43
International dimensions of democratization Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of Social Sciences, University of Glasgow Adam Smith Building S210 Glasgow G12 8RT, Scotland, UK E-mail: [email protected] Abstract: Most research on democracy treats each nation state as completely independent, thus ignoring some of the central aspects of interdependence and interaction across borders in World Politics. This paper demonstrates that international aspects such as the political structures in proximate states and the regional threats that states face strongly influence the likelihood that a country will be democratic and experience transitions. The distribution of authority characteristics is not independent between countries, but displays strong evidence of patterns of diffusion. I show that the most commonly emphasized domestic processes within countries cannot by themselves account for the observed variation in distribution of political democracy over time and space. The regional context in which countries are located and their prior history provide important elements for explaining transitions and changes in the distribution of authority structures over time. Przeworski and Limongi's (1997:159) claim that “democracy appears exogenously as a deus ex machina”overlooks these patterns, and is thus incorrect. I am grateful for comments from Brian A’Hearn, Matthew Baum, Renske Doorenspleet, Håvard Hegre, Yi Feng, Erik Gartzke, Nils Petter Gleditsch, Zeev Maoz, Solomon Polacheck, Bruce M. Russett, and in particular Michael D. Ward. This research was supported in part by a grant from the Research Council of Norway #128560/530. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the Peace Science Society, Ann Arbor, MI, 8-10 October 1999.

Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

International dimensions of democratizationÖ

Draft version, comments welcome

Kristian S. Gleditsch

Faculty of Social Sciences, University of Glasgow

Adam Smith Building S210

Glasgow G12 8RT, Scotland, UK

E-mail: [email protected]

Abstract: Most research on democracy treats each nation state as completely independent, thus ignoring

some of the central aspects of interdependence and interaction across borders in World Politics. This

paper demonstrates that international aspects such as the political structures in proximate states and the

regional threats that states face strongly influence the likelihood that a country will be democratic and

experience transitions. The distribution of authority characteristics is not independent between countries,

but displays strong evidence of patterns of diffusion. I show that the most commonly emphasized

domestic processes within countries cannot by themselves account for the observed variation in

distribution of political democracy over time and space. The regional context in which countries are

located and their prior history provide important elements for explaining transitions and changes in the

distribution of authority structures over time. Przeworski and Limongi's (1997:159) claim that “democracy

appears exogenously as a deus ex machina” overlooks these patterns, and is thus incorrect.

Ö I am grateful for comments from Brian A’ Hearn, Matthew Baum, Renske Doorenspleet, Håvard Hegre, Yi Feng, Erik Gartzke, Nils Petter Gleditsch, Zeev Maoz, Solomon Polacheck, Bruce M. Russett, and in particular Michael D. Ward. This research was supported in part by a grant from the Research Council of Norway #128560/530. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the Peace Science Society, Ann Arbor, MI, 8-10 October 1999.

Page 2: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

1

Democracy and democratization in time and space

Theories accounting for how political structures vary over time and across space have a long tradition.

The best-known effort is probably Lipset’s (1960) “social requisites” hypothesis, which states that a

society’s level of development influences its prospects for democracy. Other perspectives hold that

certain cultural aspects, norms, or values favor the emergence and sustainment of democratic rule (e.g.,

Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

aspects such material inequality or the relative strength of groups or classes (e.g., Muller 1988, 1995,

Rueschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens 1992, Vanhanen 1990). Theories of transitions to democracy more

specifically stress factors such as the timing of national development, negotiated pacts between elites, and

“critical junctures” or forms of path dependence in political development (e.g., Bollen 1979, Casper and

Taylor 1996, Moore 1973, O'Donnell, Schmitter and Whitehead 1986, Przeworski 1991, Rueschemeyer et

al. 1992).

These explanations differ considerably from each other, and may suggest quite different

observable implications for variation in authority structures (see, e.g., Vanhanen 1990 for a

comprehensive review). Despite their differences, however, these schools are in one sense all “similar” in

that they relate a country’s prospects for democratization or sustaining democratic rule to various

domestic economic, societal and political factors. By focusing exclusively on domestic processes, these

theories effectively treat the distribution of democracy as if this were independent among countries.1

Similarly, most research interested in the consequences of political democracy tends to treat the

distribution of authority structures and changes in these as stemming from purely domestic processes.

I argue that the distribution of democracy is not independent among countries and that

international factors and processes influence the likelihood that a country will become or remain

democratic. The international context thus contains central aspects of democratization processes. The first

part of this paper discusses some international contexts of democratization. The second part shows

empirically that the distribution of democracy and democratization cluster spatially, suggesting an

international dimension to democratization over time. The third part demonstrates more systematically

that this clustering cannot be attributed to other domestic factors affecting authority structures, and

evaluates the relative importance of internal and external dimensions of democratization. Though

Przeworski and Limongi (1997) are correct in concluding that transitions to democracy cannot be

1 Studies on effects of external dependence or how position in the so-called “World-System” influence prospects for democratic rule provide a possible exception (e.g., Bollen 1983, Wallerstein 1979). Other doubts about these theories aside (see e.g., Weede 1996), these usually consider dependence between national economies rather than political structures, and rarely draw explicit linkages between World-System position and authority structures. Those that do almost exclusively hypothesize that external factors affect domestic conditions which in turn influence a country’s authority structures or propensity for democracy. Somewhat ironically, the domestic processes by which external dependence is held to impede democratization are actually often very similar to those highlighted by the social requisites school.

Page 3: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

2

predicted from wealth alone, their claim that democratization is random is patently incorrect, as there is a

systematic relationship between transitions and regional context.

International contexts of democratization

Though most work on democratization emphasizes domestic causal relationships that are presumed to be

constant over time, it is widely recognized that the global distribution of democracy varies considerably

over time. Figure 1 displays the distribution of democracy in the international system since 1800, as

measured by the proportion of democratic polities and the mean level of institutionalized democracy on

the composite scale in the POLITY 98 data.2

Year

Pro

porti

on o

f dem

ocra

cies

1800 1850 1900 1950 2000

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

-6-4

-20

2

Mea

n le

vel o

f dem

ocra

cy

Proportion of democraciesMean level of democracy

Figure 1: The global distribution of democracy, 1800-1996

The extent of political democracy in the world indeed seems greater at the present than at any

previous period in history (e.g., Huntington 1991). Though the mean and median values resemble the so-

called “three waves” of democracy, other measures of central tendency yield quite different images of the

2 This scale ranges from a low of –10 to a high of 10 in degree of institutionalized democracy (Gurr, Jaggers and Moore 1989). I here treat the scale as if it were continuous, though it is strictly speaking ordinal rather than interval (Gleditsch and Ward 1997). The threshold for “democracy” is here set to a score of six or above.

Page 4: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

3

evolution of political democracy in the world. The mode is the minimum value for most years well

throughout the middle of the 19th Century, and fluctuates between high and low values in the 20th Century

after World War I. Only in the latter part of the 19th and the earliest part of 20th Century are the modal

values close to the mean. That the mode oscillates between the extremes of the POLITY 98 scale reflects

a bimodal distribution, but also indicates that there is considerable difference in “typical countries” over

time.

As the domestic and economic conditions that typically are assigned causal importance tend to

change relatively slowly over time, it seems questionable whether the observed variation in the

distribution of democracy can be attributed to changes in these factors alone. At a minimum, the

relationship between such domestic attributes and authority structures does not seem structurally stable

over time.3

The recent changes toward greater political democracy commonly known as the “third wave” of

democracy have sensitized researchers to that trends in democratization may reflect influences from a

changing global environment rather than similar processes operating independently or in a parallel

fashion within each case (e.g., Huntington 1991). In a remarkable change of emphasis, Whitehead (1996)

even claims that of all the democracies existing at the beginning of the 1990s, only in Sweden,

Switzerland, and the United Kingdom did political democracy evolve independently of international

events. Though recent work focuses almost exclusively on the diffusion of democratic authority

structures, changes at the global level have not been consistently toward greater democracy. Most

notably, the breakdowns of fragile democracies in the inter-war period and in the aftermath of

decolonialization suggest that a spread of autocracy prevailed for much of the 20th century (see also

O'Loughlin et al. 1998).

Merely attributing democratization or autocratization to some “international context,” however,

explains little without clarifying the relevant context and some hypothesized mechanisms that influence

the emergence of democracy. Many look to changes at the global level itself, and attribute variation in the

global distribution of democracy over time to changes in largely autonomous belief structures and the

relative status of political ideologies (e.g., Fukuyama 1992), or the changing nature of hegemony and the

position of the United States on democracy (e.g., Robinson 1996). These studies tend to remain rather

descriptive, and rarely provide any explicit hypotheses as to why the balance of ideologies or hegemony

change in such a way as to favor democracy.4

3 Some of the differences stem from new states entering the international system rather than changes in countries in the system. But while some of the major breakpoints in Figure 1 are associated with changes in the composition of the system — notably the two world wars and the process of decolonialization — the variation in the mode of democracy indicates that there is no simple relationship between system size and the global distribution of democracy. 4 Marxist and World-Systems analysts such as Robinson (1996) essentially assert that whatever changes occur are due to the changing nature of hegemony — thereby directly assuming what is to be proven. US presidential administrations also seem to differ considerably in the emphasis on democracy in foreign policy. Though the Carter administration, at least initially, placed greater emphasis on democracy and human rights, these features were much less prominent under Reagan and Bush when the “third wave” picked up speed.

Page 5: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

4

In one of the few empirical studies of global level influences, Ray (1995b) evaluates how much

of the total variance in transitions to democracy can be attributed to system-level and national attributes

respectively. His analysis indicates that the global share seems relatively modest, and Ray surmises that

the global influences on democracy may have been overstated.

Such largely negative findings could also be due to the all-encompassing nature of the notion of

global context. Global-level influences on democratization are often presented in a fashion so general as

to render a systematic assessment difficult. Assuming that everything is related to everything else makes

empirical analysis nearly intractable, and assuming universal global influences might be as grossly

inaccurate as fully identical processes operating independently within each country. Invoking global

context furthermore implicitly assumes that external influences on regime change and political authority

structures at any point in time are essentially similar or consistent across all countries.

By contrast, I submit that regions or local environments provide a more reasonable context of

diffusion and container of primary external factors and interactions influencing changes in political

authority structures. Geography and distance induce dependence and affectedness, and shape incentives

and behavior among neighboring countries. Spatially grounded measures that incorporate influences from

neighboring states can help address implications of interdependence for international conflict and

cooperation (Gleditsch 1999, Gleditsch and Ward 2000, Shin and Ward 1999), and provide a promising

avenue to examine international dimensions of democratization.

Diffusion and dependence at the local level can have dramatically different implications for

entities within the global system, depending upon the specific composition of neighboring states or their

regional context. A stable share of countries that by some criterion are judged to be “democracies” at the

global level may mask considerable variation at the local level. Local differences such as countries within

highly autocratic regions becoming more autocratic while polities in more democratic contexts experience

transitions to democracy could wash out in the aggregate. Though such changes go in different directions,

they can nonetheless be seen as qualitatively similar processes that induce similarity in authority

structures within regions or geographical clusters that differ markedly between each other.

Towards a theory of diffusion

What factors underlie such local diffusion and dependence in authority structures? Recent literature on

democratization argues that democracy emerges as an outcome of enduring social conflict when no single

actor possesses sufficient resources to impose itself upon others (e.g., Olson 1993, Przeworski 1988,

Vanhanen 1990). Institutionalizing methods for sharing power and establishing political and civil rights

become rational options when social actors are unable or unlikely to have their unrestricted preferences

prevail. There is no inherent reason why such struggles over influence and applicable resources should

“stop at water’s edge,” or be fully confined within the boundaries of individual countries. The balance of

power or the resources and influence that given social groups can mobilize can be altered decisively not

Page 6: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

5

only by domestic factors and processes, but through external events and opportunities for assistance from

“outside” actors as well.

External influences that alter the balance of power at the domestic scene may be located at a

variety of types of levels and actors. Many non-governmental social and political networks are clearly

transnational in nature and operate across national borders. Though such groups may rarely alone

undermine ruling coalitions or influence policies directly, they can exert critical indirect effects through

altering the existing distribution of resources or influence that groups within states can muster. Many

political movements associated with ethnic groups such as the Irish Republican Army and the Kurdish

Labor Party (PKK) have drawn heavily upon resources mobilized in diasporas. History exhibits several

examples of international networks actively trying to change the course of events in other countries,

spanning from peace activists to commercial interests, armed insurgencies, and revolutionary varieties of

Islam (Deutsch 1954, Keck and Sikkink 1999, Randle 1991, Smith, Pagnucco and Lopez 1998). States or

domestic coalitions in power will often take an active interest in events occurring in neighboring countries

and try to influence outcomes according to their preferences. Foreign policies are shaped by demands

from transnational actors (e.g., Davis and Moore 1997), and neighboring states may supply important

resources to actors that can affect the outcomes of political struggles at the margin.

Such coalitions between external and internal actors are likely to exert the most dramatic effects

on authority structures when there are shifts in the coalitions that hold power in neighboring entities, as

these tend to be associated with large changes in the resources or means of influence that actors can

mobilize. Many studies invoke variations on Schelling’s (1971) “tipping model” to show how merely

small changes in external context can suffice to yield cascades of individual participation, thereby

generating a critical mass in political contestation (e.g., Kuran 1989, 1991, Lohmann 1994). Such

processes are often held to have played out in the fall of socialism in Eastern Europe, where the initial

political changes in Poland and Hungary changed the relative influence of actors and constraints on

feasible actions which spurred subsequent changes in Czechoslovakia and East Germany.

Diffusion processes may also induce regime changes other than transitions to democracy. Ghana

can be seen as prototypical for the development of governance in many post-colonial African societies.

After the relatively democratic constitution at the time of independence in 1958, president Nkrumah

became increasingly dictatorial and severely limited political opposition. The one-party system

introduced in 1964 quickly spread to many neighboring states. More recently, regime changes and

insurgencies in Central Africa display similar diffusion processes. Many regard the Ugandan support as

critical for the 1994 RPF takeover in Rwanda. The changes in Rwanda again boosted Kabila’s armed

uprising that toppled Mobutu in neighboring Zaïre. Many regime changes involving major political

reorientations may not show up in measures of authority structures, however, as changes in the leadership

or ideological orientation of autocracies do not necessarily yield changes in institutional structures per se.

If diffusion processes operate between states operate more generally, we should see a serial

clustering geographically both in the distribution of authority structures as well as changes in such

Page 7: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

6

attributes. I will later show that we indeed find such clustering in authority structures, and that transitions

and survival for regimes co-vary dramatically with the regional context.

Democratization and the diffusion of conflict and peace

Though transnational integration might provide a facilitating condition for many forms of diffusion

processes, some forms are clearly possible even in the absence of significant integration. In particular, the

diffusion of conflict and insecurity within regions may severely constrain prospects for democratic rule.

Many have elevated the so-called “democratic peace”, or the empirical finding that pairs of

democracies seem to have a lower likelihood of conflict than other combinations of polities, to an

“empirical law” of international relations (e.g., Levy 1989, Russett 1993). In this research tradition, the

distribution of authority structures in the international system is taken as exogenous or given when

comparing the conflict proneness of pairs of countries with different authority structures. However, the

likelihood that a country is democratic or experiences transitions may itself be related to its propensity for

conflict and peace. Stated differently, democracy cannot be considered fully exogenous if countries that

are less likely to experience conflict or enjoy a more secure peace have better prospects for democracy in

the first place.

Many proponents and opponents of the democratic peace concede that the likelihood of

transitions or sustaining democracy in part may be related to peace itself, but disagree about whether such

broader linkages revolve around positive feedback between democracy and peace or reverse causal

linkages from secure peace to democracy. In the first instance, linkages from democracy to peace

reinforce the democratic or broader liberal peace proposition. Under the latter view, the notion of

democracy as a path to peace confuses the direction of causality and the substantive implications of the

association between the two.

Many proponents of the democratic peace suggest feedback mechanisms between peace and

democracy, where democracy first makes peace more likely and the improved prospects for peace

subsequently enhances the prospects for sustaining democracy (see, e.g., Russett 1998). In addition, some

of the domestic socio-economic factors seen as conducive to democratization and democratic

consolidation such as economic performance, wealth, and trade may conceivably influence the propensity

for peace and conflict (e.g., Hegre 1999, Rosecrance 1986). Many critics assert as a self-evident

proposition that peace is a prerequisite for preserving democracy. Some surmise that the absence of war

between democracies could merely stem from that democracy is likely to break down under the threat of

war and thus rarely survives until war breaks out (e.g., Layne 1994). Others hypothesize that times of war

will be associated with a decline in democracy, as efforts to wage war can be incompatible with civil

liberties or induce at least temporary restrictions in democracies (e.g., Gates, Knutsen and Moses 1996).

Similarly, Mansfield and Snyder (1998) hold that young democracies with fragile institutions are at

greater risk for reversals when involved in or at risk of conflict.

Page 8: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

7

Numerous cases where stability and lack of belligerence go together with autocratic rule attest to

that peace cannot be sufficient for democracy. Nor can peace or absence of conflict involvement be

strictly necessary for democracy, since many democracies participate in interstate wars and sustained

conflict and yet remain democracies. Of course, this does not imply that the no linkages may exist from

conflict and peace to democracy, and few probably hold that merit of hypotheses on the potential effects

of peace on democratization should be judged by whether such deterministic regularities obtain. These

examples do, however, indicate that assertions that democracy is incompatible with conflict in their

general form are not evidently correct, and that such hypotheses require emendation to be tested

empirically in any meaningful manner.

Thompson (1996) set forward a more general war-making/state-making perspective on

democratization that clarifies some possible linkages. According to Thompson, the political systems that

eventually emerge historically have been strongly shaped by rulers’ need to obtain resources and mobilize

for military efforts. Sustained perpetual rivalry and threats to vital security tend to foster authoritarianism

as power becomes more centralized. A situation of relative regional peace, by contrast, may facilitate the

initial emergence of political pluralism as internal political processes can unfold within some degree of

insulation from external demands or threats. Thompson argues that contemporary and historical “zones of

peace” emerged when previously dominant states were forced to abandon ambitions of regional

hegemony. In Norway, for example, efforts to push for full independence from Sweden were put on hold

in the late 19th century over concerns over increased Russification in Finland, and it is not incidental that

the 1905 independence coincides with the defeat of the perceived threat in the Russo-Japanese war.

Barzel and Kiser (1997) set forward an alternative interpretation of the role of war and security in

the emergence of voting institutions in medieval Europe. Warfare has in some cases moved states towards

democratization through rulers’ need to cede political rights to subjects in exchange for the ability to

extract tax revenue (e.g., Kiser and Barzel 1991). Though many theories relate the emergence of

democracy and political rights to weak rulers, Barzel and Kiser hold the security of rule as essential for

the possibility of contracting between rulers and the ruled. The less secure a ruler, the lower the potential

level of cooperative contracting, and the lower the rate of development of voting institutions. In addition

to lower internal threats, the relative geographical isolation and protection from external threat may in

part explain why voting institutions were more developed and durable in England than in France.5 While

these linkages are quite different from those of Thompson (1996), the observable implications for

linkages between regional peace and democracy are largely similar.

From this perspective, it is less surprising that the presence or absence of war among states

correlates with the extent of their political democracy. The idea of democracy as a path to peace amounts

to “putting the cart before the horse” if a situation of relatively secure peace or absence of regional threat

was an important prerequisite for the emergence of democratic political systems. Though this “regional

5 If regional threats do impede democracy, there is certainly something to be said for “splendid isolation.” Such linkages may in part underlie the relationship between democracy and insularity some emphasize (e.g., Anckar and Anckar 1995).

Page 9: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

8

peace precedes democratization” hypothesis does not necessarily disprove the democratic peace, it

suggests that constraints on initial democratization and their relationship to international interactions may

have been disregarded in previous work. Such omissions make it difficult to evaluate the implications of

existing findings and leave an unstable foundation for inferring policy implications.

Thompson and Barzel and Kieser illustrate their arguments by various historical cases, but

linkages from war and peace to democracy have rarely been examined in any systematic manner. Some

studies examining whether wars exert some effect on the prospects for democracy find that conflict

involvement does not seem to decrease democracy (e.g., McLaughlin 1996, Mousseau and Shi 1999).

However, not all incidents of “war” and “peace” as the absence of war at some given point in time are

qualitatively equivalent, and correlating general war involvement with democracy can miss out on central

ways by which conflict may influence democracy.

First, researchers have examined whether general participation in conflict is associated with

democratization and autocratization, though the relevant variable is the extent of threats to security in a

country’s regional context. The “cart before the horse” hypothesis suggest that persistent insecurity over

time can inhibit the emergence of democracy rather than that participation in conflict is incompatible with

democracy in and of itself. Existing efforts to test linkages from conflict to prospects for democracy

focus on a state’s general “belligerence”, and have not sought to identify the locus of conflict involvement

or to what extent conflicts pose threats to a state’s vital security. Participation in UN peacekeeping forces

outside the regional context or remote colonial wars that do not expose the core territory to risks, for

example, should not be expected to lead to a breakdown of democracy in developed societies.

Second, effects of conflict on the prospects for democracy are not necessarily one-time events

immediately following outbreaks of war, but hinge upon more enduring forms of insecurity and threats

that do not necessarily break out into open warfare or conflict all the time. Rather than just the peaks of

conflict resulting in wars, we need to consider the broader array of hostile interactions in a country’s

regional context over time. The history of interaction shapes the perceived insecurity that may affect

long-term prospects for democracy through risk of recurrence and diffusion of conflict. Though the extent

of real and perceived “threats” over time is a latent or not directly observable factor, measures based on

interaction across time and space can provide more valid indicators than data on single events.

To assess the element of threat, I thus distinguish between local conflict and conflict involvement

elsewhere in the international system. If the hypotheses linking conflict and peace to democracy have

some merit, we should observe a relationship between democracy and the stability of peace in a country

i’s regional context.

Page 10: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

9

Empirical analysis

Clustering of democracy and democratization

If the idea of regional diffusion of authority structures has some merit, we should to observe a positive

relationship between the composition of authority structures in the proximate regional context and a

country’s own domestic authority structures. Democracy and democratization should cluster in disparate

and qualitatively different zones over time and space. We can explore the empirical record more

systematically through descriptive statistics of the extent of clustering and variation across space.

Conceptually, the extent of spatial clustering in data on geographically situated units can be

studied at either a global or a local level. Attributes are clustered globally if values on the particular

variable are distributed in some geographic pattern deviating systematically from a random distribution or

what one would expect from chance. By contrast, local measures of spatial clustering identify whether

specific regions cluster or exhibit strong similarity in attributes or behavior. Stated differently, global

indicators of spatial clustering indicate whether aspects are non-randomly distributed in space, whereas

local indicators indicate which regions or locales display high or low values respectively.

The most common statistic for assessing the extent of global clustering in some variable x for a

cross-section of geographical units is the so-called Moran’s (1950) I coefficient. This is defined as

In

ww

x x x xx xijji

iji j

iiji

=− −

−∑∑ ∑∑∑~~ ( )( )

( )2 (1)

where ijw~ denotes an element [ , ]i j of a row-standardized matrix ~W that acquires a non-zero value if

units i and j are contiguous. 6 The value of the Moran’s I statistic indicates the similarity of xi for each

unit i with its J neighboring entities x j . However, the coefficient is not bounded by ±1, and the expected

value is E I( ) = −−11N

rather than 0. The estimated standard error of the Moran’s I statistic,

V I E E IIa f c h a f= −σ2 2 , allows testing whether the observed levels of global clustering in a given

sample differ significantly from the null hypothesis of no spatial clustering.7

6 The rows of

~W each sum up to one. Note that the diagonal of

~W by convention is set to zero so that countries are

not considered contiguous with themselves. 7 The expected value of the variance E

Iσ 2b gturns out to be somewhat cumbersome to express and depends upon

sampling assumptions. Cliff and Ord (1973:15) develop the expected value of the variance of Moran’s I under a

normality assumption and a randomization assumption. Under normality, EI

σ 2b g is n S nS S

S n

2

1 2 0

2

0

2 2

3

1

− +

−b g while under

randomization EI

σ 2b g turns out to be n n n S nS S E x x n n S nS S

S n n n

i

2

1 2 0

2 4 2

1 2 0

2

0

2

3 3 3 2 6

1 2 3

− + − + − − − − +

− − −

( )( )( )( )

b g b g, where

Page 11: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

10

To assess whether the distribution of political authority structures cluster geographically in a non-

random fashion in the international system, I calculate Moran’s I coefficients for the levels in the

composite institutionalized democracy scale in the POLITY 98 data set for each year in the period 1875-

96, as well as changes on this scale over the prior ten years. I generate contiguity data from a new data set

on the minimum distances between polities, and consider states contiguous if they are less than 950

kilometers apart from each other.8 I plot the value of the Moran’s I coefficients over time in Figure 2.

Significant values are indicated by filled circles, and blank circles indicate cases where the null

hypothesis of no spatial dependence cannot be rejected at p <.05. The expected value of Moran’s I is

plotted as a solid line.9

Moran's I, level of democracy

Year

Mor

an's

I (9

50 k

m)

1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

-0.2

0.2

0.6

1.0

Moran's I, change in democracy

Year

Mor

an's

I (9

50 k

m)

1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

-0.2

0.2

0.6

1.0

Figure 2: Moran’s I for clustering of institutionalized democracy and changes in democracy, 1875-1996

S w wi j j ij

n

i

n

0 11= +

== ∑∑ , ,a f , S w w

i j j ij

n

i1

2

11

1

2= +

== ∑∑ , ,a fn

, S w wi j j ij

n

i2

2

11= +

== ∑∑ ~ ~, ,

a fn

, and wi j, denotes an element

[ , ]i j in a binary connectivity matrix W , all the other variables as defined above. 8 This data set allows varying the cut-off criteria for what is to be considered “relevant” distances, and has been adjusted to incorporate border changes since 1875. It is described in greater detail in Gleditsch and Ward (1999a). A 950-km cut-off criterion has a range of inclusion corresponding quite closely to the notion of geographical regions. I have used cut-off criteria for relevance set to 950, 475, and 50 kilometers respectively to generate binary contiguity matrices. For considerations of space, only results based on the 950 km threshold are shown here. The results at other distance threshold do not yield substantively different conclusions and are available on request. 9 The expected value of Moran’s I depends upon sample size, but the change from one year to another is relatively small and the flat nature of the line suggests that comparisons across time are not too problematic here. Though the null hypothesis here obviously is spatial independence (i.e., that observations are not correlated across space), the interpretation of tests can be ambiguous since potential patterns of spatial dependence may lack a known representation. In this sense, we only fail to reject a null hypothesis of no-spatial dependence for some specific hypothesized pattern, and cannot conclusively rule out other patterns of cross-unit dependence (Anselin 1988).

Page 12: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

11

The upper row in Figure 2 displays the extent of global clustering in institutionalized democracy.

These results strongly suggest that institutionalized democracy is distributed non-randomly in space. With

the exception of a few years (notably during World War II), the values of Moran’s I indicate quite

consistent, significant spatial clustering in the observed data from the end of the 19th century. In other

words, the likelihood of observing whether a given country will be democratic or not differs according to

its regional context or the properties of neighboring countries.

The lower row indicates whether the changes in authority structures over a ten-year period appear

to be distributed geographically in a non-random fashion. Changes are quite infrequent, and for most

years, the Moran’s I coefficients do not achieve statistical significance. From the late 1970s and on,

however, the null hypothesis of no spatial clustering is rejected for most years. Even at the aggregate level

of the international system, we thus find evidence of a geographical clustering in political changes and

transitions during the “third wave” of democratization.

The Moran’s I indicates geographic clustering in the aggregate, but does not by itself indicate

where democracies and autocracies cluster. The so-called *iG statistic is a common indicator of local

clustering or whether values of a given variable x are similar for entities around some location i (Ord and

Getis 1995). This is defined as

Gw x w w x

n w w ni

ij j iji iij

x ij i ijj

*( )

$ / ( ),=

− +

− −

∑∑∑∑σ 2 2

1 (2)

where ijw denotes element [ , ]i j in a binary contiguity matrix W and jx denotes an observation at

location j.10 The values of the *iG statistic can be interpreted as standardized Z-scores. A positive value of

*iG at a particular location implies spatial clustering of high values around that location, while a negative

value indicates a spatial grouping of low values.

10 Since the interest here is in to what extent observations are similar to their neighbors, the diagonal entries in W are all set to one. An alternative statistic Gi , which does not include the values of i itself, indicates to what extent values surrounding location i are similar values. See Ord and Getis (1995) and Gleditsch (1999: ch. 4) for further details.

Page 13: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

12

Values of G*i Democracy (1992)(<-3)(-3,-1.96)(-1.96,-1.65)(-1.65,1.65)(1.65,1.96)(1.96,3)(>3)No Data

Map 1: Values of Gi* for level of democracy, 1992

The annual *iG statistics for the years 1875-1996 reveal several discernible zones or clusters of

states with similar authority structures within the international system. Map 1 displays the localized

clustering in democracy in the international system in 1992, as seen in the values Gi* at a 950-km

threshold. Shades of green denote zones with significant positive spatial clustering or strong clustering of

high levels of democracy. By contrast, shades of orange indicate significant spatial clustering of low

values of democracy or zones of autocracies. There is significant positive clustering of democracy

throughout most of Europe, and a similar, though less strong, clustering in democracy in the Western

Hemisphere. Conversely, these zones of democracy are matched by a belt of strong clustering in

authoritarianism, stretching from Central and East Africa through the Middle East.

Can we find similar evidence of clustering for changes in authority structures as well? Map 2

indicates the extent of clustering for changes in authority structures over the prior decade as assessed by

the Gi* statistic. The significant clustering in the changes toward greater democracy both in the Southern

Cone and Eastern Europe leads some support to that the “third wave” of democratization in part unfolded

regionally.

Page 14: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

13

G*i change in democracy, 1982-92(<-3)(-3, -1.96)(-1.96, -1.65)(-1.65, 1.65)(1.65, 1.96)(1.96, 3)(>3)No Data

Map 2: Values of Gi* for changes in level of democracy over prior 10 years, 1992

Internal and external dimensions of democracy

Though many suggest international dimensions to democratization, relatively few empirical analyses have

examined systematically the importance of regional diffusion. Existing efforts to analyze empirically the

diffusion of democracy and authority structures across borders (e.g., O'Loughlin et al. 1998, Starr 1991)

largely disregard the potential influences that domestic attributes and processes may exert.

Merely reporting an aggregate relationship between a country’s authority structures and the

composition in its regional context does not in itself provide convincing evidence that diffusion processes

operate. There is in all likelihood comparable non-random geographical clustering among the principal

social and economic conditions hypothesized to influence democracy. As such, what analyses that ignore

domestic aspects altogether attribute to diffusion may simply stem from geographical clustering in

omitted domestic attributes that influence the propensity for democracy. 11 To say something about the

relative effects of external dimensions of democracy, these must be assessed while simultaneously

considering some of the plausible confounding domestic factors. While I cannot consider all theories

relating democracy to domestic processes here, the primary alternative hypothesis is obviously the “social

11 Gleditsch (1996) compared the influences of diffusion and socio-economic development on democracy as reflected by the Freedom House data more systematically. This study encompassed a relatively limited sample of

Page 15: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

14

requisites” school or that democracy is related to a country’s level of socio-economic development (e.g.,

Lipset 1960, 1994).

Much of the existing comparative research on the relationship of democracy to domestic

attributes and processes exhibits various other problems. Studies have relied on largely cross-sectional

designs where the variance is predominantly between countries. However, researchers are interested in

the likely implications of changes in the independent variables over time, and often proceed to make

inferences about prospects for democratization. Though rarely stated explicitly, many assume that the

temporal dynamics simply are mirror images of the differences between countries. In principle, however,

there is no logical connection between the two empirical domains, and it can easily be shown that

inferences about temporal dynamics based on cross-sectional variation may be misleading if the two are

not identical (e.g., Brunner and Liepelt 1972, Smith 1995).12 The basic point that the dynamics of

democratization cannot be directly inferred from levels or the distribution of democracy at a given point

often appears to have been overlooked.13

Many studies pool time-series for several countries, but fail to address the problems that the

structure of the data poses for analysis (Arat 1988, Gonick and Rosh 1988).14 Given the inherent temporal

ordering of annual observations for some country i, it would be tenuous at best to treat these observations

as independent. As authority structures rarely change from one year to the other, these observations are

likely to be highly correlated over time. Most of the variance in the pooled data is thus still between

countries rather than over time. Though there is considerable empirical evidence indicating a strong

association between a country’s development, it is less clear whether the causal effect most commonly

inferred — that economic development will yield changes toward greater democracy over time — obtains

as strongly as many assume.

To assess the relative importance of external and internal factors, I examine how the distribution

of democracy varies across time and space according to both domestic social requisites as well as external

factors in the surrounding regional context. I measure a society’s economic wealth or “social requisites”

countries, however, and suffered from problems of non-systematic coding of “proximity” or “closeness” between entities, based upon subjective assessments of each individual case. 12 Some critics like Tilly (1984) hold that cross-sectional designs are based on an underlying assumption that history follows general sequences or similar paths. This assertion, however, is highly questionable. Since the values on right hand side variables can both decrease and increase, there is no form of “evolution” assumed by the design alone. If the processes over time and space are similar, the variation across units in a cross-section might be more informative about long-run behavior than relatively short individual unit time-series. 13 Though various more historically grounded macro-comparative studies examine changes in democracy over time (e.g., Moore 1973), many researchers rely on often rather controversial historical interpretations as unambiguous and indisputable “evidence” (see Goldthorpe 1991, Lustick 1996). Others criticize the extreme determinism, where class constellations and events several decades, if not centuries, earlier are held to fully determine current regime structures (e.g., Przeworski and Limongi 1997). 14 Burkhart and Lewis-Beck (1994) try to remedy some of these shortcomings, but understates the extent of permanence over time in the data by purging the serial correlation of observations over time before the analysis and (see Beck and Katz 1996, Gleditsch 1996). Since regimes rarely change from one year to another and the serial correlation approaches 1, purging the autocorrelation essentially leaves a regression of covariates on the first differences of the annual observations where any change would have to be attributed to the covariates by construction.

Page 16: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

15

by the natural logarithm of its GDP per capita in purchasing power parities at time t (denoted ln ,Pi tc h

symbolically), using data from the Penn World Tables (Summers and Heston 1991).15 I assess the

regional context of democracy by the average of the authority structures in the region surrounding country

i using a 950-km threshold (denoted Di tR, ). I use the clustering of years without local conflict involvement

τ in the polities within 950-km of each country i as a proxy indicator of the extent of threat or stability of

peace (denoted Gi t,* τ ). More specifically, I regress a country i’s level of democracy at time t (denoted

Di t, ) on the natural logarithm of its GDP per capita in purchasing power parities at time t, the regional

average authority structures at time t, and the stability of peace in the regional context. To prevent serial

correlated residuals from inducing biased estimates and statistical overconfidence, 16 I include the first lag

of the dependent variable or country i’s level of democracy in the preceding year (i.e., Di t, − 1) on the right-

hand side. This parameter can also be interpreted as a measure of the persistence over time in the

dependent variable. Symbolically, we have the regression equation

D D P D Gi t i t i t i tR

i t i t, , , , ,*

,ln( )= + + + + +−α β β β β τ µ0 1 1 2 3 4 a f , (3)

all the variables as defined above.

15 Many suggest that differences in GDP capita probably matter comparatively more at lower levels of per capita income (e.g., Burkhart and Lewis-Beck 1994, Jackman 1973). As a linear relationship seems implausible, I use a logarithmic transformation of GDP per capita. The natural logarithm is obviously a somewhat arbitrary transformation, and other types of non-linear functional forms are of course possible (see, e.g., Jackman 1973 for a more extended discussion). Some include an additional a square term of GDP per capita (e.g., Przeworski and Limongi 1997). However, though effects may decrease in magnitude at higher per capita income, this specification seems theoretically inappropriate as there is no clear reason why additional income above some threshold should be associated with a lower level of democracy. 16 Serial dependence or autocorrelation implies that the error terms for different observations are correlated rather than independent of each other. The variance-covariance matrix V of the coefficient estimates for a regression

model is given by X X X X X XT T Tc h c h c h− −1 2 1σ Ω . Generally stated, an error structure exhibits autocorrelation

whenever Ω is not the identity matrix I , and the expected value of the off-diagonal entries ω ij are not all 0. Generalized least squares (GLS) techniques model the correlation-structure of Ω explicitly by some hypothesized estimate $Ω , and can be shown to yield consistent estimates and various desirable asymptotic properties (e.g., Hsiao 1986). Since the “true” structure of Ω is generally not known, researchers must resort to some hypothesized estimate and it is commonly assumed that error structures follow either AR(1), MA(1), or ARMA (1,1) processes. In an AR(1) structure, the correlation between two residuals ε εt t j, − reflects a common correlation coefficient ρ <1

as well as their temporal distance so that cor t t jjε ε ρ, − =c h . The serial correlation is always larger than zero, but

becomes increasingly smaller and negligible for longer temporal distances. An MA(1) structure implies that the error term incorporates the values of prior residuals ε t − 1 in addition to the stochastic component µ t , so that

ε µ λµt t t= − − 1 . Analysts typically estimate ρ from the residuals of a regression, and then purge the autoregressive component from the model until the estimated residuals appear to be white noise. However, the properties of GLS hold only asymptotically and may not obtain in an actual limited sample situation. Beck and Katz (1996) provide Monte Carlo simulation results indicating that feasible GLS estimates are not generally more efficient than regular OLS regression, with some minor corrections to control for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity, in applied settings with the data properties common in social science. More importantly, purging the serial correlation might be an adequate statistical solution, but coefficient estimates that fail to reflect the stickiness or autoregressive structure can easily be analytically misleading in that we are likely to exaggerate the substantive implications of changes in the right-hand side variables on the dependent variable.

Page 17: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

16

As the model probably will not fit all countries equally well and some may display larger

variance in the error terms than others, the pooled nature of the data is also likely to invalidate the

assumption of homoskedasticity or constant variance of the expected values of the error term between

observations.17 Table 1 thus reports heteroskedastic consistent standard errors for estimating Equation 3

based on MacKinnon and White’s (1985) jack-knife estimator.

Table 1: Regression of level of democracy on regional context, wealth, and conflict

LEVEL OF DEMOCRACY

INDEPENDENT VARIABLES COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE

STANDARD ERROR

Constant -1.122 .045

Democracy at time t-1 .960 .005

GDP per capita, natural log .147 .001

Regional context of democracy .0258 .007

Regional clustering of years at peace .040 .018

F4 4095, = 22990, N = 4096

As reflected in the .96 coefficient estimate in Table 1, there is a near deterministic relationship

between level of democracy in the previous and current year. Given the high persistence in authority

structures over time, variation in the explanatory variables is unlikely to be associated with dramatic

effects on the level of democracy, at least in the short term. The high degree of permanence indicated here

cannot be dismissed merely as an idiosyncratic feature of the POLITY data, but should be seen as an

actual feature of authority structures.18 Of course, dichotomous indicators of “democracies” and “non-

17 Heteroskedasticity means that the entries on the diagonal matrix Ω in the variance covariance matrix of the coefficient estimates V are not identical but vary in size. Heteroskedasticity does not bias coefficient estimates, but the standard error estimates will no longer be efficient. White (1980) show that a so-called “sandwich estimator” Sw , or a diagonal matrix with the squared estimated residuals of the regression $σi

2 on the diagonal, under quite

general conditions yield a consistent estimate of σ2Ω . MacKinnon and White (1985) suggest an alternative

estimator known as the “jack-knife” Smw . This weights the diagonal entries $$

σi

ih

2

21 − by the influence each

observation exerts on the coefficient estimates, as measured by the diagonal elements of the so-called “hat” matrix

given by H X X X X=−T Tc h 1

. Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) suggest that the jack-knife estimator Smw performs

better than the original White estimator Sw in small samples. 18 This estimate corresponds almost perfectly to a similar analysis (Gleditsch 1996) using the Freedom House data on democracy, with a different panel and a distinct set of right hand side variables in the model.

Page 18: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

17

democracies” would tend to display even greater persistence over time than the more disaggregated 21-

point POLITY institutionalized democracy scale.

The coefficient estimate for the other exogenous variables are all in the hypothesized direction

and statistically significant at conventional levels. As in previous research, there is a positive association

between the natural log of a country’s GDP per capita and its level of democracy. However, if we

consider the coefficient estimate relative to the metric of the variable, the actual implied differences

following variation in wealth are relatively limited. The difference between the GDP per capita of

developing countries and the values corresponding to developed OECD countries in Western

Europe/North America19 actually translates to a relatively marginal predicted difference, less than a full

point on the institutionalized democracy scale.20

Attributes such as GDP per capita or economic income are furthermore relatively static or display

changes only slowly over time. Consider a developing society with a GDP per capita of about $2,000 —

roughly equivalent to Spain in the 1950s or Guatemala in the 1970s. If we assume that this experiences a

sustained real growth rate of about 7.5% annually, even over a period of 20 years, the propensity for

democracy predicted by the model increase only marginally as its GDP per capita reaches approximately

$8,500. Many previous studies may thus have overstated the impact of changes in levels of development.

Level of democracy cannot be directly predicted on the basis of level of wealth alone. At the same time,

democratization or sustaining democracy need not be impossible in developing societies. Other recent

analysis relying on somewhat different approaches similarly find limited effects of changes in

development on democracy over time (e.g, Londregan and Poole 1996, Przeworski and Limongi 1997).21

Some may blame the measure of wealth for the seemingly weak association. Development is

often used in a much broader sense than the monetary value of the economic output, including

factors such as economic diversification, levels of education, and at times even civil liberties and the

status of women. Some argue that a proper test of the development to democracy hypothesis should

include various other indicators as alternatives to GDP per capita or additional variables (e.g.,

Gasiorowski 1988). However, proposed composite indices of “development” typically lack a coherent

theoretical foundation, and are often not comparable over time. Adding a series of alternate variables

in the same regression would induce massive multicollinearity and unstable inferences. Finally, most

other social and economic aspects hypothesized to be important for democracy such as material

19 GDP per capita values in PPP vary between $221 and $31,969 in the sample, all figures in 1985 constant dollars. The higher value limit, however, is somewhat misleading, since the distribution is highly skewed. The largest values stem from a few rather unrepresentative countries. Notably, some of the oil producing countries in the Middle East display very high GDP per capita, though these do not necessarily correspond to many of the aspects attributed to “developed societies.” By comparison, GPD per capita in 1990 for the United States is about $18,000, or a natural log of about 9.8. 20 The difference between results using the raw GDP per capita figures and logged figures is relatively marginal, and do not change the qualitative conclusions here. The overall fit as measured by an F-test, however, is somewhat better for the regression using the logged figures. 21 An econometric study by Barro (1996), arguing that development causes democracy, examines a cross-section with average growth rates and may understate the persistence in authority structures.

Page 19: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

18

inequality (e.g., Muller 1995) are likely to display even less change over time than GDP per capita.

As such, it is unlikely that these would display a stronger association with authority structures over

time.22

The coefficient estimate for the regional context of democracy may seem relatively small as well.

However, since the metric of the variable is restricted to a range from -10 to 10 and the distribution

covers the entire span of possible values between the extremes, the predicted difference over reasonable

ranges are at least as large as the plausible effects of variation in GDP per capita. The susceptibility to

change and feasibility of variation over a short time period is obviously also greater for the regional

context of democracy than most social and economic attributes. This indicates that the regional context of

democracy regional can be substantively more important than economic development, in particular as

regional shocks or changes elsewhere in a region diffuse.

Finally, Table 1 indicates some evidence of a positive relationship between a country’s levels of

democracy and the geographical clustering in peace within in its regional context, as measured by

Gi t,* τb g. Countries located in more peaceful regions tend to display more democratic authority structures

than countries in regions where threats to security are more pronounced. By distinguishing between types

of conflict involvement and considering impacts of conflict involvement beyond outbreaks, we find

empirical evidence for a negative relationship between conflict or insecurity and democracy. While the

measure of regional conflict is not devoid of problems, this supports that authority structures and conflict

may be related more broadly than just the seeming peace between democracies.

Levels of significance aside, as with economic development, the relationship between conflict,

peace, and the prospects for democracy does not appear as strong as some have surmised. Based upon the

aggregate data, values between -3 and 5 can be considered a feasible range of variation. The predicted

differences in authority structures for countries located in highly conflictual as opposed to relatively

peaceful regional contexts are still relatively limited. Many developing societies where linkages from

conflict and insecurity to authority structures presumably may apply also fall out of the sample due to

missing GDP per capita data.23

Some hypothetical thought experiments can help illustrate what these coefficient estimates imply

with respect to how international and domestic conditions influence the likelihood that countries will

become democratic over time. If we assume that the continuous values reflect some form of latent

propensity for a country to be democratic (with values above 6 indicating a democracy), we can examine

22 It may be contended that any such changes in the level of democracy are expected to be gradual, and therefore should be reflected in changes in past values of authority as well. A longitudinal study by Lichbach (1984), however, concludes that such gradual transitions were not the rule in the evolution of European polities. 23 Excluded observations from developing countries include Afghanistan, Albania, Cambodia, Cuba, Lebanon, Libya, North Korea, South Vietnam, Vietnam/North Vietnam, Yemen (after unification) and South Yemen. None of the post-Soviet republics — Estonia, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kirgizhia, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldova, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, Uzbekistan — or the former states of the Yugoslav republics — Bosnia, Croatia, Macedonia, Slovenia — are included here, as these states all become independent at the very end of the sample period. Finally, New Zealand drops out of the analysis as it has no neighboring entities within the 950 kilometer distance span.

Page 20: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

19

how changes in changes in the right-hand side variables over time influence the likelihood that a country

will be democratic. For a country starting at a GDP per capita of about $2,000 with a high annual growth

rate of 5%, keeping the other values at 0 (which is roughly similar to the aggregate means), the predicted

values on the continuous scale do not reach the threshold for “democracy” even over a forty-year period.

Consider then a different scenario where a country has the same growth rate, but during the first ten years

is located in a zone of protracted conflict and polities with low levels of political democracy. Following

some external shock, the composition of authority structures in neighboring countries as well as the extent

of threats to security in the regional context gradually moves or “co-evolves” from the high to the low end

and remains there at the end of the period. The estimated propensity for a country experiencing such

changes towards a more democratic and peaceful regional context are shown in Figure 3.

Year

Pro

pens

ity fo

r dem

ocra

cy

1950 1960 1970 1980

-10

-50

510

Figure 3: Predicted levels under transition experiment

As can be seen, the predicted propensity declines at first, reflecting a regional context with

protracted conflict and perpetuating autocracy. Following the change in the regional context after the first

ten initial years, however, the estimated propensity increases quite dramatically. Towards the end of the

period it eventually reaches the threshold value of six for “democracy” indicated by the dashed line.

Though this hypothetical thought experiment admittedly is somewhat arbitrary and assuming different

starting values and changes over time would of course yield different predictions, it indicates that social

Page 21: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

20

and economic processes within states are unlikely to alone induce changes in the distribution of

democracy in the absence of changes in the regional context. International influences and regional context

can exert very important influences on a country’s authority structures. Rather than exogenous factors or

nuisances, such differences and changes in the regional context seem central aspects of democratization

processes. Such factors can both work independently and support or contravene other domestic processes.

Though we cannot conclusively predict exogenous shocks or what aspects regional contexts will acquire,

we can make better informed predictions about democratization if we know something about how these

aspects change.

A Markov process specification of transitions

Though the above results tell us something about how authority structures vary according to regional and

domestic attributes, these findings do not necessarily translate directly into evidence on changes in

authority structures. A plausible model must take into account that relationships to levels of democracy

may not be equivalent to effects on changes or transitions. Gleditsch and Ward (1997) suggested that

changes in authority structures could be analyzed as a Markov chain process of transition between

different states over time,24 and demonstrated the relative lack of variance by showing that the observed

unconditional probabilities of transitions in the POLITY III data were rather low. Figure 4 similarly

displays the estimated first-order transition probabilities for the 21-point institutionalized democracy scale

with the updated POLITY 98 data. The rows of the matrix, or the values on the left axis of the figure,

indicate state at the previous time period t − 1, while the columns or values on the right hand axis indicate

state at the next time period t . As can be seen from the height of the diagonal, almost all observations

remain at the same state, and the on-diagonal transition (im)probabilities are never lower than .86 for any

single state on the scale.

24 A Markov chain specifies the probability distribution of some discrete variable y ti ( ) at time t as a function of the

state of observation i at previous time periods and a J J× matrix P ta f of the probabilities of transition between the various J possible states that y ti ( ) may acquire. All the entries of P ta f in each row, indicating transitions from a given state at some time period t to the next, must sum to unity. A Markov chain is said to be first-order Markov if the transition probabilities depend only on the state at the preceding time period y ti ( )− 1 and are independent of the state at previous T time periods y t y t y t Ti i i( ), ( ),..., ( )− − −2 3 . Finally, a Markov chain is said to be stationary if the transition probabilities do not depend on time t (see, e.g., Amemyia 1985: 412-7, Harary, Norman and Cartright 1965:371-7).

Page 22: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

21

-10

-5

0

5

10

Democracy at time t

-10

-5

0

5

10

Democracy at time t-1

00.

20.

40.

60.

81

Tran

sitio

n pr

obab

ility

Figure 4: Observed first-order Markov transition probabilities

Though not readily apparent from Figure 4, “anocracies” that combine features of both autocracies and

democracies tend to have somewhat higher transition values. If we take the expectation of the first-order

matrix several years ahead or power, we find greater concentrations at the extremes of the

institutionalized democracy scale. This yields some support to Eckstein and Gurr’s (1975) “congruence

theory”, which holds that incongruous anocratic polities are less stable and tend to become either more

consistently autocratic or democratic over time. The expected values estimated from the first-order

transition probabilities over a time span of thirty years are displayed in Figure 5.

Page 23: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

22

-10

-5

0

5

10

Democracy at time t+30

-10

-5

0

5

10

Democracy at time t

00.

20.

40.

60.

81

Tran

sitio

n pr

obab

ility

Figure 5: Estimated first-order Markov transition probabilities at time t+30

Figure 5 clearly indicates two main peaks of concentration or stability in the density of the

expected transition probabilities, located at the extreme poles of autocracy and democracy. The

probabilities that polities will remain at these two stages over a period of thirty years are .52 and .81

respectively. In the middle ranges, the likelihood of observing no change over three decades is generally

less than .2. As such, even the seemingly static relationships of the estimated first-order transition

probabilities indicate differences in the long-term expected stability for polities over time, as well as some

cues as to how polities with different combinations of authority structures are likely to evolve. “Perfectly”

consistent autocratic and democratic polities tend to remain coherent over time, whereas anocracies with

elements of both are likely to become either more autocratic or more democratic over time. The

asymmetric shape of the surface of the off-diagonal entries reflects the secular trend towards greater

democracy over the 18th and 19th century. More autocratic polities have experienced changes toward

democracy than constrained polities experiencing converse changes or transitions to more autocratic

forms of governance.

The unconditional first-order Markov model above can be extended to derive conditional

transition probabilities given some set of covariates of interest. Przeworski and Limongi (1997, especially

178-183) use a Markov chain to estimate the conditional likelihood of transitions between regime types

given a country’s GDP per capita or “level of development.” Their results indicate little effect of

differences in level of development, and Przeworski and Limongi (1997) insist that any seeming

association between development and democracy stems from differences in how economic performance

influence the survival of different types of regimes. Growth or increasing development enhances the

Page 24: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

23

survivability of democracies, and performance is relatively more important for the survival of

democracies than autocracies. Autocracies display a “bell shaped” curvilinear pattern of instability, and

are most likely to be replaced at “moderate” levels of performance. Since regimes in their view are

endogenous to performance, development and democracy may appear to be associated, but transitions to

democracy are entirely unrelated to economic performance. 25 In fact, Przeworski and Limongi (1997)

claim that there are no systematic causes of transitions to democracy, and that regime change is fully

exogenous and simply emerges as a “deus ex machina” out of the whims of history.

Though the effects of economic wealth may be more negligible than many have surmised,

Przeworski and Limongi’s claim that transitions are random are highly inconsistent with the notion of

international contexts of democratization and diffusion between countries. In the following section, I

demonstrate that this claim is incorrect, as the regional context strongly influences the likelihood that

countries will experience transitions.

A Markov model of transitions and regional context

By estimating the probability of transitions conditional on the regional context of democracy, we can

gauge the importance of spatial diffusion and directly evaluate Przeworski and Limongi’s (1997) claim

about the randomness of transitions. Przeworski and Limongi (1997) reiterate the defense in Alvarez et al.

(1996) of dichotomous indicators of political democracy. Despite some skepticism over the

appropriateness of dichotomous indicators (e.g., Bollen 1993, Bollen and Jackman 1989), I here

dichotomize democracy as a value of six or above on the POLITY 98 democracy scale to facilitate

comparison. The binary variable R ti a f indicates the state or regime type of country i at time t. At any

given time period, this can be either autocratic or democratic. For simplicity, I hereafter denote the two

possible states for a country i at time t simply as Ai t, and Di t, , where one condition must be true and the

other by implication false. The probability that a given regime Ri is autocratic at time t can be denoted

respectively p R t Ai i t( ) ,=c h. Since there are only two mutually exclusive outcomes or regime types for a

state at any point in time t, we must by implication have that p R t D p R t Ai i t i i t( ) ( ), ,= = − =c h c h1 .

Let p tjk ( ) be the probability of being at state k at time t given that an entity was at state j at time

t − 1. We can denote the set of transition probabilities in P ta f as p t p t p t p taa ad da dd( ), ( ), ( ), ( ). These

indicate the probabilities of a country remaining autocratic from one year to the other, a transition to

democracy, a transition to autocracy, and remaining democratic respectively. In a first-order Markov

25 Many scholars argue that economic performance could be endogenous to regime type in the sense that aspects of democratic institutions such as the rule of law may have important consequences facilitating economic growth (e.g., Alesina and Perotti 1994, Clague et al. 1996, Scully 1992, Wittman 1989). However, Przeworski and Limongi (1993) strongly reject that regime type consistently affects economic growth. Though some find evidence of a positive relationship between democracy and growth, these results do not appear robust to alternative specifications (de Haan and Siermann 1995, Levine and Renelt 1992).

Page 25: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

24

process with no exogenous variables where the state R ti ( ) at time t only depends upon the state in the

preceding period R ti − 1a f and the transition probabilities or survival rates p jj between states are constant

over time, the expected probabilities of observing either state are given by E R t t R ti i+ = ×1a f P( ) ( ) .

Since each column contains all the possible ways a democracy or autocracy can be observed at time t and

the possible transitions and survival probabilities must sum to one across each row, the probability of

observing an autocracy given previous state can be written as

E A R t p p A p p D

p A p p A

p p p p A

i t i aa i t da i t

i t da i t

da aa da i t

, , ,

, ,

,

( ) $ $ $ $

$ $ $

$ $ $ $ ,

− = +

= + −

= + −

− −

− −

1

1

1 1

1 1

1

c h c hc h c h

b g c h (4)

where the probabilities in the last expression can be estimated from the observed data.

Amemyia (1985: 414-5) shows that stationary first order Markov chain models conditional on

some set of exogenous variables X can be parameterized in a fashion similar to limited dependent

variables models as P t Fjk t( ) = X β for some function where F jkk

K

==∑ 1

1

. If diffusion mechanism operate

between countries and the regional context influences the likelihood of transitions, the conditional

probabilities p jj would differ according to the extent of democracy in the spatial context, Di tR, − 1, as

measured by the composition of regimes in a country i’s J neighboring countries at time t-1. We can

estimate the conditional probability of observing an autocracy at time t given spatial context at time t-1 by

a regression without an intercept term with either a logit or a probit link while we condition on the regime

status of country i in the previous year t-1. 26 The probabilities of observing a democracy and transitions

can then be derived from these estimates as shown above.

I thus estimate the equation

$ , , ,, ,p A D D Ai t

R Ri t i ti t i t

c h e j= + × +− − −Φ β α µ1 1 11 1

, (5)

where Φ is the cumulative density function of the standardized normal distribution. The results of the

probit model for the conditional transition probabilities in Equation 5 are displayed in Table 2.

26 Whether logit or probit is appropriate depends on whether the error term is expected to follow a logistic or normal distribution. The two will generally yield identical results (see, e.g., Maddala 1983). I use probit here to facilitate comparison with Przeworski and Limongi (1997).

Page 26: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

25

Table 2: Probit of regime type by spatial context, 1876-1996

CONDITIONING VARIABLES COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE

STANDARD ERROR

Spatial context of democracy t − 1 (i.e., β1 ) -.1326 .0062

Spatial context of democracy t − 1 × Regime t − 1 (i.e., α 1)

-.0563 .0085

Residual deviance27: 10372.65, N=9286

As can be seen from the negative coefficient estimate β1 , the likelihood that a country will be

autocratic declines quite dramatically if the spatial context is more democratic. The negative sign of

coefficient α 1 indicates that the effect of the regional context is relatively greater for countries that were

autocracies in the previous year. This suggests that a more autocratic regional context decreases the

probability of a transition to democracy even further for autocracies. However, since β1 is greater than

α 1, this effect is reversed when the regional or spatial context is more democratic, and autocracies are

much less likely to remain autocracies if the level of democracy is high in adjacent countries or its

regional context. Both democracies and autocracies are considerably less likely to survive in a regional

context characterized by authority structures that differ from those of the country itself. Substantively,

though the odds of transitions in the aggregate may seem generally low, there is a clear tendency for

transitions towards states that are more similar to the spatial context.

27 Note that conventional goodness of fit measures based on residual deviance to null deviance are meaningless in this setting, since that model does not include an intercept and there is no clear null alternative for the estimated model.

Page 27: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

26

Democratization

Spatial context of democracy

Pro

babi

lity

of tr

ansi

tion

t-1 to

t

-10 -5 0 5 10

0.0

0.4

0.8

Autocracy persists

Spatial context of democracy

Sur

viva

l rat

e fr

om t-

1 to

t

-10 -5 0 5 10

0.0

0.4

0.8

Autocratization

Spatial context of democracy

Pro

babi

lity

of tr

ansi

tion

t-1 to

t

-10 -5 0 5 10

0.0

0.4

0.8

Democracy endures

Spatial context of democracy

Sur

viva

l rat

e fr

om t-

1 to

t

-10 -5 0 5 10

0.0

0.4

0.8

Figure 6: Estimated survival and transition probabilities given spatial context of democracy

What is the magnitude of predicted effects with respect to the likelihood of survival and

transitions? Figure 6 shows the implied predicted likelihood of regime survival and change from the

above coefficients. As can be seen, the estimated probabilities co-vary closely with the values of the

spatial context. In fact, the estimated values approach 0s and 1s. These results suggest an almost

deterministic relationship between spatial context and the likelihood that a country will endure or

experience regime changes that resemble the composition of authority structures in its regional context.

Autocracies are almost certain to endure in highly autocratic regional interaction contexts, and the

predicted likelihood of observing a democracy among other autocratic states virtually approaches zero.

However, the estimated probabilities that an autocracy will endure if located in a highly democratic

regional context are negligible. Conversely, changes to democracy become more likely as the regional

context of authority structures that a country is located in becomes more democratic. By the same token,

democracies are predicted to break down if the regional context becomes more autocratic.

These results are broadly consistent with many transitions both in the recent “third wave of

democracy” as well as the “second wave of autocracy” after decolonialization. In fact, it is hard to find

clear examples where polities persist in stark contrast to their surrounding entities or regional context.

Many of the examples that come to mind are countries that have somehow isolated themselves from

Page 28: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

27

influences from their regional context, either geographically or through self-sufficiency, size, or the

pervasive influence from external actors. The fact that Cuba is an island may in part account for the

stability of the regime, while India and the superpower “overlay” in the case of Israel and its Middle

Eastern neighbors might provide examples of the latter (e.g., Buzan 1991, Väyrynen 1984).

Table 3: Observed versus predicted regime status from Equation 4, 1876-1996

PREDICTED REGIME STATUS OBSERVED REGIME STATUS Autocracy Democracy

Autocracy 4815 862

Democracy 1664 1944

The predicted effects are undoubtedly strong, and one might wonder how credible they are.

Large-scale transitions between “democracy” and “non-democracy” are obviously very rare events. Since

the above result is based on a relatively small number of transitions and might be sensitive to the choice

of cut-off point for “democracy”, the results may not be stable or robust to alternative specifications. The

“fit” of the model in terms of predictive ability can be evaluated by comparing predicted and observed

regime states in Table 3, which indicates a reasonable correspondence. The overall percentage of

observations that are classified correctly is 73%. However, the validity of the overall classification as a

measure of prediction is somewhat limited by the preponderance of autocracies. Similarly, there is no

clear null model to evaluate the increase in predictive ability from. Perhaps more interestingly, we also

find that the proportion of democracies predicted correctly by the model is about 54%.

These results provide strong support for that the regional context of authority structures exerts

strong effects on regime changes. Knowing a country’s location and the characteristics of surrounding

entities does yield some predictive power, and there is a marked tendency for cases to change in ways

similar to their regional context over time. Given such evidence of dependence and diffusion between

countries, the claim that regime change is entirely random and exogenous seems incorrect or at least

overly strong. Like Monet’s water lilies that look like random dots up close and only acquire shape with a

change of perspective, the randomness of democratization may lie in the eye of the beholder.

Is there an equilibrium probability of democracy given wealth?

How do these results compare with Przeworski and Limongi (1997), and what are the implications of

regional context and diffusion for their inferences? Do the claims about the existence of stable

equilibrium probabilities of democracy given economic wealth hold up when the regional context is taken

Page 29: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

28

into account? And finally, do the conditional probabilities of transitions given regional context results

differ if we consider potential influences of economic wealth as well?

Przeworski and Limongi’s (1997) analysis is somewhat opaque and not fully documented. Based

on the description that they “estimate transitions probabilities on level [of per capita income] ... plus its

square” (1997:160), I infer that they estimated a probit model specifying the functional relationship

between GDP per capita (presumably in constant figures) and democracy as a second order quadratic

term, i.e.,

$ , , , ,, , , ,p A P P P A P Ai t i t i t i ti t i t i t i tc h e j e j= + + × + × +

− − − −− −Φ β β α α µ1 22

1 1 22

11 1 1 1, (6)

all the terms as defined above. The squared term in the functional relationship is justified by the “non-

linearity of observed patterns” in transitions.28

The Przeworski and Limongi (1997) study differs markedly from the present study in terms of the

data, functional form, time period, and countries in the sample. Przeworski and Limongi (1997) define

their population only loosely, and include a number of micro-states that I do not include in the population

of independent states.29 The effective dates of many countries’ independence in their study differ

considerably from commonly recognized dates. The Penn World Tables constrain the Przeworski and

Limongi sample to the 1950-90 period, while data on regional context are available for virtually every

country year in the 1875-1996 period.30 As data on economic wealth are missing from a large number of

countries, the aggregate transition probabilities may conceivably look quite different in the two studies

given differences in the composition of the samples.

Most importantly, Przeworski and Limongi (1997) use a dichotomous indicator of democracy in

the Alvarez et al. (1996) data set (hereafter ACLP),31 and this displays some noticeable differences with

the binary indicator of democracies and autocracies based on the institutionalized democracy scale in

POLITY 98. Alvarez et al. (1996) report very high aggregate correlations between their binary indicator

and other measures of democracy, including the POLITY data. Since the institutionalized democracy

28 This specification presumes that the coefficient estimate of GDP per capita is negative while that the square of GDP per capita income is positive, or increases the likelihood of observing an autocracy. Many dispute whether the relationship between development and democracy is linear, as additional development above some level probably matters less. However, this particular functional form is non-monotonic, and substantively it is not clear why one should expect the likelihood of democracy to decrease with greater wealth beyond some threshold. Przeworski and Limongi seem to defend the specification on the basis of the fit to the data. Yet, they also exclude six (unnamed) countries without other justification than that these “derive more than half their income from oil revenue” (Przeworski and Limongi 1997:159). 29 For a discussion of some of the problems involved in identifying the population of states in the international system and establishing dates of national independence, see Gleditsch and Ward (1999b). 30 Estimates of the transitions probabilities given regional context based on a sample restricted to the post 1945 period are nearly identical to the 1875-1996 estimates, and do not change the substantive interpretations notably. These results are available on request. Note also that the temporal difference should be irrelevant under the assumption that the transition probabilities P ta f are constant and do not change over time. 31 I am grateful to José Antonio Cheibub for providing me with a copy of the Alvarez, Cheibub, Limongi and Przeworski data set.

Page 30: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

29

scale in POLITY is heavily bimodal, it might be assumed that, if dichotomized, the two measures should

be identical or at least very similar. This, however, turns out not to be the case.

Of all the country-years for which the two data sets overlap,32 the percentage of observations in

agreement between the Alvarez et al. regime indicator and the dichotomous democracy is about 92%.

Some of the discrepancies, however, seem substantial. Botswana is never considered a democracy in the

ACLP data, despite being assigned a perfect score of 10 on the institutionalized democracy scale in the

POLITY data since 1966. Similar examples include Gambia 1965-93 and Malaysia 1957-68, neither of

which is ever considered a “democracy” in ACLP. In addition, several country-years with low scores in

POLITY are considered “democracies” in the ACLP data, including Argentina 1950-61 (ranging between

–9 and –1 in POLITY), the Dominican Republic 1966-77 (-3 in POLITY), and Guatemala 1950-54, 1958-

62, 1968-81, 1986-90 (never above 2 in POLITY).

Alvarez et al. (1996:10-3) discuss the case of Botswana at some length in the context of what

they call “type II” errors in classifying democracies. According to Alvarez et al., some systems in which

chief executives are elected in seemingly free multi-party elections may not be genuine democracies,

since it is not clear whether the ruling party actually would cede power to the opposition if it were to lose

an election. On the basis of this, they only classify regimes in which there has been a peaceful transfer of

power as “democracies.” Periods prior to a turnover of political power — such as Norway until 1965 and

Japan for most of the postwar period — are then “backcoded” retroactively as democracy-years.

This approach has numerous problems. Several polities commonly considered “democracies” are

classified as “autocracies” by this operationalization.33 Most fundamentally, turnovers or transfer of

power are not a defining property of political democracy, but should rather be seen as a consequence of

democracy being in place. Though a turnover criterion has often been used as a “litmus test” for

classifying democracies (e.g., Huntington 1991, Ray 1995a), turnovers in themselves do not appear in any

common definitions of democracy. We may be interested in the “stability” of democracy to opposition

victories, but the consequences of democracy should be distinguished from definitions of the concept

itself. Measures that are systematically associated with observable components that are not part of the

definition of democracy display a particular form of non-random measurement bias or a “method factor”

32 Alvarez et al (1996:3) describe their data set as “a classification of political regimes as democracies and dictatorships for a set of 141 countries between 1950 or the year of independence,” but provide no definition of system membership or states in the international system. Upon closer inspection, their data seem to classify only country-years for which data is available in the Penn World Tables. For example, West Germany is in their data from 1950, while East Germany appear only after 1970. Various developing and socialist states such as Afghanistan, Albania, Cambodia, Cuba, Lebanon, Libya, North Korea, South Yemen, and Vietnam are simply not in the ACLP data at all. In so far as the likelihood of observing data for a given country thus may be correlated with aspects of interest in other studies (e.g., conflict), this data set contains inherent sample selection biases which make it less useful for general purposes. 33 The Alvarez et al. (1996) data set includes an indicator of observations excluded by “possible type II error.” They suggest that people may include these cases as “democracies” if they disagree with the retroactive coding rule. However, this includes numerous cases of country-years which would not qualify as democracies on other criteria, such as Mexico (at least prior to the 1990s).

Page 31: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

30

(see Bollen 1993).34 This is analogous to the problems with operational definitions of democracy that

incorporating stability in the measure itself (see Bollen and Jackman 1989). If we make stability a

defining property of democracies, we exclude ourselves from studying the stability of democratic

regimes. Since many of the polities commonly considered “democracies” do not meet the turnover

criterion and are never classified as democracies, we can by construction not observe a breakdown of

democracy or transition to democracy in these countries in the ACLP data. However, these countries

would seem to provide pertinent information about the survival of democracies by the criteria set forward

in Przeworski and Limongi (1997).

From the above, it is clear that the two data sets have incommensurate definitions of democracy.

Furthermore, the two data sets are coded differently with respect to the timing of transitions in the annual

data. POLITY will generally indicate the regime that was in place throughout the larger part of the year,35

while ACLP explicitly codes transition year according to the characteristics of the regimes that emerge in

that year. Accordingly, it is less surprising that the degree of agreement on “transitions” between the two

is not particularly high. As can be seen in Table 4, only about 40% of the transitions in the ACLP data set

can be retrieved from the POLITY data, and only slightly more than half the transitions in POLITY

appear in the ACLP data set.

Table 4: Share of transition years for POLITY and ACLP data

ACLP DATA SET

POLITY No transition Transition

No transition 4197 55

Transition 34 37

If the agreement between the two data sets on transitions between states is so low out the outset,

then predicting transitions from one year to the other may obviously vary considerably if other

conditioning variables vary as well. Ignoring other differences, however, I am able to essentially replicate

the results reported by Przeworski and Limongi estimating Equation 6 with the POLITY binary

democracy data.36 These results are displayed in Table 5.

34 Bollen (1993) and Bollen and Paxton (1999) examine some systematic measurement biases in various subjective measures of liberal democracy. 35 An accompanying project labeled POLITY IIID (e.g., McLaughlin et al. 1998) contains the actual timing of changes in the POLITY data. 36 Przeworski and Limongi (1997:159) state that they exclude “six countries that derive at least half of their income from oil revenues,” but do not identify the countries. Though no theoretical justification is provided as to why these cases are not pertinent to the study, I exclude some of the wealthy oil producing countries in the Middle East —Bahrain, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, and United Arab Emirates — to emulate their restriction.

Page 32: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

31

Table 5: Probit results for transitions by GDP per capita and its square, 1950-1990

EQUATION 4

PARAMETER COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE

STANDARD ERROR

β1 -.00090 .00006

α 1 .00226 .00008

β2 .00000005 .000000004

α 2 -.00000001 .000000005

Residual deviance 1274.7, N=4188

Przeworski and Limongi hold that their results indicate that Huntington (1968:43) “was correct

with regard to dictatorships: they exhibit a ‘bell-shaped pattern of instability’ (Przeworski and Limongi

1997:160)”. They use these results to derive conditional “equilibrium probabilities” or proportions of

democracies and autocracies that the distribution will converge to and remain stable, “whatever the initial

distributions (1997:180),” in the absence of exogenous disturbances. However, they provide no

theoretical rationale for why there should be such stable “equilibrium probabilities” over time. These

claims seem to treat the empirical data as an immaculate arbiter with almost extreme reverence. Even if

such “equilibrium probabilities” of democracy and autocracy exist, can these be corroborated as “inherent

features” of data in the absence of a theory? In the following, I show that Przeworski and Limongi’s

empirical results depend upon a seemingly arbitrary parameterization and do not hold up under other

plausible alternatives.

The non-linear functional specification of a square term seems insufficiently justified on

theoretical terms and largely arbitrary. There is no explanation for why the “equilibrium probability” for

democracies should decline at higher levels of economic wealth, and the natural log of GPD per capita

provides a more reasonable non-linear specification that preserves monotoncity. This suggests an

alternative model for the likelihood of observing an autocracy given economic per capita income and

regime state in the previous year specified as

$ ln ln, , ,, ,p A P P Ai t i t i ti t i tc h e j e j= + × +

− − −Φ β α µ1 1 11 1, (7)

all the terms as previously defined. The estimated results for Equation 7 are displayed in Table 6.

Page 33: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

32

Table 6: Probit results for natural log of GDP per capita, 1950-1990

CONDITIONING VARIABLES COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE

STANDARD ERROR

GDP per capita t − 1 β1b g -.2635 .0103

GDP per capita t − 1× Regime t − 1 α 1b g .5694 .0138

Residual deviance: 621.837, N=4188

As can be seen from Table 6., the simpler model in Equation 7 has a smaller residual deviance,

despite having two fewer restrictions or a smaller loss in degrees of freedom than Przeworski and

Limongi’s more complicated model in Equation 6. The alternative specification is in this sense clearly

both less restrictive and more consistent with the data than the specification Przeworski and Limongi

propose.

Przeworski and Limongi’s (1997) interpretation no longer hold under the results from the simpler

model. As can be seen from the coefficient estimate β1 , these results also indicate that democracies are

less likely to break down the higher their GDP per capita. In addition, the coefficient estimate α 1

indicates that higher GDP per capita increases the likelihood that countries remain autocracies, and that

this effect is comparatively larger. In this sense, these results do clearly not support the notion that greater

economic wealth increases the likelihood of transitions to political democracy. However, the idea of

stable equilibrium proportion of democracies or a “bell shaped” survival pattern for autocracies no longer

obtains. Rather, the initial distribution could remain relatively stable over time irrespective of economic

performance. Przeworski and Limongi’s (1997) interpretations follow directly from their seemingly

arbitrary choice of functional form for the model rather than any inherent feature of the data as such. Why

should we expect “the true relationship” to be square rather than, say, cubic, or leptokurtotic?

Lack of available data and the relative scarcity of transitions prevents estimating Przeworski and

Limongi’s (1997) original model adding the spatial context of democracy to gauge the potential

contribution of diffusion. However, we can estimate a version of the specification in Equation 7 with

parameters for the spatial context of democracy,

$ ln ln, , , ,, , , ,p A P D P A D Ai t

Ri t

Ri t i ti t i t i t i t

c h e j e j e j= + + × + × +− − − −− −Φ β β α α µ1 2 1 1 2 11 1 1 1

, (8)

all the terms as defined above. The results of estimating Equation 8 are displayed in Table 7.

37 Note that conventional goodness of fit measures based on residual deviance to null deviance are meaningless in this setting, since the model does not include an intercept and there is no clear null alternative for the estimated model.

Page 34: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

33

Table 7: Probit of transitions by spatial context and GDP per capita, 1950-90

CONDITIONING VARIABLES COEFFICIENT ESTIMATE

STANDARD ERROR

GDP per capita t − 1 -.2655 .0112

GDP per capita t − 1× Regime t − 1 .5493 .0146

Spatial context of democracy t − 1 -.0573 .0184

Spatial context of democracy t − 1× Regime t − 1 -.0412 .0245

Residual deviance: 574.838, N=4195

The estimated coefficients for the economic variables are virtually undistinguishable from those

in Table 6. Though the estimated coefficients for the spatial context are somewhat reduced, the implied

relationship resembles the previous results. As such, the association between the transition or survival

probabilities for regimes and the regional context of authority structures does not merely stem from

failing to control for geographical clustering in higher values of GDP per capita.

38 Note that conventional goodness of fit measures based on residual deviance to null deviance are meaningless in this setting, since the model does not include an intercept and there is no clear null alternative for the estimated model.

Page 35: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

34

-10-5

05

10

Democratic context

5000

10000

15000

GDP per capita

00.

050.

1

Dem

ocra

cy b

reak

s do

wn

-10-5

05

10

Democratic context

5000

10000

15000

GDP per capita

0.75

0.80

.850

.90.

951

Aut

ocra

cy p

ersi

sts

-10-5

05

10

Democratic context

5000

10000

15000

GDP per capita

0.9

0.95

1

Dem

ocra

cy p

reva

ils

-10-5

05

10

Democratic context

5000

10000

15000

GDP per capita

00.

050.

10.1

50.2

0.25

Tran

sitio

ns to

dem

ocra

cy

Figure 7: Transition and survival probabilities by context and real GDP per capita

Figure 7 shows how the transition and survival probabilities of democracy and autocracy vary in

two-dimensional space over GDP per capita and the regional composition of authority structures. Looking

at how the transition probabilities vary with respect to GDP along the left axis indicates how Przeworski

and Limongi got part of the story right: Transitions cannot be predicted by wealth alone. In fact, the two

rightmost plot indicate that autocracy actually is much less likely to break down in wealthier countries

than the very poorest, and that transitions to democracy under certain conditions are more likely in poorer

societies. However, given the greater instability of regimes at low levels of GDP per capita, Przeworski

and Limongi are correct in suggesting that democracy is more likely to endure in wealthier states.

Whereas Przeworski and Limongi assumed that regime probabilities depend only GDP per capita,

we can see that effects of GDP per capita on the transitions and survival probabilities vary dramatically

depending on the regional context. The effects of wealth on whether autocracy persists or perishes are

negligible while the regional context is autocratic. Similarly, GDP per capita is unlikely to exert much

effect on the prospects for survival for democracies in highly democratic contexts. Democracies are more

likely to break down in highly autocratic regional contexts, and autocracy is unlikely to be sustained in

highly democratic contexts. The qualitative conclusions with respect to the effects of regional context do

not change, even if the magnitude of the effects are somewhat reduced. Since the change in curvature

Page 36: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

35

over the democracy axis is larger than that over GDP per capita and the regional context is considerably

more amenable to change in the short run than economic wealth, these results suggest the spatial context

of democracy provides a dynamic component in transitions and democratization processes. As can be

seen from Table 8, the overall success in prediction of the model is very high, with about 98.6 of all the

observations correctly predicted.

Table 8: Predicted versus observed regime status, 1950-90

OBSERVED

PREDICTED Democracy Autocracy

Democracy 1523 27

Autocracy 32 2612

Conclusion

What does this tell us about domestic and international dimensions of democracy and democratization?

Though democratic societies on average are wealthier than non-democratic states, there is less evidence

that changes in socio-economic development yield changes towards democracy. Countries’ authority

structures display strong persistence over time, and previous studies that disregard the stickiness of

regime type may have overstated the substantive implications of domestic economic change on the

likelihood of democratic rule. Moreover, democracy and democratization are not exclusively related to

domestic attributes or similar processes unfolding independently within each country, but also affected by

external conditions and events.

The distribution of democracy in the international system is strongly influenced by diffusion

processes among states, especially at the regional level. There is a strong association between a country’s

authority structures and the extent of democracy in the surrounding regional context. Not only do regimes

tend to be similar within regions, but there is also a strong tendency for transitions to occur in ways

yielding regimes more similar to the regional context. Since the regional context is more permeable to

changes in the short term than socio-economic factors, international influences on democracy appear to be

as important as the domestic “social requisites.”

A history of prior conflict and a hostile regional context decreases the likelihood that a country

will be democratic. Though it is more dubious whether this relationship alone dominates the association

between democracy and peace, taking the diffusion of conflict and peace into account enable us to say

more about prospects for democratization and its potential consequences for conflict. I have shown

elsewhere that the composition of countries in regions is more important for conflict proneness than the

Page 37: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

36

characteristics of individual countries (Gleditsch 1999). Though democratization can improve the

prospects for peace, the effects are only likely to be substantial when democratization occurs on a broader

regional basis. In addition, democracies are much more likely to break down when they are located in

zones that contain many autocracies, and such reversals to autocracy have the highest likelihood of

conflict.

Though this paper does not fully specify or describe the micro-level processes of democratization

and how international factors influence these, it seems theoretically inappropriate to treat the international

and domestic arena as fully independent with attributes in one “given” or determined by the other. Nor

does it make sense to simply assume that transitions to democracy are random and exclude the regional

context when this is the component that explains the greatest share of the variance. Though we may not

be able to predict transitions and how regions evolve over time, considering the interaction between

domestic processes and regional context allows a better delineation of plausible and observed trajectories.

Page 38: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

37

References

Alesina, Alberto, and Robert Perotti. 1994. “The Political Economy of Growth: A Survey of Recent Literature.” World Bank Economic Review 3:351-71. Almond, Gabriel A., and Sidney Verba. 1963. The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Boston, MA: Little, Brown. Alvarez, Michael R., Adam Przeworski, José Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 1996. “Classifying Political Regimes.” Studies in Comparative International Development 31:3-36. Amemyia, Takashi. 1985. Advanced Econometrics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Anckar, Dag, and Carsten Anckar. 1995. “Size, Insularity, and Democracy.” Scandinavian Political Studies 18:211-30. Anselin, Luc. 1988. Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models. Dordrecht: Kluwer. Arat, Zera. 1988. “Democracy and Economic Development: Modernization Theory Revisited.” Comparative Politics 21:21-36. Barro, Robert J. 1996. “Democracy and Growth.” Journal of Economic Growth 1:1-27. Barzel, Yoram, and Edgar Kiser. 1997. “The Development and Decline of Medieval Voting Institutions: A Comparison of England and France.” Economic Inquiry 35:244-60. Beck, Nathaniel, and Jonathan N. Katz. 1996. “Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross-Section Models.” In Political Analysis, Volume 6, edited by Walter Mebane, 1-34. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Bollen, Kenneth A. 1979. “Political Democracy and the Timing of Development.” American Sociological Review 44:572-87. Bollen, Kenneth A. 1983. “World System Position, Dependency, and Democracy: The Cross-National Evidence.” American Sociological Review 48:468-79. Bollen, Kenneth A. 1993. “Liberal Democracy: Validity and Method Factors in Cross-National Measures.” American Journal of Political Science 37:1207-30. Bollen, Kenneth A., and Robert W. Jackman. 1989. “Democracy, Stability, and Dichotomies.” American Sociological Review 54:612-21. Bollen, Kenneth A., and Pamela Paxton. 1999. “Subjective Measures of Political Democracy.” Comparative Political Studies 32:in press. Brunner, Ronald D., and Klaus Liepelt. 1972. “Data Analysis, Process Analysis, and System Change.” Midwest Journal of Political Science 17:538-69. Burkhart, Ross, and Michael Lewis-Beck. 1994. “Comparative Democracy: The Economic Development Thesis.” American Political Science Review 88:903-10.

Page 39: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

38

Buzan, Barry. 1991. People, States, and Fear: An Agenda for International Security Studies in the Post-Cold War Era. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Casper, Gretchen, and Michelle M. Taylor. 1996. Negotiating Democracy: Transitions from Authoritarian Rule. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press. Clague, Christopher, Phillip Keefer, Stephen Knack, and Mancur Olson. 1996. “Property and Contract Rights in Autocracies and Democracies.” Journal of Economic Growth 1:243-76. Cliff, Andrew D., and J. Keith Ord. 1973. Spatial Autocorrelation. London: Pion. Davidson, Russell, and James G. MacKinnon. 1993. Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press. Davis, David R., and Will H. Moore. 1997. “Ethnicity Matters: Transnational Ethnic Alliances and Foreign Policy Behavior.” International Studies Quarterly 41:171-84. de Haan, Jakob, and Clemens L. J. Siermann. 1995. “A Sensitivity Analysis of the Impact of Democracy on Economic Growth.” Empirical Economics 20:197-215. Deutsch, Karl W. 1954. Political Community at the International Level: Problems of Definition and Measurement. Garden City, NY: Doubleday. Eckstein, Harry, and Ted Robert Gurr. 1975. Patterns of Authority: A Structural Basis for Political Inquiry. New York: Wiley. Fukuyama, Francis. 1992. The End of History and The Last Man. New York: Free Press. Gasiorowski, Mark J. 1988. “Economic Dependence and Political Democracy: A Cross-National Study.” Comparative Political Studies 20:489-515. Gates, Scott, Torbjørn L. Knutsen, and Jonathon W. Moses. 1996. “Democracy and Peace: A More Skeptical View.” Journal of Peace Research 33:1-10. Gleditsch, Kristian S. 1996. Aspects of Democratization: Economic Development, Spatial Diffusion, and Persistence in Time. MA Thesis, Department of Political Science, University of Colorado. Gleditsch, Kristian S. 1999. Peace Has Its Victories, No Less Renowned than War: A Local Interaction Approach to Conflict, Integration, and Democratization. Doctoral Dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Colorado. Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 1997. “Double Take: Reexamining Democracy and Autocracy in Modern Polities.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 41:361-83. Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 1999a. Measuring Space: A Minimum Distance Data Set. Draft, Faculty of Social Sciences, University of Glasgow. Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 1999b. “A Revised List of Independent States Since 1816.” International Interactions 25:393-413. Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 2000. “War and Peace in Time and Space: The Role of Democratization.” International Studies Quarterly 44:1-29.

Page 40: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

39

Goldthorpe, John H. 1991. “The Uses of History in Sociology: Reflections on Some Recent Tendencies.” British Journal of Sociology 42:211-30. Gonick, Lev S., and Robert M. Rosh. 1988. “The Structural Constraints of the World-Economy on National Development.” Comparative Political Studies 21:171-99. Gurr, Ted R., Keith Jaggers, and Will H. Moore. 1989. Polity II Codebook. Center for Comparative Politics, Department of Political Science, University of Colorado, Modified Online Version Available at http://www.colorado.edu/IBS/GAD/spacetime/data/Polity.html. Harary, Frank, Robert Z. Norman, and Dorwin Cartright. 1965. Structural Models: An Introduction to the Theory of Directed Graphs. New York: Wiley. Hegre, Håvard. 1999. Development and the Liberal Peace: What does it Take to be a Trading State? Paper Presented at the 40th Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, Washington, DC, 16-20 February. Hsiao, Cheng. 1986. Analysis of Panel Data. New York, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven. CT: Yale University Press. Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman, OK: Oklahoma University Press. Jackman, Robert E. 1973. “On the Relation of Economic Development to Democratic Performance.” American Journal of Political Science 17:611-21. Keck, Margaret E., and Kathryn Sikkink. 1999. “Transnational Advocacy Networks in International and Regional Politics.” International Social Science Journal 51:89-101. Kiser, Edgar, and Yoram Barzel. 1991. “The Origins of Democracy in England.” Rationality and Society 3:396-422. Kuran, Timur. 1989. “Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipated Revolution.” Public Choice 61:41-74. Kuran, Timur. 1991. “The East European Revolution of 1989: Is it Surprising that We Were Surprised?” American Economic Review 81:121-5. Layne, Christopher. 1994. “ Kant or Cant: The Myth of the Democratic Peace.” International Security 19:5-49. Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions.” American Economic Review 82:942-63. Levy, Jack S. 1989. “The Causes of War: A Review of Theories and Evidence.” In Behavior, Society, and Nuclear War, Vol. 1, edited by Phillip E. Tetlock, Jo L. Husbands, Robert Jervis, Paul C. Stern, and Charles Tilly, 2120-333. New York, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lichbach, Mark I. 1984. Regime Change and the Coherence of European Governments. Denver, CO: University of Denver Graduate School of International Studies monograph series.

Page 41: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

40

Lipset, Seymour M. 1960. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. Garden City, NY: Anchor. Lipset, Seymour M. 1994. “The Social Requisites of Democracy Revisited.” American Sociological Review 59:1-22. Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. “The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989-91.” World Politics 47:42-101. Londregan, John, and Keith T. Poole. 1996. “Does High Income Promote Democracy?” World Politics 49:1-30. Lustick, Ian S. 1996. “History, Historiography, and Political Science: Multiple Historical Records and the Problem of Selection Bias.” American Political Science Review 90:605-18. MacKinnon, John G., and Halbert White. 1985. “Some Heteroskedasticity Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimators With Improved Finite Sample Properties.” Journal of Econometrics 21:305-25. Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mansfield, Edward, and Jack Snyder. 1998. Institutional Strength and Transitions. Typescript, Department of Political Science, Ohio State University. McLaughlin, Sara. 1996. The Endogeneity of the Democratic Peace. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Peace Science Society (International), Houston, TX. McLaughlin, Sara, Scott Gates, Håvard Hegre, Ranveig Gissinger, and Nils Petter Gleditsch. 1998. “Timing the Changes in Political Structures: A New Polity Database.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 42:231-42. Moore, Barrington. 1973. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston, MA: Beacon Press. Moran, Patrick A.P. 1950. “A Test for Serial Independence of Residuals.” Biometrika 37:178-81. Mousseau, Michael, and Yuhang Shi. 1999. “A Test for Reverse Causality in the Democratic Peace Relationship.” Journal of Peace Research :639-63. Muller, Edward N. 1988. “Democracy, Economic Development, and Income Inequality.” American Sociological Review 50:47-61. Muller, Edward N. 1995. “Economic Determinants of Democracy.” American Sociological Review 60:966-82. Muller, Edward N., and Mitchell A. Selligson. 1994. “Civic Culture and Democracy: The Question of a Causal Relationship.” American Political Science Review 88:635-52. O'Donnell, Guillermo, Philippe C. Schmitter, and L. Whitehead. 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Page 42: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

41

O'Loughlin, John, Michael D. Ward, Corey L. Lofdahl, Jordin S. Cohen, David S. Brown, David Reilly, Kristian S. Gleditsch, and Michael Shin. 1998. “The Diffusion of Democracy, 1946-1994.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 88:545-74. Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Democracy, Dictatorship, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87:567-76. Ord, J. Keith, and Arthur Getis. 1995. “Local Spatial Autocorrelation Statistics: Distributional Issues and an Application.” Geographical Analysis 27:286-306. Przeworski, Adam. 1988. “Democracy as a Contingent Outcome of Conflict.” In Constitutionalism and Democracy, edited by Jon Elster and Rune Slagstad, New York: Cambridge University Press. Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press. Przeworski, Adam, and Fernando Limongi. 1993. “Political Regimes and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7:51-69. Przeworski, Adam, and Fernando Limongi. 1997. “Modernization: Theories and Facts.” World Politics 49:155-83. Putnam, Robert D. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Randle, Michael. 1991. People Power: The Building of a New European Home. Stroud: Hawthorn. Ray, James L. 1995a. Democracy and International Politics. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina Press. Ray, James L. 1995b. “Global Trends, State-Specific Factors and Regime Transitions, 1825-1993.” Journal of Peace Research 32:49-63. Robinson, William I. 1996. Promoting Polyarchy: Globalization, US Intervention, and Hegemony. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press. Rosecrance, Richard N. 1986. The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest in the Modern World. New York: Basic Books. Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens. 1992. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Russett, Bruce M. 1993. Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for the Post Cold War World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Russett, Bruce M. 1998. “A Neo-Kantian Perspective: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organization in Building Security Communities.” In Security Communities, edited by Emanuel Adler and Michael Barnett, Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press. Schelling, Thomas C. 1971. “Dynamic Models of Segregation.” Journal of Mathematical Sociology 1:143-86.

Page 43: Draft version, comments welcome Kristian S. Gleditsch Faculty of … · 2014-05-07 · Almond and Verba 1963, Muller and Selligson 1994, Putnam 1993). Still others emphasize distributional

42

Scully, Gerald W. 1992. Constitutional Environments and Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Shin, Michael E., and Michael D. Ward. 1999. “Lost in Space: Military Expenditure.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 43:793 - 816. Smith, Jackie, Ron Pagnucco, and George A. Lopez. 1998. “Globalizing Human Rights: The Work of Transnational Human Rights NGOs in the 1990s.” Human Rights Quarterly 20:379-412. Smith, Mark A. 1995. Time Serial Designs and Cross-Sectional Designs: Uncovering the Structural Logic of Pooled Analyses. Typescript, Department of Political Science, University of Minnesota`. Starr, Harvey. 1991. “Democratic Dominoes: Diffusion Approaches to the Spread of Democracy in the International System.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35:356-81. Summers, Robert, and Alan Heston. 1991. “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:327-68. Thompson, William R. 1996. “Democracy and Peace: Putting the Cart Before the Horse?” International Organization 50:141-74. Tilly, Charles. 1984. Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons. New York: Sage. Vanhanen, Tatu. 1990. The Process of Democratization: A Comparative Study of 147 States, 1980-88. New York: Crane Russak. Väyrynen, Raimo. 1984. “Regional Conflict Formations: An Intractable Problem of International Relations.” Journal of Peace Research 21:335-59. Wallerstein, Imanuel. 1979. The Capitalist World-System. New York: Cambridge. Weede, Erich. 1996. Economic Development, Social Order, and World Politics: With Special Emphasis on War, Freedom, the Rise and Decline of the West, and the Future of East Asia. Boulder, CO: Rienner. White, Halbert. 1980. “A Heteroscedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroscedasticity.” Econometrica 48:817-38. Whitehead, Laurence. 1996. “Three International Dimensions of Democratization.” In The International Dimensions of Democratization: Europe and the Americas, edited by Laurence Whitehead, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Wittman, Donald. 1989. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97:1395-427.