36
KNOWLEDE ASSETS AND DECISION RIGHTS IN JOINT VENTURES: A PROPERTY RIGHTS VIEW Evidence from Hungarian Joint Ventures Josef Windsperger Associate Professor of Organization and Management Center for Business Studies, University of Vienna, Brünner Str. 72, Austria Phone: +431427738180; Fax: +431427738174; Email: [email protected] Eva Kocsis Associate Professor of Economics Department of Economics, Corvinus University of Budapest Fővám tér 8 H-1093 Budapest, Hungary Phone: +36 1 482-5308; Fax; +361 482-5137 Email: [email protected] Miklos Rosta PhD candidate, Department of Economics, Corvinus University of Budapest Fővám tér 8 H-1093 Budapest, Hungary Phone: +36 1 482-5308; Fax; +361 482-5137 Email: [email protected] Abstract.The paper examines the role of joint venture partners’ knowledge assets as determinant of the decision structure in joint ventures (JV). According to the property rights approach, the structure of residual decision rights depends on the distribution of intangible knowledge assets that generate the JV-firm’s residual surplus. Intangible knowledge assets refer to the knowledge and skills (know-how) that cannot be easily codified and transferred through contracts (e.g. through licensing), since they have an important tacit component. Our analysis derives the following hypothesis: The more important the JV-partner's knowledge assets for the generation of residual surplus, the more residual decision rights are assigned to him. In addition, we examine two views on the relationship between residual decision and residual income rights in joint ventures: (a) Under the substitutability view, residual decision and residual income rights may be negatively related

Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

KNOWLEDE ASSETS AND DECISION RIGHTS IN JOINT

VENTURES: A PROPERTY RIGHTS VIEW

Evidence from Hungarian Joint Ventures

Josef WindspergerAssociate Professor of Organization and Management

Center for Business Studies, University of Vienna, Brünner Str. 72, AustriaPhone: +431427738180; Fax: +431427738174;

Email: [email protected]

Eva KocsisAssociate Professor of Economics

Department of Economics, Corvinus University of BudapestFővám tér 8

H-1093 Budapest, HungaryPhone: +36 1 482-5308; Fax; +361 482-5137

Email: [email protected]

Miklos RostaPhD candidate, Department of Economics, Corvinus University of Budapest

Fővám tér 8H-1093 Budapest, Hungary

Phone: +36 1 482-5308; Fax; +361 482-5137Email: [email protected]

Abstract.The paper examines the role of joint venture partners’ knowledge assets as determinant of the decision structure in joint ventures (JV). According to the property rights approach, the structure of residual decision rights depends on the distribution of intangible knowledge assets that generate the JV-firm’s residual surplus. Intangible knowledge assets refer to the knowledge and skills (know-how) that cannot be easily codified and transferred through contracts (e.g. through licensing), since they have an important tacit component. Our analysis derives the following hypothesis: The more important the JV-partner's knowledge assets for the generation of residual surplus, the more residual decision rights are assigned to him. In addition, we examine two views on the relationship between residual decision and residual income rights in joint ventures: (a) Under the substitutability view, residual decision and residual income rights may be negatively related because a certain level of control may result either from the allocation of ownership (residual income) rights or the transfer of residual decision rights to the joint venture partners. (b) Under the complementarity view, residual decision and residual income rights are complements. This means that the JV-partner’s motivation to use his intangible assets to generate residual income is increased if the residual income rights are collocated with the residual decision rights. These property rights hypotheses are tested in the Hungarian market.

Keywords: Joint ventures, intangible knowledge assets, residual decision rights, ownership

rights

Page 2: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

1 Introduction

This paper explains the allocation of decision rights in joint ventures by applying the property

rights theory. The aim of the property rights theory, developed by Alchian, Demsetz, Fama,

Jensen, Barzel, Grossman, Hart and Moore (Alchian, Demsetz 1973; Fama, Jensen 1983;

Barzel 1997; Grossman, Hart 1986; Hart, Moore 1990; Hart 1995), is to explain the allocation

of residual rights of control of firms and networks (Jensen, Meckling 1992; Brynjolfsson

1994; Brickley, Dark, Weisbach 1991 ; Christie, Joye,Watts 1995; Hitt, Brynjolfsson 1997;

Windsperger 2004; Baker, Hubbard 2003, 2004). According to the property rights view, the

structure of residual decision rights (as residual rights of control) depends on the distribution

of intangible knowledge assets that generate the firm’s residual surplus. Intangible knowledge

assets refer to the knowledge and skills (know-how) that cannot be easily codified and

transferred to other agents, since they have an important tacit component (Kogut, Zander

1993; Contractor 2000; Contractor, Ra 2002). In joint venture relationships intangible

knowledge assets refer to the joint venture partners’ noncontractible capabilities (know how

in R&D, production and procurement management, marketing and advertising, human

resource management, organization design) that cannot be easiliy transferred by contract

(Hennart 1988; Nakamura, Xie 1998; Nakamura 2005;Eapen, Hennart 2005). The thesis of

the paper is that the more important the JV-partner‘s intangible knowledge assets relative to

the other for the generation of residual income, the more residual decision rights should be

assigned to him. In addition, we examine two views on the relationship between residual

decision and ownership rights (residual income rights) in joint ventures: Under the

substitutability view, residual decision and residual income rights may be negatively related

because a certain level of control may result either from the allocation of residual income

rights or the transfer of residual decision rights to the joint venture partners. Under the

complementarity view, residual decision and residual income rights are complements. This

means that the JV-partner’s motivation to use his intangible assets to generate residual income

2

Page 3: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

is increased if the residual income rights are collocated with the residual decision rights.

These property rights hypotheses are tested in the Hungarian market.

Although theoretical and empirical studies dealing with the allocation of decision

rights exist in the organizational economics and accounting literature (Aghion,Tirole 1997;

Dessein 2000; Christie et al. 1995; Baiman, Larcker, Rajan 1995; Nagar 2002; Arrunada et al.

2001; Arrunada et al. 2004; Lerner, Merger 1998; Desai, Foley, Hines 2002; Kaplan,

Stromberg 2003; Elfenbein, Lerner 2003; Windsperger 2003, 2006), no prior research

develops and test an institutional economic approach of the allocation of decision rights in

joint venture companies. This deficit may result from the difficulty in collecting data on

knowledge assets and decision rights in JV. On the other hand, in the international

management literature several studies investigate the problem of control in joint ventures

(Killing 1983, Geringer, Hebert 1989; Mjoen, Tallmann 1997; Chalos, O’Connor 1998;

Calantone, Zhao 2000; Pangarka, Klein 2004; Choi, Beamish 2004). Control has been

modelled by relative degree of ownership and/or a high level of management control and/or a

high level of control of specific activities (Blodgets 1991a,b; Gray, Yann 1992; Mjoen,

Tallman 1997). The main deficit in this literature lies in the heterogeneous concept of control

and hence in the lack of theoretical rigor concerning the operationalization of control (Yan,

Gray 2001).

Based on the property rights theory, in this paper we operationalize control by the

distribution of residual decision rights (Aghion, Tirole 1997; Baker et al. 2005; Windsperger

2003). This view is closely related to Rajan and Zingales’ concept of access to critical

resources (Rajan, Zingales 1998; 2001). They argue power stems form control over critical

assets that generate the residual income strem. Our main contribution to the joint venture

literature is twofold: First, we present a property rights view of the allocation of residual

decision rights as residual rights of control of the JV-company, and second we empirically

investigate the influence of intangible knowledge assets on the structure of residual decision

rights in Hungarian joint ventures. Consequently, this research moves forward the theoretical 3

Page 4: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

view of structuring decision making in JV by stating that the allocation of residual decision

rights depends on the intangibility (noncontractibility) of knowledge assets of the joint

venture partners.

The paper is organized as follows. Section two uses the property rights approach to

examine the relationship between the characteristics of the JV-partner’s knowledge assets and

the allocation of residual decision rights. We develop the proposition that the structure of

residual decision rights depends on the distribution of intangible knowledge assets between

the joint venture partners. Section three investigates the relationship between residual decision

and ownership rights in joint ventures. In section four we apply this framework to derive

testable hypotheses. The hypotheses are finally tested in Hungary.

2 Knowledge Assets and Decision Rights in Joint Ventures

2.1 A Property Rights View of Structuring Residual Decision Rights

Based on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992) argued that organizational

efficiency requires that those with the responsibility for decisions also have the knowledge

valuable to those decisions. Co-location of decision rights with knowledge can be achieved by

transferring the knowledge to the person who has the decision right or by transferring the

decision rights to the person with the knowledge. Such transfers mean that knowledge transfer

costs determine the degree of centralization of decision making. Which factors influence the

knowledge transfer costs? According to the property rights approach (Hart, Moore 1990) the

structure of residual decision rights depends on the distribution of intangible (noncontractible)

assets. The person who has intangible knowledge assets that generates the residual surplus

should have the residual decision rights to maximize the residual income. These rights refer to

the use of specific knowledge of place and time (Hayek 1945) that cannot be easily

communicated and specified in contracts due to too high transaction costs. Consequently,

given the distribution of intangible knowledge assets the maximum resource value obtains if

the residual decision rights are assigned to those who are best able to use these assets (Wruck, 4

Page 5: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Jensen 1994). In sum, the property rights view of the relationship between knowledge assets

and decision rights can be stated by the following proposition: The more important a person’s

intangible knowledge assets for the generation of the residual income relative to another

person, the more residual decision rights should be assigned to that person.

2.2 Allocation of Decision Rights in Joint Ventures

Now we apply the property rights approach to the allocation of decision rights in joint

ventures. Which knowledge assets are generated and used in joint venture companies and how

are the decision rights allocated between the JV-partners? In the following, we analyse a joint

venture company (JV) with two joint venture partners (JPI and JPII). The JV-partner’s parent

firms that create a joint venture company faces the problem of maximizing the returns to the

intangible assets when they are dependent on investments in intangible assets of the other

partner. The intangible knowledge assets (know-how) of JPI includes knowledge and skills

(capabilities) in product development, procurement, production and branding, and the

intangible knowledge assets of JPII refer to the local market access, cultural know-how and

human resource management capabilities (Lecraw 1984; Fagre, Wells 1982; Hennart 1988;

Nakamura 2005).

How does the distribution of intangible knowledge assets between the JV-partners

influence the distribution of decision rights in the JV-company? Decision rights refer to the

strategic and operative decisions of the JV, such as strategy, organization design, product,

price, marketing, advertising, procurement and production, finance and investment, human

resource management, and controlling system. According to Jensen and Meckling (1992),

two ways for allocating decision rights exist: Either knowledge must be transferred to those

with the right to make decisions or decision rights must be transferred to those who have the

knowledge. Thus, decision rights are allocated to JPI when the costs of transferring

knowledge from JPII to JPI are relatively low. This is the case when JPII‘s knowledge assets

are less intangible and therefore more contractible. In this case JPI has a stronger bargaining 5

Page 6: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

power, due to his intangible knowledge assets, and can easily acquire the knowledge assets of

JPII, due to its high degree of contractibility (low degree of intangibility). On the other hand,

residual decision rights have to be transferred to JPII when his know-how is very specific and

consequently the knowledge transfer and control costs are very high. In this case, the

bargaining power of JPII is relatively strong due to his noncontractible know-how. Moreover,

if it is important to take advantage of both partners’ intangible knowledge assets to generate

the residual income stream, decision making power must be allocated to both partners to

efficiently utilize their specific knowledge. This property rights view is compatible with the

resource-based view of bargaining power developed in the resource-based theory (Pfeffer,

Salancik 1978; Lecraw 1984; Blodgetts 1991; Chi 1994; Yan, Gray 1994); however, this

literature does not apply a homogeneous construct for control and differentiate between more

and less contractible (intangible) resources.

In sum, according to the property rights theory residual decision rights have to be

allocated according to the distribution of intangible knowledge assets between the JV-

partners. More intangible assets of JPI compared to JPII must lead to a higher proportion of

residual decision rights of JPI relative to JPII and vice versa. Therefore, an efficient decision

structure implies co-location of knowledge assets and decision rights (Milgrom, Roberts

1995; Hitt, Brynjolfsson 1997).

The following example illustrates this implication. We differentiate between two cases:

Case A: JPI has a large fraction of intangible knowledge assets (for instance

technological and brand name know-how) and the know-how of JPII (for

instance local market knowledge, human resource capabilities) is less

intangible (more contractible). Due JPI’s dominant know-how position he

should get a large fraction of residual decision rights to maximize the JV’s

residual income stream.

6

Page 7: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Case B: JPII has a large fraction of intangible knowledge assets that generate a

high residual surplus and the JPI’s assets are less intangible. In this case, the

residual decision rights must be assigned according to JPI and JPII’s know-

how position. Therefore, compared to case A, JPII has a stronger bargaining

power and hence more residual decision rights are transferred to JPII.

If these conditions are not fulfilled, the following inefficiencies may arise: Inefficiencies arise

(1) when – in case A - a large fraction of residual decision rights is transferred to JPII

although JPI has the most important part of intangible knowledge assets that creates a large

fraction of the total residual income stream of the JV, or (2) when - in case B - a low fraction

of residual decision rights is transferred to JPII, although JPI has only a small part of

intangible knowledge assets. Due to this incompatibilitiy between the distribution of

intangible knowledge assets and the allocation of decision rights the JV’s residual surplus

cannot be maximized.

The property rights proposition about the structure of residual decision rights in joint

ventures can be summarized as follows: The more important the JV-partner’s intangible

knowledge assets for the generation of the residual income relative to other partner, the more

residual decision rights should be assigned to him. The following testable hypothesis can be

derived:

H1: The higher the intangible knowledge assets of JPI relative to JPII, the

higher is JPI’s portion of residual decision rights.

3 Residual Decision and Ownership Rights: Complements versus Substitutes

Since the governance structure of the JV-company consists of ownership (residual income)

and decision rights, the question to ask is which relationship exists between residual income

rights and residual decision rights. There are two views on the relationship between residual

decision rights and ownership rights:

7

Page 8: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

(I) Under the complementarity view of the governance structure (Milgrom, Roberts 1995),

residual decision and residual income rights are complements. This means that the JV-

partner’s motivation to use his intangible assets to generate residual income is increased if the

ownership rights are collocated with the residual decision rights. Hence the transfer of

ownership rights increases the knowledge and incentive effect of residual decision rights

(Brickley et. al 1995). This is primarily the case when one JV-partner has a dominant know-

how position and hence his investment incentive in intangible knowledge assets primarily

determines the total residual income stream of the JV.

(II) Under the substitutability view of the governance structure, residual decision and

residual income rights are substitutes. As already Lecraw (1984) mentioned, residual decision

and residual income rights may be negatively related because a certain level of control may

result either from the allocation of ownership rights as high powered incentives or the transfer

of residual decision rights. Under this view, the more residual decision rights are assigned to a

joint venture partner, the less ownership rights must be allocated to him to maintain a certain

level of control. This is primarily the case when both partners have a strong know-how

position and hence their co-specialized investments in intangible knowledge assets determine

the total residual income stream. In this situation, a lower proportion of ownership rights of

JPI relative to JPII must be compensated by a higher proportion of residual decision rights. In

sum, the interaction effect between decision and ownership rights depends on the impact of

the JV-partners intangible assets on the creation of the total residual surplus of the JV. We can

derive the following hypotheses:

H2a: Complementarity hypothesis: The JV-partner’s residual deicision rights are

positively related with his ownership rights.

H2b: Substitutability hypothesis: The JV-partner’s residual decision rights are negatively

related with his ownership rights.

8

Page 9: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

4 Empirical Analysis

4.1 Data Collection

The empirical setting for testing these hypotheses is the Hungarian market. We used a

questionnaire to collect the data from a sample of 800 Hungarian companies. Since we have

no details on the shared ownership status of these companies, we received unfilled

questionnaires from more than thirty percent of these companies. The data set was collected

between October 2004 and March 2005. The questionnaire took, on average, approximately

15 minutes to complete. We received 80 completed responses. To trace non-response bias, we

investigated whether the results obtained from analysis are driven by differences between the

group of respondents and the group of non-respondents. Non-response bias was measured by

comparing two groups of responders (October 2004, March 2005) (Amstrong & Overton

1977). No significant differences emerged between the two groups of respondents.

4.2 Measurement

To test our property rights hypotheses the following variables are important: Intangible assets

of the joint venture partners, ownership rights, residual decision rights, as well as firm size,

age of the JV and technological uncertainty as control variables.

Intangible Knowledge Assets

The joint venture partner’s intangible assets refer to the specific knowledge of local markets,

distribution channel, procurement, human resource management, technological know-how

and knowledge of the institutional environment. In the questionnaire the managers of the

Hungarian JV-companies were asked to rate on a seven-point scale to evaluate JV-partner's

intangible assets. A ten-item scale measures the know-how advantage of JPI compared to JPII

(see appendix). The ten-item measure was extracted by employing factor analysis. All

variables had a loading in excess of 0.7. The total amount of variance explained by the factor

9

Page 10: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

solution is 64 percent. The reliability of this scale was assessed by Cronbach’s alpha (0.93)

(Hair, Anderson, Tathan, Black 1998).

Residual Decision Rights of the Joint Venture Partners

The indicator of decision rights (DR) is a measure about the distribution of decision-making

authority between the joint venture partners. Our decision rights variable includes the

following decisions of the JV: Procurement decision, price and product decisions, advertising

decision, human resource decisions (recruitment and training), investment and finance

decisions and decisions concerning the application of accounting and control systems. The

indicator of decision rights addresses the extent to which residual decisions are made by JPI

compared to JPII. Hence it is a measure for distribution of decision rights in the joint venture

company that is compatible with the Nagar’s measure of decision rights in retail banking

(Nagar 2002). The managers of the joint venture companies were asked to rate the joint

venture partner's influence on these decisions on a seven-point scale. By averaging the scale

values we constructed a decision index varying between 1 and 7. The higher the index, the

higher the JPI's influence on residual decision making in the joint venture company relative to

JPII.

Ownership Rights of the Joint Venture Partners

The joint venture partner’s ownership rights (OR) are measured by percentage of ownership

of the joint venture partners in the joint venture company (= equity ratio).

Control Variables

We controlled for three variables that might affect the allocation of decision rights in joint

ventures. These variables refer to the average sale volume of the parent firm, the age of the

joint venture, and the technological uncertainty.

10

Page 11: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Firm Size (SIZE): We use the average sale value of the JV-partner’s parent firm as

proxy of the firm size representing economies of scale of coordination. The larger the size of

the parent firm, the larger its coordination and monitoring capacity, the more easily the parent

firm can control the joint venture company, and the lower the propensity to transfer residual

decision rights to the other partner.

Joint Venture Experience (AGE): We use the number of years of the joint venture

company’s existence as proxy for interorganizational learning. The older the joint venture

company, the larger the knowledge conversion effect from tacit to more explicit knowledge

due to organizational learning (Inkpen 2000; Nonaka, Takeuchi 1995), the larger is the parent

firm’s access to the joint venture partners knowledge (Inkpen 2000, Nonaka, Takeuchi 1995),

and hence the more residual control can be exercised by the parent firm.

Technological Uncertainty (UNCERT): We use technological uncertainty as proxy for

the costs of knowledge spillover. The cost of knowledge spillover may arise because

competitors and/or joint venture partners could learn intangible knowledge assets when the

joint venture company is created (Nakamura 2005; Hennart, Zeng 2005). Under given

intangible assets, the spillover costs may increase with uncertainty due to the dynamics and

frequency of technological change. If the technological uncertainty is high, the JV-partner

may lose his know how advantage, when the the partner has a large fraction of the residual

control rights. Hence the higher the technological uncertainty, the higher the JV-partners risk

of knowledge spillover, and the more residual decision rights are necessary to capture a large

fraction of the residual surplus.

4.3 Results

4. 3. 1 Descriptive Statistics

Table 1 and 2 present descriptive data for the Hungarian joint venture companies.

11

Page 12: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Table 1: JV-Partner’s Know How and Ownership Rights

78 ,04 ,99 ,6208 ,22224

80 1,00 7,00 3,2750 2,20457

80 1,00 7,00 2,7750 1,71350

80 1,00 7,00 3,4625 1,98056

80 1,00 7,00 3,7750 2,01246

80 1,00 7,00 3,8875 2,0188679 1,00 7,00 3,8481 2,26506

79 1,00 7,00 3,4304 1,85834

79 1,00 7,00 3,8861 2,05680

79 1,00 7,00 3,3671 2,23135

79 1,00 7,00 3,0000 1,96116

JV-partner 1's proportionof ownershipKnow how in productionand logisticsKnow how in humanresource managementLocal services know howKnow how in strategicplanningKnow how in controllingR&D-know howKnow how inorganization designKnow how in strategyformationLocal market knowledgeKnowledge of localinstitutions

N Minimum Maximum MeanStandarddeviation

Table 2: Decision Rights in Joint Ventures

79 1,00 7,00 3,0886 2,19083

79 1,00 7,00 3,1392 2,06766

78 1,00 7,00 3,3205 2,09200

79 1,00 7,00 3,4304 2,07354

79 1,00 7,00 3,4430 2,09240

79 1,00 7,00 3,5190 2,06845

79 1,00 7,00 3,5570 2,28005

80 1,00 7,00 3,6375 2,24027

79 1,00 7,00 3,6456 2,11247

78 1,00 7,00 3,7051 2,18084

79 1,00 7,00 3,7722 2,18942

80 1,00 7,00 3,8625 2,26556

80 1,00 7,00 4,2375 2,33977

80 1,00 7,00 4,2750 2,29460

80 1,00 7,00 4,3500 2,10545

79 1,00 7,00 4,3924 2,21543

79 1,00 7,00 3,69410 1,78139

DR in recruiting humancapitalDR in training of humancapital DR in selectingcooperation partnersDR in selectingsuppliersDR in determiningincentives and wagesDR in promotion andadvertisingDR in determining theproduct priceDR in determining theJV-organizationDR in marketingmanagementDR in productionmanagementDR in productmanagementDR in accounting andcontrollingDR in selecting lendersDR in financialmanagementDR in strategy buildingDR in selectinginvestment projectsDecision right index

N Minimum Maximum MeanStandarddeviation

12

Page 13: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

4. 3.2 Regression Analysis

H1: Decision Rights-Hypothesis:

To test the hypothesis we carry out an ordinal regression analysis with the index of decision

rights (DR) as independent variable (Chu, Anderson 1992): The explanatory variables refer to

joint venture partner’s knowledge advantage (KNOW), firm size (SIZE), age (AGE) and

technological uncertainty (UNCERT). Therefore, we estimate the following regression

equation:

DR = + 1KNOW+ 2SIZE + 3AGE + 4UNCERT

Based on our property rights hypothesis, DR varies positively with the JPI-know-how

advantage (KNOW). Further, we include three control variables: DR vary positively with the

following variables: SIZE due to economics of scale of coordination and monitoring, AGE

due to organizational learning and technological uncertainty (UNCERT) due to the

knowledge spillover risk.Hence 1, 2, 3 and 4 have a positive sign.

Results of the ordinal regressions are provided in table 3. The fit of the models was

based on the log of the likelihood ratio. For model 1 the chi-square value of 31.178 is

significant at p < 0.001 thus rejecting the null hypothesis that the estimated coefficients are

zero.The overall fit of the ordinal regression model point to the appropriateness of the set of

variables in predicting the distribution of residual decision rights in joint ventures. In model 1

the coefficients of intangible knowledge assets (KNOW) is highly significant and consistent

with our property rights hypothesis. The larger JV1-know how advantage, the more residual

decision rights are transferred to him. In addition, the coefficients of the control variables

(SIZE and UNCERT) have the expected positive sign and are significant. On the other hand,

AGE is not significant. Finally colinearity diagnosis was performed using correlations

between the independent variables (see table 4). 13

Page 14: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Table 3: Ordinal Regression Results

MODEL 1

Dependent Variable: Decision Rights (DR)

Independent Variables CoefficientsThreshold Constants

Intangible Knowledge Assets (KNOW)

Firm Size (SIZE)

Age of the Joint Venture (AGE)

Uncertainty (UNCERT)

Model Statistics:N = 68Model Chi-square = 31.178 (p < 0.001)-2 Log likelihood = 219.943Nagelkerke R Square = 0.377

-1,172(1.228)0,056

(1,205)1,146

(1,213)2,508**(1,237)3,205**(1,254)

4,303***(1,298)

1,148***(0.264)0,464**(0.22)0,377

(0.351)0,72***(0,228)

*** p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1; values in parentheses are standard errors.

Table 4: Correlations between independent variables

1,000 ,154 ,220 -,281,154 1,000 ,001 -,054,220 ,001 1,000 -,172

-,281 -,054 -,172 1,000

SIZEAGEKNOWUNCERT

SIZE AGE KNOW UNCERT

H2: Interaction between Decision and Ownership Rights

The hypotheses (H2a, H2b) are tested by using ordinal and 2SLS regression.The governance

structure of the joint venture consists of residual decision rights (DR) and ownership rights

14

Page 15: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

(OR). Hence the choice of DR may depend on the choice of the OR, and other factors, such as

intangible assets, size, age and uncertainty.

DR = + 1KNOW+ 2SIZE + 3AGE + 4UNCERT + 5OR

Support for substitutability exists if DR and OR are negatively related and support for

complementarity exists if DR and OR are positively related. To estimate the equation, we

employ ordinal regression analysis and the two-stage least squares (2SLS) procedure (Greene

2000). Table 5 reports the result of the ordinal regression analysis. The fit of the model

increased compared to model 1 (Table 3). For model 2 the chi-square value of 36.908 is

significant at p < 0.001 and Nagelkerke R Square is 0.429. In model 2 the coefficients of

intangible knowledge assets (KNOW) is highly significant and consistent with our property

rights hypothesis. SIZE and UNCERT are significant and have the expected positive sign.

The coefficient of the proportion of ownership (OR) of JPI is positive and highly significant.

This result is compatible with the complementarity view of residual decision and ownership

rights. The JV-partner with intangible assets that generate a larger part of the residual income

should have a higher proportion of residual decision and ownership rights. In this case, the

transfer of ownership rights strengthens the knowledge and incentive effect of allocating

residual decision rights. Table 6 reports the result of 2SLS regression analysis. Model fit is

acceptable with F value of 7.21 and R2 value of 0,32. The result for KNOW is consistent with

the property rights hypothesis. The coefficients of SIZE and AGE have the expected sign. The

impact of UNCERT on residual decision rights (DR) is slightly significant indicating that

higher technological uncertainty requires more residual control by the parent firm to reduce

the knowledge spillover risk. However, the coefficient of OR is positive but not significant

under 2SLS regression analysis.

15

Page 16: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Table 5: Ordinal Regression Results (Model 2)

MODEL 2

Dependent Variable: Decision Rights (DR)

Independent Variables CoefficientsThreshold Constants

Intangible Knowledge Assets (KNOW)

Firm Size (SIZE)

Age of the Joint Venture (AGE)

Uncertainty (UNCERT)

Proportion of Ownership Rights (OR)

Model Statistics:N = 68Model Chi-square = 36.908 (p < 0.001)-2 Log likelihood = 217.796Nagelkerke R Square = 0.429

3,634**(1.778)

4,964***(1,796)

6.214***(1,837)

7.816***(1,91)

8,576***(1,949)

9,792***(2,025)

1,108***(0.261)0,437*(0.226)0,475

(0.354)0,659***(0,228)

2,514***(1,066)

*** p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1; values in parentheses are standard errors.

16

Page 17: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Table 6: 2SLS Results

Dependent Variable: Decision Rights (DR)

Independent Variables CoefficientsConstant

Intangible Knowledge Assets (KNOW)

Firm Size (SIZE)

Age of the Joint Venture (AGE)

Uncertainty (UNCERT)

Proportion of Ownership Rights (OR)

Model Statistics:N = 62F = 7,21 (p < 0.001)Adjusted R Square = 0.32

-2,65(2,46)

0,716***(0.177)0,258

(0,329) 0,554(0.341)0,433*(0,253)

3,73(5,872)

*** p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1; values in parentheses are standard errors.

5. Discussion and Implications

The goal of the paper is to provide a property rights explanation of the allocation of residual

decision rights in joint ventures by emphasizing the joint venture partner’s intangible

knowledge assets as explanatory variables. This study presents the first empirical evidence

that the allocation of residual decision rights in joint ventures depends on the distribution of

intangible knowledge assets between the joint venture partners. First, we develop the

hypothesis that the joint venture partners’ residual decision rights directly vary with the

importance of his intangible knowledge assets to generate the ex post surplus. The data from

80 Hungarian joint ventures confirm the hypothesis that the joint venture partner’s intangible

assets positively influence the tendency toward a higher proportion of residual decision rights.

Second, we investigate the relationship between residual decision and ownership rights of the

joint venture partners. Our results are compatible with the complementarity view of the

governance structure (Milgrom, Roberts 1995; Jensen, Meckling 1992). In this case, the JV-17

Page 18: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

partner’s motivation to use his intangible assets to generate residual income is increased if the

ownership rights are co-located with the residual decision rights. The data from 80 Hungarian

joint ventures partially support this hypothesis. In addition, compared to previous studies in

the international business literature, our study made an important contribution by

operationalizing JV-control through residual decision rights.

However, our empirical study has some limitations: First, although the database in the

survey sample is diverse, it remains far from a large and statistically random sample. Second,

while the empirical results provide some support for the proposed complementarity

relationship between residual decision and ownership rights, additional empirical evidence

would increase the generalizability of the results. Furthermore, future research has to

investigate the relationship between the allocation of decision rights and the performance of

the joint venture. Our property rights proposition suggests a positive relationship between the

complementarity of intangible assets and residual decision rights, on the one hand, and the

performance of the joint venture company, on the other hand.

This study also has managerial implications. The result of this study indicates that the

distribution of decision making authority in joint ventures must be based on the importance of

the JV-partners intangible knowledge assets for the creation of residual surplus. Therefore this

study provides companies with an explanation of a way to structure the residual decision

rights in joint ventures. The JV’s decision structure must be aligned with the JV-partners’

specific know how. High partner-specific know how under a low proportion of residual

decision rights may not generate a high residual surplus for the joint venture company,

because the joint venture partner does not efficiently use his intangible knowledge assets.

Conversely, low partner-specific know how under a high proportion of residual decision

rights is unlikely to maximize the residual income stream, because the joint venture partner

has not the capabilities to create a high residual surplus.

18

Page 19: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

References

Aghion, P., J. Tirole (1997), Formal and Real Authority in Organization, Journal of Political Economy, 105, 1 – 29.

Alchian, A.A., H. Demsetz (1993), The Property Rights Paradigm, Journal of Economic History, 33, 16 – 27.

Armstrong, J. S., T. S. Overton (1977), Estimating Non-Response Bias in Mail Surveys, Journal of Marketing Research, 14, 396 – 402.

Arrunada, B., L.Garicano, L.Vazquez (2001), Contractual Allocation of Decision Rights and Incentives: The Case of Automobile Distribution, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 17, 256 – 283.

Arrunada, B., L. Garicano, L. Vazquez (2004), Completing Contract Expost, Working Paper, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, July.

Baiman, S., D.F. Larcker, M.V. Rajan (1995), Organizational Design for Business Units, Journal of Accounting Research, 33, 205 – 229.

Baker, G., R. Gibbons, K. J. Murphy (2003), Governing Adaptation: Decision Rights, Payoff Rights, and Relationsships in Firms, Contracts, and other Governance Structures, Working Paper, Harvard Business School.

Baker, G., R. Gibbons, K. J. Murphy (2005), Contracting for Control, Working Paper, Harvard Business School and NBER, November.

Baker, G. P., T. N. Hubbard (2003), Make versus Buy in Trucking: Asset Ownership, Job Design and Information, American Economic Review, 93, 2003.

Baker G. P., Hubbard T. N. (2004), Contractibility and Asset Ownership: On-Board Computers and Governance in U.S. Trucking, Quarterly Journal of Econmics, 119, 1443 -1479.

Barzel, Y. (1997), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, New York.Blogett, L. L. (1991a), Toward a Resource-Based Theory of Bargaining Power in International Joint

Ventures, Journal of Global Marketing, 5, 35 – 54.Blogettt, L. L. (1991b), Partner Contributions as Predictors of Equity Share in International Joint

Ventures, Journal of International Business Studies, 22, 73 – 78.Brickley, J., F. Dark, M. Weisbach (1991), An Agency Perspective on Franchising, Financial

Management, 20, 27 – 35.Brickley, J. A. C. W. Smith, J. L. Zimmerman (1995), The Economics of Organizational Architecture,

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 8, 19 – 31.Brickley, J. A., C. W. Smith, J. S. Linck (2000), Boundaries of the Firm: Evidence form the Banking

Industry, Working Paper FR 00-01, University of Rochester. Brynjolfsson, E. (1994), Information Assets,Technology, and Organization, Management Science, 40,

1645-1662.Calatone, R. J., Y. S. Zhao (2000), Joint Ventures in China: A Comparative Study of Japanese,

Korean, and U.S. Partners, Journal of International Marketing, 10, 53 – 77.Chalos, P., N.G. O’Connor (1998), Management Control in Sino-American Joint Ventures: A

Comparative Case Analysis, Managerial Finance, 24, 53 – 72.Chi, T. (1994), Trading in Strategic Resources: Necessary Conditions, Transaction Cost Problems, and

Choice of Exchange Structure, Strategic Management Journal, 15, 271 – 290.Choi, C.-B., P. W. Beamish (2004), Split Management Control and International Joint Venture

Performance, Journal of International Business Studies, 35, 201 – 215.Christie, A., A., M. P.Joye, R.L.Watts (1995), Decentralization of the Firm : Theory and Evidence,

Working Paper, William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration, University of Rochester.

Chu, W., E. M.Anderson (1992), Capturing Ordinal Properties of Categorical Dependent Variables:A Review with Application to Modes of Foreign Entry, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 9, 149 – 160.

Contractor, F. J. (2000), Valuing Corporate Knowledge and Intangible Assets: Some General Principles, Knowledge and Process Management, 7, 242 – 255.

Contractor, F. J., W. Ra (2002), How Knowledge Attributes Influence Alliance Governance Choices: A Theory Development Note, Journal of International Management, 8, 11 – 27.

Demaris, F. (1992), Logit Modeling: Practible Applications, London.Desai, M. A., C. F. Foley, J. R. Hines Jr. (2002), The Costs of Shared Ownership: Evidence from

International Joint Ventures, Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 02-29.19

Page 20: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Dessein, W. (2000), Authority and Communication in Organizsations, Working Paper,Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago.

Eapen, A., J.-F. Hennart (2005), Entering India: Licensing or Joint Venture? 28th EIBA Annual Congress, December, Athens.

Elfenbein, D. J. Lerner (2002), Ownership and Control Righs in Internet Portal Alliances, 1995 – 1999, RAND Journal of Economics, 34, 356 – 369.

Fagre, N., L. T. Wells (1982), Bargaining Power of Multinationals and Host Governments, Journal of International Business Studies, Fall, 9 -23.

Fama, R.,M. Jensen (1983), Separation of Ownership and Control, Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 301 – 325.

Foss, K., N. Foss (1998), The Knowledge-Based Approach: An Organizational Economics Perspective, Working Paper, Copenhagen Business School, July 1998.

Geringer, J.M., Hebert, L. (1989), Control and Performance of International Joint Ventures, Journal of International Business Studies, Summer, 235 – 254.

Gray, B., A. Yann (1992), A Negotiation Model of Joint Venture Formation, Structure and Performance: Implications for Global Management,Advances in International Comparative Management, 7, 41 – 75.

Grossman, S. J., O. D. Hart (1986), The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691 – 719.

Hair, J. F., R. E. Anderson, R. L.Tathan, W. C. Black (1998), Multivariate Data Analysis, Prentice Hall.

Hart, O. (1995), Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure, Oxford.Hart, O., J. Moore (1990), Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy,

98, 1119 – 1158.Hart, O., J. Moore (1999), On the Design of Hierarchies: Coordination versus Specialization, Working

Paper, Harvard University, Department of Economics.Hayek, F. A. (1945), The Use of Knowledge in Society, American Economic Review, 35, 519 – 530.Hennart, J.-F. (1988), A Transaction Cost Theory of Equity Joint Ventures, Strategic Management

Journal, 9, 361 – 374.Hennart, J.-F., M. Zeng (2005), Structural Determinants of Joint Venture Performance, European

Management Review, 2, 105 – 115.Hitt, L. M., E. Brynjolfsson (1997), Information Technology and Internal Firm Organization: An

Exploratory Analysis, Journal of Management Information Systems, 14, 81 – 101.Hosmer, D.W., S. Lemeshow (1989), Applied Logistic Regression, New York.Inkpen, A. C. (2000), Learning Through Joint Ventures: A Framework of Knowledge Acquisition,

Journal of Management Studies, 37, 1019 – 1043.Jensen, M. C., W. H. Meckling (1992), Specific and General Knowledge and Organizational Structure,

in: L. Werin, H. Wijkander (eds.), Contract Economics, Oxford, 251 – 274.Kaplan, S. N., P. Stromberg (2003), Financial Contracting Theory Meets the Real World: Evidence

from Venture Capital Contracts, Review of Economic Studies, April, 281 – 316.Killing, J. P. (1983), Strategies for Joint Venture Succes, New York.Kogut, B., U. Zander (1993), Knowledge of the Firm and the Evolutionary Theory of the

Multinational Corporation, Journal of International Business Studies, 24, 625 – 645.Lecraw, D. J. (1984), Bargaining Power, Ownership, and Profitability of Transnational Corportations

in Developing Countries, Journal of International Business Studies, Summer, 27 – 43.Lerner, J., R. P. Merges (1998), The Control of Strategic Alliances: An Empirical Analysis of

Biotechnology Collaborations, Journal of Industrial Economics, 46, 125 – 156.Malone, T. W. (1997), Is Empowerment Just a Fad? Control, Decision Making and IT, Sloan

Management Review, Winter, 23 – 35.Milgrom, P., J. Roberts (1995), Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, Structure and Organizational

Change in Manufacturing, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19, 179– 208.Mjoen, H., S. Tallmann (1997), Control and Performance in International Joint Ventures, Organization

Science, 8, 257 – 274.Nagar, V. (2002), Delegation and Incentive Compentsation, Accounting Review, 77, 379 – 395.Nakamura, M., J. Xie (1998), Nonverifiability, Noncontractibility and Ownership Determination

Models in Foreign Direct Investment, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 16, 571 – 599.

20

Page 21: Decision and Ownership Rights in Franchising …emnet.univie.ac.at/fileadmin/user_upload/conf_EMNet/2005/... · Web viewBased on the property rights theory, Jensen and Meckling (1992)

Nakamura, M. (2005), Joint Venture Instability, Learning and the Relative Bargaining Power of Parent Firms, International Business Review, 14, 465 – 493.

Nonaka, I., H. Takeuchi (1995), The Knowledge Creating Company, New York.Pangarkar, N., S. Klein (2004), The Impact of Control on International Joint Venture Performance: A

Contingency Approach, Journal of International Marketing, 12, 86 – 107.Pfeffer, J., G. R. Salancik (1978). The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence

Perspective. New York.Rajan, R., L. Zingales (1998), Power in a Theory of the Firm, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108,

387 – 432.Rajan, R., L.Zingales (2001), The Firm as Dedicated Hierarchy: A Theory of the Origins and Growth

of Firms, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 805 - 852.Windsperger, J. (2003), Centralization of Franchising Networks: Evidence from the Austrian

Franchise Sector, Journal of Business Research, 57, 2004, 1361 – 69.Windsperger, J. (2004). The Dual Network Structure of Franchising Firms: Property Rights, Resource

Scarcity and Transaction Cost Explanations. In J. Windsperger et. Al. (eds.), Economics and Management of Franchising Networks, Heidelberg: 69 – 88.

Windsperger, J., A. Yurdakul (2006), The Governance Structure of Franchising Firms: A Property Rights View, in: G. Cliquet et al. (2006) (eds.), Economics and Management of Networks: Franchising, Strategic Alliances, and Cooperatives, Heidelberg (in print).

Wruck, K. H., M. C. Jensen (1994), Science, Specific Knowledge, and Total Quality Management, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 18, 247 – 287.

Yan, A., B. Gray (1994), Bargaining Power, Management Control, and Performance in US China joint ventures: A Comparative Case Study, Academy of Management Journal, 37, 1478 – 1517.

Yan, A., B. Gray (2001) Antecedents and Effects of Parent Control in International Joint Ventures, Journal of Management Studies, 38, 393 – 416.

APPENDIX: MEASURES OF VARIABLES

Intangible knowledge assets (KNOW): (ten items; Cronbach Alpha = 0,94): (no advantage 1 – 7 very large advantage) JV-partner 1’s know how advantage compared to JV-partner 2 evaluated by the joint venture manager concerning the following items:

(Production and logistics, recruiting, local market services, strategic planning, controlling, R&D, organization design, strategy formation, local market knowledge, local institutional knowledge)

Firm size (SIZE): Average sale value of the parent firm (per year)

Age of the joint venture company (AGE): Joint venture companies’ years of existence

Technological uncertainty (UNCERT) (one item):JV-manager has to evaluate technological uncertainty on a 5-point scale:Extent of technological changes: (1 – not at all; 5 – very large extent)

Decision rights index (DR) (Mean of 1. – 15): To which extent are the following decisions made by the JV-partner 1 compared to JV-partner 2? (no extent 1 – 7 to a very large extent)

(Recruiting, training, selection of cooperation partners, selection of suppliers, incentives and wages, promotion and advertising, investment projects, price decisions, organization structure and strategy, marketing, product management, production and procurement, accounting and controlling system, selection of lenders)

Ownership rights (OR): Percentage of asset ownership of the joint venture partners (= equity ratio)

21