Protectionist Jan Feb1988

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    1/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUtS JANUARY/FEBRUARY 1988

    Protectionist Trade Policies: A

    Survey ofTheory, Evidence andRationale

    Cletus C. Coughlin, K.Alec Chrystal andGeoffrey E. Wood

    ROTECTIONIST pm-essures have been mounting

    won-idwide during the 1980s. These pn-essmmres are due

    to various economic problems incltnding the lam-ge and

    persistent balance of tnade deficits in the UnitedStates; the hard times expenienced by seven-al indus-

    tries; and tire show growth of many foreign countn-ies.

    Pn-oponents of protectionist trade policies amgue that

    international trade has contributed substantially to

    these problems and that protectionist tmade policies

    will head to improved nesults. Professional economists

    in the United States, however-, generally agree that

    tmade restn-ictions such as tariffs and quotas substan-

    tially reduce a nations economic well~being.2

    This article surveys the theory, evidence and na-

    tionale concen-ning protectionist trade policies. The

    first section illustrates the gains from fm-ce tn-ade usingthe concept ofcompan-ative advantage. Recent demel-

    opments in international trade theorm that emphasize

    other reasons for- gains from trade are also reviewed.

    The theoretical discussion is followed hiy an exami-

    nation of recent empirical studies that demonstm-ate

    the large costs of protectionist trade policies. Then,

    the rationale for restricting trade is presented. The

    concluding section summarizes the papers main

    arguments.

    CletusC. Coughlin is a senior economist attheFederal Reserve Bank

    ofSt Louis. K. Alec Chnystal is theNational WestminsterBankProfes-sor of Personal Finance at City University, London. Geoffrey E Woodisa professor of economics at City University, London. This article waswritten while Chrystal was a professor of economics attheUniversity ofSheffield, Sheffield, England. ThomasA. Pollmann provided researchassistance.

    See Page (1987) for a detailed examination of trade protectionismsince 1974.

    2 This consensus was found in a survey published in the late 1970s(Keart et at., 1979). Recent developments in international tradetheory, which can be used to justify governmental intervention intrade policy, have not altered the consensus (Krugman, 1987).

    THE GAINS FRONt FREE TRADE

    The most famous demonstration of the gains fn-om

    tnade appear-ed in 1817 in David Ricardos PrinciplesofPolitical Economy and Ta,vation. We use his example

    inmolming tn-ade between England and Portugal to dem

    onstnate how both countries can gain fn-om tnade.. The

    two countnies pn-oduce the same two goods, wine and

    cloth, and the only pn-oduction costs ane labor- costs.

    The figures below list the amount of lahior leg..

    won-ker-daysi requin-ed in each country to pn-oduce one

    bottle (ifwnne on-one hiolt of cloth.

    England

    Portugal

    Wine

    3

    1

    Cloth

    Since both goods ar-c tiione costly to produce in En-

    gland than in Por-tugal, England is ahisolmrtely less

    efficient at producinig both goods than its prospective

    trading partner. Portugal has an absolute advantage in

    hioth wine and cloth. At fin-st glance, this appear-s to

    r-ule. (iut mutual gains fn-om trade; howeme,n-, as we

    demonstrate below, absolute advantage is irrelevant in

    discerniing whether tnade can hienefit both countn-ies.

    The natio of the pr-oductioni costs fon the two goods

    is diffenent in the two countries. hn England. a bottle (if

    wine will exchange for 3/7 ofa bolt (ifcloth becamnse the

    labor content of the wine is 3/7 of that for (:10th. In

    Portmtgal, a bottle ofwinie ivill exchanige for 1/5 ofa boltof cloth. Thus, wine is relatively cheaper in Portugal

    than in Englanid and, conmersels, cirith is relativehs

    cheaper in England than in Portmngal. the example

    indicates that Pom-tugal has a compam-atime admamitage in

    mvimie pr-oduction and England has a comiiparative ad-

    vantage in cloth pnocluction.

    The different relative pm-ices provide the basis fom

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    2/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARVIFEBRUARY lies

    both countries to gain fn-omn iriternational trade. The

    gains arise from both exchange and specialization.

    The gains from exchangecan be highlighted in the

    following manner. Ifa Portn.mguese wine producer sells

    five bottles of wine at home, he receives one bolt of

    cloth. Ifhe trades in England, he receives more than

    two bolts ofcloth. Hence, he can gain by expon-ting his

    mvine to England. English cloth-pn-oducen-s are willing

    to trade in Portugal; for emeny 3/7 ofa bolt of cloth the

    sell there, they get just (iven twri bottles of wine. The

    English gain from exporting cloth to land imponting

    wine fn-omi Por-tugal, and the Portuguese gain from

    expon-tingwine to land importing cloth fromi England.

    Each country gains by expon-tinig the good in which it

    has a compan-ative advantage and by impon-ting the

    good in which it has a compam-ative disadmantage.

    Gains fn-om specialization can be denionstrated in

    the follomming manner. tnitially, eachi country is pto-ducing some ofboth goods. Suppose that, as a n-esutt of

    tr-ade, 21 units of labor are shifted fnom mvine to cloth

    pnoduction in England, while, in Portugal, 10 units of

    labor- are shifted from cloth to wine production. lhis

    reallocation oflabor- does not altet- the total amount of

    labor used in the two countn-ies; howeven-, it causes the

    pn-oduction changes listed below.

    Bottles of Wine Bolts of Cloth

    7 3

    The shift of 21 rnnits of labor to the English cloth

    industr raises cloth production by three bolts, while

    reducing wine production by seven biotttes. In Pomtrn-

    gal, the shift (if 10 units of labor from cloth to wine

    raises winie pmoduction liv 10 bottles, while n-educing

    cloth pm-oduction by two liolts. This reallocation nif

    labor imicreases the total pnoduction of Iiothi goods

    wine by thn-ee bottles and cloth hiy one bolt. This

    increased output will be shared Iiy the two countries.

    Thus, the consumption of liothi goods and the wealth

    of both countries ane incn-eased by the specializa

    tion bm-ought about by trade based on compar-ative

    advantage.

    TRADE THEORY SINCE HICARDO

    Since 1817, numerous analyses have gener-ated in-

    sights concerning the gains from tmade, lhiey chiefly

    examine the consequences rif relaxing the assump-

    tions used in the pn-eceding example. For example,

    labor was the only resource used to produce the two

    goods in the example above; yet, labor is really only

    one of many resources used to prodmnce goods. The

    example also assumed that the costs of producing

    additional units of the goods ar-c constant. For exam-

    ple, in England, three units of labor an-c used to pro-

    duce one bottle ofwine regardless of the level ofwine

    pn-oduction. In reality, unit production costs could

    either increase or- decrease as more is produced. A

    thim-d assumption was that the goods an-c produced in

    per-fectlv competitive mat-kets. tn other- won-ds, an indi-

    vidual firm has no effect on the price ofthe good that it

    pnoduces. Some industries, however-, are dominated

    by a small numhier of firms, each of which can affect

    the manket pr-ice ofthe good iw altering its production

    decision. Sonic of these extensions at-c discnnssed in

    the appendix.

    These theoretical developnients genem-atly have

    strengthened the case for an open rn-ading system.

    They suggest thn-ee soun-ces of gains fi-om trade. First,

    as the market potentially served by firms expands

    from a national to a world market, then-c are gains

    associated with declining per unit pnoduction costs. A

    second sour-ce of gains results fn-om the reduction in

    the monopoly power- of domestic firms. Domestic

    firms, facing more pressure from fon-eign competitors,

    are forced to produce the (iutput demanded by con-

    sumers at the lowest possible costlhird is the gain to

    consumers from increased product variety and lomver

    prices. Generally speaking, the gains fiomn tm-ade r-esult

    from the increase in competitive pressures as the

    domestic economy becomes less insulated from the

    world economy.

    The gains fmoni free trade can also he illustrated

    gt-aphicallv. The shaded insert on pages 14 and 15

    examines the gains fiom ttade in pemfectly competitime

    markets using supply and demand analysis. The in-

    sert also analyzes the effects of tn-ade n-estn-ictions, a

    topic that we discuss below.

    COSTS OF TRADE PROTECTIONISM

    Protectionist trade policies can take numenous

    forms, some of which are discussed in the shaded

    insert on pages 16 amid 17. All forriis of lirotectioni an-e

    A profit-maximizing firm produces its output at minimum cost. Whenfirms are insulated from competition, costs are not necessarily beingminimized. This situation, which is catted X-etficiency, has beenstressed by Leibenstein (1980). The increase in competitive pres-sures due to international trade reduces the probability that costsare not minimized.

    England

    Portugal 10

    Net 3

    9

    1

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    3/18

    A Supply and Demand Analysis of the Gains from FreeTrade and the Effects of a rliarjff

    A starndaid flinstr-aliori tnt liii gains 1mm tree tiad, puikm liii nragrrilLrdr- mt tlrtse grin, and

    hat], arid tie ctin-ls ol il till ill is pn~crnturIhrIm~- Io~s-s trsing thr- cm mt-ph ut roiIsmirniii- .uiti jil ii

    I lu ,rl,i\ sk issl_rnhis Irr-tr-I~m m-onrpctiti p nw- uiu,-i-i smnr-1

    nltjs air inn seen iii tir4lri-i I - C mrrp,LrrrIt-is

    Lets tlniorrghoni. gain i tno na s_ Iniliaiim ,tniistrnnitr-s i;irrclras-tI

    ft. al a purr 11cr trnil ii I - flitir Ire tiatlr. Ihm-~- , inmrriliast V. at till- inner 11cc ill-n minnrt cr1 P I iii,,

    (.ains trout tree 1 rude - --r~arrrrs r-epr-rsenteti mm tb, rcI-tanMie I lii I. - In

    tin tigtri-i I tit- rum-s S anti I) an tint L S. sirinpi\ atidrtioni tIn irn~,r 1niict irrnlirt-ts ,nrisirnltrs rn

    unit] rienirunti rmr\ts Irir a lnptnliiehrral wind. lit-i- ii i-ri-_tsr Lli,ii- i)triilizisis h,rnn 0 tin iF -- liii, gain

    ultirrsprluin at B irsmrlls In the rritrrirlni-itrrir maltips ~5

    n-pi r,rriirci Irm I ht Ir iarngic- tIC I -l he total g;tir I to

    tot1

    rri~- arrd qmrarrlit\ ii I arid 0 \~strminuti- rininsLnrnrer-s is I IC i_ in nsirng the- itrnm-r case

    etc-c] Stai,-s has a ronlpar-.itn ( dnsaLi\ uoNr4e IcItu-i s to rrpi-t-srrit tiers a - Ii - r .\inalogoList\

    pitidirtioni cii this gnu,] lii, Pr icr- n ill lit ion cr- piteltrici s lo,c un,- to the loner- ruin- tIr,-m ri-theabroad than iii tie trnit,-tl stains i_it [Iris tinner br Uteri- nmitirmrt. . - anti kr,- to ihprrrnrrnti-artimnri nil

    ~~m,niciPri I- he P rind asurne th,t t s prrtIisr-s ]~nrtitcIrun li-tin, to S - I he tori1 toss tir

    drn n,,t altect this nonid Jilt- (.rapirinalk his , dnrrr-s is I - Bi I ora

    iiiiri-seintrmI iiv lint Iic,ir,,rrit,i t~mnrtcistr1

    nptm tmrrmc, tic- inctimri as a nhrln ~zrinis inr,,nusp lint- curl

    S It onpalionslurti-tp trade this lunerncnrtl ~ snrnwr ialris mt a - In emcee,l tin innnmlmrc-

    has tnuu ittirts. I insI I s (trnstrriwrs mmiii inlrrvasp misses otah~ in -- c I inisanahsisranalsuIni-mrened

    tin,-ir- c-runi.,Iirin1

    nlicnul 1,1 I nrrci. t S. nnindnrm9s irsirin4agunti ihat inc t nnIt,i5tttr,c\jflnri~ in ritin,-,-

    mmiii contract their pi-(nultrm-tiorr In S~ iii, (mimss oh nnri-cis tire t rlited States mmiii inam, a nunirpriilIi\n

    S muniistrnipliuri n.Imen-prciciLwnoin is I _S nnrrliasrs atlurnitag,- hr itt innrulrrrlnn cr1 a gtnrcl I or Liii

    tiom tor-,-i~niprodtrr-er-s hat k. rnrports- export ~ocrd. the change tin lit, track- mmiii miLri-

    lint Ion cc ill_u_i- ~innmillanernu~Imhem-IrIs t roii urmrtirct-r gains liar i-u-c-mci rnrin,imnncr losses.

    srrrritrs ain,i hunts I _S iirintlircnr~ a fact tirat

    civil es tin,- nec-cot cturitiinu-rsral mli,c-tesruins in! I 5.

    Ihe E/Jietsoju lari/J

    tiu maLi lie ariatmsisoi proteu-tiorli~~Itrade rulirm

    Fiq.-ro rs strrrghttmrrmmmrti is ncnsiinii tiii- jrrmji~t,-t nI

    I is ;mri,ilm,.c-mt (urn, rain mn-mm aIim nonlerlrorrist li-aiim-

    I potu:m inmnmm~-mi-r.rniirni.iralirgmnnmsirnairnncr- tmr cr11~ mc-iiiirrce h, in,,- tr,itii- -esirits rn ligmrnc t wi uhrpIi

    rated ri lrgiri-i 2. Gim,ni ihc In-,-,- Lr-,icic- mmmuntd ~r~~- cr1

    A I. t S rcnnscrniniutroir rnn,lirctnnir arid irinpcni-ts aJ-rIi s acid S. U~ \,-,trrne a tar It rs inirj_rmus,-dUS nacrsiirg he pi-it n irn lit I ruled slates icr rin,-i-e;rw to

    B t~ i lu p1-itt- in tire I rued Slates mrnmm r-u-i-c-ck prirm-

    Pu in tInt mmrutd irm the arriorunt mt tin,- unit P_U

    p a bHN.,c s -F w i he higher I ~ p ri 1 Jrtists t-miinsLrrnir it

    mai-s tin ,iucr-t-asi lr-mnrni i) Inn il. clcnnretir pm)dmncticnmn unnnnn-;rspli,rnrs InnS and rrlnirurlstmr

    I denrnirp lninlnr 5 h) Iii S ii il. imni1

    io,,ini~lint~ mis us -

    - tar itt nunistrnilers mist tIlt- ar-pa P_iC P. mm ci - pgamid prid,rier~gaun th i-area PH i and Urn-

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    4/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARYIFEBRUARY ION

    not-slit- intudtnm tnri priitertc-mi at tint n\1

    nuiist~ru

    - titnnlnmslit ,-lniIsmlnie-s

    -nyu. 4p (Jilt- c-nnri

    1iit-atirjmn sti-nlns minim tarili nemeuiint~ I am

    ill rmenurc mmllicIl marl lit- m iemmemi as a gain Rn the

    gtu\ en runt-mt t-Cithiis the hrntt P_P tinlirs tlr, tjtnani

    tit~ nt ulm1

    rumts ~ 1Y t In, il-men,rc is Ninal tin aica

    t 1(11 tnm I.

    C)m,-r-ahi lint- rnalnrnmn i,)sis ini-e;Imrsc lint ccumnsnrmiltrs

    tcr~st-scIti - i- - I - n_&emm-eni the prLruhnm-11-s g;rirls

    Al f :n.~m~

    :y: t: z ::.m~t:~1Y;~:F H ~ r~~1W miemmed -t-- -c itr,s nm-smiting mum imnehlicienit

    I us dm,mnestim inn ,InicI mum mmliiiian-agii-ailiti a mid- ~- a mmti.ght c-unsnnnptnntn 11)54 amid mrrl lie mirmmctiu~ us nss US is ,, imrss nisttitinng room nii-Iliiient ttnn hltic

    mm nmlslm imi~it ii In

    mnili-rm,hith tim immmimllmm liii inrn_ilmnmr nt ninrnnn,stmr- nitntmmi rlmrrnns inn inrniilit him i-~rmni1

    nir it c1

    nirrtn, iii

    tin IuinnIr;mn iiichmmii-ns I rn inn inn ,iinmmi Iinm-rnnngii imrim cr11 rnninrrits mimni, lmnncii_znm niiiihnn,im nir~nm niiiimc

    i-its Iinnt nir,-n n~sl hit,- lnm,nin, inrtii~i-lrimrn ml mini- trrn-,n&~nm hnigiii-m nniris tmrrrln,-in imptrnts lii tim rninlictr,i mmniri,_,-Imnii,hnrm-l ,h,-mnr-tst- tIn, pm I nihnn,tnmnmn rmn~ts nI citimmirsi ml

    tim-iris mr srnmniiiiiimm mnsini,l Ilir- ,ic-n-I-~s ri

    rhmnri-n Iii liii- chrnmin,-stnr nmnriL,-t

    Then-c have lieeni numerous studies of the costs of

    protectionism. We begin by examining three recent

    studies of pm-otectioriism in the United States, then

    The specific goal of protectionist tn-ade policies is to proceed to studies examining developed and finally,

    expand domestic pn-oductioni in the protected indus developing countries.

    ti-ies, benefiting the owners, workers and suppliers of

    r-esour-ces to the protected industry. The govennment CostsqfProtectionism in theCratedimposing pr-otectioniist trade policies may also benefit, Statesfor example, in the form of taniff revenue.

    - - - . Recent studies by Tan and Morkre 119841, t-lickok1 he expansiomi ofdoniestic pn-odnnctnon mni protected - - -

    - - - . - - - 1985) and Huliuauer et al. 11986) esttmated the costs ofnndusti its is not costless it n quit is tddntnonal

    pi otcctnotusni in tin Unitc d St ntis I lit s studn s uscsources from other itidustrres. Consequently, output - . - - - -.- - . - - , , . different estnmatnoni procedunes, examine diffem-entiii other domestic industm-ies is i-educed. these nndus - .. - -

    - - - . . protectnonnst policies arid cover dnfferent tnriie periods.trres also might be made less competrtnve hecanise ot - -

    Norn thiclcss thcv ptovnde consnstenit mesultshigher pt-ices for imported inputs. Since protectionist

    tr-ade policies frequently incr-ease the price of the Tair and Mork,-e 11984) estimate annual costs to the

    protected good, domestic consumers are liar-med. U.S. economy of812.7 billion 1983 dollars) from all tan

    lhey lose in two ways. I-inst. their consuniption of the ifs and from quotas on automobiles, textiles, steel and

    pr-otected good is n-educed because of the, associated sugar-. Their cost estinuate is a net measur-e in which

    rise in its price. Second, they consume less of other the losses ofconsumers are offset partially by the gainsgoods, as their output declines and pm-ices r-ise. of domestic producers and the U.S. government.

    The preceding discussion highlights the domestic Estimates liv thickok 1985) indicate that tr-ade rt~

    winniers and losers due to pnotectionist trade policies. strictions on only three goods clothing, sugam-, and

    Domestic produrcers of the liiotected good and the automobiles caused increased consumer expenidi

    government iftariffs an-c imposed) gain; domestic con- tunes of $14 billion in 1984. I-Iickokalso shows that low

    somers and otliei cloniestic pnoducem-s lose. Fon-eigni income families am-c affected mom-c than highincome

    interests an-c also affected by trade resti-ictions. The fnnilies. The import restmaints on clothing, sugar and

    pnotection of doniestic pn-oducers will harm some automobiles are calculated to be equivalent to a 23

    foreigni pmoducers; oddly emiourgbi, other foreign pmt percent income tax sun-charge that is, an additional

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    5/18

    Fermi OfPreticfio\nisrnN

    / N

    N

    In \iuapl t in~ns in mtbbmeima Thz darn~wa AU nS fp 1 nit t mi t \p eatesicrease ad o A onlb o. I d ;a nIne I ~ dltYeier

    p a Thi tab that - I aqtwa1sh\~t t gnfl*\ at, ~ nw the

    tbc\ ~sncprdu Aue$~nat p ~,. IS4t e \S~W~ d\ m$ht\ In

    n4ie

    Tar4J~ N N N 1: N N/ /N N 4nii twagN

    T which / iS & b/ ii/ / U~e

    bN

    S\N N*~ /~. t,p N d ~ U11~,/~/ :,N~ \\\\/NNN

    N~>h t ~t :sN / N

    N, ~ /N~\ N / N / -~ v: Nta~

    N \N /(7 /~ >N, /N N wartm$ N a

    It in N atn~ i$%ta N

    N N

    ~. N N tt4zd~tcnySaniersI. 0 17110 ~ N N,~,, ~ N -N, N\~~ N\~/\N\ \N~, ~,N,S, N

    ft t ntIS ide oov N ON kim twsayill dollatamounts lb ev Lw the I 0ff , ci ,t hug

    a bSct,w anfrate~ N N ,fhel S Sat I tEes01K 1It,~l%i0ujdw fl N~ tanf N LSES\ tnt Np Phr, phabeenhgoned thG A nt ~_ N N ad I nipt / aint the prop

    N ifi uwMrhNq!iN INO othbmn~vai~. r pin sib NbJ,k, ~e tIpniQi~ frMnak?v / ci tnitant t t

    ~ N ~ N N N

    qo I s4 n~ ci Io*y ~, , ntiS pa N -N \N I St

    Quotas N tia ani fr I) Tb land/ c&n en dni mM tb~

    NqN, ttiSf, thatnmptnteNodrodtareptwbetb lisa cI. tin w~drngt. bIONitO ,da

    thd~ LI a 1 and atdN adb ~binned tnamnin nitntbei p as 11 N t t o

    lb IIiqtbahm~ N i(pac CII I ci

    flKNOLkPflC

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    6/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARY/FEBRUARY ION

    sltim-imonis miram be lint imni1

    nm,sitrtnni cit salt-tm on-1

    iotltn i-:_1rIIum~tccj,nrolstmoni st(tmn,l:tn-cls that mu-n-c mini I~ im,mislm bt-imng met

    hm tomuizmn m;mms _th ot 11mm alflimm- ri-late dir-entim tin tilt iimimm ol- gomnci. \ hmmai class ml n-,-stm-ic-tiomis mmmnrks b~nt-strict . imng ai-,-i-ss hr tb~ inr-emgri rmionnn n tqinin-tci to imnim

    Suhsul:es - - -hnimm4ui 4oocis. I tim tannnplt. a r~omemnimmitnI that

    .\ri ;mtrenunarime to u-c-~ink-timm tint- tm-minus ninth-i- mm stied mm l)itflcct its n\pmnmIimng mutt irnilirimitmlntm In him n-igni-n-s man nomuhncte nun tine lmomime mar kc-I mtmumnpelimng irititnstm-ie, mat tim- t,m hold ils n~t-hang,-

    N to stibsmdm/e cloinuestir jnmumthmeen-s.sulnsuhes mmnam ate artmht-nailm Iomm \s a mcstnil tcnnvigmt goods mmmnmmi~ilie Iortmsntl unron ami imidItNin in M~~~mr mtpon the ~ m-x

    1nc-nisnmc- iii tic- boone mnnarkt-t mmliii,- inomi-

    eqnont aetnm itos ol tInt innntnnstnm ~mim-\armnple tnt tint- gomnds mmmnnimi lit- cheaji tim el-st-as bonn- puunmhnt-nt-shia-insact In \I,inimi arid \lcgmin t,4 N irnm

    1ilim-itim au-n- smrbsrtin,tml anti horune ,omrstnnuc-r s liii

    time tm,mnmliimnati,run ol n-mu dii mnomzu_nnnns sint-m-ial tam1

    ,Iititlm all- tamed I mis jn,itic~ is nmm,nmnrailm man-ct tci

    nnm,-emntim c-s anrci diii-, t stubsidm pam mnnm-nts hat bemnttit srmstainn lii, merlIn at barth mi holctimng tint- t-mu-hnng,-

    tic I _s_ sinipimumhhng inndLmstmm - _~mn esanmn1

    nle nil lint i-ate domm ni has tin hunt- hmrvmgrn t-~c-liamngt with itorne~

    latter us tine iimnamieial _msmstinnreto inn lease e\jn~nnIs tit- rum tint - I its nmmm It isscnmcl cionrmmstic cnnnmnem

    nomi,l,-ci in lint t ~, I-.minnmmtimniptnmt ilanik thm-nmtngh imnt-mt-aa-s the donirtstir nimomnt~msunk amid evmmnttrailm

    nlnnucI loans imiamr ~irtarautues amid imnstnn amine. annit m-amnsm-s imuiialimnnn tnmllnitiomnaum iioIntits am-p mini non

    mtm._nnmmnmnt mn;mnis Iii titln,n case rim cn,itrttic,rn ill unnalim r-egai-cied as ni s,rniInlt~mvam or h)m-l)tet-titnr4 dcil\ln(nmmtt nine_,tit immdmtstm -

    I ln,t-n- is amn,ither asinec-t In) emr-hamnMc- nomnim-inis

    _\ni innllioi-iamni clill,n-,rin-t- lu-tmmet-tn strlisi,iies annni Iii, jrmstitimatitimr is tin(tt pm-~mc-mininng limimnun, m-esitipmntst;mniti, imnm mm i-s tint- u-im mnlmnt- imnriilit-ationms rim gt,mmmmn tm-nnnim inimtstinis4 tr\ cm Sta, immtmietils ,Iinnnit,sti, gu-cmmm tin

    miemnt_ tin, lmmn-nmner mmnttnlmes be gomei-minimennt inn in~.\ (us ml lead, to greater tttimmn,stn, nvtl imImestniitnlt tmi

    imnn_r nitnt nim,nmn,m mmii, nm-nt, tam-ills gentnate nlm-otnn,- tom nm-alitm ml ,rtmld tim emanli_m tIne opptnsitu Restr imtinmglint- grim em-nunri-unt -t me t-tt,-m-t mnnm ,ionmnestir rniidLnntiomi an-c css to tnmnt-ign ass,-ts nnrav raise tim, mamiznnee anti;nniti mmeliart imnrmmnm tm tarn be tInt- saline unmien , tmtn, i t nnmmem lint- nttnnm n It, dJmmilc9s iii ,tmnmiiestit mm tnltln. tnn

    cImt-s as innnmier tantts amid tirmotas In all menses tin, tin, simmnmt 11111 ii alsni rmn(t\ nppnur erie lu dnmmnntsUr

    mm m,tnmI,ti inicb_tEmm is hi-imig strinsidi-,c-iI hm iii- rent ni esnhanngm rzntt tund him-mtin - wiLt ticnrnmn-sth- pmmn~timtpt,nmimjrnnm cttntmns ins ,trmnm

    1),Iitimi

    tax added to the normal income tax) for families with

    incomes less than $10,000 in 1984 and a 3 percent

    income tax sin-charge fom families with incomes cx-

    ceeding $60,000.

    Hufbauer et al. 11986) examined 31 cases in which

    trade volumes exceeded $100 million arid the United

    States imposed protectionist trade restrictions.4

    They

    generated estimates of the welfare consequences for

    each major- group afected see table 1). The figures in

    the table indicate that annual consumer losses exceed$100 million in all hut six of the cases. The largest

    losses, $27 billion pen- year-, come fnom protecting the

    textiles and apparel industry. There also ane lan-ge

    ~Whilethere were cases in which the industry adjusted to its newcompetitive position and the protection was terminated, these caseswere more the exception than the rule. In far more cases, protection-isi policies were maintained indefinitely or removed because offavorable demand changes.

    consumet losses associated with protection in car-hon

    steel $6.8 billion), automobiles $5.8 billion) and dairy

    products $5.5 billion).

    The purpose of pr-otectionism is to IJmotect jobs in

    specific industries. A useful approach to gain somepenspective on consumer- losses is to express these

    losses on a per-job-saved basis. In 18 of the 31 cases,

    the cost per-job-saved is $100,000 or more pen-year-; the

    consumer losses per-job-saved in benzenoid chemni-

    cais, carbon steel )two separate periodsL specialtysteel, and bolts, nuts and screws exceeded $500,000

    per year.

    Table I also neveals that domestic producers were

    the primary beneficiaries of protectionist policies;

    however, there are some noteworthy cases where fom~

    eign producers realized relatively lam-ge gains. For the

    US-Japanese voluntary export agn-eenient in automo-

    biles, foreign producers gained 38 percent of what

    domestic consumers lost, while a similar computation

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    7/18

    FECfRAL RESERVE BANK OF sr. LOWS JANUARY/FEBRUARY lOSS

    Table 1

    Distribution of Costs and Benefits from Special Protection

    Producer- consumer Losses Gains eltare costs of Restraints

    Gamn to Tariff EfficiencyTotals Per job Totals foreigners revenue loss

    (million saved (million (million (million (mmIlion

    case dollars) (dollars) dollars) dollars) dollars) dollars)

    Murutaciun mgSt-OK r-nanaoclmnra S 500 5 ~00 000 S KTh n--c S 0 5 29Benzpr-ond clrernca~ 2 650 fl? 1 2 2h0 ceo 252 14

    :n-tnt:.rl

    200 2Lno 000 1-30 meg 54 13Rr,Lbe- tr,otwoa. 230 30 000 90 rreg 139 33sc-am--; am:nrjen 9u 47.500 25 --cg 69 6erarm;clc-s 116 135000 oP ~ 55 11Orarnge u-ce 525 240 oco 39O neq 29 150Gannenlnna 9~ 7~.00Q 74 5 10 4laxnlr-s ond apoae Phase; 9.400 22 njOO 6700 ico 1 56 lOUlexlnles ond appasl Phase ml 20 000 37000 8000 350 243 3 100Texmnies and Hpnarci Phase UI oT 000 42000 22000 1 800 2.535 4850Gareo-~steel- Pt-aspi 1.970 240.000 1 330 330 290 50

    carbon steel rb-,~etn 4 30 62000(3 2 /70 940 a56 120Carbon steel Phase lit 6 $00 750 000 3 800 2.000 560 33crBail 004nnnus 43 90000 21 neq 18 -cc

    Snou only slee- 520 1 000 Xc cc so 32 30Nr-nwbner trMnwea 700 55 000 250 220 lbColor leiev-snom-s 420 420 000 190 140 77 7~B aoo; 55 93.000 n4 nt-a 32 3Bolts -Us arge svews ~10 550 000 50 nanPetared imnsnrcorns 3S 11/000 reg /5 r) 8Autrynob-les 5.800 105 000 2.1-00 2200 /90 200

    MolomnyLe~ 04 50 000 67 meg 1 1 7

    St- rv.cosMdr tnme nrouslnes 3000 270 000 2 njOO req 10 1 000

    Agr.cul~reard fnsbemnesSugar 930 60 000 550 410 -, 130

    690-acreDavy pmoduris 5 500 220 000 5 000 S0 3-4 I 370

    800 ~ow

    Pcanuis 1/0 000 dcrP 170 nag 9 14Meat - 800 150000 1 600 135 44

    725 t-paoFnsh 560 21-300 200 170 1// 5

    M-nnrgPelroneum 6 900 160 000 4 800 2 000 /0 3 000Leacljr-Lzrnc 67 30000 41- 4 I:

    Neo mneg: gnoieUnless oherwnse sr-pc -fpc. t.ommro: ire oar wor-0rEsI marco eumncs colk.clecn on sn-n) mepanns on-fnrmeo -abroaci-i Ions case becaLse of Ihe way tnt: ouctas were alnoratoni the ganrs to iporir ms arc- Led ~Urjonnestnc metnnos ratit-r tar tnmengrexporters

    SOURcE Irude Protpn Inorl nt-ne Umnn:ed blaIcs 31 Case Stuc-es

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    8/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOWS JANUARY/FEBRUARY IS

    for the latest phase of protection for carbon steel was

    29 percent.

    Finally, table 1 indicates that the efficiency losses

    ane small in compan-ison to the total losses borne by

    consumers. These efficiency losses, which are defined

    precisely and illusu-ated in the fir-st shaded insert,

    result fr-on) the excess domestic production and the

    reduction in consumption caused lw pr-otectnonisttrade policies. En laige cases such as textiles and

    apparel, petroleum, dairy pm-oducts and the maritime

    industries, these losses equal or exceed $1 billion. It is

    likely that these estimates understate the actual costs

    because they do not capture the secondary effects that

    occur as pn-oduction and consumption changes in one

    industry affect other industries.~ In addition, restric-

    tive trade policies generate additional costs because of

    hun-eaucn-atic enforcement costs and efforts by the

    pi-ivate sector to influence these policies fon- their own

    gain as well as simply comply with administrative

    r-egulations.

    Costs o/Protectionism Throughout the

    World

    In 1982, the Organization for Economic Co

    opet-ation and Development OECD) began a pn-oject to

    analyze the costs and benefits of protectionist policies

    in manufacturing in OECD countnes. The DEC131983) highlighted a numbei- ofways that protectionist

    policies have generated costs far in excess of benefits.

    Since protectionist policies increase pr-ices, the i-epon-t

    concludes that the attainment of sustained non-

    inflationary growth is hindered by such priceincreasing effects. Moreovei-, economic growth is po

    tentiallv reduced ifthe uncertainty created by varying

    tnace policies depnesses investment.

    Wood and Mudd 1978), and many others, have

    shown that impoi-ts do not cause higher unemploy-

    ment. Conversely, the OECD study stresses the fact

    that a r-eduction in imports via trade restr-ictions does

    not cause gn-eater employment. A reduction in the

    value of imports i-esults in a similar reduction in the

    5Recent estimates of the costs of protectionist policies using general

    equilibrium models suggest thai the secondary effects, to the limitedextent they are measurable, are substantial. For example, Grais, deMelo and Urata (1986) estimate that the elimination of quotas inTurkey in 1978 would have caused a 5.4 percent rise in grossdomestic product, while Clarete and Whalley (1985) estimate thatthe elimination of tariffs, quotas and export taxes in the Philippines in1978 would have caused a 5.2 percent rise in gross nationalproduct.

    value of exports. One r-ationale for this finding is that a

    reduction in the pun-chases of foreign goods reduces

    foreign incomes and, in turn, causes reduced foreign

    purchases of domestic goods.

    While the reduction in impot-ts increases employ-

    mnent in industries that produce pn-oducts similar to

    the previously imported goods, the reduction in cx-

    por-ts decreases employment in the expor-t industries.In other words, while some jobs are saved, other-s ar-c

    lost; however-, this economic n-ealitv may not be obvi-

    ous to businessmen, labon- union leaders, politicians

    and others. Luttrell 1978) has stressed that the jobs

    saved by piotectionist legislation are more readily

    obsened than the jobs lost due to protectionist legis-

    lation. In other words, the jobs that are protected in,

    say, the textiles industry by U.S. import restrictions on

    foreign textiles are more readily apparent land publi-

    cized) than the jobs in agriculture and high technol-

    ogy industries that do riot materialize because of the

    impoi-t restrictions. These employment effects will net

    to appi-oximately zei-oY

    the OECt) study also stresses that developing coun-

    ti-ies need exports to offset their debts. Thus, pr-otec-

    tionist tn-ade policies by developed countries affect not

    only the economic activity of the developing coun

    tries, but the stability of the intet-natiorial financial

    system as debtor nations find it increasingly difficult

    to service their debts.

    Not only does a free trade policy by developed

    countries benefit developing countries, hut a free

    trade policy by developing countries benefits develop-

    ing countries. A recent World Bank study (1987) of41

    developing countr-ies compar-ed the perion-mance of

    countries following a fr-ce tr-ade policy with countries

    following a restricted trade policy. Table 2 lists the

    eRecent evidence shows that protectionist legislation actually mayreduce employment. Denzau (1987) estimated that 35,600 manu-facturing jobs were lost as a result of the September 1984 voluntaryexport restraints that limited the level of U.S. steel imports. Despitean increased employment for producers of steel (14000) and pro-ducers of inputs for steel producers (2,800), these increases weremore than offset by the 52,400 job losses by steel-using firms.These losses are due to the higher steel prices that cause steel-using firms to be less competitive in export markets and subjectthem to more foreign competition in the U.S. market.

    The World Bank study divides trade strategies into two groups:outward oriented and inward oriented. An outward-oriented strat-egy, which we call a free trade policy, is one in which trade andindustrial policies do not discriminate between production for thedomestic market and exports, nor between purchases of domesticand foreign goods. An inward-oriented strategy, which we call arestricted trade policy, is one in which trade and industrial policiesare biased toward production for the domestic market relative to theexport market.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    9/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARY/FEBRUARY 1988

    Table 2

    Annual Average Growth of Per Capita Real Gross National ProductFree Trade Restricted Trade

    Period Strongly Moderately Moderately Strongly

    1963-73 S;ngapore 9 0-~ Braznl 55% Ynngoslav-a 49% Turkey a 5--.Soutn Korea 7 1 lsrae- 5.4 Mexnco 43 Dornnr-cun Pc-publnc 34Hong Kong 6 0 Tha-and 4 9 Nngena 4 2 Burur-dn 3 2

    l-ndonesna 4 6 Turrs:a 4 0 Arger-t na 3costa Rnca 3 9 Kenya 3 9 Pakrstar 3Malays.a 3 8 Phnlnppnnes 22 Tanzanna 2 7Ivory coast 3 5 Bolnvna 2 0 Sm Lanka 2 3co-orbna 33 Honduas 1 9 Erhnoona 1 9Guaremaa 27 E Sa-vador 1 4 Chnle 1 7~amerooi 01 Madagascar 1 1 Peru i

    N-caraoua 1 I Uruguay l 5Senegal 0 6 7amb-a 1 2

    Inc-na 1.1

    Ghana 0Bang:aoesh 4Sudan 1.9

    197355 Snngapore 65 Malaysn~ 4 1 Cameroon 56 Banglacesh 20HongKong 63 Tnanlano SO lndorc-sna 40 mona 20South Korea 54 Tunrsna 29 Sn Lanka 33 Buruno 1 2

    Braz-- 1 ~ Pa~nsnan 31 Domnnncan Repub.rc 05Turkey 1 4 Yugoslavia 2 7 Efhnoona 0 4Isree. 04 cola-tb-a 1 8 Sudan 0 4Uruguay 0.4 Mexnco 1 3 Peru 1chnne 0.1 Phnlnpp-nes 1 1 Tan?anna 6

    Kcnya 0 3 Argenrnna 2 0Honduras 0 I Zamh,a 2 3Senegan 0 5 Nnqerna 2 5

    costa Rca 1 0 Bonnvna 31Guatemala 1 0 Ghana 3 2Ivory Coast 1 2 Madagascar 3 4En Savaoo 35Nncaragua 39

    SOURCE World Doveroomenn Reporl 1987 and TheEconomist l1987l

    ;rnirLnai nu-nar4n gn-uniii ni fl ii pin r.npil;r gnnnss Hr innustninenil ~einrrured mmmi- aiidiimrnn 1

    Innun_nI pniniinirl trr-emr-k tnt line II rniinritnir, tim 19mM 7% rnnnrnti ni-s luIInfl\nnlg a liii- 1mar11 pn1

    i thur .1 ri

    nd 97:; M_5 I hrrsr rrrtnmitniis hat did nut bias indi_ns stnin-ni-d path- pnnIni-~ Ike n1.nsunn is that a

    tii;tijinimdnmnlionilo~~rndrhrdrnnni-stnnmnnarknlim\ mum- nilinlniiinnn-mit nlinn~snr~mnrnlInn 11r\\ in, is mmI hn~lnl~

    mnslri-lnrnnms r~nn~\ri t_n,lri natr-~tIn~nnn lutist- rlnnl nun \~rlineniInss ~~lniin a rvstnirlnl traIt- n-nn~innnninn,ennl tinsfinn i-\mnnnpli- lInt n.m-n-ar_re amninnn.nl ginn~~tImn-atm iii n-n-rI linris n-r-nmnmnnnmnjr inremniiw

    pt-n r-.r1

    nil I inn nun,- Inn- lUh%-7% ~as U.U penlenni innnm-rnnnr)nunin--, sin-nmnnj.l~ inn triter

    1Inn rye Marie rrnrl

    in lInt- et-n,nnrrnmies stnnninr_I~ nmnni-mnierl mm n_n

    sIr jeir-mI p adi- I inn 1)7% 55 lines. r nfl tin n nit-s flint- i 9

    iir run 0 I ni-er- nil ni-s1

    nei-tn~n-Is

    Inn- stnnnI~ )nn)n(mni-, Inn nrIrnitii~ Ii.- Iin.nlrr)nlmrmniimnnir- It j)nmntnrIirnnnn~.nnnis,mnnnnstl~.~~in~i.1

    mnnrli-n-Iir,niisnnn sin

    nr,,mnni mm liii LrruinrnI tinnninmnr_r \ Un\mnn nrnnrntnmnt ni nnn~\1

    nin\nsnn~ I !ni~snrtnnnln n-n~nn~~~tint rnn.nlnnn nnr4nnnmninni.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    10/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF Si. LOUIS JAIIUARYIPEBRUARY INS

    for restricting tiade and provides explanations for the

    existence ofprotectionist trade policies.

    National he/ease

    The national defense argument says that impor-t

    barrier-s are necessary to ensure the capacity to pro-

    duce cr-ucial goods in a national emergency. While thisar-gument is especially appealing for weapons dun-ing

    a war, then-c will likely be demands from other indus-

    tn-ies that deem themselves essential. For- example, the

    footwear industry will demand protection because

    militam personnel need combat boots.

    The national defense ar-gument ignores the possibil-

    ity of purchases from friendly countries dur-ing the

    emer-gency. The possibilities of storage and depletion

    r-aise additional doubts about the general applicability

    of the aigument. If crucial goods can be stored, for

    example, the least costly way to prepare for an erner-

    gency might be to buy the goods from foreigners at the

    low world pr-ice befone an emer-gency and store them.

    Ifthe crucial goods ar-c depletable miner-al resour-ces,

    such as oil, then the restriction ofoil imports befon-e an

    erner-gency will cause a more rapid depletion of do-

    mestic r-eserves. Once again, stockpiling might be a far

    less costly alternative.

    Income Redistribution

    Since pr-otectionist tr-ade policies affect the distribu-

    tion of income, a trade restriction might be defended

    on the grounds that it fayors some disadvantaged

    group. It is unlikely, however, that trade policy is thebest tool for dealing with the perceived evils ofincome

    inequality, because ofits bluntness and adverse effects

    on the efficient allocation of resources. Attempting to

    equalize incomnes directly by tax and transfer pay-

    merits is likely less costly than rising trade policy. In

    addition, as Hickoks 19851 study indicates, trade re-

    strictions on many items increase r-ather than de-

    crease income inequality-

    Optirnurn Tariff.zirgurnent

    The optimum tar-iffargument applies to situations

    in which a country has the economic po\\el to alter

    won-Id prices. This power exists because the countr

    or a group of countries acting in consor-t like the

    Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countr-iesl is

    such a large producer- or consumer of a good that a

    change in its production or- consumption patterns

    influences world prices. For- example, by imposing a

    tarifL the countny can make tbr-eign goods cheaper.

    Since a tariffreduces the demand for foreign goods, if

    the tariff-imposing country has some mar-ket power-,

    the world price for the good will fall. The tariff-

    imposing countr will gain because the pr-ice per unit

    ofits imnports will have decreased.

    There ar-c a number of obstacles that preclude the

    widespread application ofthis ar-gnment. Few couri-

    tries possess the necessary market power and, when

    they do, only a small number of goods is cover-ed.

    Secondly, in a won-Id of shifting supply and demand,

    calculating the optimum tan-iff and adjusting the rateto changing situations is difficult. Finally, the possibil-

    ity offoreign retaliation to an act of economic warfare

    is likely. Such metaliation could leave both countries

    won-se off than they would have been in a fm-ce trade

    environment -

    Balancing the Balance o/Trade

    Many conntnies enact prDtectionist tnade policies in

    the hope of eliminating a balance of trade deficit on

    increasing a balance of tr-ade surplus. The desire to

    increase a balance of ti-ade surplus follows from the

    mer-cantilist view that larger trade surpluses are bene-

    ficial from a national perspective.

    This argument is suspect on a numben of grounds.

    First, there is nothing inherently undesir-able about a

    tr-ade deficit or- desirable about a surplus For exam-

    ple, faster economic growth in the United States than

    in the rest of the won-Id would tend to cause a trade

    deficit. In this case, the trade deficit is a sign of a

    healthy economy. Second, protectionist policies that

    r-educe irnports will cause exports to decrease by a

    comparable amount. Hence, an attempt to increase

    exports permanently relative to imports will fail. tt is

    doubtful that the trade deficit will be reduced even

    tempor-ar-ily because imnpont quantities do not decline

    quickly in r-esponse to the higher- impor-t pr-ices and

    the revenues offoreign producer-s might r-ise.

    If a country such as the United States has no market power, theworld price is fixed. Consequently, the price faced by U.S. con-sumers and producers rises by the full amount of the tariff. In theoptimum tariff case, the price faced by U.S. consumers and pro-ducers rises, but not by the full amount of the tariff. This must be thecase because the world price falls and the amount of the tariff is thedifference between the world price and the U.S. price.

    See Chrystal and Wood (1988) earlier in this issue.See Pine (1984).

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    11/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF Si. LOUIS JANUARYIFEBRUARY INS

    Protection ofJobs Public Choice

    The protection of jobs ar-gumenit is closely related to

    the balance of trade argument. Sinceareduction in

    imports via trade n-estr-ictions will result in a similar

    reduction in exports, the over-all employment effects,

    as found in the OECD 1985) study and many others,

    are negligible. While the overall effects are negligible.

    won-kens land r-esour-ce owners) in specific industriesame affected differently.

    A domestic industry faced with increased impomts

    fr-ore its foreign competition is under pressure to n-e-

    duce production and lower- costs. Pn-oductive n-c-

    sources mnust mnove fi-om this industry to other domes-

    tic industmies. Wor-ker-s must change jobs and, in some

    cases, relocate to other cities. Since this change is

    forced upon these workers, these won-ken-s hear m-eal

    costs that they are likely to resist. A similar statement

    can be made about the owner-s of capital in the af-

    fected industry.

    Workers and other mesoinr-ce owner-s ~villllikely resist

    these changes by lobbying for trade r-estr-ictions. Thepr-eviously cited studies on the costs of protectionism

    demonstt-ated that tr-ade restrictions entail substantial

    neal costs as well. lhese costs likely exceed the adjust-

    mnent costs because the adjustment costs ar-c one-time

    costs, while the costs of protectionism continue aslong as trade restrictions are maintained.

    An obvious question is why politicians supply the

    protectionist legislation demanded by workers arid

    otlier resource owner-s. A bm-anch of economics called

    public choice, which focuses on the interplay between

    individual pr-eferences and political outcomes, pro-vides an answer. The public choice liter-atur-e views the

    politician as an individual who offer-s voters a bundle

    of governmentally supplied goods in order to win

    elections. Many argue that politicians gain by pr-ovid

    ing protectionist legislation. Even though the national

    economic costs exceed the benefits, the politician

    faces different costs and benefits.

    lhose hat-med by a protectionist trade policy for a

    domestic industry, especially household consumen-s,

    will incur a small individual cost that is difficult to

    identify. For example, a consumer is unlikely to pon-

    der how much extra a shirt costs because of protec-

    tionist legislation for the textiles and apparel industry.

    The role of pressure groups, acting in their economic self-interest,has been stressed by Stigler (1g71) and Peltzman (1976). Forreferences, as well as an example of an international trade studyfocused on the interaction of politicians and interest groups, seeCoughlin (1985).

    Even though the aggregate effect is lange, the harm to

    each consumen- may be small. this small cost, ofwhich

    an individual may not even be awar-e, and the costs of

    organizing consumers deter the formationi of a lobby

    against the legislation.

    On the other hand, worker-s arid other- nesoun-ce

    owner-s are vex-v concer-ned about protectionist legisla

    tiori for their industry. liieir benefits tend to be largeindividually and easy to identity. Their voting and

    campaign contributions assist politicians who sup-

    port thein positions and penalize those who do riot.

    Thus, politiciarns are likely to respond to their de-

    mnands for- pr-otectionist Iegislationiz

    In/Cat .Industries

    Ehe preceding ar-gunient is couched in terms of

    protecting a domestic industry. A slightly different

    argument, the so-called infant industry case, is

    couched in terms ofpromoting a domestic industry.

    Suppose an industry, already established in othercountm-ies, is being established in a specific coinntrv.

    The country might riot he able to realize its compar-a

    tive advantage in this industry because of the existing

    cost and other advantages of foreign fir-nis. Initially,

    owner-s ofthe fledgling firm must be willing to suffer

    losses until the firm develops its mar-ket and lower-s its

    production costs to the level of its fon-eign rivals. Inon-den- to assist this entr-ant, tan-ill pn-otection can be

    used to shield the fir-ni fnom some for-eign competition.

    After this temnporan~period ofprotection, free trade

    should be n-estor-ed; howeven-, the removal of tariff

    protection frequently is resisted. As the industry de-velops, its political power- to thwan-t opposing legisla-

    tion also increases.

    Another- pr-oblenn with the infant industry arguniierit

    is that a tariff is not the best way to intervene. A

    production subsidy is super-ion- to a tariff if the goal isto expand pn-oduction. A suhsidv will do ibis directly,

    while a tariff has the undesin-able side effect ofr-educ

    inig consumptioti.

    In many cases, intervention might not be appr-opri

    ate at all. Ifthe infant industny is a good candidate for

    being competitive inter-nationudly, borr-ouing from the

    2Special interests benefiting from trade will likely resist the forces forprotectionist legislation. Destler and OdeIl (1987) identify exporters,industrial import users, retailers of imported products, businessesproviding trade-related services, foreign exporters, and foreign gov-ernments as interest groups capable of exerting some anti-protection pressure. Decisions about protectionist legislation resultfrom the interaction of both pro-protection and anti-protectionforces.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    12/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BAtIK OF ST. I.OUiS JANUARYIFEBRUART INS

    pr-ivate capital markets can finance the expansion.

    Investors are willing to ahsor-b losses temporarily ifthe

    prospects for- future profits ar-c sufficiently good.

    Spillover Effects

    The justification for pn-otecting an industry, infant orotherwise, frequently entails a suggestion that the

    industry generates spilloven benefits for other in

    dustrres ot individuals fon which the industry is not

    compensated. Despite patent laws, one common sug-

    gestion is that cer-tain industn-ies are not fully compen-

    sated for their- r-esear-ch arid development expendi-

    tur-es. This argument is frequently clirected toward

    technologically progressive industries where some

    firms can capture the nesults of other- finns nesearch

    and development simply by dismantling a pr-oduct to

    see how it works.

    The application of this ar-gumnent, however-, enigeti-

    den-s a niurnbem of pn-oblems. Spillovens of knowledge

    ane diffic,ult to measure. Since spilloven-s am-e not mar-

    ket tr-ansactions, they do not leave an obvious tr-ail to

    idemitifv their- heneficiar-ies. The lackofniar-ket tr-ansac-

    tions also complicates an assessment of the value of

    these spillovers. To determine the appr-optiate sub-

    sidy, one must be able to place a dollar value on the

    spillovers genen-ated by a given reseamch and develop-nient expenditure. Actually, the calculation requires

    munch mom-c than the alneady difficult task of recon-

    stn-ucting the past. It r-equir-es complex estimates ofthe

    spillovens future worth as well. Since resources are

    moved fioni other industries to the targeted industry,

    the goven-nment must tinder-stand the functioning of

    the entire economy.

    Finally, then-c are political pr-ohlems. An aggressive

    application of this an-gumuent might lead to retaliation

    and a mutually destructive tn-ade war. In addition, as

    intenest groups compete for the gover-nmental assis-

    tance, there is no guar-antee that the tight gr-oups

    will be assisted or that they will use the assistance

    efficientl.

    Strategic Trade PolicyRecent theor-etical developments have identified

    cases in which so-called stn-ategic tr-ade policy is supe-

    rior- to fl-ce trade. As we discussed earlier, decreasing

    unit production costs and market structures that con-

    tain monopoly elements ar-e conirnon hi industr-ies

    involved in inter-miational tmade. Mar-ket imperfections

    immediately suggest the potential benefits of govern

    mental intervention. In the str-ategic trade policy argu-

    ment, gover-nmnent policy can alter the terms ofcom-

    petition to favor-domestic over foreign firms and shift

    the excess returns in monopolistic mar-kets from for-

    eign to domestic fir-ms.

    Knugman 1987) illustrates an example of the angu-

    rnent. Assume that there is only one firm in the United

    States, Boeing, and one multinational Iir-m in Europe

    Airbus, capable of producing a 150-seat passenger

    aircraft. Assume also that the aim-cr-aft is pn-oduced only

    for export, so that the returns to the firm can be

    identified with the national interest. This export mar-

    ket is pn-ofitable for either fin-nm if it is the only producer;

    however, it is unprofitable for both fir-ms to pnodtice

    the plane. Finally, assume the following payoffs are

    associated with the four combinations of production:

    1) ifboth Boeing and Airbus pr-oduce the aircr-aft, each

    firm loses $5 million; 2) if neither Boeing non Ainbus

    pnoduces the aircn-aft, profits are zero; 3) if Boeing

    pn-oduces the aircraft and Air-bus does not, Boeing

    profits by $100 million and Air-bus has zero pr-oUts; and4) ifAir-bus produces the air-cr-aft and Boeing does not,

    Airbuns profits by $100 million and Boeing has zero

    profits -

    Which finnn)s) will pr-oduce the air-craft? The exam-

    ple does not yield a unique outcome. A unique out-

    come can be genen-ated if one firm, say Boeing, has a

    head stant and begins production before Airbus. tn

    this case, Boeing will n-cap pn-ofits of $100 million and

    will have deter-n-ed Airbus from emitening the niarketbecause Air-bus will lose $5 million if it enters after

    Boeing.

    Stnategic trade policy, however-, suggests that judi-

    cious gover-nmental intervention can alter the out-

    come. Ifthe Eunopean governments agree to subsidize

    Air-bus production with $10 million no mnatter what

    Boeing does, then Airbus will produce the plane. Pro-

    duction by Air-bus will yield more profits than not

    producing, no matter- what Boeing does. At the same

    time, Boeing will be cleterred fiom pnoducing because

    it would lose money. Thus, Airhus will captur-e the

    emitime rnar-ket and reap profits of $110 mnillion, $100

    mnillion of which can be viewed as a tnansfer of pr-ofits

    from the United States.

    The criticismns ofa strategic trade policy ar-c similar

    to the criticisms agaimist pr-otectimig a technologically

    pr-ogn-essive industry that gener-ates spilloverbenefils.

    Then-c are major- infonmational pn-obleniis in applying a

    3A recent volume edited by Paul Krugman (1986) examines theolicy implications of the new trade literature, See Grossmansarticle in that volume for a discussion of the information require-ments.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    13/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARY/FEBRUARY 1988

    strategic trade policy. The government must estimate

    the potential payoff of each course of action. Eco-

    nomic knowledge about the behavior of industnies

    that have monopoly elements is limited. Firms mnay

    behave competitively on- cooper-ativel~and may com-

    pete by setting pm-ices on- outpr.rt. The behavior- of rival

    govem-nments also must he amiticipated. loreign retalia-

    tiomi must be viewed as likely where substantial profits

    are at stake. In addition, many intem-est gr-oups will

    compete for the govem-nmental assistance. Though

    only a small number of sector-s can be conisidered

    poterrtiall~stmategic, many industries will make a case

    for assistance.

    Reciproci~vand the Level Playing Field

    Bhagwati and Irwin 1987) note that U.S. tnade policy

    discussions in recent year-s have frequently stressed

    the importance of fair tr-ade. The concept of fair

    trade, which is technically n-efen-red to as reciprocity,means diffen-ent things to different people.

    Under the Genen-al Agreement on Iariffs and made,

    negotiations to reduce trade ham-mien-s focus upon

    matching concessions. This form of reciprocity,

    known as first-difference reciprocity, attempts to n-e-

    duce trade barrier-s by r-equiring a country to provide a

    tariff rtduction of value compan-able to one pr-ovided

    by the other country. In this case, neciprocity is

    defined in terms of matching changes.

    Recent U.S. demands, exemplified by the Gephardt

    amendment to the cur-rent tn-ade legislation, r-eyeal an

    approach that is called fbll reciprocity. This approachseeks r-eciprocitv in terms of the level of pr-otection

    bilaterally and ovem a specific n-ange of goods. Beci-

    pn-ocitv n-equines equal access and this access can he

    deter-mined by bilatemal tnade balances. A tnade deficit

    with a trading partner is claimed to be prima fade

    evidence of unequal access. Examples ahounnd. For

    example, U.S. construction fin-mns have not had a major

    contract in Japan since 1965, while Japanese con-

    stm-uction fim-ms did $1.8 billion wonth ofbirsiness in the

    United States in 1985 alone. Recent legislation liar-s

    Japanese panticipation in U.S. public won-ks pnojects

    until the Japanese offer r-ecipn-ocal pr-ivmleges.

    As the name suggests, the fundamental argument

    for fain- trade is one ofequity. Domestic producens irm a

    fl-ce tnade country argue that foneign trade harrier-s am-c

    unfair because it places them at a competitive disad-

    vantage. In an extreme yer-sion, it is asserted that this

    unfain competition will vir-tually eliminate [1.5. mnanu

    factoring, leaving only jobs that consist primarily of

    flipping hamburgers at fast food restaun-ants on-, as

    Bhag%%-ati and Inwin have said, rolling mice cakes at

    Japanese-owned sushi bar-s. While domestic pm-o-

    ducers are relatively disadvantaged, the wisdom ofa

    pn-otectionist response is doubtful. Again, the costs of

    pr-otectionismn exceed substantially the benefits froni a

    miatiorial perspective.

    In an attempt to reinfon-ce the ar-gument for fair

    tnade, pr-oponents also an-gue that n-etaliatory thn-eats,

    combined with changes in tariffs and miontamiffbarri-

    ers, allow for the simultaneous pr-otectiomi of domesticindustries against unequal comnpetition and indunce

    mon-c open fom-eign mnar-kets. This mom-c flexible ap-

    pr-oach is viewed as super-ior to a onesided free

    trade policy. lhe suggestion that a fair tnade policy

    produces a tnading environment with fewer- trade ne-

    strictions allows pmoponents to asser-t that such a

    policy serves to pn-omote both equity and efficiency. In

    other- words, not only will domestic and foreign pno-

    ducem-s in the same industry be treated equally. but the

    gains associated with a fneer tr-ading envir-onment will

    he n-ealized.

    On the other- hand, critics ofa fair trade policy argue

    that such a policy is simply disguised protectionisni

    it simply achieves the goals of specific intemest

    gn-otnps at the expense of the nation at lam-ge. In mnany

    cases, fair tr-ader-s focus ori a specific pr-actice that can

    be portr-ayed as pn-otectionist while ignon-imig the entine

    package ofpolicies that are affecting a nations comn-

    petitive position. In these cases, the fon-eign coumitmv is

    muon-c likely either not to respond or retaliate by in-

    cr-easing r-athcr- than n-educing their tracle barriens. In

    the latter- case, the escalation oftrade han-mien-s causes

    losses for- both nations, which is exactly opposite to

    the alleged efiects of an activist fair trade policy.

    Critics of fain trade proposals ar-c especially both-

    er-ed by the use of bilateral trade deficits as evidence of

    unfair trade. In a world of many tn-ading countries, tle

    trade between two countnies need not be balanced for

    the tr-ade of each to be in global balance. Diffemimig

    demands and pr-oductive capabilities across countries

    will cause a specific coumitry to have trade deficits with

    some countries and sur-pluses with other- counitmies.

    These bilateral imbalances an-c a rionmual result of

    coumitmies tradimig on the basis of comnpar-ative advan-

    tage.4

    Thus, the focuns on the hilater-al tnade deficit can

    produce inappr-opriate conclusions about fain-ness

    and, niiore impor-tantly, policies attempting to elimi-

    nate bilatenal trade deficits ar-c likely to be very costly

    becaunse they eliminate the gains from a multilateral

    tn-ading system.

    ~Bergstenand Cline (1985) estimate an equilibrium U.S-Japanesebilateral trade deficit of $20$25 billion annually.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    14/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK Of ST. LOUIS JANUARY/FEBRUARY INS

    CONCLUSION

    The pr-olifer-ation of pnotectm()nist tr-ade policies in

    recemit year-s pm-ovides an impetus to m-econsidem their

    wor-th. In the won-id of tr-aditionial trade theory, chan-ac

    terized by perfect competition, a definitive recoin

    mendatiori in favor- of fl-ce trade can he made. The

    gains fnonii initen-nationial trade result fm-om a m-ealloca

    tioni ofpn-oducti~em-esour-ces towam-d goods that cami he

    lino(lumced less costly at home than abroad amid theexchange ofsome of these goods for goods that can he

    pm-odunced at less cost aljnoad than at home.

    Recent developments in inter-national tm-ade theory

    have examitied the consequences of international

    tr-ade in mar-kets when-c tliene ar-c nianket imperfec-

    tions, such as momiopoly and technological spillo\er-s.

    Do these imperfections justitv protectionist trade poli-

    cies? The answer- continues to he no. While protec-

    tionist trade policies may offset monopoly power- over-

    seas or advantageously use domestic moniopol~

    power, trade restrictions tend to reduce the competi-tion faced by domestic producers, protecting domes-

    tic producer-s at the expense of domestic conisunIens.

    chic empirical evidence is clear-cut. The costs of

    pr-otectionist tr-ade policies far exceed the benefits.

    the losses suffer-ed by consumer-s exceeml the gains

    reaped by domestic pr-oducens and government. Low-

    inconiie consumer-s ar-c nelatively more adversely af-

    fected than high-income consumers. Not only are

    then-c inefficiencies associated with excessive domes-

    tic production and restricted consumption, but then-c

    ane costs associated with the enfor-cemnent of the pm-o

    tectionist legislationm and attempts to influence tradepolicy.

    The primam~reason for these costly protectionist

    policies relies on a public choice an-gumemit. The desireto influence trade policy arises froni the fact that trade

    policy changes benefit some gr-oups, while har-ming

    others. Consumer-s are ham-med by pr-otectionist legis-

    lation; however-, ignor-ance, small individual costs, and

    the high costs of or-ganizing consumers pr-event the

    consumers from beirig an eflective for-ce. On the other

    hand, wor-ken-s and other resour-ce owner-s in an indus-

    tn-v ar-c mor-e likely to be effective politically because of

    their relative ease ofom-ganizing and their- individually

    large and easy-to-identify benefits. Politicians inter--

    ested in reelection will most likely respond to the

    demands for- pmotectionist legislation ofsuch an inter-

    est group.

    Ihe enmpimical evidence also suggests that the ad-

    ~er-seconsumer effects ofpr-otectionist trade policies

    ame riot shor-t-lived. These policies genem-ate lower eco-

    nomic gn-owth n-ales than the rates associated with fr-ce

    trade policies. In turn, slow gr-owth contributes to

    additional pr-otectionist pressum-es.

    Interest gr-oup pressunes from industries expenienc-

    ing difficulty and the gener-al appeal ofa level playing

    field combine to make the reduction oftrade hiar-riersespecially difficult at the present timmic in the United

    States. Nonetheless, national inten-ests will be served

    best by such an admittedly difficult political comm-se. Imi

    light of the cur-rent tJmuguay Round negotiations un-

    der- the General Agn-eement on Taniffs and Tm-ade, as

    well as numerous bilateral discussions, this fact is

    especially timnely.

    REFERENCES

    Bergsten. C. Fred, and William R. Cline. The United States-JapanEconomicProblem (Institute for International Economics, October1985).

    Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and Douglas A. Irwin, The Return of theReciprocitarians U.S. Trade Policy Today, World Economy(June 1987), pp. 10930.

    Brander, James A. Intra-Industry Trade in Identical Commodities,JournalofInternational Economics(February 1981), pp. 114.

    Brander, James A.. and Paul R. Krugman. A Reciprocal DumpingModel of International Trade, JournalofInternational Economics(November 1983), pp. 31321.

    Chrystal, K. Alec, and Geoffrey E. Wood. Are Trade Deficits aProblem? this Review(January/February 1988), pp. 5i 3.

    Clarete, Ramon L., and John Whalley. interactions Between TradePolicies and Domestic Distortions, Center for the Study of Inter-national Economic Relations Working Paper 8522C (London, On-tario: University of Western Ontario, 1985).

    Coughlin, Cletus C. Domestic Content Legislation: House Votingand the Economic Theory of Regulation, EconomicInquiry (July1985), pp. 43748.

    Denzau, Arthur T. How Import Restraints Reduce Employment,Washington University Centerfor the Study of American Business,Formal Publication #80 (June 1987).

    Destler, I. M., and John S. Odell, Anti-Protection: Changing Forcesin United States Trade Politics (Institute for International Eco-nomics, 1987).

    Dixit, Avinash K., and Victor D. Norman. Theory of InternationalTrade(Cambridge University Press, 1980).

    Dixit. Avinash K., and Joseph E. Stiglit2. Monopolistic Competitionand Optimum Product Diversity, American Economic Review(June 1977), pp. 297308.

    The Economist. July 4,1987, p.74

    .

    Grais, Wafik, Jaime de Melo, and Shujiro Urata. A General Equilib-rium Estimation of the Effects of Reductions in Tariffs and Quanti-

    tative Restrictions in Turkey in 1978, in T. N. Srinivasan and JohnWhalley, eds. General Equilibrium Trade Policy Modeling (MITPress, 1986).

    Grossman, Gene M. Strategic Export Promotion: A Critique, Stra-tegic Trade Policy and theNew InternationalEconomics in Paul R.Krugman, ed. (MIT Press, 1986), pp. 4768.

    Helpman, Elhanan. International Trade in the Presence of ProductDifferentiation, Economies of Scale and Monopolistic Competi-tion, Journal ofInternational Economics (August 1981), pp. 30540.

    Hickok, Susan. The Consumer Cost of U.S. Trade Restraints,Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review (Summer1985), pp. 112.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    15/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOWS

    Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, Diane T. Berliner, and Kimberly Ann Ellioti,TradeProtection in theUnitedStates:31 Case Studies (Institute forInternational Economics, 1986).

    Kearl, James R., Clayne L. Pope, Gordon C. Whiting, and Larry T.Wimmer, A Confusion of Economists? American EconomicReview, Papers and Proceedings (May 1979), pp. 2837.

    Kierzkowski, Henry K. Recent Advances in International TradeTheory: A Selective Survey, OxfordReviewofEconomicPolicy(Spring 1987), pp. ii9.

    Krugman, Paul R. Is Free Trade Pass? Journalof EconomicPerspectives (Fall 1987), pp. 131-44.

    Strategic Trade Policy and theNew InternationalEco-nomics (MIT Press, 1986).

    Lancaster, Kelvin. Intra-Industry Trade Under Perfect MonopolisticCompetition, JournalofInternational Economics(May 1980), pp.15175.

    Variety, Equity, and Efficiency (Columbia UniversityPress, 1979).

    Leibenstein, Harvey. Beyond Economic Man (Harvard UniversityPress, 1980).

    Luttrell, Clifton B. Imports and Jobs The Observed and theUnobserved, this Review (June 1978), pp. 210.

    Mill, John Stuart. PrinciplesofPolitical Economy, W. J. Ashley, ed,

    (Longman, 1909).Morici, Peter, and Laura L. Megna. U.S. EconomicPolicies Affecting

    Industrial Trade: A Quantitative Assessment (National PlanningAssociation, 1983).

    Munger, Michael C. The Costs of Protectionism: Estimates of theHidden Tax of Trade Restraint, Washington University Center for

    JANUARY/FEBRUARY 1988

    the Study of American Business, Working Paper #80 (July 1983).

    Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development(OECD). Costsand Benefits ofProtection (1985).

    Page, Sheila. The Rise in Protection Since 1974, OxfordReviewofEconomicPolicy(Spring 1987), pp. 37Si.

    Peltzman, Sam, Toward a More General Theory of Regulation,JournalotLawand Economics (August 1976), pp. 211-40.

    Pine, Art. Footwear Industry Tells Congress Shoe Gap Threatens

    U.S. Defense, Wall StreetJournal, August 24, 1984.Ricardo, David. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation

    (Penguin, 1971).Stigler, George J. The Theory of Economic Regulation, BellJour-

    nal ofEconomics and ManagementScience (Spring 1971), pp. 321.

    Stolper, Wolfgang, and Paul A. Samuelson, Protection and RealWages, ReviewofEconomicStudies (November 1941), pp. 5873.

    Tarr, David G., and Morris E. Morkre. AggregateCosts totheUnitedStates ofTariffs and Quotas on Imports: General Tariff Cuts andRemovalofQuotas on Automobiles, Steel, Sugar, and Textiles,Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commis-sion (December1984).

    Venables, Anthony, and Alasdair Smith, Trade and Industrial Pol-

    icy Under Imperfect Competition, Economic Policy (October1986), pp.62172.

    Wood, Geoffrey E., and Douglas R. Mudd. The Recent U.S. TradeDeficitNo Cause for Panic, this Review (April 1978), pp. 27.

    World Bank. World Development Report 1987 (Oxford UniversityPress, 1987).

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    16/18

    FEDERAl. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARYIFEBRUARY INS

    Appendix

    Developments in International Trade Theory and theGains from Trade

    Since 1817, numerous developments have taken

    place in inter-national trade theory. The consequencesof mone than one factor ofpn-oduction, increasing amid

    decn-easing unit pn-oduction costs, amid imper-fectly

    competitive markets are examined mi this appemmdix.

    Special attention is focused on developments in inten-

    natiomial tm-ade theory in the last decade.

    Increasing the Number ofFactors of

    Production

    Assume that, in the United States, two resoun-ces,

    labor- arid capital (e.g., machinesi, ar-c used in the

    pr-oduction of two goods, automobiles amid air-planes.The pnices of these resources will be affected differ-

    ently by tr-ade. As trade develops, demnanid for- the

    exported good that is, the good in which the United

    States has a comparative advantage) will incnease amid

    demand for U.S. pr-oductiomi of the imported good will

    fall. hhis demand shift causes the price of the ex-

    ported good to rise nelative to the pr-ice of the ire

    ported good. Similar-h, the shiff may also pn-oduce

    changes imm the pr-ices of r-esoun-ces: however-, these

    pm-ice changes an-c not always obvious.

    Initially, assumne that the resoum-ces cannot be tm-ans

    ferred across industnies. For examnple, the labor- and

    capital used to pr-oduce automobiles, the good im

    ported into the United States, cannot he used to pro-

    duce aimplamies, the expon-ted good. Consequently, as

    the pr-ice of airphanes n-ises imi the United States, the

    compensation for- lahor and capital in the air-plane

    industry will rise; meanwhile, the decline in automo-

    bile pr-ices causes a decline in compensation for- labor

    and capital in the industry. It would riot be surpn-ising

    if labor and owners of capital in the imidustrv would

    mesist such changes by asking for- tn-ade pm-otection.

    While resources may not be easily transfer-n-edacr-oss industries imi the shont n-un, worker-s can change

    jobs and capital cart be moved as time passes. hf

    resources are mobile, then the longer-run conse-

    quences for- labom- and owmiens of capital an-c different

    from those described above. Even iflahor and capital

    are perfectly mnobihe, however, one set of mesource

    owner-s may benefit while another- gn-oup is har-mned by

    trade.

    The real world is more complicated than this dis-

    cussion has allowed. Them-c are mon-c thami two factor-sof pr-oduction amid vamyimig degrees of mobility for

    these factor-s. For example, the U.S. labor- for-ce contaimis scientists and engirmeers as well as shorton-dem-

    cooks. Nonetheless, the underlying analysis does sug-

    gest somne generalizations. When trade occur-s, owners

    of the resoun-ces that ar-c mor-e specialized imi the

    pn-oduction ofexport goods will tend to become weal

    Who wins and who loses? It depends on the U.S. endowment ofcapital to labor relative to other countries. If the United States hasrelativelylarger amounts of capital to labor relative to othercountries,then owners of capital would benefit, while labor would be harmed.

    This result follows from the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem (Stolperand Samuelson, 1941). In the example. the United States is definedto be capital-abundant. The example also implicitly assumes thatairplanes are produced by capital-intensive methods and automo-biles by labor-intensive methods, Thus, the production of airplanesrequires the use of more capital relative to labor than automobiles,Since the United States is relatively well-endowed with capital andthe production of airplanes is capital intensive, the United States willhave a comparative advantage in the production of airplanes. Withthe elimination of trade barriers, the relative price of airplanes toautomobiles will increase. The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem showsthat an increase in the relative price of the capital intensive good willincrease the return to capital relative to the prices of both goods andreduce the return to labor relative to the prices of both goods.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    17/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARY/FEBRUARY 1988

    thier; those who own n-esoun-ces mon-c specialized in

    the production of import-competing goods will tend

    to lose wealth. People also gain or- lose, howeven,

    depending on what happens to the pr-ices of the goods

    they buy. Individuals who chiefly consume imported

    goods will benefit, while those who pr-efer- consuming

    the exported goods will lose. Thus, the net effect on

    any individual depends on both the gains or losses

    associated with the price changes on the goods thathe consumes and the effect oftrade on his wealth (or-

    income I.

    Increasing UnitProduction Costs

    A second assumption underlying the Ricandian ex-

    ample of the gains fr-ore trade is that unit production

    costs are constant. If unit production costs rise as

    more is produced, however, the general conclusions

    about the gains fr-nm tr-ade remain essentially un-

    changed. The major- difference is that rising unit pro-

    duction costs limit the extemit to which speciahizatiomioccurs.

    Decreasing UnitProduction Costs and

    Imperfect Competition

    On the other hand, if unit production costs de-

    crease as production increases, the extent to which

    actual trade patterns can be explained by comparative

    advantage becomes unclear. lt also fonces tr-ade theory

    to deal with nunmerous char-acteristics ofinternational

    trade in the real wor-hd. The market structure ofindus-

    tries engaged in tnade is fr-equently highly concen-

    tnated. In other words, the individual firms in an

    industry, contrany to those in a perfectly competitive

    industry, can affect the manket price oftheir good by

    their productiomi and advertising decisions. In addi-

    tion, trade statistics show that intra-industny trade

    (i.e., the simultaneous export and import of the output

    of the same industnz accounts for- incn-easinglv larger

    shames ofwon-Id trade.

    In Ihe last decade, trade theorists have developed

    numnen-ous models to deal with these facts. An exhaus-

    tive r-eview of this rapidly expanding hitenature is be-

    yond the scope of this appendix; howeven, a few illus-trative articles are discussed in order to establish

    some key points. Brander (1981) and Br-ander and

    Knugman (1983) developed models using a homogene-

    ous good to highlight how imperfect competition can

    cause intra-industry trade and how intna-industry

    tn-ade can arise in the absence of cost differences.

    Assume two countries with one firm in each coun-

    try. The firms an-c pmoducing a homogeneous good

    under identical cost situations and then-c am-cno trans-

    pontation costs. Each firm openates under what istermed a Cournot comijectun-e, meaning that each

    firm assumnes its pmoduction decision ivill not affect its

    rivals pmoduction decision. Before inter-national tnade,

    each firm has a monopoly position in its home man-ket.

    Aliowing for- fr-ce trade induces each fin-rn to emiter the

    othen br-ms niarket, because price exceeds mnamginalcost in each coumitry. Thus, the same good will flow to

    and fr-om each country.

    Kierzkowski l1987n has noted that the bulk of intn-a-

    industry trade involves differentiated rather than ho-

    mogeneous goods. Two approaches, Lancasters

    (1979) chanacteristics approach and Dixit and Stighitzs

    (1977) hove of variety appr-oach, have pr-ovided the

    foundation for- trade models involving differentiated

    goods.

    In the chanactenistics approach, individuals have

    pn-eferences for- the characteristics of goods m-ather

    than for- collections of time goods themselves, A group

    of goods is defined as goods possessing the sanre

    characteristics but in diffem-ent pn-oportions. A diversity

    in consumner pr-eferences causes different consumner-s

    to pr-efen different products (i.e., vanieties) ofa gr-oup of

    goods.

    Fleipman (1981) and Lancaster)lSSD) used the char--

    actem-istics approach to show how intra-industry tnade

    results fnom combining the demand for- variety with

    economies of scale, The change fr-om autan-chy to free

    trade enlarges the mar-ket and causes output of the

    existing varieties to increase and the production of

    new varieties to begin. Consumers gain from the pro-

    ductiomm of more varieties and lowem pr-ices as econo-

    mies of scale are realized,

    The sources ofgains from tr-ade are identical using

    the love-of-variety and character-istics appr-oaches. In

    the love-of-variety approach, which is used by Dixit

    and Norman )1980r, consumers have identical tastes

    and prefen to consume as many types of the differenti-

    ated product as possible.

    The introduction of imperfect competition and de-

    clining unit pm-oduction costs suggest three sources of

    gain from free trade. As the market potentially served

    by firms expands fi-om a national to a world market,

    there will be gains due to declining unit production

    costs. The second is the reduction in nmonopol~power

    of firnms faced with foreign competitors. The thin-d isthe gain to consumer-s fm-onn lower prices and in-

    creased product variety. Gener-ally speaking. gains

    from trade result from the increase in competitive

    pr-essures as the domestic econonmy becomes less

    insulated from the world economy. Nonetheless, time

    numerous market structur-es and firm hehavions pos-

    sible under imperfect competition preclude a defini-

    tive statement about the optimahity offr-ce trade.

  • 7/31/2019 Protectionist Jan Feb1988

    18/18

    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS JANUARYIFEBRUARY ISa

    Figure 3

    Ttj~

    P4V

    ICUS

    D~512

    ~ D~5

    a

    The demand curve is D,, and the marginal cost curve is

    MC,,~.(The mnarginah revenue curve associated with lJ,,~

    is omitted.) The monopoly pr-ice and output are P,~

    and Q~

    The change from autarchy to free tnade transforms

    the national monopolies into a world duopoly. As-

    suninng the firnis follow a Cournot str-ate~, price

    declines from P~ to P,~, sales in the United States

    incnease from Q,,, to Ii,,,, and consumers gain an-ca P~

    ES P,, or h + i. Profits ignoring fixed costs) in the

    United States decline fr-om area P,,, RWM or i + j + k toarea P, SXM or j + k + 1. The domestic firm has one-half ofthe domestic market, so its profits an-c j with k +I going to the foreign firm. The domestic firms expon-ts

    allow it to captune one-half of the foreign mar-ket. Ifthe

    foreign mar-ket is identical to the domestic market, the

    firms profits on ibr-eign sales will equal k + I. There-

    fore, the net reduction in the domestic fin-rns profits is

    I and the overall welfare gain to the economy is

    h + I.

    Sometimes the benefits of expanded consumption

    resulting from fl-ce trade an-c less than the costs associ-

    ated with distorted pr-oduction. Venables and Smith

    (1986) pn-ovide a graphical illustn-ation, duplicated in

    figure 3, of the preceding point using the Br-ander-

    Kr-ugman duopoly model. Assume the U.S. market and

    the market in the rest of the won-Id for- a specific good

    are monopolies, the good is produced at a constant

    marginal cost, and there are no tr-ansportation costs.

    Ifthe assumption of identically sized domestic and

    foreign mar-kets is dropped, then a different conclu-

    sion is possible. Ifthe foreign market is smaller- than

    the domestic, the profits of the domestic firm in the

    foreign market will be less than k + 1 . Assuming zero

    exports, the domestic gains fr-nm trade are h k, and

    the domestic economy could lose from fnee trade. In

    this case, consumer- gains can be mon-c than offset by

    the shifting of profits fi-onm the domestic to the fbreign

    economy. lhis shifting reflects the contraction of an

    activity that is already too little to an even smaller- level.

    TI

    w~x