial disputes between states a central cause of international conflict?

    In: Vasquez JA (ed.) What do We Know about War?Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 85110.

    Huth PK and Allee TL (2002) The Democratic Peace and Territorial Conflict in the Twentieth Century .

    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Kathman J (2010) Civil war contagion and neighboring interventions.International Studies Quarterly54(4):

    9891012.

    Kleiboer M (1996) Understanding success and failure of international mediation. Journal of Conflict

    Resolution40(2): 360389.

    Kydd A (2003) Which side are you on? Bias, credibility, and mediation. American Journal of Political

    Science47(4): 597611.

    Kydd A (2005) Trust and Mistrust in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Leeds BA, Ritter JM, Mitchell SM and Long AG (2002) Alliance treaty obligations and provisions, 1815

    1944.International Interactions28(3): 237260.

    Lemke D and Regan PM (2004) Interventions as influence. In: Diehl PF (ed.) The Scourge of War: New

    Extensions on an Old Problem. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press, pp. 145168.Leng R (2000)Bargaining and Learning in Reccurring Crises: The SovietAmerican, EgyptianIsraeli, and

    IndoPakistani Rivalries. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Lieb D (1985) Iran and Iraq at Algiers, 1975. In: Touval S and Zartman IW (eds)International Mediation in

    Theory and Practice. Boulder, CO: Westview.

    Maoz Z (1996)Domestic Sources of Global Change. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Maoz Z (2005)Dyadic MID Dataset (version 2.0). Available at: http://psfaculty.ucdavis.edu/zmaoz/dyadmid.

    html

    Marshall MG and Jaggers K (2002) Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions,

    18002002. Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.

    Available at: http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/index.htm

    Maundi MO, Zartman IW, Khadiagala G and Nuamah K (2006) Getting In: Mediators Entry into theSettlement of African Conflicts. Washington, DC: United Institute of Peace Press.

    Melin M (2011) The impact of state relationship on if, when and how conflict management occurs.

    International Studies Quarterly55(3): 691715.

    Melin M and Koch M (2010) Jumping into the fray: Alliances, power, institutions, and the timing of conflict

    expansion.International Interactions36(1): 127.

    Melin M and Svensson I (2009) Incentives for talking: Accepting mediation in international and civil wars.

    International Interactions35(3): 249271.

    Mitchell CR (1993) External peace-making initiatives and intra-national conflict. In: Midlarsky MI (ed.) The

    Internationalization of Communal Strife. London: Routledge.

    Mitchell SM (2002) A Kantian system? Democracy and third-party conflict resolution. American Journal of

    Political Science46(4): 749759.Mitchell SM, Kadera KM and Crescenzi MJC (2008) Practicing democratic community norms: Third party

    conflict management and successful settlements. In: Bercovitch J and Gartner SS (eds) International

    Conflict Mediation: New Approaches and Findings. London: Routledge.

    Mitchell SM and Powell EJ (2011)Domestic Law Goes Global: Legal Traditions and International Courts.

    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press

    Nooruddin I (2002) Modeling selection bias in studies of sanctions efficacy.International Interactions28(1):

    5975.

    Olson M and Pearson FS (2002) Civil war characteristics, mediators, and resolution. Conflict Resolution

    Quarterly19(4): 421445.

    Rauchhaus RW (2006) Asymmetric information, mediation, and conflict management. World Politics58(2):

    207241.

  • 8/13/2019 Conflict Management and Peace Science 2013 Melin 354 68

    16/16

    368 Conflict Management and Peace Science30(4)

    Regan PM and Aydin A (2006) Diplomacy and other forms of intervention in civil wars. Journal of Conflict

    Resolution50(5): 736756.

    Regan PM and Stam AC (2000) In the nick of time: Conflict management, mediation timing, and the duration

    of interstate disputes.International Studies Quarterly44(2): 239260.

    Rost N and Greig JM (2011) Taking matters into their own hands: An analysis of the determinants of state-

    conducted peacekeeping in civil wars.Journal of Peace Research48(2): 171184.Savun B (2008) Information, bias and mediation success.International Studies Quarterly52(1): 2547.

    Shannon M (2009) Preventing war and providing the peace? International organizations and the management

    of territorial disputes. Conflict Management and Peace Science26(2): 144163.

    Sick G (1985) The partial negotiator: Algeria and the US hostages in Iran. In: Touval S and Zartman IW (eds)

    International Mediation in Theory and Practice. Boulder, CO: Westview, pp. 2166.

    Siverson RM and Starr H (1991) The Diffusion of War: A Study of Opportunity and Willingness. Ann Arbor,

    MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Slantchev BL and Tarar A (2010) Mutual optimism as a rationalist explanation of war. American Journal of

    Political Science55(1): 135148.

    Sullivan P (2007) War aims and war outcomes: Why powerful states lose limited wars. Journal of Conflict

    Resolution51(3): 496524.Svensson I (2006) Elusive peacemakers: A bargaining perspective on mediation in internal armed conflicts.

    Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala University, Uppsala.

    Svensson I and Wallensteen P (2010) The Go Between: Jan Eliasson and the Styles of Mediation. Washington,

    DC: United States Institute of Peace Press.

    Terris LG and Maoz Z (2005) Rational mediation: A theory and a test. Journal of Peace Research42(5):

    563583.

    The Correlates of War 2 Project (n.d.) Colonial/Dependency Contiguity Data, 18162002. Version 3.0.

    Available from: http://correlatesofwar.org

    Touval S (1975) Biased intermediaries: Theoretical and historical considerations. The Jerusalem Journal of

    International Relations1(1): 5169.

    Touval S (2003) Mediation and foreign policy.International Studies Review5(4): 9195.Touval S and Zartman IW (1996) International mediation in the post-Cold War era. In: Crocker C, Hampson

    FO and Aall P (eds) Turbulent Peace: The Challenges of Managing International Conflict. Washington,

    DC: United States Institute of Peace Press.

    Wedgwood R (1998) The enforcement of Security Council Resolution 687: The threat of force against Iraqs

    weapons of mass destruction.American Society of International Law92(4): 724728.

    Wehr P and Lederach JP (1991) Mediating conflict in Central America. Journal of Peace Research28(1):

    8598.

    Werner S and Lemke D (1997) Opposites do not attract: The impact of domestic institutions, power, and prior

    commitments on alignment choices.International Studies Quarterly41(3): 529546.

    Wiegand KE (2011) Militarized territorial disputes: States attempts to transfer reputation for resolve. Journal

    of Peace Research48(1): 101113.Wiegand KE and Powell EJ (2001) Past experience, quest for the best forum, and peaceful attempts to resolve

    territorial disputes.Journal of Conflict Resolution55(1): 3359.

    Wilkenfeld J, Young K, Asal V and Quinn D (2003) Mediating international crises: Cross-national and exper-

    imental perspectives. The Journal of Conflict Resolution47(3): 279301.

    Zartman IW (2000) Ripeness: The hurting stalemate and beyond. In: Stern P and Druckman D (eds)

    International Conflict Resolution after the Cold War. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Zartman IW and Touval S (1992) Mediation: The role of third-party diplomacy and informal peacemaking.

    In: Brown S and Schraub KM (eds) Resolving Third World Conflict. Washington, DC: US Institute of

    Peace Press, pp. 241261.