22
The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment By: Ryan Holcomb and Larisa Zimoglyad June 29, 2013 Capstone Final

The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification:

What Deserves More Punishment

By: Ryan Holcomb and Larisa Zimoglyad

June 29, 2013

Capstone Final

Page 2: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Section 1: Introduction

One of the main focuses of modern investment theory has been the relationship between the

shareholders and management of a firm. Many different areas and fields have devoted time and energy

to studying this interesting dichotomy and for good reason. In theory, the main goal of the management

of public corporations is to maximize shareholder value---although the extent to which this duty is

upheld is often debated in court---and thus arises the question of what falls into the realm of fiduciary

responsibility for the firm and what investors can and should implement more efficiently themselves.

One aspect of this relationship was studied by Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller and resulted in the

Modigliani–Miller theory (MM theory). Modigliani and Miller stated that a firm’s capital structure only

added value to the extent that interest payments on debt provided a tax shield to earnings. Individual

investor preferences regarding the capital structure are irrelevant because investors can change the

degree of leverage within their portfolios more efficiently and at a smaller cost than firms can.

Diversification follows along parallel lines. Investors can diversify more cheaply than firms; compare

brokerage fees with investment banker fees. Since investors are not homogenous in their diversification

needs, it is more efficient and practical to leave diversification to shareholders.

Diversification is a main theme in modern investment and theorists and practitioners utilize the concept

of the efficient frontier to help show the benefits of having a well-diversified portfolio of assets. The

underlining theory of diversification and the efficient frontier is that investors are compensated for

enduring risk. However, there is more than one type of risk and the financial theory demonstrates that

investors are only compensated for risks that cannot be diversified away. The broadest categories that

risk is divided into are systematic risk and unsystematic risk. Discussing the latter first, unsystematic risk

represents the risks inherent in owning a single investment. There are many individual events that could

negatively affect a single firm or industry. However, by diversifying across a multitude of industries and

asset classes the theory of diversification states that these individual uncorrelated events will mitigate

each other. For example, if an individual has a large number of uncorrelated assets the theory states

that the probabilities of a negative random event striking an individual asset class or sector and a

positive random event in one of the other investment sectors offset one another and that will stand to

mitigate the risks inherent in single investments. Thus, investors can eliminate unsystematic risk

through diversification and therefore will not be compensated for enduring risks that can be eliminated.

Page 3: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

In contrast, systematic risk represents the uncertainty involved in providing capital to risky markets

where there is a possibility of loss or reduction of principal. Systematic risk is ubiquitous in the sense

that it can negatively impact all asset classes and investments simultaneously. Thus, there is no

possibility of diversifying systematic risk away and therefore investors require compensation for bearing

the risks of the market. Each asset class represents the opportunity for differing systematic exposure

and thus offers the investor alternative levels of expected return. The aforementioned discussion states

that investors should diversify across different asset classes to reduce unsystematic risk and to gain

exposure to the returns promised by systematic risk.

The main question we wish to ask in this paper is whether the market rewards or punishes firms for

engaging in diversification. If investors can diversify in a more cost effective way, firms that diversify

should trade at a discount compared to firms who don’t diversify. However, managers give many

reasons for why diversification at the firm level makes sense and adds value.

Lang and Stulz (1993) examined how the market values diversified firms and showed that there is a

negative relationship between firm diversification and Tobin’s Q, a measure of the value the market

places on a firm. They used cross-sectional data from 1984 as well as time series data from 1976-1988

obtained from COMPUSTAT. Lang and Stulz concede toward the beginning of their paper that the

conclusions reached by studies of this nature are heavily influenced by the sample period. For this

reason, we will examine whether the same relationships hold using only cross-sectional data from 2009,

also obtained from COMPUSTAT. In addition, we examine the effects on their findings of using different

measures of firm diversification, namely Palepu’s (1985) measure of entropy, as well as the

traditional Herfindahl–Hirschman Index. Both measures will be discussed in greater detail in the

definition section.

In addition, we hypothesize that the relationship between Tobin’s Q and diversification becomes even

more negative if the diversification is unrelated to the firm’s core business. In some sense, we believe

that firms are punished more by the markets for stepping too far out of the bounds of their core

business.

Page 4: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides definitions of terms used throughout this paper as

well as how those terms are interpreted. Section 3 reviews the literature in this area of study. Section 4

describes our methodology and provides the reasoning behind the variables we used as well as the

expected relationships. This section also describes our data and the sources used to obtain it. Section 5

shows our results and Section 6 analyzes our results to arrive at conclusions. Section 7 discusses

potential future research questions. Section 8 summarizes our conclusions and highlights our

contribution to the current literature.

Section 2: Definitions

Throughout this paper, we will refer to different measures commonly used in the diversification

literature. For the reader unfamiliar with how these measures are calculated and interpreted, we

proceed to define the key measures and provide sources for further information.

Herfindahl-Hirschman Index

The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) is most commonly used to measure the concentration of an

industry. This measure is calculated by taking the sum of the squared weights, where the weights

represent the market share of an individual firm. For example, in an industry with one firm, the HHI

would be 10000 (1*(1002)). A more interesting example would be an industry with four firms, each with

25% of the market share. The HHI for this industry would be 2500 (4*(252)). A final example to consider

would be an industry with 4 firms, but one firm controls 70% of the market and the remaining firms

each have 10%. In this case, the HHI would be 5200 (702+3*(102)). In general, the formula for HHI is

where si is the percentage of the ith firm’s market share.

It should be noted that the HHI ranges from approximately zero to 10000, where approximately zero

means a very high level of competition and 10000 indicates that the industry is a monopoly.

Additionally, some people use decimals instead of percentages, which reduces the range from

approximately zero to 1.

Page 5: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

For our purposes, we looked at each individual firm in our sample as one would look at an industry and

calculated the HHI. We took the weight of each operating segment within the firm, squared it, and

added up the individual segments. An HHI of 1 meant that the firm conducted business within only one

segment, as defined by a specific four digit SIC code. Smaller HHI’s reflected an increasing degree of

diversification. For more information on the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, see Rhoades (1993).

Tobin’s Q

Tobin’s Q is a slightly more complex version of a market to book ratio. The formula has several

variations. The variation we used was:

( )

Tobin’s Q conceptually looks at the sum of the market value of equity and the market value of debt over

the replacement value of assets. In our calculation, it is assumed that the book value of debt equals the

market value of debt and that the book value of assets equals the replacement value of assets. This

metric was calculated for all firms in our sample using 2009 data.

A higher value of Tobin’s Q indicates that the market is valuing the company at a greater multiple of

book value. It is also similar to the widely accepted P/E ratio, except that Tobin’s Q is expanded to the

firm level, not just the equity of the firm. We will use Tobin’s Q as a measure of the premium or discount

the market is applying to specific firms. Tobin’s Q has some limitations that are widely addressed in the

literature. A discussion of this follows in the literature review.

Palepu’s Measure of Entropy

Palepu’s entropy measure as aforementioned is a different metric used in testing the relationship

between performance and diversification of firms. The following are four formulas used to calculate the

degree of total diversification, related diversification, and unrelated diversification. One would first use

the RDj formula to find the related diversification as a result of operating in several business segments

within an industry group j. This is then used as an input to find the overall related diversification. It can

be interpreted as simply taking a weighted average of the RDj where the weights are the total sales to

industry j, Pj. The third equation calculates the unrelated diversification as basically a weighted sum of

Page 6: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

the industries the firm is operating in as measured by industry sales Pj. The final equation can be proved

by algebra, and simply states that total diversification is the sum of related and unrelated diversification.

∑ (

)

∑ (

)

Choi and Russell (2005) provide a slightly more expanded explanation of the calculation. Alternatively,

one could reference the original Palepu (1985) article.

Our calculation began with unrelated diversification. The first step was to cross reference the NAICS

codes and the income statement for a particular firm to separate the firms divisions. Using the income

statement makes it necessary to eliminate all categories that do not contribute significantly to the

overall revenue. Since firms are required to only disclose segments that contribute more than ten

percent of revenue, this was the test used to determine significance. We then can use the

aforementioned formula to calculate the unrelated diversification. For illustrative purposes, consider a

firm that has revenues broken down into two categories of 88.67% and 11.57%, the calculation would

be as follows:

UD= [(.8667 ln (1/.8667)) + (.1157 ln(1/.1157))] = .374

This process can be expanded for as many different categories as necessary. To calculate the related

diversification we need to examine the relatedness between categories by breaking down the categories

into further subsets and using the above formula. For example if the 88.67% category can be broken

down into the following subsets with their respective weights, X1 (51%), X2 (37%), X3 (6%), X4 (4%), and X5

(3%), the calculation would be:

RD= .8667 [(.51ln(1/.51)) + (.37ln(1/.37)) + (.06ln(1/.06)) + (.04ln(1/.04)) + (.03ln(1/.03))] + .1157

[(.78ln(1/.78)) + (.09ln(1/.09)) + (.03ln(1/.03))] = 1.025

Page 7: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Once again this can be expanded to incorporate as many variables as necessary. The formula for related

diversification was similarly applied. Finally, total diversification can intuitively be found by summing

both related and unrelated diversification.

Section 3: Literature Review

The question of whether it is profitable for firms to diversify is not a new one and this section focuses on

the previous work of several authors and their contribution to the study of firm diversification.

Specifically, we will be examining Montgomery (1994) in “Corporate Diversification,” Wernerfelt and

Montgomery (1988) in “Tobin’s Q and the importance of Focus in Firm Performance,” Rumelt (1982) in

“Diversification Strategy and Profitability,” and finally Lang and Stulz (1993) in “Tobin’s Q, Corporate

Diversification and Firm Performance.” The following section will discuss each of these papers in turn

and present their results and conclusions. These results will serve as a benchmark against which we

compare our own results in Section 6.

Montgomery starts her paper out by asking the question of: why do firms diversify? As has been stated,

the common belief in modern finance is that diversification is more easily and efficiently implemented

by investors. However, there are still conglomerates and firms still utilize mergers and acquisitions (M &

A) to expand into unrelated industries. So the big question is why do firms diversify? Montgomery,

based on the research of several other authors, suggests that market power, resource-view, and agency

view are the reasons why firms, for better or for worse, still diversify. The following is a discussion of

each rationale, respectively.

Montgomery, building on the work presented by Edwards (1955) in “Conglomerate bigness as a Source

of Market Power,” points out that it was the common belief held by economists that diversified firms

would have an advantage over undiversified firms for three reasons: cross-subsidization—the ability of

firms to engage in “predatory pricing” behavior in certain markets because its other markets can

temporarily subsidize the other segment, mutual forbearance—the reduction in competition between

firms that compete in multiple markets due to “interdependence,” and finally reciprocal buying—where

large firms prevent small firms from competing because of the “interrelationships” between large firms.

These rationales for corporate diversification all fall under the heading of the market-power view of

Page 8: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

corporate diversification and scholars that believe in this theory argue that there is a positive

relationship between diversification and performance.

The agency view of why firms diversify is based on the disconnect between the owners of a firm and the

managers of the firm; specifically, the managers of a firm have divergent goals and desires from those of

the firms owners and since ownership is spread out amongst many owners, it is hard for owners to

prevent managers from taking less profitable routes. Managers pursue strategies that may not be in the

best interest of owners for three reasons: empire building—this refers to the inherent desire of

managers to control more assets in the attempt to be seen as more powerful or important, managerial

entrenchment—this refers to managers engaging in diversification activities to concentrate on areas the

manager is good at in order to increase his or her importance to the firm and thereby provide job

security, and finally—managers may pursue diversification strategies to reduce the risk of the firm even

though investors can do this far more efficiently. All three of these rationales for why managers may

pursue diversification strategies have one thing in common. They sacrifice the maximization of

shareholder wealth for personal benefits which is the definition of an agency cost. Thus, the agency view

theory would predict a negative relationship between diversification and profitability.

The resource view is based on the work of Penrose (1959) and presented in her work “The Theory of the

Growth of the Firm.” Montgomery explains that the resource view leads a firm to diversify because of

three reasons: the “indivisibility” of resources—pertaining to the need to attain economies of scale for

certain high cost investments, the malleable nature of some resources—which provide opportunities for

penetration into new markets, and finally because in the course of normal operations a firm has the

opportunity to continually develop new “productive services”. Montgomery also points out that there

are different dimensions that describe the productive factors that firms have and this leads to the

conclusion based on a resource view that different firms will have different optimal diversification levels.

The difference in dimensions has to do with the specificity of resources. Specifically, firms that have

resources that are very specific in nature will have limited scope in its ability to transcend its current

market segments. Furthermore, firms that have resources that are more general in nature might be

able to take advantage of other markets to increase efficiency or may find greater profit margin in

another sector. Thus, firms with specific resources may be optimal at lower levels of diversification

whereas firms with more malleable resources may be optimal at higher levels of diversification.

Page 9: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

The rationales mentioned above provide some explanations for why firms may choose to diversify.

However, these rationales don’t answer the question of whether they should diversify and if it makes

economic sense for companies to diversify. Based on her previous works and the work of other

pertinent authors on the subject matter, Montgomery concludes that the typical firm that chooses

higher levels of diversification will not attain increased wealth for its shareholders. Firms that choose the

diversification path are on average less likely to satisfy owners. Montgomery believes the underpinnings

of this hypothesis can be contributed to the analysis of the three reasons why firms diversify that were

presented above.

Specifically, Montgomery believes that there is evidence for both the resource based view and agency

view. However, she believes there is strong evidence against the market-power view of diversification.

In explaining her opinion on the market-power view of diversification, Montgomery points to previous

work which studies the relationship between concentration and diversification. Based on studies by

Berry (1974) and Caves (1981), the data showed that a positive correlation between diversification and

industry concentration in highly concentrated industries did not exist. It should be noted that increases

in concentration were only observed in new or less concentrated industries. These results lead

Montgomery to conclude that there is little evidence for the market-power view as there is no

relationship between diversification and increased market-share in competitive industries. Based on

Lang, Stulz and Walking’s (1991) and Kaplan and Weisbach’s (1992) works on free cash flow,

Montgomery posits that there is definite evidence for the theory of agency view in relation to

diversification. These studies focused on the excess of free-cash flows, defined by Jensen (1986) as the

free-cash flow above the amount necessary for normal NPV projects. They found that there is a negative

relationship between the amount of excess free-cash flow and the performance of firms. This

relationship is characterized by the idea that excess amounts of free-cash flow will be invested by

managers into less optimal investments that benefit managers but hurt investors. Montgomery also

states that there is large evidence that firms with more specific resources tend to diversify less than

firms with less specific resources, which is consistent with the resource-based reason for diversifying.

This research led Montgomery to the conclusion that diversification is largely unprofitable, although she

concedes that this research question is far from being conclusively answered.

In a prior paper titled “Tobin’s Q and the importance of Focus in Firm Performance,” Montgomery,

working with Wernerfelt, (1988) seek to explore the profitability of firms by analyzing the relative

Page 10: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

importance of industry and focus on a firm’s Tobin’s Q. Specifically, they wish to test the theory that

largely diversified firms perform sub-optimally because of the firm’s inability to reproduce competencies

in a large amount of separate markets compared to focused firms who are better able to implement

competitive advantages. The following is a presentation of their methodology and results.

The first distinction Wernerfelt and Montgomery make is the divergence from the traditionally used

accounting measures to determine profitability to the use of Tobin’s Q, which they believe is a more

accurate measure. Specifically, they believe that traditional accounting measures fail to account for firm

differences in systematic risk, temporary disequilibrium effects, tax laws, and accounting conventions.

Tobin’s Q is calculated as a firm’s total capital market value divided by the replacement value of its

assets. Theoretically, the Tobin Q measure corrects for all of the above mentioned biases and thus

represents a more stable measure of firm profitability across multiple firms and industries. Tobin’s Q

represents the dependent variable for the analysis.

To construct the independent variable measuring diversification, Wernerfelt and Montgomery multiply

the firm’s total sales against the industry average capital output ratio and utilize the concentric index to

arrive at the total amount of diversification. The concentric index utilizes the data from sales from

industry and weighs the correlation by using the SIC code reference number (Wernerfelt & Montgomery

P.3). The following are the two equations that Wernerfelt and Montgomery used in their regressions:

In Wernerfelt and Montgomery’s first equation, the betas represent the effect on profitability from

industry, γ is the shared effect, and theta represents the effect from focus or diversification. Equation

two adjusts for problems pertaining to “industry specific” intangible assets and thus includes measures

of marketing, research and development, and the replacement value of intangible assets.

Wernerfelt and Montgomery’s results show that as expected, most of the variation in profitability can

be explained by industry effects. Furthermore, there is evidence that diversification does play a role in

the variability of returns for firms, which leads Wernerfelt and Montgomery to the conclusion that there

Page 11: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

is some loss involved when firms spread their competencies to thin. They take these results to be an

argument for the revisionist theory that diversification does not enhance returns. Presented below are

FIGURE 1: With Correction for Marketing and R&D

the tables and graphs that Wernerfelt and Montgomery used in their research paper. Figure 1 shows the

R2 and adjusted R2 for the different regressions they ran as well as the p-values for models that

corrected for marketing and research and development investment. Figure 2 shows the same chart but

doesn’t include correction for marketing and research and development investment. These two figures

correspond directly to the equations presented above.

Page 12: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Figure 2: Without correction for marketing and R&D

Rumelt (1982) in “Diversification Strategy and Profitability” explores the relationship between

diversification and profitability. Specifically, Rumelt argues that there is a statistically significant

difference in the profitability of diversified firms and that the firms who diversify into related industries

outperform those who diverge significantly from their core competencies. To test his theory, Rumelt

constructs seven tranches of diversification which range from single business units to unrelated

businesses. To construct the tranches, Rumelt calculates several metrics and then measures the firms

against them to determine what level of diversification the firm exhibits. The metrics include a firm

specialization ratio (Rs)—the fraction of revenues from the largest business unit, a firm related-core ratio

(Rc) —the fraction of revenue from its largest group of related businesses, a related ratio (Rr)—the

fraction of revenues from the largest group of semi related businesses, and a vertical ratio (Rv)—the

fraction of revenues from products that share the same raw materials. Once the metrics are calculated

Page 13: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Rumelt compares them to established benchmarks to categorize the degree of diversification; the

benchmarks are presented below (Rumelt P.3).

Rumelt’s data sample includes the 500 largest corporations in the US for the years 1949, 1959, 1969,

and 1974. A random sample of the 500 largest firms was taken for each of the aforementioned years.

The diversification levels of the firms were analyzed over the period 1949-1974 and the firms were

placed into one of the seven tranches based on the above mentioned metrics. A table of the percentage

breakdowns by category is displayed below.

Based on the dataset, Rumelt notes that there is a large decline in single business units over the

specified time period. Furthermore, businesses early in the study focused on related diversification,

whereas, later in the time period firms focused more on unrelated diversification.

To measure the profitability of diversification over the time period, Rumelt utilized return on invested

capital which is defined as:

( )

Page 14: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

where Y is net income after taxes, I is the interest rate on long-term debt, and K equals the sum of

owner’s equity and long-term debt (Rumelt P.5). Rumelt’s regression function is presented below.

Based on the regression results included below, Rumelt concluded that his study was significant and that

his model was able to show the benefits and consequences of diversification. As can be seen in the

table below, unrelated diversification significantly underperforms that of the related constrained group

which is an indication that related diversification is indeed profitable. Rumelt concludes his paper by

discussing the reasons for the premium returns experienced by the related diversification firms. He

argues that economies of scope—developing a lower cost per unit through expanded sales, idiosyncratic

investment—the specificity of competitive advantages that lead to related diversification, and uncertain

imitability—the creation of barriers to entry through productive processes, are the reasons for higher

returns.

The final paper that we would like to draw attention to is Lang and Stulz’s “Tobin’s Q, Corporate

Diversification and Firm Performance” (1993). The main argument presented by these authors is that

firms turn to diversification when they have exhausted all internal growth opportunities and thus seek

to expand into new markets. The results presented by Lang and Stulz show that there is a negative

Page 15: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

relationship between diversification and firm performance as measure by Tobin’s Q. Their research

focuses on the approach presented by LeBaron and Speidell (1989) which is called the “chop-shop”

approach. This approach permits comparisons of a diversified firm’s Q measure to that of a stand-alone

firm. Essentially this approach allows the researchers to analyze how the conglomerate firms would

perform had they been operated as stand-alone firms. Lang and Stulz argue that if diversification really

does add value, then this should be reflected in higher Q-values for diversified firms compared to that of

stand-alone segments. The following is a presentation of their results and conclusions regarding the

profitability of diversification.

One important aspect of their analysis is that they looked at not only time-series data but also cross-

sectional data. They realized that the profitability of diversification can be more accurately measured

during one static period as opposed to over several time periods because the results become heavily

dependent on the time periods analyzed. Furthermore, using a static time period allows the researchers

to avoid the use of a risk adjustment that could have potentially negative effects on the analysis. Like

the previous articles we have discussed in this paper, Lang and Stulz utilize Tobin’s Q because of its

diverse benefits and its apt ability to measure the performance of firms. The researchers utilize a

modification of Tobin Q presented by Lindenberg and Ross (1981) which provides a way to calculate the

replacement costs of assets.

Lang and Stulz’s data is compiled using COMPUTSTAT from the year 1984. The graph below comes from

their paper and displays the correlations between HHI and Tobin’s Q which stands to show the

relationship between diversification and profitability.

Page 16: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

As can be seen from the above table, there is a significant negative correlation between diversification

and profitability. Below is also a table which displays the means and medians of both highly diversified

and more focused companies. The graph illustrates that the means and medians of specialized firms are

higher than that of diversified firms regardless of which measure is being used. According to the table,

the mean and median for the entire sample is 1.11 and .77 respectively for the year of 1984. In

addition, the table also shows that the mean and median values for specialized firms exceed their

diversified counterparties by 39% and 31% respectively. Lang and Stulz argue that this is further

evidence that diversification does not add value to owners (Lang and Stulz P. 19).

Table three presents regression data from Lang and Stulz where they construct a dummy variable to

take on the property of being more or less diversified in order to measure the marginal benefit of

diversification. This regression provides more evidence for their theory as the regression results are

significant and shows that diversified firms, on average, have a lower Q-rating. Based on these results,

Lang and Stulz argue that diversification does not, on average, lead to an increase in value to the

organization.

Page 17: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Section 4: Data and Methodology

Our findings in reviewing the literature indicate that the question of whether diversification adds value

is still largely unanswered. Some find significant discounts for diversified firms, others argue that there

may be good reasons for diversification, and yet others distinguish based on how related the

diversification is to the firm’s core business. For this reason, we collected data and performed our own

analysis. The data for our analysis came from two different sources. We were able to obtain the

breakdown of operating segments from 2009 for 388 firms from COMPUSTAT. From this we were able

to calculate the HHI for each firm. Furthermore, we would like to thank Karin Schnarr for providing

additional data on the 388 companies as well as performing many of the calculations.

Page 18: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Our review of the literature suggested that there were benefits to adding additional measures of

diversification. Stan Xiao Li and Royston Greenwood (2004) point out that Palepu’s entropy measure is

the preeminent choice for testing the relationship between diversification and performance. This

measure was not used by Lang and Stulz. We will examine the effects of using these measures while also

using the more common HHI metric.

The following table breaks down our sample of firms by the different diversification metrics and shows

the average and median Tobin’s Q as well as a count of the number of firms that fall under that

category. The first category is pure play firms. The categories progress to higher levels of diversification.

The last category shows those firms that are highly diversified. For the related and unrelated

diversification metrics, the last couple categories are combined to provide a reasonable number of firms

in each category.

HHI 1 1>x>.8 .8>x>.6 .6>x>.4 .4>x>.2 .2>x>0

Average Tobin's Q 2.340119 1.752236 1.781966 1.643909 1.703855 1.758242

Median Tobin's Q 1.827088 1.486365 1.496348 1.461802 1.510884 1.571115

Count 90 33 47 92 114 12

Total Diversification 0 0<x<.5 .5<x<1 1<x<1.5 1.5<x<2 2<x<3

Average Tobin's Q 2.034387 2.048399 1.864682 1.714184 1.780025 1.646143

Median Tobin's Q 1.578312 1.695231 1.588718 1.489933 1.580462 1.445543

Count 23 74 129 109 43 10

Related Diversification 0 0<x<.5 .5<x<1 1<x<1.5 1.5<x<3 Average Tobin's Q 1.784187 1.811128 1.914233 1.875241 2.010917 Median Tobin's Q 1.555855 1.452866 1.594203 1.516314 1.715888 Count 93 104 120 59 12

Unrelated Diversification 0 0<x<.5 .5<x<1 1<x<1.5 1.5<x<2 Average Tobin's Q 2.082656 1.802089 1.58639 1.505698 1.742659 Median Tobin's Q 1.743211 1.505454 1.365018 1.397169 1.707081 Count 179 73 96 32 8

A close examination of the table reveals some very interesting results. Looking just at the HHI, increased

diversification results in a decreased Tobin’s Q. From this we can conclude that diversifying reduces

Not diversified Highly diversified

Page 19: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

value. However, looking at the entropy measure of total diversification reveals that a small amount of

diversification actually results in an increased average and median Tobin’s Q, although the results seem

to oscillate. The related diversification metric clearly shows that increasing diversification in related

fields results in an increasing Tobin’s Q. Unrelated diversification also shows a clear discount for

increasing diversification with an anomaly for the highest category of diversification. Our next step was

to examine the correlations between the relevant variables.

The following correlation matrix includes the relevant variables as well as significance levels. Although

some of the correlations are very close to zero, they are still significant, which provides justification for

including them in regressions. Because of the inconclusiveness of some aspects of the above table, we

feel that regression analysis will better synthesize the results. It should be noted that the correlation

between HHI and Tobin’s Q in our data is very similar to the correlation found by Lang and Stulz.

Drelated Dunrelated Dtotal Assets Sales Tobin’s

Q

Market

Value

HHI

Drelated 1.00

Dunrelated -0.28* 1.00

Dtotal 0.64* 0.55* 1.00

Assets 0.08*** 0.14* 0.18* 1.00

Sales 0.03 0.09*** 0.10** 0.64* 1.00

Tobin’s Q 0.07 -0.23* -0.13* -0.15* -0.12** 1.00

Market Value 0.11** 0.09*** 0.16* 0.64* 0.69* 0.16* 1.00

HHI -0.03 -0.57* -0.48* -0.13** -0.09*** 0.24* -0.10** 1.00

Significant at the: *.01, **.05, ***.1. Otherwise, not significant, except diagonals.

Section 5: Results

To determine the effect of diversification on the market’s valuation of firms as measured by Tobin’s Q,

we ran four different regressions, one for each of the different diversification measures along with

return on assets, market value, and net sales against Tobin’s Q. Market value was included to control for

size differences between firms. Return on assets controls for differences in efficiency. Net sales is a

commonly suggested control to use when using Tobin’s Q. The following table summarizes the betas of

the diversification metric for each regression, along with the R2, the adjusted R2 and the P-value.

We can see that the regression involving HHI and Unrelated Diversification were highly significant with a

P-value of 0.0000. Total Diversification was significant at the 5% confidence level, and related

diversification wasn’t significant when compared to standard measures of significance.

Page 20: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Metric Beta R2 Adjusted R2 P-value

HHI 0.6562 0.3224 0.3153 0.0000

Total Diversification -0.1860 0.2932 0.2858 0.0110

Related Diversification 0.1138 0.2846 0.2771 0.1770

Unrelated Diversification -0.4099 0.3197 0.3126 0.0000

Section 6: Conclusion

The regression results presented in Section 5 are consistent with a lot of the results that we found while

reviewing the literature. When interpreting the regression using HHI, it should be kept in mind that a

decreasing HHI corresponds to an increase in the amount of diversification of the firm. The regression

using HHI shows a positive relationship between HHI and Tobin’s Q, so when HHI decreases, Tobin’s Q

also decreases. Stated in different terms, when the firm’s diversification increases, the market’s

valuation of the firm decreases. This confirms the findings of Montgomery and Wernerfelt and Lang and

Stulz that diversification destroys value.

Using the entropy measure for total diversification confirms that there is a negative relationship

between increased diversification and decreased market valuation. However, the beta for this

regression is not as significant and the beta is much lower in absolute value than the beta in the HHI

regression. This suggests that the discount may not be as bad as show by HHI.

The regression using the related diversification was not statistically significant. However, the results

show that as related diversification increases, Tobin’s Q also increases. If this regression was statistically

significant, it would provide support to Rumelt’s argument that related diversification increases value.

The main contribution of this paper is examining the difference between the discount applied to

diversification as measured by total diversification versus the discount applied to unrelated

diversification. We couldn’t find any studies that others performed to evaluate if engaging in unrelated

diversification is worse than simply engaging in diversification. Using unrelated diversification as the

measure of diversification revealed that for a given increase in diversification, the impact on Tobin’s Q is

a much larger decrease than the decrease from just total diversification. In percentage terms, the beta

associated with unrelated diversification is 54.6% larger than the beta associated with total

diversification.

Page 21: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

We also conducted a t-test to determine whether the difference between the betas was statistically

significant. Our calculated t-statistic was -2.538 ((-0.4099-(-.186))/.08821). To determine the critical

value of t, we looked at a Student’s T distribution with 383 degrees of freedom. This converges to the

normal distribution and results in a critical value of -1.96. Therefore, we conclude that the discount the

market applies to firms that diversify outside of their line of business is significantly larger than the

average discount applied to firms for engaging in diversification.

Section 7: Recommendations for Future Analysis

As Lang and Stulz noted, the results of this type of analysis are highly dependent on the data and time

period analyzed. For this reason, the exercise of repeating this analysis with more recent data would not

be in vain, even if it just served to confirm the findings of others. Another question that could be

addressed is the flip side of one of our questions, namely does the market reward firms for related

diversification. Although there is a lot more in the literature on this topic, the findings are still not

entirely conclusive.

Section 8: Summary

The main contribution of this paper is to show that there is a significant discount in the market

for engaging in unrelated diversification. We suggest to management of firms to avoid

unrelated diversification, as it does not maximize shareholder value. Related diversification is

acceptable and may result in a higher valuation. However, this result is inconclusive with the

data we used.

1 0.0882 is the standard error of the beta corresponding to unrelated diversification.

Page 22: The Market’s Reaction to Corporate Diversification: What Deserves More Punishment

Bibliography

Berry, Charles H., "Corporate Diversificationand Market Structure," Bell Journal of Economics and

Management Science, Spring 1974,5 196-204.

Caves, Richard E., "Diversification and Seller Concentration: Evidence from Changes, 1963-72," Review of

Economics and Statistics, May 1981, 63, 289-93.

Choi, J., & Russell, J. S. (2005). Long-term entropy and profitability change of United States public

construction firms. Journal of Management in Engineering, 21(1), 17-26.

Edwards, C. (1955). Conglomerate bigness as a source of power. Princeton University Press, (Business

Concentration and Price Policy), (p. 331 - 359). doi: 0-87014-196-1

Jensen, Michael C., "Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers," American

Economic Review, May 1986, 76, 323-29.

Kaplan, Steven N., and Michael S. Weisbach, "The Success of Acquisitions: Evidence from Divestitures,"

Journal of Finance, March 1992, 47, 107-38.

Lang, L. H., & Stulz, R. M. (1993). Tobin's q, corporate diversification and firm performance (No. w4376).

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Lang, Larry H. P., Renee M. Stulz, and Ralph A. Walkling, "A Test of the Free Cash and Tobin's q," RAND

Journal of Economics, Winter 1988, 19, 623-32.

LeBaron, D., & Speidell, L. (1989). Why are the parts worth more than the sum? "chop shop," a

corporate valuation model. Retrieved from http://www.bos.frb.org/

Li, S. X., & Greenwood, R. (2004). The effect of within‐industry diversification on firm performance:

Synergy creation, multi‐market contact and market structuration. Strategic Management

Journal, 25(12), 1131-1153.

Palepu, K. (1985). “Diversification strategy, profit performance, and the entropy measure.” Strategic

Manage. J., 6(3), 239–255.

Penrose, E. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford University Press, doi: 0-19-828977-4

Rhoades, S. A. (1993). Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, The. Fed. Res. Bull., 79, 188.

Rumelt, R. (1982). Diversification strategy and profitability. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 3(No. 4

(Oct. - Dec., 1982)), pp. 359-369Published. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/2486302

Wernerfelt, B., & Montgomery, C. (1988). Tobin's q and the importance of focus in firm performance.

The American Economic Review, Vol. 78, No(1 (Mar.,1988)), pp.246-50. Retrieved from

http://www.jstor.org/stable/1814713