BlackScholes Handouts

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 BlackScholes Handouts

    1/4

    Mathematical Methods for Financial Markets

    by M. Jeanblanc, M. Yor and M. Chesney

    Springer Verlag 2009, Chapter 2.

    Definition 1.4.1.1

    The continuous process X is said to be a standard Brownian motion, if:

    1. The process X has stationary and independent increments

    2. For any t > 0, the r.v. Xt follows the N(0, t) law

    3. X0 = 0

    2.3.1 The Model

    The Black and Scholes model assumes that there is a riskless asset with interestrate r and that the dynamics of the price of the underlying asset are

    dSt = St(dt + dBt)

    under the historical probability P. Here, the risk-free rate r, the trend and thevolatility are supposed to be constant (note that, for valuation purposes, maybe an F-adapted process). In other words, the value at time t of the risky asset is

    St = S0 exp(t + Bt 2

    2 t).

    Indeed, by applying Itos lemma to the function ln():

    d ln(St) =1

    StdSt +

    1

    2

    1

    S2t

    2S2t dt =

    2

    2

    dt + Bt

    Proposition 2.3.1.2

    In the Black and Scholes model, there exists a unique e.m.m. Q, precisely Q|Ft =exp(Bt 122t)P|Ft where = r is the risk-premium. The risk-neutral dy-namics of the asset are

    dSt = St(rdt + dWt)

    where W is a Q-Brownian motion.

    Theorem 2.3.2.1 Black and Scholes formula:

    Let dSt = St(dt + dBt) be the dynamics under the historical probability P ofthe price of a risky asset and assume that the interest rate is a constant r. Thevalue at time t of a European call with maturity T and strike K is CE(x, t) where

    CE(x, t) = xN

    d1

    x

    Ker(Tt), T t

    (1)

    Ker(Tt)Nd2 xKer(Tt)

    , T t1

  • 8/3/2019 BlackScholes Handouts

    2/4

    where N(di) =di

    12

    e1

    2y2dy for i = 1, 2

    d1(y, u) = 12u

    ln(y) + 122u, d2(y, u) = d1(y, u) 2u ,

    where we have written

    2 so that the formula does not depend on the sign of .

    Proof:

    Let (, ) be a replicating portfolio and

    Vt = tCt + tSt

    We assume that the value of this portfolio satisfies the self-financing condition, i.e.,

    dVt = tdCt + tdSt

    Then, assuming that Ct is a smooth function of the underlying value and of time,i.e., Ct = C(St, t), by relying on Itos lemma the differential of V is obtained:

    dVt = t(xCdSt + tCdt +1

    22S2t xxCdt) + tdSt ,

    where tC (resp. xC ) is the derivative of C with respect to the second variable(resp. the first variable) and where all the functions C, xC , . . . are evaluated at

    (St, t). From t = (Vt tSt)/Ct, we obtaindVt = ((Vt tSt)(Ct)1xC + t)StdBt (2)

    +

    Vt tSt

    Ct

    tC+

    1

    22S2t xxC+ StxC

    + tSt

    dt.

    If this replicating portfolio is risk-free, one has dVt = Vtrdt: the martingale parton the right-hand side vanishes, which implies

    t = (StxC Ct)1 VtxC

    and Vt tStCt

    tC+

    1

    22S2t xxC+ StxC

    + tSt = rVt . (3)

    Using the fact that txC + t = 0, i.e.

    (Vt tSt)(Ct)1xC + t = 0

    we obtain that the term which contains , i.e.,

    St

    Vt St

    CtxC+ t

    2

  • 8/3/2019 BlackScholes Handouts

    3/4

    vanishes. After simplifications, we obtain

    rC = 1 + StxCC StxCtC+ 122x2xxC (4)=

    C

    C StxC

    tC+1

    22x2xxC

    (5)

    and therefore the PDE evaluation

    tC(x, t) + rxxC(x, t) +1

    22x2xxC(x, t)

    = rC(x, t), x > 0, t [0, T[ (6)is obtained. Now,

    t = VtxC(SxC Ct)1 = V0 N(d1)KerTN(d2)

    . (7)

    Note that the hedging ratio is

    tt

    = xC(St, t) .

    Reading carefully the Black and Scholes (1973) paper, The pricing of options andcorporate liabilities (Journal of Political Economy), it seems that the authors as-

    sume that there exists a self-financing strategy (1, t) such that dVt = rVtdt,which is not true, and the portfolio with value Ct + StN(d1) = Ker(Tt)N(d2)is not risk-free.

    The solution of the PDE (eq. (6)) with terminal condition

    C(x, T) = (x K)+

    is the Black-Scholes formula.

    Final comment: Another way to find the solution is to compute the conditionalexpectation under the equivalent martingale measure of the discounted terminal

    payoff.

    In a Black and Scholes model, the price of a European option is given by:

    CE(S0, T) = EQ(erT(ST K)1{STK}) (8)

    = EQ(erTST1{STK}) erTKQ(ST K). (9)

    Hence, ifk = 1

    ln(K/x) (r 1

    22)T

    , using the symmetry of the Gaussian law,

    one obtains

    Q(ST K) = Q(WT k) = Q(WT k) = N

    d2

    x

    KerTwhere the function d2 is given in Theorem 2.3.2.1.3

  • 8/3/2019 BlackScholes Handouts

    4/4

    From the dynamics of S, one can write:

    erTEQ(ST1{STK}) = S0EQ1{WTk} exp(22 T + WT) .The process (exp(2

    2t + Wt), t 0) is a positive Q-martingale with expectation

    equal to 1. Let us define the probability Q by its Radon-Nikodym derivative withrespect to Q:

    Q|Ft = exp(2

    2t + Wt)Q|Ft .

    Hence,erTEQ(ST1{STK}) = S0Q

    (WT k) .

    Girsanovs theorem implies that the process (Wt = Wtt,t 0) is a Q-Brownianmotion. Therefore,erTEQ(ST1{STK}) = S0Q

    ((WT T) k T) (10)= S0Q

    WT k + T , (11)

    i.e.,

    erTEQ(ST1{STK}) = S0N

    d1

    xKerT

    .

    The Greeks:

    The greeks for a European call option are given by:

    =CEx

    = N(d1) > 0

    =2CEx2

    =(d1)

    x

    T t > 0

    = CEr

    = K(T t)er(Tt)N(d2) > 0

    =CE

    t= x(d1)

    2

    T t rKer(Tt)

    N(d2) < 0

    V =CE

    = x(d1)

    T t > 0

    where (x) = 1

    2e

    x2

    2 is the density for a standard normal

    random variable.

    4