33
Inter-Industry Gender Wage Gaps by Knowledge Intensity: Discrimination and Technology in Korea Beyza P. Ural Department of Economics, Syracuse University, Syracuse NY, 13244, USA. William C. Horrace * Center of Policy Research, 426 Eggers Hall, Syracuse University, Syracuse NY, 13244, USA. [email protected] Jin Hwa Jung Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Seoul National University, San 56-1 Sillimdong Kwanakgu, Seoul 151-742, Korea. ABSTRACT A new gender wage gap decomposition methodology is introduced that does not suffer from identification problems caused by unobserved non-discriminatory wage structure. The methodology is used to measure the relative size of Korean gender wage gaps from 1994 to 2000 across industries, differentiated by industrial knowledge intensity, where knowledge intensity is the extent to which industries produce or employ high-technology products. Korea represents an important case study, since it possesses one of the fastest growing knowledge- intensive economies, among industrialized countries. Empirical results indicate that over this period, discrimination (the unexplained portion of the gender wage gaps) in Korea was statistically smaller in knowledge-intensive industries than in industries with low knowledge intensity. Also, discrimination was declining on average over the period. This suggests that continued growth in knowledge-intensive industries in Korea may lead to further declines in the overall gender gap. JEL Codes: C12, J31, J71 Keywords: discrimination, labor markets, wage differential, compensation. Running Title: Inter-Industry Gender Wage Gaps by Knowledge Intensity * Corresponding Author

Inter-Industry Gender Wage Gaps by Knowledge Intensity

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Inter-Industry Gender Wage Gaps by Knowledge Intensity: Discrimination and Technology in Korea Beyza P. Ural Department of Economics, Syracuse University, Syracuse NY, 13244, USA. William C. Horrace * Center of Policy Research, 426 Eggers Hall, Syracuse University, Syracuse NY, 13244, USA. [email protected] Jin Hwa Jung Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Seoul National University, San 56-1 Sillimdong Kwanakgu, Seoul 151-742, Korea.

ABSTRACT

A new gender wage gap decomposition methodology is introduced that does not suffer from

identification problems caused by unobserved non-discriminatory wage structure. The

methodology is used to measure the relative size of Korean gender wage gaps from 1994 to

2000 across industries, differentiated by industrial knowledge intensity, where knowledge

intensity is the extent to which industries produce or employ high-technology products. Korea

represents an important case study, since it possesses one of the fastest growing knowledge-

intensive economies, among industrialized countries. Empirical results indicate that over this

period, discrimination (the unexplained portion of the gender wage gaps) in Korea was

statistically smaller in knowledge-intensive industries than in industries with low knowledge

intensity. Also, discrimination was declining on average over the period. This suggests that

continued growth in knowledge-intensive industries in Korea may lead to further declines in

the overall gender gap.

JEL Codes: C12, J31, J71 Keywords: discrimination, labor markets, wage differential, compensation.

Running Title: Inter-Industry Gender Wage Gaps by Knowledge Intensity

* Corresponding Author

2

I. INTRODUCTION

Although there is an extensive body of literature on the decomposition of gender wage

differentials, based on a single cross-section of data, there have been relatively few studies that

analyze how these components evolve over time. For example, see Blau and Kahn (1999),

Kidd and Shannon (2001), or Finnie and Wannell (2004). In the last few years, many

developing countries have undergone substantial changes in their industrial compositions and

market structures, due to development strategies, shifting trade policies, and sectoral shifts in

the global economy (Freeman, 2004). Therefore, a dynamic analysis of the evolution of the

gender wage gap in a developing country seems particularly relevant. In particular, developing

countries in Asia experienced a substantial shift towards knowledge-intensive industries at the

end of the last decade (OECD, 2000), where knowledge intensity is measured as the extent to

which industries utilize a skilled or educated workforce or the extent to which technologically

advanced processes are used in the production of output.

An interesting question is then, "are these 'knowledge-based' industries more or less

prone to gender discrimination than "non-knowledge-based" industries?" A second interesting

question is, "to what extent has this shift towards knowledge-based industries been

accompanied with a change in the prevalence of gender discrimination in Asian economies?"

In this study, we analyze inter-industry gender wage gaps by knowledge intensity in Korea,

using a cross sectional occupational wage survey between the years 1994 and 2000. The

Korean economy provides a good test case, as the transition towards knowledge-based

industries in this country was substantial (OECD, 2000). Also, Korea experienced a steady

decrease in the overall female-male wage differentials.1 We find that in each year considered,

Korean knowledge-based industries were less discriminatory than non-knowledge-based

1 For non-agricultural industries, the average female-to-male earnings ratio was 44.2% in 1980 but was 63.2% in 2000 (Korean Labor Institute, Labor Statistics, 2004).

3

industries in terms of pay differentials. We also find that the decrease in the overall wage gap

was accompanied by a decrease in the discriminatory (unexplained) portion of the gap.

To analyze inter-industry wage differentials by knowledge intensity, we identify a new

decomposition methodology that allows us to make relative comparisons across industries and

across time. Conventional decomposition techniques (Oaxaca 1972, and Blinder, 1973) are not

identified in the sense that the investigator must decide a priori on an appropriate measure of

the unobserved non-discriminatory wage structure (Neumark, 1988). Our method identifies

relative inter-industry gender wage gaps and does not require an ad hoc proxy for the non-

discriminatory wage structure, because the estimation is designed to eliminate this structure,

when it can be assumed to be fixed across industries and across time. Our estimates reveal that

gender discrimination in knowledge-based industries was significantly lower than in non-

knowledge-based industries in Korea in all years considered. The results hold for knowledge-

based industries within both the manufacturing and service sectors of the Korean economy, as

well as for the economy as a whole. Our analysis reveals that dynamic fluctuations of

discrimination in the manufacturing sector at the end of the millennium were consistent with

the timing of the Asian financial crisis, and it may be possible that gender discrimination

improved during a period of intense industrial competition. While this is not formally

investigated or tested, it is consistent with the arguments of Becker (1971).

The paper is organized as follows. The next section summarizes theories that link

industrial composition and knowledge intensity to the magnitude of the unexplained gender

wage gap. In Section III, we develop a relative estimation strategy to estimate inter-industry

"non-discriminatory percentages", our normalized measure of gender discrimination. Our

strategy does not suffer from the lack of identification described by Neumark (1988). Section

IV describes the survey data used in this study, as well as the classification of industries into

"knowledge-based" and "non-knowledge-based" categories. Section V presents the empirical

4

results and compares the components of inter-industry wage differentials in knowledge-based

industries with non-knowledge-based industries. We repeat the analysis at a more

disaggregated level and compare the manufacturing sector and service sector by their

knowledge intensity. The final section summarizes and concludes.

II. INDUSTRIAL COMPOSITION AND GENDER WAGE GAPS

Krueger and Summers (1988) refueled an empirical and theoretical debate about the causes of

gender wage differentials. They found that the structure of the wage in the United States was

not compatible with a neoclassical model (Edin and Zetteberg, 1992), showing that inter-

industry gender wage disparities persisted between workers with identical individual

characteristics and working conditions. Several other studies, using standard wage regressions,

also support the existence of inter-industry gender wage differentials for apparently equally

skilled workers; many of these studies conclude that gender discrimination cannot be refuted.

See Gibbons and Katz (1992), Helwege (1992), Fields and Wolff (1995), and Abowd,

Karamarz, Margolis (1999).2 In the last decade, many developing countries experienced

changes in industrial composition due to development strategies, trade liberalization, and

global economic shifts (OECD, 2000). If the level of gender discrimination is different (lower)

in industries that are experiencing higher growth rates relative to other industries, then a

change (decrease) in the economies overall gender gap may accompany these changes in the

industrial composition (ceteris paribus).

There are several reasons why we might expect different levels of gender

discrimination in different industries. First, productivity of labor in some industries is an

increasing function of physical power for which the female labor force has comparative and

2 It is not our intent to argue the validity of wage regression for decomposing wage differentials, because they clearly have their drawbacks. However, they have been and continue to be a fairly standard tool in the literature.

5

absolute disadvantage. Other things being equal, it is natural to expect higher gender wage

disparities in these industries relative to the industries that do not require physical strength.

Clearly, this is an argument for a marginal product differential, but these differences may push

employers in these industries towards discriminatory tastes. Second, there are substantial

differences in the degree of competition in different industries due to differences in product

and labor markets, government regulations, and trade policies. Becker (1971) claims that

increasing competition results in lower levels of discrimination, which would cause inter-

industry differences in the wage gaps. Finally, given today's globalization of markets,

industries that are export-oriented (and not global monopolies) may be less likely to

discriminate in their long-run labor practices, as competition in international market precludes

survival of firms with inefficient (discriminatory) labor market practices.

Melitz (2003) develops a dynamic model to analyze the intra-industry effects of

international trade. In this model, exposure to trade causes only the most productive firms to

survive within an industry. There is also a large empirical literature showing that exposure to

trade increases the overall level of productivity in an industry through the mechanism

described above. In the classic Becker (1971) model, a firm (employer) that has tastes for

discrimination will employ fewer than the profit maximizing number of female employees, and

consequently will achieve suboptimal profits. We expect that market mechanism would force

firms with tastes for discrimination to exit the market, causing the overall level of

discrimination to be lower in export-oriented industries relative to industries that trade

domestically. Hellerstein, Neumark, and Troske (2002) test whether competitive market forces

reduce or eliminate discrimination using plant level longitudinal data. They find a positive

relationship between firm-level profitability and the proportion of female labor force. They

also find evidence that among plants with high market power, those that employ a relatively

large female labor force are more profitable, whereas no such relationship exist for plants with

6

low market power. The results are consistent with the short-run implications of Becker’s

model of employer discrimination.

There is also a class of models that posit differential employment search costs as

support for the existence of employer discrimination. Black (1995) constructs a model that

supports employer discrimination when sequential search costs are considered. In this model,

prejudiced employers only hire majority workers, whereas unprejudiced employers hire both

majority and minority workers. Since job search costs are higher for minority workers, they

lower their reservation wage, creating a wage differential between majority and minority

workers. Black's model also predicts that as the fraction of unprejudiced firms increases, the

wage differential vanishes, because search cost are effectively reduced for minority workers.

Therefore, if discrimination is different (lower) on average in developed counties than in

developing countries (for a variety of reasons that will not be discussed here), then a shift

towards trade liberalization and a global economy would (change) decrease wage differentials

in developing economies on average (ceteris paribus).

If there are differences between industries in terms of discriminatory practices, then the

evolution of gender wage gaps may be partially correlated with the changes in the industrial

structure of the countries, holding worker characteristics constant. Insofar as knowledge-based

industries are less capital intensive and more human capital intensive, they may exhibit smaller

(physical) capital barriers to entry and higher potential long-run competition than non-

knowledge-based industries. Assuming the existence of discrimination, as an economy shifts

towards more knowledge-based and (potentially) more competitive industries, the overall level

of gender wage gaps should decrease even when male-female characteristics are unchanged.

In this study, we identify and estimate a decomposition of inter-industry gender wage gaps by

knowledge intensity in Korea, a country that experienced a large transition to knowledge-based

7

industries in the last three decades.3 Korea is also an extreme example of rapid improvement

in the overall gender wage gaps, although gender wage gaps in Korea are still larger than most

OECD countries. Figure 1 shows the evolution of female-to-male ratio of earnings between

1980 and 2000. For non-agricultural industries, the female-to-male earnings ratio in Korea had

increased monotonically and quickly, from 44.2% in 1980 and 63.7% in 1998, and leveled off

between 1998 and 2000. This continuous improvement in the earnings ratio is associated with

an improvement in discrimination (or the unexplained portion of the usual average wage gap).

Our results indicate that there appears to be a strong correlation between a transition towards

knowledge-based industries and a decrease in gender discrimination in Korea at the end of the

millennium.

III. DECOMPOSITION FRAMEWORK

The classic Oaxaca-Blinder wage decomposition attempts to quantify gender discrimination in

a highly stylized Becker (1971) model (See Oaxaca, 1973 or Blinder, 1973). This

decomposition hinges on perfectly competitive labor markets where workers with the same

skills earn the same wage everywhere. That is, there exists some non-discriminatory wage

structure vector, θ , that maps the demographic attributes (including education, age, and

experience) of a worker into a wage, regardless of industry, occupation, or human capital

investment.4 Empirical implementations posit that if worker i possess demographic

characteristic vector, ix , then the worker should be paid a non-discriminatory wage, θii xy = ,

where the wage is typically in logarithmic form. Then, gender discrimination can be

quantified, in part, as deviations of observed male and female wage structures from the

unobserved or hypothetical standard, θ .

3 For years from 1990 to 2000, for instance, the growth of real value-added of the Korean economy was mainly led by knowledge-based manufacturing, while employment growth mainly led by knowledge-based services. For details, see Jung and Choi (2006). 4 In what follows, we effectively assume that this non-discriminatory structure is constant over time, as well.

8

While much has been written on the estimation of the male and female wage structures

using regression, little has been written on the estimation of θ to which the estimated

structures are to be compared, in order to quantify discrimination. The Oaxaca-Blinder

procedure proceeds by substituting either the estimated male wage structure or the estimated

female wage structure for θ to calculate discrimination. According to Neumark (1988),

substituting the estimated male wage structure implies the additional assumption that males are

paid their marginal product, while substituting the estimated female wage structure implies that

females are paid their marginal product. The choice of which estimate to use for the

unobserved non-discriminatory structure, θ , has implications for the measurement of

discrimination. An extreme example of this range is Ferber and Greene (1982), where wage

discrimination for a sample of university professors was 2 percent, based on the male non-

discriminatory wage structure, and was 70 percent, based on the female non-discriminatory

wage structure. It is in this sense that these estimates are "not identified." Neumark suggests

an alternative estimator for θ based on a regression that pools male and female observations in

the sample. The technique presented here use differences in counterfactual wage estimates to

produce measures of relative discrimination that are no longer a function of θ , so the arbitrary

decision on which structure to choose is eliminated. It is in this sense that our estimates are

"identified." 5

The goals here are: a) to partition a Korean labor market data set by year and industry,

where industries can be categorized as either "knowledge-based" or "non-knowledge-based"

and b) to estimate gender wage gaps over time and industry type to determine if gender wage

gaps have been statistically declining over time, and if their decline is in anyway related to

5 In the context of a 'data descriptive' wage model, 'identification' is not identification is the strictest sense of the word. However, the arbitrary selection of non-discriminator wage structure suggests a lack of identification, albeit an unconventional one. It is also admitted that a single non-discriminatory wage structure across all varieties of industries may be somewhat farfetched, even in perfectly competitive labor markets. However, this assumption is implicit in the wage decomposition literature, when decompositions are based on wage regressions that pool workers across industries.

9

knowledge intensity. These estimates are calculated at various levels of aggregation in the

data. The next subsection details estimation strategies at each level of aggregation considered.

A. Estimation of wage gaps

Let Kk ,...,1= index industries at different levels of aggregation (e.g., knowledge-based and

non-knowledge-based, or hi-tech, medium hi-tech, medium lo-tech, and lo-tech

manufacturing). Let Tt ,...,1= index time in years. Consider the T×2 log-wage regressions.

ft

K

kftkftkftftft dxy εβθ ++= ∑

=2 (1)

mt

K

kmtkmtkmtmtmt dxy εβθ ++= ∑

=2

(2)

where fty and mty are tF - and tM -dimensional column vectors, respectively, representing the

log wage for female and males, respectively; ftx and mtx are )( gFt × and )( gM t × dimensional

matrices, respectively, of observable explanatory variables; ftθ and mtθ are g-dimensional

parameter vectors; ftkβ and mtkβ are scalar parameters; ftkd and mtkd are tF - and tM -

dimensional vectors (respectively) of observable dummy variables for industry; and ftε and

mtε are tF - and tM -dimensional error vectors, respectively, satisfying the usual set of

regression assumptions. Define the following averages:

ftFt

ft xF

xt

ι′=1 )1( g× and mtM

tmt x

Mx

tι′=

1 )1( g×

where tFι and

tMι are tF - and tM -dimensional column vectors of ones, respectively. These

are average demographic characteristics in each year for females and males, respectively.

Ordinary least squares yields KT ××2 predicted counterfactuals in each industry:

ftkftftftk xy βθ ˆˆˆ += , (3)

10

mtkmtmtmtk xy βθ ˆˆˆ += , (4)

where 0ˆˆ11 == mtft ββ .

These are counterfactuals in the sense that we use ftx average female characteristics in

year t for all industries (instead of average female characteristics in year t in industry k) to

calculate ftky . This produces the predicted wage that an average female in year t would make

if they were randomly placed in industry k. The procedure is similar for calculating mtky .

This difference is essentially how identification is achieved. Then, KT × decompositions of

counterfactual male-female wage differences are:

θθθθθββ )()}ˆ()ˆ()ˆˆ{(ˆˆ mtftmtmtftftmtkftkmtkftk xxxxyy −+−−−+−=− (5)

where θ is some unobserved, non-discriminatory wage structure; it is the marginal product of

labor of a labor market that does not have tastes for discrimination. This is similar to the

Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition with one minor difference: the counterfactual male-female

differential is decomposed and not the average male-female differential (say, mtft yy − ).

Using the counterfactual seems reasonable, because the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition

implicitly assumes that labor markets are competitive, and in this highly stylized world, labor

should be readily substitutable across industries, particularly when it is the average laborer

being substituted. In what follows, we cannot solve or account for this particular shortcoming

of the model.6

A particularly appealing feature of this formulation of the decomposition is that

equation (5) highlights the fact that the explained portion of the gap, θ)( mtft xx − , is not

identified. Therefore, the extent to which changes in the overall gap over t due to changes in

average male-female characteristic differential, )( mtft xx − , is not estimable without knowing

6 That is, we still must assume that θ is constant over industries, and also over time.

11

θ . Therefore, even gender wage differences based on worker productivity differences are not

measurable in the context of the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition. This is important, because the

decomposition is usually dichotomized into an "explained" and an "unexplained" portion, but

without knowledge of θ , nothing is truly "explained."

This may seem like a somewhat grim view of the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition, but

the decomposition is salvageable (in some sense). The problem is that the decomposition seeks

to identify a dichotomy based on some "gold standard", θ , which assigns weights (or

importance) to average worker characteristics. However, if the gold standard is the same

across industries (as these models typically assume), then we can use the variability over k to

identify a relative measure of discrimination that is based on some male and female worker of

average characteristics working in any industry k and being paid some economy-wide gold

standard, θ . (This is the essence of the identifying assumption.) Based on equation (5),

discrimination (the bracketed potion of the counterfactual wage decomposition in the equation)

is:

)}ˆ()ˆ()ˆˆ{(),,(ˆ θθθθββθδ −−−+−= mtmtftftmtkftkmtfttk xxxx (6)

which is also not identified, since θ is not identified. Let ),,(ˆmax),,(ˆ][ mtfttkkmtftkt xxxx θδθδ = .

Notice that because of the linearity (monotonicity) of the decomposition, it doesn't matter what

we use for θ to find the index of the maximum, ][k . The magnitude of ),,(ˆ][ mtftkt xxθδ is a

function if θ , but the index of the maximum, ][k , is the same regardless of what is selected

forθ , because it is mapping into a set of characteristics, ftx or mx that doesn't vary over k.

Therefore, selecting 0=θ is fine for finding ][k , but mtθθ ˆ= is what is normally used (men

are paid the non-discriminatory standard, and women are paid below it). Then differencing

across k:

),,(ˆ),,(ˆ),(ˆ ][ mtfttkmtftktmtfttk xxxxxx θδθδγ −= (7)

12

)ˆˆ()ˆˆ(),(ˆ ][][ mtkftkkmtkftmtfttk xx ββββγ −−−= (8)

These are comparisons within years but between industries, and they sweep out the non-

discriminatory wage structure, θ , and are therefore identified. Relative estimators of this type

were first considered by Horrace and Oaxaca (2001). Horrace (2005) explains that these

measures are "relative to a within sample standard," and argues that the differencing may

reduce estimation biases associated with non-zero means for ftε and mtε .

The measure in (8) identifies relative comparisons between industries while sweeping

out θ but (unfortunately) not between years, because the averages ftx and mtx are a function

of t. To make comparisons between years and occupations, define the averages male and

female characteristics across industries and years as fx and mx . Let

∑=

=T

ttFF

1 and ∑

=

=T

ttMM

1

then grand means over all years and industries are

∑=

=T

tfttf xF

Fx

1

1 )1( g× and ∑=

=T

tmttm xM

Mx

1

1 )1( g×

Plugging these values in for ftx and mtx in the previous analysis, we can difference across k

and t. Let

)}ˆ()ˆ()ˆˆ{(),,(ˆ θθθθββθδ −−−+−= mtmftfmtkftkmftk xxxx (9)

Let ),,(ˆmax),,(ˆ,][ mftkktmftk xxxx θδθδ = , so that

),,(ˆ),,(ˆ),(ˆ ][ mftkmftkmftk xxxxxx θδθδγ −= (10)

and,

)ˆˆ()ˆˆ()ˆˆ()ˆˆ(),(ˆ ][][][][ mttmmfttffmtkftktkmtkfmftk xxxx θθθθββββγ −−−+−−−= , (11)

13

where ][tk corresponds to the index of the maximal tkδ for 0=θ over both k and t , and

where ][t corresponds to index of the same year associated with ][tk . These are comparisons

between years and industries, that sweep out θ , because the averages fx and mx are no longer

a function of t .

There is some industry in some year, ][tk , that possesses that maximal value of the

unexplained counterfactual wage gap (discrimination): ][tkδ . Then the difference, 0ˆ ≥tkγ ,

captures the (relative) extent to which industry k in year t is discriminatory. A convenient

normalization is the "non-discriminatory percentage" ]1,0(}~exp{ ∈− tkγ , Kk ,...,1= , Tt ,...,1= .

The normalization can be interpreted as follows: "in a labor market where skill and the non-

discriminatory wage structure are constant over industry and time (save for the differentials

ftkβ and mtkβ ), industry-year ][tk is 100 percent non-discriminatory relative to all industry-

years in the sample tk , and all other industry-years are some fraction (of 100 percent) non-

discriminatory." Clearly, certain problems inherent in the classical Oaxaca-Blinder

decomposition remain here. For example, actual labor markets are marked with some level of

heterogeneity across industries in terms of worker characteristics and (presumably) in terms of

their non-discriminatory wage structures. However, our measure does not suffer from the lack

of identification embodied in an arbitrary selection of, say mtθθ ˆ= . Also, there is truly no

sense in which we have identified the "unexplained portion" of some observed wage gap,

mtft yy − . In fact we are decomposing the estimate mtkftk yy ˆˆ − , which is technically "not

observed," so there is no way to relate our measure back to the overall gap, mtft yy − .

However, this is the cost of the identification: everything is relative to the unidentified

difference ),,(ˆ][ mftk xxθδ , not the "identified" difference mtft yy − .

14

The estimates in equation (11) are used in the empirical analyses that follow. First, we

partition the data into "knowledge-based industries" and "other industries", so that K = 2 (one

dummy variable in each regression). This produces two estimate of ),(ˆ mfkt xxγ in each of

seven years, 2000,...,1994=t . Then, we partition the data into four industries: knowledge-

based manufacturing, knowledge-based services, other manufacturing, and other services, so

that K = 4 (three dummy variables in each regression). This produces four estimates of

),(ˆ mfkt xxγ in each of seven years, 2000,...,1994=t . We now discuss variance estimation for

the estimates in equation (11).

B. Variance-covariance estimation

Since θ will ultimately be eliminated by differencing, we set 0=θ in what follows. Hence,

the estimator of interest is:

)ˆˆ()ˆˆ(),,0(ˆmtkmtmftkftfmftk xxxx βθβθδ +−+= (12)

Let ]ˆ,...,ˆ,ˆ[ˆ2

* ′= ftKftftft ββθθ and ]ˆ,...,ˆ,ˆ[ˆ2

* ′= mtKmtmtmt ββθθ be )1( −+ Kg column vectors, so

that ]ˆ,...,ˆ[ˆ **1

* ′= fTff θθθ and ]ˆ,...,ˆ[ˆ **1

* ′= mTmm θθθ are )1( −+ KgT column vectors. Let Q be a

1−K identity matrix bordered above by a 1−K row vector of zeros. Therefore Q is a

)1( −× KK matrix. Therefore, ],[ QxIC fKTf ⊗⊗= ι and ],[ QxIC mKTm ⊗⊗= ι are

)1( −+× KgTTK matrices. Then,

**

)1(

ˆˆ),,0(ˆmmff

TKmf CCxx θθ −=Δ

×

(13)

is a TK column vector, and is the vector representation of the estimates in equation (12), with

typical element tkδ . Let D be constructed from a ( 1)TK − negative identity matrix with a

column vector of ones inserted in ][tk column position from the left and then a column of

15

zeroes inserted in the ][tk row position from the top. For example if ][tk is the second element

of Δ , then

⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢

−−

10010001010001100000000011

)(

L

OMMMM

L

L

L

L

TXTKD

Then,

),,0(ˆ)]',(ˆ)...,(ˆ[),(ˆ11

1mfmfTKmf

TKmf xxDxxxxxx Δ==Γ

×

γγ (14)

is the vector representation of the ),(ˆ mftk xxγ in equation (10). Since the male and female

samples are independent,

DCVarCCVarCDxxVar mmmfffTKTK

mf ′′+′=Γ×

])ˆ()ˆ([)},(ˆ{ ** θθ

(15)

Treating the samples in each of the T regressions as independent,

⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢

=

)ˆ(

)ˆ()ˆ(

)ˆ(

*

*2

*1

*

fT

f

f

f

Var

VarVar

Var

θ

θθ

θ

K

MOMM

K

K

00

0000

,

a )1( −+ KgT square matrix, where )ˆ( *ftVar θ is a )1( −+ Kg square matrix returned by any

regression software package. It follows similarly for )ˆ( *mtVar θ . Also notice that θ is a

constant, so it is true that

)},,0(ˆ{)},,(ˆ{)(

mfTKTK

mf xxVarxxVar Δ=Δ×

θ (16)

Therefore,

16

mmmfffmf CVarCCVarCxxVar ′+′=Δ )ˆ()ˆ()},,(ˆ{ ** θθθ (17)

IV. DATA

The data used for the empirical analysis are from the 1994 to 2000 Wage Structure Survey of

the Ministry of Labor of Korea, and were previously analyzed by Jung and Choi (2004, 2006).

The survey provides information on personal characteristics and earnings data for workers

employed in firms with 10 or more employees in all industries, except the public

administration sector.7 For the empirical analysis, the agricultural and mining industries, as

well as agricultural occupations, were excluded. The final data set includes about 0.4 million

workers for years 1994-1998, and about 0.5 million workers for 1999 and 2000.

The industrial classification for the empirical analysis is presented in Table 1.

Knowledge-based manufacturing sectors are classified based on their R&D intensity and

knowledge-based service sectors are classified based on the ratio of college graduates.

Knowledge-based manufacturing refers to high-technology manufacturing in areas such as

electronics and communication equipment, and also to medium-high-technology

manufacturing in areas such as computers and motor vehicles. Other manufacturing includes

medium-low-technology manufacturing covering chemicals, rubber and plastic products,

metals, and also low-technology manufacturing ranging from food and textiles to paper

products. Knowledge-based services include communications, finance, business services,

health, education, and cultural services. Non-knowledge-based services or "other services"

include the industries like utilities, construction, wholesale and retail trade, hotels and

restaurants, and transport and storage. These industrial groupings were made based upon the

two-digit Korean Standard Industrial Classification (KSIC). 7 The Survey was extended to include small firms with 5-9 employees starting in 1999, but workers employed in firms with 5-9 employees were excluded from the final data set for consistency.

17

V. RESULTS

In order to estimate non-discriminatory percentages for industry groups, wage regressions for

male and female groups were estimated for years 1994 to 2000. The first set of regressions

included dummy variables for whether an individual was employed in a knowledge-based

industry or not. Estimation results of these regressions are presented in Table 3. As an

estimator of equation (11), we report two values ( 2,1=k ; knowledge- and non-knowledge-

based) of the "non-discriminatory percentages," }ˆexp{ tkγ− , for seven years 7,...,1=t . The top

section of Table 5 contains these values and the standard errors of the estimators.8 Here, the

largest value of 4445.0ˆ][ −=tkδ corresponds to the knowledge-based industries in 1999.9

Thus, for knowledge-based industries in 1999, 0ˆ =tkγ and 1}ˆexp{ =− tkγ , so in 1999

knowledge-based industries were "100 percent non-discriminatory," meaning that, relatively

speaking, knowledge-based industries in 1999 were the least discriminatory industry-year in

the sample. All other industry-years are evaluated relative to this standard.

Table 5 shows that, in 1994 knowledge-based industries were 93.8 percent non-

discriminatory and non-knowledge-based industries were 90.7 percent non-discriminatory. In

2000, knowledge-based industries were 98.4 percent nondiscriminatory and non-knowledge-

based industries were 96.2 percent non-discriminatory. Figure 2 shows the values of non-

discriminatory percentages as well as 95 percent confidence intervals based on the standard

errors in equation (17). According to our estimation, knowledge-based industries had

significantly higher non-discriminatory percentages in all years considered. Although in 1996

8 Note that the standard errors are for tkγ not the normalization }ˆexp{ tkγ− , but they can be used to calculate

confidence intervals on the }ˆexp{ tkγ− , since it is a monotonic transformation of tkγ . We do this in the sequel. 9 Note that 4445.0ˆ

][ −=tkδ is not readily interpretable as a measure of discrimination, because it is evaluated at

0=θ .

18

the two estimates were relatively close, the difference was still significant based on the 95

percent confidence intervals. The non-discriminatory percentages in the two groups of

industries follow a different trend between 1994 and 2000. Non-knowledge-based industries or

"other industries" (the solid line) show a relatively fast improvement between 1994 and 1996,

followed by a relatively steady three years and a significant improvement in 2000. Knowledge-

based industries (the dashed line), however, follow a different pattern. Between 1994 and 1996

non-discrimination improved very slightly, followed by a large improvement in 1997 and an

insignificant decline in 1998. In 1999, knowledge-based industries have the largest non-

discriminatory percentage (100 percent), but it decreased to 98.4 percent in 2000.

There is a strong possibility that we are picking up the effects of the Asian Financial

Crisis that occurred between 1997 and 1998. This may be particularly true for knowledge-

based manufacturing industries in Korea, which experienced very strong growth immediately

before the financial crisis. The OECD (2000) report characterizes Asian economies before the

financial crisis as “industrial over-capacity due to excessive investment in manufacturing”.

The rapid increase in the non-discriminatory percentages for knowledge-based industries

between 1996 and 1997 may be correlated with this over-capitalization in Asian manufacturing

and the subsequent steep decline in Asian currencies after the crisis. It is not clear what

mechanism produced this apparent correlation, nor are we willing to speculate on it, since it is

beyond the scope of this research. However, the coincidence of the decrease in the

unexplained portion in the gender wage in Korean knowledge-based industries and the Asian

financial crisis is too pronounced in Figure 2 to be ignored. In the next analysis, we will show

that the changes in discrimination for knowledge-based industries were, in fact, substantial in

the manufacturing sector, but weak or non-existent in the service sector.

To disaggregate the industry effects, we re-estimated the regressions with three industry

dummies representing the knowledge-based manufacturing, knowledge-based services, non-

19

knowledge-based manufacturing (other manufacturing), and the non-knowledge-based services

(other services) as the omitted category. The regression results are tabulated in Table 4.

Normalized estimates of equation (11) can be found in Table 5. Figures 3 and 4 show the

evolution of non-discriminatory percentages for these four industry classifications. Lower and

upper limits of confidence intervals (based on standard errors reported in Table 5) show that

the non-discriminatory percentages were significantly higher in knowledge-based industries for

both manufacturing and services.

The empirical finding that non-discriminatory percentages are significantly higher in

knowledge-based industries is consistent with the hypothesis that non-productivity related

discrimination in knowledge-based industries is more costly than in non-knowledge-based

industries. That is, non-productivity related discrimination is perhaps more detrimental to the

competitiveness of knowledge-based industries than non-knowledge-based industries, where

the former is heavily dependent upon knowledge inputs, and perhaps subject to a higher degree

of competition. Notice, also, that non-discriminatory percentages are higher in services than in

manufacturing. Non-discriminatory percentages in non-knowledge-based services are lower

than those in knowledge-based services and are higher than those in both knowledge-based and

non-knowledge-based manufacturing. Also, the difference in non-discriminatory percentages

between knowledge-based sectors and non-knowledge-based sectors is smaller for

manufacturing than for services.

Again, there seems to be some (unexplained) correlation between the steep increases in

the non-discriminatory percentages in the manufacturing sector (Figure 4) and the Asian

Financial Crisis that occurred between 1997 and 1998. In Figure 4, we see a significant drop in

1999 knowledge-based manufacturing industries, as well as in non-knowledge-based

industries. Although it is beyond the scope of this paper to analyze effects of the Asian crisis

on Korean labor markets, it is interesting to see that the improvements in non-discriminatory

20

percentages between 1994 and 1998 were partially reversed in knowledge-based

manufacturing industries and completely reversed in non-knowledge-based manufacturing

industries as the financial crisis was mitigated. In 2000, there was a significant improvement in

non-knowledge-based industries and a slight decrease in knowledge-based industries. Figure 3

shows that, in the service sector, the correlation between the financial crisis and gender

discrimination was not as clear as in the manufacturing sector. In 1998, there was a slight

decrease in non-discriminatory percentages in non-knowledge-based services, followed by a

significant improvement. In knowledge-based service industries, however, there was a slight

decrease in the trend, followed by a significant improvement. In 2000, both knowledge- and

non-knowledge-based service industries experienced a decline in non-discriminatory

percentages.

VI. CONCLUSIONS

If one accepts the validity of Oaxaca-Blinder decompositions from linear wage regressions

then the counterfactual decomposition presented herein is identified, while the usual

decomposition is not. Our technique also readily lends itself to comparisons across separate

regression periods and to a convenient normalization of discrimination to percentages on the

unit interval. We have also provided an explanation of how to calculate standard errors for our

estimates. Our technique could be applied to any partition of the data (not just a partition

based on knowledge intensity) and to other forms of discrimination (e.g., discrimination by

race), as well.

Our application suggests that discrimination was smaller in knowledge-intensive

industries in Korea than in non-knowledge-intensive industries at the end of the last decade,

and this difference seems to have been most pronounced in the manufacturing sector. In

absolute terms we do not know the difference and by how much it changed over time; this is

21

the cost of the relative estimation procedure. There was some volatility in the level of

discrimination around the time of the Asian Financial Crisis, particularly in the manufacturing

sector. Despite this volatility, discrimination declined on average over the seven-year period.

It would be interesting to explore the nature of the causality (if any) between the overall

decline in discrimination and the events surrounding the Asian Financial crisis, but this is left

for future research.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We would like to thank to Dan Black, Tom Kniesner, Devashish Mitra, Joseph Marchand, and

participants in American Economic Association 2005 Meetings in Philadelphia for their helpful

comments. The authors are responsible for all remaining errors.

22

REFERENCES Abowd, J.M., Karamarz F., and Margolis D.N. (1999) High wage workers and high wage firms. Econometrica, 67, 251-333. Altonji J.J. and Blank, R.M. (1999) Race and gender in the labor market, in: O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (ed.), Handbook of Labor Economics, edition 1, volume 3, chapter 48, pages 3143-3259, Netherlands: Elsevier. Becker, G.S. (1971) The Economics of Discrimination, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Black, D. (1995). Discrimination in an equilibrium search model. Journal of Labor Economics, 13, 308-33. Blau, F.D. and Kahn, L.M. (1999). Analyzing the gender pay gap. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 39, 625-646. Blinder, A.S. (1973). Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates. The Journal of Human Resources, 8, 436-455. Edin, P and Zetteberg, J. (1992) Interindustry wage differentials: evidence from Sweden and a comparison with United States. The American Economic Review, 82, 1341-1349. Ferber, M.A., and Green, C.A. (1982) Traditional or reverse sex discrimination? A case study of a large public university. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 35, 550-64. Fields, J. and Wolff E. (1995) Interindustry wage differentials and gender wage gap. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 49, 105-120. Finnie, R and Wannell T. (2004) Evolution of the gender earnings gap among canadian university graduates, Applied Economics 36, 1967-78. Freeman, R. (2004). The great doubling: the real effect of globalization on labor. Unpublished Manuscript, Department of Economics, Harvard University. Gibbons F. and Katz L. (1992) Does unmeasured explain inter-industry wage differentials? Review of Economic Studies, 59, 515-535. Hellerstein J.., Neumark, D. and Troske, K.R. (2002) Market forces and sex discrimination. Journal of Human Resources, 37, 353-380. Helwege, J. (1992) Sectoral shifts and inter-industry wage differentials, Journal of Labor Economics, 10, 55-84. Horrace, W.C. (2005) On the ranking uncertainty of labor market wage gaps. Journal of Population Economics, 18, 181-187. Horrace, W.C. and Oaxaca, R.L. (2001) Inter-Industry Wage differentials and the gender wage gap: an identification problem Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54, 611-618.

23

Jung, J.H. and Choi K. (2004) Gender wage differentials and discrimination in Korea: comparison by knowledge intensity of industries, International Economic Journal, 18, 561-579. Jung, J. H. and Choi K. (2006) The labor market structure of knowledge-based industries: a Korean case. Journal of Asia Pacific Economy, 11, 59-78. Kidd, M.P. and Shannon M. (2001) Convergence in the gender wage gap in Australia over the 1980s: identifying the role of counteracting forces via the Juhn, Murphy and Pierce decomposition, Applied Economics 33, 929-36. Krueger B.A. and Summers L.H. (1988) Efficiency wages and inter-industry wage structure, Econometrica, 56, 259-293. Melitz, M.J. (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity, Econometrica, 71, 1695-1725. Neumark, D. (1988) Employers’ discriminatory behavior and the estimation of wage discrimination. The Journal of Human Resources, 23, 279-295. Oaxaca, R., (1973) Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets. International Economic Review, 14, 693-709. Oaxaca, R.L. and Ransom M. (1999) Identification in detailed wage decompositions., Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 154-157. OECD (2000) Knowledge-based Industries in Asia. OECD. Paris.

24

FIGURES

Figure 1: Female-to-Male Ratio of Average Earnings

0.40

0.45

0.50

0.55

0.60

0.65

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

Source: Korean Labor Institute, Labor Statistics (2004). Figure 2: Non-Discriminatory Percentages, Knowledge-based Industries and Other Industries

0.900

0.925

0.950

0.975

1.000

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Knowledge Based Industries Other Industries

Figure plots }ˆexp{ tkγ− where tkγ is based on equation (11). [tk] = [Knowledge-based Industries, 1999]. 95% confidence bounds. Other Industries = Non-Knowledge-based Industries.

25

Figure 3: Non-Discriminatory Percentages, Knowledge-based Services and Other Service

0.8000

0.8500

0.9000

0.9500

1.0000

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Know ledge Based Services Other Services

Figure plots }ˆexp{ tkγ− where tkγ is based on equation (11). [tk] = [Knowledge-based Services, 1999]. 95% confidence bounds. Other Services = Non-Knowledge-based Services.

Figure 4: Non-Discriminatory Percentages, Knowledge-based Manufacturing and Other Manufacturing

0.7500

0.7750

0.8000

0.8250

0.8500

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Know ledge Based Manufacturing Other Manufacturing

Figure plots }ˆexp{ tkγ− where tkγ is based on equation (11). [tk] = [Knowledge-based Services, 1999]. 95% confidence bounds. Other Manufacturing = Non-Knowledge-based Manufacturing.

26

Table 1: Classification of Knowledge-based Industries

R&D Intensity1

(1999)

College Graduates2

(2001) Knowledge- High-tech Electronical machinery 10.6 16.8 based Communication equipment 17.9 19.8 Manufacturing (KBM) Medium-high-tech Office/accounting/computing machinery 7.0 17.0

Motor vehicles 8.9 11.8 Other Medium-low- Chemicals 3.6 29.6 Manufacturing tech Rubber/plastic products 3.5 12.1 (OM) Non-metallic mineral products 1.9 11.5 Metals 1.0 13.6 Fabricated metal products 1.0 8.9 Non-electrical machinery 3.6 11.5 Precision instruments 4.1 8.9 Other transport equipment 1.1 26.5 Furniture, and Manufacturing n.e.c. 1.6 10.2 Low-tech Food, beverages, tobacco 0.7 10.0 Textiles, apparel, leather 0.9 6.7 Wood and paper products 0.5 3 14.1 Printing - 29.0 Petroleum refineries/products 0.5 44.7 Recycling - 3.8 Knowledge- Communications 5.0 29.2 based Financial services - 31.0 Services Business services - 35.2 (KBS) Education services - 59.5 Health services/social work - 31.2 Culture/recreation - 23.3 Other Electricity, gas, water supply 0.9 30.7 Services Construction 0.7 13.2 (OS) Wholesale/retail trade - 15.4 Hotels and restaurants - 4.7 Transport and storage - 10.9 Real estate activities - 15.0 Other services - 18.7

All Industries 1.8 19.0 Notes: 1) R&D expenditures as a percentage of value added in each industry. 2) The ratio of 4-year college graduates to the total employed(%). 3) Includes printing industry. Sources: OECD(2002), Science, Technology and Industry Outlook, NSO, Korea(2002), The Economically Active Population Survey.

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics*

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male

Logarithm of Hourly Wage (Won) * 8.00 8.55 8.16 8.68 8.34 8.84 8.44 8.92 8.45 8.93 8.46 8.90 8.59 9.02

(0.44) (0.49) (0.45) (0.49) (0.46) (0.52) (0.47) (0.51) (0.48) (0.52) (0.52) (0.54) (0.52) (0.55)

Age 30.72 36.39 30.92 36.67 31.39 36.69 31.96 37.21 32.12 37.61 32.14 37.48 32.68 37.82

(11.57) (9.95) (11.67) (10.06) (11.69) (10.27) (11.70) (10.33) (11.46) (10.03) (11.09) (9.87) (11.06) (10.00)

Married 0.43 0.76 0.43 0.76 0.44 0.74 0.47 0.76 0.47 0.78 0.49 0.76 0.49 0.75

(0.49) (0.43) (0.50) (0.43) (0.50) (0.44) (0.50) (0.43) (0.50) (0.42) (0.50) (0.43) (0.50) (0.43)

Tenure 3.48 5.94 3.79 6.33 3.66 5.99 3.92 6.25 4.27 6.74 4.33 6.64 4.22 6.68

(3.67) (5.73) (3.89) (6.02) (4.03) (6.06) (4.21) (6.13) (4.35) (6.29) (4.34) (6.24) (4.47) (6.45)

Education:

Less Than High School 0.32 0.21 0.30 0.19 0.28 0.17 0.26 0.16 0.23 0.14 0.21 0.14 0.20 0.14

(0.47) (0.41) (0.46) (0.39) (0.45) (0.37) (0.44) (0.37) (0.42) (0.35) (0.41) (0.35) (0.40) (0.35)

High School 0.54 0.48 0.54 0.48 0.53 0.48 0.52 0.48 0.51 0.46 0.51 0.45 0.48 0.45

(0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50) (0.50)

Two-Year College 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.10 0.09 0.12 0.10 0.14 0.11 0.14 0.11 0.16 0.12

(0.26) (0.28) (0.28) (0.28) (0.30) (0.29) (0.32) (0.30) (0.35) (0.31) (0.35) (0.32) (0.37) (0.32)

Four-Year College or above 0.06 0.23 0.07 0.24 0.09 0.26 0.10 0.26 0.12 0.28 0.14 0.30 0.15 0.29

(0.24) (0.42) (0.26) (0.43) (0.29) (0.44) (0.30) (0.44) (0.32) (0.45) (0.35) (0.46) (0.36) (0.45)

* Hourly wage = [regular monthly pay + yearly bonus pay/12] /regular monthly work hours

28

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics, con’t *

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male

Establishment Size:

10-29 Employees 0.22 0.21 0.23 0.22 0.24 0.22 0.25 0.24 0.26 0.24 0.30 0.25 0.30 0.27

(0.42) (0.41) (0.42) (0.41) (0.43) (0.42) (0.44) (0.42) (0.44) (0.42) (0.46) (0.43) (0.46) (0.45)

30-99 Employees 0.30 0.28 0.28 0.27 0.28 0.26 0.28 0.26 0.27 0.26 0.29 0.25 0.31 0.27

(0.46) (0.45) (0.45) (0.44) (0.45) (0.44) (0.45) (0.44) (0.45) (0.44) (0.45) (0.43) (0.46) (0.44)

100-299 Employees 0.19 0.21 0.19 0.20 0.19 0.20 0.20 0.21 0.20 0.21 0.19 0.22 0.18 0.21

(0.40) (0.41) (0.39) (0.40) (0.40) (0.40) (0.40) (0.41) (0.40) (0.41) (0.39) (0.41) (0.38) (0.40)

300-499 Employees 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.06

(0.25) (0.26) (0.25) (0.26) (0.25) (0.26) (0.26) (0.25) (0.25) (0.25) (0.22) (0.23) (0.23) (0.24)

500+ Employees 0.21 0.23 0.23 0.24 0.22 0.24 0.20 0.22 0.20 0.23 0.17 0.22 0.15 0.19

(0.41) (0.42) (0.42) (0.43) (0.41) (0.43) (0.40) (0.42) (0.40) (0.42) (0.38) (0.42) (0.36) (0.39)

Industries**:

Knowledge-based Industries 0.37 0.28 0.40 0.30 0.43 0.32 0.45 0.33 0.48 0.36 0.47 0.34 0.48 0.33

(0.48) (0.45) (0.49) (0.46) (0.49) (0.47) (0.50) (0.47) (0.50) (0.48) (0.50) (0.47) (0.50) (0.47)

Knowledge-based Manufacturing 0.12 0.10 0.14 0.11 0.13 0.12 0.13 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.12

(0.33) (0.30) (0.35) (0.31) (0.34) (0.32) (0.34) (0.32) (0.33) (0.32) (0.32) (0.32) (0.33) (0.32)

Knowledge-based Services 0.25 0.18 0.26 0.19 0.29 0.21 0.32 0.22 0.36 0.24 0.36 0.23 0.36 0.21

(0.43) (0.39) (0.44) (0.39) (0.46) (0.41) (0.46) (0.41) (0.48) (0.43) (0.48) (0.42) (0.48) (0.41)

* The values in parenthesis correspond to standard deviations of the variables.

** Refer to Table 1 for classification of the industries.

29

Table 3: Regression Results – Two Industry Dummies, Dependent Variable: Logarithm of hourly wage in Korean Won. *

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male

(Constant) 7.14 6.92 7.34 6.98 7.39 7.12 7.51 7.23 7.53 7.13 7.51 6.74 7.65 6.80

[2337.02] [2476.09] [2412.69] [2583.62] [2348.87] [2571.38] [2335.75] [2603.06] [2138.41] [2364.39] [1935.69] [2086.14] [2033.06] [2120.42]

Age 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.07 0.02 0.07

[121.12] [347.97] [99.56] [367.00] [132.90] [353.28] [116.15] [348.16] [103.75] [336.23] [69.86] [434.96] [75.26] [432.26]

Age-squared -0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.05 -0.03 -0.06 -0.02 -0.08 -0.02 -0.08

[-135.54] [-334.08] [-117.69] [-347.82] [-153.49] [-337.90] [-137.62] [-329.02] [-130.46] [-314.91] [-83.03] [-421.37] [-94.49] [-405.52]

High School 0.24 0.17 0.26 0.19 0.26 0.21 0.27 0.21 0.24 0.20 0.32 0.19 0.28 0.21

[320.95] [334.23] [342.83] [378.20] [322.84] [379.19] [324.32] [367.50] [249.69] [320.51] [303.29] [280.44] [280.49] [308.73]

2-year college 0.39 0.29 0.41 0.32 0.40 0.35 0.42 0.36 0.37 0.35 0.44 0.32 0.42 0.35

[339.77] [374.53] [384.21] [437.54] [367.68] [450.72] [380.86] [468.73] [318.14] [428.95] [340.62] [363.31] [345.92] [404.66]

4-year college + 0.66 0.53 0.66 0.56 0.69 0.59 0.70 0.60 0.65 0.57 0.71 0.58 0.70 0.61

[554.29] [908.09] [604.69] [992.26] [633.73] [963.95] [632.70] [960.08] [553.95] [865.10] [567.89] [797.49] [583.15] [846.72]

30-99 employees -0.02 -0.04 -0.04 -0.05 0.00 -0.04 0.00 -0.06 -0.03 -0.05 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01

[-26.63] [-86.35] [-54.55] [-92.55] [-5.97] [-82.03] [-3.27] [-108.32] [-38.33] [-96.54] [14.02] [-5.71] [-6.38] [-16.12]

100-299 employees -0.01 -0.06 0.00 -0.05 0.00 -0.06 0.02 -0.07 0.01 -0.05 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.04

[-6.65] [-104.14] [3.06] [-99.46] [5.18] [-116.19] [27.98] [-127.19] [12.08] [-85.59] [30.09] [62.81] [39.15] [58.90]

300-499 employees 0.03 -0.04 0.06 0.01 0.05 0.02 0.06 -0.01 0.06 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.10 0.14

[28.49] [-46.74] [53.67] [11.02] [46.73] [21.18] [53.95] [-7.37] [49.82] [34.29] [31.73] [83.25] [70.45] [146.73]

500+ employees 0.08 0.04 0.07 0.06 0.12 0.08 0.14 0.10 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.19 0.12 0.13

[100.26] [78.66] [100.51] [106.18] [161.89] [147.85] [180.53] [179.74] [154.85] [226.08] [135.32] [294.45] [122.82] [200.32]

30

Table 3: Regression Results – Two Industry Dummies, con’t

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Married -0.01 0.09 0.00 0.09 -0.01 0.10 -0.02 0.08 -0.01 0.08 0.01 0.07 0.00 0.08

[-8.59] [147.93] [0.02] [170.04] [-12.29] [170.22] [-26.71] [138.96] [-11.23] [125.39] [10.35] [114.26] [5.32] [123.49]

Tenure-square -0.21 -0.11 -0.21 -0.10 -0.18 -0.10 -0.18 -0.09 -0.15 -0.09 -0.13 -0.06 -0.19 -0.11

[-241.88] [-260.47] [-258.77] [-284.97] [-226.39] [-276.53] [-238.63] [-253.33] [-185.61] [-244.43] [-153.27] [-148.77] [-214.62] [-258.30]

Tenure 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.08 0.04 0.09 0.05

[573.86] [603.72] [616.85] [645.92] [564.96] [631.49] [575.51] [595.35] [514.08] [587.41] [462.27] [436.81] [540.87] [550.69] Knowledge-Based Industry 0.12 0.08 0.10 0.09 0.10 0.10 0.12 0.09 0.14 0.11 0.16 0.10 0.14 0.11

[216.71] [201.87] [186.69] [225.33] [193.65] [247.74] [224.18] [215.06] [235.26] [256.37] [247.97] [229.08] [219.94] [252.61]

* t-values of the coefficients are presented in the brackets.

31

Table 4: Regression Results – Four Industry Dummies, Dependent Variable: Logarithm of hourly wage in Korean Won.* 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male

(Constant) 7.18 6.98 7.39 7.04 7.44 7.15 7.55 7.27 7.56 7.20 7.57 6.83 7.68 6.92 [2359.04] [2472.80] [2428.99] [2592.81] [2366.75] [2558.74] [2363.52] [2597.50] [2151.97] [2369.76] [1985.76] [2103.02] [2068.51] [2160.12] Age 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.07 0.02 0.07 [130.75] [336.08] [110.38] [352.87] [144.59] [345.43] [129.82] [337.59] [115.09] [319.83] [85.32] [420.34] [92.70] [413.64] Age-squared -0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.06 -0.04 -0.06 -0.03 -0.05 -0.03 -0.05 -0.03 -0.08 -0.03 -0.07 [-147.29] [-324.80] [-130.76] [-336.52] [-167.90] [-331.95] [-153.95] [-321.26] [-143.48] [-302.21] [-99.80] [-411.73] [-112.51] [-392.97] High School 0.21 0.17 0.23 0.19 0.23 0.21 0.25 0.21 0.22 0.20 0.28 0.19 0.25 0.21 [286.39] [332.96] [303.14] [375.70] [288.32] [380.05] [294.25] [369.88] [230.90] [324.30] [271.33] [284.03] [256.16] [310.73] 2-year college 0.32 0.28 0.35 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.35 0.36 0.33 0.34 0.36 0.31 0.36 0.34 [275.43] [367.87] [312.48] [430.88] [302.13] [444.88] [315.22] [460.95] [271.85] [421.19] [276.77] [355.63] [287.07] [389.20] 4-year college + 0.60 0.52 0.60 0.54 0.63 0.58 0.63 0.58 0.60 0.56 0.62 0.56 0.62 0.58 [490.39] [881.14] [530.88] [960.91] [560.28] [938.41] [560.71] [931.09] [498.86] [838.14] [490.95] [767.28] [510.69] [804.39] 30-99 employees -0.01 -0.04 -0.03 -0.04 0.01 -0.04 0.01 -0.05 -0.02 -0.05 0.03 0.00 0.01 0.00 [-17.66] [-85.18] [-42.55] [-90.08] [7.38] [-79.98] [10.65] [-104.05] [-25.25] [-90.12] [35.53] [6.93] [14.15] [5.27] 100-299 employees 0.01 -0.06 0.02 -0.05 0.02 -0.06 0.03 -0.07 0.02 -0.04 0.06 0.05 0.06 0.05 [14.54] [-99.19] [22.37] [-91.52] [24.62] [-110.97] [45.26] [-119.94] [25.97] [-76.92] [62.77] [74.67] [69.58] [79.59] 300-499 employees 0.05 -0.03 0.07 0.02 0.07 0.02 0.08 0.00 0.08 0.04 0.08 0.09 0.13 0.16 [41.67] [-42.21] [69.48] [20.30] [59.94] [26.24] [68.65] [0.07] [63.33] [47.27] [53.82] [99.20] [98.10] [173.67] 500+ employees 0.11 0.06 0.11 0.08 0.16 0.10 0.18 0.12 0.16 0.16 0.19 0.22 0.16 0.17 [146.02] [107.57] [147.25] [148.92] [204.34] [167.07] [220.27] [209.81] [186.34] [266.18] [192.80] [332.29] [170.72] [266.82]

32

Table 4: Regression Results – Four Industry Dummies, con’t *

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Married 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.09 -0.01 0.10 -0.02 0.08 -0.01 0.08 0.02 0.07 0.01 0.07 [-3.97] [147.67] [-2.46] [169.13] [-8.01] [170.98] [-21.75] [139.94] [-14.23] [125.74] [16.60] [114.44] [10.10] [121.34] Tenure-square -0.20 -0.11 -0.21 -0.11 -0.18 -0.11 -0.18 -0.10 -0.15 -0.10 -0.13 -0.07 -0.19 -0.11 [-242.42] [-270.47] [-264.70] [-297.14] [-227.00] [-282.28] [-242.73] [-263.69] [-188.02] [-259.72] [-151.54] [-161.47] [-212.36] [-271.52] Tenure 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.08 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.07 0.05 0.09 0.06 [560.45] [611.48] [613.28] [655.48] [556.93] [634.35] [574.00] [603.66] [511.48] [600.96] [451.92] [452.57] [528.48] [568.12] Knowledge-based Manufacturing -0.05 0.00 -0.06 -0.01 -0.05 0.05 -0.04 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.08 -0.01 -0.08 -0.05 [-51.60] [3.16] [-66.49] [-13.33] [-50.66] [70.60] [-37.89] [13.77] [-1.77] [-3.45] [-69.14] [-16.05] [-68.41] [-65.19] Knowledge-based Services 0.14 0.10 0.10 0.12 0.10 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.13 0.13 0.14 0.11 0.13 0.14 [179.05] [189.50] [130.31] [225.26] [135.48] [229.55] [155.10] [217.10] [168.98] [255.96] [165.78] [190.42] [156.28] [234.62] Other Manufacturing -0.07 -0.03 -0.09 -0.03 -0.08 -0.01 -0.09 -0.02 -0.07 -0.03 -0.14 -0.06 -0.12 -0.08 [-92.74] [-64.86] [-124.97] [-73.34] [-114.49] [-21.20] [-121.97] [-39.65] [-89.84] [-59.68] [-160.91] [-122.59] [-137.01] [-161.57]

* t-values of the coefficients are presented in the brackets.

33

Table 5: Non-Discriminatory Percentages

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Two Industry Dummies:

Knowledge-based Industries 0.938 0.939 0.945 0.974 0.973 1.000 0.984

(0.00081) (0.00079) (0.00079) (0.00079) (0.00080) (0.00000) (0.00084)

Non – Knowledge-based Industries 0.907 0.930 0.941 0.940 0.942 0.944 0.962

(0.00073) (0.00072) (0.00073) (0.00074) (0.00076) (0.00080) (0.00078)

Four Industry Dummies:

Knowledge-based Manufacturing 0.771 0.793 0.820 0.828 0.844 0.801 0.800

(0.00119) (0.00113) (0.00116) (0.00117) (0.00123) (0.00136) (0.00127)

Non-Knowledge-based Manufacturing 0.757 0.771 0.790 0.783 0.786 0.752 0.766

(0.00088) (0.00087) (0.00090) (0.00091) (0.00095) (0.00100) (0.00097)

Knowledge-based Services 0.933 0.928 0.952 0.964 0.966 1.000 0.982

(0.00098) (0.00095) (0.00096) (0.00096) (0.00096) (0.00000) (0.00102)

Non-Knowledge-based Services 0.811 0.842 0.860 0.859 0.847 0.869 0.863

(0.00100) (0.00097) (0.00098) (0.00098) (0.00101) (0.00104) (0.00105)

Values are }ˆexp{ tkγ− , where tkγ is based on equation (11). Values in parentheses are standard errors for tkγ , used to construct confidence intervals in Figures 3 – 5.