28
Business environment in the EU Prepared by Dr. Endre Domonkos (PhD) 1st Semester, Academic Year 2011/2012

Taxation harmonization in the European Union

  • Upload
    yered

  • View
    23

  • Download
    2

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Taxation harmonization in the European Union. Business environment in the EU Prepared by Dr. Endre Domonkos (PhD) 1st Semester, Academic Year 20 11 /201 2. I. The need for a common tax policy I. The EEC Treaty was very cautious as regards tax harmonisation. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

Business environment in the EU Prepared by Dr. Endre Domonkos (PhD)1st Semester, Academic Year 2011/2012

Page 2: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

I. The need for a common tax policy I.

The EEC Treaty was very cautious as regards tax harmonisation.

What it wanted above all was the introduction and observance of the rule of fiscal neutrality in Community trade.

The Treaty did not call for any harmonisation or other Community action with regard to direct taxes.

Cumulative multi-stage taxes, which did not guarantee fiscal neutrality, were replaced by a new turnover tax, the value added tax.

The principle of fiscal neutrality was thus guaranteed.

Page 3: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

I. The need for a common tax policy II.

However, in the single market goods must be able to move completely freely, and to achieve this, tax has to be imposed on them either in the country of origin or in that of destination.

This led, at the end of the 1980s, to the alignment of VAT and excise duties.

Inside the economic and monetary union, tax harmonisation should progress at the same pace as economic integration.

In the short term there was no question of making a single fiscal territory of the European Community.

In the field of taxation policy most of measures were centred on achieveing fiscal neutrality and equal conditions of competition among the Member States.

Page 4: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

II. The fiscal neutrality in the common market I.

If the Member States of a common market had absolute freedom in the fiscal field, they could very quickly replace the customs barriers to trade by tax barriers.

It was therefore necessary that indirect taxes, in particular turnover tax, have no influence on intra-Community trade flows.

Fiscal neutrality between domestic production and imports from the partner countries was needed.

The rule of the tax of the country of origin:

The system of the tax of the country of destination:

Page 5: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

II. The fiscal neutrality in the common market II.

Even if the system of the tax of the country of destination were imposed uniformly, fiscal neutrality could still not be ensured if some countries in the common market applied a system of cumulative multi-stage turnover tax.

Article 97 of the EEC Treaty:

In addition, there existed important specific taxes on consumption, known as excise duties.

The differences between Member States in excise duty structures could give rise to significant disturbances in conditions of competition.

In the interest of proper functioning of the common market and the attainment of the Community agricultural, energy and transport objectives, the structures of these taxes needed to be harmonised.

Page 6: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

III. Taxation and conditions of competition Just behind the harmonisation of the structures of all indirect

taxes came, of course, the harmonisation of their rates.

In order to create a completely impartial conditions of competition in the common market a common system of taxes on consumption is needed.

In effect, the different rates of taxes could have a different influence on the consumption of various products in the common market and could distort the conditions of competition between the undertakings of the Member States.

In fact, the requirements for tax harmonisation increase together with progress in economic integration.

The long-term goal is to reach a taxation framework conducive to enterprise, job creation and environment protection in the Union.

Page 7: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

IV. Harmonisation of indirect taxation

Indirect taxes are those on turnover, production or consumption of goods and services – regarded as components of cost prices and selling prices – which are collected without regard to the realisation of profits, or indeed income, but which are deductible when determining profits.

Customs duties are a form of indirect taxation.

Article 99 of the EEC Treaty:

The problem of cumulative multi-stage taxes:

The Commission was convinced at the beginning of the 1960s, that the only radical solution to the problem arising from cumulative multi-stage taxes was to replace them by the value added tax.

Page 8: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

V. Value added tax I.

The Council adopted on 11 April 1967 two Directives on the harmonisation of the legislation of Member States concerning turnover taxes.

Those two Directives (Directives 69/443 and 77/388) and laid the groundwork for the common value added tax systems and a third one, adopted in 1969, introduced it in the tax systems of the Member States.

According to Article 2 of the first Directive of 1967, VAT is a general tax on consumption, i.e. a tax on all expenditure on goods and services.

The tax is levied at each stage of an economic activity on the value added at that stage.

The tax is proportional to the price of the products and services irrespective of the number of transactions.

Page 9: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

V. Value added tax II.

The tax is paid to the State by the vendor in each transaction.

Tax paid at previous stages, on deliveries made or services rendered to the taxable person, and the tax paid on imports, is deductible from the turnover tax of the taxable person.

Given this deductibility of taxes already paid, VAT is neutral from the point of view of domestic competition.

The sixth directive (Directive 69/2006) on the harmonisation of turnover taxes :

Directive 77/388:

These rules are known as „the uniform basis of assessment of VAT”.

Page 10: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

V. Value added tax III.

Regulation 1777/2005 lays down implementing measures for Directive 77/388.

Directive 2006/58:

Directive 2003/96 and Directive 2004/74:

Regulation 1777/2005:

Main aim of Regulation 1777/2005: the uniform application of the current VAT system + to improve the operation of the internal market guidelines.

Page 11: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

V. Value added tax IV. On 1 January 2007, the Sixth Directive was replaced by the VAT

Directive (Directive No 2006/112/EC).

Moreover, it does not set out the rates of VAT to be applied in Member States, only a minimum rate of 15% fixed until 31 December 2010.

Currently, Member States apply a standard rate of between 15% and 25%.

They may also apply 1 or 2 reduced rates of at least 5%.

There are a number of temporary derogations, e.g. zero rates in the United Kingdom and Ireland.

The VAT coverage also still differs from one Member State to another.

On 5 May 2009, the Council adopted Directive 2009/47/EC.

Page 12: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VI. Removal of fiscal frontiers I.

One of the main challenges to the completion of the single market was in the tax field.

Prior to 1992, goods and services moving within a Member State were taxed differently from those that were exported.

The tax was paid to the country in which the goods arrived at the final consumption stage.

The protection, which that system afforded against tax evasion, depended on controls at borders.

The notion of„fiscal frontiers”.

The Commission actually proposed that as from 1 January 1993 all sales of goods and services should be taxed at the rate of the country of origin.

Page 13: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VI. Removal of fiscal frontiers II.

The Directive (Directive 2004/66) on the approximation of VAT rates supplemented Directive 77/388 and completed the common VAT system.

It stipulates that, during the operational period of transitional VAT arrangements (where the VAT rate is that of the country of destination and not of the country of origin), the Member States shall apply a standard VAT rate of at least 15%.

However, the standard VAT rate varies between 15 and 25% in the twenty-five Member States.

All the higher VAT rates existing in several Member States have been abolished, leading to a significant fall in consumer prices in some sectors, such as automobiles.

Page 14: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VI. Removal of fiscal frontiers III.

The Member States however enjoy the option of applying alongside the normal rate, one (or two) reduced rates, equal to or higher than 5%, applicable only to certain goods and services of a social or cultural nature.

The preservation of the zero and extra-low cost rates (below 5%) is authorised on a transitional basis.

The common system of VAT dispensed with customs procedures.

Intra-Community trade in goods between taxable bodies is subject to taxation in the country of destination.

In the case of sales between companies subject to VAT, i.e. the vast majority, the vendor exempts the deliveries made to clients in other Member States.

Page 15: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VI. Removal of fiscal frontiers IV. Individuals travelling from one Member State to another pay

VAT there where they purchase the goods and are no longer subject to any VAT-related taxation or any border formality when they cross from one Member State to another.

In return, the system of travellers’ allowances (tax free sales in ports, airports, etc.) was abolished in intra-Community travelling.

The abolition of frontier controls and the resultant fraud risk require cooperation between government authorities in the area of indirect taxation to combat tax evasion.

The core of the system is an on-line network linking the relevant administrations of the Member States („SCENT – taxation”).

The Fiscalis programme:

Page 16: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VII. Excise duties I. In a fiscally integrated Community a number of major

special taxes on consumption (excise duties), i.e. taxes on the consumption of certain products are maintained.

They are separate taxes.

Excise duties can easily be adapted to the various economic, social and structural requirements.

Two conditions had to be met so as not to disturb the common market:

1. Their structures had to be harmonised. 2. Their rates had to be harmonised.

(Directive 92/12 and Directive 2004/106):

Page 17: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VII. Excise duties II.

The tax is payable when the product is put up for consumption and must be acquitted in the country of actual consumption.

Excise duties are paid by the consignee in the country of destination and the appropriate provisions are taken to this effect.

Individuals can purchase the products of their choice in other Member States, inclusive of tax, for their personal use.

Denmark, Finland and Sweden are, however, authorised by the Council to continue restricting quantities of certain alcoholic drinks and tobacco products which individuals purchase in other Member States and import for their own consumption.

Page 18: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VII. Excise duties III. Seven specific directives to harmonise the structures and

minimum excise duty rates on manufactured tobaccos, mineral oils, spirits and alcohol beverages.

The Directive on taxes which affect the consumption of manufactured tobacco was consolidated in 1995.

Directive 92/79, on the approximation of excise duty rates on cigarettes.

Directive 92/80, on the approximation of taxes on manufactured tobaccos other than cigarettes.

Directive 92/83 covers the harmonisation of excise-duty structures on spirits and alcoholic beverages.

Directive 92/84 sets the minimum excise duties on spirits and alcoholic beverages.

Page 19: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

VIII. Other indirect taxation Various other indirect taxes whose harmonisation is

important for European integration also exist in addition to value added tax and special taxes on consumption.

Examples of these taxes on insurance policies and taxes on motor vehicles intended for the carriage of passengers, which vary greatly between Member States.

The Commission proposes a number of policy measures and initiatives in the area of passenger car taxation.

Also important from the point of view of competition are capital duty and stamp duty levied on shares in registered capital (share and securities).

Directive 1969/335:

Page 20: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

IX. Harmonisation of direct taxation Taxes on the revenue of undertakings (firms, companies,

businesses) and private individuals, which are not incorporated in cost prices or selling prices and the rate of which is often progressive, may be regarded as direct taxes.

The two important categories of direct taxes are income tax and capital gains tax.

Article 92 of the EC Treaty:

The EC Treaty does not deal with direct taxes and does not call for them to be harmonised.

It gradually became clear, however, that the free movement of capital and the rational distribution of production factors in the Community required a minimum degree of harmonisation of direct taxes.

Page 21: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

X. Company taxation I.

In the field of company taxation the European Commission had tabled proposals to this end in 1969, after the realisation of the customs union.

But the Council needed 21 years of debate, before it could approve these proposals, vital for transnational cooperation and company mergers in the single market.

The first Directive (Directive 90/434) on business taxation.

The second Council Directive of July 1990 (Directive 90/435) relates to the common fiscal system applicable to parent companies and subsidiaries situated in different Member States.

Page 22: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

X. Company taxation II.

A code of conduct on business taxation.

A group within the framework of the Council has the task to assess the tax measures that may fall within the scope of the code and to oversee the provision by the Member States of information on those measures.

A common system of taxation is applicable to interest and royalty payments made between associated companies in different Member States.

For budgetary reasons, Greece, Spain and Portugal may apply transitional measures in introducing the new system.

The Commission has proposed a strategy for providing companies with a consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB) for their EU-wide activities.

Page 23: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

XI. Effort to combat tax avoidance I.

Problem in the area of direct taxation: international tax avoidance.

Therefore, a 1977 Directive (Directive 77/799) instituted a mutual assistance by the competent authorities of the Member States in the field of direct taxation (income tax, company tax and capital gains tax) and certain excise duties and taxation of insurance premiums.

A regulation (Regulation 2073/2004) lays down a set of conditions and procedures to assist administrative authorities in preventing fraud and distortions of competition in movements of excisable products.

The liberalisation of capital movements as from 1 July 1990 has increased the risk of tax evasion.

Page 24: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

XI. Effort to combat tax avoidance II.

In order to lessen the risk of tax distortion, evasion and avoidance, it was necessary to intensify the exchange of information between tax authorities.

These objectives are aimed at by the Directive (Directive 2003/48) ensuring a minimum of effective taxation of savings income in the form of interest payments within the Community.

In order to preserve the competitiveness of European financial markets, the European institutions entered into discussions with key third countries, such as the USA, Switzerland, Liechtenstein, Monaco, Andorra and San Marino, to promote the adoption of equivalent measures in those countries, notably effective exchange of information.

Agreements have been reached with the European countries, notably Switzerland, Liechtenstein, Andorra and San Marino.

Page 25: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

XII. Tax legislation in the Treaty of Lisbon

The Treaty on the Functioning of the EU (TFEU), under Article 113, specifically provides for the Council, acting unanimously in accordance with a special legislative procedure and after consulting the European Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee, to adopt provisions for the harmonisation of Member States' rules in the area of indirect taxation(principally Value Added Tax and Excise Duties).

Member States have also adopted EU-wide legislation in the field of mutual assistance and co-operation in tax matters, under Articles 113, 114 or 115 of the TFEU.

Member States’ tax systems and tax treaties must in any event respect the Fundamental Treaty principles on the free movement of workers, services and capital and the freedom of establishment (Articles 45, 49, 56 and 63 TFEU) and the principle of non-discrimination.

Page 26: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

XIII. Conclusion I.

It was, however urgent for the common market to harmonise turnover tax structures and consequently to achieve fiscal neutrality.

That was to a large extent achieved with the adoption of the VAT system by all original Member States at the beginning of the 1970s and by the new Member States after their accession.

Such a close harmonisation of turnover taxes as that resulting from the adoption by all Member States of the value added tax with a uniform basis of assessment was not called for by the Treaty of Rome.

The completion of the single market required the abolition of fiscal frontiers.

The harmonisation of indirect taxation is very important, not just for the smooth operation of the internal market but also for the convergence of economic conditions in the Member States.

Page 27: Taxation harmonization in the European Union

XIII. Conclusion II.

Some very important areas of direct taxation, such as personal income tax, are not directly targeted by the harmonisation process.

As EMU advances, however, a procedure for the coordination of national fiscal policies will have to be introduced to enable these policies to converge progressively in parallel with the convergence of economic policies.

Such coordination should not necessarily aim at uniform tax rates.

The definitive VAT system should be as simple as possible for enterprises, particularly SMEs.

In the field of direct taxation, the harmonisation process will be longer because of the differences in corporate taxations between the Member States.

Page 28: Taxation harmonization in the European Union