91
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1105398 Economic Consequences of Financial Reporting and Disclosure Regulation: A Review and Suggestions for Future Research * Christian Leuz Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI) [email protected] and Peter Wysocki Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology [email protected] Comments Welcomed March 2008 (First version: May 2006) Abstract This paper surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the economic consequences of financial reporting and disclosure regulation. We integrate theoretical and empirical studies from accounting, economics, finance and law in order to contribute to the cross-fertilization of these fields. We provide an organizing framework that identifies firm-specific (micro-level) and market-wide (macro-level) costs and benefits of firms‟ reporting and disclosure activities and then use this framework to discuss potential costs and benefits of regulating these activities and to organize the key insights from the literature. Our survey highlights important unanswered questions and concludes with numerous suggestions for future research. Keywords: Accounting, Asymmetric information, Capital markets, Institutional economics, International, Mandatory disclosure, Political economy, Regulation, Standards JEL Classifications: D78; D82; G14; G18; G30; G38; K22; K42; M41; M42 * We wish to thank Andrew Karolyi, Ken Peasnell and seminar participants at New York University, Manchester Business School, 2007 AAA International Accounting Section Conference, 2007 INTACCT Workshop, and 2007 Accounting & Economics Conference in Fribourg for helpful comments and suggestions.

SSRN-id1105398

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: SSRN-id1105398

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1105398

Economic Consequences of Financial Reporting and Disclosure Regulation:

A Review and Suggestions for Future Research*

Christian Leuz

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago,

European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI)

[email protected]

and

Peter Wysocki

Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology

[email protected]

Comments Welcomed

March 2008

(First version: May 2006)

Abstract

This paper surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the economic consequences of

financial reporting and disclosure regulation. We integrate theoretical and empirical studies from

accounting, economics, finance and law in order to contribute to the cross-fertilization of these

fields. We provide an organizing framework that identifies firm-specific (micro-level) and

market-wide (macro-level) costs and benefits of firms‟ reporting and disclosure activities and

then use this framework to discuss potential costs and benefits of regulating these activities and

to organize the key insights from the literature. Our survey highlights important unanswered

questions and concludes with numerous suggestions for future research.

Keywords: Accounting, Asymmetric information, Capital markets, Institutional economics,

International, Mandatory disclosure, Political economy, Regulation, Standards

JEL Classifications: D78; D82; G14; G18; G30; G38; K22; K42; M41; M42

* We wish to thank Andrew Karolyi, Ken Peasnell and seminar participants at New York University, Manchester

Business School, 2007 AAA International Accounting Section Conference, 2007 INTACCT Workshop, and 2007

Accounting & Economics Conference in Fribourg for helpful comments and suggestions.

Page 2: SSRN-id1105398

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1105398

1

1. Introduction

Three recent trends have spurred the debate about financial reporting and disclosure

regulations around the world. First, international financial crises and corporate scandals often

bring about securities regulation reforms and greater reporting and disclosure requirements. The

Asian Financial Crisis of 1997, the Enron debacle in the U.S., and the recent credit market crisis

are but a few important examples. In the aftermath of these events, regulators and policy makers

have called for improved corporate transparency, increased scrutiny and often enacted significant

changes to accounting and disclosure requirements and regulations. Second, stock exchanges

and accounting standards bodies from numerous countries around the world have adopted

International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) to achieve the stated goal of “harmonization”

and “convergence” of accounting rules. Third, both the debate about the competitiveness of U.S.

capital markets and the increasing internationalization of capital markets highlight securities

regulation as a global issue.1

Despite the importance of corporate transparency as a recurring policy issue, there is (i)

limited research on the costs and benefits of financial reporting and disclosure regulation, (ii)

few attempts to systematically organize the key economic principles of and empirical findings on

this type of regulation, and (iii) little guidance on important unanswered questions about the

economic consequences of regulating financial reporting and corporate disclosure.

This paper reviews the theoretical and empirical literature on the economic consequences

of financial reporting and disclosure regulation, with a particular emphasis on recent research

advances in the literature. We integrate theoretical and empirical studies from accounting,

economics, finance and law in order to contribute to the cross-fertilization of these fields.

1 See, e.g., the U.S. Chamber of Commerce sponsored report by the Commission on the Regulation of U.S. Capital

Markets in the 21st Century (2007).

Page 3: SSRN-id1105398

2

Moreover, we provide an organizing framework that identifies firm-specific (micro-level) and

market-wide (macro-level) costs and benefits of firms‟ reporting and disclosure activities. We

then use this framework to discuss the potential costs and benefits of regulating these activities in

global capital markets and to organize the key insights from the literature. We highlight

important unanswered questions to provide directions for future research.2 As such, this survey

and framework should prove useful to researchers, as well as standards setters, policy makers,

and regulators as they debate the economic consequences of past and future regulatory choices.

Generally speaking, our survey finds a paucity of evidence on market-wide and aggregate

economic and social consequences of reporting and disclosure regulation, rather than the

consequences of individual firms‟ accounting and disclosure choices. Until recently, most of the

literature focuses on managers‟ voluntary disclosure and financial reporting choices.3 These

studies provide important insights into the nature of the private costs and benefits of voluntary

reporting and disclosure choices and, in this sense, provide a micro foundation. However, these

studies provide few insights into the overall desirability, economic efficiency or aggregate

outcomes of reporting and disclosure regulation. On the other hand, there has been a recent

flurry of studies examining international differences in the effects of different regulatory regimes

and on the economic consequences of regulatory changes, such as Regulation Fair Disclosure

and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. We synthesize the insights of these studies in our survey. However,

there are still many unanswered questions, especially, (i) why disclosure regulation is so

pervasive; (ii) the dynamics and (iii) the process of regulation; (iv) the real and macro-economic

consequences of disclosure regulation, (v) its complementarities with other regulations, (vi) its

2 Survey papers that review the disclosure literature or the information/asset pricing literatures include Healy and

Palepu (2001), Core (2001), Amihud, Mendelson and Pedersen (2005), and Botosan (2006). Our review

complements these surveys by highlighting recent research on the regulation of firms‟ financial reporting and

disclosure activities. In addition, our review includes numerous new research studies that post-date prior surveys. 3 These recent advances are an impetus for our survey and are reviewed in detail.

Page 4: SSRN-id1105398

3

optimal form given imperfect enforcement; and (vii) the issue of regulatory competition. We

discuss these open questions and conclude our survey with suggestions for future research in

these areas.

Despite the focus on regulation, this paper should not be understood as advocating the

necessity of regulation or reforms to existing regulations. In fact, we highlight the importance of

market forces in influencing firms‟ disclosure and reporting choices, both in isolation as well as

the interactions with regulatory acts. For instance, we highlight that corporate transparency

likely is a joint outcome of market forces and the incentives provided by various rules and

regulations (including the quality of their enforcement). We also point to significant

complementarities between the elements of a country‟s institutional infrastructure. Given these

complementarities, we highlight that unilateral changes in disclosure and accounting rules are

unlikely to yield the desired outcomes. Similarly, we stress that global diversity in institutional

and economic factors may limit the effectiveness of a “one-size-fits-all” set of global accounting

standards and disclosure regulations. Finally, we emphasize that the issue of firms‟ avoidance

strategies, which have long been known to seriously impair the effectiveness of regulation, is

further compounded by the growing integration of capital markets around the world, which

provides firms with alternatives outside their home countries and leads to regulatory competition.

Our survey touches issues that are discussed in the economics literature on regulation in

general, such as political lobbying and regulatory capture. However, this literature often focuses

on the regulation of product-market monopolists and the corresponding impact on consumers

(see, e.g., Kahn, 1988; Laffont and Tirole, 1993). Disclosure settings have their own unique

economic and regulatory issues where many firms interact with heterogeneous investors in

capital markets. To highlight these unique disclosure issues, our framework identifies and

Page 5: SSRN-id1105398

4

discusses: (i) firm-specific (micro-economic) costs and benefits arising from firms‟ voluntary

disclosure activities, (ii) potential (macro-economic) market-wide costs and benefits of firms‟

voluntary disclosure activities, and (iii) aggregate costs and benefits of regulating and enforcing

firms‟ financial reporting and disclosure activities in global capital markets.

The survey is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the theoretical literature on the

firm-specific costs and benefits of disclosure, the market-wide costs and benefits of financial

reporting and disclosure, and costs and benefits of regulating these activities. In section 3, we

review empirical studies on firms‟ disclosure choices. Section 4 presents and discusses empirical

studies on changes in disclosure regulation and across country comparisons of disclosure regimes.

Section 5 discusses new institutional research in accounting as well as recent studies on the

adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) as these advances also help our

understanding of the economic outcomes of financial reporting and disclosure regulation.

Section 6 concludes the paper with an extensive discussion of suggestions for future research.

2. Theory of Corporate Disclosure and Reporting Regulation

In this section, we outline the theory of firms‟ disclosure choices and the theory of

disclosure regulation. We use a framework that first identifies possible firm-specific (micro-

economic) and market-wide (macro-economic) costs and benefits of firms‟ disclosure activities

in the absence of regulation. We then overlay the potential effects of disclosure and reporting

regulation. Finally, we give some consideration to the question of how to mandate disclosures,

i.e., the mechanism and at which level, and how to enforce the rules.

Page 6: SSRN-id1105398

5

Both firm-specific and market-wide effects are relevant for evaluating the economic

consequences of reporting and disclosure regulation.4 The former are important because the

confluence of firm-specific costs and benefits of voluntary disclosures determines whether they

are beneficial to the firm, i.e., whether they increase firm value. However, the mere existence of

net benefits to voluntary disclosure is not sufficient to justify mandatory disclosure because, in

this case, a firm already has incentives to voluntarily provide information (e.g., Ross, 1979). That

is, precisely in the situation where the firm-specific benefits exceed the costs, it is not clear that

we need any regulation. Unfortunately, debates about disclosure and financial reporting

regulation often incorrectly point to firm-specific (net) benefits of voluntary disclosure choices

rather than focus on the aggregate effects of regulation. However, firm-specific effects of

disclosure can still be relevant in regulatory debates if (i) they inform us about the nature and

form of the costs and benefits, (ii) they tell us how mandated disclosure can differentially affect

firms (including potential wealth transfers among firms), and (iii) they help us predict which

firms are likely to engage in avoidance strategies or may lobby for or against a proposed

regulation given its differential effects on firms.

Market-wide effects of firms‟ disclosures (in the absence of regulation) are relevant

because they capture costs and benefits that firms may ignore or not fully internalize when

making their individual disclosure decisions. Knowledge of these market-wide effects and

externalities provides a basis for identifying the costs and benefits of regulating and enforcing

corporate financial reports and disclosures.

4 We use the term “market-wide effects” to denote effects that go beyond a single firm. They could affect a group of

firms, an entire industry, and/or all firms in the economy.

Page 7: SSRN-id1105398

6

2.1. Firm-Specific Benefits of Corporate Disclosures

Current theories typically focus on direct capital market outcomes of firms‟ disclosure

activities. These market outcomes include liquidity, cost of capital and firm valuation.5 Arguably,

the firm-specific benefit of disclosure best supported by theory is the effect on market liquidity

(see also, Verrecchia, 2001). At its core is the insight that information asymmetries among

investors introduce adverse selection into share markets. Uninformed or less informed investors

have to worry about trading with privately or better informed investors.6 As a result, uninformed

investors lower (increase) the price at which they are willing to buy (sell) to protect against the

losses from trading with an informed counterparties. The price adjustment reflects the

probability of trading with informed traders and the potential information advantage of these

investors. This form of price protection when buying or selling shares introduces a bid-ask

spread into secondary share markets.7 Similarly, information asymmetry and adverse selection

reduce the number of shares that uninformed investors are willing to trade. Both effects reduce

the liquidity of share markets, i.e., the ability of investors to quickly buy or sell shares at low cost

and with little price impact.

Corporate disclosure can mitigate the adverse selection problem and increase market

liquidity by leveling the playing field among investors (Verrecchia, 2001). Its effect is two-fold.

First, more information in the public domain makes it harder and more costly for traders to

become privately informed. As a result, fewer investors are likely to be privately informed,

5 Other potential observable outcomes of firms‟ disclosure activities include changes in analyst following and

institutional holdings. However, these outcomes are often viewed as indirect measures of access to low cost sources

of capital. 6 In essence, an uninformed investor fears that an informed investor is willing to sell (buy) at the market price only

because the price is currently too high (too low) relative to the information possessed by the informed trader (e.g.,

Glosten and Milgrom, 1985). 7 If the counter party is informed with probability one, the market breaks down analogous to the “market for

lemons” in Akerlof (1970).

Page 8: SSRN-id1105398

7

which reduces the probability of trading with a better informed counter party. Second, more

disclosure reduces the uncertainty about firm value, which in turn reduces the potential

information advantage that an informed trader might have. Both effects reduce the extent to

which uninformed investors need to price protect and hence increase market liquidity.

An important question is whether and how these effects map into firm value or the cost of

capital. Illiquidity and bid-ask spreads essentially impose (out-of-pocket) trading costs on

investors, for which investors need to be compensated in equilibrium. Thus, the required rate of

return of a security increases by its per-period transaction costs (e.g., Constantinides, 1986;

Amihud and Mendelson, 1986). In addition, adverse selection can distort investors‟ trading

decisions and result in inefficient and hence costly asset allocations for which investors need to

be compensated, leading to a higher required rate of return or cost of capital (Garleanu and

Pedersen, 2004).

Moreover, adverse selection problems and trading costs in secondary markets fold back

to the point at which the firm issues shares. Investors anticipate that they face price protection

when they sell shares in the future and hence reduce the price at which they are willing to buy

shares in the initial securities offering (e.g., Baiman and Verrecchia, 1996; Verrecchia, 2001).

As a result, a firm must issue more shares to raise a fixed amount of capital. Thus, information

asymmetry also translates into a higher cost of raising capital.

In addition, information asymmetry and adverse selection in primary share markets can

reduce the offering price and lead to underpricing. Myers and Majluf (1984) show that a firm

may be willing to pass up profitable investment opportunities if the firm has to issue new

securities to finance the investment and information is asymmetrically distributed managers and

outside investors. Rock (1986) presents a model where uninformed investors face a winner‟s

Page 9: SSRN-id1105398

8

curse and a firm has to underprice its securities to ensure the participation of uninformed

investors in the offering.8

Next, there are theories that provide a direct link between disclosure and the cost of

capital (or firm value), without reference to market liquidity (and adverse selection costs). For

example, Merton (1987) develops a model where (some) investors have incomplete information

and are not aware of all firms in the economy. As a result, risk sharing is incomplete and

inefficient. Disclosures by these lesser known firms can make investors aware of their existence

and enlarge the investor base, which in turn improves risk sharing and lowers the cost of capital.

This effect is likely to be less relevant to large firms with a substantial analyst and investor

following. Moreover, the investor base effect is susceptible to arbitrage if some investors know

which of the stocks are not known by all investors (Merton, 1987; Easley and O‟Hara, 2004).

A direct link between disclosure and the cost of capital can also arise from estimation risk

(e.g., Brown, 1979; Barry and Brown, 1984 and 1985; Coles, 1988). Estimation risk arises

because parameters such as a firm‟s beta factor must be estimated (e.g., based on historical stock

returns). For example, Barry and Brown (1985) and Coles et al. (1995) consider an information

environment where some firms have longer time-series of returns than others. They find that, in

this environment of asymmetric parameter uncertainty, securities with long time-series of returns

have lower betas and expected returns than they would without estimation risk. However, they

are unable to unambiguously sign the effect for securities with short time-series of returns.

Aside from a relatively narrow representation of information, these studies do not provide

comparisons across high- and low-information firms in a world with asymmetric parameter

uncertainty and hence do not address the question of how firm-specific disclosures can influence

8 For a survey of IPO literature, see Ljungqvist (2004).

Page 10: SSRN-id1105398

9

betas or expected returns. Moreover, it is not clear that parameter uncertainty for individual

firms survives the forces of diversification (e.g., Clarkson et al., 1996).

Recently, Jorgensen and Kirschenheiter (2003), Hughes, Liu, and Liu (2007), and

Lambert, Leuz and Verrecchia (2007a) re-examine the issue of estimation risk and firms‟ cost of

capital. Lambert et al. (2007b) model estimation risk using an information-economics approach

where firms‟ disclosures are noisy signals of their future cash flows. They show that the

assessed covariances of a firm‟s cash flow with the cash flows of other firms decrease as the

quality (or precision) of firm-specific disclosures increases, and that this effect unambiguously

moves a firm‟s cost of capital closer to the risk-free rate. This information effect is not

diversifiable because it is present for all covariance terms. Only the firm-specific variance term

is likely to be diversified in “large economies” where investors can form portfolios of many

stocks. The information effects in Lambert et al. (2007a) are consistent with the CAPM and

hence should affect firms‟ betas and the market risk premium.9

In addition to the direct effects on the assessed covariances, corporate disclosures have

the potential to change firm value by affecting managers‟ decisions and hence altering the

distribution of future cash flows. Many studies in agency theory suggest that more transparency

and better corporate governance increases firm value by improving managers‟ decisions or by

reducing the amount that managers appropriate for themselves (e.g., Shleifer and Wolfenzon,

2002).10

There can also be an indirect effect on the cost of capital (e.g., Lombardo and Pagano,

2002; Lambert et al., 2007a). For example, Lambert et al. (2007a) demonstrate that, if better

9 Hughes, Liu and Liu (2007) provide a similar model with a more restrictive information structure than Lambert et

al. (2007a). As a result, disclosures merely affect the market risk premium but not firms‟ beta factors. See also Yee

(2006). Jorgensen and Kirschenheiter (2003) analyze the question of firms‟ ex post incentives to disclose

information about firm-specific variances. 10

See also the surveys by Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and Lambert (2001). There are also a number of legal studies

that emphasize the role of disclosure in mitigating agency problems (see, for example, Mahoney, 1995 and Ferrell,

2004). As these studies typically discuss the role of regulation, they are reviewed in Section 2.6.

Page 11: SSRN-id1105398

10

disclosure reduces the amount of managerial appropriation11

, this effect generally reduces a

firm‟s cost of capital. Moreover, better corporate disclosures can improve managers‟ production

or investment decisions if investors and firms coordinate with respect to capital allocation via

public disclosures and share prices.12

But the directional impact of these effects on the cost of

capital is ambiguous (Lambert et al., 2007a). The reason is that the projects that are induced by

better disclosures and more outside monitoring could have larger covariances with the cash flows

of other firms in the economy and hence be riskier. This example illustrates that disclosure may

have first-order effects on agency problems and investment efficiency. However, this line of

research is still in its infancy and certainly warrants further investigation.

2.2. Firm-Specific Costs of Corporate Disclosures

The direct costs of corporate disclosures, including the preparation, certification and

dissemination of accounting reports, are conceptually straightforward. However, as illustrated

by the recent debate about the economic consequences of SOX (e.g., Wall Street Journal,

2/10/2004; Ribstein, 2005), these direct costs can be substantial, especially considering the

opportunity costs of those involved in the disclosure process. Moreover, fixed disclosure costs

lead to economies of scale and can make certain disclosures particularly burdensome for smaller

firms.

Disclosures can also have indirect costs because information provided to capital market

participants can also be used by other parties (e.g., competitors, labor unions, regulators, tax

authorities, etc.). For example, detailed information about line-of-business profitability can

11

Managerial appropriation of corporate resources can take many forms, such as outright stealing of cash, the use of

excess cash for „pet projects‟ from which the manager derives some private utility, lavish business trips, or simply

excessive compensation. 12

At the same time, disclosures can also have adverse real effects and lead to production distortions. Kanoida et al.

(2000) and Sapra (2002) illustrate this in the context of hedge disclosures.

Page 12: SSRN-id1105398

11

reveal proprietary information to competitors (e.g., Feltham et al., 1992; Hayes and Lundholm,

1996). The fact that other parties may use public information to the disclosing firm‟s

disadvantage can dampen its disclosure incentives (Verrecchia, 1983; Gal-Or, 1985). However,

a competitive threat may not always induce firms to withhold information. For example,

incumbent firms may disclose information to deter entry by competitors. Firms might also share

information about market demand to prevent overproduction in the industry (Kirby, 1988).

Furthermore, competitors can infer information from the fact that a firm does not make certain

disclosures. Thus, the relation between disclosures and proprietary costs is complex and depends

on the type of competition threat (e.g., Vives, 1984; Gal-Or, 1986; Verrecchia, 1990;

Wagenhofer, 1990; Feltham et al., 1992).

A related argument is that more transparency could be costly to existing financing

relationships, especially with banks (e.g. Rajan and Zingales, 1998; Leuz and Oberholzer-Gee,

2006). Relationship financing may require some private information flows between a firm and

its bank in order to protect relationship-specific investments that make financing arrangements

viable where a firm pays above market in good times but in return obtains credit in bad times. If

disclosures put outside financiers on a level-playing field, the relationship is unlikely to survive

the forces of competition in good times. Thus, firms that have or seek such financing

relationships are likely to be reluctant to provide full disclosure.

In summary, there are numerous direct and indirect reporting and disclosure costs, which

in turn are likely to make the optimal amount of disclosure specific to each firm.

2.3. Market-Wide Effects and Externalities of Corporate Disclosure

An individual firm‟s disclosure can have effects beyond the firm itself. We refer to those

effects as market-wide effects. The competitive effects of corporate disclosure discussed in

Page 13: SSRN-id1105398

12

Section 2.2 are one example. But the effects of corporate disclosure extend beyond competing

firms. An individual firm‟s disclosures may have externalities that benefit non-competing firms

in other industries by revealing relevant information about new consumer trends, technological

shocks, best operating practices, governance arrangements, etc. This information can be useful

to other firms for decision making but it can also help reduce agency problems in other firms.

Firms‟ disclosures of operating performance and governance arrangements provide useful

benchmarks that help outside investors to evaluate other firms‟ managerial efficiency or potential

agency conflicts and in doing so lower the cost of monitoring. While the incremental

contribution of each firm‟s disclosure is likely to be small, these information transfers could

carry substantial benefits for the market or the economy as a whole. The real effects of

information transfers and potential governance spillover effects are still largely unexplored.

Most of the work has focused on information transfers in capital markets, starting with Foster

(1981).

Dye (1990) and Admati and Pfleiderer (2000) analyze positive externalities in the form

of information transfers and liquidity spillovers in capital markets. As firm values and cash

flows are likely to be correlated, the disclosure of one firm is useful to investors in valuing other

firms and increases the investors‟ demand for shares in other firms. Lambert et al. (2007a) show

that this argument applies to estimation risk. Each firm‟s disclosure has a (small) impact on

investors‟ assessed covariances of other firms, which in turn lowers the estimation risk and cost

of capital of other firms. Jorgensen and Kirschenheiter (2007) show similar externalities in the

context of disclosures about firms‟ sensitivity to a market-wide risk factor. Again, while these

effects are likely to be small individually, they could be large across all firms in the market or

economy. There is also the argument that firm-specific disclosures have market-wide benefits

Page 14: SSRN-id1105398

13

because they eliminate duplicative efforts of information intermediaries and investors and that

firms are likely the lowest-cost producer for corporate information (e.g., Coffee, 1984;

Easterbrook and Fischel, 1984; Diamond, 1985).13

At the same time, there can be negative effects or costly externalities to firms‟ reporting

and misreporting activities. For example, Fishman and Hagerty (1989) show that an increase in

disclosure by one firm can attract investors away from other firms (e.g., if processing

information is costly). In markets that are not perfectly competitive, this effect lowers the price

efficiency of other firms and creates a negative externality. This argument can be extended to

apply across markets or countries. If markets that are not perfectly competitive, then high

transparency in one capital market can siphon off investors and lower the price efficiency in

other capital markets.

In addition, a firm‟s disclosures can have effects on the efficiency of risk sharing in a

market. Adverse selection can distort market-wide risk sharing because investors with relatively

high risk tolerance will hold smaller positions (i.e., bear less risk) than they would otherwise

because they anticipate the costs of liquidating larger positions in a market with information

asymmetry among traders. This effect leaves more risk to be borne by less risk tolerant investors,

leading to a higher market risk premium. Diamond and Verrecchia (1991) illustrate this point in

a model with risk-neutral and risk-averse traders, but it also applies to economies with

differentially risk averse investors (see also Lambert, Leuz and Verrecchia, 2007b).

Finally, an individual firm‟s misreporting activities may have negative spillovers to

related firms, governments, and investors. For example, Sidak (2003) argues that fraudulent

13

This idea also relates to Hirshleifer (1971) who argues that private information acquisition for speculative gains in

securities markets merely creates wealth transfers and hence the costs of such activities are socially wasteful.

Page 15: SSRN-id1105398

14

disclosures and financial reports can send false signals to industry players about new investment

opportunities, lead governments to pursue incorrect regulatory policies, and cause capital

rationing in the industry.

In summary, there are numerous reasons why an individual firm‟s disclosures extend

beyond the firm itself. Moreover, the market-wide effects could be large in the aggregate while

imposing relatively small costs on the disclosing firm. But as individual firms generally cannot

internalize the market-wide benefits of their disclosure activities, even relatively small disclosure

costs could deter socially optimal disclosure activities. As with other externalities, the problem

is that firms trade off only the private (or firm-specific) costs and benefits only and hence do not

provide the socially optimal level of disclosure. As discuss next, there are market and regulatory

solutions to this problem. Moreover, it is important to recognize that the social value of

disclosure can be greater or less than the private value of disclosure, and as a consequence, firms

may provide too much or too little information.

2.4. The Economics of Mandated or Regulated Disclosure

As many before us have noted, the existence of (net) benefits to voluntary disclosure is

not sufficient to justify mandatory disclosure because firms have incentives to voluntarily

provide information if the benefits exceed the costs (e.g., Ross, 1979). The idea of market-based

disclosure incentives is best illustrated with the unraveling argument (Grossman and Hart, 1980;

Grossman, 1981; Milgrom, 1981). Without corporate disclosures, investors are unable to

distinguish between good and bad firms and therefore offer a price that reflects the average value

of all firms. So, firms with an above-average value have an incentive to disclose private

information about their true value. Once these firms disclose, investors rationally infer that the

average value of all non-disclosing firms is lower and adjust the price to reflect this expectation.

Page 16: SSRN-id1105398

15

This reaction in turn triggers the remaining non-disclosing firms with values above the newly set

market price to disclose information about their private value, and so on. In the end, all firms

(except the worst) disclose their private information about value voluntarily.

However, the preceding argument relies on a number of simplifying assumptions. For

example, disclosure of private information and its verification must be low cost and investors

must know that firms possess private information. Without these assumptions, the described full

disclosure equilibrium may not prevail (e.g., Ross, 1979; Verrecchia, 1983; Dye, 1985; Jung and

Kwon, 1988). However, even if these assumptions are violated, the general spirit of the

unraveling argument still applies: Firms are expected to voluntarily provide information if there

are net benefits to disclosure because they ultimately bear the costs of withholding information.

Thus, an economic justification of mandatory disclosure has to show that a market

solution is unlikely to produce a socially desirable level of disclosure. Moreover, competition

and private contracting can address market failures (Coase, 1960). Thus, a market failure alone

is not sufficient to justify regulation. To avoid the Nirvana fallacy, one has to show that a

regulatory solution would in fact achieve better outcomes or be cheaper than a market solution

(e.g., Stigler, 1971). Regulatory processes are far from perfect and face many problems (e.g.,

Peltzman et al., 1989). Moreover, firms are likely to be better informed about their cost-benefit

tradeoff with respect to disclosure than regulators.

The literature commonly appeals to the following arguments to justify the regulation of

firms‟ financial reporting and disclosure activities: the existence of externalities, market-wide

cost savings from regulation, strict sanctions that are difficult to produce privately and dead-

Page 17: SSRN-id1105398

16

weight costs from fraud and agency conflicts that could be mitigated by disclosure.14

We review

each of these arguments in favor of disclosure regulation but note that they are related and often

combined.15

The first argument is that corporate disclosures create several externalities, which can

lead to private over- or underproduction of information. In theory, disclosure regulation can

mitigate this problem by mandating the socially optimal level of disclosure. However, in

practice, it is likely to be difficult for regulators to determine the socially optimal level of

disclosure and whether markets produce too little or too much information, especially

considering that there exist many different positive and negative externalities. Moreover, as

mentioned before, market solutions can mitigate the problems created by externalities. For

instance, consider the argument that the social value of disclosure exceeds the private value

because it mitigates duplicative private information acquisition by investors. As Mahoney

(1995) points out, this argument is not very convincing as a justification for mandating quarterly

and annual reports because investors continue to have incentives to acquire private information

in the interim. It might still serve as a rationale for mandatory ad-hoc disclosure of material

information (e.g., 8-K reports in the U.S.). But even for such timely disclosures, market forces

likely limit the extent to which private and social values of information can diverge and hence

the degree to which information is overproduced. For instance, prices tend to reveal some of the

private information that traders have, which in turn curbs incentives to acquire information

privately (Grossman, 1977; Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980). Furthermore, widespread duplication

14

These arguments are not specific to the disclosure literature and have been used in many other regulatory contexts.

Hermalin and Katz (1993) show in a general bargaining context that there are only three reasons for outside

interference with private contracting: (i) the parties are asymmetrically informed ex ante; (ii) there is an externality

on a third party; and (iii) the state has access to more remedies than private parties. 15

Much of the debate on mandatory disclosure has taken place in the legal literature, rather than in accounting,

finance or economics. See, e.g., Seligman (1983), Coffee (1984), Easterbrock and Fischel (1984), Mahoney (1995).

Page 18: SSRN-id1105398

17

and overproduction of information create incentives for specialization where some investors

produce reports and other pay for them (e.g., Gonedes, Dopuch and Penman, 1976; Mahoney,

1995). Thus, it is likely an empirical question whether mandatory disclosures create externalities

that make them in fact socially desirable.

A second argument put forth to justify disclosure regulation is that a mandatory regime

serves as a low-cost commitment device (e.g., Mahoney, 1995; Rock, 2002).16

The basic idea

can be illustrated in an IPO setting. Given the forces underlying the unraveling argument, firms

have strong incentives at the time of the IPO to provide information and other assurances about

firm value to investors. However, these incentives may change once the capital has been issued.

It is easy to imagine situations after the IPO in which firms have incentives to withhold or

manipulate information (e.g., when performance is poor). Thus, a mere promise at the IPO to

provide high-quality disclosures in the future is unlikely to be credible. In contrast, disclosure

requirements specify which information a firm has to provide and force it to reveal this

information in both good and bad times. This commitment can mitigate information

asymmetries and reduce uncertainty, both when going public and in secondary markets (e.g.,

Verrecchia, 2001). But as noted before, this argument alone is not sufficient to justify a

mandatory disclosure regime because firms would voluntarily seek such commitments if they are

beneficial (e.g., Ross, 1979). Thus, we need to argue (or provide evidence) that mandatory

disclosure provides commitment at lower costs.

Alternatively, we can look for reasons why mangers might not privately seek disclosure

commitments even if they are beneficial to the firm. Before we review this third class of

arguments, we note that managerial agency problems and a potential reluctance of managers to

16

Again, the idea that law can function as a commitment device is not specific to disclosure regulation. See, e.g.,

Aghion and Hermalin (1990).

Page 19: SSRN-id1105398

18

disclose information do not change the above reasoning. To illustrate this point, let us consider a

family-owned firm that has delegated day-to-day operations, including disclosure decisions, to a

manager. Assume that this firm tries to raise additional capital from outside investors and that

the manager promises to periodically disclose certain information to outside investors. Despite

this promise, outside investors understand that situations may arise where it is in the manager‟s

interest to withhold information (e.g., disclosures that would lead to her dismissal). Anticipating

these incentives, outside investors raise the rate of return at which they are willing to provide

capital to the firm, which implies that the controlling family ultimately bears the costs of not

providing a credible commitment as well as the costs of any residual agency problems. Thus, as

stated above, controlling owners have incentives to seek commitments and mitigate managerial

agency problems (Jensen and Meckling, 1976).

Despite these incentives, a mandatory regime can be beneficial if it is limited to

disclosures that almost all firms are willing to provide voluntarily (Ross, 1979).17

The

requirement saves firms the cost of negotiating disclosures when the result does not vary much

across firms and hence the costs of complying with a one-size-fits-all regime are relatively low.

Using this reasoning, Mahoney (1995) argues that “agency information,” i.e., disclosures about

related-party transactions, underwriting fees, and self-dealing, has this feature as it addresses

agency problems that arise in almost all securities offerings. In contrast, information that

primarily helps investors to project future cash flows and value the firm is likely to be highly

firm-specific and hence should be discretionary. Based on this justification, the key issue is to

identify disclosures that generate economy-wide cost savings.

17

Hermalin and Weisbach (2007) also argue that mandatory disclosure beyond the level chosen voluntarily is likely

to reduce social welfare.

Page 20: SSRN-id1105398

19

A third and closely related argument is that privately producing a sufficient level of

disclosure commitment can be very expensive and in many cases even impossible. The penalties

that private contracts can impose are generally quite limited. For instance, in our example of a

family-controlled firm, the threat of dismissal or monetary penalties may not be sufficient to

ensure that the manager always adheres to the owners‟ disclosure policy. Thus, a mandatory

disclosure regime can be beneficial if it offers access to criminal penalties or other remedies that

are not available to private contracts.

A recent stream of literature argues that controlling shareholders and corporate insiders

(e.g., the family in the preceding example) can extract substantial private benefits from firms and

thereby effectively expropriate outside investors (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; La Porta et al.,

2000). As a result, controlling insiders may be reluctant to provide disclosures that limit their

ability to consume private benefits. That is, controlling insiders may not seek a disclosure

commitment, even when it increases firm value and reduces the cost of capital. But as Jensen

and Meckling (1976) argue, outside investors are likely to price protect, so the controlling

owners bear the costs of extracting private benefits and providing insufficient disclosures.

Besides, even if outsiders do not fully anticipate the level of expropriation, as long as controlling

owners value the resources they divert or consume at least as much as outside investors, private

benefits simply constitute a wealth transfer and not a social loss.

However, it seems plausible that the diversion activities themselves are costly, in which

case there are social losses (e.g., Burkhart et al, 1998; Shleifer and Wolfenzon, 2002). Moreover,

and perhaps more importantly, controlling insiders are likely to forgo profitable investment

opportunities for the sake of private benefits (e.g., Shleifer and Wolfenzon, 2002). This behavior

is not socially costly if other firms enter the business and exploit these opportunities. But it can

Page 21: SSRN-id1105398

20

have substantial social costs if other firms cannot exploit these opportunities and they are lost to

the economy as whole. Thus, competition and the ability of new entrants to raise capital play an

important role for the extent to which the consumption of private benefits has social costs. First,

competition likely limits the extent to which controlling insiders can appropriate resources

without threatening the survival of the firm. Second, new entrants that intend to exploit the

opportunities forgone by the incumbents need ways to credibly commit so that they can raise the

necessary capital.

Thus, a potential benefit of a mandatory disclosure regime is that it makes it easier for

new entrants to commit and hence to raise capital, which in turn increases competition and

reduces social losses from private benefits consumption (see also Ferrell, 2004).18

In contrast,

the incumbents are likely to oppose such a regime and, more generally, have an incentive to

prevent the creation of legal institutions that facilitate commitment, lead to more competition and

lower private benefits (Rajan and Zingales, 2003).19

In promoting the development of financial

markets, mandatory disclosure can also benefit investors, e.g., in creating new investment

opportunities for their savings. Again, incumbent firms would not necessarily create such

opportunities as they may make it easier for entrants to raise finance (Rajan and Zingales, 2003).

The preceding discussion illustrates that mandatory disclosure can have a number of

benefits and be socially desirable. However, to avoid the Nirvana fallacy, it is important to

recognize that mandatory disclosure regimes have costs and are not without problems. First,

mandatory regimes are costly to design, implement and enforce. Second, incumbent firms have

18

It may also have the direct benefit of making it harder for controlling insiders to consume private benefits and thus

of mitigating the root cause of the problem. 19

This incentive exists regardless of whether controlling insiders of incumbent firms consume private benefits or not.

But the incentive is likely to be stronger when they do extract such benefits.

Page 22: SSRN-id1105398

21

an incentive to capture the regulatory process, e.g., to implement a system that inhibits, rather

than promotes competition, which in turn can create substantial indirect costs (Stigler, 1971).

Recognizing these issues, Djankov et al. (2003) propose an enforcement theory of

regulation. Their premise is that all strategies to implement a socially desirable policy are

imperfect and that optimal institutional design involves a tradeoff between imperfect

alternatives.20

A Coasian implementation, which relies heavily on courts and private litigation,

can be quite imperfect, especially when “weapons” are unequal across litigants. For instance, it

seems plausible that richer, better connected, and better represented promoters and underwriters

have a stronger influence on the course of justice than defrauded, small investors (Shleifer, 2005).

One way to address this shortcoming of private orderings with private enforcement is to specify

mandatory disclosures because rules limit court discretion.21

As Shleifer (2005) points out, it is

easier for a firm to influence a court or judge when there are no specific rules of what needs to be

disclosed. This discussion highlights two important points: (i) it can be beneficial to combine

public rules and private enforcement (e.g., Hay and Shleifer, 1998) and (ii) the desirability and

effectiveness of particular disclosure rules depends also on the chosen enforcement mechanism,

which highlights an important complementarity in the institutional framework. We will come

back to the issue of complementarities.

Another important factor is the level at which disclosure regulation takes place and hence

who is the regulator. It is conceivable to create mandatory regimes at the exchange, state,

country or supranational level. Each level has its advantages and drawbacks. Regulating at a

higher level (e.g., country) generates larger benefits from standardization and exploits network

20

They characterize the problem as a tradeoff between two basic social costs: disorder and dictatorship. Shleifer

(2005) explicitly discusses this tradeoff in the context of securities regulation. 21

In a related fashion, Easterbrock and Fischel (1984) and Mahoney (1995) also argue that mandatory disclosure

and anti-fraud provisions are complementary.

Page 23: SSRN-id1105398

22

externalities. Regulating at a lower level (e.g., exchange) avoids the problems of a one-size-fits-

all approach and allows firms to opt into a particular regime, which in turn creates competition

among regulatory regimes. The latter can have benefits and drawbacks for the development and

enforcement of mandatory disclosures (e.g., Mahoney, 1997; Romano, 1998 and 2001; Huddart

et al., 1999; Rock, 2002; Chemmanur and Fulghieri, 2006). These issues become even more

complicated in global securities markets where the regulations of various countries interact with

each other but are harder to coordinate. Barth, Clinch and Shibano (1999) explore these issues in

the context of accounting harmonization and show that countervailing forces imply that

accounting harmonization can have beneficial or deleterious effects on security markets.

Generally speaking, however, there is little research on the interaction between financial

globalization and countries‟ disclosure regulations.

2.5. Concluding Remarks on the Theory of Financial Reporting and Disclosure Regulation

In summary, the potential costs and benefits of disclosure regulation are numerous and

complex. Our framework identifies important costs and benefits of firms‟ voluntary disclosure

activities, as well as potential costs and benefits of regulating these activities. Our review

illustrates that the net effect of disclosure regulation on a market or an economy is largely an

empirical question. Moreover, the extant theoretical literature typically analyzes and evaluates

disclosure regulation in a static way. However, there are important issues of with respect to the

dynamics, process and form of reporting and disclosure regulation, complementarities with

other regulations, and regulatory competition that are still unexplored in the theoretical literature.

We discuss these issues as directions for future research in Section 6.

Page 24: SSRN-id1105398

23

3. Empirical Evidence on the Costs and Benefits of Disclosure

In this section, we review empirical studies on the potential costs and benefits of firms‟

information financial reporting and disclosure policies. We again apply the framework

developed in section 2 to identify possible firm-specific (micro-level) and market-wide (macro-

level) effects of firms‟ disclosure and reporting activities. Our review complements prior

surveys of the empirical disclosure literature by Healy and Palepu (2001) and Core (2001) by

focusing in particular on new studies that post-date these surveys.

As a first step, we outline how the empirical literature defines and measures the quality of

firms‟ disclosures and financial reporting attributes. What is meant by “high quality” disclosures

and financial reports is often ambiguous and difficult to measure. We also highlight the fact that

most empirical studies explore the association between firms‟ voluntary disclosure choices and

various costs and benefits of these choices across firms in a given sample. These firm-specific

effects can be relevant in regulatory debates if: (i) they help us pinpoint key costs and benefits of

financial reporting and disclosure, (ii) they inform us about the differential costs and benefits to

firms, which in turn helps us understand how uniform reporting requirements may differentially

affect firms (including potential wealth transfers among firms), or (iii) they help us predict which

firms may take avoidance actions or lobby for or against a proposed regulation given the

potential differential effects on firms and wealth transfers between them. In general, however,

voluntary disclosure studies cannot provide insights into the overall desirability, economic

efficiency, or aggregate outcomes of regulating these disclosures. Therefore, it is also important

to review the empirical evidence on the macro-level effects and externalities of firms‟ disclosure

choices.

Page 25: SSRN-id1105398

24

3.1. Measuring Disclosure and the Quality of Accounting Numbers

Corporate information can be disseminated through financial reporting (e.g., the annual

report or SEC filings like the 10-K or 10-Q) and through various scheduled and unscheduled

disclosures (e.g., press releases, conference calls). Disclosures are often qualitative and narrative

in nature which makes objective measurement difficult for empiricists. Moreover, theoretical

research provides little guidance on what form, quantity and frequency of disclosure is relevant

for various stakeholders. Yet, there seems to be agreement that that timely, relevant, verifiable,

reliable, unbiased, comparable and consistent disclosures and financial reports are all “desirable”

properties of corporate disclosures and financial reports (FASB, Statement of Financial

Accounting Concepts No. 2). However, many of these properties are in conflict with each other

and, as a result, empirical researchers face challenges in identifying and capturing the most

important dimensions of high quality corporate information.

A widely-used disclosure measure is based on the annual survey of financial analysts‟

rankings of U.S. firms‟ disclosure activities by the Association for Investment Management and

Research (AIMR) (e.g., Lang and Lundholm, 1993, 1996; Welker, 1995; Healy, Hutton and

Palepu, 1999; and Nagar, Nanda and Wysocki, 2003).22

These rankings arguably capture the

usefulness of firms‟ disclosures as perceived by expert users of this information. The disclosure

rankings capture a broad range of disclosure activities including annual report information,

voluntary disclosures in quarterly reports, and more diffuse disclosures arising from investor

relations activities. The limitations of the AIMR rankings are that they are only applicable to a

subset of large U.S. firms ranked in the survey during the 1980s and 1990s. Moreover, there are

22

The AIMR has changed its name to CFA Institute. The disclosure ratings were published under the old name

(AIMR) and discontinued in the mid 1990‟s. Academic studies still refer to these ratings as AIMR ratings.

Page 26: SSRN-id1105398

25

questions about potential bias in the rankings based on sell-side analysts‟ objectives in assigning

disclosure ratings.23

Other studies use measures of disclosure activities constructed by researchers (e.g.,

Botosan, 1997; Hail, 2003; Francis, Nanda and Olsson, 2005). These self-constructed measures

generally use a check-list of information disclosures in firms‟ annual reports. International

studies often rely on the international CIFAR index, which is also constructed from annual report

information for large firms across a range of countries and typically averaged at the country level

(e.g., La Porta et al, 1998; Hope, 2003; Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki, 2003), and the Standard and

Poor‟s scores of international firms‟ disclosures (e.g., Khanna, Palepu, and Srinivasan, 2004;

Doidge et al., 2007a). The limitations of these types of measures are that the selection and coding

of the relevant disclosures are subjective, that they generally capture the existence of particular

disclosures, rather than their quality, and that the construction of a single index assigns particular

weights to the different disclosure items. Moreover, these measures often do not capture other

disclosure activities that can complement or substitute for financial report disclosures.

Other studies focus on the timing and frequency of firms‟ disclosures such the frequency

and precision of management forecasts of earnings (see Hirst, Koonce and Venkataraman, 2008,

for a review of the literature), ), and conference calls with analysts (e.g., Tasker, 1998; Frankel,

Johnson, and Skinner, 1999; Bushee, Matsumoto, and Miller, 2003). While it is difficult to

objectively quantify the information issued with management forecasts and during conference

calls, the studies highlight that these disclosure events generally reveal useful qualitative and

contextual information to outside investors.

23

There are concerns that the surveyed sell-side analysts simply assign higher ratings to firms with better prospects

and financial performance. For example, Lang and Lundholm (1993) find that AIMR disclosure ratings are strongly

correlated with past performance. Healy and Palepu (2001) also identify additional limitations of the AIMR data.

Page 27: SSRN-id1105398

26

More recently, studies have made a more direct attempt to measure the “quality” of

accounting information provided to outside investors by analyzing the properties of a firm‟s

reported earnings. For instance, research suggests that conservative accounting reports (e.g.,

Basu, 1997; Ball, Kothari and Robin, 2000), earnings smoothing activities (e.g., Leuz, Nanda

and Wysocki, 2003; Francis, LaFond, Olsson and Schipper, 2004; LaFond, Lang, and Skaife,

2007), earnings persistence (e.g., Dechow and Dichev, 2002; Francis, LaFond, Olsson and

Schipper, 2004) and the value-relevance of earnings (Collins, Maydew and Weiss, 1997; Francis

and Schipper, 1999) can capture important (positive or negative) dimensions of a firm‟s

discretionary information quality. In addition, the proxies developed in the earnings management

literature also provide ways to measure lower quality earnings (see, for example, Healy and

Whalen, 1999, and Dechow and Skinner, 2000).

Several papers use these individual proxies or aggregate them to measure accounting

quality. For example, Leuz, Nanda and Wysocki (2003) examine four earnings properties that

indicate opaque financial reporting and/or earnings management, both of which can limit the

usefulness of the accounting information for outside investors. These measures have been used

in a variety of contexts and by several other studies (e.g., Bhattacharya, Daouk and Welker,

2003; Lang, Raedy and Yetman, 2003b; Lang, Raedy and Wilson, 2006; Burgstahler et al. 2006).

By aggregating across measures or showing similar results for several different measures, these

studies attempt to address concerns about measurement error. As with the construction of

disclosure indices, there is the question on how to weight the properties and the issue that the

relations and tradeoffs between properties are ignored.

Page 28: SSRN-id1105398

27

Dechow and Dichev (2002) and Francis, LaFond, Olsson and Schipper (2005) model the

relation between a firm‟s cash flows and working capital accruals to derive a measure of

earnings quality. Subsequent research even suggests that these accruals-based measures can

potentially capture a firm‟s overall information quality (e.g., Ecker, Francis, Kim, Olsson, and

Schipper, 2006). However, Core, Guay and Verdi (2007), Hribar and Nichols (2007), Liu and

Wysocki (2007) and Wysocki (2007) present evidence casts doubt on this claim and even

questions the extent to which “accruals quality” captures a firm‟s earnings quality.

There are also related empirical studies that examine and attempt to quantify a firm‟s

information environment. While these studies do not directly measure a firm‟s disclosure or

reporting activities, they do attempt to capture the information asymmetry among traders in a

firm‟s securities. For example, Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O‟Hara (2002) use the probability of

informed trade in a firm‟s shares (PIN) as a proxy for information asymmetry among traders.

Subsequently, this measure has been used to examine the link with firms‟ disclosure activities,

In sum, the existing literature shows that measuring firms‟ financial reporting and

disclosure activities is difficult and that commonly used proxies exhibit many problems. Thus,

there is clearly a need for more research to improve existing proxies as well as to capture

qualitative and narrative disclosures more broadly (see also Core, 2001).

3.2. Benefits of Voluntary Disclosures and High Quality Financial Reports

3.2.1. Liquidity Benefits of Disclosures and Financial Reports

As discussed in section 2.1, a possible direct firm-specific benefit of high quality

disclosures and financial reports is greater liquidity of a firm‟s securities. Survey evidence

suggests that managers believe that such a liquidity benefit exists. Graham, Harvey and

Rajgopal (2005) survey managers from 312 public U.S. firms and find that 44% of managers

Page 29: SSRN-id1105398

28

strongly agree with the statement that “voluntarily communicating information increases the

overall liquidity of our stock” (compared to 17% of managers who strongly disagree with the

statement). However, the survey provides no evidence on the economic magnitude of the

liquidity benefit nor which types, quantity, frequency, and quality of voluntary disclosures are

necessary to achieve a measurable impact on stock liquidity.

Other cross-sectional studies attempt to directly quantify the stock market liquidity

benefits of greater voluntary disclosure. Welker (1995) tests the liquidity impact of firms‟

voluntary disclosure using AIMR disclosure rankings. He finds that firms in the lowest third of

the disclosure rankings have about 50 percent higher bid-ask spreads than firms in the highest

third of the rankings. However, his tests for the sensitivity of bid-ask spreads to disclosure

policy based on the probability of informed trade activity and probability of information event

occurrences are statistically insignificant. Healy, Hutton, and Palepu (1999) also use AIMR

rankings to examine a sample of firms that exhibit a voluntary and sustained increase in their

disclosures. They find these firms had a significant increase in their liquidity (bid-ask spreads

and trading volume) after the perceived increase in their disclosure quality. Recent work by Ng

(2007) also suggests that certain information quality attributes are associated with the liquidity of

a firm‟s shares and with a firm‟s estimated loading on the liquidity factor suggested by Pastor

and Stambaugh, 2003. He finds that management forecast frequency is negatively associated

with a firm‟s loading on the liquidity risk factor, whereas accounting earnings attributes such as

value relevance and accruals quality are not significantly associated with the loading on the

liquidity risk factor. Ng (2007) also provides some evidence that the effect of better information

quality in lowering liquidity risk is stronger for firms with less private information.

Page 30: SSRN-id1105398

29

In an international setting, Leuz and Verrecchia (2000) examine a sample of German

firms that voluntarily adopt more onerous disclosure requirements by switching from German

GAAP to an international reporting regime (i.e., IAS or U.S. GAAP). Leuz and Verrecchia

(2000) find that switching firms have smaller bid-ask spreads and higher trading volume

following the switch and relative to German GAAP firms, consistent with the notion that a

commitment to more disclosure reduce adverse selection in capital markets.

These studies show that certain voluntary disclosures and accounting attributes are

associated with greater liquidity for a firm‟s shares and suggest that traders require less price

protection when buying or selling shares. However, in many instances, the economic

significance of the liquidity effects in cross-sectional studies of U.S. firms appears to be small.

One issue is that these studies analyze firms‟ disclosures within the rich and stringent U.S.

disclosure system where the effects of additional voluntary disclosures are likely to be small

(Leuz and Verrecchia, 2000). Moreover, cross-sectional studies may understate the true liquidity

impact of voluntary disclosures. For example, firms with non-existent or minimal disclosures do

not appear in the samples, but are likely to have such large bid-ask spreads that there is little or

no public trading.24

In other words, these extreme cases are often missing from cross-sectional

studies, and therefore the results may understate the true magnitude of the liquidity impact of

public disclosure in share markets.

3.2.2. Voluntary Disclosure, Accounting Quality and Firms’ Cost of Capital

Another possible benefit of voluntary disclosures and high quality financial reports is that

they directly lower a firm‟s cost of capital. As outlined in section 2.1, there are several

24

Consistent with this claim, Bushee and Leuz (2005) document that firms in the OTC markets have extremely low

levels of market liquidity and Leuz, Triantis and Wang (2007) show that liquidity essentially “vanishes” if firms

cease to provide public disclosures on a regular basis.

Page 31: SSRN-id1105398

30

mechanisms by which an increase in corporate disclosures can manifest in a lower cost of capital.

At present, however, the literature has primarily focused on establishing the link between

disclosure and the cost of capital and has provided relatively little evidence on the mechanism. In

this section, we review several of the key papers and results without trying to be comprehensive

(see also Healy and Palepu, 2001; and Core, 2001).

Again, there is survey evidence suggesting that managers perceive a cost of capital

benefit from expanded voluntary disclosures. Graham, Harvey and Rajgopal (2005) find that

39% of managers strongly agree with the statement the “voluntarily communicating information

reduces our cost of capital”, while 22% strongly disagree with this statement. However, the

economic magnitude of this cost of capital effect cannot be determined from this survey.

Moreover, it should be noted that the perceived benefits of disclosure do not apply equally to all

firms. Graham et al. (2005) find that the perceived reduction in the cost of capital is greatest for

firms with high analyst following.25

Theory suggests that information asymmetry and the adverse selection problems of non-

disclosure can flow back to the firm‟s share issuance decision and translate into a higher cost of

raising capital. Consistent with this conjecture, research documents a positive link between

external capital raising activities and disclosure quantity and quality (e.g., Frankel, McNichols

and Wilson, 1995; Healy, Hutton and Palepu, 1999; Lang and Lundholm, 2000). More recently,

there are also studies that document more extensive pre-IPO disclosures are associated with

lower underpricing (e.g., Schrand and Verrecchia, 2005; Leone, Rock and Willenborg, 2007)

Other cross-sectional studies attempt to directly quantify the cost of capital benefits of

greater voluntary disclosure. One of the first studies in this vein is Botosan (1997). She creates a

25

They also find that the beneficial impact of voluntary disclosures on a firm‟s P/E (which can be viewed as a rough

measure of its cost of equity capital) is much more muted for firms with low analyst following.

Page 32: SSRN-id1105398

31

self-constructed index of voluntary annual report disclosures for a sample of U.S. manufacturing

companies and links it to an ex ante imputed cost of capital measure. In her overall sample, she

does not find a significant relation between voluntary disclosure and equity cost of capital.

However, firms with low analyst following do exhibit the predicted negative relation between

disclosure and cost of equity capital. Interestingly, this result is exactly opposite to the survey

findings of Graham et al. (2005), which suggest that the disclosure-cost of capital relation is

weakest for firms with low analyst following.26

Follow-up research by Botosan and Plumlee (2002) finds a significant negative relation

between cost of equity capital and annual report disclosures.27

However, they find contradictory

evidence suggesting that the cost of capital is higher for firms with more timely voluntary

disclosures, and no association between the cost of capital and firms‟ investor relations activities.

Other mixed evidence on the cost of capital outcomes is also presented in Healy, Hutton and

Palepu (1999). They find that firms‟ realized stock returns are higher in the years following an

improvement in their disclosures. Taken literally, this finding suggests that better disclosure

actually increases firms‟ cost of capital. However, it should be noted that realized returns are

likely to be a relatively poor proxy for firms‟ cost of capital unless they are measured over very

long time periods (e.g., Elton, 1999).

In an international context, Hail (2003) examines a sample of Swiss firms where

mandated disclosure is low and there is large variation in firms‟ voluntary disclosure policies. He

finds that more forthcoming firms enjoy around a 2.5% cost advantage over the least

26

The Merton (1987) model of incomplete information and risk sharing suggests that firms can make investors

aware of their existence and enlarge the investor base, which in turn lowers their cost of capital. This effect would

seem most pronounced for small firms (e.g., in the OTC markets) and it less relevant for large firms with high

analyst following. 27

See also Botosan (2006).

Page 33: SSRN-id1105398

32

forthcoming firms. The considerable magnitude of his findings in a weak disclosure environment

is consistent with the idea expressed in Leuz and Verrecchia (2000) that the magnitude of the

relation may depend on countries‟ institutional factors. These findings also illustrate the possible

interactive effects between firms‟ disclosure policies, institutional factors, and ultimately the

impact of disclosure regulation.

There is also a growing literature on the link between a firm‟s accounting attributes (such

as earnings volatility and accruals quality) and the firm‟s cost of capital. For example, Francis,

LaFond, Olsson and Schipper (2004) and Verdi (2006) show that smoother earnings are

associated with a lower implied cost of capital. Francis, LaFond, Olsson and Schipper (2005)

examine the link between cost of equity capital and the “quality” of a firm‟s accruals. They find

a strong negative relation between their measure of accruals quality and various cost of capital

measures including P/E ratios, market betas, and observed stock returns, suggesting that the cost

of capital decreases when earnings quality increases. Francis et al. (2005) also create an

economy-wide risk factor based on their “accruals quality” measure. They argue that their stock

returns tests support the idea that “accruals quality” is a systematic, i.e. non-diversifiable, risk

factor, over and above beta. Ogneva (2007) also provides evidence that “accruals quality” seems

to be a priced risk factor after controlling for shocks to a firm‟s expected cash flows.

However, recent research suggests that the apparent association between accounting

attributes and cost of capital is often not robust and also not unambiguous in its interpretation.

For example, Core et al. (2007) show that the asset pricing tests in Francis et al. (2005) and

Ecker et al. (2006) are not appropriate to determine whether accruals quality is a priced risk

factor. When conducting proper (two-stage cross-sectional tests) asset pricing tests, Core et al.

(2007) find little evidence that accruals quality is priced as a separate risk factor. In addition,

Page 34: SSRN-id1105398

33

McInnis (2007) finds no relation between smooth earnings and neither average stock returns nor

a firm‟s implied cost of capital after adjusting for analysts‟ biases in their earnings forecasts.28

He also shows that the bias in analysts‟ forecasts may also drive the apparent association

between accruals quality and a firm‟s implied cost of capital (Francis et al, 2004, and Core, Guay,

Verdi, 2007). Furthermore, Nichols (2006) and Liu and Wysocki (2007) show that the Francis et

al (2005) findings on the association between accruals quality and cost of capital are not robust

after controlling for firm‟s fundamental operating characteristics, suggesting that the accruals

quality measure does not properly separate firms‟ reporting activities and the properties of its

operating processes.

Recent studies also examine the association between cost of debt capital and voluntary

disclosures. Sengupta (1998) uses AIMR rankings of firms‟ disclosures to examine the relation

between cost of debt and voluntary disclosure. He documents an inverse relation between

disclosure and the effective interest cost of raising debt. Miller and Puthenpurackal (2002) also

find that U.S. debtholders demand economically significant premiums on bonds for foreign firms

that have no prior history of on-going disclosure. Moreover, Zhang (2006) finds that lenders

offer lower up-front interest rates to firms that report conservative earnings numbers and that

these findings are robust to controlling for numerous of other earnings attributes.29

This evidence

contrasts with other studies that claim that conservative earnings properties are not a primary

factor in determining cost of (equity) capital (e.g., Francis, LaFond, Olsson and Schipper, 2004).

28

See Easton (2008) for a comprehensive discussion of the theoretical, empirical and methodological issues related

to estimating a firm‟s implied cost of capital. 29

Graham, Harvey and Rajgopal (2005) survey managers from 312 public firms and find that 42% of managers

strongly agree with the statement that “a smooth earnings path is preferred because it achieves or preserves a desired

credit rating.” This compares with 19% of managers who strongly disagree with this statement. This statement is

relevant because 47% of the managers also strongly agree with the statement that “a smooth earnings path is

preferred because it promotes a reputation for transparent and accurate reporting.” In other words, smooth earnings

appear to be synonymous with high quality financial reporting and this property appears to be valued by debtholders.

However, this is somewhat ironic because the most surveyed managers also stated that smooth earnings fail to

clarify true economic performance.

Page 35: SSRN-id1105398

34

However, a major difficulty of tests involving the cost of debt is to control for the specifics of

firms‟ debt contracts, in particular the covenants, and their impact on the cost of debt.

Overall, the evidence on the cross-sectional relation between a firm‟s voluntary

disclosures, accounting attributes and cost of capital is still evolving and hence it is difficult to

draw definitive and unambiguous conclusions whether the empirical evidence supports current

theories on the link between information quality and cost of capital. The empirical results appear

to be sensitive to and can vary across different measures of cost of capital (i.e., realized returns

versus ex ante cost of capital proxies), types of firms (i.e., different sizes), with the presence of

other intermediaries (i.e., financial analysts), across types of disclosures or earnings attributes

(i.e., annual reports versus timely disclosures versus conservative earnings), across types of

investors (shareholders versus bondholders), and across different institutional environments (i.e.,

U.S. versus other markets).

Another issue is that voluntary disclosure and reporting studies face a self-selection

problem, which makes proper identification and estimating the marginal effects of voluntary

disclosures on the cost of capital (and other outcomes such as liquidity) difficult. The fact that

many studies do not address this issue may also contribute to the lack of consistent findings (e.g.,

Leuz and Verrecchia, 2000; Core, 2001; Nikolaev and van Lent, 2005; Larcker and Rusticus,

2005).

3.3. Empirical Evidence on the Firm-Specific Costs of Voluntary Disclosures

There is a general paucity of empirical evidence on the direct costs and out of pocket

expenses of firm‟s disclosure and reporting choices. It is often difficult to quantify the direct

costs especially if they come in the form of opportunity costs such as managerial time. However,

the empirical literature suggests that there are fixed costs to information production and

Page 36: SSRN-id1105398

35

dissemination than induce economies of scale in disclosure. Empirical disclosure studies

consistently find that larger firms have better average disclosure quality (e.g., Lang and

Lundholm, 1993).

On the other hand, there is more evidence on the indirect costs of voluntary disclosures.

For example, there are a number of empirical studies that examine the effects of proprietary costs

on firms‟ voluntary disclosure decisions.30

Harris (1998) explores the association between

product market competition and detailed industry segment disclosures. She finds that profitable

operations in less competitive industries are less likely to be reported as industry segments.

Berger and Hann (2003) also provide insights into the issue of proprietary costs by examining a

change to U.S. reporting requirements for segment disclosures (i.e., the transition from SFAS 14

to SFAS 131). Under SFAS 14, firms were arguably given greater discretion in defining industry

segments and therefore hiding segment information. SFAS 131 reduced this flexibility and

discretion. Berger and Hann (2003) compare segment disclosures under both standards and find

that firms that previously aggregated information under SFAS 14 had higher abnormal

profitability and operations with more divergent performance. Leuz (2004) also examines

proprietary costs for voluntary disclosures of segment information for a sample of German firms.

He finds that firms are less likely to voluntarily disclose segment information if profitability

across segments is heterogeneous and the mean profitability reported in the consolidated income

statement is less revealing. Together results generally support the existence of variation in

proprietary costs across firms and provide evidence that these differential costs influence firms‟

voluntary disclosure choices.

30

Proprietary costs are the costs faced by a firm if it reveals information to outside parties. These costs include the

revelation of trade secrets, the disclosure of profitable customers and markets, or the exposure of operating

weakness to competing firms, unions, regulators, investors, customers or suppliers.

Page 37: SSRN-id1105398

36

Other research posits that shareholder litigation provides a disincentive for firms to

voluntarily provide forward-looking disclosures. Many early studies find mixed evidence on the

effect of litigation on disclosure, especially bad news disclosures (see, for example, Kasznik and

Lev, 1995; Skinner, 1997; and Johnson, Kasznik and Nelson, 2001). Field, Lowry and Shu

(2005) attempt to reconcile this mixed empirical evidence on the relation between bad news

disclosures and litigation. They highlight a possibly endogenous relation between observed

litigation outcomes and voluntary management disclosures of bad news. After explicitly

modeling the endogeneity in their empirical tests, their results suggest that disclosure potentially

deters litigation. Therefore, given the threat of litigation, more forthcoming disclosure can

benefit the firm in the sense that it reduces expected litigation costs. On the other hand, managers

may also face significant ex post personal costs to disclosing bad news to investors. For example,

Kothari, Shu and Wysocki (2007) present evidence consistent with widespread withholding of

bad news by managers. They argue that managerial career concerns (broadly-defined) motivate

them to accumulate and withhold bad news in the hope that things will turn around and they can

bury the bad news.

Finally, it is possible that disclosure activities have indirect costs for existing private

financing or political relationships. As discussed in Section 2.2, firms with relationship

financing through their banks may be more reluctant in their full disclosure. At present, there is

relatively little evidence on these indirect costs of disclosure. One example is the study by Leuz

and Oberholzer-Gee (2006), which provides evidence on a tradeoff between transparency and

political relationships for a sample of Indonesian firms with close ties to President Suharto.

Page 38: SSRN-id1105398

37

3.4. Market-Wide Impact of Firms’ Disclosure and Reporting Activities

It seems intuitive that one firm‟s disclosures and financial reports should provide

information about the prospects of other related firms. Foster (1981) was among the first to

empirically show that a firm‟s earnings announcement provides information to investors about

other firms in the same industry. Han, Wild and Ramesh (1989) also show that managers‟

voluntary earnings forecast disclosures affect the security prices of firms in the same industry.

While other follow-up studies also look at these direct information transfers, the more interesting

question for our purposes is the existence and magnitude of market-wide externalities from

firms‟ disclosure activities.

Recent cases of accounting restatements suggest that not only do restating firms face

equity market penalties (arguably related to an increased cost of capital), but such penalties also

transfers to the firm‟s competitors (Gleason, Jenkins and Johnson, 2004; and Xu, Najand and

Zigenfuss, 2006). Durnev and Mangen (2007) also argue that one firm‟s restatement

announcement reveals information about the efficiency of its competitors past investments.

Durnev and Mangen argue and present supporting evidence that a firm‟s past misreporting

activities affected competitors‟ past investment decisions leading to sub-optimal investment

based on the erroneous information. Specifically, when a restatement is announced, investors

recognize the competitors‟ past inefficient investment choices and they revise downwards their

assessment of the competitors‟ future expected cash flows. Sidak (2003) presents similar

arguments in his case study of the Worldcom accounting fraud. He argues that WorldCom's

fraudulent disclosure and financial reports had real negative effects on other telecom firms,

governments and capital markets. WorldCom's falsified reports and disclosures lead to: (i) the

widespread overinvestment in network capacity by other firms, (ii) the formulation of flawed

Page 39: SSRN-id1105398

38

government telecommunication policies, and (ii) the sustained retrenchment of financing sources

away from future telecom investment projects. Sadka (2006) also presents similar arguments on

the real spillover investment effects of firms‟ misreporting activities.

4. Evidence on Reporting and Disclosure Regulation

In this section, we focus primarily on recent empirical studies that can provide more

direct insights into the aggregate and macro-economic economic consequences of financial

reporting and disclosure regulations. We review studies that examine the economic outcomes of

changes in regulations, as well as studies that explore international differences in disclosure

regulations and firms‟ and investors‟ responses to these differences.

As Healy and Palepu (2001) note in their survey, empirical research on disclosure

regulation and the economic consequences of (major) regulatory events is rare and most of these

studies focus on early U.S. disclosure regulation in the 1930s. To be sure, there is a vast

literature on the capital-market consequences of mandated changes of (particular) accounting

standards.31

However, these studies examine firms that are already subject to the U.S. disclosure

regime and generally focus on individual (accounting) rule changes, rather than broader changes

in the disclosure regime. Moreover, much of this literature uses the association between reported

accounting numbers and stock returns (or prices) as a way to evaluate particular rules or rule

changes. As Holthausen and Watts (2001) point out, there is little theory supporting the

31

See, e.g., the surveys in Watts and Zimmerman (1986), Fields, Lys, and Vincent (2001) and Kothari (2001).

Page 40: SSRN-id1105398

39

association criterion for standard setting and, as a consequence, it is not clear to what extent this

literature can guide accounting regulators.32

More recently, there are a number of studies evaluating the economic consequences of

major regulatory changes, such as the 1964 Securities Act Amendments, the 1999 Eligibility

Rule on the OTC Bulletin Board, and Regulation Fair Disclosure in 2000, and the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act of 2002. There is also recent research exploiting international variation in disclosure

regulation. In this section, we review these relatively new studies in addition to the early work

on disclosure regulation. In following section, we then separately focus on the economic

consequences of the introduction of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS).

4.1. Studies Evaluating Early U.S. Disclosure Regulation

The early empirical literature on disclosure regulation primarily studies the Securities Act

of 1933 and the Exchange Act of 1934 and is generally skeptical about the merits of the

regulation, e.g., its value to investors. Stigler (1964) and Jarrell (1981) analyze abnormal returns

to new issues as a way to gauge whether fewer fraudulent or overpriced securities are brought to

the market after the 1933 Act. Both studies find no evidence that, after the 1933 Act, registered

securities exhibit larger returns than unregistered securities offered before the Act, questioning

the widely held view that unregistered securities offerings in the 1920‟s were generally

overpriced and that investors are better off after the Act. However, both studies also find that the

variance of abnormal returns decreases (see also Simon, 1989), suggesting that securities

offerings are less risky since the introduction of SEC disclosure regulation. In addition, Jarrell

(1981) provides evidence that default rates of registered bonds have decreased after the Act.

32

Barth, Beaver and Landsman (2001) reply to the Holthausen and Watts (2001) critique and provide a defense of

the value relevance literature.

Page 41: SSRN-id1105398

40

Benston (1969) finds little evidence of fraud related to financial statements in the period

before the Acts of 1933 and 1934. In addition, he documents that there was widespread

voluntary disclosure prior to the Acts. Benston (1973) confirms that there were few abuses in

reporting prior to the Act and finds little evidence that the risk of securities has significantly

decreased. Finally, Chow (1983) analyzes stock reactions to events related to the passage of the

Acts and finds negative abnormal stock returns, which are partly attributable to effects on firms‟

accounting-based debt covenants. This evidence is consistent with the notion that the 1933 Act

had significant out-of-pocket costs for firms and that it affected firms‟ investment and financing

opportunities by tightening existing covenants. It also highlights that regulation may have

(unintended) effects on financial contracts.

All these findings have been heavily debated and repeatedly been challenged (e.g., Friend

and Herman, 1964; Seligman, 1983; Coffee, 1984; Easterbrook and Fischel, 1984; Romano,

1998; Fox, 1999). Proponents of mandatory disclosures often point to the result that the variance

of abnormal returns of new issues decreases after the imposition of SEC disclosure regulation.

They interpret this evidence as supporting the notion that mandatory disclosures improve

investors‟ assessment of risky securities (e.g., Seligman, 1983). Critics of disclosure regulation

in turn argue that this result likely reflects a selection rather than a treatment effect. They point

out that, after the Acts, there is a trend from public debt offerings towards private debt

placements, and this trend is more pronounced among relatively risky bonds (Benston, 1969;

Jarrell, 1981; Simon, 1989). Thus, it is possible that the Acts have simply shifted riskier

securities to less regulated markets.

Another issue is that the early studies do not control for changing market conditions over

the time period, in particular the onset of the Great Depression. The problem is that all

Page 42: SSRN-id1105398

41

exchange-traded firms were affected by the new regulation and hence the studies do not have a

natural control group.

Recent studies by Daines and Jones (2005) and Mahoney and Mei (2006) address these

shortcomings. They examine changes in information asymmetry and market liquidity around the

Acts using cross-sectional analyses and private placements to control for time period effects.

Both studies document a decline in spreads and an increase in market liquidity but find little

evidence that these results are attributable to the imposition of SEC disclosure regulation. The

improvements in market liquidity seem to be driven by market-wide trends unrelated to the

regulation.

4.2. Studies on Subsequent Extensions of U.S. Disclosure Regulation in the OTC Markets

There are several recent studies analyzing the 1964 Securities Act Amendments or the

1999 Eligibility Rule for the OTC Bulletin Board. These two regulatory events essentially

extended SEC disclosure regulation to segments of the OTC markets. As such they represent

major changes in disclosure regulation. But as these events apply only to a subset of publicly

traded firms in the economy, there are natural control groups allowing for tighter research

designs than the original introduction of SEC disclosure regulation in the U.S.

Ferrell (2003) analyzes the Securities Act Amendments of 1964 which subjected larger

OTC securities, many of which later traded on NASDAQ, to the Acts of 1933 and 1934. As the

earlier studies, he finds that the imposition of SEC disclosure regulation is associated with a

significant reduction in volatility among OTC securities, relative to securities that are already

subject to SEC disclosure requirements. This finding is consistent with the notion that

information is more quickly impounded in prices, leading to lower volatility and hence more

Page 43: SSRN-id1105398

42

efficient prices. In addition, he documents that OTC securities exhibit positive abnormal returns

during the time period over which passage of the 1964 Amendments became likely.

In a concurrent study, Greenstone et al. (2006) also find positive abnormal stock returns

to firms affected by the 1964 Securities Acts Amendments. They differentiate between firms

that are more or less affected to properly identify the effect of the 1964 Amendments. They

document that OTC firms most affected by the imposition of SEC disclosure regulation

experience abnormal returns between 11-22% from the time the regulation was proposed to

when it went into force, and abnormal returns of about 3.5% in the weeks surrounding firms‟

announcements that they had first come into compliance. The authors attribute the positive

market reaction to reduced conflicts of interests between controlling insiders and outside

shareholders (Shleifer and Wolfenzon, 2002). Consistent with this explanation, Greenstone et al.

(2006) find that OTC firms experience an increase in operating performance relative to

unaffected firms. Moreover, Ferrell (2003) and Greenstone et al. (2006) show that there is no

difference in abnormal returns subsequent to when the regulation was passed and came into

effect, consistent with the notion that securities markets have fully priced the effect of regulation.

Improved stock price efficiency, as suggested by the evidence in Ferrell (2003), can be

socially beneficial if it results in an improvement in the allocation of capital. Similarly, a

reduction in agency costs associated with conflicts of interests between controlling insiders and

outside investors, as suggested by Greenstone et al. (2006), can be socially desirable if diversion

by insiders and outsider expropriation are inefficient and socially costly (e.g., Shleifer and

Wolfenzon 2002). However, at present, there is little empirical evidence on the link between

information, stock price efficiency and capital allocation (e.g., Durnev, Morck and Yeung, 2003;

Verdi, 2006). The inefficiency of expropriation and whether better institutions spur economic

Page 44: SSRN-id1105398

43

growth is also still debated (e.g., Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, 2001 and 2002; Glaeser, La

Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, 2004). Moreover, the overall welfare consequences of the

effects in Ferrell (2003) and Greenstone et al. (2006) are unknown because neither study can

determine the extent to which shareholders‟ gains resulted from wealth transfers from controlling

insiders or other stakeholders in these companies. Thus, more research on the aggregate

consequences of disclosure regulation is clearly warranted.

A recent study by Bushee and Leuz (2005) make a small step in this direction. Their

study exploits a regulatory act, the so called “Eligibility Rule,” in the previously unregulated

OTC Bulletin Board (OTCBB) in 1999. Prior to the Rule, smaller firms that were not subject to

1964 Securities Act Amendments could be quoted on the OTCBB without filing with the SEC.

The Rule eliminates this possibility and forces these firms to comply with the reporting

requirements under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. In analyzing firms that are subject to

the Rule and those that should be unaffected but are in the same market, the study is probably the

first to provide evidence on externalities from disclosure regulation. They find that OTCBB

firms that were already subject to SEC reporting obligations experience positive abnormal

returns around key announcements dates of the rule, as well as sustained increases in liquidity.

This evidence is consistent with the existence of positive externalities of disclosure regulation,

possibly due to liquidity spillovers or to an enhanced reputation of the OTCBB. However, this

interpretation hinges crucially on the extent to which firms outside the OTCBB are an

appropriate control group against which the externalities can be measured.

Illustrating that disclosure regulation has not only benefits, Bushee and Leuz (2005) find

that the imposition of SEC disclosure requirements forced over 2,600 firms (or 76% of the

market segment) into the less regulated Pink Sheets market, at significant costs in terms of

Page 45: SSRN-id1105398

44

market value and liquidity. This evidence suggests that, for the majority of (smaller) OTCBB

firms, the firm-specific costs of SEC disclosure regulation outweigh the benefits. Even firms

that were compelled to adopt SEC disclosures to avoid removal from the OTCBB exhibit

negative abnormal returns associated with the announcement of the rule change, suggesting that

the regulatory change is on balance costly to these firms, which is consistent with the fact that

the rule eliminated the prior (and presumably preferred) disclosure strategy of these firms.33

The existence of significant “crowding out” effects of disclosure regulation in Bushee

and Leuz (2005) is consistent with the earlier findings in Jarrell (1981) that firms shifted from

public offerings to private placements after the Securities and Exchange Acts. These findings

illustrate that it is important to consider the various ways in which firms can respond to the

imposition of regulation. For instance, firms can go private, move to an unregulated market, or

choose not to go public. Understanding firms‟ potential responses and avoidance strategies is

crucial when evaluating the costs and benefits of disclosure regulation and also when designing

the rules in the first place.

4.3. Studies on Recent Changes in U.S. Disclosure Regulation

Two recent changes in U.S. disclosure regulation, Regulation Fair Disclosure and the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act, have led to a flurry of regulatory studies. Regulation FD was adopted by

the SEC in October 2000 and was intended to increase confidence and fairness in capital markets

by prohibiting managers from selectively releasing material non-public information to market

professionals or institutional shareholders, but not to the public at large. Thus, Regulation FD

33

Nevertheless, these firms experience significant increases in liquidity upon compliance, consistent with earlier

findings in the literature that increases in the commitment to disclosure manifest in higher liquidity.

Page 46: SSRN-id1105398

45

may have changed the degree of information asymmetry between investors. At the same time, it

may have changed firms‟ incentives to provide information to the markets in the first place.

The evidence on Regulation FD is mixed, but most studies point the existence of costs

and benefits arising from the regulation. First, there is considerable evidence that information

production by financial analysts changed around Regulation FD. For instance, Gintschel and

Markov (2004) show a reduction in the price impact of information disseminated by analysts.

Gomes, Gorton and Madureira (2005) document a shift in analyst coverage from smaller to

larger firms. Bushee, Matsumoto and Miller (2004), Gintschel and Markov (2004), Eleswarapu,

Thompson and Venkataraman (2004) and Chiyachantana, Jiang, Taechapiroontong and Wood

(2004) document decreases in effective bid-ask spreads after Regulation FD, consistent with the

notion that information asymmetry decreases when selective disclosures are reduced. Similarly,

Bailey, Li, Mao and Zhong (2003) document that an increase in trading volume. But there is

also conflicting evidence by Straser (2002) and Sidhu, Smith, Whaley, and Willis (2008)

suggesting that the adverse selection component of the bid-ask spread has risen after Regulation

FD. Jorion, Liu and Shi (2005) also examine the impact on select intermediaries, namely credit

rating agencies who can still receive non-public information from companies and these

communications are exempt from Regulation FD. Therefore, credit rating agencies have access

to confidential information that is arguably not available to equity analysts after Regulation FD.

Jorion et al (2005) find that the market impact of announcements of credit rating changes is

larger in the post-FD period. This evidence is consistent with the notion that non-uniform

regulation can give a strategic advantage to the certain parties.

Second, there is also on shifts in firms‟ disclosure policies around Regulation FD. For

instance, Heflin, Subramanyam and Zhang (2003) and Bushee, Matsumoto and Miller (2004)

Page 47: SSRN-id1105398

46

provide evidence that firms‟ disclosures remain constant or even increase after Regulation FD.

On the other hand, Kothari, Shu and Wysocki (2007) find evidence consistent with Regulation

FD leveling the playing field with respect to good news and bad news disclosures and, on

average, firms have reduced their withholding of bad news (relative to good news) after the

passage of the new disclosure rules. Gomes et al. (2006) provide evidence that larger firms were

able to compensate the loss in analyst coverage via other information channels but that small

firms could not and as a result face a higher cost of capital. Duarte et al. (2007) also use the cost

of capital as a way to assess the net effects of Regulation FD with respect to information

asymmetry and information dissemination. They find no change in the cost of capital for AMEX

and NYSE firms and a small increase in the cost of capital for NASDAQ firms. In contrast,

Chen, Dhaliwal and Xie (2006) find that firms‟ implied cost of capital declines in the post-FD

period, the decrease in the cost of capital is mainly due to medium and large firms but is not

significant for small firms and that the decrease in the cost of capital is systematically related to

firm characteristics indicative of selective disclosure before Regulation FD.

Third, Francis, Nanda and Wang (2006) highlight the concern that studies on Regulation

FD may reflect concurrent changes in the U.S. information environment that are not related to

the regulation. To gauge this concern, they benchmark changes in public information metrics

(return volatility, informational efficiency and trading volume) and changes in analyst

information metrics (forecast dispersion and accuracy) against concurrent changes for foreign

firms that are cross-listed on U.S. markets but exempted from Regulation FD.34

The findings

suggest that Regulation FD did not uniquely affect the U.S. information environment, but that it

reduced information dissemination through the channel of analyst reports.

34

It should be noted that Gomes et al. (2006) and Chen et al. (2006) also benchmark their results against ADR firms.

Page 48: SSRN-id1105398

47

Finally, there is a recent series of papers evaluating the effects of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act

(henceforth SOX), which was passed in 2002 response to a series of corporate scandals. It is

probably the most sweeping change to U.S. securities regulation since the Securities and

Exchange Acts of 1933 and 1934. Romano (2004) argues that it also represents a significant

departure in the approach to securities regulation because SOX prescribes particular corporate

practices, rather than just the disclosure of these practices. This aspect sets SOX apart from the

regulatory changes that we have previously discussed and makes it a particularly interesting

object to study.

As with Regulation FD, the evidence is decidedly mixed. Jain et al. (2004) analyze

changes in market liquidity and document an improvement in liquidity measures following SOX.

Rezaee and Jain (2005) find positive abnormal stock price reactions to events that increased the

likelihood of the passage of SOX. Li et al. (2004) document positive abnormal returns to events

resolving the uncertainty regarding the contents of SOX regulations. In contrast, Zhang (2007)

finds negative cumulative abnormal returns to legislative events leading to the passage of SOX.

In examining abnormal returns around legislative events, the latter three studies attempt to shed

light on the net costs or benefits of SOX to firms or even the corporate sector.

However, a major difficulty in evaluating SOX is that it broadly applies to SEC-

registered firms and hence to the vast majority of publicly traded firms. As a result, it is difficult

to separate the effects of SOX from other contemporaneous events.35

For instance, foreign

equity markets experienced negative abnormal returns around key SOX events as well (e.g.,

Zhang, 2007), which casts serious doubt that the abnormal returns to legislative events can be

solely attributed to SOX.

35

For a discussion of this issue and examples of contemporaneous events, see Leuz (2007).

Page 49: SSRN-id1105398

48

Recognizing this issue, Berger et al. (2006) and Litvak (2006) assess the impact of SOX

on foreign firms that are cross-listed on U.S. exchanges, relative to U.S. firms and foreign firms,

respectively. Berger et al. (2006) find that the value-weighted portfolio of cross-listed foreign

firms has a significantly more negative stock price reaction to SOX than the value-weighted U.S.

market, suggesting that SOX has been costly to foreign firms. Similarly, Litvak (2006) finds that

foreign firms that are subject to SOX react more negatively than either matched cross-listed

foreign firms that are not subject to SOX or non-cross-listed foreign firms. Overall, these studies

suggest that SOX imposes net costs on foreign firms. However, it is an open question whether or

not we can extrapolate the findings for foreign firms to U.S. firms. For instance, it is

conceivable that foreign firms are affected more negatively by the Act if SOX compliance

creates contradictions with foreign governance regulation.

An alternative way to identify SOX effects is to exploit cross-sectional differences in the

way SOX affects firms. For instance, Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2007) provide evidence that

firms that have to make more changes to be compliant with the provisions of SOX earn positive

abnormal returns around key SOX events compared to firms that are less compliant. However,

this result holds only for large firms. Small firms that are less compliant earn negative abnormal

returns relative to firms that have to make fewer changes to be compliant, indicating that the

costs of SOX outweigh the benefits for smaller firms. The differential effect of SOX on large

and small firms is also exploited in Gao, Wu and Zimmerman (2007). They provide evidence on

the possible unintended consequences of SOX exemptions for small companies (i.e., firms with

public float less than $75 million). They predict and find evidence that the size-based

exemptions provide incentives for firms to remain small leading firms to take real actions that

inhibit firm growth, such as investment cuts.

Page 50: SSRN-id1105398

49

Hochberg et al. (2007) use lobbying behavior of corporate insiders as a way to identify

firms that are more likely to be affected by SOX. They demonstrate that firms whose insiders

lobbied against a strict SOX implementation experience significantly positive abnormal returns

over the passage of SOX, relative to firms that did not lobby (and hence are deemed less

affected). They interpret this result as evidence that SOX improves disclosure and governance of

lobbying firms and hence benefits outside shareholders. To support this interpretation, they

provide evidence that lobbying firms are not as well governed and more likely to consume more

private control benefits at the expense of outsiders. The advantage of using lobbying behavior is

that it relies on observable behavior that is directly related to SOX. However, we still need firm

characteristics (e.g., about governance) to aid the interpretation and preclude alternative

explanations. For instance, without corroborating evidence on the governance structure of

lobbying firms, it is possible that the documented return differential simply reflects that better

governed firms are better able to cope with costly regulation and also have more time to lobby.

Thus, the interpretation of cross-sectional differences in abnormal SOX returns hinges critically

on having convincing a priori predictions on how SOX has differentially affected firms.

At this point, the evidence on the net costs or benefits of SOX to firms is inconclusive.

An alternative approach to determine whether a regulatory act has been costly or beneficial to

firms is to examine their responses to the regulation. For instance, if SOX has been costly to

firms, we expect firms to engage in avoidance strategies. There are several papers that follow

this path. For instance, Engel, Hayes and Wang (2007) analyze firms‟ going-private decisions

around SOX as well as market responses to these decisions. They argue that firms can avoid the

costs associated with SOX by going private and that they will do so whenever the costs imposed

by SOX outweigh the benefits generated by SOX and the net benefit from being public prior to

Page 51: SSRN-id1105398

50

SOX. Engel et al. (2007) document an increase in Rule 13e-3 transactions after SOX. These

transactions allow firms to deregister their securities from the SEC and to go private. They also

show that the announcement returns to these transactions are positive and increase for smaller

firms after SOX. These results are consistent with the notion that the costs of SOX to firms have

increased the incidence of going private and that SOX has larger net costs for smaller firms..

However, as Leuz (2007) points out, the increase in going private activities is unlikely to be

attributable to SOX as there are similar going private trends in other countries around the world.

Moreover, Leuz, Triantis and Wang (2007) point out that there is a considerable number

of public companies that deregister their securities from the SEC, cease to make periodic filings

to the SEC, but continue to trade publicly in the Pink Sheets, which do not require SEC

registration. Leuz et al. (2007) show that these “going dark activities” account for the bulk of the

recent surge in SEC de-registrations after SOX and that going dark (but not going private) is

associated with SOX-related events. They also provide evidence that for many firms cost

savings are likely to be the primary reason for going dark, which in turn suggests that SOX

imposes substantial costs on firms, particularly smaller ones. However, as with the lobbying

evidence presented by Hochberg et al. (2007), the latter interpretation depends crucially on the

reason why firms exit the SEC disclosure system after the imposition of SOX. It is also possible

that firms go dark in order to avoid the additional scrutiny intended and imposed by SOX.

Consistent with this hypothesis, Leuz et al. (2007) provide evidence that, at least for some firms,

particularly when governance and investor protection are weak, controlling insiders appear to

take their firms dark to protect private control benefits and decrease outside scrutiny.

In a similar vein, Hostak, Karaoglu, Lys and Yang (2007) examine the extent to which

foreign firms de-list and deregister their ADRs from U.S. exchanges around the passage of SOX.

Page 52: SSRN-id1105398

51

Again, the motive could be the costs of complying with SOX or, alternatively, insiders‟ loss of

control rents due to the corporate governance mandates of SOX. Consistent with the going dark

findings in Leuz et al. (2007), the authors find that the passage of SOX coincides with an

increase in voluntary de-listings of foreign ADRs from US stock exchanges. They also present

evidence that is more consistent with the hypothesis that foreign firms with weaker corporate

governance delist to avoid complying with the corporate governance mandates of SOX than the

claim that direct compliance costs drive these decisions.

In sum, the empirical findings on the impact of both Regulation FD and SOX are often

mixed. However, most studies do point the existence of costs and benefits to firms as well as

losers and winners from these regulations. These recent studies on changes in U.S. reporting and

disclosure regulations have substantially increased our understanding of how to frame and test

the question “What are the economic consequences of regulatory changes?” But despite these

advances, it remains an unresolved question whether the market-wide (or macro-economic)

benefits of recent changes to reporting and disclosure regulations exceed their aggregate costs.

4.4. International Evidence on Costs and Benefits of Disclosure Regulation

The previous sub-sections summarize empirical studies that examine regulatory changes;

typically changes that occurred in the U.S. An alternative approach to studying the economic

consequences of regulation is to exploit cross-sectional variation, notably international

differences in disclosure and securities regulation, including firms‟ and investors‟ responses to

these differences.36

36

There are also studies that examine the effects of changes in countries‟ accounting rules, e.g., on firms‟ cost of

capital or market liquidity. We discuss these studies in Section 5.

Page 53: SSRN-id1105398

52

Glaeser, Johnson and Shleifer (2001) compare the regulation of financial markets and the

associated stock market development in Poland and the Czech Republic in the 1990s. They

exploit that securities laws and markets were designed from scratch after the two countries

emerged from socialism and point in particular to the role of enforcement and the incentives of

the enforcer. Consistent with this notion, Glaeser et al. (2001) find that strict enforcement of

securities law and a highly motivated regulator are associated with a rapidly developing stock

market in Poland. In the Czech Republic that took a more hands-off approach to regulation,

delistings and expropriation were rampant after an initial boom period.

La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer (2006) extend the analysis of securities regulation

and financial development to 45 countries. They create a dataset evaluating the strength of

countries‟ securities regulation and provide evidence that stricter and better enforced securities

regulation is associated with higher financial market development, as measured for example by

the size of a country‟s equity markets and IPO activity. Building on this dataset, Hail and Leuz

(2006) examine international differences in firms‟ cost of equity capital across 40 countries and

their association with the quality of countries‟ legal institutions and securities regulation. They

show that firms in countries with more extensive disclosure requirements, stronger securities

regulation and stricter enforcement mechanisms have a significantly lower cost of capital. They

also demonstrate that these cost of capital effects are much smaller for capital markets that are

globally more integrated. The latter finding is consistent with economic theory and suggests

capital market integration puts an upper bound on the cost of capital benefits from strong

disclosure regulation.

There are also a number of studies that analyze the joint outcomes of firm-level

disclosure choices and countries‟ institutional features. For instance, Chen, Chen and Wei

Page 54: SSRN-id1105398

53

(2003) find that both higher country-level investor protection and higher disclosure and corporate

governance ratings contribute to a lower cost of equity capital for Asian firms. However, their

findings also suggest that, in emerging markets, strengthening countries‟ investor protection and

corporate governance appears to be more important in reducing the cost of equity capital than

firms‟ expanding their disclosures. In contrast, Francis, Khurana and Pereira (2005) analyze the

link between disclosure and cost of capital for firms from 34 countries and find that more

disclosure is associated with a lower cost of capital but firms‟ voluntary disclosure choices

appear to operate independently of country-level regulations. Again combining firm-level

choices and country-level institutions, Eleswarapu and Venkataraman (2007) examine U.S.

ADRs from 44 countries and find that after controlling for firm-level determinants of trading

costs and home country market share, trading costs (i.e., effective spreads and price impact of

trades) are lower for stocks from countries with higher judicial efficiency, accounting standards,

and political stability.

There is also a growing literature on how firms cope with or overcome disadvantages

they face in their home markets due to regulatory, institutional, or other constraints that among

other things limit their ability to raise capital. For instance, many firms from emerging market

economies have sought cross listings in the U.S. and subjected themselves to U.S. securities

regulation. That is, firms can opt into a foreign regime and thereby bond themselves to the more

onerous disclosure, accounting and governance requirements and stricter enforcement regime of

another country, which is called the bonding hypothesis (Coffee, 1999; Stulz, 1999). The

problem is that firms in countries with weak institutional frameworks have difficulties in raising

external finance because controlling insiders in these environments cannot sufficiently assure

outside investors that they will not expropriate them. Outside investors react to this commitment

Page 55: SSRN-id1105398

54

problem with price protection, which increases the cost of raising capital. This problem matters

more to firms with growth opportunities that require outside finance and, consequently, these

firms have an incentive to seek bonding devices that sufficiently reassure outside investors.

Coffee (1999) and Stulz (1999) argue that U.S. cross listing makes it harder and more

costly for controlling owners and managers to extract private control benefits and to expropriate

outside investors. The idea is that U.S. securities laws afford stronger rights to outside investors

than those in most other countries and that these rights are more strictly enforced, either via the

SEC or private securities litigation. By cross listing in the U.S., foreign firms subject themselves

to these laws and their enforcement.37

U.S. cross listing also forces foreign firms to substantially

increase their disclosures (via Form 20-F), making it less costly for outsiders to monitor the

behavior of controlling insiders. Finally, cross listing may increase the attention by financial

analysts and monitoring by sophisticated U.S. capital market participants (e.g., pension funds

and institutional investors).

Consistent with the bonding hypothesis, recent empirical work by Reese and Weisbach

(2002), Lang, Lins and Miller (2003a), Lang, Raedy and Yetman (2003b), Doidge, Karolyi, and

Stulz, 2004, Bailey, Karolyi, and Salva (2006), and Hail and Leuz (2006) shows that foreign

firms with cross listings in the U.S. raise more external finance, have higher valuations, a lower

cost of capital, more analyst following and report higher quality accounting numbers than their

foreign counterparts.

Similar to the voluntary disclosure literature, cross-listing studies face the issue that firms

that choose to cross-list. As a result, firms with cross-listings may be fundamentally different

37

Examples are the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, Rule 10-b5, SEC enforcement actions and U.S.-style class action

suits.

Page 56: SSRN-id1105398

55

than their foreign counterparts in ways that are difficult to control or observe. In other words,

the documented differences in accounting quality, valuations of these firms and the cost of

capital could reflect observed heterogeneity, rather than the decision to cross list per se (e.g.,

Lang et al., 2003a; Doidge et al., 2004). In addition, there is little direct evidence on the sources

of the cross-listing effects. Thus, it is unclear which of the requirements associated with cross

listing on U.S. exchanges give rise to the documented effects (e.g., Leuz, 2003). Moreover, it

possible that market forces (rather than legal requirements) are responsible for improvements in

corporate transparency around U.S. cross listings. For instance, Siegel (2005) raises doubts

about the effectiveness of the U.S. legal system and SEC enforcement activities against foreign

firms listed on U.S. exchanges and points to reputational effects. However, it should be noted

the bonding hypothesis does not claim that all expropriation is deterred. It only maintains that

U.S. cross listings provide some additional reassurance to outside investors. The relevant

comparison is therefore either the same firm without a cross listing or similar firms in the same

country without cross listings. That said, market forces may be an important factor for the cross

listing effects that have been documented by prior work. In fact, it seems like that documented

cross-listing effects stem from a combination of legal and market forces (e.g., Leuz, 2006).

The cross-listing literature provides a number of insights on the potential costs and

benefits of stringent regulations. The results suggest that more demanding regulations and

standards can be beneficial to (certain) firms. On the other hand, countries with regulations that

are perceived too onerous and hence costly may fail to attract foreign firms. Such claims have

recently been made for cross listings on U.S. exchanges after the passage of SOX. Non-U.S.

firms are said to prefer cross listings on the London Stock Exchange. While recent research

disputes this claim (e.g., Doidge et al., 2007; Piotroski and Srinivasan, 2007), this discussion

Page 57: SSRN-id1105398

56

highlights that it can be important for regulators to consider the consequences of disclosure

regulation on firms‟ cross listing behavior and that stringent disclosure regulation can be a

double-edged sword. With the globalization of financial markets, firms have ever-increasing

options to respond to regulation in their home countries, to attract capital from foreign investors

as well as to “opt into” stricter foreign regulatory regimes.

Finally, there are recent studies that suggest that foreign investors seek out firms with

higher quality voluntary disclosures and invest more in countries with better disclosure

regulations. A number of international studies demonstrate that foreign firms with better

voluntary disclosures attract greater following by U.S. institutional investors (Bradshaw, Bushee,

and Miller, 2004) and mutual funds (Aggarwal, Klapper and Wysocki, 2005). Aggarwal et al.

(2005) find that reporting quality has investment effects that show up at both the firm and

country level and that there are important interactions between the firm-level and country-level

decisions.38

Leuz, Lins, and Warnock (2007) present evidence that firms with governance

problems attract significantly less foreign investment (using comprehensive portfolio data of U.S.

investors) and that the association between governance and U.S. investment is most pronounced

in countries with overall governance weaknesses and poor information flows. While these

studies suggest that firms are penalized by foreign investors for poor quality financial reporting,

the findings also suggest an important interplay among numerous factors such as corporate

governance, voluntary reporting choices, and disclosure rules and regulations.

38

For example, Aggarwal et al. (2005) find that firm-level voluntary disclosure effects are most pronounced for

firms that reside in jurisdictions with lower mandated disclosures.

Page 58: SSRN-id1105398

57

5. New Institutional Accounting Research and the Introduction of IFRS

A recent and important trend in financial reporting and disclosure regulation is the

increasingly widespread adoption of uniform financial reporting standards by stock exchanges

and accounting standards bodies from different countries. These uniform standards are labeled

International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) and their stated goal is to achieve global

“harmonization” and “convergence” of financial reporting rules and regulations. This section

reviews empirical studies on this major trend in financial reporting regulation. These studies

complement the empirical work on disclosure regulation. We also review studies on the relation

between reporting quality and countries‟ institutional features because this literature offers

important insights to the debate about the economic consequences of IFRS adoption.

5.1. Evidence on the Importance of Countries’ Institutional Features for Reporting Quality

International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) are accounting rules issued by the

International Accounting Standards Board (IASB). In contrast to local accounting rules

(domestic GAAP) that differ across markets and countries, IFRS are a set of uniform rules that,

in theory, apply in the same way to all public companies in markets that adopt the standards.

IFRS are principles-based reporting standards that attempt to cover a broad range of economic

conditions, transactions, activities or events. Over 100 countries have recently moved to IFRS

reporting or decided to require the use of these standards in the near future, and even the U.S. is

considering allowing U.S. firms to prepare their financial statements in accordance with IFRS.

While the overall impact of IFRS is still to be determined, promoters of IFRS often argue

that uniform global standards are obviously superior to disparate, and in many cases competing,

standards across markets. However, the optimality of a single set of mandated global financial

reporting rules, let alone the specific uniform rules contained in the current IFRS, is not obvious

Page 59: SSRN-id1105398

58

(e.g., Dye and Sunder, 2001). While mandatory uniform rules and regulations may provide

aggregate economic benefits, the individual and aggregate costs of uniform global regulations on

firms, investors, and other stakeholders are often not recognized nor discussed. In particular,

IFRS draw heavily on the current financial reporting regulations of countries and markets that

are geared toward outside capital providers. Moreover, these advanced countries have

institutional infrastructures that complement the type of reporting regulations that have

developed in these markets. Therefore, it is far from clear that IFRS will be superior or even

effective in countries that have different capital-market paradigms and lack the necessary

institutional infrastructures to support the effective application and enforcement of the uniform

global standards.

There is a growing body of evidence that countries‟ legal institutions are important

determinants of financial market development, firms‟ capital and ownership structures, dividend

policies, and insiders‟ private control benefits.39

Building on this work, recent international

accounting studies investigate the link between countries‟ institutional features and financial

reporting outcomes (e.g., reporting quality) as well as the market effects of these outcomes (e.g.,

with respect to the cost of capital). Specifically, Ball, Kothari, and Robin (2000), Hung (2001),

and Leuz, Nanda and Wysocki (2003) highlight that a country‟s legal and institutional

environment can affect firms‟ financial reporting incentives and hence influence the quality of

financial information reported to outside investors. Ball, Kothari, and Robin (2000) analyze

firms from seven countries that differ with respect to their governance models and the extent to

which they resolve information asymmetries via public disclosure or private communication.

They show that firms from common law countries exhibit more timely loss recognition,

39

See surveys by Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and La Porta et al (2000).

Page 60: SSRN-id1105398

59

consistent with the role of earnings in these economies. Leuz, Nanda and Wysocki (2003)

examine the level of earnings management and the opaqueness of accounting earnings reported

by firms from 31 countries. They show that both investor protection laws and the enforcement

of these laws are important determinant of reporting quality. More importantly, they show that

these investor protection effects persist even after controlling for a country‟s accounting rules. A

key message of these papers is that mandated accounting rules and regulations cannot be

considered in isolation and that these rules may have limited effectiveness without understanding

other economic and institutional factors that affect firms reporting incentives (see also Ball,

2001). The results in Ball, Robin, and Wu (2003) further reinforce this conclusion. Ball et al.

(2003) examine the properties of four Asian countries that have similar accounting standards as

other common law countries (i.e., U.S. or U.K.) but different economic and institutional

structures. They find that reported earnings from firms in Hong Kong, Malaysia, Singapore and

Thailand have properties similar to code law countries and are less timely than reported earnings

from U.S. or U.K. firms. Thus, despite the similarity of the accounting standards, the properties

of reported earnings are different and in line with institutional factors.40

The results of the aforementioned studies show that other institutional factors can limit

the effectiveness of the accounting standards, leading to lower quality financial reporting. One

such factor is a firm‟s ownership structure, which responds to a country‟s institutional

framework (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer, 1999; Claessens, Djankov, and Lang,

2000; Faccio and Lang, 2002; Denis and McConnell, 2003). Weak protection of minority

shareholders‟ rights combined with concentrated ownership appear to lead to significant

valuation discounts for firms (e.g., La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny, 2002;

40

Leuz (2003) provides the converse result by examining firms that are trading in Germany‟s New Market where

institutional factors and reporting incentives are largely held constant, but firms‟ accounting standards differ. We

review this paper in Section 5.

Page 61: SSRN-id1105398

60

Claessens, Djankov, Fan, and Lang, 2002; Lemmon and Lins, 2003). Recent research shows that

firms‟ ownership structures also shape insiders‟ reporting incentives and hence the quality of

observed financial reporting (e.g., Fan and Wong, 2001; Haw et al., 2004; Ball and Shivakumar,

2005; Burgstahler et al., 2006). These findings again highlight that isolated changes to

disclosure regulations and accounting standards may lead to unexpected or ineffective outcomes

if other important institutional arrangements such as firms‟ ownership structures are ignored.

Other factors that can affect the financial reporting properties and disclosure outcomes include

the enforcement activities of tax authorities and the development of the auditing profession. For

example, Guenther and Young (2000) and Haw et al. (2004) suggest that a strong tax

enforcement system within a country is associated with higher-quality reported accounting

numbers. On the other hand, it is unclear whether tax enforcement leads to financial reporting

outcomes, or whether other institutional factors lead to high-quality financial reporting which

then has the spillover benefit of greater observed tax compliance (Wysocki, 2003). Francis,

Khurana, and Pereira (2003) explore the impact of a developed private-sector auditing profession

on reporting outcomes. They find higher average financial reporting and disclosure quality in

countries with more developed auditing infrastructures and greater auditing enforcement.

The effective implementation of uniform reporting standards can also be limited by

political influences within a country which can lead to the misapplication of or exclusion from

reporting regulations for particular firms. Watts (1977) and Watts and Zimmerman (1986)

discuss the role of political lobbying in development and implementation of accounting rules.

Ball (2006) also discusses how political factors may specifically undermine the proper

enforcement of IFRS in certain countries. However, there is a paucity of research on the factors

that affect the likelihood and implementation of reporting and disclosure regulation in national or

Page 62: SSRN-id1105398

61

global capital markets. The forces (including political) that the affect the regulatory process are

important and largely unexplored issues in the literature that we discuss in section 6.

5.2 Recent Empirical Studies Examining the Economic Impact of IFRS Adoption

The development of uniform international accounting standards is a recent phenomenon

and the mandated use of IFRS is still in its infancy. For example, the European Union did not

mandate the use of IFRS for public European companies until 2005. As a result, there is still

relatively little data on the economic consequences arising from the mandate to use of IFRS.

Ball (2006) provides an overview of the issues surrounding the adoption of IFRS and identifies

several key issues that may limit the success and effectiveness of mandated IFRS. However,

many of these concepts have yet to be tested because mandated use of IFRS is so recent.

At present, there are only a few studies that analyze the economic consequences of the

introduction of mandatory IFRS reporting. Most studies examine firms‟ voluntary decisions to

provide financial reports that conform with “high quality” international accounting standards.

We provide an overview of both types of studies. Soderstrom and Sun (2007) also provide a

survey of studies that examines the link between IFRS adoption and the quality of firms‟

accounting numbers.

Empirical on the economic consequences of voluntary IFRS adoptions generally analyze

direct capital-market effects (such as liquidity or cost of equity capital) or the effects on various

market participants (such as the impact on analyst forecast properties or on the holdings of

institutional investors). Examples of studies that examine the capital-market effects of voluntary

IFRS adoptions include Leuz and Verrecchia, (2000), Barth et al. (2007), Karamanou and

Nishiotis, (2005), Cuijpers and Buijink (2005), Daske (2006), Hung and Subramanyam (2007),

and Daske, Hail, Leuz, and Verdi (2007a).

Page 63: SSRN-id1105398

62

Leuz and Verrecchia (2000) examine German firms that adopt IAS or U.S. GAAP and

find that IAS and U.S. GAAP firms exhibit lower bid-ask spreads, higher turnover, and decrease

in spreads and turnover around IAS or U.S. GAAP adoption (compared) to German GAAP firms.

Cuijpers and Buijink (2005) use implied cost of capital estimates and do not find significant

differences across local GAAP and IFRS firms in the EU. Daske (2006) examines voluntary IAS

adoption by German firms and finds that IFRS firms even exhibit a higher cost of equity capital

than local GAAP firms. Daske, Hail, Leuz, and Verdi (2007a) show that firms with a “serious”

commitment to adopting IRFS experience larger cost of capital and market liquidity benefits than

firms that are simply adopting IFRS as a “label.” Finally, Karamanou and Nishiotis (2005)

examine the short-window announcement returns to IFRS adoptions. However, the caveat to

these types of studies is that the short-window market reactions also capture news effects that are

potentially associated with the adoption of IFRS (e.g., information about growth opportunities).

Therefore, this type of research design may not be appropriate to isolate the effects of IFRS

reporting.

Focusing on reporting quality, Barth, Landsman and Lang (2007) analyze changes in the

properties of reported earnings around the voluntary adoption of IFRS reporting and present

evidence that firms‟ reporting quality increases. Hung and Subramanyam (2007) examine a

sample of German firms and test for the financial statement effects of adopting IAS between

1998 through 2002. They find that the no difference in the value relevance of accounting

numbers with IAS adoption, but there is weak evidence that IAS income exhibits greater

conditional conservatism than income reported under German GAAP.

There are also a few studies on the reaction of market participants to voluntary IFRS

adoptions. Cuijpers and Buijink (2005) find an increase in analyst following around IFRS, but

Page 64: SSRN-id1105398

63

the effect is not robust to controls for self selection. Covrig et al. (2007) document that foreign

mutual fund ownership is significantly higher for IFRS adopters compared to local GAAP firms

and that the difference in mutual fund holdings increases for firms in poor information

environments and with low visibility, suggesting that IFRS reporting can help firms attract

foreign institutional investment.

In sum, the evidence on voluntary IFRS adoptions is mixed. As discussed with respect to

the voluntary disclosure literature, a key challenge for these studies is the fact that firms choose

whether and when to adopt IFRS reporting. Therefore, it is difficult to attribute the observed

effects to IFRS reporting per se. Moreover, studies on a firm‟s voluntary financial reporting

decisions can tell us little about the aggregate impact of mandated IFRS.

Thus, we now turn to the few recent studies that examine the economic consequences of

the transition to mandatory IFRS reporting. Existing research studies on the transition to

mandatory IFRS reporting generally examine: (i) the stock market reactions to major events

before IFRS adoption that affect the likelihood that a jurisdiction (notably the European Union)

will adopt mandatory IFRS, or (ii) the observed capital market outcomes after the introduction of

mandatory IFRS in a jurisdiction.

Studies in the first category use stock market reactions (to events affecting the likelihood

of IFRS adoption) to infer whether the shareholders perceive net benefits or net costs to eventual

IFRS adoption. The empirical evidence in these studies is generally mixed. First, Comprix et al.

(2003) examine the stock returns of European firms on four major event dates in the year 2000

that arguably increased the likelihood that the EU would adopt mandatory reporting under IFRS.

They find average negative returns for European stocks on the four major event dates. However,

certain type of firms did experience significantly positive abnormal stock returns on certain event

Page 65: SSRN-id1105398

64

dates. In particular, positive stock returns are observed for firms that that are audited by a big

five auditor, those located in countries expected to have greater overall improvements in

reporting quality from IFRS adoption, and firms located in countries with higher legal levels of

enforcement. Second, Armstrong et al. (2007) examine the stock market reaction to 16 events

between 2002 and 2005 that affect the likelihood of IFRS adoption in the EU. Armstrong et al.

(2007) find a positive market reaction to events that increase the likelihood of IFRS adoption and

a negative market reaction to events that decrease the likelihood of IFRS adoption. The study

also finds that the stock market reaction is more positive for firms with lower quality pre-IFRS

information environments, with higher pre-IFRS information asymmetry, and for firms from

common law countries. Finally, Christensen et al. (2007a) examine the market reactions of U.K.

stocks to announcements of events related to mandatory IFRS reporting. They find that the

average U.K. market reaction is small. Using the degree of similarity with German voluntary

IFRS and U.S. GAAP adopters as a proxy for a U.K. firm‟s willingness to adopt IFRS, they find

that this proxy is positively (negatively) related to the stock price reaction to news events

increase ng (decreasing) the likelihood of mandatory IFRS reporting. They find a similar

association for changes in the implied cost of equity capital. The heterogeneity in the results

across firms is consistent with the reporting incentives view.

Studies in the second category analyze the post-adoption market effects of mandated

IFRS. For example, Platikanova (2007) examines measures of stock market liquidity for firms in

four European countries. While she finds heterogeneous changes in the liquidity measures for

the four countries after IFRS adoption, she does find that an overall decline the liquidity

differences across the countries after the IFRS adoption. Daske, Hail, Leuz and Verdi (2007b)

also examine the impact of IFRS adoption in 26 countries on market liquidity, cost of equity

Page 66: SSRN-id1105398

65

capital and Tobin‟s q. They find that, on average, market liquidity and equity valuations increase

around the introduction of mandatory IFRS in a country. However, these market benefits exist

only in countries with strict enforcement regimes and institutional environments that provide

strong reporting incentives. Interestingly, they also find that the capital market effects after

mandatory adoption are most pronounced for firms that first voluntarily switched to IFRS before

it was actually mandated. Finally, Christensen et al. (2007b) analyze whether IFRS

reconciliations provided with the last U.K. GAAP financial statements convey new information

to the markets.

Overall, the results are consistent with the view that reporting quality is shaped by

numerous factors in countries‟ institutional environments which points to the importance of

firms‟ reporting incentives and countries‟ enforcement regimes. As more data becomes available,

there will undoubtedly be a flood of empirical studies on the outcomes of the mandated adoption

of IFRS in countries around the world. At present, however, there is little evidence on the

important macro-economic outcomes of changes to mandated financial reporting rules.

6. Conclusions and Suggestions for Future Research

This article surveys the literature and highlights recent research advances that add to our

understanding of the economic consequences of financial reporting and disclosure regulation.

We provide an organizing framework that identifies the firm-specific (micro-level) and market-

wide (macro-level) costs and benefits of firms‟ reporting and disclosure activities and then use

this framework to discuss the potential costs and benefits of regulating these activities in various

forms recognizing the existence of global capital markets. Our framework synthesizes the key

insights from theoretical and empirical studies in accounting, economics, finance and law to

contribute to the cross-fertilization of ideas from these fields. We particularly highlight the

Page 67: SSRN-id1105398

66

interactions between accounting rules and disclosure requirements with other securities

regulations and institutional factors within a country and across markets.

Our survey illustrates a general paucity of evidence on market-wide and the aggregate

economic and social consequences of reporting and disclosure regulation, rather than the

consequences of individual firms‟ accounting and disclosure choices. Until recently, most of the

prior literature focuses on managers‟ voluntary disclosure and financial reporting choices, which

can provide important micro-economic insights that helps us understand the impact of regulation.

However, these studies provide few insights into the overall desirability, economic efficiency or

aggregate outcomes of reporting and disclosure regulation. Moreover, even the recent flurry of

studies on major regulatory changes in the U.S., notably Regulation Fair Disclosure and the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act, focus primarily on the economic consequences to firms, but provide little

evidence on aggregate or macro-economic effects, externalities or economic consequences to

investors or consumers.

The literature also exhibits a heavy emphasis on regulatory changes in the U.S. However,

there have also been major changes in reporting and disclosure regulation in other countries,

notably in emerging markets and transition economies. Researchers have not fully explored the

outcomes and implications of these numerous and major regulatory and enforcement changes in

other countries. Furthermore, the introduction of mandatory IFRS reporting around the world

provides a unique opportunity to test the impact of a uniform set of reporting rules in diverse

economic settings. Finally, areas where there are relatively unregulated markets (like the U.S.

OTC markets) offer interesting settings for future studies.

Despite the fact that our survey focuses on disclosure and reporting regulation, it does not

advocate the necessity of regulation or reforms to existing regulations. Instead, we synthesize

Page 68: SSRN-id1105398

67

the lessons from existing research to highlight the tradeoffs that standards setters, policy makers,

and regulators face in evaluating existing or proposed accounting rules and disclosure

requirements. We also suggest possible areas of future academic research that could inform

them about the economic consequences of financial reporting and disclosure regulation. To

conclude the survey, we discuss these suggestions next.

As we noted earlier, one finding of our survey is that much of the financial reporting and

disclosure literature has focused on managers‟ voluntary disclosure and financial reporting

choices. These studies are also frequently cited in the debate on reporting and disclosure

regulation. However, they provide few insights into the overall desirability, economic efficiency

or aggregate outcomes of reporting and disclosure regulation. Therefore, our suggestions for

future research focus on questions and unresolved issues related to the determinants and

aggregate outcomes of financial reporting and disclosure regulation.

Suggestions for Future Research

Our first suggestion is that we need to have a better understanding why disclosure and

reporting regulation is so pervasive in advanced economies. Standard economic theory and

much of the literature are skeptical about the need for and the benefits of regulation, except

perhaps in extreme cases of market failure. Contrasting this view is the observation that, in

successful financial markets and economies, firms‟ reporting and disclosure activities are often

heavily regulated. Do these markets thrive because of regulation or in spite of it? Opportunities

exist to understand this question and to address the apparent disconnect between standard

economics and actual regulatory practice.

Towards this end, one promising avenue for research is to explore whether standards and

regulation play a beneficial role by “stabilizing expectations” in financial markets, when

Page 69: SSRN-id1105398

68

contracts and information are incomplete and market participants are boundedly rational. For

example, reporting regulation may solve coordination problems among market participants by

providing a “coarse” standardized (or default) solution that is widely understood by both

suppliers and users of information and applied in many transactions and contracts.41

Financial

reporting rules and disclosure regulation in most advanced economies strike us as such a

“coarse” standardized solution.

In addition, financial reporting and disclosure regulation may stabilize financial markets

by limiting asset bubbles (i.e., periods when firms trade at prices that significantly deviate from

fundamental value). Financial bubbles can harm an economy by causing a significant

misallocation of capital. Therefore, during times of technological or financial innovation which

often coincide with financial bubbles, mandated reporting and disclosure rules can: (i) limit

asymmetric information among market participants, which can contribute to the formation of

bubbles (e.g., Brunnermeier, 2003), and (ii) force firms to talk about fundamentals such as

verifiable current cash flows, profits, net assets and ownership claims rather than firms‟

aspirations for future success. In other words, seemingly-dated reporting rules and disclosure

regulations can capture the cumulative wisdom (and wounds) from previous episodes of hype

and exuberance and provide a fundamentals-based reality check for the current generation of

market participants who are navigating seemingly “new” market conditions.42

At present, it is

41

See also the tradeoff between precision and shared understanding in the work on optimal communication by

Morris and Shin (2006). 42

For example, the Securities Acts of 1930‟s were enacted in reaction to the apparent asset bubble and subsequent

1929 market crash. The Securities Acts provided a basis for the SEC‟s ban on upward revaluations of assets reported

in firms‟ financial statements (Walker, 1992, and Watts, 2003). This “lower of cost or market” principle persists

today in U.S. accounting standards and arguably reinforces firms‟ incentives to report conservative financial

statements (Basu, 1997 and Watts, 2003).

Page 70: SSRN-id1105398

69

unclear whether and to what extent disclosure and reporting regulation mitigates asset bubbles

and financial crises. If it does, it could explain why regulation often follows financial crises.43

A countervailing concern is that existing regulations are inflexible and fail to adapt to

fast-changing and dynamic markets. Inflexible regulations can stifle financial innovation, which

in turn can affect whether new technologies and ideas are financed. Therefore, refinements to

the theory of disclosure regulation should capture the role and dynamic nature of markets for

ideas and capital. More generally, we note that the extant theory of disclosure regulation is

mostly static and concerned with the questions of whether and how to regulate. Thus, as a

second direction for new research, we propose more work on the dynamics of regulation. For

instance, there is little evidence on how the costs and benefits of disclosure regulation differ at

different stages of economic development and how the tradeoffs change as economies evolve.

The third (and closely related) research suggestion is to generate insights into the process

through which financial reporting and disclosure regulations are created and implemented.

Factors likely to influence the implementation process include within-country political forces

and market and political influences from outside a country. The traditional literature on the

economics of regulation (see, e.g., Stigler, 1971; Posner, 1974; Peltzman, 1976) provides

significant insights into issues related to special interests and regulatory capture. However, this

literature generally focuses on direct government regulation of product-market monopolists.

Disclosure requirements in turn are increasingly used as a public policy instrument in lieu of

more conventional and direct regulation that restricts or mandates certain behaviors or business

practices (e.g., Graham, 2002). Moreover, the markets for financial information are likely to be

substantially different from the product markets. However, there is little research on the factors

43

An obvious alternative explanation is that policy makers and regulators must be viewed as “acting” after financial

crises leading to ever increasing regulation.

Page 71: SSRN-id1105398

70

that affect the likelihood and implementation of reporting and disclosure regulation in national or

global capital markets. Early work by Watts (1977) and Watts and Zimmerman (1978 and 1986)

provide useful insights into the political factors that influence adoption of financial reporting and

disclosure rules and regulations. However, there has been little follow-on research on these

adoption issues.44

Interestingly, there is essentially no research how political intervention affects

the implementation of reporting and disclosure regulation. Ball (2006) hypothesizes that

political intervention may undermine the uniform is implementation of IRFS, but this conjecture

is yet to be tested.

The fourth direction suggests opportunities for more research on the real and macro-

economic outcomes of regulation. This research would go beyond capital market effects and

address the real investment, consumption and possibly social outcomes of regulation in an

economy. For example, does the existence of regulation (or lack therefore) affect the type,

timing and amount of total real investment by companies? Is there a link between transparency

of the corporate sector and economic growth? Does mandated disclosure of financial

information by companies feed back into the aggregate consumption decisions of consumers?

Does disclosure regulation directly affect allocation outcomes and influence who are the winners

and losers in the economy? Research into these matters could capitalize on recent regulatory

changes. For example, mandatory adoption of IFRS in many countries around the world could

provide insights into aggregate changes in disclosure quality and possible aggregate capital

market, investment and consumption effects. Moreover, there is wide variation in the types of

firms, the providers of capital, and institutional arrangements across countries that recently

adopted IFRS. Future research can also capitalize on this heterogeneity in firms, investors and

44

A few exceptions are Francis (1987), McLeay, Ordelheide and Young (2000), McLeay and Merkl (2004), and

Ramanna (2007).

Page 72: SSRN-id1105398

71

institutions to help us better understand the differential impact of uniform standards on different

stakeholders in different environments. However, it must be noted that the adoption of IFRS in

many countries is neither exogenous nor unexpected. Firms, investors and consumers can

anticipate the required implementation of IFRS, which may confound attempts to draw direct

inferences in this setting. Other recent regulatory changes, e.g., the market reforms in emerging

markets, may provide further opportunities. There is also an extensive literature on financial

liberalization and economic growth (Levine, 2001). However, in this literature, the role of

transparency and disclosure regulation is still largely unexplored.

As a fifth direction for future research, we suggest studies to better understand the

interactions among elements of the institutional infrastructure within an economy, including

both free-market forces and regulation. As an example, there can be complementarities between

various elements of a country‟s institutional structure. For instance, outside investor protection

and public disclosure are likely to be complements in promoting arm‟s length financing

arrangements. Similarly, rules typically need complementary enforcement to be effective. Such

complementarities imply that changing one element of the institutional structure independently

of the other elements is unlikely to yield desired outcomes and hence the desirability of

disclosure regulation should not be studied in isolation.45

Complementarities also imply that

countries‟ institutional systems exhibit path dependence, which in turn suggests a role for

historical analyses (e.g., Bebchuk and Roe, 1999; Schmidt and Spindler, 2002). At present,

however, we have relatively little research into the existence and nature of these institutional

interactions. For example, Leuz, Nanda and Wysocki (2003) provide (descriptive) evidence on

45

In the international accounting debate, the notion of complementarities implies that simply introducing IFRS

without supporting changes in countries‟ institutional infrastructures is unlikely to improve reporting quality (Ball,

2001).

Page 73: SSRN-id1105398

72

the existence of institutional clusters and then show that these clusters can explain cross-

sectional differences in reporting quality across countries.

Another example for interactions among institutional elements is the possibility that

seemingly innocuous regulation can interact with existing agency problems leading to

“surprisingly” undesirable outcomes.46

For example, Coates (2007) argues that the introduction

of SOX in the U.S. may have interacted with the litigation concerns of managers, directors and

auditors, which motivated these parties to over-invest in SOX compliance and internal controls,

making the regulation much more costly than expected.

Our sixth suggestion for future research highlights the need for more research on the

optimal form of regulation given imperfect enforcement, especially with respect to the balance

between ex ante regulation to discourage malfeasance versus ex post enforcement to penalize

malfeasance. Recent work by Glaeser, Johnson and Shleifer (2001) and Djankov, Glaeser, La

Porta, Lopes-de-Silanes and Shleifer (2003) suggests important interactions and tradeoffs

between the costs and benefits of an ex ante approach where regulation and standards attempt

level the playing field for market participants versus an ex post approach where the terms and

outcomes for loss recovery (often through the courts) must be specified. For example, if ex ante

regulation fails to specify all contingencies or capture innovations in malfeasance, then parties

must often rely on the courts to argue the existence and extent of injuries and penalties. On the

other hand, if there are inequalities in the judicial weapons available to litigants or there are

agency problems in the court, then regulations can serve to limit the latitude and discretion of the

court. As Shleifer (2005) points out as well, there is little research on this central issue of

regulation. Furthermore, it is far from clear that the same mix of regulation and enforcement

46

This notion can be viewed as a manifestation of the “theory of the second best” (Lipsey and Lancaster, 1956).

Page 74: SSRN-id1105398

73

should apply in economies with different existing institutional infrastructures or at different

economic stages of economic development. Therefore, there are many opportunities to examine

the optimal form and implementation of regulation and enforcement across markets and

countries.

Our seventh and final suggestion calls for future research to understand the interactions

among and competition between various markets and regulatory regimes in a global economy.

Firms, investors and policy makers in a given market cannot make decisions in isolation without

considering the actions and reactions of other players in global and at least partially integrated

markets. For example, changes to U.S. GAAP and SEC disclosure rules cannot be contemplated

without factoring in the existence of competing IFRS in other markets. Is competition in

regulatory regimes (e.g., accounting standards) a wasteful duplication of resources or does it

provide choices for firms and investors, which in turn lead to experimentation and learning? Is it

a competitive regulatory race to the top or a race to the bottom? There are arguments in both

directions for both questions (e.g., Barth, Clinch and Shibano, 1999; Dye and Sunder, 2001;

Coffee, 2002), but very little empirical evidence on these matters. Moreover, even if IFRS are

adopted by all markets and countries, competition is likely to grow across exchanges and

countries along other dimensions: (i) the implementation guidance and interpretation of the board

principles-based standards contained in IFRS, (ii) other disclosure requirement outside of

mandated financial reports, and (iii) the enforcement of financial reporting standards. Thus,

issue of competition across markets and regimes is likely to remain an important topic in the area

of reporting and disclosure regulation.

Page 75: SSRN-id1105398

74

7. References

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative

Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 91, 1369-1401.

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, 2002. Reversal of Fortune: Geography and

Development in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution. Quarterly Journal of

Economics 117, 1231-1294.

Admati, A., and P. Pfleiderer, 2000. Forcing Firms to Talk: Financial Disclosure Regulation and

Externalities. Review of Financial Studies 13, 479-515.

Aggarwal, R., L. Klapper and P. Wysocki, 2005. Portfolio Preferences of Foreign Institutional

Investors. Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 2919-2946.

Aghion, P. and B. Hermalin, 1990. Legal Restrictions on Private Contracts Can Enhance

Efficiency. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 6, 381-409.

Akerlof, G., 1970. The Market for “Lemons:” Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.

Quarterly Journal of Economics 84, 488-500.

Amihud, Y. and H. Mendelson, 1986. The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk and

Size on Stock Returns. Journal of Finance, 479-486.

Amihud, Y., H. Mendelson, and L. Pedersen, 2005. Liquidity and Asset Pricing. Foundation and

Trends in Finance 1, 269–364.

Anand, A., F. Milne, and L. Purda, 2006. Voluntary vs. Mandatory Corporate Disclosure.

Queen‟s University Working Paper.

Armstrong, C., M.E. Barth, A. Jagolinzer, and E.J. Riedl, 2007. Market Reaction to Events

Surrounding the Adoption of IFRS in Europe. Harvard Business School Working Paper.

Bailey, W., G.A. Karolyi, G.A., and C. Salva, 2006. The Economic Consequences of Increased

Disclosure: Evidence from International Cross-Listings. Journal of Financial Economics 81,

175-213.

Bailey W., H. Li, C. Mao and R. Zhong, 2003. Regulation Fair Disclosure and Earnings

Information: Market, Analyst, and Corporate Responses. Journal of Finance 58, 2487-2514.

Baiman, S., and R. Verrecchia, 1996. The Relation among Capital Markets, Financial Disclosure,

Production Efficiency, and Insider Trading. Journal of Accounting Research, 1-22.

Ball, R., 2001, Infrastructure Requirements of an Economically Efficient System of Public

Financial Reporting and Disclosure. Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, 127-

169.

Ball, R., 2006. International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS): Pros and Cons for Investors.

Accounting and Business Research: International Accounting Policy Forum, 5-27.

Ball, R., S. P. Kothari, and A. Robin, 2000. The Effect of International Institutional Factors on

Properties of Accounting Earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 29, 1-51.

Ball, R., A. Robin, and J. Wu, 2003. Incentives Versus Standards: Properties of Accounting

Income in Four East Asian Countries. Journal of Accounting and Economics 36, 235-270.

Page 76: SSRN-id1105398

75

Ball, R., and L. Shivakumar, 2005. Earnings Quality in U.K. Private Firms: Comparative Loss

Recognition Timeliness. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39, 83–128.

Basu, S., 1997. The Conservatism Principle and the Asymmetric Timeliness of Earnings. Journal

of Accounting and Economics 24, 3-37.

Barry, C., and S. Brown, 1984. Differential Information and the Small Firm Effect. Journal of

Financial Economics 13, 283-294.

Barry, C., and S. Brown, 1985. Differential Information and Security Market Equilibrium.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 20, 407-422.

Barth, M., W. Beaver, and W. Landsman, 2001. The Relevance of Value Relevance Research for

Accounting Policy Makers: Another View. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31, 77-

104.

Barth, M., G. Clinch, and T. Shibano, 1999. International Accounting Harmonization and Global

Equity Markets. Journal of Accounting and Economics 26, 201-235.

Barth, M., W. Landsman, and M. Lang, 2007. International Accounting Standards and

Accounting Quality. Journal of Accounting Research, Forthcoming.

Bebchuk, L., A. Cohen, and A. Ferrell, 2004. What Matters in Corporate Governance, Harvard

University Working Paper.

Bebchuk, L., and M. Roe, 1999. A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate Ownership and

Governance. Stanford Law Review 52, 127-170.

Benston, G., 1969. The Value of SEC's Accounting Disclosure Requirements. The Accounting

Review 54, 515-532.

Benston, G., 1973. Required Disclosure and the Stock Market: An Evaluation of the Securities

Exchange Act of 1934. The American Economic Review 63, 132-155.

Berger, P., and R. Hann, 2003. The Impact of SFAS 131 on Information and Monitoring. Journal

of Accounting Research 41, 163-223.

Berger, P., F. Li, and M. Wong, 2006. The Impact of Sarbanes-Oxley on Cross-listed

Companies. University of Chicago Working Paper.

Bhattacharya, U., H. Daouk, and M. Welker, 2003. The World Price of Earnings Opacity.

Accounting Review 78, 641-678.

Botosan, C., 1997. Disclosure Level and the Cost of Equity Capital. The Accounting Review 72,

323-349.

Botosan, C., 2006. Disclosure and Cost of Equity Capital: What Do We Know? Accounting and

Business Research: International Accounting Policy Forum.

Botosan, C., and M. Plumlee, 2002. A Re-Examination of Disclosure Level and the Expected

Cost of Equity Capital. Journal of Accounting Research 40, 21-40.

Bradshaw, M., B. Bushee, and G. Miller, 2004. Accounting Choice, Home Bias, and U.S.

Investment in Non-U.S. Firms. Journal of Accounting Research 42, 795-841.

Brown, S., 1979. The Effect of Estimation Risk on Capital Market Equilibrium. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15, 215-220.

Page 77: SSRN-id1105398

76

Brown, S., K. Lo, and S. Hillegeist, 2004. Conference Calls and Information Asymmetry.

Journal of Accounting and Economics 37, 343-366.

Brunnermeier, M., 2003. Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information - Bubbles, Crashes,

Technical Analysis and Herding. Oxford University Press.

Burgstahler, D., and I. Dichev, 1997. Earnings Management to Avoid Earnings Decreases and

Losses. Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, 99-126.

Burgstahler, D. C., L. Hail, and C. Leuz, 2006. The Importance of Reporting Incentives:

Earnings Management in European Private and Public Firms. The Accounting Review 81,

983–1017.

Burkhart, M., D. Gromb, and F. Panunzi, 1998. Why Higher Takeover Premia Protect Minority

Shareholders. Journal of Political Economy 106, 172-204.

Bushee, B., and C. Leuz, 2005. Economic Consequences of SEC Disclosure Regulation:

Evidence from the OTC Bulletin Board. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39, 233-264.

Bushee, B., and C. Noe, 2000. Corporate Disclosure Practices, Institutional Investors, and Stock

Return Volatility. Journal of Accounting Research 38, 171-202.

Bushee, B., D. Matsumoto, and G. Miller, 2003. Open versus Closed Conference Calls: The

Determinants and Effects of Broadening Access to Disclosure. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 34, 149-180.

Bushee, B., D. Matsumoto, and G. Miller, 2004. Managerial and Investor Responses to

Disclosure Regulation: The Case of Reg FD and Conference Calls. The Accounting Review

79, 617-643

Bushman, R., and J. Piotroski, 2006. Financial Reporting Incentives for Conservative

Accounting: The Influence of Legal and Political Institutions. Journal of Accounting and

Economic 42, 107-148.

Bushman, R., J. Piotroski, and A. Smith, 2004. What Determines Corporate Transparency?

Journal of Accounting Research 42, 207-252.

Bushman, R., J. Piotroski, and A. Smith, 2006. Capital Allocation and Timely Accounting

Recognition of Economic Losses. University of Chicago Working Paper.

Chhaochharia, V., and Y. Grinstein, 2007. Corporate Governance and Firm Value: The Impact of

the 2002 Governance Rules. Journal of Finance 62, 1789-1825.

Chemmanur, T., and P. Fulghieri, 2006. Competition and Cooperation among Exchanges: A

Theory of Cross-Listing and Endogenous Listing Standards. Journal of Financial Economics

82, 455-489.

Chen, K., Z. Chen, and K. Wei, 2003. Disclosure, Corporate Governance, and the Cost of Equity

Capital: Evidence from Asia's Emerging Markets. HKUST Working Paper.

Chow, C., 1983. The Impacts of Accounting Regulation on Bondholder and Shareholder Wealth:

The Case of the Securities Acts. Accounting Review 58, 485-520.

Chiyachantana, C., N. Taechapiroontong, C. Jiang, and R. Wood. 2004. The Impact of

Regulation Fair Disclosure on Information Asymmetry and Trading: An Intraday Analysis.

The Financial Review 39, 549-577.

Page 78: SSRN-id1105398

77

Christensen, H., E. Lee, and M. Walker, 2007a, Cross-sectional Variation in the Economic

Consequences of International Accounting Harmonisation: The Case of Mandatory IFRS

Adoption in the UK. The International Journal of Accounting, Forthcoming.

Christensen, H., E. Lee, and M. Walker, 2007b, Do IFRS/UK-GAAP reconciliations convey new

information? Manchester Business School Working Paper.

Claessens, S., S. Djankov, and L. Lang, 2000. The Separation of Ownership and Control in East

Asian Corporations. Journal of Financial Economics 58, 81-112.

Claessens, S., S. Djankov, J. Fan, and L. Lang. 2002, Disentangling the Incentive and

Entrenchment Effects of Large Shareholdings. Journal of Finance, 57, 2741-2771.

Clarkson, P., J. Guedes, and R. Thompson, 1996. On the Diversification, Observability and

Measurement of Estimation Risk. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, 69-

84.Coase, 1960.

Coates, J., 2007. The Goals and Promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Journal of Economic

Perspectives 21, 91-116.

Coffee, J., 1984. Market Failure and the Economic Case for a Mandatory Disclosure System.

Virginia Law Review 70, 717-753.

Coffee, J., 1999. The Future as History: The Prospects for Global Convergence in Corporate

Governance and Its Implications. Northwestern University Law Review, 641-708.

Coles, J., 1988. Equilibrium Pricing and Portfolio Composition in the Presence of Uncertain

Parameters and Estimation Risk. Journal of Financial Economics 22, 279-303.

TColes, J., U. Loewenstein, J. Suay, 1995. On Equilibrium Pricing Under Parameter Uncertainty.

The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 30, 347-374.

CCCollins, D., E. Maydew, and I. Weiss, 1997. Changes in the Value-Relevance of Earnings and

Equity Book Values over the Past Forty Years. Journal of Accounting and Economics 24,

39–67.

Comprix, J., K. Muller, and M. Stanford-Harris, 2003. Economic Consequences from Mandatory

Adoption of IASB Standards in the European Union. Penn State University Working Paper.

Constantinides, G., 1986. Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs. Journal of

Political Economy 94, 842-862.

Core, J., 2001. A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature: Discussion, Journal of

Accounting and Economics 31, 441-456.

Core, J., W. Guay, and R. Verdi, 2007. Is Accruals Quality Priced as a Factor? Journal of

Accounting and Economics, Forthcoming.

Covrig, V., M. DeFond, and M. Hung, 2007. Home Bias, Foreign Mutual Fund Holdings, and

the Voluntary Adoption of International Accounting Standards. Journal of Accounting

Research 45, 41–70.

Cuijpers, R., and W. Buijink, 2005. Voluntary Adoption of Non-Local GAAP in the European

Union: A Study of Determinants and Consequences. European Accounting Review 14, 487–

524.

Page 79: SSRN-id1105398

78

Daines, R., and C. Jones, 2005. Mandatory Disclosure, Asymmetric Information and Liquidity:

The Impact of the 1934 Act. Columbia University Working Paper.

Daske, H., 2006. Economic Benefits of Adopting IFRS or US-GAAP – Have the Expected Costs

of Equity Capital Really Decreased? Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 33, 329–

373.

Daske, H., and G. Gebhardt. 2006. International Financial Reporting Standards and Experts‟

Perceptions of Disclosure Quality. Abacus 42, 461–498.

Daske, H., L. Hail, C. Leuz, and R. Verdi, 2007a. Adopting a Label: Heterogeneity in the

Economic Consequences of IFRS Adoptions. University of Chicago Working Paper.

Daske, H., L. Hail, C. Leuz, and R. Verdi, 2007b. Mandatory IFRS Reporting Around the World:

Early Evidence on the Economic Consequences. University of Chicago Working Paper.

Dechow, P., and I. Dichev, 2002. The Quality of Accruals and Earnings: The Role of Accrual

Estimation Errors. The Accounting Review 77 (Supplement), 35-59.

Dechow, P., and C. Schrand, 2004. Earnings Quality. Monograph of the Research Foundation of

CFA Institute, Charlottesville, Virginia.

Dechow, P. and D. Skinner, 2000. Earnings Management: Reconciling the Views of Accounting

Academics, Practitioners, and Regulators. Accounting Horizons (June): 235-250.

Denis, D., and J. McConnell, 2003. International Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial

and Quantitative Analysis 38, 1-36.

Dhaliwal, D., Z. Chen, and H. Xie, 2006. Regulation Fair Disclosure and the Cost of Equity

Capital. University of Arizona Working Paper.

Diamond, D., and R. Verrecchia, 1991. Disclosure, Liquidity, and the Cost of Capital. Journal of

Finance 46, 1325-1359.

Diamond, D., 1985. Optimal Release of Information by Firms. Journal of Finance 40, 1071-

1094.

Djankov, S., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer, 2003. Courts. Quarterly Journal

of Economics 118, 453-517.

Doidge, C., A. Karolyi, K. Lins, D. Miller, and R. Stulz, 2005. Private Benefits of Control,

Ownership, and the Cross-Listing Decision. NBER Working Paper Number 11162.

Doidge, C., G. Karolyi, and R. Stulz, 2007. Has New York Become Less competitive in Global

Markets? Evaluating Foreign Listing Choices over Time. Ohio State University Working

Paper.

Doidge, C., A. Karolyi, and R. Stulz, 2004. Why Are Foreign Firms Listed in the U.S. Worth

More? Journal of Financial Economics 71, 205-238.

Durnev, A. and C. Mangen, 2007. Erroneous Accounting and the Efficiency of Industry

Investment. McGill University Working Paper.

Durnev, A., R. Morck, and B. Yeung. 2003. Value Enhancing Capital Budgeting and Firm-

Specific Stock Returns Variation. Journal of Finance 59, 65-106

Page 80: SSRN-id1105398

79

Dye, R., 1990. Mandatory Versus Voluntary Disclosures: The Cases of Financial and Real

Externalities. The Accounting Review 65, 1-24.

Dye, R., and S. Sunder, 2001. Why Not Allow FASB and IASB Standards to Compete in the

U.S.? Accounting Horizons 15, 257-272.

Easley, D., S. Hvidkjaer, and M. O'Hara, 2002. Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset

Returns? Journal of Finance 57, 2185-2221.

Easley, D., and M. O'Hara, 2004. Information and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Finance 59,

1553-1583.

Easterbrook, F., and D. Fischel, 1984. Mandatory Disclosure and the Protection of Investors.

Virginia Law Review 70, 669-715.

Easton, P., 2008. Estimating the Cost of Capital Implied by Market Prices and Accounting Data.

University of Notre Dame Manuscript.

Ecker, F., J. Francis, I. Kim, P. Olsson, and K. Schipper, 2006. A Returns-Based Representation

of Earnings Quality, The Accounting Review. The Accounting Review 81, 749-780.

Eleswarapu, V., R. Thompson, and K. Venkataraman, 2004. The Impact of Regulation Fair

Disclosure: Trading Costs and Information Asymmetry. Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis 39, 209-225.

Eleswarapu, V., and K. Venkataraman, 2007. The Impact of Legal and Political Institutions on

Equity Trading Costs: A Cross-Country Analysis. Review of Financial Studies 19, 1081-

1111.

Elton, E. 1999. Expected Return, Realized Return, and Asset Pricing Tests. Journal of Finance

54, 1199-1220.

Engel, E., R. Hayes, and X. Wang, 2007. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and Firms‟ Going-Private

Decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, Forthcoming.

Faccio, M., and L. Lang, 2002. The Ultimate Ownership of Western European Corporations.

Journal of Financial Economics 65, 365-395.

Fan, J., T. Wong, 2001. Corporate Ownership Structure and the Informativeness of Accounting

Earnings in East Asia. Journal of Accounting and Economics 33, 401-426.

Feltham, G., F. Gigler, and J. Hughes, 1992. The Effects of Line-of-Business Reporting on

Competition in Oligopoly Settings. Contemporary Accounting Research 9, 1-23.

Ferrell, A., 2003. Mandated Disclosure and Stock Returns: Evidence from the Over-The-Counter

Market. Harvard Law School Working Paper.

Ferrell, A., 2004. The Case for Mandatory Disclosure in Securities Regulation Around the

World. Harvard Law School Working Paper.

Field, L., M. Lowry, and S. Shu, 2005. Does Disclosure Deter or Trigger Litigation? Journal of

Accounting and Economics 39, 487-507.

Fields, T., Lys, T., Vincent, L., 2001. Empirical Research on Accounting Choice. Journal of

Accounting and Economics 31, 255-308.

Page 81: SSRN-id1105398

80

Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1980. Qualitative Characteristics of Accounting

Information. Statement of Financial Accounting Concepts No. 2. FASB, Stamford, CT.

Fishman, M., and K. Hagerty, 1989. Disclosure Decisions by Firms and the Competition for

Price Efficiency. Journal of Finance 44, 633-646.

Foster, G. 1981. Intra-Industry Information Transfers Associated with Earnings Releases. Journal

of Accounting and Economics 3, 201-232.

Fox, M., 1999. Retaining Mandatory Securities Disclosure: Why Issuer Choice is Not Investor

Empowerment. Virginia Law Review 85, 1335-1419.

Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P., and Schipper, K., 2004. Costs of Equity and Earnings

Attributes. The Accounting Review 79, 967-1010.

Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P., and Schipper, K., 2005. The Market Pricing of Accruals

Quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39, 295-327.

Francis, J., Nanda, D., and Olsson, P., 2005. Voluntary Disclosure, Information Quality, and

Costs of Capital. Duke University Working Paper.

Francis, J. R., 1987. Lobbying against Proposed Accounting Standards: The Case of Employer‟s

Pension Accounting. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6, 35-57.

Francis, J., I. Khurana, and R. Pereira, 2003. The Role of Accounting and Auditing in Corporate

Governance and the Development of Financial Markets around the World. Asia-Pacific

Journal of Accounting and Economics 10, 1-30.

Francis, J. R., I. Khurana, and R, Pereira, 2005. Disclosure Incentives and Effects on Cost of

Capital around the World. The Accounting Review 80, 1125-1162.

Francis, J., and K. Schipper, 1999. Have Financial Statements Lost their Relevance? Journal of

Accounting Research 37, 319-352.

Frankel, R., M. McNichols, and G. P. Wilson, 1995. Discretionary Disclosure and External

Financing. The Accounting Review 70, 135-150.

Frankel, R., M. Johnson, and D. Skinner, 1999. An Empirical Examination of Conference Calls

as a Voluntary Disclosure Medium. Journal of Accounting Research 37, 133-150.

Friend, I., and E. Herman, 1964. The SEC Through a Glass Darkly. Journal of Business 37, 382-

401.

Gal-Or, E., 1985. Information Sharing in Oligopoly. Econometrica, 329-343.

Gal-Or, E., 1986. Information Transmission - Cournot vs. Bertrand. Review of Economic

Studies, 85-92.

Gao, F., J. Wu, and J. Zimmerman, 2007. Unintended Consequences of Granting Small Firms

Exemptions from Securities Regulation: Evidence from the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. University

of Rochester Working Paper.

Garleanu, N., and L. Pedersen, 2004, Adverse Selection and the Required Return. Review of

Financial Studies 17, 643-665.

Gintschel, A., and S. Markov, 2004. The Effectiveness of Regulation FD. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 37, pp. 293–314.

Page 82: SSRN-id1105398

81

Glaeser, E., S. Johnson, and A. Shleifer, 2001. Coase vs. the Coasians. Quarterly Journal of

Economics 116, 853-899.

Glaeser, E., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, 2004. Do Institutions Cause Growth?

Journal of Economic Growth 9, 271-303.

Glaeser, E., and A. Shleifer. 2003. The Rise of the Regulatory State. Journal of Economic

Literature 41, 401-425.

Gleason, C., N. Jenkins, and W. Johnson, 2004. Financial Statement Credibility: The Contagion

Effect of Accounting Restatements. University of Iowa Working Paper.

Glosten, L., and P. Milgrom, 1985. Bid, Ask and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market with

Heterogeneously Informed Traders, Journal of Financial Economics 14, 71-100.

Gonedes, N., N. Dopuch, and S. Penman, 1976. Disclosure Rules, Information Production, and

Capital Market Equilibrium: The Case of Forecast Disclosure Rules, Journal of Accounting

Research (Spring), 89-137.

Gomes, A., G. Gorton, and L. Madureira, 2004. SEC Regulation Fair Disclosure, Information,

and the Cost of Capital. NBER Working Paper No. 10567.

Graham, M., 2002. Democracy by Disclosure. Governance Institute, Brookings Institution Press,

Washington, D.C.

Graham, J., C. Harvey, and S. Rajgopal, 2005. The Economic Implications of Corporate

Financial Reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 40, 3-73.

Greenstone, M., P. Oyer, and A. Vissing-Jorgensen, 2006. Mandated Disclosure, Stock Returns,

and the 1964 Securities Acts Amendments. Quarterly Journal of Economics 1221, 399-460.

Grossman, S., 1977. The Existence of Futures Markets, Noisy Rational Expectations and

Informational Externalities. Review of Economic Studies 44, 431-449.

Grossman, S. J., and O. D. Hart, 1980. Disclosure Laws and Takeover Bids, Journal of Finance

35, 323-334.

Grossman, S. and J. Stiglitz, 1980. On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets.

American Economic Review 70, 393-408.

Grossman, S., 1981. The Informational Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product

Quality. Journal of Law and Economics 24, 461-483.

Guenther, D., and D. Young, 2000. The Association between Financial Accounting Measures

and Real Economic Activity: A Multinational Study. Journal of Accounting & Economics

29, 53-72.

Hail, L., 2003. The Impact of Voluntary Corporate Disclosures on the Ex Ante Cost of Capital

for Swiss Firms. European Accounting Review 11, 741-743.

Hail, L., and C. Leuz, 2006. International Differences in the Cost of Equity Capital: Do Legal

Institutions and Securities Regulation Matter? Journal of Accounting Research 44, 485-531.

Hail, L., and C. Leuz, 2007. Cost of Capital Effects and Changes in Growth Expectations around

U.S. Cross Listings. University of Chicago Working Paper.

Page 83: SSRN-id1105398

82

Han, J., J. Wild, and K. Ramesh, 1989. Managers‟ Earnings Forecasts and Intra-Industry

Information Transfers. Journal of Accounting and Economics 11, 3-33.

Harris, M., 1998. The Association between Competition and Managers' Business Segment

Reporting Decisions. Journal of Accounting Research 36, 111-128.

Haw, I., B. Hu, L. Hwang, and W. Wu, 2004. Ultimate Ownership, Income Management and

Legal and Extra-Legal Institutions. Journal of Accounting Research 42, 423-462.

Hay, J., and A. Shleifer, 1998. Private Enforcement of Public Laws: A Theory of Legal Reform.

American Economic Review 88, 398-403.

Hayes, R, and R. Lundholm, 1996. Segment Reporting to the Capital Market in the Presence of a

Competitor. Journal of Accounting Research 34, 261-279.

Healy, P., A. Hutton, and K. Palepu, 1999. Stock Performance and Intermediation Changes

Surrounding Sustained Increases in Disclosure. Contemporary Accounting Research 16,

485-520.

Healy, P., and J. Whalen, 1999. A Review of the Earnings Management Literature and Its

Implications for Standards Setting. Accounting Horizons 13, 365-383.

Healy, P., and K. Palepu, 2001. Information Asymmetry, Corporate Disclosure, and the Capital

Markets: A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 31, 405-440.

Heflin, F., Subramanyam, K., Zhang, Y., 2003. Regulation FD and the Financial Information

Environment: Early Evidence. The Accounting Review 78, 1-37.

Hermalin, B. and M. Katz, 1993. Judicial Modification of Contracts between Sophisticated

Parties: A More Complete View of Incomplete Contracts and Their Breach. Journal of Law,

Economics and Organization 9, 230-255.

Hermalin, B. and M. Weisbach, 2007. Transparency and Corporate Governance. NBER Working

Papers 12875.

Hirshleifer, J., 1971. The Private and Social Value of Information and the Reward to Inventive

Activity. The American Economic Review 61, 561-574.

Hirst, D., L. Koonce, and S. Venkataraman, 2008. Management Earnings Forecasts: A Review

and Framework. University of Texas Working Paper.

Hochberg, Y., P. Sapienza, and A. Vissing-Jorgensen, 2007. A Lobbying Approach to

Evaluating the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. Northwestern University Working Paper.

Holthausen, R., and R. Watts, 2001. The Relevance of the Value-Relevance Literature for

Financial Accounting Standard Setting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 31, 3-75.

Hope, O., 2003. Disclosure Practices, Enforcement of Accounting Standards and Analysts'

Forecast Accuracy: An International Study. Journal of Accounting Research 41, 235-272.

Hostak, P., E. Karaoglu, T. Lys, and Y. Yang, 2007. An Examination of the Impact of the

Sarbanes-Oxley Act on the Attractiveness of US Capital Markets for Foreign Firms. Journal

of Accounting Research, Forthcoming.

Page 84: SSRN-id1105398

83

Hribar, P., and C. Nichols. 2007. The Use of Unsigned Earnings Quality Measures in Tests of

Earnings Management. Journal of Accounting Research 45, 1017-1053.

Huddart, S., J. Hughes, and M. Brunnermeier, 1999. Disclosure Requirements and Stock

Exchange Listing Choice in an International Context. Journal of Accounting and Economics

26, 237-269.

Hughes, J., J. Liu, and J. Liu, 2007. Information, Diversification, and Cost of Capital.

Accounting Review, Forthcoming.

Hung, M., 2001. Accounting Standards and Value Relevance of Financial Statements: An

International Analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics 30, 401-420.

Hung, M., Subramanyam, K. 2007. Financial Statement Effects of the Adoption of International

Accounting Standards: the Case of Germany. Review of Accounting Studies, 12, 623-657.

Jain, P., J. Kim, and Z. Razaee et al, 2004. Trends and Determinants of Market Liquidity in the

Pre- and Post-Sarbanes-Oxley Act Periods. University of Memphis Working Paper.

Jarrell, G., 1981. The Economic Effects of Federal Regulation of the Market for New Security

Issues. Journal of Law and Economics 24, 613-675.

Jensen, M., and W. Meckling, 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs,

and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.

Johnson, M., R. Kasznik, and K. Nelson, 2001. The Impact of Securities Litigation Reform on

the Disclosure of Forward-Looking Information by High Technology Firms. Journal of

Accounting Research 39, 297-327.

Jones, J., 1991. Earnings Management during Import Relief Investigations. Journal of

Accounting Research 29, 193-228.

Jorgensen, B. and M. Kirschenheiter, 2003. Discretionary Risk Disclosures. The Accounting

Review 78, 449-469

Jorgensen, B. and M. Kirschenheiter, 2007. Voluntary Sensitivity Disclosures. Working paper,

Columbia University.

Jorion, P., Z. Liu, and C. Shi. 2005. Informational Effects of Regulation FD: Evidence from

Rating Agencies. Journal of Financial Economics 76, 309-330

Jung, W. and Y. Kwon, 1988. Disclosure when the Market is Unsure of Information Endowment

of Managers. Journal of Accounting Research 26, 146-153.

Karamanou, I., and G. Nishiotis, 2005, The Valuation Effects of Company Voluntary Adoption

of International Accounting Standards. University of Cyprus Working Paper.

Kanodia, C., A. Mukherji, H. Sapra, and R. Venugopalan, 2000. Hedge Disclosures, Future

Prices, and Production Distortions. Journal of Accounting Research 38 (Supplement), 53-82.

Kahn, A., 1988. The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions. Cambridge, MA:

MIT Press.

Kasznik, R., and B. Lev, 1995. To Warn or Not to Warn: Management Disclosures in the Face of

an Earnings Surprise. The Accounting Review 70, 113-134.

Page 85: SSRN-id1105398

84

Khanna, T., K. Palepu, and S. Srinivasan, 2004. Disclosure Practices of Foreign Companies

Interacting with U.S. Markets. Journal of Accounting Research 42, 475-508.

Kirby, A., 1988. Trade Associations as Information Exchange Mechanisms. RAND Journal of

Economics 19, 138-146.

Kothari, S., 2001. Capital Markets Research in Accounting. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 31, 105-231.

Kothari, S., S. Shu, and P. Wysocki, 2007. Do Managers Withhold Bad News? Working Paper,

MIT Sloan School of Management.

LaFond, R., M. Lang, and H. Skaife. 2007. Earnings Smoothing, Governance and Liquidity:

International Evidence. University of North Carolina Working Paper.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer, 2006. What Works in Securities Laws? The

Journal of Finance 61, 1-32.

La Porta, R., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., and F. Lopez de Silanes, 1998. Law and Finance. Journal

of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R. Vishny, 1999. Corporate Ownership around the

World. Journal of Finance 54, 471-517.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R. Vishny, 2000. Investor Protection and

Corporate Governance. Journal of Financial Economics 58, 3-27.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R. Vishny, 2002. Investor Protection and

Corporate Valuation. Journal of Finance 57, 1147.

Laffont, J., J. Tirole, 1993. A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation. Cambridge,

MA: MIT Press.

Lambert, R., 2001. Contracting Theory and Accounting, Journal of Accounting and Economics

32, 3-87.

Lambert, R., C. Leuz, and R. Verrecchia, 2007a. Accounting Information, Disclosure, and the

Cost of Capital. Journal of Accounting Research 45 (2007), 385-420.

Lambert, R., C. Leuz, and R. Verrecchia, 2007b. Information Asymmetry, Information Precision

and the Cost of Capital. Working paper, Wharton School and University of Chicago.

Lang, M., K. Lins, and D. Miller, 2003a. ADRs, Analysts, and Accuracy: Does Cross-Listing in

the U.S. Improve a Firm‟s Information Environment and Increase Market Value? Journal of

Accounting Research 41, 317-345.

Lang, M., and R. Lundholm, 1993. Cross-Sectional Determinants of Analyst Ratings of

Corporate Disclosures. Journal of Accounting Research 31, 246-271.

Lang, M., and R. Lundholm, 1996. Corporate Disclosure Policy and Analyst Behavior.

Accounting Review 71, 467-492.

Lang, M., and R. Lundholm, 2000. Voluntary Disclosure and Equity Offerings: Reducing

Information Asymmetry Or Hyping the Stock? Contemporary Accounting Research 17, 623.

Page 86: SSRN-id1105398

85

Lang, M., J. Raedy, and M. Yetman, 2003b. How Representative Are Firms that Are Cross-

Listed in the United States? An Analysis of Accounting Quality. Journal of Accounting

Research 41, 363-386.

Lang, M., J. Raedy, and W. Wilson, 2006. Earnings Management and Cross Listing: Are

Reconciled Earnings Comparable to U.S. Earnings? Journal of Accounting and Economics

42, 255-283.

Larcker, D. and T. Rusticus, 2005, On the Use of Instrumental Variables in Accounting

Research. University of Pennsylvania Working Paper.

Lemmon, M., and K. Lins, 2003. Ownership Structure, Corporate Governance, and Firm Value:

Evidence from the East Asian Financial Crisis. Journal of Finance 58, 1445-1468.

Leone, A., S. Rock and M. Willenborg, 2007. Disclosure of Intended Use of Proceeds and

Underpricing in Initial Public Offerings. Journal of Accounting Research 45, 111-115.

Leuz, C., 2003. Discussion of ADRs, Analysts and Accuracy: Does Cross Listing in the US

Improve a Firm‟s Information Environment and Increase Market Value? Journal of

Accounting Research 41 (Supplement), 347-362.

Leuz, C., 2004. Proprietary Versus Non-Proprietary Disclosures: Evidence from Germany, in: C.

Leuz, D. Pfaff, and A. Hopwood eds.: The Economics and Politics of Accounting. Oxford

University Press, Oxford, 164-197.

Leuz, C., 2007. Was the Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002 Really this Costly? A Discussion of

Evidence from Event Returns and Going-Private Decisions. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 44, 146-155.

Leuz, C., D. Nanda, and P. Wysocki, 2003. Earnings Management and Investor Protection: An

International Comparison. Journal of Financial Economics 69, 505-527.

Leuz.C, and F. Oberholzer-Gee, 2006. Political Relationships, Global Financing, and Corporate

Transparency: Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Financial Economics 81, 411-439.

Leuz, C., A. Triantis and T. Wang, 2007. Why Do Firms Go Dark? Causes and Economic

Consequences of Voluntary SEC Deregistrations. Journal of Accounting and Economics,

Forthcoming.

Leuz, C., K. Lins, and F. Warnock, 2005. Do Foreigners Invest Less in Poorly Governed Firms?

Review of Financial Studies, Forthcoming.

Leuz, C., and R. Verrecchia, 2000. The Economic Consequences of Increased Disclosure.

Journal of Accounting Research 38, 91-124.

Levine, R., 2001. International Financial Integration and Economic Growth. Review of

International Economics 9, 684-698.

Li, H., M. Pincus, and S. Rego, 2004. Market Reaction to Events Surrounding the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act of 2002. University of Iowa Working Paper.

Lipsey, R., and K. Lancaster, 1956. The General Theory of Second Best. The Review of

Economic Studies 24, 11-32.

Liu, M., and P. Wysocki, 2007. Cross-sectional Determinants of Information Quality Proxies and

Cost of Capital. MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper.

Page 87: SSRN-id1105398

86

Litvak, K., 2005. The Effect of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act on Non-US Companies Cross-Listed in

the US. Journal of Corporate Finance 13, 195-228.

Ljungqvist, A., 2004. IPO Underpricing, in: Eckbo, B. E. (ed.), Handbook of Empirical

Corporate Finance. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Forthcoming.

Lombaro, D. and M. Pagano, 2002. Law and equity markets: a simple model, CSEF Working

Paper No. 25, and CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2276, in Corporate Governance Regimes:

Convergence and Diversity, J. McCahery, P. Moerland, T. Raaijmakers and L. Renneboog

(eds.), Oxford University Press, 343-362.

Mahoney, P., 1995. Mandatory Disclosure as a Solution to Agency Problems. The University of

Chicago Law Review 62, 1047-1112.

Mahoney, P. and Mei, 2006. Mandatory vs. Contractual Disclosure in Securities Markets:

Evidence from the 1930s. University of Virginia Law School Working Paper.

Mahoney, P., 1997. The Exchange as Regulator, Virginia Law Review 83, 1453-1500.

McInnis, J., 2007. Are Smoother Earnings Associated with a Lower Cost of Equity Capital?

University of Iowa Working Paper.

McLeay, S., D. Ordelheide, and S, Young, 2000. Constituent Lobbying and Its Impact on the

Development of Financial Reporting Regulations: Evidence from Germany. Accounting,

Organizations and Society 25, 79-98,

McLeay, S. and D. Merkl, 2004. Drafting Accounting Law: An Analysis of Institutionalized

Interest Representation. In The Economics and Politics of Accounting: International

Perspectives on Research Trends, Policy, and Practice, Edited by C. Leuz, D. Pfaff and A.

Hopwood. Oxford University Press, London, UK.

Merton, R. C., 1987. A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete

Information. Journal of Finance 42, 483.

Milgrom, D., 1981. Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications. Bell

Journal of Economics 12, 380-391.

Miller, D., and J. Puthenpurackal, 2002. The Cost, Wealth Effects, and Determinants of

International Capital Raising: Evidence from Public Yankee Bonds. Journal of Financial

Intermediation 11, 455-485.

Morris, S., and H. Shin, 2006. Optimal Communication. Journal of the European Economics

Association Papers and Proceedings 5, 594-602.

Nagar, V., D. Nanda, and P. Wysocki, 2003. Discretionary Disclosure and Stock-Based

Incentives. Journal of Accounting and Economics 34, 283-309.

Ng, J., 2008. The Effect of Information Quality on Liquidity Risk. Wharton School Working

Paper.

Nichols, D., 2006. Fundamental Risk or Information Risk? An Analysis of the Residual Accrual

Volatility Factor. Cornell University Working Paper.

Nikolaev, V., and L. van Lent, 2005. The Endogeneity Bias in the Relation Between Cost-of-

Debt Capital and Corporate Disclosure Policy. European Accounting Review 14, 677-724.

Page 88: SSRN-id1105398

87

Ogneva, M., 2007. Accrual Quality and Expected Returns: The Importance of Controlling for

Cash Flow Shocks. USC Working Paper.

Peltzman, S., 1976. Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. The Journal of Law and

Economics 19.

Peltzman, S., M. Levine, and R. Noll, 1989. The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade

of Deregulation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics, 1-59.

Pastor, L., and R. Stambaugh, 2003. Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns. Journal of

Political Economy 111. 642-685.

Piotroski, J., and S. Srinivasan, 2008. Regulation and Bonding: The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the

Flow of International Listings. Journal of Accounting Research, Forthcoming.

Platikanova, P., 2007. Market Liquidity Effects of the IFRS Introduction in Europe. University

Pompeu Fabra Working Paper.

Posner, R., 1974. Theories of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management

Science 5, 335.

Rajan, R., and L. Zingales, 1998. Which Capitalism? Lessons from the East Asian Crisis. Journal

of Applied Corporate Finance 11(3): 40-48.

Rajan, R., and L. Zingales, 2003. The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in

the 20th Century. Journal of Financial Economics 69, 5-50.

Ramanna, K., 2007. The Implications of Fair-Value Accounting: Evidence from the Political

Economy of Goodwill Accounting. MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper.

Reese, W. and M. Weisbach, 2002. Protection of Minority Shareholder Interests, Cross-Listings

in the United States, and Subsequent Equity Offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 66,

65-104.

Rezaee, Z. and P. Jain, 2005. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 and Accounting Conservatism.

University of Memphis Working Paper.

Ribstein, L., 2005. Sarbanes-Oxley after Three Years. University of Illinois Law & Economics

Research Paper.

Rock, K., 1986. Why New Issues are Underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics 15, 187-212.

Rock, E., 2002. Securities Regulation as Lobster Trap: A Credible Commitment Theory of

Mandatory Disclosure. 23 Cardozo Law Review 23, 675-704.

Romano, R., 1998. Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation. The

Yale Law Journal 107, 2359.

Romano, R., 2001. The Need for Competition in International Securities Regulation. Theoretical

Inquiries in Law 2, Article 1.

Romano, R., 2004. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and the Making of Quack Corporate Governance.

NYU Law and Economics Research Paper.

Ross, S., 1979. Disclosure regulation in Financial Markets: Implications of Modern Finance

Theory and Signaling Theory. In F. Edwards (Ed.), Issues in Financial Regulation,

McGraw-Hill.

Page 89: SSRN-id1105398

88

Sadka, G. 2006. The Economic Consequences of Accounting Fraud in Product Markets: Theory

and a Case from the U.S. Telecommunications Industry (WorldCom). American Law and

Economics Review 8, 439-475.

Sapra, H., 2002. Do Mandatory Hedge Disclosures Discourage or Encourage Excessive

Speculation? Journal of Accounting Research 40, 933-964.

Schmidt, G. and R. Spindler, 2002. Path Dependence, Corporate Governance and

Complementarity. International Finance 5, 311-333.

Schrand, and Verrecchia, 2005. Information Disclosure and Adverse Selection Explanations for

IPO Underpricing. Wharton School Working Paper.

Scott, T., 1994. Incentives and Disincentives for Financial Disclosure: Voluntary Disclosure of

Defined Benefit Pension Plan Information by Canadian Firms. The Accounting Review 69,

26-43.

Seligman, J., 1983. The Historical Need for a Mandatory Corporate Disclosure System. Journal

of Corporation Law 9, 1.

Sengupta, P., 1998. Corporate Disclosure Quality and the Cost of Debt. Accounting Review 73,

459-474.

Shleifer, A., 2005. Understanding Regulation. European Financial Management 11, 439–451.

Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 1997. A Survey of Corporate Governance. Journal of Finance 52,

737-83.

Shleifer, A., and D. Wolfenzon, 2002. Investor Protection and Equity Markets. Journal of

Financial Economics 66, 3-27.

Sidhu, B., T. Smith, R. Whaley, and R. Willis, 2008. Regulation Fair Disclosure and the Cost of

Adverse Selection. Journal of Accounting Research, Forthcoming.

Sidak, J., 2003. The Failure of Good Intentions: the Worldcom Fraud and the Collapse of

American Telecommunications After Deregulation. Yale Journal of Regulation 20, 207-267.

Siegel, J., 2005. Can Foreign Firms Bond Themselves Effectively by Submitting to U.S. Law?

Journal of Financial Economics 75, 319-359.

Simon, C., 1989. The Effect of the 1933 Securities Act on Investor Information and the

Performance of New Issues. The American Economic Review 79, 295-318.

Skinner, D., 1997. Earnings Disclosures and Stockholder Lawsuits. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 23, 249-282.

Soderstrom, N., and K. Sun, 2007. IFRS Adoption and Accounting Quality: A Review. European

Accounting Review 16, 675-702.

Stigler, G., 1964. Public Regulation of the Securities Markets. The Journal of Business 37, 117-

142.

Stigler, G., 1971. The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and

Management Science 2, 3-21.

Straser, V., 2002. Regulation Fair Disclosure and Information Asymmetry. Working paper.

University of Notre Dame.

Page 90: SSRN-id1105398

89

Stulz, R., 1999. Globalization, Corporate Finance, and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Applied

Corporate Finance 26, 3-28.

Tasker, S., 1998. Bridging the Information Gap: Quarterly Conference Calls as a Medium for

Voluntary Disclosure. Review of Accounting Studies 3, 137-167.

U.S. Chamber of Commerce, 2007. Report and Recommendations of Commission on the

Regulation of U.S. Capital Markets in the 21st Century. Washington, DC.

Verdi, R., 2006. Information Environment and the Cost of Equity Capital. MIT Sloan School of

Management Working Paper.

Verrecchia, R., 1983. Discretionary Disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 5, 179-

194.

Verrecchia, R., 1990. Information Quality and Discretionary Disclosure. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 12, 365-380.

Verrecchia, R., 2001. Essays on Disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 32, 97-180.

Vives, X., 1984. Duopoly Information Equilibrium: Cournot and Bertrand. Journal of Economic

Theory 34, 71-94.

Wagenhofer, A., 1990. Voluntary Disclosure with a Strategic Opponent. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 12, 341-364.

Walker, R., 1992. The SEC‟s Ban on Upward Asset Revaluations and the Disclosure of Current

Values. Abacus 28, 3-35.

Watts, R., 1977. Corporate Financial Statements: A product of the Market and Political

Processes. Australian Journal of Management 2, 52-75.

Watts, R., 2003. Conservatism in Accounting - Part I: Explanations and Implications.

Accounting Horizons 17, 207–221.

Watts, R., and J. Zimmerman, 1978. Towards a Positive Theory of the Determination of

Accounting Standards. The Accounting Review 53, 112-134.

Watts, R., and J. Zimmerman, 1986. Positive Accounting Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:

Prentice-Hall.

Welker, M., 1995. Disclosure Policy, Information Asymmetry, and Liquidity in Equity Markets.

Contemporary Accounting Research 11, 801-827.

Wysocki, P., 2004. Discussion of Ultimate Ownership, Income Management and Extra-Legal

Institutions. Journal of Accounting Research 42, 462-474.

Wysocki, P., 2007. Assessing Earnings and Accruals Quality: U.S. and International Evidence.

MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper.

Xu, T., M. Najand, and D. Ziegenfuss, 2006. Intra-Industry Effects of Earnings Restatements

Due to Accounting Irregularities. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 33, 696-714.

Yee, Kenton, 2006. Earnings Quality and the Equity Risk Premium: A Benchmark Model.

Contemporary Accounting Research 23, 833-877.

Page 91: SSRN-id1105398

90

Zhang, J., 2007. Efficiency Gains from Accounting Conservatism: Benefits to Lenders and

Borrowers. Journal of Accounting and Economics, Forthcoming.

Zhang, X., 2007. Economic Consequences of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. Journal of

Accounting and Economics 44, 74-115.