66
Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging Artur Sepp Global Risk Analytics Bank of America Merrill Lynch, London [email protected] Global Derivatives Trading & Risk Management 2014 Amsterdam May 13-15, 2014 1

Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

1) Empirical evidence for the log-normality of implied and realized volatilities of stock indices 2) Apply the beta stochastic volatility (SV) model for quantifying implied and realized index skews 3) Origin of the premium for risk-neutral skews and its impacts on profit-and-loss (P\&L) of delta-hedging strategies 4) Closed-form solution for the mean-reverting log-normal beta SV model 5) Optimal delta-hedging strategies to improve Sharpe ratios 6) Argue why log-normal beta SV model is better than its alternatives

Citation preview

Page 1: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Realized and implied index skews, jumps, andthe failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Artur Sepp

Global Risk AnalyticsBank of America Merrill Lynch, London

[email protected]

Global Derivatives Trading & Risk Management 2014Amsterdam

May 13-15, 2014

1

Page 2: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Plan

1) Empirical evidence for the log-normality of implied and realized volatil-ities of stock indices

2) Apply the beta stochastic volatility (SV) model for quantifying impliedand realized index skews

3) Origin of the premium for risk-neutral skews and its impacts on profit-and-loss (P&L) of delta-hedging strategies

4) Optimal delta-hedging strategies to improve Sharpe ratios

5) Argue why log-normal beta SV model is better than its alternatives

2

Page 3: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

ReferencesTechnical details can be found in references

Beta stochastic volatility model:Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk,October, 67-73http://ssrn.com/abstract=2150614

Sepp, A. (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility andUnderlying To Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conferencein Amsterdam 2013http://math.ut.ee/~spartak/papers/PresentationGlobalDerivatives2013.pdf

Implied and realized skews, jumps, delta-hedging P&L:Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance DeltaUnder Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics”http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845

Sepp, A., (2014), “Affine Approximation for Moment Generating Func-tion of Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model”http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425

Optimal delta-hedging strategies:Sepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of SharpeRatio for Delta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and TransactionCosts,” Journal of Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59http://ssrn.com/abstract=1865998 3

Page 4: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

How to build a dynamic model for volatility?

Suppose we know nothing about stochastic volatility

We want to learn only by looking at empirical data

How do we start?

4

Page 5: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Empirical frequency of implied vol is log-normal

First, check whether stationary distribution of volatility is:A) Normal or B) Log-normal

Compute the empirical frequency of one-month implied at-the-money(ATM) volatility proxied by the VIX index for last 20 years

Daily observations normalized to have zero mean and unit variance

Left figure: empirical frequency of the VIX - it is definitely not normal

Right figure: the frequency of the logarithm of the VIX - it does looklike the normal density (especially for the right tail)!

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

Frequency

Empirical frequency of

normalized VIX

Empirical

Standard Normal

0%

1%

2%

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

Frequency

VIX

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

Frequency

Empirical frequency of

normalized logarithm of the VIX

EmpiricalStandard Normal

0%

1%

2%

3%

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

Frequency

Log-VIX

5

Page 6: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Empirical frequency of realized vol is log-normal

Compute one-month realized volatility of daily returns on the S&P 500index for each month over non-overlapping periods for last 60 years from1954

Below is the empirical frequency of normalized historical volatility

Left figure: frequency of realized vol - it is definitely not normal

Right figure: frequency of the logarithm of realized vol - again it doeslook like the normal density (especially for the right tail)

4%

6%

8%

10%

Frequency

Frequency of Historic 1m

Volatility of S&P500 returns

Empirical

Standard Normal

0%

2%

4%

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

Frequency

Vol

4%

6%

8%

10%

Frequency

Frequency of Logarithm of

Historic 1m Volatility of S&P500

Empirical

Standard Normal

0%

2%

4%

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

Frequency

Log-Vol

6

Page 7: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Dynamic model for volatility evolution shouldnot be based on price-volatility correlation

Now we look for a dynamic factor model for volatility (next slide)

We cannot apply model based on correlation between S&P500 returnsand changes in volatility because using correlation we can only predictthe direction of change, not the magnitude of change

For risk management of options, we need a factor model for volatilitydynamics

7

Page 8: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Factor model for volatility uses regression model forchanges in vol V (tn) predicted by returns in price S(tn)

V (tn)− V (tn−1) = β

[S(tn)− S(tn−1)

S(tn−1)

]+ V (tn−1)εn (1)

iid normal residuals εn are scaled by vol V (tn−1) due to log-normality

Volatility beta β explains about 70% of variations in volatility!

Left figure: scatter plot of daily changes in the VIX vs returns on S&P500 for past 14 years and estimated regression model

Right: time series of empirical residuals εn of regression model (1)Residual volatility does not exhibit any systemic patternsRegression model is stable across different estimation periods

y = -1.08x

R² = 67%

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

-10% -5% 0% 5% 10%

Chan

ge in

VIX Change in VIX vs Return on S&P500

-20%

-15%

-10%

-5%-10% -5% 0% 5% 10%

Return % on S&P 500

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30% Time Series of Residual Volatility

-30%

-20%

Dec-99

Dec-00

Jan-02

Jan-03

Jan-04

Jan-05

Jan-06

Jan-07

Jan-08

Jan-09

Jan-10

Jan-11

Jan-12

Jan-13

Volatility beta β: expected change in ATM vol predicted by price returnFor return of −1%: expected change in vol = −1.08× (−1%) = 1.08%8

Page 9: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

More evidence on log-normal dynamics of vol: indepen-dence of regression parameters on level of ATM vol

Estimate empirically the elasticity α of volatility by:

1) computing volatility beta and residual vol-of-vol for each month usingdaily returns within this month

2) test if the logarithm of these variables depends on the log of the VIXin that month using regression model

Left figure: test β̂(V ) = βV α by regression model: ln∣∣∣β̂(V )

∣∣∣ = α lnV + c

Right: test ε̂(V ) = εV 1+α by regression model: ln |ε̂(V )| = (1+α) lnV +c

The estimated value of elasticity α is small and statistically insignificantIndeed the realized volatility is close to log-normal

y = 0.15x + 0.14

R² = 2%

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5ln

(|V

IX b

eta|

)ln(VIX beta) vs ln(Average VIX)

-1.5

-1.0

-0.5

-2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0

ln(|

VIX

bet

a|)

ln(Average VIX)

y = 0.14x - 0.45

R² = 4%

-0.5

0.0

0.5

ln(|

VIX

res

idua

l vol

)

ln(VIX residualvol) vs ln(AverageVIX)

-1.5

-1.0

-2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5 0.0

ln(|

VIX

res

idua

l vol

)

ln(Average VIX)

9

Page 10: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Empirical estimation of volatility elasticity α:volatility dynamics is log-normal(maximum likelihood estimation - see my paper on log-normal volatility)Figure: 95% confidence bounds for estimated value of elasticity α usingrealized (RV) and implied (IV) volatilities for 4 major stock indices

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

Alp

ha

95% confidence bounds for

estimated elasticity alpha

-1.0

VIX

, Reg

VST

OX

X, R

eg

VIX

, ML

VST

OX

X, M

L

IV, S

&P

500

IV, F

TSE1

00

IV, N

IKK

EI

IV, S

TOX

X50

RV,

S&

P50

0

RV,

FTS

E100

RV,

NIK

KEI

RV,

STO

XX

50

Estimation results confirm evidence for log-normality of volatility:[i] In majority of cases (7 out of 12), bounds for α̂ contain zero[ii] One outlier α̂ = −0.4 (realized volatility of Nikkei index)[iii] Remaining are symmetric: two with α̂ ≈ 0.2 and two with α̂ ≈ −0.2

To conclude - alternative SV models are safely rejected:1) Heston and Stein-Stein SV models with α = −12) 3/2 SV model with α = 1

Also, excellent econometric study by Christoffersen-Jacobs-Mimouni (2010),Review of Financial Studies: log-normal SV outperforms its alternatives10

Page 11: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Beta stochastic volatility model (Karasinski-Sepp 2012):is obtained by summarizing our empirical findings fordynamics of index price S(t) and volatility V (t):

dS(t) = V (t)S(t)dW (0)(t)

dV (t) = βdS(t)

S(t)+ εV (t)dW (1)(t) + κ(θ − V (t))dt

(2)

V (t) is either returns vol or short-term ATM implied volW (0)(t) and W (1)(t) are independent Brownian motionsβ is volatility beta - sensitivity of volatility to changes in priceε is residual vol-of-vol - standard deviation of residual changes in vol

Mean-reversion rate κ and mean θ are added for stationarity of volatility

A closer inspection shows that these dynamics are similar to other log-normal based SV models widely used in industry:A) in interest rates - SABR modelB) in equities - a version of log-normal based aka exp-OU SV models

We arrived to beta SV model (2) only by looking at empirical datafor realized&implied vols and using factor model for vol dynamics

11

Page 12: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Implied interpretation of volatility beta and residual vol-of-vol from Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) volatilities, σBSM(z) as func-tions of log-strike z = ln(K/S), inferred form option prices

Compute vol skew SKEW and convexity CONV for small maturities:

SKEW = [σBSM(5%)− σBSM(−5%)] / (2× 5%)

CONV = [σBSM(5%) + σBSM(−5%)− 2σBSM(0)] /(5%2

)Volatility beta β[I] implied by skew:

β[I] = 2× SKEW

Residual vol-of-vol ε[I] implied by convexity:

ε[I] =√

3× σBSM(0)×CONV + 2× (SKEW)2

As model parameters, volatility beta (left figure) and idiosyncratic vol-of-vol (right figure) have orthogonal impact on BSM implied vols

15%

25%

35%

BSM

impl

ied

vols

Impact of volatility beta on BSM vol

Base vols with beta = -1

Down vols with beta = -0.5

Up vols with beta = -1.5

5%

15%

0.7 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.1

BSM

impl

ied

vols

Strike

15%

25%

35%

BSM

impl

ied

vols

Impact of residual vol-vol on BSM vol

Base vols with ResidVol=1.0

Down vols with ResidVol=0.5

Up vols with ResidVol=1.5

5%

15%

0.70 0.78 0.86 0.94 1.02 1.10

BSM

impl

ied

vols

Strike

12

Page 13: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Topic II: Implied and realized skew using beta SV modelUse time series from April 2007 to December 2013 for one-month ATMvols and the S&P500 index with estimation window of one month

Figure 1): Implied and realized onemonth volatilitiesATM volatility tends to trade ata small premium to realized

Figure 2): One-month average ofimplied and realized volatility betaImplied volatility beta consis-tently over-estimates realized one

Figure 3): Average of implied andrealized residual vol-of-volImplied residual vol-of-vol signifi-cantly over-estimates realized

Absolute (Abs) and relative (Rel)spreads between implieds&realizeds

Spreads Vol Beta VolVolAbs, Mean 0.51% -0.27 0.78Abs, Stdev 6.2% 0.21 0.16Rel, Mean 7% 21% 57%Rel, Stdev 24% 17% 11%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80% 1m ATM Implied Volatility

1m Realized Volatility

0%

10%

20%

Feb-07

Sep-07

Apr-08

Nov

-08

Jun-09

Jan-10

Aug-10

Mar-11

Oct-11

May-12

Dec-12

Jul-1

3

-0.5

0.0

Feb-07

Sep-07

Apr-08

Nov

-08

Jun-09

Jan-10

Aug-10

Mar-11

Oct-11

May-12

Dec-12

Jul-1

3

Implied Volatility Beta

Realized Volatility Beta

-2.0

-1.5

-1.0

0.5

0.8

1.1

1.4

1.7Implied Residual Vol-of-Vol

Realized Residual Vol-of-Vol

0.2

0.5

Feb-07

Sep-07

Apr-08

Nov

-08

Jun-09

Jan-10

Aug-10

Mar-11

Oct-11

May-12

Dec-12

Jul-1

3

13

Page 14: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Explanation of the skew premium in a quantitative way

In a very interesting study, Bakshi-Kapadia-Madan (2003), Review ofFinancial Studies, find relationship between risk-neutral and physical skewusing investor’s risk-aversion

Fat tails (not necessarily skewed) of returns distribution under phys-ical measure P along with risk-aversion lead to increased negativeskeweness under the risk neutral-measure Q

Quantitatively:

SKEWENESSQ = SKEWENESSP − γ ×KURTOSISP ×VOLATILITYP

SKEWENESSQ is risk-neutral skeweness of price returns

SKEWENESSP is physical skeweness of price returns

KURTOSISP is kurtosis as measure of fat tails of physical distribution

VOLATILITYP is volatility of returns under physical distribution

γ > 0 is risk-aversion parameter of investors

To conclude: the risk-neutral premium arises because risk-averseinvestors assign higher value to insurance puts

Important: Volatility skew is proportional to skeweness of returns14

Page 15: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Apply Merton Jump-Diffusion (JD) with normal jumpsFigure 1: Use last 14 years of daily returns on S&P 500 index to estimateskeweness and kurtosis of returns - see column ”Empirical P”Table 1: Use γ = 22.0 (estimated from time series of implied vols byinverting BKM formula) and apply BKM to obtain SKEWENESSQ = −2Figure&Table 2: Fit Merton JD to first four moments of physical andrisk-neutral distribution (jump frequency is set to one jump per month)

From calibration: JumpMean is 0 under empirical P and -5% under QEmpirical P Q

Stdev 21% 21%Skeweness 0 -2

Kurtosis 8 8

Merton JD params P QJump Mean 0% -5%

Jump Volatility 4% 0%Diffusion vol 17% 13%

Jump Frequency 12 12

Figure 3: Value one month options - implied volatility from Merton JDunder Q is skewed, while implied volatility under P is symmetric

4%

6%

8%

10%

Frequency

Frequency of S&P500 daily returns

Empirical

Frequency

Normal Density

0%

2%

4%

-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%

Frequency

Daily return

4%

6%

8%

10%

Frequency

Frequency of S&P500 daily returns

Empirical

Frequency

Physical Merton

under P

Risk-Neutral

0%

2%

4%

-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%

Frequency

Daily return

Risk-Neutral

Merton under Q

25%

30%

Imp

lie

d V

ol

Implied volatility skew for one

month options on S&P500

Physical Merton under P

Risk-Neutral Merton under Q

15%

20%

0.75 0.85 0.95 1.05 1.15 1.25

Imp

lie

d V

ol

Strike

15

Page 16: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

To summarize our developments so far:

1) Log-normal beta SV model is consistent with empirical distribu-tion for realized and implied vols

2) Beta SV model is applied to quantify realized and implied skewsand the spread between them, which turns out to be significant

Any option position is mark-to-market so no point of arguing aboutmarket pricesHowever, hedging strategy is discretionary and can be the ”edge”

By computing the delta-hedge: should we use implied or realizedskews?

This question is analyzed in the third topic of my talk:

Part I - Quantitative analysis of impact of realized and implied skews ondelta-hedging P&L

Part II - Monte-Carlo simulations for empirical analysis

16

Page 17: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Statistically significant spread between realized and im-plied skews β[R] − β[I] leads to dependence on realizedprice returns and invalidates the minimum-variance hedge

Minimum-variance delta ∆ is applied to hedge against changes in priceand price-induced changes in volatility

Given hedging portfolio Π for option U on S

Π(t, S, V ) = U(t, S, V )−∆× S∆ is computed by minimizing variance of Π using SV beta dynamics (2)under risk-neutral measure Q (classic approach) with implied vol betaβ[I]

∆ = US + β[I] × UV /Swhere US and UV model delta and vega

To see dependence on return δS due to spread between implied vol betaβ[I] and realized β[R]: given δS apply beta SV for change in vol δV underphysical measure P:

δV = β[R] × δS + ε[R] × V√δt

By Taylor expansion of realized P&L:

δΠ(t, S, V ) =[β[R] − β[I]

]× UV × δS + ε[R] × UV × V

√δt+O(dt)

ε(R) is random non-hedgable part from residual vol-of-volO(dt) part includes quadratic terms (δS)2, (δV )2, (δS)(δV )

17

Page 18: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility skew-beta is important for computing correctoption deltaFigure 1) Apply regression model(1) for time series of ATM vols formaturities T = {1m,3m,6m,12m,24m}(m=month) to estimate regressionvolatility beta βREGRES(T ) usingS&P500 returns:δσATM(T ) = βREGRES(T )× δS

Volatility beta for SV dynamics is in-stantaneous beta for very small T

Regression vol beta decays in log-Tdue to mean-reversion: long-datedATM vols are less sensitive in abso-lute values to price-returns

Figure 2) Implied vol skew for ma-turity T has similar decay in log-T

Figure 3) Volatility skew-beta isregression beta divided by skewSkew-Beta(T ) ∝ βREGRES(T )/SKEW(T )

It is nearly maturity-homogeneous

y = 0.19*ln(x) - 0.37

R² = 99%

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0.0 Regression Volatility Beta(T)

-1.0

-0.8

-0.6

0.08 0.25 0.50 1.00 2Maturity T

Regression Vol Beta(T)

Decay of Vol Beta in ln(T)

y = 0.16*ln(x) - 0.29

R² = 99%-0.4

-0.2

0.0 Implied Volatility Skew (T)

-0.8

-0.6

1m 3m 6m 1y 2y

Maturity, T

Vol Skew (T)

Decay of Skew in ln(T)

y = 0.06*ln(x) + 1.41

R² = 80%1.0

1.5

2.0 Volatility Skew-Beta(T)

Vol Skew-Beta (T)

0.0

0.5

1m 3m 6m 1y 2y

Maturity T

Vol Skew-Beta (T)

Decay of Vol Skew-Beta in ln(T)

18

Page 19: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Technical supplement to compute model implied skew-beta (omitted during the talk)Using backward pricers and PDE:1) Compute the term structure of ATM volatility σATM(S0;T ) and skewSKEW(S0;T ), with strike width α%, implied by model parameters2) Bump the spot price down by α%, S1 = (1− α%)S0, and apply corre-sponding bumping rule for model state variablesFor the beta SV:

V1 → V0 + βα , θ → θ +β

2κα (3)

3) Compute new term structure of ATM vols σATM(S1;T )4) Compute model implied skew-beta

Skew-Beta(T ) = −σATM(S1;T )− σATM(S0;T )

α× SKEW(S0;T )(4)

Using Monte-Carlo pricers:1) Specify number of paths and simulate set of independent Brownians2) Compute paths starting from {S0, V0}2A) Evaluate term structure of ATM volatility σATM(K = S0;T ) andskew using σ(K = S1;T ), both using Brownians in 1)3) Compute paths starting from {S1, V1} with S1 = (1−α%)S0 and V (1)bumped as in Eq (3), using Brownians in 1)4) Evaluate ATM vols σATM(K = S1;T ) and skew-beta by Eq (4) 19

Page 20: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility and Skew contribution to P&L - important forvolatility positions with daily mark-to-market!

Mark BSM implied vol σBSM(K) in %-strike K relative to price S(0):σBSM(K;S) = σATM(S) + SKEW× Z(K;S)

Z(K;S) is log-moneyness relative to current price S:Z(K;S) = ln (K × S(0)/S)

SKEW < 0 is inferred from spread between call and put implied vols

In practice, this form is augmented with extras for convexity and tails

Any SV model implies quadratic form for implied vols near ATM strikes(Lewis 2000, Bergomi-Guyon 2012) so my approach for vol P&L is generic

Volatility P&L arises from change in spot price S → S {1 + δS}:δσBSM(K;S) ≡ σBSM (K;S {1 + δS})− σBSM(K;S)

= δσATM(S) + SKEW× δZ(K;S)

First contributor to P&L: change in ATM vol δσATM(S):δσATM(S) = σATM (S {1 + δS})− σATM(S)

Second contributor to P&L: change in log-moneyness relative to skew:δZ(K;S) = − ln(1 + δS) ≈ −δS

20

Page 21: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Example of volatility and skew P&L with regression beta(omitted during the talk)

σATM(S(0)) = 15%, δS = −1.0%, SKEW = −0.5, βREGRESS = −1.0

It is very important how we keep log-moneyness Z(K;S):1) For strikes re-based to new ATM level (forward-based strikes):S → S{1 + δS} and log-moneyness does not change δZ(K;S) = 0P&L arises from change in ATM vol predicted by price return com-puted using βREGRESS:

δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS × δS = −1.0×−1% = 1%

2) For strikes fixed at old ATM level (vanilla strikes with fixed S(0))Thus log-moneyness changes by δZ(K;S) ≈ −δS = 1%P&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for change in money-ness:δσBSM(K) = βREGRESS×δS+SKEW×δS = 1%+(−0.5)×(1%) = 0.50%

0.5%

0.8%

1.0%

Change in vols, strikes fixed to ATM 0

Change in vols, strikes re-based to ATM 1

0.0%

0.3%

0.5%

90% 95% 100% 105%

Strike K%

18%

21%

BSM

vol

(K)

BSM vol 0, strikes fixed to ATM 0

BSM vol 1, strikes fixed to ATM 0

BSM vol 1, strikes re-based to ATM 1

12%

15%

90% 95% 100% 105%

BSM

vol

(K)

Strike K%

21

Page 22: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Changes in skew are not correlated to changes in priceand ATM vols - important for correct predict of vol and skew P&L

Empirical observations yet again confirm log-normality dynamics!(Using S&P500 data from January 2007 to December 2013)

Figure 1: weekly changes in 100% − 95% skew vs price returns formaturity of one month (left) and one year (right)Regression slope = 0.13 (1m) & 0.03 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 1% (1y)

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in 1m skew vs Price Return

y = 0.13x - 0.00

R² = 0%-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

-15% -5% 5% 15%

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Price return

y = 0.03x - 0.00-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in 1y skew vs Price Return

y = 0.03x - 0.00

R² = 1%

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

-15% -5% 5% 15%

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Price return

Figure 2: weekly changes in 100%− 95% skew vs changes in ATMvols for maturity of one month (left) and one year (right)Regression slope = −0.15 (1m) & −0.06 (1y); R2 = 0% (1m) & 2% (1y)

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in 1m skew vs 1m ATM vol

y = -0.15x - 0.00

R² = 0%-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

-15% -5% 5% 15%

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in ATM vol

-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in 1y skew vs 1y ATM vol

y = -0.09x - 0.00

R² = 2%

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

-15% -5% 5% 15%

Chan

ge in

Ske

w

Change in ATM vol

22

Page 23: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility skew-beta combines the skew and volatilityP&L together

Given price return δS:S → S {1 + δS}

Volatility P&L is computed by:

1) For strikes re-based to new ATM levelLog-moneyness does not change, δZ(K;S) = 0P&L follows change in ATM vol predicted by regression beta and volskew-beta:

δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S) = βREGRESS × δS= SKEWBETA× SKEW× δS

2) For strikes fixed at old ATM levelLog-moneyness changes by δZ(K;S) ≈ −δSP&L is change in ATM vol adjusted for skew P&L:

δσBSM(K) ≡ δσATM(S)− SKEW× δS= [SKEWBETA− 1]× SKEW× δS

Positive change in ATM vol from negative return is reduced byskew

23

Page 24: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility skew-beta under minimum-variance approachis applied to compute min-var delta ∆ for hedging againstchanges in price and price-induced changes in implied vol

A) We adjust option delta for change in implied vol at fixed strikes

B) The adjustment is proportional to option vega at this strike:∆(K,T ) = ∆BSM(K,T ) + [SKEWBETA(T )− 1]× SKEW(T )× VBSM(K,T )/S

∆BSM(K,T ) is BSM delta for strike K and maturity TVBSM(K,T ) is BSM vega, both evaluated at volatility skew

I classify volatility regimes using vol skew-beta for delta-adjustments:

∆(K,T ) =

∆BSM(K,T ) + SKEW(T )× VBSM(K,T )/S, Sticky local

∆BSM(K,T ), Sticky strike

∆BSM(K,T )− SKEW(T )× VBSM(K,T )/S, Sticky delta

∆BSM(K,T ) + 12SKEW(T )× VBSM(K,T )/S, Empirical S&P500

”Shadow” delta is obtained using ratio O (may be different from 1/2):

∆(K,T ) = ∆BSM(K,T ) +O × SKEW(T )× VBSM(K,T )/S

which is traders’ ad-hoc adjustment of option delta24

Page 25: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Does ”shadow” delta create a vision or an illusion?

We need a quantitative model to describe different volatilityregimes and produce correct option delta !

25

Page 26: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility skew-beta and vol regimes (also see Bergomi 2009):

SkewBeta =

2, Sticky local regime: minimum-variance delta in SV and LV

1, Sticky strike regime: BSM delta evaluated at implied skew

0, Sticky delta regime: model delta in space-homogeneous SV

Empirical estimates for skew-beta and its lower and upper bounds arefound by regression model (see my paper)

In beta SV model, with empirical estimate of vol beta and adding jumps/risk-aversion to match skew premium, we fit empirical vol skew-beta:1) S&P 500: empirical skew-beta of about 1.52) STOXX 50: strong skew-beta close to 23) NIKKEI: weak skew-beta is about 0.5

As result: beta SV model with jumps can produce the correct delta!

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

26

Page 27: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Second part of topic III: Monte Carlo analysis of delta-hedging P&L

Now let’s have some fun and do some number crunching!

We are going to simulate the market dynamics and compare hedgingperformance under different specifications of delta

In next few slides I briefly discuss the methodologyDetails are provided for the interested for self-studying

Details are important to understand how to improve the performance ofdelta-hedging strategiesApplication to actual market data produces equivalent conclusions

In my talk, I will only discuss final results and conclusions

27

Page 28: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Apply beta SV for dynamics under physical measure P:1) Index price S(t),2) Volatility of returns Vret(t):3) Short-term implied volatility Vimp(t):

dS(t) = Vret(t)S(t)dW (0)(t)

dVret(t) = κ[P ](θ[P ] − Vret(t)

)dt+ β[P ]Vret(t)dW

(0)(t) + ε[P ]Vret(t)dW(1)(t)

dVimp(t) = κ[I](θ[I] − Vimp(t)

)dt+ β[I]Vimp(t)dW

(0)(t) + ε[I]Vret(t)dW(1)(t)

4) At-the-money (ATM) implied vol Vatm(t) is obtained by computingmodel implied ATM vol for maturity T using model dynamics for Vimp(t)

Important: Model parameters are estimated from time series bymaximum likelihood methods - as a rule, parameters for returns vol[P ] and for implied vol [I] are differentHere, apply the same parameters for clarity

Physical for Returns dVret(t), [P ] Vol dVimp(t), [I]

V.(0) 16% 16.75%θ[.] 16% 16.75%κ[.] 3.0 3.0ε[.] 0.5 0.5β[.] -1.0 -1.0

28

Page 29: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Volatility and skew premiums are produced using BSM impliedvolatility, σBSM(K), as function of % strike K relative to S(0):

σBSM(K) = Vatm(t) + SKEW× ln (K × S(0)/S(t)) (5)

SKEW = −0.5 is vol implied skew specified exogenously bystrike % BSM vol σBSM(K) σBSM(K)− Vret(0)

99% 17.25% 1.25%

100% 16.75% 0.75%101% 16.25% 0.25%

Market Skew -0.50

Important - option delta is computed using two models:1) Beta SV model with market implied beta β[I] = -1.1

2) Beta SV model with empirical beta β[I] = -1.0 and jumps (risk-aversion) to price-in excessive skew −1.1− 1.0 = −0.1 (discussed later)Both SV models fit to market skew exactly!

[i] Premium of implied vol to realized vol is:16.75% − 16% = 0.75% (in line with empirical spread)[ii] Premium of implied and empirical beta is:β[I] − β[R] = -1.1 − ( -1.0 ) = -0.1 (empirical is about −0.2)

As we saw using Madan-Merton fits, physical dynamics don’t need tohave asymmetric jumps to produce skew premium - now, skew premiumarises from excess kurtosis produced by empirical SV model for returns29

Page 30: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Consistency with market skew does not guar-antee fit to empirical dynamics

Both hedging models are consistent with market implied skew

However, we observe discrepancy:

SV model with market implied beta,called Minimum variance hedgeImplies vol skew-beta about 2.0 , which is inconsistent with empiricaldynamics

SV model with jumps and empirical beta, called Empirical hedge:Implies vol skew-beta about 1.6 , which is consistent with empiricaldynamics

Important - no re-calibration along a MC path is applied:

Both hedging models are initially consistent with the market skew - asprice S(t) and vol Vimp(t) change, both models remain very close tomarket skew

Log-normality assumption - independence of implied&realized skewfrom volatility - comes into play

30

Page 31: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Specification for trading in delta-hedged positions:

1) Straddle - short ATM put and callFigure 1: P&L profile with Delta= 0 is function of realized return squared

Important: P&L/delta of straddle are not sensitive to realized/impliedskew - Benefits from small realized variance of price returns

2) Risk-reversal - short put with strike 99% and long call with strike101% of forwardFigure 2: P&L profile with Delta= −0.8 is function of realized return

Important: P&L/delta of risk-reversal are very sensitive to real-ized/implied skew - Benefits from small realized covariance of changesin price and ATM vol

-5.0%

-2.5%

0.0%

2.5%

5.0%PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with Delta=0

PayOff

-10.0%

-7.5%

-5.0%

-10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10%

Straddle P&L vs Price return

-2.5%

0.0%

2.5%

5.0%

7.5%

10.0%PayOff+PV-DeltaHedge with delta=-0.8

PayOff

-10.0%

-7.5%

-5.0%

-2.5%

-10%-8%-6%-4%-2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8%10%

Risk-Reversal P&L vsPrice return

31

Page 32: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Specification for notionals of delta-hedged positions

Notionals are normalized by CashGamma=(1/2)× (S2)×OptionGamma

Notionals for straddle:

PutNotional(tn) = CallNotional(tn) = −0.5

ATM CashGamma(tn)

Notionals for risk-reversal:

PutNotional(tn) = −0.5× (Vatm(tn))2T

2%× {Put Vega(tn)}

CallNotional(tn) = +0.5× (Vatm(tn))2T

2%× {Call Vega(tn)}where 2% comes from strike width 2% = 101%− 99%

Important: for Straddle, cash-gamma is 1.0For Risk-reversal, the vanna (vega of delta) is 1.0

32

Page 33: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Monte-Carlo analysis: P&L accrualDaily re-balancing at times tn, n = 1, ..., NAt the end of each day, we roll into new position so straddle is at-the-money and risk-reversal has the same strike width

Realized P&L is P&L on hedges minus P&L on options position:

P&L =N∑n=1

{∆(tn−1)[S(tn)− S(tn−1)

]−[Π (T − dt, S(tn), Vatm(tn))−Π

(T, S(tn−1), Vatm(tn−1)

)]}

Π (T, S(tn), Vatm(tn)) is options position computed using BSM formula andimplied volatility skew (5) with Vatm(tn), T = 1/12, dt = 1/252Transaction costs are 2bp (k = 0.0002) per delta-rebalancing:

TC = k |∆(t0)|S(t0) + kN∑n=1

|∆(tn)−∆(tn−1)|S(tn)

where ∆(tn) is combined delta for newly rolled position

Important: P&L across different days and paths is maturity-timeand strike-space homogeneous - robust for statistical inference!

33

Page 34: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Monte-Carlo analysis - final notesTrade notional is 100,000,000$Realized P&L and explanatory variables are reported in thousands of $

Option maturity: one monthDaily re-hedging with total for each path: N = 21P&L is annualized by multiplying by 12

Draw 2,000 paths and compute realized P&L and price return, variance,volatility beta for changes in price and ATM vol, etc

Price and volatility paths are the same for straddle and risk-reversaland different hedging strategies

A) Analyze realized delta-hedging P&L (Profit and Loss) by[i] Realized P&L and its volatility, transaction costs[ii] Sharpe ratios

B) P&L Explain using regression model with explanatory variablesWhat factors (realized variance, covariance, etc) contribute to P&L

34

Page 35: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

1. Analysis of realized P&L for straddle

Figure left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costsRight - realized P&L with transaction costs

Approximately, straddle P&L is spread between implied&realized vols2:

P&L = Γ×{

(Vatm)2 − (Vret)2}

= 100,000×{

(16.75%)2 − (16.00%)2}

= 246

where Γ is cash-gamma notional in thousands $

Realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy

Important is that asset drift is zero, otherwise P&L-s for different hedgingstrategies have directional exposure to realized asset drift

244 243100

200

300 Straddle P&L, zero trans costs

0

Minimum var Empirical beta

161 161100

200

300 Straddle P&L after trans costs

161 161

0

Minimum var Empirical beta

35

Page 36: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

2. Analysis of realized P&L for risk-reversal

Figure: left - realized P&L with no accounting for transaction costsRight - realized P&L with transaction costs

Approximately, risk-reversal P&L is spread between implied and realizedco-variance of price and vol returns:

P&L = V ×{−SKEW×

[(Vatm)2 + (Vret)

2]

+ β[R] × (Vret)2}

= 100,211×{

0.5×[(16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2

]− 0.88× (16.00%)2

}= 431

where V is vanna notional in thousands $

Again, realized P&L little depends on the delta hedging strategy whenasset drift is zero

423 423

100

200

300

400

500 Risk-Reversal P&L, zero trans costs

0

100

Minimum var Empirical beta

190 192100

200

300

400

500 Risk-Reversal P&L after trans costs

190 192

0

100

Minimum var Empirical beta

36

Page 37: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

3. Analysis of transaction costs

Transaction costs are 2bp per traded delta notional or 1$ per 5,000$

Left figure: realized transaction costs1) Risk-reversal has higher transaction costs due to larger delta notional2) Minimum variance hedge and empirical hedge imply about equal trans-action costs for straddle3) Minimum variance hedge implies higher transaction costs forrisk-reversal because of over-hedging the put side

Right figure: volatility of transaction costsVolatility is about uniform and very small compared to mean costs

233 231100

200

300 Realized Transaction costs

83 82

0

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for

risk-reversal

5 52

4

6

Volatility of Transaction costs

2 2

0

2

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for

risk-reversal

37

Page 38: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

4. Volatility of Realized P&L

Left figure: P&L volatility without accounting for transaction costsEmpirical hedge implies lower P&L volatility for:[i] Risk-reversal (about 20%)[ii] Straddle (about 2− 3%)

Because Minimum Variance delta over-hedges for put side and make deltamore volatile

Right figure: volatility of realized P&L accounting for costs1) Transaction costs increase P&L slightly by about 1− 2%2) Contrast with reduction of realized P&L by about 50%

328 320

100

200

300

400 P&L Volatility, zero transaction costs

122 102

0

100

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for

risk-reversal

331 323

100

200

300

400 P&L Volatility, after transaction costs

122 102

0

100

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for

risk-reversal

38

Page 39: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

5. Sharpe ratios of realized P&L-s

Left figure: Sharpe ratios for delta-hedging P&L without account-ing for transaction costsRight figure: Sharpe ratios for P&L accounting for costs

1) For straddle, both Minimum Variance and Empirical hedges implyabout the Sharpe ratio

2) For risk-reversal, Minimum Var hedge implies smaller Sharpethan Empirical hedge (by about 20%) because of higher P&L volatilityand transaction costs

3.464.14

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

Sharpe ratio, zero tranaction costs

0.74 0.760.00

1.00

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for risk-

reversal

1.561.88

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00Sharpe ratio, after transaction cost

0.49 0.50

0.00

0.50

Min var for

straddle

Empirical

beta for

straddle

Min var for

risk-reversal

Empirical

beta for risk-

reversal

39

Page 40: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

P&L Attribution to risk factors is applied to understandwhat factors contribute to P&L by using regression

P&L = α+ s1X1 + s2X2 + s3X3 + s4X4 + s5X5 + s6X6 (6)

α (”Alpha”) is theta related P&L - P&L we would realize if nothing wouldmove

X1 (”Var”) is returns variance: X1 =∑(

S(tn)S(tn−1) − 1

)2

X2 (”VolChange”) is change in ATM vol: X2 =∑(

Vatm(tn)− Vatm(tn−1))

X3 (”Covar”) is covariance: X3 =∑(

S(tn)S(tn−1) − 1

) (Vatm(tn)− Vatm(tn−1)

)X4 (”VarVol”) is variance of vol changes: X4 =

∑(Vatm(tn)− Vatm(tn−1)

)2X5 (”Return3”) is cubic return: X5 =

∑(S(tn)S(tn−1) − 1

)3

X6 (”Return”) is realized return: X6 =∑(

S(tn)S(tn−1) − 1

)Summation

∑runs from n = 1 to n = N , N = 21

R2 indicates how well the realized variables explain realized P&L (notaccounting for transaction costs) - we should aim for R2 = 90%Some explanatory variables are correlated so it is robust to test reducedregressions

40

Page 41: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

P&L explain for straddle by realized variance of returns:Empirical hedge has stronger explanatory power

Is needed to confirm theoretical P&L explain by MC simulations

For P&L of straddle hedged at implied vol, first-order approximation:

V 2atm −

∑n

[S(tn)

S(tn−1)− 1

]2

First term is alpha or ”carry” - approximate alpha isα = Γ× V 2

atm = 100,000× 0.16752 = 2806Second term is short risk to realized variance - key variable for P&LTheoretical slope should be −Γ = −100,000

Figure: explanatory power using only realized variance is weak becauseof impact of other variables and skew (for multiple variables, R2 ≈ 90%)

P&L = -48,768*Var + 1,559

R² = 30%

0

4,000

P&

L

Straddle P&L by Min-Var Hedge

-8,000

-4,000

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15

P&

L

Realized Variance

P&L = -55,132*Var + 1,730

R² = 40%

0

4,000

P&

L

Straddle P&L by Empirical hedge

-8,000

-4,000

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15

P&

L

Realized Variance

41

Page 42: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

P&L explain for risk-reversal by realized vol beta:Empirical hedge implies that realized vol beta is cleardriver behind P&L of risk-reversal with R2 = 50%

For P&L of risk-reversal hedged at implied vol skew, approximation:

−SKEW×

{V 2atm +

∑n

[S(tn)

S(tn−1)− 1

]2}

+∑n

(S(tn)

S(tn−1)− 1

)(Vatm(tn)− Vatm(tn−1))

In terms of returns vol Vret and implied vol beta βR:

−SKEW×{V 2atm + V 2

ret

}+ β[R] × V 2

ret

First term is ”carry” or alphaSecond term is risk to realized beta between returns and vol - key variableIn our example: α = 0.5× V × {(16.75%)2 + (16.00%)2} = 2,682Slope= V × (16.00%)2 = 2,560

P&L = 2129*Beta + 2570

R² = 37%

0

1500

3000Risk-Reversal P&L

by Min-Var Hedge

-1500

0

-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5

P&

L

Realized Volatility Beta

P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490

R² = 49%

0

1500

3000Risk-Reversal P&L

by Empirical Hedge

-1500

0

-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5

P&

L

Realized Volatility Beta

42

Page 43: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Important: vol beta (for skew) is comparable to Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) implied volatility (for one strike)

1) Volatility and vol beta are meaningful and intuitive model pa-rameters which can be inferred from both implied and historical data

Implied vol σ[I] is inferred from option market priceRealized vol σ[R] is volatility of price returns

Implied vol beta β[I] is inferred from market skew (β[I] ≈ 2× SKEW)Realized vol beta β[R] is change in implied ATM volatility predicted byprice returns: β[R] = 〈dS(t)dVatm(t)〉 /(σ[R])2

2) Both serve as directs input for computation of hedges

3) Both allow for P&L explain of vanilla options in terms of impliedand realized model parameters:Implied/realized volatility- P&L of delta-hedged straddle:(

σ[I])2−(σ[R]

)2

Implied/realized volatility beta- P&L of short delta-hedged risk-reversal(more noisy because of contribution from σ[R]):

−β[I] ×{

1

2

[(σ[I]

)2+[σ[R]

]2]}+ β[R] ×

(σ[R]

)2

43

Page 44: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Conclusion: existing practical approaches for hedgingimprovement are not fully satisfactory - we need propermodel for dynamic delta-hedging!A) Hedge all vega exposure

B) Recalibration for computing delta-risks (most common):⊗ Project change in implied volatility using empirical backbone(For example, by applying empirical volatility skew-beta)⊗ Re-calibrate valuation model to bumped volatility surface⊗ Re-valuate and compute delta by finite-differences

However runs into problems:1) A) - vega-hedging is (very) expensive and unprofitable unlessimplied skew and vol-of-vol are sold at large premiums to future realizeds

2) B) - re-calibration works poorly for path-dependent and multi-asset products and it makes P&L explain very noisyRecall applying regression for P&L explain of straddle and risk-reversal

3) any mix of A) and B) becomes very tedious for CVA computations

Important: the choice between local vol (LV) or stoch vol (SV) is irrel-evant when hedging using minimum variance hedge at implied vol skew -any combination of LV and SV produces almost the same deltas!

44

Page 45: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Beta SV model with jumps is fitted to empirical&implieddynamics for computing correct delta (Sepp 2014):

dS(t)

S(t)= (µ(t)− λ(eη − 1)) dt+ V (t)dW (0)(t) + (eη − 1) dN(t)

dV (t) = κ(θ − V (t))dt+ βV (t)dW (0)(t) + εV (t)dW (1)(t) + βη dN(t)

1) Consistent with empirical dynamics of implied ATM volatility byspecifying empirical volatility beta β

2) Has jumps, as degree of risk-aversion, to make model fit to bothempirical dynamics and risk-neutral skew premiumOnly one parameter with simple calibration! - explained in a bit

Jumps/risk-aversion under risk-neutral measure Q produced by:Poisson process N(t) with intensity λ:negative&positive jumps in returns&vols with constant size η < 0&βη > 0

3) Easy-to-implement (with no extra parameters) extension to multi-asset dynamics using common jumps - produces basket correlation skew

4) Beta SVJ model is robust to produce optimal hedges for path-dependent and multi-asset trades and CVA

45

Page 46: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Third to last topic: closed-form solution for log-normalBeta SV

Mean-reverting log-normal SV models are not analytically tractable

I derive a very accurate exp-affine approximation for moment generatingfunction (details in my paper)

Idea comes from information theory: apply Kullback-Leibler relative en-tropy for unknown PDF p(x) and test PDF q(x) with moment constraints:∫xkp(x)dx =

∫xkq(x)dx, k = 1,2, ...

Now let’s think in terms of moment function:[i] MGF for Beta SV model with normal driver for SV (as in Stein-SteinSV model) has exact solution, which has exp-affine form

[ii] Correction for log-normal SV has an exp-affine form

15%

20%

25%

30%

35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500

options, beta SV, NO JUMPS

Analytic for Normal SV

5%

10%

15%

0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Strike

Analytic for Normal SV

Closed-form for Log-normal SV

Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV

15%

20%

25%

30%

35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500

options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS

5%

10%

15%

0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Strike

Analytic for Normal SV

Closed-form for Log-normal SV

Monte-Carlo for Log-normal SV

46

Page 47: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Proof that closed-form MFG for log-normal model pro-duces theoretically consistent probability density

1) Derive solutions for excepted values, variances, and covariances of thelog-price and quadratic variance (QV) by solving PDE directly

2) Prove that moments derived using approximate MGF equal to theo-retical moments derived in 1)

Using closed-form MFG for log-normal model, we apply standard valuationmethods for affine SV models based on Lipton-Lewis formula

Implementation of closed-form moment function (MGF), MC, and PDEpricers produce values of vanilla options on equity and quadratic variancethat are equal within numerical accuracy of these methods

15%

20%

25%

30%

35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500

options, beta SV, NO JUMPS

Closed-form MGF

5%

10%

15%

0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Strike

Closed-form MGF

Monte-Carlo

PDE, numerical solver

15%

20%

25%

30%

35% Implied vol for 1y S&P500

options, beta SV, WITH JUMPS

Closed-form MGF

5%

10%

15%

0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Strike

Closed-form MGF

Monte-Carlo

PDE, numerical solver

47

Page 48: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Second to last topic - optimal hedging under discretetrading and transaction costs

To adopt to practical option trading:a) change ”kid” to ”trader”b) change ”cantaloupes” to ”millions of delta over an infinitesimal timeperiod dt”

As we saw in simulation of P&L, we need quantitative framework thatincorporates discrete hedging and optimizes trade-off between:the reward - higher P&L and lower transaction coststhe risk - higher P&L volatility

48

Page 49: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Illustration of trading in implied&realized vol with strad-dle: unique optimal hedging frequency can be found!

Figure 1) Forecast expected upside:the spread between implied and real-ized vol for given maturity TThis is independent of valua-tion&hedging model and hedgingfrequency

Figure 2) Forecast P&L volatilityand transaction costsThese depend on valuation&hedgingmodel and hedging frequency

Part of P&L volatility is not hedge-able due to vol-of-vol and jumps -Not optimal to hedge too fre-quently

Figure 3) Obtain Sharpe ratio as ra-tio of forecast P&L after costs andP&L volatility

1%

2%

3%Expected/Forcasted P&L(N)

0%

1%

10 160 310 460 610 760 910

N - hedging frequency

1%

2%

3% Expected/Forcasted P&L Volatility and Costs (N)

P&L Volatility

Transaction costs

0%

1%

10 160 310 460 610 760 910

N - hedging frequency

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

1.4 Expected/Forcasted Sharpe Ratio (N)

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

10 160 310 460 610 760 910

N - hedging frequency

49

Page 50: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Solution for optimal Sharpe ratio with dynamics underphysical measure driven by Diffusion and SV with jumps

Sharpe(N) =Expected P&L−TransactionCosts(N)

P&L Volatility(N)

N is hedging frequency - for details see my paper on optimal delta-hedging

Using this solution we can analyze:Figure 1) What maturity is optimal to trade given the forecast spreadbetween implieds and realizeds(longer maturities have higher spreads but their P&L is more volatilebecause of higher risk to ATM vol changes)

Figure 2) What is optimal hedging frequency for each maturityTranslate into approximations of optimal bands for price and delta triggers

Naturally, results are sensitive to assumed price dynamicsUnder SV with jumps: lower Sharp ratio and less frequent hedging

1.0

1.3

1.6

Optimal Sharpe ratioDiffusion

Stochastic volatility with jumps

0.4

0.7

1m

4m

7m

10m

13m

16m

19m

22m

25m

28m

31m

34m

37m

Option maturity in months

4

6

8

10

12 Optimal hedging frequency in days

Diffusion

Stochastic volatility with jumps

0

2

4

1m

4m

7m

10m

13m

16m

19m

22m

25m

28m

31m

34m

37m

Option maturity in months

50

Page 51: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Last topic: why the beta stochastic vol model withjumps is better than its alternatives (for stock indices)

The most important feature for dynamic hedging model:1) Ability to produce different volatility regimes as observed in themarket and to imply empirically consistent delta

Recall definition of volatility skew-beta: change in term structure of ATMvolatility, σATM(T ), predicted by price return times SKEW(T )

We saw that vol skew-beta is very important to account for correct P&Larising from change in BSM implied vols

Skew-consistent SV and LV models imply skew-beta of 2Empirical vol skew-beta: S&P 500 ≈ 1.5; STOXX50 ≈ 1.8; Nikkei≈ 0.5

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for STOXX 50

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for NIKKEI

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

51

Page 52: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Why the beta SV with jumps is better than its alterna-tives

Extra arguments to look at apart from implied volatility skew-beta

2) Fit to empirical distribution of implied and realized volatilities

3) Interpretation of model parameters in terms of impact on model impliedBSM vols

4) P&L explain for delta-hedging strategies of vanilla options in terms ofimplied and realized model parameters

5) Stability of model parameters

Calibration to vanilla options is not a problem in practical applications -it is easy to achieve by introducing a (small) local vol part

Calibration problem is solved by Dupire (1994) for diffusions, Andersen-Andreasen (2000) for jump-diffusions, Lipton (2002) for SV with jumps

52

Page 53: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

I. Non-parametric local volatility model - textbook im-plementation of Dupire local volatility using discrete setof option prices and interpolation

It is a good competitor to start my comparison because it fails on allcounts

As for interpretation and stability of model parameters - see quiz on thenext slide

53

Page 54: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Interpretation and stability of non-parametric LV

Quiz: one of two figures below is[A] local vol surface fitted to discrete prices of S&P500 index options[B] Eckert IV map projection of a ski mountain where I was skiing lastwinterWhich is which ?

The same conclusion is for any SV and LV model implemented naivelyusing direct calibration to market prices and mean-variance hedging:1-2) Wrong hedges and empirical inconsistency3-5) Uninterpretable and unstable model parameters

54

Page 55: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

II. Industry-standard alternative (in equity derivatives)Implied volatility@strike-into-density@price approach (my terminology)Conceptually:

σimpl(K;T )→ Pimpl(S(T ) = K) (7)

where→ is Dupire LV formula in terms of implied vols at strike K&mat T

Figure 1A) Given parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K;T )

Figure 1B) Given backbone function fbackbone(δS;K,T ) to map pricechanges δS into changes in vols δσimpl(K;T ) according to specified regime

Figure 2) → in Eq(7) serves as interpolator from implied vols in strikespace to implied densities in price space

Figure 3) LV model projects densities to option prices in ”model-independent”way using MC or PDE methods

20%

30%

40%

50%

Imp

lie

d V

ola

tili

ty

Implied Volatility (S0=1.00)

Implied Volatility (S1=0.95)

Change in IV from backbone function

0%

10%

20%

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2

Imp

lie

d V

ola

tili

ty

Strike

0.75%

1.50%

2.25%

Density

Implied Density from LV mapping (S0=1.00)

Implied Density from LV mapping (S1=0.95)

Change in Density from LV mapping

-0.75%

0.00%

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2

Density

Spot

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

PV

PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S0)

PV Risk-Reversal 95-105% (S1)

Change in PV Risk-Reversal 95-105%

-0.20

-0.10

0.00

0.10

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2

Spot

55

Page 56: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

1) Hedging performance for local vol approach are pri-mary driven by parametric form for implied vols σimpl(K;T )and empirical backbone function

2) No consistency with empirical distribution of implied and realized vol

3) & 4) Model interpretation and P&L explain are possible only in termsof parameters of functional form for implied volatility

Key drawback of implied volatility-into-density approach:

[i] For computation of delta it requires a re-calibration of local vol andre-valuation for any change in market data

[ii] Lacks vol-of-vol so it is inconsistent for hedging of path-dependentoptions sensitive to forward vols and skews

56

Page 57: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Alternatives for local vol or σimpl(K;T )→ Pimpl(S(T ) = K)approach do not produce improvements

Instead of LV to map implied vol into price density, it is also customaryto use SV or LSV models as interpolators with extra degree of freedom

Hereby hodel choice is typically motivated by availability of a ”closed-form” solution, not empirical consistency!

Figure: SV and LSV models are not applied for hedging as dynamicmodels since their model delta is wrong - with and without minimumvariance hedge - but through re-calibration to empirical backbone

1.5%

2.5%

3.5%Change in implied vol, S1-S0=-0.05

SV model delta

SV with Min Var Hedge

Empirical backbone

-1.5%

-0.5%

0.5%

0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20

Strike

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00Delta for 1y call option on

S&P500

SV model

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20 Strike

SV with Min Var hedge

Sticky-Strike BSM delta

SV re-calibrated to empirical backbone

To conclude I use a quote from Richard P. Feynman:It doesn’t matter how beautiful your theory is, it doesn’t matterhow smart you are. If it doesn’t agree with experiment, it’s wrong!

57

Page 58: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

III. Arguments in favor of Beta SVJ model:1) the model has ability to fit empirical vol skew-betaand produce correct option delta without re-calibration

Figure: delta from SVJ model fits empirical backbone

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00 Delta for 1y call option on

S&P500

SV model

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00 1.10 1.20Strike

SV with Min Var hedge

SV re-calibrated to Market backbone

SVJ (without re-calibration)

2) Consistent with the empirical distributions of implied and realizedvolatilities, which are very close to log-normal

3) It has clear intuition behind the key model parameters:Volatility beta is sensitivity to changes in short-term ATM volResidual vol-of-vol is volatility of idiosyncratic changes in ATM vol

4) P&L explain is possible in terms of implied and realized quantitiesof key model parameter - vol beta

5) Stability and calibration - next slide

58

Page 59: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Calibration of beta SV model is based on econometricand implied approaches without large-scale non-linearand non-intuitive calibrations

1) Parameters of SV part are estimated from time series

2) Jump/risk-aversion params are fitted to empirical vol skew-beta

Params in 1) & 2) are updated only following changes in volatility regime

3) Small mis-calibrations of the SV part and jumps are correctedusing local vol (LV) partContribution to skew from LV part is kept small (no more than 10-15%)

Local vol part is re-calibrated on the fly to reproduce small variations insome parts of implied vol surface, which are caused by temporary supply-demand factors specific to that part

It is also robust to compute bucketed vega risk in this way

In practical terms:1) Local volatility part accounts for the noise from idiosyncraticchanges in implied volatility surface

2) Stochastic volatility and jumps serve as time- and space-homogeneousfactors for the shape of the implied volatility surface

59

Page 60: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

More details on calibration of beta SV model (technicalpart omitted during the talk)1) Parameters of SV part are calibrated using maximum likelihood meth-ods from time series of 1m implied ATM volatility (or the VIX)[i] mean-reversion κ is estimated over longer-period, at least 5 years, -better to keep it constant at 3.00[ii] vol beta β and residual vol-vol ε are estimated over shorter periods,1y, - typically β ≈ −1.00 and ε ∈ [0.60,1.00]

2) Negative jump in return η is fitted using Merton jump model to putoptions with maturity of 6 months and [80% − 100%] OTM strikes -typically η = −30%

3) Given 1) and 2): 3A) jump intensity λ is calibrated to fit the empiricalsensitivity of implied volatility changes to price changes, aka volatilityskew-beta, - typically λ ∈ [0.03,0.2]Given all above: 3B) initial vol V (0) and mean vol θ calibrated to fit thecurrent term structure of ATM vols

Parameters in 1), 2) 3A) (relatively uniform for major stock indices) areupdated infrequently

4) Local vol part is added to fit daily variations in implied vol surface

60

Page 61: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

For risk-neutral pricing, distribution of jumps does notmatter - jumps are only needed to fit skew premium

Recall illustration of emergence of Q-skew using Bakshi-Kapadia-Madanformula and Merton jump model:[i] Under P, jumps are symmetricwith mean of 0% and volatility of 4%[ii] The risk-neutral mean jump is−5% with zero volatility

4%

6%

8%

10%

Frequency

Frequency of S&P500 daily returns

Empirical

Frequency

Physical Merton

under P

Risk-Neutral

0%

2%

4%

-9% -7% -5% -4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 7%

Frequency

Daily return

Risk-Neutral

Merton under Q

Yet, jumps are needed to fit market prices & compute correct deltas

Also jumps are important to fit market prices of options on realized andimplied volatilities (VIX) - see my presentations at GD in 2011 & 2012

Practical explanation for excessive risk-neutral skew premium:

1) Risk-averse investors always ready to over-pay for insurance ir-respectively of price changes

2) As part of index correlation skew premium, when holders ofstock portfolios buy index puts for (macro) protection

To make things robust, I assume constant jumps with simple calibration61

Page 62: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

How to explain the difference between impliedand realized dynamics using preference theory

For retail option buyer - option value is derived from his preference/utilityfor specific payoffs in certain market scenarios

For institutional option seller - option value is derived from:[i] Expected hedging costs[ii] Smooth stream of fees and P&L[iii] Premium for suffering losses in bad market conditions

As a result:

1) Option prices in the market are set by demand-supply equilibriumbetween sellers and buyers

2) Risk-aversion parameters is a degree of demand-supply imbal-ance

3) Implied and realized vols and, in particular, skews are different

62

Page 63: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

To conclude: we can think of jumps as a mea-sure of risk-aversion for pricing kernel!Recently, interesting research is made and also presented at Global Deriva-tives on how to imply the ”expected-implied” physical distribution fromoptions market prices and specified risk-aversion

Stephen Ross:The Recovery Theorem, GD2012, Journal of Finance 2014Peter Carr: Can we recover?, Global Derivatives 2013

Computation of ”empirical” delta and calibration of excessive skew arerelated concepts:1) Compute option delta under ”expected-implied” physical distri-bution using empirical vol beta2) Fit level of risk-aversion to excessive skew premium observed inmarket prices of index options

These concepts and volatility skew-beta are related to the interplay be-tween the implied and realized risk premiums:[i] high implied / positive realized risk premiums - sticky strike vol regime[ii] low implied / negative realized risk premiums - sticky local vol regime

To be continued at next year Global Derivatives conference...

63

Page 64: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Summary1) Dynamics of implied and real-ized vols are log-normal

2) Implied vol beta significantlyoverestimates realized beta

3) Vol skew-beta is important forcorrect P&L - any dynamic hedgingmodel should fit empirical skew-betaRisk-Aversion/Jumps parameteris added to fit empirical skew-betaSVJ fits empirical skew-beta≈ 1.5,unlike Minimum Var delta≈ 2.04) Beta SVJ model applied fordelta-hedging risk-reversal is tool toproduce P&L from spread be-tween implied and realized skews

Log-normal beta SVJ model:⊗Is consistent with the empiricaldynamics of ATM volatility⊗Produces correct option deltas⊗Can significantly improve Shar-pe ratios for delta-hedging P&Ls

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

Freq

uency

Empirical frequency of

normalized logarithm of the VIX

EmpiricalStandard Normal

0%

1%

2%

3%

-4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4

Freq

uency

Log-VIX

-0.5

0.0

Feb-07

Sep-07

Apr-08

Nov

-08

Jun-09

Jan-10

Aug

-10

Mar-11

Oct-11

May-12

Dec-12

Jul-1

3

Implied Volatility Beta

Realized Volatility Beta

-2.0

-1.5

-1.0

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50Vol Skew-Beta for S&P500

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

0.00

0.50

1m

3m

5m

7m

9m

11m

13m

15m

17m

19m

21m

23m

T in months

SVJ Skew-Beta with empirical beta

Sticky local with Min-var delta

Empirical bounds

P&L = 2050*Beta + 2490

R² = 49%

0

1500

3000

P&

L

Risk-Reversal P&L vs

Realized Vol Beta

-1500

0

-2.0 -1.5 -1.0 -0.5

P&

L

Realized Volatility Beta

64

Page 65: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

Disclaimer

The views represented herein are the author own views and do not neces-sarily represent the views of Bank of America Merrill Lynch or its affiliates

65

Page 66: Realized and implied index skews, jumps, and the failure of the minimum-variance hedging

ReferencesAndersen, L., Andreasen, J., (2000), “Jump-Diffusion Processes - Volatility Smile Fittingand Numerical Methods for Option Pricing ,” Review of Derivatives Research 4, 231-262Bakshi, G., Kapadia, N., Madan, D., (2003), “Stock return characteristics, skew laws,and the differential pricing of individual equity options,” Review of Financial Studies 16(1), 101-143Bergomi, L., (2009), “Smile dynamics 4,” Risk, December, 94-100Bergomi,L.,Guyon,J.,(2012),“Stochastic volatility’s orderly smiles,”Risk,May,117-123Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., Mimouni, K., (2010), “Models for S&P 500 Dynam-ics: Evidence from Realized Volatility, Daily Returns and Options Prices,” Review ofFinancial Studies 23(8), 3141-3189Derman, E., (1999), “Volatility Regimes,” Risk, April, 55-59Dupire, B. (1994), “Pricing with a smile”, Risk, July, 18-20Karasinski, P., Sepp, A., (2012), “Beta stochastic volatility model,” Risk, October,67-73Lewis, A., (2000), “Option valuation under stochastic volatility,” Finance Press, New-port Beach, CaliforniaLipton, A., (2002). “The vol smile problem”, Risk, February, 81-85Ross, S., (2014). “The Recovery Theorem”, Journal of Finance, forthcomingSepp, A., (2011), “Efficient Numerical PDE Methods to Solve Calibration and PricingProblems in Local Stochastic Volatility Models”, Global Derivatives conference in ParisSepp, A., (2012), “Achieving Consistent Modeling Of VIX and Equities Derivatives”,Global Derivatives conference in BarcelonaSepp, A., (2013), “Consistently Modeling Joint Dynamics of Volatility and UnderlyingTo Enable Effective Hedging”, Global Derivatives conference in AmsterdamSepp, A., (2013), “When You Hedge Discretely: Optimization of Sharpe Ratio forDelta-Hedging Strategy under Discrete Hedging and Transaction Costs,” The Journalof Investment Strategies 3(1), 19-59Sepp, A., (2014), “Empirical Calibration and Minimum-Variance Delta Under Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Dynamics,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2387845Sepp, A., (2014), “Affine Approximation for Moment Generating Function of Log-Normal Stochastic Volatility Model,” Working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2522425

66