21
Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Case of Both Normative and Coercive Ties to the World Polity Rachel Sullivan Robinson Received: 15 October 2012 / Accepted: 26 May 2014 Ó Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2014 Abstract During the 1980s and 1990s, two-thirds of sub-Saharan African coun- tries adopted national population policies to reduce population growth. Based on multivariate statistical analysis, I show that countries with more ties to the world polity were more likely to adopt population policies. In order to refine world polity theory, however, I distinguish between normative and coercive ties to the world polity. I show that ties to the world polity via international nongovernmental organizations became predictive of population policy adoption only after the 1994 United Nations International Conference on Population and Development institu- tionalized reproductive health as a global norm to which countries could show adherence through population policies. Ties to the World Bank in the form of indebtedness, presumed to be coercive, were associated with population policy adoption throughout the time period observed. Gross domestic product per capita, democracy, and religion also all predicted population policy adoption. The case of population policy adoption in sub-Saharan Africa thus demonstrates that ties to organizations likely to exert normative pressure are most influential when some- thing about international norms is at stake, while ties to organizations with coercive capacity matter regardless of time, but may be easier for wealthier countries to resist. Keywords Population policy Sub-Saharan Africa Institutionalism International Conference on Population and Development International nongovernmental organizations R. S. Robinson (&) School of International Service, American University, 4400 Massachusetts Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 20016-8071, USA e-mail: [email protected] 123 Popul Res Policy Rev DOI 10.1007/s11113-014-9338-5

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Case of Both Normative and Coercive Ties to the World Polity

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Caseof Both Normative and Coercive Ties to the WorldPolity

Rachel Sullivan Robinson

Received: 15 October 2012 / Accepted: 26 May 2014

� Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2014

Abstract During the 1980s and 1990s, two-thirds of sub-Saharan African coun-

tries adopted national population policies to reduce population growth. Based on

multivariate statistical analysis, I show that countries with more ties to the world

polity were more likely to adopt population policies. In order to refine world polity

theory, however, I distinguish between normative and coercive ties to the world

polity. I show that ties to the world polity via international nongovernmental

organizations became predictive of population policy adoption only after the 1994

United Nations International Conference on Population and Development institu-

tionalized reproductive health as a global norm to which countries could show

adherence through population policies. Ties to the World Bank in the form of

indebtedness, presumed to be coercive, were associated with population policy

adoption throughout the time period observed. Gross domestic product per capita,

democracy, and religion also all predicted population policy adoption. The case of

population policy adoption in sub-Saharan Africa thus demonstrates that ties to

organizations likely to exert normative pressure are most influential when some-

thing about international norms is at stake, while ties to organizations with coercive

capacity matter regardless of time, but may be easier for wealthier countries to

resist.

Keywords Population policy � Sub-Saharan Africa � Institutionalism �International Conference on Population and Development �International nongovernmental organizations

R. S. Robinson (&)

School of International Service, American University, 4400 Massachusetts Avenue, NW,

Washington, DC 20016-8071, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

123

Popul Res Policy Rev

DOI 10.1007/s11113-014-9338-5

Introduction

What determines when and whether countries adopt policies? Research across a

variety of disciplines tells us that policies are not the result of a simple cost-benefit

analysis where the policy adopted is the one that costs the least, helps the most

people, or has the greatest evidentiary base (Nathanson 1996; Wedel et al. 2005;

Yanow 1996). Instead, countries adopt policies in response to both local

constituencies and global considerations and for reasons that often appear far from

rational. In particular, neo-institutionalist scholars have found that countries’

differential levels of embeddedness in the world polity—the global set of

organizations, beliefs, and values that reflect much of modernity—are often

strongly associated with state-level behavior (e.g., Frank et al. 2000; Meyer et al.

1977; Simmons and Elkins 2004; True and Mintrom 2001). These scholars

frequently operationalize ties to the world polity by the number of international

nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) that have either individual or organiza-

tional members in a country, and argue that such ties transmit norms about the

appropriate ways for nations to behave, thus driving much policy behavior (Boli and

Thomas 1997; Meyer 2004).

To refine world polity theory, it is necessary to better understand when global

norms are most influential to national-level behavior, and when ties to the world

polity might actually coerce countries into behaving in particular ways. This article

thus uses the case of population policy adoption in sub-Saharan Africa—where

during the 1980s and 1990s two-thirds of countries announced national population

policies to reduce population growth—to tease out when norms matter most to state-

level behavior, to theorize and demonstrate the influence of coercive and normative

pressure on policy adoption, and to assess the relative role of country-level

characteristics in policy adoption. Understanding the policy response to high

fertility in sub-Saharan African countries is more than an academic exercise. In

these countries, women have on average five children in their lifetimes, so lowering

fertility is key to reducing the world’s highest levels of maternal mortality and thus

meeting Millennium Development Goal Five, and will strongly influence global

population size in coming years (Ahmed et al. 2012; Population Reference Bureau

2013; United Nations 2011).

The general conclusion of world polity research is that above and beyond

national characteristics, countries have adopted policies in response to the world

polity (Schneiberg and Clemens 2006). Scholars working from this perspective have

shown the influence of ties to the world polity on economic policies (Henisz et al.

2005; Macpherson 2006; Macpherson and Weymouth 2012; Simmons et al. 2006;

Simmons and Elkins 2004), environmental policies, laws, and ministries (Frank

et al. 2000; Matisoff 2008), educational systems (Meyer et al. 1977, 1992), human

rights treaty ratification (Hafner-Burton and Tsutsui 2005), women’s suffrage

(Ramirez et al. 1997), and bureaucracies for gender mainstreaming (True and

Mintrom 2001). World polity scholars often cite the fact that few countries fully

implement policies, a so-called decoupling between intent and action, as evidence

that those policies were adopted primarily to achieve externally oriented symbolic

goals (Meyer et al. 1997; Meyer and Jepperson 2000).

R. S. Robinson

123

Previous research on population policy adoption has similarly found a strong

explanatory role for the world polity (Barrett 1995; Barrett and Frank 1999; Barrett

et al. 2010). Because this previous research covered policy adoption only through

1990, it necessarily excluded the majority of population policy adoptions in sub-

Saharan Africa, which occurred after that date. This article thus expands the

geographic scope of research on population policy, and through an event history

analysis with cross-national data makes two additional contributions to our

understanding of how ties to the world polity influence policy adoption. First, I

show that normative ties to the world polity through international NGOs became a

significant predictor of population policy adoption only after the United Nations

International Conference on Population and Development in 1994. This conference

institutionalized the right to reproductive health,1 and I argue motivated countries

without population policies to adopt them as a means to show adherence to global

norms about women’s rights. Second, I provide evidence for the role of coercive ties

to the world polity in state-level policy behavior: the World Bank both promoted

population policy and, as a major creditor, had significant leverage over most

African countries. Across time, characteristics of countries, specifically wealth,

democracy, and religion, were also significantly associated with policy adoption.

Following a brief background on population policy, the paper uses the existing

literature as well as the experiences of particular African countries with population

policy to develop three arguments for the drivers of population policy adoption

(normative pressure, coercive pressure, and the desire for socioeconomic develop-

ment) and then examines the arguments statistically using cross-national data for all

sub-Saharan African countries.

Background

A population policy is a national policy approved by a country’s government, called

a ‘population’ policy, which aims to purposively alter the size, structure, or

geographic distribution of a country’s population (cf. May 2012). In the case of sub-

Saharan Africa, these policies have focused predominantly on reducing population

growth rates, lowering mortality levels, and shifting the urban–rural population

distribution. The texts of African population policies are quite similar and derive

primarily from reference documents resulting from international and regional

conferences on population, reflecting their origins in the world polity (Barrett et al.

2010; Meyer et al. 1997). The policies generally start with a broad statement about

the relationship between population factors and development and well-being, are

followed by a discussion of the demographic and economic situation of the country,

present policy objectives and strategies, and conclude with a description of the

institutional structures for implementing the policies as well as plans for monitoring

and evaluation.

1 According to the World Health Organization (2012), reproductive health ‘implies that people are able

to have a responsible, satisfying and safe sex life and that they have the capability to reproduce and the

freedom to decide if, when and how often to do so.’ Access to family planning is a vital aspect of

reproductive health.

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

The first countries in sub-Saharan Africa to announce population policies were

Kenya in 1967 and Ghana in 1969 (Caldwell and Sai 2007; Chimbwete et al. 2005;

Locoh and Makdessi 1996). Following these early declarations, no new policies

were adopted for almost 20 years until Kenya announced a revised policy in 1986

and Nigeria, Senegal, and Liberia adopted policies in 1988 (Harvard School of

Public Health 1988–1996/1997; United Nations Population Fund and Population

Reference Bureau 2003). This trend continued through 1999, with 27 additional

countries adopting new policies, and Ghana revising its 1969 policy. Since then, no

country without a policy has announced a new one, although countries have revised

extant policies. Table 1 describes this process year-by-year and lists the 15 sub-

Saharan countries without population policies in the note. Although the impact of

population policies is beyond the scope of this paper, previous research shows that

countries that adopted population policies received, on average, more funding from

the United States Agency for International Development (Barrett and Tsui 1999). In

addition, countries with population policies experienced statistically greater fertility

declines between 1987 and 2002 than those without such policies: 21 % compared

to 14 % (author’s calculations from World Bank (2009)).

There are three arguments for why African countries adopted population policies.

First, ties to the world polity may have transmitted norms about the importance of

human rights in general, and the linkage between population and development

(Barrett 1995; Barrett and Frank 1999; Barrett et al. 2010). Second, coercive

pressure from international organizations may have been the primary driver (e.g.,

Connelly 2006; Hartmann 1995; Liagin 1996). Third, a rational desire by

governments to slow population growth in order to foster socioeconomic

development (e.g., Chamie 1994; Lacey 1990; Nassim and Sai 1990) may have

led to the adoption of population policies. I present each of these arguments below,

illustrating with examples from the population policies themselves and particularly

from the cases of Kenya, Tanzania, and Nigeria. I then turn to testing the relative

weight of the three arguments for population policy adoption in the statistical

analysis.

Population Policy Via Normative Pressure

The existing cross-national research on population policy by Barrett and colleagues

(Barrett 1995; Barrett and Frank 1999; Barrett et al. 2010) draws strongly from a

world polity perspective and shows how a belief among the global community that

rapid population growth had negative implications for socioeconomic growth was

transmitted to developing countries via international population conferences and

demographic training programs. From this perspective, population policies were the

result of ‘coreless’ diffusion, whereby the first actor to adopt an innovation is not

actually the actor who created it (Barrett et al. 2010).2 Technocratic policy elites,

who participated in these conferences and were often educated abroad, helped make

2 Even if core countries do not have population policies to mimic, they have small families and are

wealthy, suggesting that smaller families could lead to greater wealth. Thornton et al. (2012) describe

such ‘‘developmental idealism’’ across countries. I thank an anonymous reviewer for making this point.

R. S. Robinson

123

population policies a reality in their home countries (Thomas and Grindle 1994), as

was the case in Kenya and Malawi (Chimbwete et al. 2005), and also in Nigeria

(Robinson 2012).

There is little doubt that ties to the world polity have influenced population policy

adoption. There is good reason, however, to probe more deeply into when a

population policy would be most likely to serve externally valued goals. Such an

opportunity emerged in 1994 when population policy became a way to express

allegiance to international norms related to human (reproductive) rights. The United

Nations hosted three major, decennial international population conferences between

1974 and 1994. Each of these conferences produced a document intended to serve as

a point of reference on population for governments and international organizations,

with the Program of Action from the 1994 conference serving that function through

2014 (McIntosh and Finkle 1995). For those countries that had not yet adopted a

population policy by 1994, I argue that the conference provided extra motivation to

do so by institutionalizing the concept of reproductive health as a human right and

making population policy a way to show support for that norm.

Table 1 Timing of adoption of population policies in sub-Saharan Africa, 1967–1999

Year Country Annual

frequency

Cumulative

frequency

Cumulative

percentage

1967 Kenya (first policy) 1 – –

1969 Ghana (first policy) 1 – –

1986 Kenya (revised policy) 1 1 2.1

1988 Liberia, Senegal, Nigeria 3 4 8.5

1989 Sierra Leone, Zambia 2 6 12.8

1990 Madagascar, Rwanda 2 8 17.0

1991 Burkina Faso, Mali 2 10 21.3

1992 Cameroon, Gambia, Guinea, Niger, Tanzania 5 15 31.9

1993 Ethiopia 1 16 34.0

1994 Chad, Ghana (revised policy) Malawi, Lesotho 4 20 42.6

1995 Cape Verde, Mauritania, Uganda 3 23 48.9

1996 Benin 1 24 51.1

1997 Botswana, Cote d’Ivoire, Namibia 3 27 57.4

1998 Central African Republic, South Africa, Togo,

Zimbabwe

4 31 66.0

1999 Mozambique 1 32 68.1

Total 32

The two earliest countries to adopt population policies, Kenya and Ghana, are included in the analysis

presented in this paper using the dates of adoption for their revised policies. The denominator for the

cumulative percentage is 47, although two countries did not exist as sovereign states until after 1986

(Namibia in 1990 and Eritrea in 1993). States that have never adopted population policies include Angola,

Burundi, Comoros, Congo, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea,

Gabon, Guinea-Bissau, Mauritius, Sao Tome and Principe, Somalia, Sudan, and Swaziland

Source: Author’s data (see text for details)

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

The global norm of reproductive health rights symbolized by the 1994 conference

signaled an end to the era of population control (Eager 2004; Hodgson and Watkins

1997; McIntosh and Finkle 1995). Although the previous two world population

conferences had produced documents well within the framework of human rights,

the 1994 Cairo Program of Action signed by 179 countries (including all countries

from sub-Saharan Africa) emphasized rights to a greater degree than ever before.

The institutionalization of reproductive health as a global norm at Cairo, the fact

that there was no associated reproductive health treaty that countries could sign, and

the implication in the Program of Action that population policies were a desirable

outcome (Findlay and Borgegard 1995; United Nations 1995) suggest that

population policy adoption after the conference became a means to show allegiance

to international norms. And indeed, when comparing the policies written before and

after the conference, there is a steady increase in the number of mentions of ‘rights.’

Those adopted after 1994 mention rights on average 8.8 times per policy, while

those adopted before 1994 mention rights only 6.4 times.3

Population Policy Via Coercive Pressure

World polity interpretations of policy adoption by developing countries have

downplayed the coercive aspects of ties to the global community (see True and

Mintrom (2001) for a good discussion). Although research emphasizing normative

diffusion notes the importance of power differentials (Henisz et al. 2005; Simmons

et al. 2006) and there is excellent research showing inequality in the world polity

(Beckfield 2008, 2010; Hughes et al. 2009; Smith and Wiest 2005), research in this

tradition has tended to privilege normative over coercive force. There is good

reason, however, to suspect coercion played a role in population policy adoption in

sub-Saharan African countries given African countries’ relative disadvantage in

negotiations with donors committed to population reduction, and the presence of

high fertility norms that made population policy domestically risky.

Some scholars have claimed that international organizations leveraged the

distribution of aid to force developing country governments to implement

population policies (Connelly 2006; Hartmann 1995; Liagin 1996). While direct

coercion is difficult to prove, there is little doubt that international organizations

strongly promoted population policy in developing countries (e.g., Demeny 2011),

and in Africa in particular during the 1980s. Globally, the World Bank most

emphasized the impact of population growth on economic development during the

1970s and early 1980s (Fair 2008). Because of structural adjustment programs, the

World Bank and the International Monetary Fund in the 1980s had a high degree of

leverage in most sub-Saharan African countries. In particular, the Bank’s

involvement in population-related activities on the continent accelerated at that

same time (Gibbon 1992; Mosley and Branic 1989; Sinding 1991). The United

States Agency for International Development also believed slowing population

3 Difference is significant at the p \ 0.10 level using a one-tailed t test. The increase in the number of

references to rights reflects other research in the world polity tradition which notes that national-level

policies reflect global cultural norms at the time of adoption (cf. Boli (1987) on constitutions).

R. S. Robinson

123

growth was a necessary precursor to economic development, and in the 1980s

funded the Futures Group to develop a series of presentations for a number of

countries—including many in sub-Saharan Africa—detailing the negative impacts

of population growth on the economy, health care system, schools, and beyond.

These presentations, called Resources for the Awareness of Population Impacts on

Development (RAPID), were given to policymakers and other leaders (Hartmann

1995) and are still used today.

Qualitative accounts of policy adoption in individual countries confirm the

importance of international organizations in the creation and adoption of these

policies. Kenya adopted a population policy in 1967 that was a near copy of the

report of the Population Council’s recent visit there (Chimbwete et al. 2005; Frank

and McNicoll 1987; Warwick 1982). Richey (2008) describes Tanzania’s 1992

population policy as resulting in part from international donors, including the

United Nations Population Fund, the World Bank, the International Labor

Organization, and the Economic Commission for Africa. International organiza-

tions, particularly the World Bank, were also implicated in policy adoptions in

Senegal and Nigeria (Robinson 2012; Sai and Chester 1990; World Bank 1992).

Finally, almost half of the population policy documents themselves mention

international organizations as funding preparatory meetings, outreach, and/or

publication efforts related to each policy.

That donor organizations promoted population policy, however, does not imply

that the process was entirely coercive. Adopting otherwise unsavory population

policies may have served as an act of extraversion (Bayart 2000), a strategy

whereby African leaders used their country’s disadvantageous global status to

procure resources from foreign donors. In Nigeria, adopting a policy assuaged the

World Bank’s concerns about the management of demographic growth to protect

socioeconomic development and was followed by major loans and grants from the

World Bank and the United States Agency for International Development (Liagin

1996; Sai and Chester 1990; World Bank 1991). It also formed part of a larger

political restructuring process that General Babangida, then head of state, used to

show to donors and citizens alike that Nigeria was indeed on a return path to

democracy (Robinson 2012). Tanzania and Kenya also strategically deployed

population policy in their relationships with donors. Richey (1999, 2003, 2008)

describes the Tanzanian government’s ‘strategically ambivalent’ stance on popu-

lation growth and population policy as a means to balance the competing interests of

international donors, who were in favor of population policy, and local political and

religious groups, who were against it. In Kenya, President Kenyatta put aside his

personal objection to family planning and facilitated the adoption of the 1967

population policy in part because it brought money for family planning that the

government could redirect toward maternal and child health care (Chimbwete et al.

2005). As in Nigeria, the Kenyan policy led to increased donor financing

(Chimbwete et al. 2005; Hodgson and Watkins 1997). And in many countries,

the policy explicitly referred to financing from donors, as in Benin: ‘The National

Commission on Human Resources and Population and its decentralized bodies will

attend to… the mobilization of development partners for their support for

population programs’ (Republic of Benin 1996: 99–100). Thus, although donor

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

organizations promoted population policy and had significant leverage over African

countries because of levels of debt and a continuing need for aid, African countries

simultaneously had good reason to suspect that policy adoption would lead to the

procurement of financial resources and may have manipulated and/or played along

with donors accordingly.

Population Policy to Improve Socioeconomic Development

Demographers and practitioners have described population policies as the result of

governments ‘realizing’ that they needed to slow population growth in order to

ensure socioeconomic development (Chamie 1994; Lacey 1990; Nassim and Sai

1990). According to this perspective, throughout the 1960s and 70s, relatively

robust economic growth, a desire to achieve economies of scale through large

populations, and norms favoring high fertility meant that most African governments

watched their populations grow with ‘quiet satisfaction’ (Mabogunje and Arowolo

1978: 44 as cited in Miro and Potter 1980). Improvements in well-being for most

Africans following independence in the 1960s were, however, short lived. The oil

crisis and a sharp decline in the availability of foreign exchange in the late 1970s,

combined with falling prices of primary goods during the 1980s, hit African

economies hard (Bryceson 2012; Clapham 1996). As a result, and as Fig. 1 shows,

during the 1980s, sub-Saharan African countries experienced negative gross

domestic product (GDP) per capita growth on average and did not fully recover

positive per capita GDP growth rates until after the mid-1990s. Population growth

contributed mathematically to this negative GDP per capita growth: the average

population growth rate across all sub-Saharan African countries in the 1980s was

2.9 % per year (World Bank 2009), implying population sizes would double in just

25 years.

All African population policies reflected a desire to improve well-being, and

particularly economic well-being. Indeed, of the 25 policies for which the text could

be located, all but one policy was adopted by the Ministry of Planning, the

bureaucracy charged with economic and financial matters.4 The primary objective

of all African population policies was to improve the quality of life of the

population through increased socioeconomic development, as well as reduced

mortality, decreased unemployment, slower urban–rural migration, and increased

education. As Botswana’s policy described it, ‘The policy addresses the major

concerns and issues critical to the growth, structure and characteristics of our

population and provides strategies to influence them in a manner conducive to the

attainment of sustainable human development’ (Republic of Botswana 1997:

foreword). And in Mali, ‘The Government should adopt measures to ensure… a

balance between population growth and the process of socio-economic develop-

ment’ (Government of Mali 1991: para 2.2.1). On a lighter note, Cameroon’s policy

proposed improvements to well-being more broadly defined: ‘Concerned with the

balanced and harmonious development of all aspects of the population, the national

4 The missing policies are predominantly from French-speaking countries, which is not by design, but an

anomaly of the historical record. The remaining policy (Nigeria’s) was adopted by the Ministry of Health.

R. S. Robinson

123

population policy will stress the improvement of the physical and psychic wellbeing

of Cameroonians by: the promotion of sports; the development of cultural activities;

the promotion of local tourism; the restructuring of leisure time; the promotion of

culture (such as the music and painting)’ (Republic of Cameroon 1993: 44).

At face value, then, population policies were clearly framed as means to improve

socioeconomic, human, and overall development, suggesting that poorer countries

would be more likely to adopt them. Because African leaders were under pressure

from both citizens and lenders to improve socioeconomic well-being, and although

adopting a population policy in no way guaranteed the promised positive outcomes,

adopting one looked like concrete action to both citizens and lenders. Furthermore, a

population policy was a convenient opportunity to deflect blame for poor economic

performance away from the government, making population growth the scapegoat.

Reconciling Arguments

There are thus three arguments for when and whether sub-Saharan African countries

adopted population policies. The first (Hypothesis 1) is that population policy is the

result of countries’ differential ties to organizations, particularly international

NGOs, through which norms related to human rights flowed. Based on global trends

in thinking about reproductive rights, I hypothesize that such normative pressure

was influential in African countries only after the 1994 International Conference on

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

Mea

n C

ount

ry A

nnua

l Gro

wth

Rat

e (%

)

Year

Mean Annual Population Growth Rate (w.out Rwanda)

Mean GDP Growth (five-year moving average)

Fig. 1 Mean national economic and demographic growth rates, sub-Saharan African Countries,1960–2008Note: Population growth rate excludes Rwanda because of extreme values (both positive and negative)during the 1990s. Source: World Bank (2009)

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

Population and Development institutionalized reproductive health as a human right

and turned population policies into a vehicle to show commitment to that norm. The

second argument is that population policy is the result of coercive pressure from

lender organizations (Hypothesis 2). Whether policy adoption was due to coercive

pressure, or was the result of extraversion on the part of African leaders cannot be

identified statistically, although qualitative studies provide support for both

interpretations. The third argument is that countries with higher rates of population

growth and lower rates of economic growth were more likely to adopt population

policies (Hypothesis 3). Whether they did so in the hopes that the policies would

slow population growth and improve socioeconomic development, or because doing

so was strategically beneficial in managing state-donor relationships is impossible to

discern statistically.

These three arguments for policy adoption are, of course, not mutually exclusive.

Ties to the World Bank and ties to international NGOs are both ties to the world

polity. And as the qualitative examples demonstrate, there is more driving policy

adoption than external pressure, be it normative or coercive, much of which is very

difficult to operationalize for the purpose of cross-national statistical analyses.

African countries, and poor countries in general, can and do act in their own interest

to procure resources from donors and manage relationships with more powerful

countries, even in the presence of extreme power imbalances. National-level actors

can ‘localize’ international norms (Acharya 2004), as well as assert agency over

policy processes through a variety of mechanisms (Fourcade-Gourinchas and Babb

2002). Population policy also presented states with a means to potentially deepen

state–society relationships by convincing people that they, and not the leaders of

ethnic and religious subgroups, could set the rules for how people should behave

(Migdal 2001). For example, many population policies referred to guidelines for

marriage and numbers of children. In Liberia, the policy read, ‘Programs shall be

introduced to extend and improve the registration of births, deaths and marriages to

cover the whole country’ (Republic of Liberia 1988: 18), and in Ghana, a stated

purpose of the policy was ‘to educate the youth on population matters which directly

affect them… in order to guide them towards responsible parenthood and small

family sizes’ (Republic of Ghana 1994: para. 4.3.7). And in The Gambia, the policy

stated, ‘A strategy is needed to modify cultural influences so as to promote the

attainment of the goals of the population policy’ (Republic of The Gambia 1992:

30). Thus, while the analysis below tests three specific hypotheses about ties to the

world polity as well as measurable internal characteristics, a broader set of factors

was certainly also at play.

Data and Methods

The data set includes observations starting from 1984, the year in which developing

countries, including many in Africa, indicated at the international population

conference in Mexico City that they had become more open to family planning (see

statements in Sadik (1991)). This date thus marks the beginning of the period in

which an African country could be expected to consider adopting a population

R. S. Robinson

123

policy, and also coincides with the era of increasingly intense World Bank

involvement in sub-Saharan Africa through structural adjustment. The data are

censored at 2003, 5 years after the last policy adoption in 1999. Table 2 includes

descriptive statistics for all variables in the analysis.

Year of Population Policy Adoption

The dependent variable, year of national population policy adoption, comes from

the various population documents themselves, the Annual Review of Population

Law (1988–1996/1997) and the United Nations Population Fund and Population

Reference Bureau publication Country Profiles for Population and Reproductive

Health: Policy Developments and Indicators (2003, 2005). This variable differs

somewhat from the information that comes from the biennial United Nations

publication World Population Policies (United Nations 2007) used in much

previous research (e.g., Barrett 1995; Barrett and Frank 1999; Barrett et al. 2010;

Barrett and Tsui 1999) as it refers specifically to national population policies, and

not to other documents such as development plans that include provisions about

population growth. Thus, the United Nations data conflate different types of

documents and are not ideal for testing ideas about adoption of a document called a

‘population policy.’ The date of population policy adoption used in the analysis

below differs from that of the United Nations for slightly more than half of the

countries in sub-Saharan Africa. For approximately two-thirds of those differences,

the United Nations publication indicates an earlier date. Table 1 shows frequencies

for the population policy variable for the analysis below. Table 2 shows that among

countries included in the statistical analysis, approximately three quarters adopted

population policies and the average year of adoption was 1993.

Ties to the World Polity (Hypotheses 1 and 2)

To measure the extent of normative pressure, and to test Hypothesis 1, I use the

number of ties to international NGOs from each country. These data come from the

Yearbook of International Organizations (Union of International Associations 1985/

1986–2005/2006). I use the raw count of ties to such organizations, rather than a per

capita measure, on the grounds that messages about population policy would be

targeted toward the government, and not the general population, and each country

has only one government. Results using a per capita measure are, however,

substantively the same. I take the natural log of this variable to correct for skew. On

average, countries had a total of slightly more than 200 ties to such organizations.

To measure the leverage of donor organizations in a country, and thus the degree

of coercive pressure to test Hypothesis 2, I use the extent to which the World Bank

was involved in a country, measured by the balance of International Bank for

Reconstruction and Development loans and International Development Association

credits in a given year, expressed in constant 2000 US dollars (World Bank 2009).

Again, I use the total amount of loans, rather than a per capita measure, as this better

represents the degree to which the World Bank was vested in a particular country.

(Results using a per capita measure are, again, substantively the same.) I take the

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

natural log of this variable to correct for skew. The average annual balance for a

country over the observed time period was US$271.5 million.

Hypothesis 3 and Controls

A number of characteristics of countries themselves may have also influenced

population policy adoption. Population and GDP growth rates (World Bank 2009)

reflect Hypothesis 3, that countries with more rapidly growing populations and

slower-growing economies were more likely to adopt population policies, either to

improve socioeconomic development or as an act of extraversion to garner

resources from international donors. Average annual population growth rates and

GDP growth rates balanced each other out over the time period in question, at 2.7 %

per year.

The control variables for the analysis are also all internal characteristics of

countries. GDP per capita (World Bank 2009) reflects a variety of features of a

country, including its overall capacity, as well as the degree to which donors were

able to pressure the country. On average, GDP per capita was only slightly more

than US$600. I presume that government opinion that population growth was ‘too’

high in 1987 (Sadik 1991) was a necessary, although not sufficient, predictor of

policy adoption. Three-fifths of governments believed in 1987 that population

Table 2 Descriptive statistics, analysis of population policy adoption, sub-Saharan Africa, 1984–2003

Variable Min Max Mean SD N

Dependent variable

Adopted population policy 0.00 1.00 0.74 0.45 42

Year of population policy adoption 1986 1999 1993 3.52 42

World Polity Factors

Normative Pressure

International NGOs, ln of total 1.39 6.55 5.30 0.68 510

Coercive Pressure

World Bank involvement,

ln of total loans, and credits in US$2000

12.80 21.95 19.42 1.31 508

Internal Factors

Economic and Demographic Pressure

GDP growth rate (annual %) -28.10 23.60 2.72 5.63 512

Pop. growth rate (annual %) -0.20 6.05 2.72 0.85 512

Controls

GDP per capita, ln 4.39 10.27 6.41 0.94 512

Gov. believed pop. growth too high 1987 0.00 1.00 0.60 0.48 42

Catholic population (%) 0.00 95.90 24.63 23.65 42

Democracy -10.00 10.00 -3.42 5.65 500

Conflict indicator 0.00 1.00 0.22 0.42 512

NGO is nongovernmental organization; GDP is gross domestic product

Source: See text

R. S. Robinson

123

growth in their country was too high. Catholicism is the religion with the greatest

resistance to contraception, so countries with a high percentage of the population

that is Catholic (Bratton and van de Walle 1997) were presumably less likely to

adopt a population policy (Barrett et al. 2010). On average, 24 % of the population

in each country was Catholic, but this value ranged from 0 to 96 %. Democracy

comes from the Polity IV data set (Marshall et al. 2010) and measures the polity on

a score of -10 (complete autocracy) to ?10 (complete democracy). Leaders of

democracies may have been less likely (because they feared backlash from voters),

or more likely (because they had a greater investment in social welfare to which

voters held them accountable) to adopt population policies. African countries had an

average value of -3.42 for the polity measure during the time period examined,

indicating weak autocracy. Disruption and distraction caused by conflict presumably

made countries less likely to adopt population policies. Data on armed conflict come

from the International Peace Research Institute database (Harbom and Wallensteen

2009). For a country to be classified as having experienced an armed conflict in a

given year, armed force had to have been used between two parties, one of which

was the government of the state, and resulted in 25 or more battle-related deaths.

Countries in the data set were in conflict for slightly more than one-fifth of the years

observed.

Overall Data set and Analysis Technique

I make use of a binary variable to indicate whether an observation came from 1994

or later to create an interaction term in order to test Hypothesis 1, that the impact of

ties to international NGOs was more predictive of population policy adoption after

the 1994 United Nations International Conference on Population and Development

that institutionalized reproductive health as a global norm and right.

There were 47 countries in sub-Saharan Africa by the end of 2003, of which 30

had adopted a new population policy since 1984. I include Kenya and Ghana’s

revised policies (adopted in 1986 and 1994, respectively) in the analysis on the

grounds that enough time had passed since these countries’ original policy

adoptions in the 1960s to make them again ‘at risk’ for adopting a policy.5 I exclude

Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Sao Tome and Principe, and Somalia due to large

amounts of missing data. I exclude South Africa for being an outlier in terms of

GDP and because it did not receive World Bank loans and credits during the time

period in question. In the end, the analysis includes a total of 42 countries of which

31 adopted policies: 16 before 1994, and 15 in 1994 or later. I lag the measures of

normative and coercive pressure, as well as the measures of population and GDP

growth, by 2 years in order to account for an approximate 1-year delay necessary to

obtain macroeconomic and population data, and a second, approximately 1-year

delay to react to it with policy.

5 The results of the analysis are substantively the same regardless of whether Kenya and Ghana are

included.

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

I present event history analysis results to examine which factors predict when

countries adopted population policies in a multivariate context. Specifically, I use

discrete-time methods because most of the data are available only yearly and

because such methods facilitate the management of tied data (years in which more

than one country adopted a policy). Discrete-time event-history analysis results in a

logistic regression of the following form:

logPit

1� Pitð Þ

� �¼ at þ b1xi þ b2zit ð1Þ

where Pit is the probability that country i adopts a population policy in year t given

that it has not already done so; a is a constant in year t; xi is a time-constant vector

of covariates for country i; zit is a time-varying vector of covariates for country i;

and b1 and b2 are vectors of effects describing xi and zit, respectively (Allison 1995).

Forty-one observations, covering seven countries, were missing data for World

Bank involvement, GDP growth, GDP per capita, or government opinion on pop-

ulation growth, and so were assigned the mean value for that variable for that year.

After the data were lagged, an additional six observations were dropped because of

data being unavailable for World Bank involvement and ties to international NGOs.

The final data set thus has approximately 500 observations. Because there are

multiple observations per country, time-invariant variables repeat for each country,

so I present robust standard errors to test for statistical significance. I performed the

analysis using Stata, version 12.

Results

Table 3 shows the results from the event-history analysis predicting population

policy adoption in a given year across the 42 countries in sub-Saharan Africa

included in the analysis. The first model includes the variables measuring normative

and coercive ties to the world polity (Hypotheses 1 and 2, respectively), as well as

controls. The second model includes internal factors that measure economic and

demographic pressure (Hypothesis 3), as well as controls. Model 3 includes both

world polity and internal factors. The final model interacts the measure of normative

pressure, the number of international NGOs, with an indicator for the post-1994

period.

The results from the regression analysis indicate that both ties to the world polity

and internal characteristics of countries predict population policy adoption.

Considering world polity factors, the number of ties to international NGOs is only

a significant predictor of population policy adoption after 1994 (Model 4),

supporting the argument (Hypothesis 1) that normative ties to the world polity

became more salient after the 1994 United Nations conference that institutionalized

reproductive health as a global norm. Substituting an indicator for whether a country

had an affiliate of the International Planned Parenthood Federation in a given year

as a precise measure of the local presence of a specific international organization

supportive of population policy, the effect is not significant in either period. (Results

R. S. Robinson

123

not shown.) In addition, across all models, higher levels of World Bank involvement

are positive, significant predictors of population policy adoption, supporting

Hypothesis 2 that countries that experienced greater coercive pressure were more

likely to adopt population policies.

There is no support for Hypothesis 3, that countries with low economic growth or

high population growth were more likely to adopt population policies. GDP per capita,

one of the control variables, is, however, a significant predictor of population policy

adoption across models. Indeed, poorer countries were more likely to adopt population

policies, suggesting that organizations like the World Bank would have had greater

leverage over them, that their governments might have been more desperate to take

visible action toward improving socioeconomic development, or that their leaders

may have deployed strategies of extraversion to extract resources from donors. Thus,

there is some support for the economic component of Hypothesis 3.

In addition to GDP per capita, in all but one model, the percentage of a country’s

population that was Catholic has a significant, negative relationship with population

Table 3 Coefficients from logistic regressions predicting population policy adoption, sub-Saharan

Africa, 1984–2003

Variable Model

(1) (2) (3) (4)

World Polity Factors

Normative Pressure

International NGOs 0.57 0.65 0.41

International NGOs*post-1994 0.18*

Coercive Pressure

World Bank involvement 0.87** 0.87** 0.91**

Internal Factors

Economic and Demographic Pressure

GDP growth rate 0.05 0.07 0.07

Pop. growth rate 0.19 -0.08 0.08

Controls

GDP per capita -0.63* -0.68** -0.77** -0.67*

Gov. believed pop. growth too high 1987 0.80 0.64 0.79 1.22*

Catholic population -0.04* -0.01 -0.04* -0.04*

Democracy 0.13** 0.08* 0.13** 0.10*

Conflict -1.01 -0.71 -1.07 -1.13

Intercept -18.55** 1.09 -17.99** -19.25**

N 495 500 495 495

Number of countries 42 42 42 42

Log likelihood -91.67 -104.30 -90.19 -88.23

Pseudo R2 (%) 19.0 8.1 20.3 22.0

See Table 2 for descriptions of variables

Unexponentiated coefficients; * p \ 0.05, ** p \ 0.01, *** p \ 0.001 (two-tailed tests)

Source: See text

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

policy adoption. Presumably in these countries, leaders were less willing to take on

the issue of population policy, or opposition from Catholic groups complicated the

process of policy adoption. Democracy is also significant across all models: more

democratic countries were more likely to adopt population policies. Whether

democracies had greater commitment to social welfare or responded to popular

pressure to take some action to improve the economy is impossible to tell. Model 4

shows that governments of countries who believed population growth was too high

in 1987 were significantly more likely to adopt policies. The measure of conflict is

not significant in any model, although as Table 1 shows, many of the countries that

did not adopt population policies experienced multiple years of conflict during the

time period observed.

The results of the regression analysis thus provide support for the first two

hypotheses: (1) that normative pressure from international NGOs predicted

population policy adoption only after population policy became a means to express

support for the internationally sanctioned norm of reproductive rights; and (2) that

coercive pressure from international donors was associated with population policy

adoption across time. There is also some support for the third hypothesis that a poor

economic outlook in the form of lower GDP per capita may have prompted

countries to adopt population policies. In addition, regardless of time, democracies

were more likely, and countries with larger Catholic populations were less likely, to

adopt population policies.

Of course, not all countries in sub-Saharan Africa adopted population policies.

The countries without such policies are listed at the bottom of Table 1, and in

general are quite fragile, having disproportionately suffered conflict and economic

collapse. The World Bank has lent these countries money, but proportionately less

than those with population policies, and these countries also have fewer ties to

international NGOs (results not shown). Thus, the fact that these countries have no

policy to reduce population growth reflects the conclusions drawn from the

regression analysis. At the most basic level, the economic and political chaos faced

in many of these countries likely severely limited their capacity to adopt policies of

any type, as well as prevented donors from promoting population policies to their

governments.

Conclusions

The analysis of population policy in sub-Saharan Africa provides guidance in

interpreting the role of the world polity in state-level behavior. Specifically, the

analysis above shows that ties to the world polity predict the behavior of developing

countries, but in varied ways. Ties to organizations likely to exert normative

pressure are most influential when something about international norms—

reproductive health as a human right in the case of population policy—is at stake.

Ties to organizations that can exert coercive pressure matter regardless of time, but

may be easier for wealthier countries to resist. Across time, characteristics of

countries themselves are still important: in the case of population policy,

particularly GDP per capita, democracy, and religion.

R. S. Robinson

123

What of population policy today? The global community’s interest in the topic

waned in the 1990s as HIV prevalence rose and fertility rates continued to drop

around the world. In addition, and somewhat ironically, the 1994 Cairo conference’s

emphasis on improving women’s status more broadly shifted global attention away

from contraceptive provision (Cleland et al. 2006). There has, however, been a

resurgence of interest in slowing population growth and increasing contraception

provision as the environmental movement has regained steam and the 2015 deadline

approaches to meet Millennium Development Goal Five, reducing maternal

mortality (May 2012). Indeed, the July 2012 family planning summit convened

by the Gates Foundation and DfID, the British bilateral aid agency, generated new

enthusiasm, and new financial support, for family planning (Shiffman and Quissell

2012). The renewed prioritization of family planning reflects a shift away from

reproductive health and a reemphasis on technological solutions to problems

(unwanted pregnancy, maternal mortality) that ultimately have deep social,

political, and economic roots. Given that most developing countries already have

population policies, the newfound support for family planning most likely will not

lead to new population policies. Instead, countries are more likely to revise existing

policies—as did Kenya and Malawi in 2012 (Government of Malawi 2012;

Republic of Kenya 2012)—or to develop less expansive programs and strategies

that hone in on the provision of contraception. African governments’ experiences

with population policy, however, deepen our understanding of how ties to the world

polity influence country-level action. They serve as a reminder that the global ties

that structure the world polity remain far from balanced and are highly complex,

such that understanding individual countries’ behavior requires analyzing both the

ties, as well as how countries experience and deploy the material and ideological

resources transmitted by those ties.

Acknowledgments This research was supported by a National Science Foundation Graduate Research

Fellowship as well as a Faculty Research Award from American University. It greatly benefitted from

feedback from the Berkeley Center for Culture, Organization, and Politics workshop, the Berkeley

Department of Demography Brown Bag Series, and the session on cross-national sociology at the 2006

American Sociological Association meeting. I am particularly indebted to the suggestions of the

anonymous reviewers from PRPR. I thank Yolande Bouka, Dorothy Fort, Barbara Lukunka, Katie Rice,

Jennifer Vanderburgh and Yang Zhang for their research assistance. I also gratefully acknowledge the

thoughtful comments of Deborah Barrett, Neil Fligstein, David John Frank, Shannon Gleason, Gene

Hammel, Jennifer Johnson-Hanks, Kate Haulman, Charles Kurzman, Adrea Lawrence, Damon Mayrl,

Benjamin Moodie, Aliya Saperstein, Evan Schofer, Susan Shepler, Sarah Staveteig, Ann Swidler, Bryan

Sykes, Sarah Walchuk Thayer, Sarah Tom, Kenneth Wachter, Susan Watkins, Brenda Werth, Elizabeth

Worden, and Danzhen You.

References

Acharya, A. (2004). How ideas spread: Whose norms matter? norm localization and institutional change

in asian regionalism. International Organization, 58(2), 239–275.

Ahmed, S., Li, Q., Liu, L., & Tsui, A. O. (2012). Maternal deaths averted by contraceptive use: An

analysis of 172 countries. The Lancet, 380(9837), 111–125.

Allison, P. D. (1995). Survival analysis using SAS: A practical guide. Cary, NC: SAS Institute.

Barrett, D. (1995). Reproducing Persons as a Global Concern: The Making of an Institution. Doctor of

Philosophy Dissertation, Stanford University, Stanford, CA.

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

Barrett, D., & Frank, D. J. (1999). Population control for national development: From world discourse to

national policies. In J. Boli & G. M. Thomas (Eds.), Constructing world culture: International

nongovernmental organizations since 1875 (pp. 198–221). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Barrett, D., Kurzman, C., & Shanahan, S. (2010). For export only: Diffusion professionals and population

policy. Social Forces, 88(3), 1183–1207.

Barrett, D., & Tsui, A. O. (1999). Policy as symbolic statement: International response to national

population policies. Social Forces, 78(1), 213–234.

Bayart, J. F. (2000). Africa in the World: A history of extraversion. African Affairs, 99, 217–267.

Beckfield, J. (2008). The dual world polity: Fragmentation and integration in the network of

intergovernmental organizations. Social Problems, 55(3), 419–442.

Beckfield, J. (2010). The social structure of the world polity. American Journal of Sociology, 115(4),

1018–1068.

Boli, J. (1987). Human rights or state expansion? Cross-national definitions of constitutional rights,

1870–1970. In G. M. Thomas, J. W. Meyer, F. O. Ramirez, & J. Boli (Eds.), Institutional structure:

Constituting state, society, and the individual (pp. 71–91). Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.

Boli, J., & Thomas, G. M. (1997). World culture in the world polity: A century of international non-

governmental organization. American Sociological Review, 62, 171–190.

Bratton, M., & van de Walle, N. (1997). Political regimes and regime transitions in Africa, 1910–1994

[Computer file]. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research

[distributor].

Bryceson, D. F. (2012). Discovery and denial: Social science theory and interdisciplinarity in African

Studies. African Affairs, 111(443), 281–302.

Caldwell, J. C., & Sai, F. T. (2007). Family planning in Ghana. In W. C. Robinson & J. A. Ross (Eds.),

The global family planning revolution (pp. 379–391). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Chamie, J. (1994). Trends, variations, and contradictions in national policies to influence fertility.

Population and Development Review, 20, 37–50.

Chimbwete, C., Watkins, S. C., & Zulu, E. M. (2005). The evolution of population policies in Kenya and

Malawi. Population Research and Policy Review, 24(1), 85–106.

Clapham, C. S. (1996). Africa and the international system: The politics of state survival. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Cleland, J., Bernstein, S., Ezeh, A., Faundes, A., Glasier, A., & Innis, J. (2006). Family planning: The

unfinished agenda. The Lancet, 368(9549), 1810–1827.

Connelly, M. (2006). Population control in India: Prologue to the emergency period. Population and

Development Review, 32(4), 629–667.

Demeny, P. (2011). Population policy and the demographic transition: Performance, prospects, and

options. Population and Development Review, 37, 249–274.

Eager, P. W. (2004). Global population policy: From population control to reproductive rights.

Burlington, VT: Ashgate.

Fair, M. (2008). From population lending to HNP results: The evolution of the World Bank’s strategies in

health, nutrition and population. In IEG Working Paper 2008/2003. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Findlay, A. M., & Borgegard, L.-E. (1995). Demography, destiny and population policies. Applied

Geography, 15(3), 197–202.

Fourcade-Gourinchas, M., & Babb, S. L. (2002). The rebirth of the liberal creed: Paths to neoliberalism in

Four Countries. American Journal of Sociology, 108(3), 533–579.

Frank, D. J., Hironaka, A., & Schofer, E. (2000). The Nation-State and the natural environment over the

twentieth century. American Sociological Review, 65(1), 96–116.

Frank, O., & McNicoll, G. (1987). An interpretation of fertility and population Policy in Kenya.

Population and Development Review, 13(2), 209–243.

Gibbon, P. (1992). Population and poverty in the changing ideology of the world bank. In M.

Hammarskjold, B. Egero, & S. Lindberg (Eds.), Population and the Development Crisis in the South

(pp. 133–145). Bastad, Sweden: Programme on Population and Development in Poor Countries.

Government of Malawi. (2012). National Population Policy. Lilongwe: Ministry of Economic Planning

and Development.

Government of Mali. (1991). Declaration of the National Population Policy of Mali Bamako: Ministry of

Planning and International Cooperation, National Planning Directorate.

Hafner-Burton, E. M., & Tsutsui, K. (2005). Human rights in a globalizing world: The paradox of empty

promises. American Journal of Sociology, 110(5), 1373–1411.

R. S. Robinson

123

Harbom, L., & Wallensteen, P. (2009). Armed conflict, 1946–2008. Journal of Peace Research, 46(4),

577–587.

Hartmann, B. (1995). Reproductive rights and wrongs. Boston, MA: South End Press.

Harvard School of Public Health. (1988–1996/1997). Annual review of population law. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard School of Public Health.

Henisz, W. J., Zelner, B. A., & Guillen, M. F. (2005). The worldwide diffusion of market-oriented

infrastructure reform, 1977–1999. American Sociological Review, 70(6), 871–897.

Hodgson, D., & Watkins, S. C. (1997). Feminists and neo-Malthusians: Past and present alliances.

Population and Development Review, 23(3), 469–523.

Hughes, M. M., Peterson, L., Harrison, J. A., & Paxton, P. (2009). Power and relation in the world polity:

The INGO Network Country Score, 1978–1998. Social Forces, 87(4), 1711–1742.

Lacey, L. (1990). The new generation of African population policies. In G. Roberts (Ed.), The role of the

world bank in shaping third world population policy (pp. 135–146). New York: Praeger.

Liagin, E. (1996). Excessive force: Power, politics, and population control. Washington, DC: Information

Project for Africa Inc.

Locoh, T., & Makdessi, Y. (1996). Population policies and fertility decline in sub-Saharan Africa (F.

M. Moursund, Trans.). Paris: Centre Francais sur la Population et le Developpement.

Mabogunje, A. L., & Arowolo, O. (1978). Social science research on population and development in

Africa South of the Sahara. Mexico City: International Review Group of Social Science Research on

Population and Development.

Macpherson, J. M. (2006). Palace wars and privatization: Did Chicago Beat Cambridge in influencing

economic policies. European Management Review, 3, 190–198.

Macpherson, J. M., & Weymouth, S. (2012). The social construction of policy reform: Economists and

trade liberalization around the world. International Interactions, 38(5), 670–702.

Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2010). Polity IV project dataset users’ manual. Severn, MD:

Center for Systemic Peace.

Matisoff, D. C. (2008). The adoption of state climate change policies and renewable portfolio standards:

Regional diffusion or internal determinants? Review of Policy Research, 25(6), 527–546.

May, J. F. (2012). World population policies: Their origin, evolution, and impact. Dordrecht: Springer.

McIntosh, C. A., & Finkle, J. L. (1995). The Cairo conference on population and development: A new

paradigm? Population and Development Review, 21(2), 223–260.

Meyer, J. W. (2004). The Nation as Babbit: How countries conform. Contexts, 3(3), 42–47.

Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., Thomas, G. M., & Ramirez, F. O. (1997). World society and the Nation-State.

American Journal of Sociology, 103(1), 144–181.

Meyer, J. W., & Jepperson, R. L. (2000). The ‘Actors’ of modern society: The cultural construction of

social agency. Sociological Theory, 18(1), 100–120.

Meyer, J. W., Ramirez, F. O., Rubinson, R., & Boli-Bennett, J. (1977). The World Educational

revolution, 1950–1970. Sociology of Education, 50(4), 242–258.

Meyer, J. W., Ramirez, F. O., & Soysal, Y. N. (1992). World expansion of mass education, 1870–1980.

Sociology of Education, 65(2), 128–149.

Migdal, J. S. (2001). State in society: Studying how states and societies transform and constitute one

another. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Mosley, H. H., & Branic, G. (1989). Population policy in Sub-Saharan Africa: Agendas of International

Agencies. In Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa: Drawing on International Experience (pp.

463–506). Liege, Belgium: International Union for the Scientific Study of Population.

Nassim, J., & Sai, F. T. (1990). Family planning and maternal and child health in the World Bank’s

population, health, and nutrition program. In H. M. Wallace & G. Kanti (Eds.), Health care for

women and children in developing countries. Oakland, CA: Third Party Press.

Nathanson, C. A. (1996). Disease prevention as social change: Toward a theory of public health.

Population and Development Review, 22(4), 609–637.

Population Reference Bureau. (2013). 2013 World Population Data Sheet. Washington, DC: Population

Reference Bureau.

Ramirez, F. O., Soysal, Y., & Shanahan, S. (1997). The changing logic of political citizenship: Cross-

national acquisition of women’s suffrage rights, 1890 to 1990. American Sociological Review, 62(5),

735–745.

Republic of Benin. (1996). Declaration of the population Policy of the Republic of Benin. Porto-Novo:

Ministry of Economic Restructuring and of Employment Promotion.

Republic of Botswana. (1997). National Population Policy. Gabarone: Government Printer.

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123

Republic of Cameroon. (1993). Declaration of National Population Policy. Yaounde: National

Population Commission.

Republic of Ghana. (1994). National Population Policy (Revised). Accra: National Population

Commission.

Republic of Kenya. (2012). Sessional Paper No. 3 of 2012 on Population Policy for National

Development. Nairobi: National Council for Population and Development.

Republic of Liberia. (1988). National policy on population for social and economic development.

Monrovia: National Population Commission.

Republic of The Gambia. (1992). National population policy for socio-economic development. Banjul:

National Population Commission.

Richey, L. A. (1999). Family planning and the politics of population in Tanzania: International to local

discourse. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 37(3), 457–487.

Richey, L. A. (2003). Women’s reproductive health and population policy: Tanzania. Review of African

Political Economy, 30(96), 273–292.

Richey, L. A. (2008). Population politics and development: From the policies to the clinics. New York:

Palgrave Macmillan.

Robinson, R. S. (2012). Negotiating development prescriptions: The case of population policy in Nigeria.

Population Research and Policy Review, 31(2), 267–296.

Sadik, N. (Ed.). (1991). Population policies and programmes: Lessons learned from two decades of

experience. New York: United Nations Population Fund.

Sai, F. T., & Chester, L. A. (1990). The role of the World Bank in shaping Third world population policy.

In G. Roberts (Ed.), Population policy: Contemporary issues (pp. 179–191). New York: Praeger.

Schneiberg, M., & Clemens, E. S. (2006). The typical tools for the job: Research strategies in institutional

analysis. Sociological Theory, 24(3), 195–227.

Shiffman, J., & Quissell, K. (2012). Family planning: A political issue. Lancet, 380(9837), 181–185.

Simmons, B. A., Dobbin, F., & Garrett, G. (2006). Introduction: The international diffusion of liberalism.

International Organization, 60(4), 781–810.

Simmons, B. A., & Elkins, Z. (2004). The globalization of liberalization: Policy diffusion in the

international political economy. The American Political Science Review, 98(1), 171–189.

Sinding, S. W. (1991). Strengthening the Bank’s Population Work in the Nineties Policy Research

Working Papers. Washington, DC: Population and Human Resources Department The World Bank.

Smith, J., & Wiest, D. (2005). The uneven geography of global civil society: National and global

influences on transnational association. Social Forces, 84(2), 621–652.

Thomas, J. W., & Grindle, M. S. (1994). Political leadership and policy characteristics in population

policy reform. [Article]. Population and Development Review, 20, 51–70.

Thornton, A., Binstock, G., Yount, K., Abbasi-Shavazi, M., Ghimire, D., & Xie, Y. (2012). International

fertility change: New data and insights from the developmental idealism framework. Demography,

49(2), 677–698.

True, J., & Mintrom, M. (2001). Transnational networks and policy diffusion: The case of gender

mainstreaming. International Studies Quarterly, 45(1), 27–57.

Union of International Associations. (1985/1986–2005/2006). Yearbook of International Organizations.

Brussels: Union of International Associations.

United Nations (1995) Report of the International Conference on Population and Development. Cairo:

United Nations.

United Nations. (2007). World Population Policies. New York: United Nations, Department of Economic

and Social Affairs, Population Division.

United Nations. (2011). 2010 Revision of World Population Prospects. New York: United Nations.

United Nations Population Fund, & Population Reference Bureau. (2003). Country Profiles for

Population and Reproductive Health: Policy Developments and Indicators 2003: UNFPA and

Population Reference Bureau.

United Nations Population Fund, & Population Reference Bureau. (2005). Country Profiles for

Population and Reproductive Health: Policy Developments and Indicators 2005: UNFPA and

Population Reference Bureau.

Warwick, D. P. (1982). Bitter Pills. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Wedel, J. R., Shore, C., Feldman, G., & Lathrop, S. (2005). Toward an Anthropology of Public Policy.

The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 600(1), 30–51.

World Bank. (1991). National Population Project between Federal Republic of Nigeria and International

Development Association Retrieved 11 June 2008, from http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/

R. S. Robinson

123

default/main?pagePK=64193027&piPK=64187937&theSitePK=523679&menuPK=64187510&

searchMenuPK=64187283&siteName=WDS&entityID=000114496_2004090121020411.

World Bank. (1992). Population and the World Bank: Implications from Eight Studies. Washington, DC:

World Bank.

World Bank. (2009). World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.

World Health Organization. (2012). Health Topics: Reproductive Health Retrieved 9 August 2012, 2012,

from http://www.who.int/topics/reproductive_health/en/.

Yanow, D. (1996). How does a policy mean? Interpreting policy and organizational actions. Washington,

DC: Georgetown University Press.

Population Policy in Sub-Saharan Africa

123