24
Economics 101A (Lecture 1) Stefano DellaVigna January 17, 2018 Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 1 / 24

Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Economics 101A (Lecture 1)

Stefano DellaVigna

January 17, 2018

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 1 / 24

Page 2: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Outline

1 Who are we?

2 Prerequisites for the course

3 A test in math

4 The economics of discrimination

5 Optimization with 1 variable

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 2 / 24

Page 3: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Who are we?

Who are we?

Stefano DellaVigna – call me ‘Stefano’

Professor of Economics

Bocconi (Italy) undergraduate (Econ.), Harvard PhD (Econ.)

Psychology and Economics (Behavioral Economics), Economicsof Media

Evans 515, Office Hours: Th 1.00-3.00 (except this week)

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 3 / 24

Page 4: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Who are we?

GSIs

Peter Jones (2 Sections)

Graduate Student, Department of Economics

Office Hours: Th 9AM-11AM, 640 Evans

Jonathan Schellenberg (2 Sections)

Graduate Student, Department of Economics

Office Hours: We 10AM-12PM, 640 Evans

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 4 / 24

Page 5: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Prerequisites

Prerequisites

Mathematics

Good knowledge of multivariate calculus – Math 1A or 1B and53Basic knowledge of probability theory and matrix algebra

Economics

Knowledge of fundamentals – Ec1 or 2 or 3High interest!

Go over syllabus

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 5 / 24

Page 6: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

A Test in Math

A Test in Math

1 Can you differentiate the following functions with respect to x?

1 y = exp(x)

2 y = a + bx + cx2

3 y = exp(x)bx

2 Can you partially differentiate these functions with respect to xand w?

1 y = axw + bx − c xw + d

√xw

2 y = exp(x/w)

3 y =∫ 10 (x + aw2 + xs)ds

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 6 / 24

Page 7: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

A Test in Math

3 Can you plot the following functions of one variable?

1 y = exp(x)

2 y = −x2

3 y = exp(−x2)

4 Are the following functions concave, convex or neither?

1 y = x3

2 y = − exp(x)

3 y = x .5y .5 for x > 0, y > 0

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 7 / 24

Page 8: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

A Test in Math

5 Consider an urn with 20 red and 40 black balls?1 What is the probability of drawing a red ball?2 What is the probability of drawing a black ball?

6 What is the determinant of the following matrices?

1 A =

[1 23 4

]

2 A =

[10 1020 20

]Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 8 / 24

Page 9: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

The Economics of Discrimination

What do economists know about discrimination?

Model of discrimination in workplace (inspired by Becker,Economics of Discrimination, 1957)

Workers:

A and B. They produce 1 widget per dayBoth have reservation wage u

Firm:

sells widgets at price p > u (assume p given)dislikes worker BMaximizes profits (p∗ no of widgets − cost of labor) – disutilityd if employs B

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 9 / 24

Page 10: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

Wages and employment in this industry?

Employment

Net surplus from employing A: p − uNet surplus from employing B: p − u − dIf u < p < u + d , Firm employs A but not BIf u + d < p, Firm employs both

What about wages?

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 10 / 24

Page 11: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

Wages

Case I. Firm monopolist/monopsonist and no union

Firm maximizes profits and gets all the net surplusWages of A and B equal u

Case II. Firm monopolist/monopsonist and union

Firm and worker get half of the net surplus eachWage of A equals u + .5 ∗ (p − u)Wage of B equals u + .5 ∗ (p − u − d)

Case III. Perfect competition among firms that discriminate(d > 0)

Prices are lowered to the cost of productionWage of A equals p (= u)B is not employed

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 11 / 24

Page 12: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

The Magic of Competition

Case IIIb. Perfect competition + At least one firm does notdiscriminate (d = 0)

This firm offers wage p to both workersWhat happens to worker B?She goes to the firm with d = 0!In equilibrium now:

Wage of A equals pWage of B equals p as well!

Competition eliminates the pay and employment differentialbetween men and women

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 12 / 24

Page 13: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

Evidence?

Is this true? Any evidence?

S. Black and P. Strahan, American Economic Review, 2001.

Local monopolies in banking industry until mid 70sMid 70s: deregulationFrom local monopolies to perfect competition.Wages?

Wages fall by 6.1 percent

Discrimination?

Wages fall by 12.5 percent for menWages fall by 2.9 percent for womenEmployment of women as managers increases by 10 percent

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 13 / 24

Page 14: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

• Summary: Competition is not great for workers (wagesgo down)

• BUT: Drives away the gender gap

Summary: Competition is not great for workers (wages go down)BUT: Drives away the gender gapStefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 14 / 24

Page 15: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

More Evidence

More evidence on discrimination: Does black-white andmale-female wage back derive from discrimination?

Field experiment (Bertrand and Mullainathan, AmericanEconomic Review, 2004)

Send real CV with randomly picked names:

Male/FemaleWhite/African American

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 15 / 24

Page 16: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

• More evidence on discrimination: Does black-whiteand male-female wage back derive from discrimina-tion?

• Field experiment (Bertrand and Mullainathan, Amer-ican Economic Review, 2004)

• Send real CV with randomly picked names:

— Male/Female

— White/African American

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 16 / 24

Page 17: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

Results

Measure call-back rate from interviewResults (Table 1):

Call-back rates 50 percent higher for Whites!No effect for Male-Female call back rates

• Measure call-back rate from interview

— Results (Table 1):

∗ Call-back rates 50 percent higher for Whites!

∗ No effect for Male-Female call back rates

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 17 / 24

Page 18: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

The Economics of Discrimination

Results

Strong evidence of discrimination against African Americans

Did Obama change this? Interesting question

Example of Applied Microeconomics

Not covered in this class: See Ec140-141-142 (Econometricsand Applied Metrics) and 131 (Public), 157 (Health), and 172(Development)Also: URAP – Get involved in a professor’s researchIf curious: read Steven Levitt and Stephen Dubner,Freakonomics

At end of semester, more examples

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 18 / 24

Page 19: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Optimization with 1 Variable

Optimization with 1 Variable

Nicholson, Ch.2, pp. 21-24

Example. Function y = −x2

What is the maximum?

Maximum is at 0

General method?

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 19 / 24

Page 20: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Optimization with 1 Variable

Sure! Use derivatives

Derivative is slope of the function at a point:

∂f (x)

∂x= lim

h→0

f (x + h)− f (x)

h

Necessary condition for maximum x∗ is

∂f (x∗)

∂x= 0 (1)

Try with y = −x2

∂f (x)∂x

= = 0 =⇒ x∗ =

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 20 / 24

Page 21: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Optimization with 1 Variable

Does this guarantee a maximum? No!

Consider the function y = x3

∂f (x)∂x

= = 0 =⇒ x∗ =

Plot y = x3.

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 21 / 24

Page 22: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Optimization with 1 Variable

Sufficient condition for a (local) maximum

∂f (x∗)

∂x= 0 and

∂2f (x)

∂2x

∣∣∣∣x∗

< 0 (2)

Proof: At a maximum, f (x∗ + h)− f (x∗) < 0 for all h.

Taylor Rule: f (x∗ + h)− f (x∗) = ∂f (x∗)∂x h + 1

2∂2f (x∗)∂2x

h2+ higherorder terms.Notice: ∂f (x∗)

∂x = 0.f (x∗ + h)− f (x∗) < 0 for all h

=⇒ ∂2f (x∗)∂2x

h2 < 0 =⇒ ∂2f (x∗)∂2x

< 0

Careful: Maximum may not exist: y = exp(x)

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 22 / 24

Page 23: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Optimization with 1 Variable

Tricky examples

Minimum. y = x2

No maximum. y = exp(x) for x ∈ (−∞,+∞)

Corner solution. y = x for x ∈ [0, 1]

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 23 / 24

Page 24: Economics 101A (Lecture 1) - Department of EconomicsJan 17, 2018  · Case III. Perfect competition among rms that discriminate (d > 0) Prices are lowered to the cost of production

Next Class

Next Class

Multivariate Maximization

Comparative Statics

Implicit Function Theorem

Envelope Theorem

Going toward:

PreferencesUtility Maximization (where we get to apply maximizationtechniques the first time)

Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 1) January 17, 2017 24 / 24