7
Brown Brothers Harriman | COMMODITY MARKETS UPDATE Issue 3 2017 1 The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy By Jay Foraker The United States was born a resource-rich exporting colony of the United Kingdom, generating federal revenues and protecting infant industries through tariffs on imports in the decades following its founding. Although tariff rates had fallen by the onset of the Civil War, the Union’s need to fund the war effort and the removal of opposition from Southern states in Congress began a period of relatively high tariffs that lasted until shortly before World War I, when they were lowered in conjunction with the introduction of a federal income tax. Tariffs were once again raised in the 1920s, but a key inflection point was the Tariff Act of 1930, also known as the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. Smoot-Hawley represents a high-water mark for tariffs, after which the U.S. took a leading role on the world stage in reducing tariffs globally and creating a legal framework for resolving trade disputes via the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and World Trade Organization (WTO). In this article, we reflect on the evolution of U.S. trade policy, specifically as it pertains to tariffs, and highlight lessons learned from key events, including Smoot-Hawley. 1 1 This article provides a historical overview of U.S. trade policy. For more details on how trade changes could affect today’s economy, read Chief Investment Strategist Scott Clemons’ first quarter 2017 InvestorView article, “The Economy and Markets in the Time of Trump.”

The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

  • Upload
    vominh

  • View
    216

  • Download
    3

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E Issue 3 2017 1

The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy By Jay Foraker

The United States was born a resource-rich exporting colony of the United Kingdom, generating federal revenues and protecting infant industries through tariffs on imports in the decades following its founding. Although tariff rates had fallen by the onset of the Civil War, the Union’s need to fund the war effort and the removal of opposition from Southern states in Congress began a period of relatively high tariffs that lasted until shortly before World War I, when they were lowered in conjunction with the introduction of a federal income tax.

Tariffs were once again raised in the 1920s, but a key inflection point was the Tariff Act of 1930, also known as the Smoot-Hawley Tariff. Smoot-Hawley represents a high-water mark for tariffs, after which the U.S. took a leading role on the world stage in reducing tariffs globally and creating a legal framework for resolving trade disputes via the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and World Trade Organization (WTO).

In this article, we reflect on the evolution of U.S. trade policy, specifically as it pertains to tariffs, and highlight lessons learned from key events, including Smoot-Hawley.1

1 This article provides a historical overview of U.S. trade policy. For more details on how trade changes could affect today’s economy, read Chief Investment Strategist Scott Clemons’ first quarter 2017 InvestorView article, “The Economy and Markets in the Time of Trump.”

Page 2: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E Issue 3 2017 2

2 Galbraith, John Kenneth. Economics in Perspective: A Critical History. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1987, p. 157.

3 Ibid., p. 158.

4 Robertson, Ross. History of the American Economy. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1955, p. 328.

U.S. Tariffs in the 18th and 19th CenturiesAt the nation’s founding, U.S. trade policy was decidedly protec-tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared with the present day.

The first federal tariff was enacted in 1789; as early as 1795, Treasury Secretary Alexander Hamilton’s Report on Manufactures encouraged protection of young “infant” industries in the new nation from more developed foreign com-petitors. Soon thereafter, in the early 19th century, Sen. Henry Clay of Kentucky advocated a system of industrial development in the United States underpinned by the imposition of tariffs on imports.2

Yet the early republic was divided – decisively along regional bounds – over the issue of import tariffs. Generally speaking, Northern industrialists supported tariffs to protect a burgeon-ing domestic manufacturing sector, while Southern agricultural interests opposed them. The Tariff of 1828 (or “Tariff of Abomi-nations,” as it was known to Southern opponents) starkly revealed schisms of the era. It allowed average tariff rates to rise to approximately 60% on most imports and contributed to the Nullification Crisis of 1833, in which South Carolina voted to nullify federal tariffs. The result was the Compromise Tariff of 1833, which gradually lowered federal tariffs over time.

Opposition to tariffs grew along ideological, in addition to regional, lines. This included those who opposed tariffs because of the resulting federal revenue surpluses, which caused con-tention over what to do with said surpluses.3

The advent of the Civil War largely shifted the contours of the debate as Southern representatives left Congress following secession and the voice of surplus opponents softened as the costs of waging the war shrank the surplus. The Civil War ush-ered in a high-tariff era that lasted until the early 20th century.

The newly formed Republican Party led by President Lincoln campaigned on a high-tariff platform in 1860, partly to gain sup-port from Eastern industrialists. Following the party’s electoral victory, the Morrill Tariff was passed in 1861, which was the first in a long series of tariff increases that lasted until the early 20th century.4

U.S. Tariffs in the Early 20th CenturyTariffs were the primary source of federal tax revenues until the Progressive Era of the early 20th century. At this time, vari-ous forces – including the maturing of domestic manufacturing industries and the fact that the U.S. populace was beginning to push back against tariff-induced price increases – led to a shift away from tariffs and toward an income tax for raising revenues

WHAT IS A TARIFF?

A tariff is a tax levied on finished goods or raw materials entering one country from another. They can be used as a mechanism for making imports artificially more expensive in order to protect domestic producers of these goods or raw materials. Tariffs can also be a more efficient and effective way for countries to raise revenues compared with levying income, sales or other types of tax. U.S. trade policy has been cyclical in nature with respect to tariffs, as illustrated in the nearby chart. Tariffs represent the dollar value of duties collected.

Data as of January 30, 2006 (Historical Statistics of the United States Millennial Edition Online) and September 15, 2017 (The World Bank).

Source: Historical Statistics of the United States Millennial Edition Online and The World Bank.

U.S. Historical Average Tariff Rates(1790-2015)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

1790

1795

1800

1805

1810

1815

1820

1825

1830

1835

1840

1845

1850

1855

1860

1865

1870

1875

1880

1885

1890

1895

1900

1905

1910

1915

1920

1925

1930

1935

1940

1945

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

Tariffs as % of All Imports Tariffs as % of Dutiable Imports

1828: “Tariff of Abominations”

1861: Morrill Tariff

1833: Nullification Crisis & Compromise Tariff

1913: Underwood Act

1930: Smoot-Hawley Tariff

1933: U.S. tariffs peak

1922: Fordney-McCumber Tariff

1947: Beginning of GATT

Page 3: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E Issue 3 2017 3

5 Ibid., p. 329.

6 Leuchtenburg, William. The Perils of Prosperity 1914-1932, 2nd Edition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993, p. 109.

7 Garraty, John A. The Great Depression. New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, 1986, p. 54.

8 Gordon, John Steele. An Empire of Wealth: The Epic History of American Economic Power. New York: Harper Collins, 2004, pp. 320-321.

9 “The Battle of Smoot-Hawley.” The Economist. December 18, 2008.

10 Kennedy, David M. Freedom from Fear: The American People in Depression and War, 1929-1945. Vol. 9 of The Oxford History of the United States. New York: Oxford University Press, 1999, p. 50.

to fund the federal government. Resulting was the 1913 ratifica-tion of the 16th Amendment to the Constitution allowing for a federal income tax, along with the passage of the Underwood Tariff Act instituting a federal income tax and gradually lowering basic tariff rates from 40% to 25% under Democratic President Woodrow Wilson.5

Following World War I, the U.S. returned to a high-tariff policy under the Fordney-McCumber Tariff of 1922. Key drivers of this were military costs from the war, the emergence of new infant industries (e.g., chemicals) viewed as needing protection and a desire to protect domestic agriculture production. This return to high tariffs, however, had two negative consequences: difficulty for Europe to export to the U.S. and thereby recover financially from the war, as well as subsidizing U.S. agricultural overpro-duction.6 These factors are frequently cited as contributors to the Great Depression.

The Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930The origins of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff can be traced to the 1928 presidential campaign, during which Republican candi-date Herbert Hoover campaigned on a platform of alleviating the plight of the U.S. farmer. Again, as many economists and historians have cited, a central agricultural problem in the 1920s was overproduction.7

Following Hoover’s victory and the control of both houses of Congress by his party, additional industries came before Congress and pleaded for protection, with the result being the Smoot-Hawley Tariff of 1930, which introduced the highest average tariff rates since the 1830s.8

Both Sen. Reed Smoot (R-Utah and Senate Finance Committee chair) and Rep. Willis Hawley (R-Oregon and House Committee on Ways and Means chair) hailed from predominantly rural, agri-cultural states. As such, the act initially had a special focus on agriculture. However, following the 1929 stock market crash and act’s passage in June 1930, its scope expanded to include over 900 imported agricultural and non-agricultural products and raised average tariff rates to nearly 60%.9

There was strong opposition to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff at the time. A letter signed by more than 1,000 economists was pre-sented to President Hoover opposing the act. Further, Thomas Lamont, who was J.P. Morgan’s deputy at the eponymous Morgan Bank, recalled that in 1930 “I almost went down on my knees to beg Herbert Hoover to veto the asinine Hawley-Smoot Tariff. That Act intensified nationalism all over the world.”10

% o

f Tot

al U

.S. F

eder

al T

ax R

even

ues

U.S. Federal Tax Revenues, Composition of Receipts by Source(1792-2016)

Ad Valorem Taxes (Tariffs, Excise, Sales Taxes)

Fees/Charges, Business and Other (Education, Healthcare, Utility Fees)

Social Insurance Taxes (OASDI, Unemployment Insurance, Employee Retirement)

Income Taxes (Individual, Corporate)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

1792

1798

1804

1810

1816

1822

1828

1834

1840

1846

1852

1858

1864

1870

1876

1882

1888

1894

1900

1906

1912

1918

1924

1930

1936

1942

1948

1954

1960

1966

1972

1978

1984

1990

1996

2002

2008

2014

1833: Compromise Act reduces tariffs

1913: Underwood Act enacts federal income tax 1933: U.S. tariffs peak

1930: Smoot-Hawley Tariff

1937: First Social Security taxes collected

1966: Medicare launch expands payroll taxes

Data as of November 3, 2017. Source: www.usgovernmentrevenue.com.

Page 4: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E Issue 3 2017 4

11 Ahamed, Liaquat. Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World. New York: Penguin Press, 2009, p. 374.

12 Gordon. An Empire of Wealth, p. 321.

13 Krugman, Paul, and Maurice Obstfeld. International Economics: Theory and Policy, 5th Edition. New York: Addison Wesley, 2001, p. 544.

14 Ahamed. Lords of Finance, pp. 375-376.

15 Galbraith, John Kenneth. A Journey Through Economic Time: A Firsthand View. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1994, p. 82.

Statistically speaking, the impact of Smoot-Hawley was stark. In the year following the crash of October 1929, which includes the enactment of Smoot-Hawley:11

• Industrial production fell 30% in the United States, 25% in Germany and 20% in the United Kingdom.

• Five million people became unemployed in the United States.

• Commodity prices collapsed 50% globally, including coffee, wheat and cotton.

Other objective measures of Smoot-Hawley’s effect include the following:12

• The nominal value of global trade dropped from $36 billion in 1929 to $12 billion in 1932.

• The value of U.S. exports fell from $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.2 billion in 1932.

• The rate of bank failures in the U.S. began to accelerate.

While there is disagreement around the degree to which Smoot-Hawley contributed to the Great Depression, the consensus is that it had some impact.

There are several perspectives to the debate. First, although the act is widely cited as an example of bad policy, there is disagree-ment as to its actual impact and significance. Highlighting direct damage caused by Smoot-Hawley, economists Paul Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld contend that “major economic harm was done by restrictions on international trade and payments, which proliferated as countries attempted to discourage imports and keep aggregate demand bottled up at home” and that Smoot-Hawley “had a damaging effect on employment abroad.”13

To the contrary, author Liaquat Ahamed contends that far more damaging than the protectionist Smoot-Hawley Act was the

collapse in capital flows in 1930, specifically the slowdown of U.S. foreign investment in Europe. He also points out that exports were a relatively small share (4%) of U.S. GDP at the time, and as such, changes in capital flows would have dwarfed changes in trade flows, and the impact of tariffs would have been relatively limited.14 In addition, U.S. tariffs were already at relatively high levels historically in the 1920s.

Second, Smoot-Hawley illustrates what can happen when trad-ing partners react to an elevated tariff. Following its enactment in June 1930, retaliatory measures were introduced by Italy, France, Canada, Cuba, Mexico, Australia and New Zealand. Even Switzerland retaliated against the higher tariffs on Swiss watches contained in the act.15 The U.K.’s response was to insti-tute an “imperial preference system” that raised tariffs in an

Page 5: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Issue 3 2017 5

effort to keep trade within the British Empire.16 In sum, Smoot-Hawley had the result of raising domestic welfare by worsening conditions abroad. Such a policy is known as a “beggar thy neighbor” policy. For this reason, the act is frequently cited as a quintessential example of a zero-sum policy choice. Per Charles Kindleberger, Smoot-Hawley was a mistake for both economic and psychological reasons “less for its impact on the United States balance of payments, or as conduct unbecoming of a creditor nation, than for its irresponsibility” because it led to a “headlong stampede to protection and restrictions” worldwide.17

Third, U.S. tariffs have not returned to Smoot-Hawley levels since the 1930s; in fact, U.S. trade policy has decidedly changed course. The 1933 London Economic Conference failed in achiev-ing a multilateral solution to Smoot-Hawley and other retaliatory tariffs. Indeed, there was short-term evidence that “save your own neck” policies were working.18 As the Great Depression worsened, however, a major shift in U.S. trade policy occurred in 1934 with the passage of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act, which authorized the Roosevelt administration to nego-tiate trade agreements reducing tariffs bilaterally. Thirty-one such agreements were completed in the following decade.19 The 1944 Bretton Woods Agreement initially envisioned, along-side the World Bank and International Monetary Fund (IMF), the establishment of the International Trade Organization (ITO) to facilitate the multilateral reduction of tariffs. Interestingly, the ITO was never established, largely due to U.S. political opposi-tion, but can be seen as a forerunner to the WTO.20

ConclusionAfter Smoot-Hawley and the close of World War II, the U.S. turned decidedly in the direction of free trade – that is, reducing tariffs, a trend that rippled throughout the industrialized capital-ist countries.

16 Gordon. An Empire of Wealth, p. 321.

17 Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1973, pp. 28, 294.

18 Garraty. The Great Depression, pp. 70-71.

19 Trebilcock, Michael, and Robert Howse. The Regulation of International Trade, 2nd Edition. New York: Routledge, 2002, p. 20.

20 Ibid., p. 21.

U.S. Trade Policy Timeline 1789 Congress passes first federal tariff, signed by President

George Washington.

1795 Hamilton’s Report on Manufactures advocates protection of infant industries.

1828 Tariff of Abominations raises average tariff rates to approximately 60%, contributing to Nullification Crisis of 1833.

1833 Compromise Tariff commits to gradually reducing tariff rates.

1861 Morrill Tariff begins era of gradually rising tariffs that lasts until early 20th century.

1861-1865 Civil War.

1913 Underwood Act establishes federal income tax, seeking to reduce reliance of federal income on tariffs; average tariffs are lowered from 40% to 25%.

1914-1918 World War I.

1922 Fordney-McCumber Tariff reinstitutes a high-tariff policy.

1929 Stock market crashes, and the Great Depression starts.

1930 Tariff Act of 1930 (Smoot-Hawley) institutes average tariffs of approximately 60% and incites foreign tariff retaliation; this represents the high-water mark of U.S. tariffs since the 1830s.

1933 London Economic Conference fails to achieve multilateral agreement to reduce tariffs.

1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act grants Roosevelt administration authority to negotiate bilateral tariff agreements with trading partners.

1939-1945 World War II.

1944 Bretton Woods Agreement establishes post-war framework for institutions, including the World Bank and IMF; an ITO is proposed to facilitate the multilateral reduction of tariffs but not established, largely due to U.S. political opposition.

1947-1994 GATT negotiation rounds progressively reduce tariffs on a multilateral basis.

1995 U.S. and other member countries create WTO and legal framework for escalating and resolving trade disputes on a multilateral basis.

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E

Page 6: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

Brown Brothers Harriman | C O M M O D I T Y M A R K E T S U P D A T E Issue 3 2017 6

Beginning in 1947, the GATT convened and pro-gressively reduced tariffs among its members over the course of eight subsequent rounds of discus-sions, ending in 1994. Members initially included industrialized countries but later expanded to other emerging economies.21

Later, in 1995, the U.S. played a leading role in establishing the current legal framework of the WTO, under which member countries agree to the most-favored nation principle for trading with other member countries and have a system of recourse through which to channel disputes.

Statistically, the move toward a low-tariff policy post-1945 for the U.S. appears to have been a positive move:22

• Global trade increased by a factor of six in the 15 years follow-ing World War II.

• In 2000, the value of global trade was 125 times its 1950 level, equaling $7.5 trillion annually.

Nonetheless, the debate over tariffs and the relative merits of protectionism vs. free trade continues today. However, lessons from the past – particularly of Smoot-Hawley – loom large in this debate. A central lesson is the inherently unpredictable reac-tion of trading partners. What degree of retaliation would follow

a country’s unilateral imposition of higher tariffs? The WTO per-mits certain recourse against countries that unfairly raise tariffs, but are the costs of retaliation worth the benefits of domestic industry protection?

These considerations highlight the fact that policy decisions involve choice, choice sends a message, and trading partners’ reactions to this message may be costly and difficult to control.

Brown Brothers Harriman has been active in the international trade finance business for nearly 200 years and has observed many cycles. We continue to monitor the evolution of U.S. and international trade policy and will keep our clients apprised of any changes and their potential economic impact.

The WTO permits certain recourse against countries that unfairly raise tariffs, but are the costs of retaliation worth the benefits of domestic industry protection?”

21 Ibid.

22 Gordon. An Empire of Wealth, p. 378.

Page 7: The Cycles of U.S. Trade Policy - bbh.com · PDF filetoday’s economy, read Chief ... tionist, characterized by high levels of import tariffs compared ... The Great Depression. New

This publication is provided by Brown Brothers Harriman & Co. and its subsidiaries (“BBH”) to recipients, who are classified as Professional Clients or Eligible Counterparties if in the European Economic Area (“EEA”), solely for informational purposes. This does not constitute legal, tax or investment advice and is not intended as an offer to sell or a solicitation to buy securities or investment products. Any reference to tax matters is not intended to be used, and may not be used, for purposes of avoiding penalties under the U.S. Internal Revenue Code or for promotion, marketing or recommendation to third parties. This information has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable that are available upon request. This material does not comprise an offer of services. Any opinions expressed are subject to change without notice. Unauthorized use or distribution without the prior written permission of BBH is prohibited. This publication is approved for distribution in member states of the EEA by Brown Brothers Harriman Investor Services Limited, authorized and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA). BBH is a service mark of Brown Brothers Harriman & Co., registered in the United States and other countries.

© Brown Brothers Harriman & Co. 2017. All rights reserved. 2017.

PB-01801-2017-11-13 Expires 11/30/2019

NEW YORK BEIJING BOSTON CHARLOTTE CHICAGO DENVER DUBLIN GRAND CAYMAN HONG KONG

JERSEY CITY KRAKÓW LONDON LUXEMBOURG NASHVILLE PHILADELPHIA TOKYO WILMINGTON ZÜRICH

WWW.BBH.COM