33
The Politics of Vertical Integration in Extractive Industries: Business History and Political Economy Marcelo Bucheli University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, College of Business Abstract The process of vertical integration by multinational corporations in the extractive sector of poor countries is not only an economic process, but also a political one affected by the host country’s social and political dynamics, the relationship between host country and home country, and the relationship between the multinational and the home country. This essay argues that some of these complexities cannot be fully captured by the quantitative methodology that currently dominates the social sciences, but rather require a detailed historical case analysis. I illustrate this by studying cases of the banana and the nitrate industries in the 19th and 20th centuries in Latin America. Published: 2007 URL: http://www.business.uiuc.edu/Working_Papers/papers/07-0112.pdf

The Politics of Vertical Integration in Extractive Industries: Business History and Political Economy

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

The Politics of Vertical Integration in Extractive Industries:Business History and Political Economy

Marcelo BucheliUniversity of Illinois at Urbana−Champaign, College of Business

Abstract

The process of vertical integration by multinational corporations in the extractive sector ofpoor countries is not only an economic process, but also a political one affected by the hostcountry’s social and political dynamics, the relationship between host country and homecountry, and the relationship between the multinational and the home country. This essayargues that some of these complexities cannot be fully captured by the quantitativemethodology that currently dominates the social sciences, but rather require a detailedhistorical case analysis. I illustrate this by studying cases of the banana and the nitrateindustries in the 19th and 20th centuries in Latin America.

Published: 2007URL: http://www.business.uiuc.edu/Working_Papers/papers/07−0112.pdf

1

The Politics of Vertical Integration in Extractive Industries:

Business History and Political Economy

Marcelo Bucheli Assistant Professor of Business History Department of Business Administration

College of Business University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

United States of America Phone: 1- 217- 244-0208

Fax: 1- 217-244-7969 E-mail: [email protected]

2

The Politics of Vertical Integration in Extractive Industries: Business History and Political Economy

Abstract

The process of vertical integration by multinational corporations in the extractive sector

of poor countries is not only an economic process, but also a political one affected by the

host country’s social and political dynamics, the relationship between host country and

home country, and the relationship between the multinational and the home country.

This essay argues that some of these complexities cannot be fully captured by the

quantitative methodology that currently dominates the social sciences, but rather require a

detailed historical case analysis. I illustrate this by studying cases of the banana and the

nitrate industries in the 19th and 20th centuries in Latin America.

Keywords: Business History, Vertical Integration, Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment, Banana Industry, Nitrate Industry

3

Introduction

Over the last two decades, the world has witnessed intensified activity of the

multinational corporations operating in the extractive sector of less developed countries.

Several key factors have renewed attention to the political relations of extractive

multinationals: the dramatic increase in demand for commodities by the Indian and

Chinese economies, the rise of better-funded and better-organized non-governmental

organizations monitoring the human and environmental costs of the multinationals’

operations in poor countries, and the emergence of a new economic nationalism among

important oil and gas producers such as Venezuela, Russia, and Bolivia. The political

issues currently affecting the extractive multinationals’ operations in the Third World are

not the result of overnight decisions made by governments, but rather are the product of

complex political and social developments emerging over extended time periods. Thus,

the analysis of a multinational firm operating in the extractive sector in less developed

countries will be quite incomplete if it neglects the political and historical component.

Although this might read like a non-controversial and obvious remark, recent

decades have not shown much dialogue among historians, political economists, and

scholars studying international business. Several scholars have called on academics in

international business to place the State back into the center of their analyses (Jeffrey,

1980; Boddewyn, 1998; Scokpol, 1985; Murtha and Lenway, 1994), while others have

made a call to bring history back into the analysis of international business (Jones and

Khanna, 2006). Some of the more relevant recent contributions on the political economy

of foreign direct investment come from scholars using sophisticated quantitative methods

with aggregate data to analyze world trends rather than analyzing cases of individual

4

firms in particular countries (e.g., Jensen, 2003, 2005; Henisz, 2000). These works, how-

ever, face an important constraint: by using quantitative methods with mega-databases

for dozens of countries and hundreds of companies, they require large amounts of reliable

data, which is typically scarce in less-developed countries. Moreover, even for OECD

countries these databases usually cover relatively short time periods, whereas vertical

integration investments are usually long-term, and international politics are determined

by historical trends. Finally, and most importantly, as this paper maintains, individual

firms have responded in different ways to similar challenges, so research studies using

mega-databases will hardly capture the managers’ strategic responses to political events

or political regimes. By using historical case studies, this research paper brings together

the achievements of business history and international political economy for a more

complete analysis of vertical integration in international business.

An important analytical tool that is widely utilized in research studies of political

economy of foreign direct investment is the Polity IV database, which defines the degree

of democracy or totalitarianism of the countries they analyze. Polity IV is a remarkable

intellectual achievement that has put together and defined the political systems of all

countries of the world for a period of two centuries, giving a numerical score to each

political system depending on how competitive it is or not. Yet as the cases of the banana

and nitrate industries studied below show, if only using Polity IV scores, we get a skewed

picture of the ways in which different political regimes have responded to foreign capital.

This paper shows the case of a company (United Fruit), which virtually included the host

country state as a whole within its vertically integrated structure. In some historical

moments, the company even created the dictatorships, who ruled the countries where it

5

operated. Therefore, the State and the company were not two entities that developed

independently and eventually met and negotiated the terms of operations. If we were to

rely on Polity scores alone, whose methodology essentially separate types of government

from foreign investment, we would not be able to discern that foreign capital sometimes

pushed to create the political systems under which they could operate more favorably.

Some dictatorships supported by United Fruit had a Polity IV score similar to other

dictatorships that were more independent, and the ways they related to the company were

clearly different. After studying United Fruit, I turn to the case of the British companies

working in the Chilean nitrate sector. Although they came from the same home country

and operated in the same industry, their relationships with the government were not the

same.

This paper proposes an historical analysis of vertical integration in the banana and

nitrate industries using a conceptual framework organized around recent achievements in

the political economy of foreign direct investment. I argue that vertical integration by

multinational corporations in the extractive sector of poor countries is largely a

historically determined political process whose complexities require detailed analysis of

individual firms and the home and host countries’ polities. The key factors that affect a

firm’s decision to politically integrate, or not, include the political influence of the

multinational’s home country in the host country’s politics, the presence of a national

elite involved in the extractive sector in which the multinational is investing in, and the

sociological changes the host country experiences over time. I show that if a firm has a

disproportionately high economic influence in the host country the vertical integration

not only includes market elements, but also non-market, or political factors. Indeed, the

6

government of a host country with a small economy and with high dependence on the

multinational’s operations may itself become incorporated into the company’s structure.

The integration of a government within the company has proved easier under totalitarian

regimes than under democratic ones. However, this association can change with time if

social forces in the host country force a disintegration of the political system from the

company’s structure.

In past years, business scholars have relied increasingly on aggregate economic

and political data for studying the politics of international business. Yet, as the current

essay emphasizes, relying exclusively upon this methodology at the expense of case

studies can lead to inaccurate analyses. Wide-scale data analysis must, when possible, be

complemented with qualitative, historically grounded case studies in order to grasp the

internal particularities of the firm and the complexities of host countries.

Methodology

I propose an historical analysis of the role played by politics in vertical integration

in the banana and nitrate industries during the 19th and 20th centuries. Following Scokpol

(1985) and Gilpin (2001) I assume the State to operate not only as a political actor, but

also as an economic one. Similarly, I assume the multinational enterprise to be a political

and economic actor. The State can generate the conditions to permit a higher or lower

transfer of wealth from the multinational to the local society (Lipsey, 2002). This ability,

however, depends on the strength of the local institutions and the relative power

differential between the multinational and the local state. This study also assumes that a

State government can be considered a cost the company can minimize (Boddewyn, 1988;

Brewer, 1993, Boddewyn and Brewer, 1994). Finally, this paper assumes that the

7

company’s organizational structure (vertically integrated or not) is determined not only

by the economics of the firm but also by the negotiations between the company and the

host state (Gomes-Casseres, 1990).

The economics of vertical integration

During the twentieth century, the question of why and when some firms decide to

integrate their operations by putting under the same roof different stages of the value

chain was answered in different ways. Scholars like Coase (1937) and Williamson (1971,

1981, 1985) explained vertical integration as a strategy by which firms sought to reduce

the uncertainties of the market and transaction costs involved in the different stages of the

value chain. Chandler’s (1977) pioneering business historical studies explained vertical

integration as a necessary step towards the creation of the modern big business enterprise.

The creation of a mass market in the United States was only possible through the creation

of hierarchical, coordinated, vertically integrated, gigantic corporations. This integration

required completely new managerial organizations, resulting in the creation of the multi-

divisional enterprise in the early twentieth century.

This analysis was expanded by Dunning (1971) to explain the existence of multi-

national corporations. According to Dunning (1971), when a firm vertically integrates its

operations, it is internalizing otherwise external markets, endowing it with a power its

competitors did not have (what he defined as internalization advantages). Casson and

Buckley (1976) add the concept of transaction costs to Dunning’s (1971) analysis, and

maintain that vertical integration responds to the specific technical particularities of the

industry in which the firm operates. Some industries require closer coordination than

8

others, and effective coordination is more difficult when operating between different

countries.

International politics and vertical integration

Dunning (1971), and Casson and Buckley (1976) acknowledge the relevance of

politics (in the host and home country) but do not make them a central element of their

analysis. During the 1970s, in the midst of heated debates around the expropriation of

foreign property by Third World governments, scholars began to place politics and

history at the center of analysis of the operations of vertically-integrated multinationals.

The first group was comprised of scholars writing from business schools; the second

group, from within the disciplines of history and sociology.

Obsolescing bargaining power The best scholarly representatives of the business school group are Raymond

Vernon and Louis Wells, who developed the concept of “obsolescing bargaining power”

to describe the situation multinational corporations face after investing in the extractive

industries: with an investment in fixed assets already made, they maintain, the multi-

national faces an increasingly vulnerable bargaining position with respect to the host

government (Vernon, 1971a, 1971b; Wells, 1977; Fagre and Wells, 1982). For business

school scholars, the nationalization wave of the 1970s was a rational move by the host

governments because they had already acquired the knowledge the multinationals could

provide them and as a result they no longer needed the multinationals (Kobrin, 1980,

1984; Minor, 1994).

9

Dependency Theory

The second intellectual tradition was Dependency Theory, which linked the

expansion of multinational corporations with the creation of economic imperialism.

Following contributions by Lenin ([1916] 1970), Baran and Sweezy (1968), and

Wallerstein (1979), Dependency Theory scholars saw the multinational corporation as

one of the many arms of domination of the world’s economic powers over poor countries

(Castells, 1973; Frank, 1971; Dos Santos, 1973; Cardoso and Faletto, 1979; Evans,

1979). In this way, vertical integration was one of the means by which world powers

assured their economic dominance of the host country.

Political Economy of FDI since the 1990s Dependency theory flourished in the 1970s and 1980s, but faced a crisis in the

1990s partly as a result of the Latin American debt crisis and the adoption of free-market

policies in the Third World. This change left a vacuum on historical studies of the

political economy of multinational corporations in the Third World. The interest in the

political economy of foreign direct investment was revived by a new generation of

scholars who relied heavily on quantitative methods to study the relationship between

democracy, dictatorship and foreign direct investment. Following North (1990), some of

them found that democratic regimes in which the government could not change the rules

at its will, created a better environment for foreign investors (Henisz, 2000; Feng, 2001;

Jensen, 2003, 2005, 2006), others found that multinationals benefited from repressive

governments (Oneal, 1994; London and Ross, 1995; Durham, 1999; Ross, 2001; Barndt,

Gerring, Bond and Moreno, 2005), and others found that the stability of the regime

(either democracy or dictatorship) is more important for foreign investors than the type of

10

regime (Clague, Keefer, Knack, and Olson, 1996, Li and Filer, 2007). Regarding the

specific issue of vertical integration, research studies by Boddewyn (1988), Brewer

(1993), and Boddewyn and Brewer (1994) made important contributions by introducing

politics into Dunning’s (1971) internalization theory, maintaining that the host country’s

political system generates transaction costs that the firm will want to minimize. One way

to do so is by internalizing the government, something possible for some large firms in

small poor countries. Frynas (1998) found that firms operating in the extractive industries

that internalize the local government will not benefit from a more pluralistic system,

while other scholars maintain that foreign direct investment in extractive industries tend

to generate more political instability and violence (Kobrin, 1979; Karl, 1997; Le Billion,

2001; Alfaro, 2003; Li and Mihalache, 2006).

The Banana Republics: Vertical integration and dictatorships

The banana sector provides an excellent example of the vertical integration of the

local polities within the structure of the foreign company itself. In the banana sector a

single company (the United Fruit) dominated most of the market. The need for a close

and coordinated control of the industry led the company to build a vertically-integrated

network from the Caribbean Basin to the United States that included plantations, rail-

ways and ships, a process facilitated by the particular political conditions of the region

(US-dominated and ruled by dictators). Previous studies of United Fruit’s vertical

integration used the Chandlerian paradigm to explain the company’s integration process

(Read, 1983): the company integrated backward and forward to create a mass market of

bananas in the United States. Although this interpretation is correct, its neglect of politics

does not permit us to understand why the company vertically de-integrated in the 1960s.

11

In what follows, I show that the enormous power the company had in the region during

the pre-WWII period permitted it to informally integrate local polities within its vertically

integrated structure. The company had to abandon its vertical structure in the 1960s,

when it could no longer control the region’s local polities.

Creating the Banana Empire in the American “Mare Nostrum”

The creation and growth of the banana industry was led by United Fruit Company

(established in 1899 in Boston), considered the first and most successful firm at vertically

integrating its operations in the agricultural sector at the international level (Wilkins,

1974). Imports of bananas to the United States started in the 1860s, but most companies

failed to remain in business because of the very nature of bananas: they rot quickly, they

require careful handling, and they cannot be stored or frozen, so a close coordination

between producers, transporters, and retailers was crucial. This lack of coordination led

to a very high mortality rate among the banana companies: from 114 banana companies

established between 1870 and 1899, only 22 survived by 1899 (Read, 1983).

The problem of coordination in the banana industry was solved after the creation

of United Fruit. The company was the result of a merger between the businesses of US

entrepreneurs Minor C. Keith and Andrew Preston, whose interests complemented each

other perfectly: Keith owned lands and an extensive railway line in Central America, and

controlled the US South West banana market; Preston, on the other hand, owned the

Great White Fleet (which eventually became the largest privately owned steamship fleet

in the world), plantations in the West Indies, and controlled the US North East banana

market (May and Plaza, 1958). By the 1920s, the company had an extensive network of

plantations (which included housing, schools, and hospitals), railways, and the Tropical

12

Radio & Telegraph Company to keep in constant communication with its ships and

plantations (Wilkins, 1970, 1974; Taylor, 2003; Bucheli, 2005). The company also

integrated forward by acquiring the Hamburg Line and the British banana company

Fyffes to market the fruit in Europe and by establishing the Fruit Dispatch Company to

distribute and market bananas in the United States (Bucheli and Read, 2006; Jenkins,

2000). Until the late 1950s, United Fruit controlled 70% of the US banana market

(Bucheli, 2005).

The polities of the region also played an important role in United Fruit’s vertical

integration process. Its expansion coincided with the consolidation of the United States

as the main political and economic power in the Caribbean Basin. The small and

impoverished Central American republics adopted accommodating policies towards the

United States and competed with each other for American capital and political approval

(Coatsworth, 1994). They also had convincing negative incentives to not challenge

American power: before 1945, the United States had already invaded Honduras (in 1903,

1907, 1912, 1919, and 1924), the Dominican Republic (1903, 1914, 1916), Haiti (1914,

1915), Nicaragua (1907, 1909, 1915), Cuba (1906, 1912, 1917), Panama (1912, 1918,

1925), Guatemala (1920), and El Salvador (1922) (Coatsworth, 1994). The Caribbean

had become an American Mare Nostrum, providing the US firms confidence to expand

their business in that region.

The Era of the Banana Republics Before WWII, the banana producing countries depended heavily on the US and

United Fruit. The percentage of exports to the United States of total exports was 49% for

Costa Rica, 27% for Guatemala, 87% for Honduras, and 94% for Panama. Moreover, the

13

percentage of bananas total exports was 50% for Costa Rica, 27% for Guatemala, 50%

for Honduras, and 65% for Panama (Bulmer-Thomas, 2003).

Political instability and the existence of totalitarian regimes facilitated United

Fruit’s operations in Central America. For the case of Honduras -- the quintessential

Banana Republic -- United Fruit benefited from acquiring the properties of Cuyamel

Company, a US corporation that got its banana concessions after financing a military

coup in that country in 1913. Before merging, United Fruit tried to eliminate Cuyamel

through a price war and by driving the Guatemalan government (where United Fruit had

its plantations) to the brink of war with Honduras over the control of the Montagua River

region, a place crucial for Cuyamel’s operations in 1917, and to an open war in 1929.

The conflict was settled by the US government, and in 1930 both companies agreed on

merging, with United Fruit inheriting Cuyamel’s concessions in Honduras (Dosal, 1993).

In 1930 and 1932, United Fruit faced its first big labor strikes in Honduras. The

strikes failed because of lack of organization and repressive measures by the government

(McCameron, 1983). In 1932 United Fruit financed the presidential campaign of Tiburcio

Carías, who became a dictator and ruled for sixteen years (Posas, 1993). During the first

years of Carías administration, United Fruit tried to compensate the losses generated by

the Great Depression by reducing wages and cutting prices paid to local providers. The

company’s action led the workers to strike, but United Fruit found in Carías a strong ally.

The president, who had banned the Communist Party, repressed the strike and permitted

the company to reduce wages (Bulmer-Thomas, 1987, 1993). In 1949, Carías retired and

appointed former United Fruit’s lawyer, Manuel Galvez, as his successor.

14

Between 1898 and 1921, one single dictator, Manuel Estrada, ruled Guatemala.

Between 1901 and 1904, he granted United Fruit a concession for transportation between

Guatemala and New Orleans, a 99-year railway construction and management

concession, and banana production concessions (Taracena, 1993). Estrada fell from

power in 1920 and was succeeded by a series of short-term rulers until 1931, when

General Jorge Ubico -- one of the most infamous Central American dictators -- took

power. After taking power, Ubico signed a contract with United Fruit in which the

company committed to build a port in exchange for land. However, by 1936 United Fruit

dropped the port project so as not to compete with its own railway. The port was never

built, but Ubico permitted the company to keep its land and not pay any reparations.

Ubico remained in power until 1945, and during this period he gave full support to

United Fruit when conflicting with its workers (Schlesinger and Kinzer, 1990; Gliejeses,

1991).

United Fruit also had a strong presence in Panama. Indeed, it built the telegraph

lines in a contract that committed the Panama government not to build more telegraph

infrastructure (Ricord, 1974).

United Fruit had a harder time controlling the more democratic government of

Costa Rica, but the country’s dependence on the company did not give the local

government much room for maneuvering. Before establishment of United Fruit, Minor

Keith (one of the company’s founders) was one of the most influential persons in Costa

Rica. Keith had successfully renegotiated Costa Rica’s foreign debt and had built the

country’s railway system, which permitted him to monopolize banana production

(Taracena, 1993). The concessions, however, were hardly criticized in Congress,

15

particularly by Ricardo Jimenez, who approached both the workers and the planters,

showing his support and promising a change in the policy towards United Fruit

(Chomsky, 1996). In 1910, Jimenez was elected president, but once in power, his

opposition to the company was neutralized by a United Fruit loan that permitted Costa

Rica pay its foreign debt. Jimenez was succeeded by a reformist president (Alfredo

Gonzalez, 1914-1917) who attempted to increase taxation to land owners and big

companies and was overthrown by a coup that started a short dictatorship (Taracena,

1993). In the 1930s, as a result of protests against United Fruit’s power in Costa Rica

from both the landowning elite and the working class, the government made some timid

reforms that forced United Fruit to allow local planters to work in the company’s lands

(Bulmer-Thomas, 1987; Chomsky, 1996).

Social Changes and Vertical De-integration The system created by United Fruit in the first half of the twentieth century started

to collapse in 1945. In that year, a military junta overthrew Guatemala’s Ubico, installing

a democratic system. The new government made important social reforms and legalized

union activity. In the 1951 presidential elections, Guatemalans elected Jacobo Arbenz,

who came with an ambitious social agenda, which included an agrarian reform to

distribute lands among poor peasants. This plan clashed with United Fruit’s and

Guatemalan landowners’ interests. In 1954, after long debates with the government, a

group of Army rebels backed by the United States ousted Arbenz (Schlesinger and

Kinzer, 1990; Gliejeses, 1991).

Even though Arbenz was defeated the company realized that the political

environment was changing: first, although the US government opposed Arbenz, it also

16

opposed United Fruit’s monopolistic practices. Second, Central American societies were

themselves changing: they had a larger nationalist middle class and more sophisticated

and demanding labor unions. Even the dictators and the US government were aware that

they had to adapt to the changing times to some degree by accepting social reforms. In

1959, the Cuban revolutionary government expropriated United Fruit’s lands and the

Costa Rican government passed a law that forced the company to increase wages.

Fearing a domino effect, institutional investors pressured the company to change its

strategy, something the company did by gradually divesting its lands and concentrating

its operations in international marketing (Bucheli, 2005).

The end of the close relationship between the Central American dictators and

United Fruit came with the 1973 oil shock. As net oil importers and with economies

heavily dependent on banana exports, the “Banana Republics” faced economic hardships

that led them to seek new sources of income. The banana-producing countries joined

forces and created an OPEC-style cartel called UPEB (Union of Banana Exporting

Countries), in which they agreed to increase taxes paid the multinationals, and to

facilitate greater local participation in the industry. United Fruit opposed this initiative

and threatened to interrupt its export operations, an attitude that only generated more

unity among UPEB’s members. By 1975, the company accepted the new terms from the

local governments, and informed the shareholders that the new agreements with the local

governments were going to mean higher taxes and fees, and less property in Central

America. The company added, however, that it “is proud of the long working relation-

ships it has had with the nations of Latin America. We look forward to continued

associations, which are mutually beneficial both to our company and to the peoples of the

17

nations in which we work. We further have pledged to those nations our support as a

responsible corporate citizen” (United Brands, 1975). Just one year after this pledge, the

Securities Exchange Commission discovered a bribery scheme organized by the company

in Central America to receive tax benefits. The SEC’s investigations led the company’s

president, Eli Black, to commit suicide. The company was involved in another scandal in

2007, when the US Department of Justice accused it of financing paramilitary terrorist

groups in Colombia.

Vertical Integration and Politics in the Banana Industry United Fruit followed a process of vertical integration of the banana industry and

the polities of the producing countries in the WWII period, but changes in the region’s

political environment reversed this process after the 1950s. The Polity IV scores for this

period for Guatemala vary between 1 (full dictatorship) and 3, and for Honduras between

3 and 5 (with 7 being the highest possible score for democracy). For the Honduran case,

the governments that challenged United Fruit in the 1970s have the same score as that of

Tiburcio Carías, hiding crucial differences among them. The lack of political channels

for the opposition was certainly similar, as were the countries’ dependence on banana

exports. However, the social changes were going and a close reading of the company’s

reports shows that United Fruit was very well aware of them (United Fruit Company,

various years). This perception however cannot be captured in quantitative scores, but

with a detailed analysis of the country and the firm over a long period of time.

18

The Nitrate Industry: Integration through Cartelization and Government Intervention

The British nitrate companies operating in Chile in the late 19th century and early

20th century faced a different situation from that of United Fruit in the Caribbean Basin.

First, although highly dependent on British markets, Chile was not subjected by Britain to

the semi-colonial status of the Central American republics vis-à-vis the United States.

Second, the industry was not dominated by a single foreign company, but by several of

them. And third, the Chilean government was more democratic than its Central

American counterparts. Polity IV gives the same score to all the Chilean governments in

this period; yet this score is unable to capture, as in the case of the banana industry, the

Chilean state’s divergent approaches to the nitrate sector. These circumstances limited

the firms’ capability to internalize its operations or to internalize politics in the way

United Fruit did in Central America. The companies’ strategy, instead, was to create a

producers’ cartel. This organization, however, did not manage to successfully challenge

the government, mainly because of the lack of mutual trust among the cartel members.

The Arrival of the British Firms in the Guano Era Before the nitrate boom the world’s main fertilizer was guano, and Peru was its

main producer since 1840. An industrializing and urbanizing Europe with limited land

demanded fertilizers for its countryside, making guano one of the great businesses of the

19th century (Miller and Greenhill, 2006). Contrary to many raw materials produced in

poor countries in the same period, guano was not privately owned. Shortly after its

discovery, the Peruvian government nationalized the mines and established a monopoly.

Firms willing to trade guano purchased it from the Peruvian government and marketed it

abroad (Greenhill and Miller, 1973; Miller, 1977).

19

The main company involved in the international trade of Peruvian guano was the

British firm Antony Gibbs and Sons. Gibbs established a very close relationship with the

Peruvian government through its guano activities. The unstable government of Peru was

in urgent need of cash and Gibbs’ operations became a good source of it. The purchase

contracts of guano with Gibbs were always conditioned by loans Gibbs would provide

the government at favorable rates. The Peruvian government paid back with its guano

sales. This operation freed the Peruvian government from negotiating loans abroad and

impeded a vertical integration of Gibbs’ operations in guano (Greenhill and Miller,

1973). The Peruvian opposition harshly criticized Gibbs’ strong influence in Peru’s

finances, and pressured the government to not sign more new contracts with Gibbs after

1861. Afterwards, the government marketed the guano directly with some consumer

markets (Miller and Greenhill, 2006)

In the 1860s, discoveries of nitrate mines in the Atacama Desert in Southern Peru

led to a rush of foreign investors in the region, particularly Chilean, British, and

Germans, including Gibbs and British entrepreneur John North. Privately owned nitrate

exports started to compete with the government-owned guano. So in 1872, the Peruvian

Congress started considering an expropriation of nitrate works, which private investors

opposed (Greenhill and Miller, 1973; Matthew, 1977; Amayo, 1988). In 1874, due to a

fall in the international nitrate prices and the Peruvian government’s desperate financial

situation, the government intervened in the sector, establishing a state monopoly in

charge of controlling production and amounts exported. Although this action is known as

the “expropriation” of nitrate, private companies were not expropriated, but rather

subjected to quotas established by the Peruvian government. Moreover, those companies

20

not interested in selling to the government were free not to join, but the falling prices

were an incentive to join. In addition, the government hired Gibbs to manage the scheme

(Greenhill and Miller, 1973). The foreign companies complained about the new taxes in

production and export; many of them, fearing expropriation, sold their properties to North

at very low prices (Blakemore, 2004).

The relationship between Gibbs and the government were not easy after the

creation of the quota system. While Gibbs wanted to sell the nitrates on world markets at

relatively low prices to stimulate demand, the Peruvian government wanted to sell it at

the highest price possible to maximize revenue. Gibbs also wanted the industry to be

concentrated in a few companies, while the government wanted to give concessions to

many. In the end, the high prices the Peruvian government wanted encouraged

competition from Bolivia and Chile, as well as the search of substitutes in Europe. By

1879, Gibbs and the government were on bad terms, and the contract was terminated

(Greenhill and Miller, 1973).

Around the same time, the government of neighboring Bolivia increased taxes in

the nitrate sector. Arguing that this tax increase violated an agreement previously signed

between Bolivia and Chile, Chile invaded Bolivia in 1879. Peru allied with Bolivia in the

War of the Pacific (1879-1884), in which Chile permanently annexed the Peruvian and

Bolivian nitrate territories.

The War of the Pacific and the Rise of the Nitrate Industry In 1881, before the armistice, anxious to show its sovereignty in the nitrate

regions, Chile dismantled the Peruvian expropriation and auctioned off the nitrate mines

and factories, generating a speculative rush among investors including Gibbs and North

21

(Monteon, 2003). The concentration of nitrate in foreign hands took place very quickly:

before the war 123 companies operated in the region, and after the war there were just

thirty; Chilean participation in production went from 10% in 1884, to none in 1886

(O’Brien, 1982). The Chilean elite did not oppose this process because they were for the

most part landowners who produced agricultural goods, and saw the nitrate mines as

consumers of their products (O’Brien, 1982).

The new political conditions led the companies to expand their operations.

Before the war Gibbs had focused on trading, but after the conflict it started investing in

nitrate production and finance (Jones, 2000). North quickly expanded his operations by

monopolizing the region’s water--a precious good in the Atacama Desert-- with his

Tarapaca Waterworks Company, and transportation with the Nitrate Railways Company

(Monteón, 2003). In addition, he established the Nitrate Provisions and Supply Company

to supply merchandise (foodstuffs and others) to the nitrate areas (O’Brien, 1982). With

time, North’s monopoly on transportation became a point of conflict between him, the

Chilean government, and Gibbs.

Cartels and Politics after the War of the Pacific Fluctuations in international prices led North, Gibbs, and the other producers to

organize themselves in cartels or “combinations,” which were created when prices fell

but dismantled when they rose again. The companies organized combinations in 1884-

87, 1891-94, 1896-97, 1901-06, and 1906-09 (Greenhill, 1977). The combinations had

several weaknesses: first, they were integrated backward, and not forward. Second,

nitrates had to compete with other goods on the world market like guano. And third, its

members did not trust each other, since there were frequent problems of cheating among

22

the smaller producers (Brown, 1963; Greenhill, 1977). However, the combination was the

best option possible for companies not fully integrated and without a monopoly in the

sector. In fact, Gibbs, Campbell and Co. (another British firm), and the smaller producers

resented North’s transportation monopoly (Blakemore, 1977; O’Brien, 1982). These facts

explain why the combination could not be permanent.

After the election of President Balmaceda in 1886, the government attacked

North’s transportation monopoly. A market-oriented economic nationalist, Balmaceda

wanted to increase Chilean participation in the nitrate sector (Amayo, 1988). The

members of the combination were divided regarding Balmaceda’s initiatives. North

opposed them and requested help from the British government, but Campbell and Gibbs

did not dislike the idea of breaking North’s transportation monopoly, and Campbell took

the opportunity to apply for a railway concession the government granted them. By

1888, Campbell and Gibbs were lobbying Balmaceda’s government to get new

concessions, while North lobbied the opposition and the British government (O’Brien,

1982). The British government rejected Balmaceda’s attacks on North, but the British

firms’ rivalry did not lead to an open attack against the president (Blakemore, 1977).

Balmaceda faced more open and hostile opposition from the Chilean elite, who did not

want the government to disturb the nitrate companies, the main customers of their

agricultural products (O’Brien, 1982).

The opposition accused Balmaceda of abusing his power, and in 1891 some

members of the navy rebelled, starting a civil war that ended with Balmaceda’s suicide

that year. During this brief conflict North and the British government unofficially

supported the triumphant rebel forces (Monteon, 1982, 2003). Despite the British

23

intervention, the new government was not a puppet of the foreign companies. After the

war the differences between the companies continued and the new government continued

opposing the railway monopoly and imposed new duties on nitrate exports. The

combinations created after the war faced as many challenges from the government as in

Balmaceda’s times (Brown, 1963). In the decade following the war, the Chilean

participation in production increased, as did the government’s income from nitrate

exports. The companies continued lobbying the government and creating and dismantling

combinations (Blakemore, 1977; Monteon 2003). In short, the existence of conflicting

interests among the companies did not permit a process of integration of the government

within any of the companies’ structures, despite North’s attempts to do so. Between 1892

and 1894, North sold his Chilean interests and reoriented his investments to rubber

ventures in the Congo (Monteon, 2003).

The Decline of the Nitrate Industry During the twentieth century, British investments in Chilean nitrates steadily

declined and to be replaced by those of Chilean and US corporations (Monteon, 1982).

Before World War I, however, these companies were making handsome profits thanks to

the organization of combinations and the protection of the nitrate sector by the

government (O’Brien, 1989). However, they increasingly shared this wealth with the

Chilean government and the local companies (Rippy, 1948; Monteon, 1982). Gibbs

remained in Chile during WWI, forming part of a cartel the Allies created to assure

nitrate production during the conflict (Centner, 1942). Since 1900, aware of a relative

technological stagnation in the industry that increased production costs, Gibbs decided to

abandon nitrate refining in Chile and focused its efforts on marketing (O’Brien, 1989).

24

The end of the war, however, generated a difficult crisis for the nitrate sector and,

therefore, in the Chilean economy: the cartel created by the allies was dismantled and

synthetic nitrate had been improved (Centner, 1942). By the end of the war, the number

of nitrate plants in Chile fell from 134 to 43. In the 1920s, the government tried to rescue

the sector through different kinds of interventions (including the unsuccessful creation of

new cartels and the creation of a state-owned nitrate company) and the participation of

American interests (like the Guggenheims and W. R. Grace) (McConnell, 1935). Before

the collapse of the nitrate sector after 1930, the Guggenheims approached Gibbs to form

a vertically integrated trust. Gibbs, however, rejected the idea, considering that it would

antagonize the Chilean government and would encourage more synthetic nitrate

production (O’Brien, 1989). In the 1930s, the Guggenheims focused their Chilean

operations in copper.

Foreign Investment and Nitrate Politics Political competition in the Chilean government and competition between the

foreign companies did not permit a vertical integration of the local polities by any single

company. Although Gibbs, Campbell, and North came from the same home country and

operated in the same sector, they had very different approaches to the national

government, something we could not have perceived by grouping them together as

British nitrate companies operating with a series of governments with a Polity score of

seven. In addition, Chile did not have the semi-colonial status with Britain the Central

American republics had with the US, so the companies used the local political lobbying

mechanisms to protect their interests.

25

Conclusions

Vertical integration in international business is a historically determined political

process. The political complexity of this process is greater when analyzing firms from

rich countries operating in the extractive sector of poor countries. No sector generates

more economic nationalism than the extractive sector in less developed countries. Nor

does any other sector require higher levels of investments in infrastructure by the foreign

company. In no moment in history, from the nineteenth century onward, has the entry of

foreign multinationals into poor countries been a smooth process, and the political

conditions of the twenty-first century do not show signals that this will change. Thus, an

accurate analysis of the operations of multinational companies in Third World countries

requires including the political element in a historical perspective.

The perceptions the companies have on the host country’s polities can hardly be

captured with quantitative methods. This argument is particularly warranted for long

periods of time in less developed countries where no quantitative information exists.

Many countries in the world still lack accurate quantitative information and their internal

political dynamics have not been fully understood by scholars, multinational managers,

or officials of multilateral institutions. A return to the case study that uses the

achievements of political science, international business, and business history are useful

for more sophisticated analyses of the present day expansion of multinational companies

in the extractive sector in less developed countries.

26

REFERENCES

Alfaro, L. (2003). ‘Foreign Direct Investment and Growth: Does the Sector Matter?’ MS, Harvard Business School. Amayo, A. (1988). La Política Británica en la Guerra del Pacífico. Lima: Horizonte. Baran, P. and Sweezy, P. (1968) Monopoly Capital. New York: Monthly Review Press. Barndt, W. T., Gerring, J. Bond, P. and Moreno, C. (2005). ‘Democracy and Economic Growth: A Historical Perspective’. World Politics, 57, 3, 323-364. Blakemore, H. (1977). Gobierno Chileno y salitre ingles, 1886-1896: Balmaceda y North. Santiago: Andres Bello. Blakemore, H. (2004) ‘North, John Thomas, 1842-1896’, Oxford Dictionary of National Biography. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Boddewyn, J. (1988). ‘Political Aspects of MNE Theory’. Journal of International Business Studies, 19, 3, 341-363. Boddewyn, J. and Brewer, T. (1994). ‘International Business Political Behavior: New Theoretical Directions’. Academy of Management Review, 19, 1, 119-143. Brewer, T. (1993). ‘Government Policies, Market Imperfection, and FDI’. Journal of International Business Studies, 24, 1, 101-120. Brown, J. R. (1963). ‘Nitrate Crisis, Combinations, and the Chilean Government in the Nitrate Age’. Hispanic American Historical Review, 43, 2, 230-246. Bucheli, M. (2005). Bananas and Business: The United Fruit Company in Colombia, 1899-2000. New York: New York University Press. Bucheli, M. and Read I. (2006). ‘Banana Boats and Baby Food: The Banana in US Industry’, in Topik, S., Marichal, C., and Frank, Z. (eds.). From Silver to Cocaine: Latin American Commodity Chains and the Building of the World Economy, 1500-2000. Durham: Duke University Press. Bulmer-Thomas, V. (2003). An Economic History of Latin America Since Independence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bulmer-Thomas, V. (1987). The Political Economy of Central America since 1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.

27

Bulmer-Thomas, V. (1993). ‘La crisis de la economía de agroexportación’, in Acuña, V. (ed.), Historia General de Centroamérica. Madrid: Sociedad Estatal Quinto Centenario. Cardoso, F. H. and Faletto E. (1979) Dependency and Development in Latin America. Berkeley: University of California Press. Casson, M. and Buckley P. (1976). The Future of the Multinational Corporation. New York: Holmes and Meyer. Castells, M. (1973). ‘Urbanización Dependiente en América Latina’, in M. Schteingartd (ed.), Urbanización y Dependencia. Buenos Aires: Nueva Visión. Centner, C. W. (1942). ‘Great Britain and Chilean Mining, 1830-1914.’ The Economic History Review, 12, 1-2, 76-82. Chandler, A. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Chomsky, A. (1996). West Indian Workers and the United Fruit Company in Costa Rica, 1870-1940. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press. Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S., and Olson, M. (1996) “Property and Contract Rights in Autocracies and Democracies,” Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 2, 243-276 Coase, R. (1937). “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, 4, 16, 386-405. Coatsworth, J. (1994). Central America and the United States: The Clients and the Colossus. New York: Twayne. Dos Santos, Theotonio (1973). Imperialismo y empresas multinacionales. Buenos Aires: Galerna. Dosal, P. (1993). Doing Business with the Dictators: A Political History of United Fruit in Guatemala, 1899-1944. Wilmington: Scholarly Resources. Dunning, J. (1971). The Multinational Enterprise. London: Allen and Unwin. Durham, B. (1999). ‘Economic growth and political regimes’. Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 3, 81-111. Evans, P. (1979) Dependent Development. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Fagre N. and Wells L. (1982). ‘Bargaining power of multinationals and host governments’. Journal of International Business Studies, 13, 2, 9-23.

28

Feng, Y. (2001). ‘Political Freedom, Political Instability, and Policy Uncertainty: A study of political institutions and private investment in developing countries’. International Studies Quarterly, 45, 2, 271-294. Frank, A. G. (1971). Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. Harmonsworth: Penguin. Frynas, J. G. (1998). ‘Political Instability and Business: Focus on Shell in Nigeria’. Third World Quarterly, 19 (3): 457-478. Gilpin, R. (2001). Global Political Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001. Gliejeses, P. (1991). Shattered Hope: The Guatemalan Revolution and the United States, 1944-1954. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gomes-Casseres, B. (1990). ‘Firm ownership preferences and host government restrictions: an interated approach’. Journal of International Business Studies, 21, 1, 1-22. Greenhill, R. (1977). ‘The Nitrate and Iodine Trades, 1880-1914’, in Platt, D. C. M. (ed.). Business Imperialism, 1840-1930. Oxford: Clarendon. Greenhill, R. and Miller, R. (1973). ‘The Peruvian Government and the Nitrate Trade, 1873-1879’. Journal of Latin American Studies, 5, 1, 107-131. Henisz, W. (2000). ‘The Institutional Environment for Foreign Investors’. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 16, 2, 334-364. Jeffrey, L. (1980). ‘Multinational Corporations and Politics in Developing Countries’. World Politics, 32, 3, 454-483. Jenkins, V. (2000). Bananas: An American History. Washington: Smithsonian. Jensen, N. (2003). ‘Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment’. International Organization, 57, 3, 587-616. Jensen, N. (2005). ‘The Multinational Corporation Empowers the Nation-State.’ Perspectives on Politics, 3, 544-551. Jensen, N. (2006), Nation States and the Multinational Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

29

Jones, G. (2000). Merchants to Multinationals: British Trading Companies in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. New York: Oxford University Press. Jones, G. (2002). Merchants to Multinationals. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Jones, G. and Khanna, T. (2006) ‘Bringing History (Back) into International Business.’ Journal of International Business Studies, 37, 4, 453-468. Karl, T. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty. Berkeley: University of California Press. Kobrin, S. (1979). ‘Political Risk: A Review and Consideration’. Journal of International Business Studies, 10, 10, 67-80. Kobrin, S. (1980). ‘Expropriation as an Attempt to Control Foreign Firms in LDCs: Trends from 1969 to 1979’. International Studies Quarterly, 18, 329-48. Kobrin, S. (1984). ‘Foreign Enterprise and Forced Divestment in the LDCs’. International Organization, 34, 1, 65-88 Le Billion, P. (2001). ‘The Political Ecology of War: Natural Resources and Armed Conflicts’. Political Geography, 20, 5, 561-584. Lenin, V. I. ([1916] 1970). Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. Moscow: Progress Publishers. Li, Q. and Mihalache A. (2006). Democratic Institutions and Sectoral Foreign Direct Investment. International Studies Association Annual Meeting, San Diego. Li, S. and Filer, L. (2007), ‘The Effects of Governance Environment on the Choice of Investment Mode and the Strategic Implications’. Journal of World Business, 42, 80-98. Lipsey, R (2002), ‘Home and host country effects of FDI’. National Bureau for Economic Research Working Paper 9293. London B. and Ross R. (1995). ‘The Political Sociology of Foreign Direct Investment: Global Capitalism and Capital Mobility, 1965-1980’. International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 36, 198-218. Mathew, W. M. (1977). ‘Antony Gibbs & Sons, the Guano Trade and the Peruvian Government, 1842-1861’, in Platt, D. C. M. (ed.) Business Imperialism 1840-1930: An Inquiry Based on British Experience in Latin America. Oxford: Clarendon Press May, S. and Plaza, G (1958). The United Fruit Company in Latin America. Washington: National Planning Association. Mayo, J. (1987). British Merchants and Chilean Development. Boulder: Westview Press.

30

McCameron, Robert. Bananas, Labor, and Politics in Honduras: 1954-1963. Syracuse: Syracuse University Press, 1983. McConnell, D. (1935). ‘The Chilean Nitrate Industry’. Journal of Political Economy, 43, 4, 506-529. Miller, R. (1977). ‘British firms and the Peruvian government’, in Platt, D. C. M. (ed.) Business Imperialism 1840-1930: An Inquiry Based on British Experience in Latin America. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Miller, R. and Greenhill, R. (2006). ‘The Fertilizer Commodity Chain: Guano and Nitrate, 1840-1930’ in Marichal, C., Topik, S. and Frank, Z. (eds.), From Silver to Cocaine. Durham: Duke University Press. Minor, M. (1994). ‘The demise of expropriation as an instrument of LDC policy’. Journal of International Business Studies, 25, 1, 177-188. Monteón, M. (1982). Chile in the Nitrate Era: The Evolution of Economic Dependence, 1880-1930. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. Monteón, M. (2003). ‘John T. North, the Nitrate King, and Chile’s Lost Future’. Latin American Perspectives, 30, 6, 69-90. Murtha, T. and Lenway S. (1994). ‘Country Capabilities and the Strategic State: How National Political Institutions Affect Multinational Corporations’ Strategy’. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 1994, 113-129 North, D.C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press. O’Brien, T. (1982). The Nitrate Industry and Chile's Crucial Transition: 1870-1891. New York: New York University Press. O’Brien, T. (1989). ‘‘Rich Beyond the Dreams of Avarice:’ The Guggenheims in Chile’. Business History Review, 63, 1, 122-159. Oneal, J. (1994). ‘The Affinity of Foreign Investors for Authoritarian Regimes’. Political Research Quarterly, 47, 3, 565-588. Posas, M. (1993). ‘La plantación banananera en Centroamérica, 1870-1929’, in Acuña, V. (ed.), Historia General de Centroamérica. Madrid: Sociedad Estatal Quinto Centenario.

31

Read, R. (1983). ‘The Growth and Structure of Multinationals in the Banana Export Trade’ in Casson, M. (ed.). The Growth of International Business (London/Boston: Allen & Unwin. Ricord, H. (1974). Panamá y la Frutera. Panama: Editorial Universitaria. Rippy, F. (1948). ‘Economic Enterprises of the ‘Nitrate King’ and his Associates in Chile,” The Pacific Historical Review, 17, 4, 457-465. Ross, M. (2001). ‘Does Oil Hinder Democracy?’ World Politics, 53, 325-61. Schlesinger, S. and Kinzer, S. (1990). Bitter Fruit: The Untold Story of the American Coup in Guatemala. New York: Anchor. Scokpol, T. (1985). ‘Introduction’, in Scokpol T. and Evans P. (1985). Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Taracena, A. (1993). ‘Liberalismo y poder politico en Centroamérica (1870-1929)’, in Acuña, V. (ed.), Historia General de Centroamérica. Madrid: Sociedad Estatal Quinto Centenario. Taylor, T. (2003), ‘Evolution of the Banana Multinationals’, in Taylor, T. and Josling, T. (eds.), Banana Wars: The Anatomy of a Trade Dispute. Cambridge: CABI. United Brands Company. (1975). Annual Report. Boston: United Brands. United Fruit Company. (Various years). Annual Report. Boston: United Fruit. Vernon, R. (1971a). Sovereignty at Bay. New York: Basic Books. Vernon, R. (1971b). ‘The Multinational Enterprise: Power versus Sovereignty’. Foreign Affairs, 49, 736-75. Wallerstein, I. M. (1979). The Capitalist World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wells, L. (1977). ‘Negotiating with Third-World Governments’. Harvard Business Review, 55, 1, 72-80. Wilkins, M. (1970). The Emergence of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from the Colonial Era to 1914. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Wilkins, M. (1974). The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from 1914 to 1970. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

32

Williamson, O. (1971). ‘The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations’. American Economic Review, 71, 112-123. Williamson, O. (1981). ‘The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes’. Journal of Economic Literature, 19, 1537-1568. Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.