132
DET SAMFUNDSVIDENSKABELIGE FAKULTET KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET Kandidatspeciale David Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics A solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle? Vejleder: Michael Bergman Afleveret den: 21/04/08

D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

My master thesis on exchange rate modelling and imperfect knowledge. With a exchange rate model including risk, based on the Vector Auto Regressive (VAR) method.

Citation preview

Page 1: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

D E T S A M F U N D S V I D E N S K A B E L I G E F A K U L T E T K Ø B E N H A V N S U N I V E R S I T E T

Kandidatspeciale David Pedersen

Imperfect Knowledge Economics A solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle?

Vejleder: Michael Bergman

Afleveret den: 21/04/08

Page 2: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

Summary Traditional exchange rate models based on the monetary approach have had a rather hard time at

explaining the fluctuations of exchange rates over the last thirty years. Mainstream exchange rate

models assume that macroeconomic fundamentals determine the value of the exchange rate, at

least in the long run. But this sharp prediction has been rejected in several empirical studies,

showing that there is a rather weak connection between the variables. A surprising result which

has been labeled “the exchange rate disconnect puzzle”.

The theory of Imperfect Knowledge economics (IKE), suggested by Michael D. Goldberg and

Roman Frydman (2007), puts forth a proposal for solving the apparent puzzle: Agents are

assumed to be heterogeneous. Furthermore, it is assumed that the agents acknowledge that their

understanding of the true model of the economy is limited. Thus, by definition, the overall result

of the IKE model has to be different from that of the rational expectations outcome given by the

monetary approach to exchange rates.

The structure of the thesis Overall, the thesis is divided into two parts: The theoretical part of IKE and the empirical test of

one of the assumptions of the theory, the importance of uncertainty in regards to exchange rate

determination. This is chapter 4 and 5 of the thesis, respectively. Before the discussion and test of

the IKE theory, chapter 2 and chapter 3 discuss the foreign exchange market and the economic

agents participating in the market (chapter 2), as well as the theory and empirical results of the

monetary approach (chapter 3).

Stylized facts – chapter 2 This chapter both discusses the time series properties of three of the most traded currencies, as

well as the agents and the market in which the currencies are traded. Several findings are

reported: Exchange rates are non-normal, has over-kurtosis; the market is decentralized and has a

rather low degree of transparency; and the agents are heterogeneous and use different methods

for the calculation of future exchange rates.

Exchange rates: models and puzzles – chapter 3 Chapter 4 discusses the mainstream approach to exchange rates, namely the monetary approach.

Two typical monetary models, the flexible price monetary model (FPMM) and the sticky price

Page 3: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

2

monetary model, are presented and discussed. This is followed by a short study of the empirical

achievements of the monetary approach. The overall conclusion of the monetary approach’

empirical success is not supportive; hence the exchange rate disconnect puzzle, the purchasing

power parity puzzle and the forward premium puzzle. Thus, it seems that a new approach to the

modeling of exchange rates seems warranted. One such approach is discussed in this chapter as

well, the microstructure approach. The microstructure approach relaxes some of the more critical

assumptions of the monetary approach: That private information can have a significant effect,

that agents are heterogeneous, and that the institutions and structure of the exchange rate market

matter for the determination of exchange rates. Assumptions which are in line with the findings

of chapter 2. Testing a simple microstructure model with order flow included shows that private

information can have a significant effect; a result supported by several articles. Thus, the sharp

assumptions of the monetary approach seem to impede useful information on exchange rates.

The theoretical part – chapter 4 The main theme of the IKE theory is the importance of imperfect knowledge; and the

assumption that the agents recognize that their (individual) knowledge is limited. Hence, the

agents act like scientists, testing various strategies over time. Furthermore, the agents do not only

use strict macroeconomic models for forecasting the future exchange rate, but make use of

technical trading, insights from the microstructure approach and their experience. The IKE

theory adds the findings from prospect theory to the description of the agents utility: The aspect

of loss aversion (i.e. the disutility from a loss exceeds the utility of gains of the same size),

reference dependence (utility is defined relative to a reference point), and diminishing sensitivity

(i.e. the marginal utility of both gains and losses decreases with their size). Furthermore it is

assumed that loss aversion increases with the position size, preventing agents from taking

unlimited positions in the foreign exchange market. When these assumptions are coupled with

the “gap effect” – the difference between the historical benchmark value of the exchange rate

and the expected value of the exchange rate have an effect on the expected utility of agents – and

conservative revisions of strategy – i.e. agents stick to their strategies and are slow to revise them

– the exchange rate disconnect puzzle can be explained: The exchange rate diverge from PPP (i.e.

the historical benchmark) because agents are heterogeneous and thus have different expectations

(bulls or bears). But the gap effect, i.e. increases of loss aversion, pulls back the exchange rate if it

is “too” misaligned. Therefore the exchange rate does not entirely abandon the fundamental

value.

Page 4: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

3

The empirical part – chapter 5 In the empirical part a VAR model is used when testing one of the main assumptions of the IKE

theory: The importance of uncertainty. Running a GARCH model on the macroeconomic

fundamentals provide a proxy for uncertainty, as the conditional variance changes according to

changes in the fundamentals. Adding the GARCH variables to a simple monetary model is tested

to be a stationary relation for Japan, pointing to the significance of uncertainty.

Main conclusion – chapter 6 The overall conclusion supports the IKE theory: From a theoretical point, the theory

incorporates several stylised facts, such as heterogeneous agents and the use of different methods

and models. From an empirical point, the test of the importance of private information as well as

the VAR model seems to support the IKE theory as well.

Thus, I cannot reject the hypothesis that the IKE theory can explain the exchange rate

disconnect puzzle.

Page 5: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

4

Imperfect knowledge economics

- A solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle?

David Pedersen

April 2008

Page 6: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

5

Preface For this thesis I have been inspired by the course in International Monetary Economics as well as

the seminar Empirical International Finance.

First of all a special thanks to my advisor, Michael Bergman, for guidance, critical questions and

useful discussions as well as a high degree of patience.

Other persons have given valuable remarks as well, which I appreciate: Thanks to Michael D.

Goldberg for answering several questions regarding imperfect knowledge economics (IKE) and

thanks to Katarina Juselius for introducing me to the interesting ideas of IKE in the early spring

of 2007. Thanks to Lars Christensen, Chief Analyst at Emerging Market Research at Danske

Bank, and Teis Knuthsen, Head of FX Research at Danske Bank, for interesting discussions of

exchange rates, seen from a practical point of view.

Last but not least, thanks to Gitte and my beautiful daughter, Freja, for putting up with me over

the months, and making the process much more fun.

Page 7: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

6

Contents

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION....................................................................................................9

1.1 INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................................................9

1.2 DEFINITION: THE EXCHANGE RATE DISCONNECT PUZZLE..........................................................11

1.3 DELIMITATION........................................................................................................................................12

1.4 STRUCTURE OF THE THESIS ..................................................................................................................12

CHAPTER 2: STYLISED FACTS.................................................................................................. 15

2.1 INTRODUCTION ......................................................................................................................................15

2.2 THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET ...................................................................................................16

2.3 EXCHANGE RATE DATA.........................................................................................................................17

2.3.1 Descriptive statistics ......................................................................................................................................17

2.3.2 Stylised facts of exchange rate data ................................................................................................................21

2.4 THE STRUCTURE OF THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET...............................................................22

2.4.1 Features of the foreign exchange market ...................................................................................................22

2.4.2 Participants of the foreign exchange market..............................................................................................22

2.5 CONCLUSION ...........................................................................................................................................24

CHAPTER 3: EXCHANGE RATES: MODELS AND PUZZLES ...............................................26

3.1 INTRODUCING EXCHANGE RATE THEORY.............................................................................................26

3.2 THE MACROECONOMIC APPROACH TO EXCHANGE RATES............................................................27

3.2.1 Purchasing power parity...........................................................................................................................27

3.2.2 The interest rate – Uncovered interest rate parity .....................................................................................29

3.2.3 The money supply ....................................................................................................................................30

3.2.4 Summing up................................................................................................................................................31

3.3 THE MONETARY APPROACH ......................................................................................................................32

3.3.1 The flexible price monetary model..................................................................................................................33

3.3.2 The sticky price monetary model ....................................................................................................................34

3.3.3 The monetary approach – summing up..........................................................................................................36

3.4 EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF EXCHANGE RATES ............................................................................................36

3.4.1 Empirical results of the seventies ...................................................................................................................36

3.4.2 Modern empirical results ...............................................................................................................................37

3.4.3 Exchange rate puzzles..................................................................................................................................38

3.4.4 Puzzles after all? ..........................................................................................................................................40

3.4.5 Critique of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis .........................................................................................41

3.4.6 Different solutions to the exchange rate puzzles .............................................................................................42

Page 8: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

7

3.5 THE MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE APPROACH .........................................................................................43

3.5.1 Introducing market microstructure .................................................................................................................43

3.5.2 Order flow as an important factor for exchange rates .....................................................................................45

3.5.3 A microstructure model of exchange rates ......................................................................................................47

3.6 CONCLUSION ...........................................................................................................................................50

CHAPTER 4: IMPERFECT KNOWLEDGE ECONOMICS.......................................................53

4.1 INTRODUCING IMPERFECT KNOWLEDGE ECONOMICS ......................................................................53

4.2 IMPERFECT KNOWLEDGE AND UNCERTAINTY.....................................................................................55

4.2.1 Knightian uncertainty....................................................................................................................................55

4.2.2 Imperfect knowledge ......................................................................................................................................55

4.3 MODELLING PREFERENCES AND FORECASTING STRATEGIES ..........................................................57

4.3.1 The expected utility hypothesis.......................................................................................................................57

4.3.2 Critique of the expected utility hypothesis.......................................................................................................58

4.3.3 Prospect theory ..............................................................................................................................................58

4.3.4 Prospect theory and the foreign exchange market – the IKE approach............................................................59

4.3.5 Equilibrium in the FX market under Prospect theory: UAIP ......................................................................63

4.3.6 Modelling forecasting strategies I: The Gap effect ...........................................................................................65

4.3.7 Modelling forecasting strategies II: Conservative revisions ...............................................................................67

4.3.8 Summing up .................................................................................................................................................68

4.4 IKE AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: A MONETARY MODEL ....................................................................69

4.4.1 A monetary model with IKE-expectations.....................................................................................................70

4.4.2 Money markets.............................................................................................................................................70

4.4.3 Goods markets .............................................................................................................................................71

4.4.4 Foreign exchange market ..............................................................................................................................71

4.4.5 The social context .......................................................................................................................................73

4.4.6 The solution to the model .............................................................................................................................74

4.4.7 The intuition of the result ..........................................................................................................................76

4.5 IKE AND THE EXCHANGE RATE DISCONNECT PUZZLE ......................................................................77

4.6 CRITIQUE OF IMPERFECT KNOWLEDGE ECONOMICS ........................................................................78

4.7 CONCLUSION ...........................................................................................................................................79

CHAPTER 5: EMPIRICAL TEST.................................................................................................82

5.1 INTRODUCING THE EMPIRICAL PART .......................................................................................................82

5.2 THE MODEL: MOTIVATION AND SET-UP............................................................................................83

5.3 THE MODEL: SPECIFICATION AND ESTIMATION..............................................................................85

5.3.1 Introducing the empirical test .....................................................................................................................85

5.3.2 The data ...................................................................................................................................................85

Page 9: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

8

5.3.3 A brief discussion of multivariate cointegration...........................................................................................86

5.3.4 GARCH(p,q) estimation .........................................................................................................................87

5.3.5 Cointegration analysis .............................................................................................................................89

5.3.6 Lag length, residual analysis and dummy variables ..................................................................................93

5.3.7 Testing the models ...................................................................................................................................94

5.3.8 Conclusion ........................................................................................................................................... 103

5.4 THE RESULT FROM AN IKE PERSPECTIVE ...................................................................................... 103

5.5 CONCLUSION ........................................................................................................................................ 104

CHAPTER 6: CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................... 105

LITERATURE.............................................................................................................................. 107

APPENDIX A – FIGURES ...........................................................................................................114

APPENDIX B – MODELS............................................................................................................118

APPENDIX C – EMPIRICAL RESULTS ....................................................................................121

Page 10: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

9

Chapter 1

Introduction “To repeat a central fact of life, there is remarkably little evidence that macroeconomic variables

have consistent strong effects on floating exchange rates, except during extraordinary

circumstances such as hyperinflations. Such negative findings have led the profession to a certain

degree of pessimism vis-à-vis exchange rate research”

Frankel and Rose (1995), p. 1709.

1.1 Introduction For most modern economies the exchange rate is, in the words of Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000),

the single most important relative price, essential for a number of economic activities. Exchange

rate fluctuations are therefore carefully followed: By investors, as it affect the value of

international portfolios; by governments, as it affects prices on exports, imports and the value of

international debt; and by Central Banks, as it affects inflation objectives and the value of

international reserves. For the financial market in general, the fluctuations of exchange rates are

important as well: Directly, as the market for foreign exchange is the largest financial market in

the world; and indirectly, as currency fluctuations influence a range of other asset prices.

It is a puzzle, then, that exchange rate theories have had such a hard time explaining the currency

fluctuations since the free float in the 1970s, and that the link between macroeconomic variables

and the exchange rate appear almost non-existent. The empirical result of the weak relation

between exchange rates and macroeconomic variables, as reported by for example Meese and

Rogoff (1983), has since been dubbed the “exchange rate disconnect puzzle”. Meese and Rogoff

(1983) concluded that a simple random walk model would predict major-country exchange rates

as well as a range of exchange rate models. The assumption of mainstream exchange rate theories

that the value of a given currency is determined by macroeconomic fundamentals such as output,

money supply and interest rates therefore seems to be too simple. At least in the short to medium

run of six to twelve months. Looking at figure 1 below, depicting the value of the US real

effective exchange rate, it is evident that institutions such as the Central Banks also matter for the

Page 11: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

10

pricing of a currency. The Plaza Accord, for example, apparently had an impact on the value of

the dollar – which was not solely grounded in changes of macroeconomic fundamentals1. Figure 1 – The US real effective exchange rate since 1970

.

70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08

perc

ent

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

115

120

perc

ent

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

115

120 Index

T he L ouvre A ccord

P aul V olcker app. chairm an o f the F ed

T he P laza A ccord

Source: EcoWin database

In the foreign exchange market two rather large players, Central Banks and international

companies, do not solely have profit maximisation as their main objective but in addition

objectives such as price stability (Central Banks) or hedging their investments (companies). This,

obviously, affects the determination of exchange rates. Furthermore, the structure of the foreign

exchange market, which is both highly decentralised and has a quite low degree of transparency,

matters for the price setting as well. But most important for the exchange rate determination are

the economic agents in the market. Not only the aforementioned institutions and organisations,

but also the traders and investors who are buying and selling currency on a daily basis. In

traditional exchange rate theories, these agents are assumed to be homogenous and endowed

with rational expectations; i.e. they know the true model of the economy and do not

systematically over– or underestimate the value of the exchange rate. Furthermore, private

information is not deemed important in the pricing of currencies, as all agents have access to the

same relevant information, according to rational expectations.

The question, then, is whether the hypothesis of fully rational individuals is where the many

problems and puzzles of modern day exchange rate theory come from? The answer to that

1 The Plaza Accord was an agreement between USA, Germany, France, UK and Japan to intervene in the foreign

exchange market with the objective of a depreciation of the dollar.

Page 12: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

11

question is yes, according to the book “Imperfect knowledge economics: Exchange rates and

risk” by Roman Frydman and Michael D. Goldberg (2007). They consequently propose a new

theory for explaining the puzzles which are haunting exchange rates research: Imperfect

knowledge economics (IKE). The IKE theory instead suggests that agents are heterogeneous and

therefore have different expectations of the future price of a given currency. Furthermore, the

agents are fully aware that they do not know the true model of the economy. Hence, they use a

portfolio of models and methods, as well as experience and creativity, when forecasting the

future exchange rate. The result that exchange rates are not always perfectly correlated with

macroeconomic fundamentals, is therefore no surprise according to the IKE theory. Seemingly

the disconnect puzzle between fundamentals and the exchange rate is no longer a puzzle when

seen from the theoretical perspective of IKE.

From this introduction follows the purpose of the thesis: “Does Imperfect Knowledge Economics provide

a solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle?

1.2 Definition: The exchange rate disconnect puzzle The hypothesis of this thesis is whether the imperfect knowledge economics theory gives a

reliable solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle. It is therefore necessary first to define

the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

Definition of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle: The finding that the fundamentals and

the (nominal) exchange rate are only weakly correlated has been defined as the “exchange rate

disconnect puzzle” by Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000).

In Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000: 373) the puzzle is defined as follows: “The weak relationship between

the exchange rate and virtually any macroeconomic aggregates”. The definition of Sarno (2005: 674):

“Fundamentals appear to be unable to explain both the actual level of exchange rates – not only on daily, but even

monthly, quarterly and annually – and their volatility”. Other authors (e.g. Lyons, 2001: 172) label it the

“exchange rate determination puzzle”, but this identical to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

The conclusion of a weak relationship between exchange rates and macroeconomic fundamentals

(e.g. output, money supply) dates back to the aforementioned influential article of Meese and

Rogoff (1983), which will be discussed further in the empirical survey in chapter 3.

Although often discussed apart from each other, the exchange rate disconnect puzzle and the

purchasing power parity (PPP) puzzle – mentioned in chapter 3 – are very much linked together.

The first puzzles’ subject is the disconnect between fundamentals and the exchange rate, whereas

Page 13: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

12

the PPP puzzles’ subject is the long half-life when the exchange rates move towards the

fundamental value (given by PPP); half-lifes that reach as much as 3 or 4 years (Obstfeld and

Rogoff, 2000: 373; Rogoff, 1996). When looking at the disconnect puzzle, one can therefore not

go without discussing the PPP puzzle as well.

1.3 Delimitation First of all I have chosen to focus solely on the monetary approach and let the imperfect

knowledge economics theory be a critique thereof. I have not included discussions of, for

example, the new open economy macroeconomics (NOEM) or the portfolio balance models

approaches to exchange rates. Regarding the former, the NOEM approach has not produced

empirical exchange rate equations that alter the Meese and Rogoff (1983) result (cf. Lyons, 2001:

294). The monetary approach, on the other hand, has been the dominating theory of exchange

rate research since the 1970s, despite its empirical shortcomings discussed in chapter 3. Nor do I

discuss the results of behavioural economics, interesting as it may be. This could be a focus of

another thesis.

Secondly, this thesis try to answer whether the imperfect knowledge economics theory put forth

a constructive solution to the disconnect puzzle. Other solutions to the puzzle outside of the

realm of the imperfect knowledge theory (e.g. transport costs, bubbles, behavioural economics

result etc.) will therefore only be touched upon briefly, relevant as they might be for the

disconnect puzzle itself.

1.4 Structure of the thesis The thesis is structured as follows:

Chapter 2 – Stylised facts: This chapter examines the foreign exchange market from three

angles: The exchange rates and the time series property thereof; the structure of the foreign

exchange market; and the economic agents in the market with focus on the traders. This insight is

used in the following chapters, especially in regards to the IKE theory in chapter 4 which builds

on several of the stylised facts from chapter 2.

Chapter 3 – Exchange rates: Models and puzzles: The focus of this chapter is the monetary

approach and the empirical results of this theory. The main idea of the monetary approach is

Page 14: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

13

presented by two often used models, the flexible price monetary model (FPMM) and the sticky

price monetary model. The empirical study following the models demonstrate the shortcomings

of the monetary approach, one of them the exchange rate disconnect puzzle. The rational

expectations hypothesis, the backbone of the monetary approach, is discussed and criticised.

Then follows a discussion of the microstructure approach to exchange rate which serves to: i)

introduce a micro foundation to exchange rate research missing from the monetary approach,

and ii) be an introduction to the ideas of imperfect knowledge in the following chapter, which

builds on several of the insights from microstructure theory.

Chapter 4 – Imperfect Knowledge Economics: This chapter discuss the imperfect knowledge

economics (IKE) theory with the main focus on the book “Imperfect knowledge economics:

Exchange rates and risk” by Frydman and Goldberg (2007). A theoretical model based on the

IKE theory is set up, and it is discussed why this provides a theoretical solution to the exchange

rate disconnect puzzle.

Chapter 5 – Empirical test: The empirical chapter tests a monetary model with the addition of

uncertainty. The IKE theory assumes that uncertainty plays an important part in the price setting

of exchange rates, and this hypothesis is tested using the Johansen method in a multivariate VAR

model on Norway and Japan against USA. Furthermore I test a simple monetary model for both

countries which supports the general result of the shortcoming of the monetary approach seen in

chapter 3. The tests of the models with uncertainty result in some support for the importance of

the uncertainty variables in the determination of exchange rates, at least for Japan. Furthermore,

the GARCH variables, proxying uncertainty, seem to be significant for the models.

One has to be aware, though, that some of the assumptions of the VAR model are violated.

Chapter 6 – Conclusion: This chapter presents the overall conclusion of the thesis, and answers

the question put forth in the introduction: Does the Imperfect Knowledge Economics theory

provide a solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle? The result of the thesis, and hence the

answer to this question, is based on two foundations: i) The theoretical foundation of IKE, which

appears quite strong as it is based on the stylised facts discussed in chapter 2 and chapter 3 as

well as the robust results of prospect theory and the microstructure approach; ii) The empirical

foundation from testing the IKE assumptions, which show that both private information (chapter

3 on microstructure) as well as uncertainty (the empirical test of chapter 5) play a role in regards

to exchange rate determination.

Page 15: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

14

Based on this, I cannot reject the hypothesis that IKE could be a solution to the exchange rate

disconnect puzzle.

I have split the appendix in three parts: A) With figures; B) with models and calculations thereof;

and C) with results from various estimations and tests.

Page 16: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

15

Chapter 2

Stylised facts “One of the most fascinating thing about the foreign exchange market is the huge sums of

money that are exchanged on a daily basis”

Keith Pilbeam, (2006), p. 4

2.1 Introduction A necessary condition for understanding the movements and the predictability of assets and asset

returns, in this case exchange rates, is understanding the financial data as well as the market in

which these prices are set. As a starting point for the analysis later in the thesis, it is therefore

relevant to look into the regularities and composition of the foreign exchange market. This

chapter does exactly that.

The results from the latest survey of the Bank of International Settlements (BIS, 2007) show the

size and trading structures of the foreign exchange markets. The statistical properties of time

series data of exchange rates, on the other hand, are important for an initial understanding of the

exchange rate movements. The statistical properties of exchange rates, and financial data as a

whole, are often referred to as “stylised facts”, i.e. a broad generalisation of empirical findings.

The descriptive statistics of exchange rates, as we shall see, very much follows that from other

financial time series data of bonds and equities; i.e. heavy tails, over-kurtosis, (left-) skewness and

rejection of the normality assumption (see for example Campbell et al, 1997: 19ff or Pagan,

1996).

This chapter is structured as follows: First a short look at the latest BIS (2007) survey of the

foreign exchange market. Then the descriptive statistics of three different exchange rates will be

discussed. Finally a discussion of the structure and agents of the exchange rate market, based on

the survey by Cheung and Chinn of American (2001) and English traders (Cheung et al, 2004).

The insights from this chapter is build upon in chapter 3, where the monetary and microstructure

approach to exchange rates are discussed, as well as in chapter 4 of the imperfect knowledge

economics.

Page 17: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

16

2.2 The foreign exchange market The Bank of International Settlements (BIS, 2007a) triennial survey analyses the turnover of the

foreign exchange markets. According to Sarno and Taylor (2002: 271) it represents “the most

reliable source of information of foreign exchange market activity”. Table 1 below shows the result from the

survey. As can be seen, the daily turnover of the traditional (i.e. spot, forwards and swaps) foreign

exchange markets reached $3.2 trillion, an increase of almost 71 % from 2004. This increase is,

according to BIS (2007a: 1), driven by both increased activity of investor groups (e.g. hedge

funds) and technical trading. This is further supported by the second BIS report (2007b: 65),

which also points out that the foreign exchange market has been relatively attractive to leveraged

investors with short-term horizons, as well as investors with longer investment horizons trying to

diversify their portfolio. Table 1 – Foreign exchange turnover from the BIS survey, 2007

Source: BIS Triennial Survey (2007)

The dollar is the main currency although with a small downward trend since 2004 (BIS, 2007a: 7).

The Japanese Yen (JPY) and the Norwegian krone (NOK), used in the empirical test of chapter

5, are the third and tenth most traded currencies, respectively. The United Kingdom is the

geographical centre for foreign exchange trading followed by the United States and Japan (ibid.:

9). The most traded currency cross is the USD/EUR, amounting more than a quarter (27%) of

the total market turnover. Then follows USD/Other (19%), USD/JPY (13%) and USD/GBP

(12%). The largest part of the trades is between dealers (43%), followed by deals with other

financial institutions (40%) and non-financial customers (17%) (cf. BIS 2007a: 6).

Page 18: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

17

Overall the volume of the foreign exchange market is enormous, and it dwarfs any other financial

instrument (Lyons, 2001: 41).

2.3 Exchange rate data

2.3.1 Descriptive statistics

This section serves to give a general description of the time series properties of exchange rates.

The data in the following section covers the euro/dollar (EUR/USD), dollar/Japanese Yen

(USD/JPY) and dollar/British pound (USD/GBP). The three crosses have been chosen as they

are the three most traded currencies (BIS, 2007a: 8).

The data is obtained from the EcoWin database. The frequency is on a daily, weekly and monthly

basis, and covers the period from the 1st of July 1974 to 31st October 2007. Figure 2, 3 and 4

below show the realisations of the exchange rates over the period. Figure 2 – Daily observations for EUR/USD from July 1974

0,6

0,7

0,8

0,9

1

1,1

1,2

1,3

1,4

1,5

1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Source: EcoWin

For the euro/dollar exchange rate, figure 2 above, the maximum value (i.e. weak dollar) over the

period is 1.45 (September 8th 1992) and minimum value 0.63 (February 26th 1985). For the

dollar/yen, figure 3 below, the maximum (here: strong dollar) is 306.8 (December 8th 1975) and

minimum 80.6 (April 18th 1995). For the dollar/pound in figure 4 below, the maximum is 0.95

(January 11th 1985) and minimum value 0.401 (October 8th 1980).

From figures 2 and 4 (EUR/USD and USD/GBP) it is evident that the US dollar reached a local

maximum (i.e. strong dollar) in the mid 1980s.

Page 19: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

18

Figure 3 – Daily observations for USD/JPY from July 1974

75

105

135

165

195

225

255

285

1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Source: EcoWin

Figure 4 – Daily observations for USD/GBP from July 1974

0,4

0,5

0,6

0,7

0,8

0,9

1

1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Source: EcoWin

In the following the data for the three currencies is transformed into log-returns, given by

equation (2.2) below, which is defined as the natural logarithm of the gross return, equation (2.1).

(Campbell et al, 1997: 9-11).

(2.1) 1

1tt

t

PRP−

= −

(2.2) ( ) 11

log 1 log tt t t t

t

Pr R p pP −

≡ + = = −

Page 20: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

19

Now the distribution of the log returns of the exchange rates can be computed. Figure 5 below

shows the plot of daily log returns. Simple “eyeball econometrics” shows a high degree of

volatility, some serial correlation and some volatility clustering (cf. Campbell et al, 1997: 482).

The graphical log return of weekly and monthly observations, respectively, are found in appendix

A, figure 1 and 2. Table 2 below shows the descriptive statistics of the log-returns for daily,

weekly and monthly observations.

Figure 5 – Daily log returns for USD/GBP, EUR/USD and USD/JPY

Table 2 – Descriptive statistics for daily, weekly and monthly observations of log returns

Daily Weekly Monthly Daily Weekly Monthly Daily Weekly MonthlyMean 0,00002 0,0001 -0,0005 -0,0001 -0,0005 -0,0024 0,0000 0,0000 -0,0003Maximum 0,0615 0,0707 0,1243 0,0415 0,0317 -0,1566 0,0382 0,1282 0,1282Minimum -0,0648 -0,0718 -0,0931 -0,0695 -0,0423 0,1153 -0,0343 0,2816 -0,1250Std. Dev 0,0063 0,0135 0,0292 0,0065 0,0077 0,0324 0,0049 0,0071 0,0299Skewness 0,0805 -0,0351 0,1464 -0,5952 -0,4731 -0,4869 0,7187 0,2816 -0,2079Kurtosis 5,0232 2,0099 1,0591 6,5260 2,1249 1,6655 9,2880 2,2127 1,5944Normality test 3528.7 ** 184.29 ** 16.899 ** 3965.5 ** 155.02 ** 28.259 ** 1253.2 ** 194.10 ** 31.495 **

EUR/USD USD/JPY USD/GBP

From table 2 the means are (slightly) different from zero, indicating that the euro has (on

average) depreciated against the dollar on a monthly basis, whereas the dollar has appreciated

against the yen and the British pound over the period. But note that none of the means are

Page 21: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

20

significantly different from zero, given the standard deviations. The skewness and kurtosis in

table 2 are given by (Campbell et al, 1997: 16-17):

(2.3)

( )

( )

3

3

4

4

ˆ:

ˆ:

Skewness S E

Kurtosis K E

ε μσ

ε μσ

⎡ ⎤−≡ ⎢ ⎥

⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦⎡ ⎤−

≡ ⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

Where ε is a random variable with mean of μ and variance of σ2. The skewness, S, measures the

asymmetry of the distribution, with the normal distribution having a skewness of 0. The

distribution of USD/JPY in table 2 thus has more negative than positive returns for all three

frequencies. For the other currency crosses, EUR/USD and USD/GBP, the skewness measure

changes sign over the frequencies. The kurtosis, K, in table 1 is the “excess” kurtosis, i.e. above

the normal distribution which has kurtosis of 3. According to the relatively large and positive

kurtosis of table 2, the returns of exchange rates have more mass in the tails than predicted by

the normal distribution. The excess kurtosis declines over all three currency crosses as the

interval increases. Both the kurtosis and the skewness figures for the daily frequencies in table 2

are highly statistically significant, as the standard error2 for the kurtosis is 0.052 ( 24T ) and for

the skewness 0.026 ( 6T ).The skewness turns insignificant for the EUR/USD at weekly and

monthly basis, and for the USD/GBP at the monthly frequency, whereas the kurtosis stays

significant over the frequencies. Finally, the normality (or Jarque-Bera) test jointly measures

whether the skewness and kurtosis equals that of the normal distribution (i.e., 0 and 3

respectively). This is soundly rejected for all three currencies.

The results above are in line with the results of Boothe and Glassman (1987: 303-304) for

exchange rate returns. They find clear signs of excess kurtosis, which declines as the interval

increases, a strong rejection of normality and some signs of skewness.

Another way to describe the distributions of the exchange rate returns is by using quantile-

quantile (QQ) plots. Then, the quintiles of a given sample are matched with the theoretical

quintiles. Figure 6 below shows the QQ-plots of the distributions against the normal distribution.

As is evident from the three plots, there are too many observations in the tails of the distribution

(red line) compared with the normal distribution (black line). Hence the returns are not normally

2 Following Campbell et al (1997: 17) the variances of the S and K estimators are 6/T and 24/T, respectively.

Page 22: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

21

distributed, which is also the result of the normality test in table 2. The negative skewness from

table 2 of the USD/JPY, for example, is quite obvious from figure 6 (bottom chart).

Figure 6 – QQ plots for the three currency crosses

2.3.2 Stylised facts of exchange rate data

From the results above the following properties emerge:

• Exchange rates appear to be extremely volatile

• The distributions of exchange rate returns are non-normal

• Fat tails compared with the standard normal distribution. That is, large returns occur more often than

expected (kurtosis significantly larger than 3)

• The distributions are skewed, i.e. the distribution is not symmetric. The direction of the skewness is not

unequivocal, though, and turns insignificant – for some currency crosses - as frequencies decrease.

The stylised facts presented above are in line with the general result of exchange rates, see for

example Boothe and Glassman (1987), and for financial assets in general, see for example

Campbell et al (1997: 21, 67).

Page 23: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

22

2.4 The structure of the foreign exchange market In the following section the foreign exchange market is, in the words of Sager and Taylor (2006),

put “under the microscope”. As discussed in the introduction, and further elaborated on in

chapter 3, the link between macroeconomic fundamentals and the exchange rate is mixed, to say

the least. To understand why this is so, looking at the market and the participants therein can give

useful information.

This section first looks at the features of the foreign exchange market, then the participants of

the market.

2.4.1 Features of the foreign exchange market

One important thing to notice regarding the foreign exchange market is the low level of

transparency (see for example Lyons, 2001: 41; Sager and Taylor, 2006; Sarno and Taylor, 2002:

266). Where equity and bond trades has to be disclosed within minutes in most markets, trades in

the foreign exchange market has no requirement of disclosure and hence the trades in the market

is generally not observable. Furthermore, as noted by Sager and Taylor (2006: 82), the foreign

exchange market is highly decentralized, which (further) implies some degree of lack of

transparency. As noted (ibid.: 82): “ It [the foreign exchange market] is opaque – or lacks transparency – in

the sense that the absence of a physical marketplace makes the process of price-information difficult to observe and

understand”. As mentioned by Sarno and Taylor (2002: 266), this decentralisation increases

inefficiency compared with more centralised markets such as the equity market. The high degree

of decentralisation furthermore implies that there is some degree of fragmentation; that is,

transactions may occur at the same time at different prices (ibid.: 267). The aspect of lacking

transparency, and its effect on exchange rate determination, will be discussed further in chapter 3,

and is an important part of understanding the foreign exchange market.

2.4.2 Participants of the foreign exchange market

Cheung and Chinn (2001) analyse the composition of foreign exchange traders in the US using

survey data. According to the result, traders in the US foreign exchange market can roughly be

divided into four groups (ibid.: 453)3: technical trading (29.5%), customer order (23.4%),

fundamental analysis (24.9%) and “jobbing” (21.1%). Jobbing refers to a trader continuously

3 The specific question in the survey is: The best way to describe your spot FX trading is: “Technical trading rules”,

“fundamental analysis”, “customer orders driven”, “jobbing approach”, “other”. Note that the sum of the categories

does not equal 1 as there, in some cases, are multiple responses or incomplete replies (Cheung and Chinn, 2001: 453)

Page 24: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

23

buying and selling to take many (small) profits (cf. Cheung and Chinn, 2001: 454). Apparently,

only about a quarter of the respondents (state that they) use fundamental analysis as their

foremost strategy when forecasting exchange rate movements. This could, to some extent,

explain elements of the “exchange rate disconnect puzzle”, as the largest part of the traders seem

to base their strategy on other issues than the fundamental value. One should note, though, that

the number of respondents in the survey is only 142, and therefore not necessarily descriptive of

the US foreign exchange market as a whole. Furthermore the respondents in the survey, for a

large part, have rather small positions to manage.

But the overall conclusion of investor heterogeneity is supported by others. Frankel and Froot

(1990: 184), for example, concludes that the largest part of foreign exchange forecasting firms in

the years 1983-88 described themselves relying exclusively on technical trading. They state that

“shifts over time in the weight that is given to different forecasting techniques are a source of changes in the demand

for dollars, and that large exchange rate movements may take place with little basis in macroeconomic

fundamentals” (ibid.: 184). This apparent heterogeneity of traders is also supported by Frankel and

Rose (1995: 1712), De Bondt and Thaler (1994) and Sager and Taylor (2006: 91), and it seems to

be a robust finding. Menkhoff and Taylor (2007: 940) study the research on technical trading and

conclude: “Almost all foreign exchange professionals use technical analysis as a tool in decision making, at least

to some degree”.

The traders in the survey of Cheung and Chinn (2001: 459) assess that the fundamentals have

little to no effect on the shorter horizon, here intraday and medium run (up to six months). But a

large part (88.4%) of the respondents do believe that macroeconomic fundamentals influence the

exchange rate in the long run – here defined as longer than six months. This is, somewhat, in line

with the empirical results of exchange rate research, as mentioned in the introduction and

discussed further in chapter 3. As to why the exchange rate value differs from the fundamental

value, the respondent’s point to excess speculation (74%) and hedge fund/institutional

manipulation (68%). Around 40% of the traders in the survey believe that central bank

intervention cause the deviations from fundamental value, whereas 52% believe that this has no

effect on the exchange rates. As the most important macroeconomic fundamental the traders in

the survey point to unemployment (33.0%) and the interest rate (30.9%), whereas inflation

(18.3%) and money supply (1.6%) seem less important. A rather surprising result compared with

the mainstream view of macroeconomic variables and the exchange rate. Cheung and Chinn

(2001: 457) furthermore point out that the importance of different macroeconomic variables

shifts over time; but with interest rates always remaining important. Finally a large part (63%) of

the traders interprets the PPP model, discussed in chapter 3 below, as “merely academic jargon”

Page 25: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

24

(Cheung and Chinn, 2001: 465). Furthermore, only 13% would sell dollars if the PPP model

indicated a dollar overvaluation. As with the macroeconomic fundamentals, the trader’s views of

the relevance of the PPP model change with the horizon: at the long horizon, 40% of the

respondents find that PPP in fact has some influence.

The main results of Cheung and Chinn (2001) are more or less reproduced in a survey by Cheung

et al (2004) of UK-based foreign exchange dealers. Cheung et al (2004) also find that the agents

are heterogeneous. Furthermore, the dealers in the survey think that over-reaction as well as

speculative and band-wagon effects are very important for exchange rate determination. The UK

dealers, on the other hand, find that fundamentals have significant effect at rather short time

horizons of around six months. But only 27% of the respondents would sell dollars if the PPP

model showed that it was overvalued (ibid.: 297), in line with the result from Cheung and Chinn

(2001).

2.4.3 Stylised fact of the foreign exchange market:

• The foreign exchange market is characterised by a rather low level of transparency • The foreign exchange market is highly decentralised • The agents in the market have heterogeneous expectations and employ different methods

• The agents assessment of the importance of different macroeconomic variables change over time

• The agents believe that macroeconomic fundamentals matter in the “long-run”, but have little to no effect

at shorter horizons.

• The agents believe that the PPP model is only valid in the long run.

2.5 Conclusion In this chapter the foreign exchange rate, the foreign exchange market, and the participants of the

market has been examined.

The foreign exchange market is, by far, the largest financial market in the world, and its size

(measured by turnover) has increased markedly (70%) over the last three years. The descriptive

statistics of exchange rate returns follow that of most other financial assets; i.e. the distribution of

returns is non-normal, skewed and fat-tailed. This change as the frequencies decreases, with less

extreme observations at monthly basis compared with the weekly and daily basis for all three

currencies.

Page 26: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

25

The exchange rate market is characterised as being less transparent than other financial asset

markets, clouding the price information and further exacerbating the effect of the heterogeneous

agents as well as the tendency of asymmetric information.

Looking at the participants of the exchange rate market, the primary conclusion is that the traders

dealing with exchange rates are heterogeneous. Some use fundamental analysis as their primary

tool when forecasting exchange rates and deciding strategies; but a large part of the traders seem

to primarily use other methods which do not depend on fundamental values (e.g. technical

trading). Traders do believe that fundamentals have some importance, though. But which types

of fundamentals are important can differ over time, and it seems that the macroeconomic

fundamentals are only reckoned to be important in the long run.

Page 27: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

26

Chapter 3

Exchange rates: models and puzzles “The clear conclusion is that exchange rates are moved largely by other factors than the obvious,

observable, macroeconomic fundamentals. Econometrically, most of the “action” is in the error

term.”

Rudiger Dornbusch and Jeffrey Frankel, (1987), p. 10

“Exchange rate economics is characterized by a number of anomalies, or puzzles, which we

struggle to explain on the basis of either sound economic theory or practical thinking… the

international finance profession has not yet been able to produce theories and, as a consequence,

empirical models that allow us to explain the behavior of exchange rates with a reasonable degree

of accuracy.”

Lucio Sarno, (2005), p. 674

3.1 Introducing exchange rate theory Before the free floating of exchange rates in the 1970s, and the following expansion of theoretical

exchange rate models, the approach to exchange rate determination was primarily based on the

goods market (Lyons, 2001: 2). That is, demand for foreign exchange was assumed to come

primarily from the sales (and purchases) of goods across borders; an increase in exports is

followed by an increase in the demand for domestic currency to pay for the goods. This

approach, at first, sounded plausible. But the trade balances turned out to be uncorrelated with

the exchange rate movements. Furthermore, trade in goods and services accounts for a very small

fraction of the daily foreign exchange trading, around 5 % (ibid.: 2). As a consequence of this the

asset market – or monetary – approach emerged in the 1970s, and this has since been the

dominant approach for exchange rate research (Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 46). In this chapter the

focus is on the monetary approach of exchange rate modelling and its empirical results. As an

alternative to the monetary models the market microstructure approach is discussed as well.

The chapter is structured as follows: First an introduction to the macroeconomic approach to

exchange rates. Then follows a discussion of the monetary approach to exchange rates, with

focus on the two most used models, the flexible price monetary model and the sticky price (or

Page 28: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

27

overshooting) model. Then a survey of the empirical results of exchange rate studies. This leads

to a discussion of the exchange rate puzzles emerging from the empirical results. Then follows a

discussion of the rational expectations hypothesis (REH), a central part of exchange rate

modelling. Finally the microstructure approach is discussed, an alternative method of determining

exchange rate movements and a good starting point for understanding the IKE theory in chapter

4.

3.2 The macroeconomic approach to exchange rates As mentioned in the introduction to chapter 1 macroeconomic fundamentals are, from an

academic viewpoint, seen as important when evaluating the determinants of exchange rates. In

the following, two of the building blocks for the exchange rate models presented in section 3.3

will be discussed: the purchasing power parity and the uncovered interest rate parity.

3.2.1 Purchasing power parity

A first approximation of what determines the exchange rate is the purchasing power parity (PPP).

PPP states that arbitrage will, when goods are measured in the same currency, lead to equalisation

of goods prices internationally (Pilbeam, 2006: 126 or Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 51). That is, the

purchasing power of a US dollar, say, should be the same in both the Euro-zone and USA. PPP

is defined as follows by Sarno and Taylor (2002: 51): “.. The PPP exchange rate is the exchange rate

between two currencies which would equate the two relevant national price levels if expressed in a common currency

at that rate, so that the purchasing power of a unit of one currency would be the same in both countries”. If the

exchange rate is misaligned (i.e. either over- or undervalued according to PPP), arbitrage would

secure that the currency reaches the parity as investors seek to take profit. As with the uncovered

interest parity presented below, the PPP builds on the notion of market efficiency. The definition

of an informational efficient market is (Campbell et al, 1997: 20-21): “Price changes must be

unforecastable if they are properly anticipated, i.e. if they fully incorporate the expectations and information of all

market participants”. Or, in the words of Malkiel (1992): “A capital market is said to be efficient if it fully

and correctly reflects all relevant information in determining security prices. Efficiency with respect to an information

set … implies that it is impossible to make economic profits by trading on the basis of [that information set]”.

That is, a market in which the prices fully reflect the (available) information is efficient. For a

more thorough discussion of the efficient market hypothesis, see Campbell et al (1997) or Sarno

and Taylor (2002).

The absolute PPP condition states that:

(3.1) *t t ts p p= −

Page 29: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

28

Where s is the (log) exchange rate, p is the (log) price level and an asterisk denotes a foreign

variable. In the following, s denotes domestic price of foreign currency, and hence an increase

(decrease) in s is seen as depreciation (appreciation). From the PPP condition, the real exchange

rate, q, can be obtained, which can be seen as a measure of deviation from PPP:

(3.2) *t t t tq s p p≡ − +

Figure 7 and 8 below plots the USD/JPY and EUR/USD against the (computed) exchange rate

as given by the PPP condition in equation (3.1). Figure 7 - USD/JPY and the PPP model, 1980 to 2007

.

80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08

perc

ent

7 5

1 0 0

1 2 5

1 5 0

1 7 5

2 0 0

2 2 5

2 5 0

2 7 5

3 0 0

perc

ent

7 5

1 0 0

1 2 5

1 5 0

1 7 5

2 0 0

2 2 5

2 5 0

2 7 5

3 0 0

P P P m o d e l

U S D / JP Y

Source: EcoWin

Figure 8 – EUR/USD and the PPP model, 1988 to 2007

.

88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07

perc

ent

0,8

0,9

1,0

1,1

1,2

1,3

1,4

1,5

1,6

perc

ent

0,8

0,9

1,0

1,1

1,2

1,3

1,4

1,5

1,6

PPP model

EUR/USD

Source: EcoWin

Page 30: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

29

As can be seen from both figures 7 and 8 above there are large deviations between the factual

exchange rate (red dotted line) and the value given by the PPP model (blue line). Furthermore,

the swings away from parity appear to be relatively persistent, for example from 1999 to 2003 for

EUR/USD or 1991 to 1997 for USD/JPY.

For the USD/JPY cross, the fundamental value given by PPP somewhat trends the nominal

exchange rate over the period. For the EUR/USD, on the other hand, the PPP value appears

more stationary around a value of 1.1, and the spot exchange rate then “cycles” around this. The

primary conclusion based on visual inspection of the two charts follows the general conclusion

on the outcome of PPP against the spot exchange rate, see for example Pilbeam (2006: 131ff).

One important thing to notice from the two charts is that the exchange rate does not fully

abandon the relationship with the PPP value, although the swings away from it can take several

years. Instead, the PPP value seems to act like an anchor around which the exchange rate gyrates.

If the nominal exchange rate appears “too” misaligned, it is pulled back towards the fundamental

value of PPP.

The apparent disconnect in the figures 7 and 8 between the PPP value and the exchange rate is

part of the “disconnect puzzle”. That is, the exchange rate seems to be, at least in the short-to

medium term, disconnected from the fundamental value (here given by PPP). But the moves

away from PPP seem to be bounded to some extent. Furthermore the slow return towards the

PPP value (i.e. the high half-lifes of the return to the fundamental value) has been dubbed the

“PPP puzzle”, following Rogoff (1996). Both puzzles will be discussed further in section 3.4.3

below on exchange rate puzzles.

The imperfect knowledge economics theory, presented in chapter 4, tries to take into account the

empirical regularities from the charts above. Hence, two of the questions which the imperfect

knowledge economics theory seeks to answer are: i) Why is the exchange rate “disconnected”

from the fundamental value? And ii) why does the exchange rate return to parity?

3.2.2 The interest rate – Uncovered interest rate parity

Another macroeconomic fundamental looked at when discussing exchange rate movements is the

interest rate. Bacchetta and Wincoop (2007: 346) point out that “… FX changes are predictable by

interest rate differentials”. This leans on another cornerstone of foreign exchange rates: the

uncovered interest rate parity (UIP). As with the PPP condition above, the UIP is an arbitrage

condition, securing that no excess return can be earned in an efficient market (Sarno and Taylor,

2002: 5). The UIP is given in equation (3.3) below. It states that changes in the interest rate

differential are set off by equal changes in the (expected) exchange rate, securing equality between

foreign and domestic asset return.

Page 31: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

30

(3.3) *1

et t ts i i+Δ = −

The domestic investor faces a choice of a secure domestic investment – with the payoff it in

period t+1 – or investing abroad with payoff it* plus the gain/loss from movements in the

currency. In an efficient market, defined as in section 3.2.1 above, the profit from the two

choices has to be equal.

The empirics on the UIP relationship are also mixed; a finding which has been dubbed the

“forward bias puzzle” or UIP puzzle (cf. Lewis, 1995) – another exchange rate puzzle that will be

discussed in section 3.4.3.

Figure 9 below shows the EUR/USD plotted against the 10 year bond differential between USA

and Euroland. There seems to be some connection between the two variables at some periods in

time, especially from 2002 until the beginning of 2005. But there is not a clear correlation over

the time span. Figure 9 – EUR/USD plotted against the US/EUR 10 year interest rate differential, 2000-2008

.

00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08

perc

ent

-1,00-0,75-0,50-0,250,000,250,500,751,001,251,50

perc

ent

0,8

0,9

1,0

1,1

1,2

1,3

1,4

1,5

1,6

<< EU R/U SD

USD 10 yrs. - EU R 10 yrs. >>

Source: EcoWin

3.2.3 The money supply

A third important fundamental when analysing exchange rates is the money supply. As the

money supply is, in the long run, assumed to correlate with the prices, this is just another side of

the argument from the PPP condition above.

Figure 10 below plots the relative money supplies against the exchange rate. There seems to be a

close relation between relative money supply and the exchange rate for a long period, around

1988 to the beginning of 1996. But this very close relationship clearly breaks down completely in

the middle of 2002 until 2007. Again, this does not coincide with the monetary models presented

Page 32: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

31

in the next section. Why do macroeconomic fundamentals appear closely related to the exchange

rate for some period of time, but unrelated for other time periods? The imperfect knowledge

theory does have an explanation for this question as well. Figure 10 – USD/JPY plotted against the relative monetary base of USA and Japan, 1988-2007

.

88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07

perc

ent

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

115

perc

ent

80

90

100

110

120

130

140

150

160US monetary base/Japan monetary base (2000 = 100)>>

<< USD/JPY

Source: EcoWin

3.2.4 Summing up

Overall, the macroeconomic glance at the exchange rate seems less than clear cut at describing

the exchange rate movements. As the figures above suggest the conclusions regarding the

relationship between the macroeconomic fundamentals and the exchange rate are mixed. Sarno

and Taylor (2002: 264) conclude: “…there seem to be substantial and often persistent movements in exchange

rates which are largely unexplained by macroeconomic fundamentals”. Part of this could stem from the

survey of the traders in chapter 2: Only around a quarter of the traders (predominantly) use

fundamental analysis when assessing future exchange rate values. The traders also believe that the

relationship between fundamentals and the exchange rate is rather small at short to medium

horizons, but larger when looking beyond six months. Finally, the structure of the market itself –

e.g. the lack of transparency – could have an effect on the exchange rate determination.

In the next section, the two parity conditions from above – PPP and UIP – is the basis for the

monetary approach to the exchange rates. The empirical survey following the theoretical models

underlines the initial result from visual inspection of the charts above – the puzzling result that

Page 33: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

32

fundamentals and exchange rates seem disconnected, at least for (longer) periods of time. A

result in sharp contrast with the conclusion of the two models, which we turn to now.

3.3 The monetary approach The monetary approach encompasses the flexible and the sticky price model, as well as several

other exchange rate models not discussed in this thesis.

The two models both starts from defining the exchange rate as the relative price of two countries

moneys (Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 108), and assume that the (relative) supply and demand for

money is the key determinant of exchange rates (Pilbeam, 2006: 152). Furthermore, the approach

assumes that there are no barriers (transaction costs) in the capital market (Frankel, 1995: 97).

Domestic and foreign assets are assumed to be perfect substitutes, i.e. the assets are equally risky.

An assumption that also covers the goods market. From this follows that the PPP condition

holds, and exchange rates are then given by the price difference between two countries. The price

level of a country is given by the demand and supply for money.

Another hypothesis shared by the two models is that of rational expectations on the part of the

agents, a key building block of most modern economic models (e.g. Frydman and Goldberg,

2007: 11; De Grauwe and Grimaldi, 2006a: 1). Rational expectation is given by the following

equation (Pilbeam, 2006: 226):

(3.4) 1| 1 1t t t tEs s u+ + += +

That is, the agents do not, on average, systematically over- or underestimate the future exchange

rate. The rational expectations hypothesis (REH) first took its form in the influential article by

Muth (1961: 316), who concluded that: “expectations… are necessarily the same as the predictions of the

relevant economic theory”. The agents in the market therefore utilise the same model as the

economist, and this is furthermore the true model of the economy. Thus, the agents know the

true model of exchange rate movements as well as the information which affects it. Hence,

private information does not matter for the determination of, in this case, exchange rates.

Furthermore information is assumed to be used effectively, cf. Muth (1961: 316). Markets are

therefore assumed to be efficient, following the discussion in section 3.2.1. Hence, the price of a

currency reflects the (relevant) information of the fundamental variables available to the agents. If

new information is revealed, this is (immediately) incorporated in the valuation of the asset. If the

agents did not use the new (relevant) information, they would pass up on profit opportunities –

which rational agents would not do.

The hypothesis of rational expectations has been criticised from several sides. The general

critique of the rational expectations hypothesis will be discussed further in section 3.3.4, as it is an

Page 34: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

33

important component of understanding the imperfect knowledge economics theory presented in

chapter 4.

3.3.1 The flexible price monetary model

For the flexible price monetary model (FPMM), prices are assumed to be fully flexible. That is,

the prices react instantly to (for example) excess demand. Versions of the model were first

presented by Frenkel (1976) and Mussa (1976). The three equations below sum up the model

(following Pilbeam (2006: 152-153) and McNown and Wallace (1994: 397)):

(3.5) *t t ts p p= −

Equation (3.5) is the PPP condition discussed above. An asterisk denotes a foreign variable and

all variables are in logarithms.

(3.6) 1 2t t t tm p y iβ β= + −

(3.7) 1 2

* * * * * *t t t t

m p y iβ β= + −

Equation (3.6) and (3.7) is the domestic and foreign money demand, respectively. M is the level

of the money supply, y the income and i the interest rates. As the money market is assumed to be

in equilibrium, money supply equal money demand. Solving for st in equation (3.5), using (3.6)

and (3.7), yields the so-called generic monetary approach to the exchange rate (cf. Sarno and

Taylor, 2002: 109):

(3.8) ( ) ( ) ( )1 2

* * * * *1 2t tt t t t ts m m y y i iβ β β β= − − − + −

According to equation (3.8), an increase (decrease) in domestic money supply, relative to the

foreign money supply, should lead to depreciation (appreciation)4. A rise (fall) in domestic output,

on the other hand, induces an appreciation (depreciation) of the currency. And finally, an increase

(decrease) in the domestic interest rate induces depreciation (appreciation) of the domestic

currency.

Inserting the UIP condition ( ( ) *1t t tE s i i+Δ = − ) into equation (3.8) and assuming that *

1 1β β= and

*2 2β β= yields the following equation (cf. Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 109):

(3.9) ( ) ( ) ( )* *1 2 1tt t t t ts m m y y E sβ β += − − − + Δ

Rearranging equation (3.9) yields:

4 Note, once again, that st is defined as units of domestic currency per foreign currency. Hence, an increase in st

denotes a depreciation

Page 35: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

34

(3.10) ( ) ( ) ( )* *1 21

2 2 2

11 1 1tt t t t ts m m y y E sβ β

β β β += − − − ++ + +

Forward iteration then yields the rational expectations solution to equation (3.10):

(3.11) ( ) ( )* *21

02 2

11 1 t i

i

t t t i t i t ii

s E m m y yβ ββ β +

+ + +=

⎛ ⎞ ⎡ ⎤= − − −⎜ ⎟ ⎣ ⎦+ +⎝ ⎠∑

Since the rational expectations result of equation (3.11) yields a (potentially) infinite set of

solutions (cf. Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 110), the general exchange rate given by this equation –

denoted ts% – has numerous solutions:

(3.12) t t ts s B= +%

Where Bt is a bubble term given by:

(3.13) ( ) ( )1 22

1 1t t tE B Bββ+ = +

In the absence of rational bubbles, the exchange rate is thus given by equation (3.9) (and (3.11) as

well) above. Hence the flexible price monetary model delivers a sharp prediction of the

connection between the macroeconomic fundamentals (here: money supply and output) and the

exchange rate between two countries. In section 3.4 below, the empirical results of the model will

be discussed. But first the sticky price version of the monetary approach is put forth as a slightly

different approach to exchange rate determination.

3.3.2 The sticky price monetary model

The domestic country in the sticky price monetary model is assumed to be a small participant in

the capital market, and thus faces a given interest rate (Dornbusch, 1988: 62). Assets are still

assumed to be perfect substitutes, “given a proper premium to offset anticipated exchange rate changes”

(ibid.: 62), and perfect capital mobility is assumed. This is given by the uncovered interest rate

parity, discussed in section 3.2.2: If the domestic exchange rate is expected to depreciate, the

interest rate on domestic assets will rise to offset this depreciation. The UIP condition is

reproduced in equation (3.14) below.

(3.14) *i i Es= + &

The expectation of the exchange rate is formed as the difference between the long-run exchange

rate (given by PPP) and the current exchange rate; it is assumed that the current exchange rate

will converge towards the long-run value at a constant rate.

(3.15) ( )Es s sθ= −&

Page 36: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

35

The current exchange rate value is denoted by s, the long-run value by s and θ is the coefficient

of adjustment (cf. Dornbusch, 1988: 63). The expected rate of depreciation is therefore

determined by the gap between the current exchange rate and the long run fundamental value

(which is assumed to be known by the agents), as well as the speed of adjustment given by the

parameter θ.

As in the flexible price model above, the demand for holding money in the domestic country is

given by:

(3.16) 1 2t t t tm p y iβ β− = −

Combining the three equations above yields the following relationship between the current spot

exchange rate, its long-run fundamental value and the price level:

(3.17) ( )*2 2 1t t t tp m i s s yβ β θ β− = + − −

As noted by Dornbusch (1986: 63), assuming a stationary money supply implies equality of the

interest rates in equation (3.14) as well as equality between the expected value of the exchange

rate and the current exchange rate in equation (3.15). This leads to the following equation for the

long-run equilibrium price level:

(3.18) ( )*2 1t t t tp m i yβ β= + −

Inserting equation (3.18) into (3.17) yields the following relationship between the exchange rate

and the price level:

(3.19) ( )2

1s s p pβ θ

= − −

Given the long-run values of the exchange rate and the price, the spot exchange rate is

determined by this equation. In the short run, an increase in the money supply m, with prices

fixed at p, is only held if interest rates drop (following equation (3.16)). Following the UIP

condition in equation (3.15) the lower domestic interest rate leads investors to require an

appreciation of the currency. This is achieved by an initial depreciation (i.e. overshooting) of the

currency, s larger than s , which is then followed by an appreciation to satisfy the UIP condition.

The increase in the money supply leads to a higher price level in the long run, from equation

(3.18) and the assumption of long-run neutrality of money, and a depreciated currency –

according to the PPP condition. But to uphold the UIP condition (expected appreciation of the

currency to offset the lower interest rate) the currency in the short-run overshoots the long-run

value, and then appreciates towards the new (albeit lower) long-run value. This is, in a short

version, the exchange rate “overshooting” model. In appendix B, a slightly more sophisticated

version of the model is shown (based on Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 104-7). From this can be seen

Page 37: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

36

that equation (3.19) above is the saddle path of the model. For any given price level the exchange

rate adjusts accordingly (instantly) to clear the asset market, following the money market

equilibrium (equation (3.16)) and the UIP condition (equation (3.14)). As the exchange rate (in

the example above) is higher than its long run equilibrium (and thus cheap), domestic prices

slowly increase to restore equilibrium, pressured by the excess demand for domestic goods

(Dornbusch, 1988: 65).

3.3.3 The monetary approach – summing up

As mentioned in the introduction, the monetary approach – either in the flexible or in the sticky

price version – has been the dominant method of modelling exchange rate movements since the

mid-seventies. Although the two models have differences – most notably whether prices are

assumed sticky or fully flexible in the short run – the models reach the same conclusion: The

value of the exchange rate – and its movements – are guided by macroeconomic fundamentals.

First and foremost the money supply (and demand) but also prices, output and interest rates.

Furthermore, both models employ the UIP and PPP condition.

In the following section the empirical results of the models are discussed, leading to a discussion

of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle. As shown in the beginning of this chapter, exchange

rates seem to be disconnected, at least in the short to medium run, from the fundamental value –

in contrast with the hypothesis of the two monetary models. Rudiger Dornbusch – the originator

of the sticky price model presented above – concluded in the late 1980s: “By now there are, I believe,

no more serious claims for the empirical relevance [of the simple monetary model]” (cited in Frankel, 1995:

139).

But not all empirical studies reach the same conclusion regarding the problems of the monetary

approach to exchange rate determination. Following the discussion of the exchange rate puzzles,

four different papers will be presented which show that the monetary approach actually has

important insights regarding exchange rate behaviour.

3.4 Empirical studies of exchange rates

3.4.1 Empirical results of the seventies

The macroeconomic overview in the beginning of this chapter hinted at potential problems when

explaining exchange rates from a purely macroeconomic standpoint. The PPP charts, for

example, show persistent discrepancies between the fundamental value and the nominal exchange

rate. The question, then, is how the monetary models of the exchange rate have performed

Page 38: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

37

empirically since the free floating of the 1970s. The short answer to that question would be: Not

very good.

Initially, the result of Frenkel (1976) strongly supported the flexible price monetary model when

looking at the German exchange rate vis-à-vis the American dollar during the hyperinflation in

the 1920s. Frenkel found that the coefficient of the money stock estimate (in equation (3.8)) was

near unity, in line with theory. But, as pointed out by for example Sarno and Taylor (2002: 123),

he overlooked the fact that the time-series in his regression could have been non-stationary.

Following Frenkels supportive result of the flexible price monetary model, the model “ceases to

provide a good explanation of variations in the exchange rate data” (Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 124). The

seminal article by Meese and Rogoff (1983) concluded that a random walk model performs at

least as well as three different monetary models – including the flexible as well as the sticky price

monetary model – when forecasting 1-12 months ahead. A ground-breaking result, which has

been rather robust to different tests since then. And a result that has “had an enduring effect on the

profession … [leading] Frankel and Rose to advocate a move away from fundamentals based models”

(MacDonald, 1999: 675). Besides the poor out of sample forecast, the coefficient estimates of

models like equation (3.8) as well as the empirical fit thereof were only good in periods of

hyperinflations – as the result of Frenkel (1976) for example shows (Frankel and Rose, 1995:

1693). The article by Meese and Rogoff (1983) initiated the so-called “exchange rate disconnect

puzzle” (cf. Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000), i.e. the finding that macroeconomic fundamentals and

the (nominal) exchange rate are only weakly correlated.

In the next section, the more recent empirical results of exchange rate research is presented and

discussed.

3.4.2 Modern empirical results

With the introduction of more advanced econometric methods for testing, the monetary models

have been examined numerous times over the last two decades.

McNown and Wallace (1994) test the flexible price model, using multivariate cointegration, on

three high-inflation countries and find strong support for long-run cointegration. But when

tested on industrialised countries, this relationship disappears. A result in line with the conclusion

from the previous section that the monetary models are most successful in periods with

hyperinflation. MacDonald and Taylor (1994) use multivariate cointegration tests as well, and find

some support for the monetary model. But the coefficients are of the wrong sign, compared with

equation (3.8) above. Groen (2000) uses panel-data set, thereby trying to reduce the small sample

bias. Using a panel of the G7 countries, he cannot reject the null-hypothesis of no-cointegration.

Cushman et al (1996) reach a less pessimistic result than Meese and Rogoff (1983), as they find

Page 39: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

38

that the exchange rate seems to be related to fundamentals (Cushman et al, 1996: 358). But, on

the other hand, they conclude that the pure monetary model seems inadequate at explaining

exchange rates over the floating period. Furthermore, one should note that they chose the seven

countries which experienced the highest inflation rate during the current float. Mark (1995) finds

that fundamentals may be able to predict the exchange rate, but only at long horizons (three-to-

four years). Frankel (1995) tests a general monetary equation of exchange rate determination

(combining long-run monetary equilibrium path with short-run overshooting) on five currencies.

He finds wrong signs on most coefficients and low significance levels; only for France are all four

coefficients in line with the hypothesis. Finally, Cheung et al (2005) test a range of exchange rate

models, including the PPP and UIP. They reach the mixed conclusion that “the results do not point

to any given model/specification combination as being very successful. On the other hand, some models do well at

certain horizons, for certain criteria. And indeed, it may be that one model will do well for one exchange rate, and

not for another” (Cheung et al, 2005: 1171).

The overall conclusion drawn from the results mentioned above is summed up by Sarno and

Taylor (2002: 136): “Empirical work on exchange rates has still not produced models that are sufficiently

statistically satisfactory to be considered reliable and robust, either in-sample or in out-of-sample forecasting”. This

conclusion is further supported by the empirical test in chapter 5, on the Japanese Yen and the

Norwegian krone against the US dollar, where a generic version of the monetary approach is

tested and firmly rejected. Thus, the problems of the monetary models when describing the

exchange rate movements seem to be a rather robust finding.

3.4.3 Exchange rate puzzles

The conclusion from the brief survey of exchange rate studies in section 3.3.1 and 3.3.2 above

emphasizes the definition of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle from the introduction in

chapter 1: The finding that macroeconomic fundamentals and the (nominal) exchange rate are

only weakly correlated (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000). Furthermore that the correlation is almost

zero in the short to medium run but increases somewhat in the longer run. Thus at three to four

years the fundamentals can predict (some of) the trend in exchange rate movement.

The influential result of Meese and Rogoff (1983: 17) that “the [monetary models] do not perform

significantly better than the random walk model” underlines the disconnect puzzle: Models based on

fundamentals fare no better than a simple random walk at predicting the exchange rate. This is

also evident from the PPP charts above (figures 7 and 8), as the nominal exchange rate

overshoots (or undershoots) its fundamental value for longer periods of time – up to several

years. This could lend some support to the conclusion of the Dornbusch (1976) overshooting

Page 40: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

39

model presented above – i.e. the exchange rate overshoots the long-run value – but studies rule

out this solution (see for example Eichenbaum and Evans, 1995).

As categorized by Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000: 380) the exchange rate disconnect puzzle is the

term for a broader class of puzzles regarding the weak link between the economy and the

exchange rate. Thus, the PPP puzzle (Rogoff, 1996) is a special case of the disconnect puzzle.

The PPP puzzle is best described by the question of Rogoff (1996: 647): “How can one reconcile the

enormous short-term volatility of real exchange rates with the extremely slow rate at which shocks appear to damp

out?”. The rather large half-lifes of the deviations from PPP is evident from figures 7 and 8 as

well. According to the result of Rogoff (1996), the PPP deviations die out at approximately 15

percent per year; implying half-lifes of roughly 3-4 years. Others (for example Murray and Papell,

2005) find even higher half-lifes than Rogoff. This finding further emphasizes the overall

disconnect puzzle of exchange rates.

Another puzzle of exchange rate research – though less related to the disconnect puzzle – is the

forward premium puzzle based on the result of Eugene Fama (1984). Fama estimated a

regression on the uncovered interest rate parity (equation (3.14) above) like the following:

(3.20) ( )1 0 1t t t ts f s uβ β+Δ = + − +

With ft being the forward rate, ut the disturbance (error) term and st the spot exchange rate. Given

that the agents are risk neutral and have rational expectations, the slope parameter should equal 1

and the disturbance term should be uncorrelated with information available at time t, following

the notion of efficient markets (Taylor, 1995: 15). But studies on regression equations resembling

equation (3.20) find that the β-parameter is closer to minus unity than 1 (see Lewis, 1995; Taylor,

1996; Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 141ff.). Excess returns are apparently non-zero, i.e. they are

predictable given current information (the forward rate, ft). Furthermore, the variances of the

returns are relatively large given the expected exchange rate changes (Lewis, 1995: 1922). The

theoretical prediction of equalisation between the expected returns of two countries has thus

been rejected by the empirics. As concluded by Lewis (1995: 1914): “The behaviour of domestic relative

to foreign returns has decisively rejected this assumption [i.e. UIP] over the floating period”.

The two building blocks – PPP and UIP – of the monetary approach apparently have several

problems when tested empirically. This obviously feed into the overall empirical performance of

models based on these two parity conditions, such as the two monetary models.

In the next section, the view of the exchange rate puzzles and the empirical results of this and the

former section will be challenged.

Page 41: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

40

3.4.4 Puzzles after all?

Not all economists subscribe to the mainstream view of exchange rate puzzles presented in

section 3.4.1 to 3.4.3. Among these, four different papers – Imbs et al (2005), Abhyankar et al

(2005), Engel et al (2007) and Alexius (2001) –question the normal view of exchange rate puzzles.

Imbs et al (2005) take on the PPP puzzle. They show that at a disaggregated level, prices revert to

parity rather quickly, with half-lifes of around eleven months (ibid.: 3). This is in stark contrast to

the mainstream belief of around 3-4 years (or even more) mentioned above. Supporting their case

of aggregation being central to the PPP puzzle, Imbs et al (2005: 3) reproduce the consensus view

when they do not correct for the heterogeneity in real exchange rates. As they point out in

regards to disagreggation being the solution to the PPP puzzle (ibid.: 2): “It is hard to think of

reasons why clothes and vegetables, say, should revert to parity at the same time”.

Alexius (2001) takes a shot at the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP). Using long interest rates

instead of short, as most articles tend to do, she finds that UIP appears to hold more often than

not. Again in contrast to the mainstream view presented above, for example put forth by Lewis

(1995).

Charles Engel et al (2007) find that monetary models actually forecast changes in exchange rates

better than the random walk using panel techniques. They conclude that “the array of evidence

presented in this paper … lends weight to the monetary models [i.e. flexible and sticky price] of exchange rates”

(ibid.: 45).

Finally, Abhyankar et al (2005) looks at the Meese and Rogoff (1983) result from a slightly

different perspective: Instead of using statistically measures of the forecasting accuracy, they test

whether using models based on fundamentals add economic value compared with the random

walk forecast. They conclude that the “gain from using the information in fundamentals in order to predict

the exchange rate out of sample (as opposed to assuming that the exchange rate follows a random walk) is often

substantial, although it varies somewhat across countries” (Abhyankar et al, 2005: 344). Furthermore, the

gains increase with the horizon and decreases with the level of risk aversion.

Based on the insight from these four papers, abandoning models based on fundamentals

altogether, as suggested by for example Frankel and Rose, does not seem to be the right solution

after all. Apparently, macroeconomic fundamentals do convey some information about exchange

rates. Simple as the monetary models may seem, they still carry insight regarding the movements

of exchange rates, albeit with some problems at the short to medium term. The IKE theory,

therefore, does not reject the monetary models, but see them as one method for forecasting

exchange rates.

Page 42: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

41

3.4.5 Critique of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis

As mentioned in section 3.2, the monetary approach to exchange rates builds on the rational

expectations hypothesis (REH). In this section, the critique of the REH is discussed. REH is an

important part of the monetary models, and critique thereof seems relevant in regards to the

difficulty of explaining exchange rate behaviour from a strict rational viewpoint.

According to Frydman and Goldberg (1996: 869), only two possible explanations can account for

the observed shortcomings and problems of the traditional exchange rate models shown in

section 3.4.1 to 3.4.3: “Either … the assumptions concerning the underlying structure of the economy, or … the

assumptions used in modelling exchange rate expectations”. Frydman and Goldberg confront this problem

by exchanging rational expectations with the imperfect knowledge economics representation of

forecasting behaviour, which will be discussed in detail in chapter 4. Regarding the rational

expectations hypothesis and the validity thereof, Muth (1961: 330) adds that “the only real test is

whether theories involving rationality explain observed phenomena any better than alternative theories”. As

concluded by De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2006a: 2): “A scientific theory, unlike religious belief or work of

art, should not be judged by its elegance but by its capacity to withstand empirical testing”. Following these

arguments, the empirical results put forth in section 3.4.1 strongly question the validity of the

REH and call for alternative theories. Besides the empirical results discussed above, episodes of

bubbles and crashes in the foreign exchange market has put the REH under additional pressure.

As argued by De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2006a: 3-4) as well as Frankel and Froot (1986), the large

swings in the dollar in the 1980s were not due to positive nor negative macroeconomic news, as

“there was not enough negative news to explain the crashes afterward” (De Grauwe and Grimaldi, 2006a: 4).

The REH assumes that the agents fully understand the economy in which they act. As noted by

De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2006a: 45): “It [REH] has started from the proposition that there is a one-to-

one correspondence between the information set embedded in the world and the information set that can be stored

and processed in each individual’s brain. This is an extraordinary assumption, which is tantamount to assuming

that each individual agent is a godlike creature”. As will be further build upon in both section 3.5 below,

as well as in chapter 4 on the imperfect knowledge economics theory, the private information set

(and the individual expectations computed on this background) available to each agent seem to

matter for the formation of the exchange rate. In addition agents use heuristics (i.e. “rule of

thumb”), past experience as well as the expected action of other agents when forming their

beliefs of the future asset price. Regarding the latter, it can be “rational to behave irrational” for

an agent, i.e. when compared to the outcome of the REH, given that he expects other agents to

behave irrational (e.g. that they use the wrong model).

Page 43: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

42

As noted by Lyons (2001: 75) the agents in the economy act non-strategic following the REH.

That is, the effect from individual trading on prices is not neglible, but still the traders in the

market act as price takers in the models; they completely disregard the effect from the other

agents’ trading. This paradox is referred to as the “schizophrenia problem” (Lyons, 2001).

Brock and Durlauf (2006) argue that if the assumption that the economic actors a priori know

the true parameters of a given dividend process was dropped, and instead replaced with an

assumption that the agents are learning about the parameters along the way, the puzzles (e.g.

equity premium puzzle) are solved. That is, the puzzles are solved by abandoning the strong

assumption of the rational expectations hypothesis. This could be the case for the range of

exchange rate puzzles as well. Brock and Durlauf (ibid.: 124) further claim that model uncertainty

increases the importance of how agents acquire information of the economy: “If an agent is

confident that he knows the true model of the economy, he is presumably going to treat the costs and benefits of

information acquisition differently than when the true model is unknown”. As they conclude, this is even

more relevant when the economy moves across regimes, “which in our context may be interpreted as

shifting models” (ibid.: 124). This, as we shall see, is in line with the conclusion of the imperfect

knowledge economics theory presented in the next chapter: Both in regards to the importance of

model uncertainty, the heterogeneity of agents and the shifting of the models they use.

Overall, the empirical anomalies of exchange rates – the exchange rate disconnect puzzle, the

PPP puzzle, the forward bias puzzle as well as the aforementioned bubbles and crash – seem to

invalidate the REH. Furthermore, the assumptions of the REH – e.g. that the agents are fully

informed – seem at odds with different surveys of currency trader behaviour, for example by

Cheung and Chinn (2001) and Cheung et al (2006) presented in chapter 2.

In the section on market microstructure below, some of the REH assumptions will be relaxed.

According to the microstructure approach, relaxing the assumptions of the monetary models

leads to a possible solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle. The imperfect knowledge

theory discussed in chapter 4 gives another solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle. This

theory, in parts, builds on some of the same assumptions and insights as the microstructure

approach; first and foremost a relaxation of the strict rational expectations hypothesis. Relaxing

the REH thus seems to be a possible solution to the exchange rate puzzles.

3.4.6 Different solutions to the exchange rate puzzles

Besides the critique of the REH discussed in the previous section, several economists have

attempted to explain the puzzling behaviour of exchange rates. Primarily two alternatives have

been put forth: to introduce either rational bubbles or non-rational behaviour into exchange rate

modelling (cf. Lyons, 2001: 172; Goldberg and Frydman, 2007: 105-6). Regarding the bubble-

Page 44: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

43

explanation, the empirical evidence has, until now, been rather unconvincing (Lyons, 2001: 172).

Regarding the latter, this has been an unattractive alternative for economists.

Another explanation has been non-linearity in the demand for money functions (Sarno and

Taylor, 2002: 126), which would lead to misspecification of the log-linear forms of the monetary

models presented above. Along the same line, Taylor and Peel (2000) argue that the adjustment

towards the equilibrium value is non-linear. Others have argued (Obstfeld and Rogoff, 2000) that

(diminutive) international trading costs in the goods market combined with “pricing to markets”

(Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 57) account for a large part of the disconnect puzzle. The significant

result of Engel and Rose (1996) of border effects when looking at prices in Canada and USA lend

some support to this argument. These possible solutions to the puzzles are, more or less, based

on the monetary approach presented above. And as argued in the critique of the rational

expectations hypothesis, maybe this is where the problem (and the possible solution) lies?

In the next section the microstructure approach to exchange rate will be presented. This

approach relaxes the strong assumptions of perfect knowledge of the monetary models. The

microstructure approach thus adds a microeconomic foundation to the exchange rate research,

which is missing entirely from the monetary approach. Furthermore the finding that private

information matters for exchange rate determination is a first step towards understanding the

imperfect knowledge economics theory presented in chapter 4.

3.5 The market microstructure approach

3.5.1 Introducing market microstructure

The exchange rate models presented above only focuses on the macro-economic aspects of the

exchange rate. But as shown in chapter 2 there seems to be a case for looking into the micro-

economic aspects of exchange rate determination as well.

The microstructure approach to exchange rates is summed up as follows by Sarno and Taylor

(2002: 264): “The foreign exchange microstructure approach, unlike the conventional macroeconomic one, typically

does not assume that only public information is relevant to exchange rates, that foreign exchange market agents are

homogenous, or that the mechanisms used for trading is inconsequential”. As shown in chapter 2 this seems

plausible and in line with, for example, the result of the survey of American traders by Cheung

and Chinn (2001) and the apparent low transparency of the foreign exchange market. Following

Lyons (2001: 4), the microstructure approach relaxes the following three assumptions of the

monetary approach:

Page 45: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

44

• Information: Microstructure models recognize that some information relevant to

exchange rates is not publicly available

• Players: Microstructure models recognize that market participants differ in ways that

affect prices

• Institutions: Microstructure models recognize that trading mechanisms differ in ways that

affect prices; i.e. trading matters for exchange rates

It is worth noticing, though, that the microstructure approach seeks to add a micro-foundation to

the macroeconomic monetary approach, not to disregard the monetary approach altogether

(Lyons, 2001).

Equation (3.21) below shows a generic version of the traditional asset-price models, as presented

in section 3.2 – e.g. equation (3.9):

(3.21) 1e

t t tS F Sβ α +′= +

Here, St denotes the spot exchange rate at time t, Ft a vector of fundamental variables with

explanatory power of the exchange rate (e.g. money supply, interest rate, output), β a vector of

factor loadings and St+1e the expected spot exchange rate at time t plus one (following Sager and

Taylor, 2006: 88). One notes that this class of models are strictly macroeconomic and, following

the bullet-points from above, omits the informational processing, agent heterogeneity, and

institutional structure in the market altogether. As noted by Sager and Taylor (ibid.: 88): “asset-

price models are essentially equilibrium models that marginalize the importance given to the means by which that

equilibrium is reached or the institutional setting in which currency prices are determined”. The market

microstructure approach thus focuses on the behaviour of the agents as well as the market

characteristics (cf. Taylor, 1995: 39); aspects which, following the quote by Sager and Taylor

above, the asset price models pay no attention to.

Regarding the former – information – it was shown in chapter 2 that agents in the market

process the information they receive differently (i.e. using methods bounded in the fundamental

value, in technical trading etc.). Below the concept of “order flow” will be discussed to shed light

at the importance of private information and its effect on the price setting of exchange rates.

Regarding the latter – institutions – the lack of transparency discussed in chapter 2 adds to the

importance of looking closely at the foreign exchange market structure. Apparently, the structure

of the exchange rate market (decentralised, non-disclosure etc) exacerbate the informational

asymmetries pointed out above.

Page 46: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

45

3.5.2 Order flow as an important factor for exchange rates

First of all it is important to be aware of the distinction between order flow and transaction

volume: Order flow is transaction volume that is signed (Lyons, 2001: 6). Furthermore, order

flow takes on a negative sign5, and the initiator of the trade is on the sell side. Over time order

flow is measured as the sum of signed buyer- and seller initiated orders. In addition, as noted by

Lyons (2001: 7), order flow is a variant of excess demand; but it does not sum to zero since the

orders are initiated against a market maker who then soaks up the difference between buyers and

sellers.

The question is, then, why order flow should be important in regards to prices? First of all,

relaxing the assumption of public information leads to order flow conveying information relevant

for prices. Two assumptions of public information in typical macroeconomic models are (cf.

Lyons, 2001: 21):

• All information relevant for exchange rates is publicly known,

• The mapping from this information to prices is also publicly known.

The second assumption relates to the “right” model of exchange rates, which will be discussed

(and relaxed) further in the next chapter on imperfect knowledge economics. As seen in the

empirical study above, there is hardly consensus on which model is the true model of exchange

rate behaviour (cf. Cheung et al, 2005). Thus, as noted by Lyons (2001: 21), relaxing the second

assumptions is hardly controversial. From this, order flow suddenly becomes important. And this

has implication for the first assumption: not all relevant information is publicly known, as order

flow is not observable by the public or by all agents in the foreign exchange market. Thus, private

information matters for exchange rate determination. Private information is defined as (cf. Lyons,

2001: 26):

• Information not known by all agents; and

• Private information produces a better price forecast than public information alone

An example (following Lyons, 2001): Two FX traders (A and B) at different banks observe the

same macro news. If agent A does not know how agent B will interpret the effect on prices from

5 Following the example in Lyons (2001): If an agent approaches a dealer (marketmaker) and sells him 10 units (eg.

dollars), transaction volume is 10 but orderflow is -10.

Page 47: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

46

the news (as the mapping of prices is not publicly known), observing the second agents trade

(order flow) gives some of this information. Hence the trade of B both influences the price as

well as agent A’s knowledge.

Since the foreign exchange market suffers from some lack of transparency, a dealer with

privileged access to order flow constitutes private information. Figures 11 and 12 below shows

the connection between order flow and exchange rate movements over a three months period

(May to August, 1996).

Figure 11 – Order flow (right hand scale) plotted against DM/USD

0,36

0,37

0,38

0,39

0,4

0,41

0,42

0,43

0,44

0,45

01/05 08/05 15/05 22/05 29/05 05/06 12/06 19/06 26/06 03/07 10/07 17/07 24/07 31/07 07/08 14/08 21/08 28/08-1200

-1000

-800

-600

-400

-200

0

200

400

600

DM/USD

Orderflow Source: Data from R.K. Lyons’ homepage, http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/lyons/fxdata.html

Looking at the two figures, there seems to be a rather strong correlation between the order flow

variable and the exchange rate movements over the period. This is supported by empirical tests.

Evans and Lyons (2002) find that order flow account for 40 to 60 per cent of the daily variation

in spot exchange rates in DEM/USD and YEN/USD. This result will be discussed further in the

following section with a test of a microstructure model. Furthermore, Evans and Lyons (2007)

find that the flows have significant forecasting power for macro fundamentals as well. That is,

order flow is central “to the process by which expectations of future macro variables are impounded into

exchange rates” (Evans and Lyons, 2007: 32). Lyons (2001), as well as Rime (2000), concludes that

private information plays a role, and that order flow conveys information on this. Gehrig and

Menkhoff (2004) finds, in a survey of foreign exchange market traders and fund managers, that

order flow analysis is almost as important as fundamental– and technical analysis, further

emphasizing the importance of the variable. Rime et al (2007) also find, using a year of data, that

orderflow have both explanatory and forecasting power for exchange rates. But as noted by

Page 48: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

47

Sarno and Taylor (2002: 274), this does not necessarily imply that order flow is the main driver of

exchange rates. Instead, macroeconomic variables may still be the underlying force of exchange

rate movements. But conventional measures of macroeconomic variables could be imprecise at

the release date.

Figure 12 – Order flow (RHS) plotted against Yen/USD

4,61

4,62

4,63

4,64

4,65

4,66

4,67

4,68

4,69

4,7

4,71

4,72

01/05 08/05 15/05 22/05 29/05 05/06 12/06 19/06 26/06 03/07 10/07 17/07 24/07 31/07 07/08 14/08 21/08 28/08-500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

YEN/USD

Orderflow

Source: Data from R.K. Lyons’ homepage, http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/lyons/fxdata.html

As Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2004) argue, the data used for exchange rate research differs from

the real-time data available to market participants when making trading decisions – as revised

data with the “true” observation is first published months after the initial (real-time) data is

observed by market participants. Thus, order flow could be a precise proxy for the

macroeconomic fundamentals as well as the variation of the expectations of future fundamentals.

In the following section an exchange rate model incorporating order flow as an important

variable is presented and tested.

3.5.3 A microstructure model of exchange rates

In the model of Evans and Lyons (2002), each day of exchange rate trading is split into three

rounds. In the first round, dealers trade with customers. In the second round, dealers trade

among themselves (spreading the risk, cf. Sager and Taylor, 2006: 90). Then, the dealers observe

the order flow, xt., from the interdealer trade. In the third round, dealers again trade with the

public (based on the information obtained from the order flow variable), thereby sharing

overnight risk (Evans and Lyons, 2002: 174).

Page 49: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

48

The model consists of two assets, one riskless and one risky (here: foreign exchange). There is T

trading periods (i.e. days), and the payoff on the risky asset is given by R:

(3.22) 1

1

T

tt

R r+

=

= Δ∑

The trΔ are i.i.d. (0, σr2) and observable before each trading day. There is N dealers on the foreign

exchange market, indexed by i, and a continuum of non-dealers (customers) indexed by

[ ]0,1z∈ . The round 1 price of dealer i is given by Pit1 and the customer order Cit

1. With Cit1 < 0

being defined as net customer selling.

The interdealer order flow at the end of round 2 is given by:

(3.23) 1

N

t iti

x T=

Δ =∑

In period 3, the dealers quote a scalar price Pit3 and total public demand is denoted by Ct

3. The

public demand can be written as:

(3.24) ( )3 3 31 3|t t tC E P Pγ +⎡ ⎤= Ω −⎣ ⎦

Here, γ is the public’s aggregate risk-bearing capacity and Ω the available public information

(Evans and Lyons, 2002: 175).

In period 3, the prices adjust such that Ct1+Ct

3 = 0. That is, 3 1t t

i

C C= −∑ . And since the order

flow indicates the customer order, Ct1, this can be written as: 1

t ti

C x= Δ∑ . Inserting into equation

(3.24) yields:

(3.25) ( )

3 31 3

1

1|

1,

t t t

t

i ii

P E P x

r x

γ

λ λγ

+

=

⎡ ⎤= Ω + Δ⎣ ⎦

= + Δ ≡∑

Equation (3.25) shows that the market clearing price in period 3 is the sum of the expected

payoff on the risky asset adjusted for a risk premium, defined by shift in order flow. This yields

the equation of price changes in the exchange rate:

(3.26) t t tP r xλΔ = Δ + Δ

Equation (3.26) shows the price change from period t-1 to period t. From this model, the

importance of order flow (the xt variable) is evident.

Page 50: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

49

Evans and Lyons (2002) estimate an equation based on (3.26), with change in the payoff, trΔ ,

defined as the change in the interest rate differential: ( )*tt tr i iΔ = Δ − . Regressing on equation

(3.27) is then a test of the model given by equation (3.26) above:

(3.27) ( )*1 2t t t t tp i i Xβ β μΔ = Δ − + Δ +

The microstructure approach argues that the sign on the Xt variable should be positive, since this

signals a net purchase of (say) dollars, which should push up the price of the asset. For the β1

coefficient on the interest rate differential, the sign should be positive as well: following the

sticky-price model from section 3.2, an increase in the interest rate initially leads to a jump

depreciation of the currency (i.e. overshooting), followed by appreciation.

The data for the interest rates in the regression is the closing price for 3 months treasury bills

taken from the EcoWin database. In Evans and Lyons (2002) the interest rates are the policy

rates for the respective countries. I find that the treasury bills are a more precise variable, as they

represent the riskfree investment, in line with the interest rates in the monetary models above.

Secondly, the policy rates in the dataset used in Evans and Lyons (2002) is rather invariable; e.g.

the policy rate of Japan is unchanged over the period. In Appendix B figure 3, the interest rates

of the three countries (USA, Germany and Japan) are plotted over time. The order flow variable

is taken from the dataset of Richard K. Lyons.

Table 3 presents the results – along with the result from Evans and Lyons (2002). T-statistics are

shown in parentheses. The fit of the two models as well as the scaled residuals are shown in

appendix A figures 4 and 5.

Table 3 – Estimates of the microstructure model (equation (3.27)) and the result of Evans and Lyons (2002)

No. obs: 80 β1 – interest rate β2 – order flow R2

DEM/USD 0.934 (1.6) 2.03 (10.3) 0.654

– Evans & Lyons 0.52 (1.5) 2.10 (10.5) 0.64

JPY/USD -0.96 (-0.671) 2.77 (7.25) 0.408

– Evans & Lyons 2.48 (2.7) 2.90 (6.3) 0.45 Source: Data taken from the EcoWin database and Richard K. Lyons homepage. T-statistics in brackets.

The first remarkable thing of the estimation is the relatively high fit of the model – an R2 between

40-65%. It is evident that using 3 months Treasury bill rates does not change much compared

with the result of Evans and Lyons (2002). In regards to the result above, Lyons (2001: 188)

concludes: “That order flow explains such a large percentage of price moves underscores the inadequacy of

Page 51: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

50

…[the] public information framework”. Lyons (2001: 173) consequently suggests a hybrid version –

equation (3.28) below – of the generic monetary model given by equation (3.21) above.

(3.28) 1' et t t tS F X Sβ φ α +′= + +

Where Xt includes microstructure components. That could be order flow but also inventories or

other important variables from the microstructure research. Lyons (2001: 176) elaborates on the

hybrid model: “the model accommodates both possibilities: information that affects price directly and information

that affects price via order flow. Armed with models that allow for both, we can let the data determine their relative

importance”. The result of the microstructure model highlights the fact that traditional

macroeconomic models of exchange rate determination have omitted important variables; in this

case order flow. It further underscores the importance private information plays in the

determination of exchange rates. A conclusion also supported by Bacchetta and Wincoop (2006:

570), who conclude that “investor heterogeneity is key to understanding exchange rate dynamics”.

But one should note, though, that a problem with models incorporating microstructure variables

like order flow is that these variables are not publicly available and hence difficult to obtain for

researchers. This further amplifies the importance of order flow, of course, since only some of

the agents in the foreign exchange market have access to useful data on this variable.

The result above does not imply that macroeconomic variables should be abandoned altogether –

as Lyons (2001) also concludes. The microstructure approach rather highlights the shortcoming

of the strictly macro based models such as the FPMM or the overshooting model presented in

this chapter.

3.6 Conclusion This chapter commenced with a macroeconomic glance at exchange rate movements. Looking at

the charts, the exchange rate puzzle(s) emerged: there seems to be a disconnect between

macroeconomic fundamentals and the exchange rate, at least for some time periods.

Then two of the most influential exchange rate models – the flexible and sticky price monetary

models – were presented. Both models are part of the dominant monetary approach to exchange

rates, stating that exchange rates is the relative price of two moneys and determined by the

relative supply and demand hereof. Furthermore macroeconomic fundamentals, such as output,

are assumed to be key determinants of exchange rates.

The empirical study showed, however, that this approach may be too simple. Although several

researchers find some relation between the exchange rate and the fundamentals in the long run

(i.e. three to four years), the results are not conclusive nor do they point to one specific model for

Page 52: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

51

exchange rate determination. And in the short to medium term, the relationship is almost non-

existent. On the other hand, some researchers actually find that the models give a relatively good

explanation of movements in the exchange rate. For some periods of time, for specific currency

crosses, specific models can give an explanation of the movements in the exchange rate, both in-

and out-of sample. But this is still a puzzling result and certainly not in line with the sharp

prediction of the two monetary models presented in this chapter.

This leads to several questions: Why can the currency be overvalued for periods of several years?

Why do different macro fundamentals seem to matter at different points in time? Why is the

exchange rate so slow to react on an overvaluation (undervaluation)? And when the exchange

rate reaches its fundamental value, why does it not stay there but continues its movement away

from parity?

One possible response to these questions could be that the underlying assumption of rational

expectations (REH) is flawed. And it is obvious that, at least to some extent, the REH seem a bit

unrealistic. Relaxing some of the assumptions, especially concerning the information set,

suddenly leads to increased importance of the microeconomic side of exchange rate

determination, as the microstructure approach argues. If private information plays a role,

variables like order flow convey important insights on exchange rate behaviour; insights that the

agents in the market utilise for setting their exchange rate expectations. As we have seen from the

test of the simple microstructure model, order flow does play an important role – at least in the

short run of up to a year. A result that has turned out to be rather robust.

In the following chapter some of the insights from the microstructure approach, as well as

conclusions from chapter 2, will be further elaborated on when presenting the imperfect

knowledge economics (IKE) theory: The criticism of rational expectations and the insights from

the microstructure approach of private information plays a central part in the IKE approach to

exchange rates, as well as the heterogeneity of agents. The IKE theory puts forth another

explanation of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle: The agents utilise a portfolio of models when

assessing the future value of the exchange rate, since they have only partial knowledge of the

market in which they participate. A portfolio which could include the monetary models discussed

above (but also technical analysis or other methods such as order flow analysis). Thus, the

outcome of the IKE model has to be different from that of the rational expectations outcome,

since the heterogeneous agents (by assumption) do not use the same models. But the IKE theory

does not abandon the macroeconomic fundamentals importance for exchange rates. Instead, the

importance of the macroeconomic variables (as seen in for example Cheung and Chinn, 2001)

changes over time. Nor does the IKE theory abandon rationality on part of the agents. Instead

Page 53: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

52

the agents behave bounded rational, knowing that they do not perfectly know (or understand) the

market completely. Hence, the IKE theory combines the insight from both the macro and micro

founded models discussed in this chapter, as well as the insights of agent’s behaviour discussed in

chapter 2.

Page 54: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

53

Chapter 4

Imperfect knowledge economics “… Macroeconomists face a choice: either they can continue to try to explain asset market

anomalies using the rational expectations hypothesis and live with the specter of gross

irrationality in assets markets, or they can reconcile that imperfect knowledge, which is an

inherent feature of the environment in which agents have to form expectations, may be the key

to reconciling the movement of asset prices with the postulate of individual rationality”

Roman Frydman and Michael D. Goldberg (2002), p. 2

”… I confess that I prefer true but imperfect knowledge, even if it leaves much indetermined and

unpredictable, to a pretence of exact knowledge that is likely to be false.”

Friedrich August von Hayek, Nobel Prize lecture (1974)

4.1 Introducing imperfect knowledge economics The central part of imperfect knowledge economics (IKE) is to place “imperfect knowledge on the

part of market participants and economists at the centre of our analysis” (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 6),

and thereby to replace the rational expectations hypothesis modelling of expectations.

In Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 8) knowledge is referred to as imperfect if: “... no one has access to

a fully predetermined model that adequately represents …the causal mechanism that underpins outcomes in all time

periods, past and future”. This is in accordance with Hayek (1945: 519): “The economic problem of society

is …a problem of the utilization of knowledge which is not given to anyone in its totality”.

Thus, the agents in the economy do not necessarily use the same (nor the “right”) model when

assessing the economy in which they live, and the agents therefore adopt different strategies in

forecasting the future; hence, the outcome (e.g. the expected value of the exchange rate) is bound

to be different from that of rational expectations.

Overall, two factors create the imperfect knowledge: a diffuse (in the sense: not fully intelligible)

as well as an unforeseeable world. Regarding the first, the agents in the society only have partial

information about the world they live in, “…market outcomes arise out of a division of knowledge whose

totality remains opaque to any one individual” (Goldberg and Frydman, 2007: 9). This is in line with the

Page 55: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

54

microstructure approach from chapter 3 and the conclusion on the importance of private

information.

Regarding the second, the future states of the economy are uncertain and this affects the agents’

decisions as well. According to Frank Knight (1921: 198): “Hence it is our imperfect knowledge of the

future, a consequence of change, not change as such, which is crucial for the understanding of our problem”. The

aspect of Knightian uncertainty and its significance for the IKE theory will be discussed in the

next section.

Because of these two factors, imperfect knowledge and uncertainty, the agents use different

theories and models when forecasting and deciding which strategy to follow. As pointed out by

Frydman and Goldberg (2004: 1): “Financial markets are always in flux. Relationships that initially hold

are sooner or later replaced by new relationships. Strategies that initially generate profits lose their ability to produce

profits with the passage of time… In such a world of imperfect knowledge, profit seeking agents must engage in a

creative forecasting process.” The agents in the economy do not, therefore, behave irrationally, but

instead act (rationally) on the notion that their knowledge is not perfect: “Rational agents recognize

that their models and rules are not strictly correct and consequently behave like scientists... they test their models

and rules against available data and in the face of contradictory evidence revise their trading strategies” (Frydman

and Goldberg, 2002: 8). This is in line with, for example, the assumption of Frankel and Froot

(1986: 34) who, regarding the bubble of the American dollar in the 1980s, conclude that “… the

bubble is the outcome of portfolio managers’ attempt to learn the model”. This is also supported by Kurz et al

(2004: 2) who point out that: “agents do not hold rational expectations, since the environment is dynamically

changing, not stationary, and true probabilities are unknown to anyone. In such a complex environment agents use

subjective models. Some consider these agents irrational, but one cannot require them to know what they cannot

know”.

In the case of exchange rates, this means that agents have imperfect knowledge of the

relationship between the macroeconomic fundamentals and the exchange rate (Frydman and

Goldberg, 1996: 870). The agents consequently utilise a number of different theories – the set of

leading theories – to forecast the movements in the exchange rates. This set of theories could

include the flexible and sticky price monetary models discussed in chapter 3 as well as technical

trading methods or microstructure models. That is, the agents have a portfolio of models when

forecasting the exchange rate. This, as we shall see below, furthermore leads to different

forecasting strategies across agents, and hence heterogeneous expectations. Because of this, the

IKE theory does not fully prespecify the changes of preferences and forecasting behaviour from

the initial point and all other points in time (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 14). This means that

the IKE theory have only qualitative predictions regarding the possible outcomes (ibid.: 66). This

Page 56: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

55

is one of the more critical points of the IKE theory, as argued by Papell (2003), and it will be

discussed further in section 4.6 below.

This chapter is structured as follows: First a discussion of imperfect knowledge as well as

uncertainty, including a discussion of the term Knightian uncertainty. Then follows a discussion

of preferences and forecasting strategies of the agents in an IKE setting, building on the results

from prospect theory. This is followed by the uncertainty-adjusted UIP, UAUIP, a new parity

condition on the foreign exchange market which implements the aforementioned prospect

theory. Then a version of a traditional monetary model which includes IKE specifications. This

model shows how the large swings away from the fundamental value (here PPP) can be sustained

in a model of exchange rates when the agents have imperfect knowledge. And why the price

eventually returns to parity. This leads to a discussion of the IKE theory as a possible solution to

the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

4.2 Imperfect knowledge and uncertainty

4.2.1 Knightian uncertainty

The term “Knightian uncertainty” stems from the book of Frank Knight (1921), “Risk,

uncertainty and Profit”. Knight introduced a clear distinction between measurable uncertainty,

called risk, and true uncertainty, which is assumed to be immeasurable. As noted by Knight

(1921: 233): “The practical difference between the two categories, risk and uncertainty, is that in the former the

distribution of the outcome in a group of instances is known (either through calculation a priori or from statistics of

past experience), while in the case of uncertainty this is not true, the reason being in general that it is impossible to

form a group of instances, because the situation dealt with is in a high degree unique”.

As discussed by Richardson (1953: 136), some writers have argued that the distinction between

risk and uncertainty is of degree, not of kind (as Knight argues), i.e. that “no future event is ever

wholly unique” (ibid. 138). Richardson therefore makes another distinction, following the idea of

Knight, between objective and subjective estimates. The first being statistical estimates, which are

demonstrable and objective in the sense that “given the same information and same rules, everyone should

get the same result” (ibid. 140). The latter distinction can, on the other hand, not be fully

demonstrated or communicated, as the “estimate is private to the estimator and in this sense subjective”

(ibid. 140). This lies end to end with the notion of private information discussed in chapter 3.

4.2.2 Imperfect knowledge

The distinction of objective and subjective estimates leads to the hypothesis of imperfect

knowledge: Since some information is private, according to Richardson (1953), knowledge is

Page 57: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

56

dispersed between the agents in the society. From this follows that the agents use different

models and methods when assessing the future value of financial assets, as argued by Frydman

and Goldberg (2007). Surveys of foreign exchange traders show that agents use different

methods when buying or selling currency (e.g. Cheung and Chinn, 2001). In addition, the agents

use rather simple methods – compared with the complexity of the market – when assessing the

future value of financial assets. As Kahneman and Tversky (1992: 317) concludes: “… when faced

with a complex problem, people employ a variety of heuristic procedures in order to simplify the representation and

the evaluation of prospects”. Secondly, a large part of the information available to the agents in the

market may be public, for example macroeconomic data, but the way the agents utilize this data

when making forecasts and decisions may be individual. As pointed out by Sarno and Taylor

(2006: 273) there is an increasing dispersion, measured by the standard deviation, in forecasts (i.e.

expectations) at longer forecast horizons.

The foreign exchange market specifically has a rather low transparency (as discussed in chapter

2), as trades are not generally observable. Hence, some agents have information which is not

available to all the participants in the market, for example order flow data. This private

information, as seen from the discussion of the microstructure approach in chapter 3, plays an

important part when the exchange rate is determined; at least in the shorter run. Private

information is an important part of the imperfect knowledge economics theory which, combined

with the uncertainty aspect discussed above, leads to a different result than given by the rational

expectations hypothesis.

It could be, though, that information of exchange rates was available to all agents but at a (small)

cost. In Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) agents are initially identical but can obtain information by

spending c. As Grossman and Stiglitz conclude (ibid.: 405): “We have argued that because information is

costly, prices cannot perfectly reflect the information which is available, since if it did, those who spent resources to

obtain it would receive no compensation”. Only when information is inexpensive, the market price will

reflect the informed agents (i.e., those who paid c) information. Even in the case of information

being available to all agents, the price of the asset (in this case the exchange rate) may not reflect

this, since it is costly (e.g. time consuming) to obtain the information. Another variant of this is

discussed in Brock and Durlauf (2006), mentioned in chapter 3, where benefits and costs of

information acquisition depend on the degree of model uncertainty – which is a central part of

the IKE theory.

Thus, in the theory of imperfect knowledge agents differ and the information available to the

agents differs, at least to some degree. This is coupled with the assumption that i) the future is

uncertain and ii) the “correct” model of the economy is unknown. Regarding the second

Page 58: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

57

assumption, the empirical survey in chapter 3 showed that none of the different monetary models

are good at describing movements in various currency crosses (following e.g. Cheung et al, 2005).

Hence, this last assumption seems to be supported by empirical evidence.

This is the foundation of the IKE theory. In the following section, the IKE preferences and

strategies of the agents are modelled.

4.3 Modelling preferences and forecasting strategies In this section, the representation of preferences and forecasting strategies in the IKE framework

will be developed. First a discussion of the expected utility hypothesis, which is the conventional

representation of preferences, followed by a critique thereof put forth by Kahneman and Tversky

(1979, 1992). Then follows a presentation of prospect theory, which is the building block for the

modelling of preferences in the IKE theory.

4.3.1 The expected utility hypothesis

Normally, economic models are based on assumptions of how rational agents rank the different

uses of the resources (or actions) that are presented to them. One of these assumptions is that of

risk aversion: Agents tend to, when faced with comparable returns, to choose the less risky

alternative. Specifying the preferences, economists usually rely on the expected utility hypothesis

(Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 155), stating that the utility of a gamble equals the expected value

of the utilities of the different outcomes compromising the gamble. According to Kahneman and

Tversky (1979: 263ff), expected utility theory is based on the following three tenets:

i) Expectation: ( ) ( ) ( )1 1 1 1, ;...; , ...n n n nU x p x p p u x p u x= + +

The overall utility of a given prospect, given by U, equals the weighted utility of the different

states (outcomes).

ii) Asset integration: ( )1 1, ;...; ,n nx p x p is acceptable at asset position w given that

( ) ( )1 1, ;...; ,n nU w x p w x p u w+ + > Thus, a prospect is acceptable given that the utility from

integrating the prospect with the assets exceeds the utility alone. As pointed out by Kahneman

and Tversky (1979: 264), the domain of the utility function is final states rather than gains or

losses.

iii) Risk aversion: u is concave ( )'' 0u < . An agent is risk averse if he prefers the certain prospect,

x, to any risky prospect (gamble) with expected value of x.

Page 59: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

58

4.3.2 Critique of the expected utility hypothesis

The three assumptions above is, as mentioned, the mostly used normative and descriptive model

for decision making under uncertainty. But as noted by Kahneman and Tversky (1992: 297): “a

substantial body of evidence shows that decision makers systematically violate its basic tenets.”. Kahneman and

Tversky presents five phenomena of choice which violates the standard model presented above

(ibid.: 298):

Framing effects: Evidence of various experiments has shown that framing the options yield

different preferences, contrary to rational choice theory.

Non-linear preferences: Following the expectation principle, utility of a risky prospect is linear

in outcome probabilities. According to Kahneman and Tversky (1992), this has been challenged

by showing that the difference between probabilities of .99 and 1.00 has a larger impact on

preferences than the difference of 0.10 and 0.11.

Source dependence: People’s willingness to bet on an uncertain event does not only depend on

the degree of uncertainty, but on its source as well.

Risk seeking: People often prefer a small probability of winning a large prize over the expected

value of that prospect. Furthermore, risk seeking is common when people have to choose

between a sure loss and a substantial probability of a larger loss.

Loss aversion: That the disutility from a loss exceeds the utility of gains of the same size

(Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 161). There is an observed asymmetry between gains and losses,

which is “far too extreme to be explained by income effects or by decreasing risk aversion” (Kahneman and

Tversky, 1992: 298)

The five “anomalies” presented above have led Kahneman and Tversky to present the alternative

theory for choices under uncertainty, prospect theory, which will be discussed in section 4.3.3.

The prospect theory is part of the basis for the imperfect knowledge economics theory.

4.3.3 Prospect theory

Prospect theory implies that the (risky) prospects are evaluated by a value function which has the

following three characteristics (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 17, and Kahneman and Tversky,

1991: 1039):

Reference dependence: “The carriers of [utility] are gains and losses defined relative to a reference point”.

Loss aversion: As shown above, the disutility from a loss exceeds the utility of gains of the same

size.

Page 60: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

59

Diminishing sensitivity: “The marginal utility of both gains and losses decreases with their size”.

According to Kahneman and Tversky (1991: 309), this leads to the following two-part power

function:

(4.1) ( )( )

0

0

x if xv x

x if x

α

βλ

⎧ >⎪=⎨− − <⎪⎩

The v(.) is defined over gains and losses in wealth relative to a reference point. The parameter λ is

the degree of loss aversion and α and β the curvature of the utility function over gains and losses,

respectively (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 19). Loss aversion on the part of the agents is implied

for λ larger than 1. According to Frydman and Goldberg (ibid.: 19) empirical results have found

the λ to be above 2, which strongly indicates loss aversion.

According to the characteristic diminishing sensitivity, above, it can be verified that the utility

function in equation (4.1) is concave in gains and convex in losses for α and β < 1 (since, for x >

0, 0x′′ < ). In the following section the prospect theory is applied to the foreign exchange

market.

4.3.4 Prospect theory and the foreign exchange market – the IKE approach

In the following setup6 there are two countries, A and B, two types of non-monetary assets, A

and B bonds. Country A is referred to as the “domestic country”, and the bonds of type A and B

are denominated in A and B currencies, respectively. The nominal return on the bonds are

denoted by Ati and B

ti . The ex-post nominal return on a pure long position in foreign exchange,

Rt+1L is given by the following equation7:

(4.2) 1 1L B At t t t tR s s i i+ += − + −

Where “L” denotes the long position and st the log level of the spot rate at time t. The return on

the pure short position is given by:

6 This section is primarily based on Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: pp. 159ff. 7 At a pure long position, the agent borrows one unit of domestic currency (say DKK) at time t, paying the interest

rate itA. The agent then sell this currency (for EUR, say) at the foreign exchange market and receive 1ts

at interest

rate itB. In period t+1, the agent will sell 1ts

(1+ itB ) at the rate st+1. The total return at time t+1 would then be:

( ) ( )1 1 1B Att t

t

s i is+ + − + . Taking logs leads to equation (4.2) above. For a pure short position, the opposite holds

true, ie. the return is –Rt+1 (cf. Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 140)

Page 61: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

60

(4.3) 1 1S A Bt t t t tR s s i i+ += − + −

Only the problem faced from country A wealth holders is evaluated, as the decision faced by

both A and B holders are identical.

Following the notion of a reference level from prospect theory above the change in wealth

(denoted by W) relative to some reference level for individual i is given by equation (4.4)

(Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 159):

(4.4) ( )1 1 1 1i i i i i A it t t t t t t t tW W W a R i p+ + +

⎡ ⎤Δ = −Γ = + + − −Γ⎣ ⎦

Here the portfolio share (i.e. the share of foreign assets, either short or long) is given by ati, pt is

the domestic rate of inflation and the individual reference level is given by Гti. Rt+1 is the return

on the position, as given by equation (4.2). Positive (negative) values of 1i

tW +Δ are equal to

individual i experiencing a gain (loss). The first problem, then, is to specify the reference level.

Following Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 160), one could define this reference level as the wealth

obtained from staying out of the market altogether, i.e. solely buying domestic bonds. This is

given by equation (4.5) below:

(4.5) ( )1i i At t t tW i pΓ = + − for all i and t

The potential gains (and losses) of agent i then comes from participating in foreign exchange

speculation, relative to this reference level. Inserting the value for the reference level, equation

(4.5), into the wealth equation (4.4) yields the following:

(4.6) 1 1i i i

t t t tW a R W+ +Δ =

For an agent holding a long position, ati > 0, a positive realisation of Rt+1 (denoted rt+1

+) leads to a

gain. On the other hand, an agent holding a short position, ati < 0, experiences a loss for rt+1

+. The

opposite is true for a negative realisation of Rt+1 (denoted by rt+1– ), which leads to a gain (loss) for

the short (long) position. An agent holding a long position is in the following defined as a “bull”,

whereas an agent holding a short position is defined as a “bear”. Hence, the IKE theory contains

heterogeneous agents. The notion of bulls and bears just serves as a simplification, though, as

there exists a continuum of different agents in the IKE theory.

First I will expand on equation (4.1) above, the utility function for the prospect theory. In the

foreign exchange market context, equation (4.6), the equation (in changes) will look like the

following:

(4.7) ( )( )

( )| | 0

| | 0

gi i

li i

W a r if WV W

W a r if W

α

βλ

⎧ Δ >⎪Δ = ⎨⎪− Δ <⎩

Page 62: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

61

Where rg (rl) is the gain (loss) for both the bull and the bear, but equals either rt+1+ or rt+1

according to the type of the agent – see equation (4.8) below. That is, the bull (bear) gains (loses)

from an increase (decrease) in the exchange rate.

(4.8) 1 1

1 1

: 0, ,

: 0, ,

g li t t

g li t t

Bull a r r r r

Bear a r r r r

+ −+ +

− ++ +

> = =

< = =

Following Frydman and Goldberg (2003: 19ff.), the utility function in equation (4.7) can be

written in a simpler, linear, version:

(4.9) ( ) ( )( )| | , | |g l g i l i i ii i i i i i t i t Gt LtV W a r W a r r f r f V V

α βλ λ− = + = +

Here, the utility function is expressed as the sum of the expected gains (rig) and expected losses

(ril) from holding a position (fti) in foreign exchange times the investment, denoted by fti. Note that

loss aversion have an influence for λ strictly larger than 1. Then, i iGt LtV V+ is the expected utility

from a position of the size fti in the foreign exchange market (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 20).

Following the assumption of Frydman and Goldberg (ibid.: 21), it is furthermore assumed that

the “fear” of a potential loss, ril, increases with the position size, fti. This prevent the agent from

taking an unlimited open position, as the disutility of expected losses grows faster than the

expected gains when position size grows (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 20). This further

requires that α > β in equation (4.7), stating that the degree of concavity of the utility function is

larger than the convexity over its losses. Equation (4.10) below adds the position size to the

determination of the degree of loss aversion:

(4.10) 1 2

, 1i l i l i i i MAXi i tr r fλ λ λ λ λ= − < <

With MAXλ being a constant. From this, the degree of loss aversion is assumed to be a function of

the position size. Inserting equation (4.10) into (4.9) yields the following:

(4.11) ( ) ( ) ( )1 2 1 2

2g i i l i i i g i i l i ii i t i t t i t i tV r f r f f r f r fλ λ λ λ⋅ = + − = + −

Differentiating equation (4.11) with respect to the position size, setting equal to zero, and solving

yields the following:

(4.12) ( ) ( )12

102

i i g i lt i ii i

t

Vfor f r r

λ∂ ⋅

= = +∂

The important thing to notice is that the value of fti depends on whether 1

g i li ir rλ+ is larger or

smaller than zero8. Note that even if 0g li ir r+ > , and agent i thus expect to earn a profit on a

8 Note that lir is negative, as it is the expected loss and hence is a measure of disutility

Page 63: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

62

given speculation, a large 1

iλ (i.e. a high degree of loss aversion) could shift the overall sign of the

equation causing the speculator to stay out of the market altogether. The expected return, in that

case, would not be large enough to compensate the agent for his large sensitivity to losses,

measured by the 1

iλ . As concluded by Frydman and Goldberg (2003: 22): “All … loss-averse

speculators require an expected return in excess of some individually determined positive value in order to take open

positions in foreign exchange”. This individual minimum premium, denoted by ˆtρ in the following,

can then be derived by rearranging equation (4.12):

(4.13) ( ) ( )1 12 2

1 1 ˆ12 2

i g l i l i it i i i t ti if r r r rλ ρ

λ λ +⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤= + + − = −⎣ ⎦⎣ ⎦

Here, the i superscript on rt+1 can either indicate a bull (+) or a bear (-), following equation (4.8)

above. From equation (4.13), the risk premium can be written as:

(4.14) ( )1ˆ 1 0i i l

t irρ λ= − >

Thus, to take a position in foreign exchange, the agent (either bear or bull, in this case) has to be

compensated enough, i.e. ˆg l ii i tr r ρ+ >

The exchange rate forecast of the agents The agents’ forecast of the future exchange rate depends on both the current exchange rate, st, as

well as on a set of causal variables, Xt, which (can) differ among the agents in the economy9. The

causal variables (can) include macroeconomic variables (as well as for example order flow), but it

also includes the preferences and individual experience of agent i. The IKE forecast of the

exchange rate is then given by:

(4.15) ,| 1

ˆˆ , 0 1i IKE i it t t t t t ts X sβ δ δ+ ′= + < <

A change in the aggregate forecast of the exchange rate for period t+1 thus comes from either

changes in the underlying variables, Xti, (macroeconomic fundamentals, preferences etc.) or from

the level of the exchange rate itself, st. Furthermore, as argued by Frydman and Goldberg (2007:

265), changes in ˆ i it tXβ occurs because of either i) revisions of forecasting strategies at time t or ii)

changes that occur because of new realizations of the set of causal variables, Xti, leads the agents

to change their forecast of the exchange rate. In contrast to (typical) rational expectations models,

the ˆ itβ can change over time (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 186). Equation (4.15) is thus similar

9 Note that in Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 264), the causal variable, Xti, is also denoted ˆa

ts .

Page 64: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

63

to the “hybrid” model (equation (3.28)) presented in the microstructure section in chapter 3, as

the causal variables can include macro- as well as micro fundamentals (such as order flow).

Which underlying variables included in Xt is not prespecified. Furthermore, the model allows for

changes in the variables determining the exchange rate: Innovations, structural changes or policy

changes may therefore change the composition of Xt. The IKE theory allows for this, as well as

for the creativity of the agents, who may change both their methods and the models used for

their individual forecasts of the exchange rate.

The total change10 in the forecast in equation (4.15) is given by (ibid.: 192):

(4.16) ( ),

| 1 1 1

,| 1,

| 1 1

ˆ ˆˆ

ˆˆˆ

i IKE i i i it t t t t t t t t t

i IKEt ti IKE i i

t t t tt

ds dX ds d X d s

sds dX

s

β δ β δ

β

+ − −

++ −

= + + +

∂= +

Where the last part is the partial change in the forecast coming from changes in the forecasting

strategy and/or the exchange rate.

4.3.5 Equilibrium in the FX market under Prospect theory: UAIP

According to Keynes (1936: 170) “the market price will be fixed at the point at which the sales of the bears

and the purchases of the bulls are balanced”. That is, by definition, the market portfolio has to be hold

by the agents. Hence, aggregating the long (“purchases”) and short (“sales”) positions of agents

in equation (4.13) and equalling these leads to the (momentary) condition for equilibrium in the

foreign exchange market (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 23). The aggregate result for the bulls

(i.e. the long position) is:

(4.17) ( ),1

1

2

1ˆ , 112

l L S

L S

n n ni L L i

t t t n ni iii

f w r where w and wρ

λ

+++

+=

= − = =∑ ∑∑

%

Here, the “L” superscript denotes a long position, and “S” a short position. The analogue result

can be obtained for the bears (short position):

(4.18) ( ),1

1

ˆ ,Sn

i S St t t

if w r ρ−

+=

= − −∑ %

10 The result is achieved as follows (here shown for the part βtiXti , the same applies for δsti):

( ), ,| 1 1| 1 1 1 1

1 1 1 1 1 1

1 1 1

ˆ ˆˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ:

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

i IKE i IKE i i i it t t t t t t t t t t t

i i i i i i i i i i i i i it t t t t t t t t t t t t t

i i i i i i i it t t t t t t t

s s X s X s

For X X X X X X X

X X X X

β δ β δ

β β β β β β β

β β β β

+ − − − − −

− − − − − −

− − −

− = + − −

− = − + − ⇔

− = Δ + Δ

Page 65: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

64

The weights, wiL and wiS, are the part of the agents being either bulls or bears, respectively. These

weights are negative functions of the degree of loss aversion, given by λ2i. Thus, the distribution

of agents can change over time between bulls and bears. For example a falling dollar (as observed

in late 2007 and beginning of 2008) could shift some agents from being bulls to bears, as the

degree of loss aversion rises. As pointed out by Kurz et al (2004: 4), the descriptive statistics of

exchange rate returns (asymmetry and high density in the tails) shown in chapter 2 could stem

from an (asymmetric) distribution of the agents – a distribution given by the weight parameter w.

The equality of the two aggregate positions in (4.17) and (4.18) yields the following:

(4.19) 1 1 1 ˆ ˆ ˆ, L St t t t t tr r r ρ ρ ρ+ −+ + += + = −% % %

The condition for equilibrium then yields:

(4.20) 1 1 1ˆ ˆ ˆL St t t t t tr r rρ ρ ρ+ −+ + ++ = − ⇔ =% % %

This is the uncertainty adjusted uncovered interest rate parity (UAIP), following Frydman and

Goldberg (2003: 24 and 2007: 210ff.). This can be rewritten as the following (Frydman and

Goldberg, 2007):

(4.21) | 1| 1 ˆˆ:

t tt tUAIP r ρ++ =

The UAIP represents equilibrium in the foreign exchange market and is the equality of the

aggregated uncertainty adjusted expected returns on foreign and domestic bonds (Frydman and

Goldberg, 2007: 211). That is, the expected return on long positions equals that of the short

positions. This follows the normal UIP condition, but here the expected returns have been

adjusted for by the larger sensitivity to potential losses (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 24). From

this it can be inferred that the sign of the uncertainty premium, | 1

ˆt t

ρ+

, depends on the sign of the

market expectation (i.e. the average of bulls’ and bears’ assessment of the expected exchange rate

movements), | 1t tr + . If the bears dominates the bulld, i.e. | 1t tr + < 0, then equilibrium in the foreign

exchange market necessitate that the bears either fear losses more than the bulls, or that they

picture a larger loss than the bulls, i.e. ˆ Stρ > ˆ L

tρ . From this concern of a higher expected loss

follows equilibrium between the long and short positions in the market. As Frydman and

Goldberg concludes (2003: 25): “The algebraic sign of the equilibrium uncertainty premium, | 1

ˆt t

ρ+

, will

change whenever the dominant weight behind the average opinion shifts between bulls and bears”.

From the context of the returns, equation (4.2), and the expected future exchange rate, (4.15)

follows:

(4.22) | 1

,| 1 ˆˆ

t t

i IKE B At t t t ts s i i ρ

++ − + = +

Page 66: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

65

All else equal, an expected rise in the exchange rate will be followed by a equal rise in the

premium; this causes the demand to decline. In the following section I will add conservative

forecasting strategy as well as the “gap” effect which, together with the UAIP condition, implies

that a change in the causal variables lead to movements in the equilibrium exchange rate and the

premium (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 216). This further explains the long swings in the

exchange rate, as observed in chapter 3, and together it provides a possible solution to the

disconnect puzzle.

4.3.6 Modelling forecasting strategies I: The Gap effect

The expected gap is defined as the difference between the conditional forecast of the exchange

rate of agent i and the agents’ assessment of the historical benchmark value, which could be the

PPP value (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 27). But note that the benchmark value will be

determined each period by different agents, with (probably) different view on how to reach this

value, and hence the benchmark will in general be different over the agents. On the other hand,

the fundamental value given by PPP is available to everyone in the market, and is therefore a

fundamental alongside the output or interest rates.

The gap effect is then the effect from the gap (the difference between the historical benchmark

and the expected value of the exchange rate) on the agents’ expected loss. The expected gap is

given by the following (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 28 and 2007: 198)11:

(4.23) ( ) ( ) ( )| 1ˆ ˆHBt t t tgap z s z s z+= −

Following Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 197), the expected unit loss for bulls and bears,

respectively, is represented by:

(4.24) ,

, | 1 1

,, | 1 1

ˆ: 0 | 0

ˆ: 0 | 0

l L i ii t t t t t

l S i ii t t t t t

Bull r E R z

Bear r E R z

+ +

+ +

⎡ ⎤= < <⎣ ⎦⎡ ⎤= − < <⎣ ⎦

Here, zti includes both causal values used when forming forecasts of the unit loss by the agent as

well as current and past values of the exchange rate.

When combining the gap effect, equation (4.23), and the expected unit loss, equation (4.24), the

representation of an individuals’ forecast of potential unit loss will be:

(4.25) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ), | 1 , | 1 , | 1 , | 1ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆl l i l l ii t t t i t t t t i t t t i t t t tr z r gap z r z r gap z+ + + +

⎡ ⎤= + −⎣ ⎦

11 Note that this is seen from the perspective of a domestic investor. Hence, an increase in st, ie. a depreciation of the

domestic currency, is a strengthening of the foreign currency – when having a long (short) position, a higher st

implies a gain (loss). See reference 6 as well.

Page 67: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

66

Furthermore the gap effect will be qualitatively restricted by the following condition, which

depends on whether the agent is either a bull (L) or a bear (S) (Frydman and Goldberg, 2004: 26):

(4.26) , ,

, | 1 , | 1, ,

ˆ ˆ0, 0

l L l Si t t i t t

i L i St t

r rgap gap

+ +∂ ∂< >

∂ ∂

From equation (4.26) an increase in the gap – given by equation (4.23) – will have different

effects on the concern of a capital loss on the part of the bulls and the bears. That is, if the gap

increases (i.e. the currency is overvalued compared with PPP and is expected to move further

away from this benchmark value in the next period), the expected unit loss of a bull (bear)

increases (decreases)12. The bull, for example, expects that an overvalued currency continues its

movement away from the benchmark value, and therefore expects a higher return from a long

position in foreign exchange. But the increase in the gap effect from equation (4.23), on the other

hand, increases the concern of a movement back towards the benchmark value and a loss on the

position (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 200). This is further elaborated on in the example below.

Frydman and Goldberg (2004: 37) find that the gap effect and the uncertainty premium are

positively correlated. Empirical testing of the US dollar thus shows that the gap effect is highly

significant and positively related to the expected excess return on foreign exchange, in line with

the IKE assumption.

An example of exchange rate overvaluation In the following example it is assumed that the currency is overvalued compared with the

fundamental value (i.e. ( ) ( )| 1ˆ ˆHBt t ts z s z+ > ). For both the bulls and the bears it is uncertain

whether the (overvalued) exchange rate will continue its movement away from the fundamental

value or revert back to parity. On the one hand the bull assumes that the exchange rate will

continue its movement, and thus expects a greater return on a long position in the foreign

exchange market. But on the other hand the gap effect, equation (4.26), leads to an increased

concern of a loss for the bull – since the exchange rate could (suddenly) move back towards the

fundamental value (given by the benchmark) and the bull would incur a loss from the long

position. Hence, the bull’s expected unit loss increases as they become less confident that the

exchange rate will continue to be overvalued in the future (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 199ff.).

Furthermore, the insight from prospect theory (loss aversion as well as the fact that the degree of

loss aversion increases with the position) adds to the insecurity of the bulls. The increase in the

unit loss then feeds directly into the premium, equation (4.14), necessary for holding a long

12 Note that an increase in the unit loss is defined as a more negative value, whereas a decrease is a less negative value

Page 68: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

67

position. The bears, on the other hand, expect a lower return on a short position. But the

increased gap leads to a smaller expected value of unit loss.

If the expected exchange rate thus moves further away from the PPP (the benchmark value), the

buyers (i.e. the bulls) raise their evaluation estimation of the losses, whereas the sellers (i.e. the

bears) lower their estimated losses. Then the uncertainty premium in equation (4.20) rises to

compensate the buyers for buying the foreign exchange. The exchange rate (st), therefore, does

not move one-for-one in the direction of the expected exchange rate | 1t ts + (Frydman and

Goldberg, 2001: 22). This happens because the buyers are unwilling to bid up the value of the

exchange rate, as their sensitivity to losses increases more than the expected return (due to loss

aversion), which then affects the risk premium. Furthermore, a continued movement away from

the benchmark value drives up the equilibrium uncertainty premium. The movement away from

PPP is thus self-limiting, as increases in the gap add to the risk assessment of the bulls, and hence

increases the risk premium. Eventually, this results in a revision of forecasting strategy which

drives the exchange rate back towards (and then away from) the fundamental value (i.e. the

benchmark). That is, the bulls’ concern of a capital loss grows so large that they no longer desire

to take on long positions (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 281). This explains the movements in

the exchange rate vis-à-vis the PPP value in figures 7 and 8 in chapter 3.

4.3.7 Modelling forecasting strategies II: Conservative revisions

A second qualitative description of the agents in the foreign exchange market is conservatism of

forecast revisions. As pointed out by Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 194): “Individuals can be slow to

change their beliefs in the face of new evidence”, which is supported by different psychological

experiments (e.g. Edwards, 1968). The definition of a conservative revision is a revision that is

“not too different” from the forecast before the change of strategy. As discussed in Frydman and

Goldberg (2007: 195) “not too different” depends on, among other, whether goods prices are

fully flexible or adjust slowly to their equilibrium value.

A way to set up the conservative restriction in the forecast of the individual is as follows (ibid.:

195):

(4.27) ,| 1 1

1 1

ˆ ˆˆ

ˆ ˆ

i IKE i i i it t t t t t

i i i i it t t t t

ds dX d X

d X E X X

β β

β β

+ −

− −

= + ⇒

⎡ ⎤< Δ⎣ ⎦

That is, the change in the individuals forecast revision at time t is less than the conditional

expectation of the change in the causal variables (in absolute terms). As pointed out by Frydman

and Goldberg (ibid.: 196), this does not necessarily imply that the change in the agents forecasts

are “small”, as this depends on the magnitude of the change in the causal variables. Furthermore,

Page 69: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

68

the restriction that δ < 1 in equation (4.15) implies that changes in the exchange rate also lead to

a “conservative” revision, as the change in the forecast does not follow a change in the nominal

exchange rate one-for-one.

Furthermore, as briefly discussed in section 4.3.5, agents do not necessarily stick to their

respective strategy (in this case being either a bull or a bear, but it could also be whether to stick

to fundamental analysis or technical trading). As noted by Slovic (1973: 2): “It is hard to follow a

predetermined policy when your financial condition is riding the crest of good fortune or plummeting with a bear

market”. This is also assumed by Goldberg and Frydman (2007) – see for example equation (4.17)

above. Hence, the strategies of the agents may not be stable when environment changes; this is

also discussed in section 4.1 and section 4.3.4 above. This is in line with the discussion from

chapter 2 and 3 where the importance of different macroeconomic fundamentals seems to shift

over time (e.g. Cheung and Chinn, 2001). And for some periods of time, fundamentals appear

unimportant altogether and focus lies on, for example, technical trading (Frankel and Froot,

1986). Looking at the IKE forecast of the future exchange rate, equation (4.15), changes in the

causable variable (given by Xt) have an impact on the forecast of the future exchange rate. This

can have a direct effect on the loss aversion, equation (4.10), or an indirect effect via the gap in

equation (4.23). These changes will then alter the relative weight of the bulls and bears, as seen in

equation (4.17). The distribution of the two types of speculators does not, therefore, remain static

as time progresses. This follows for example Corrado et al (2007) who concludes that trading

rules generate (repeated) switches between bulls and bears. This switching process further

generates a significant misalignment of the exchange rate according to Corrado et al (2007: 264).

An alternative approach of agents switching types includes De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2006), with

chartists and fundamentalists being the two types of agents instead of bulls and bears.

4.3.8 Summing up

The main insights of the IKE theory from section 4.3 are the following:

• The agents are loss averse. That is, the disutility of a loss exceeds the utility of a gain of the same size.

• The utility of a loss/gain is dependent on a reference level. This reference level can be defined as the wealth

from refraining from speculating

• Fear of losses increase with the position size

• The agents forecast of future exchange rate movements are based on both causal factors (which (can)

include macroeconomic models, insight from the microstructure approach, technical trading as well as

individual experience) and the current level of the exchange rate

Page 70: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

69

• Fundamentals matter for exchange rate determination. But the (relative) importance of different

macroeconomic variables can change over time

• The agents’ expectations are heterogeneous; in this context represented by bulls and bears. The weight of

either type can shift over time

• UAIP: The equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is the equality between the aggregate uncertainty

adjusted expected returns on foreign and domestic bonds

• The gap, i.e. the difference between the expected value of the exchange rate and the historical benchmark,

has an effect on the degree of loss aversion. The effect furthermore differs between bulls and bears

• The agents are conservative when revising their forecasts

The main conclusions pointed out above seem supported by the findings of chapter 2 and 3

above: Agents are heterogeneous (cf. Cheung and Chinn, 2001; Cheung et al, 2004) and hence

use different models when forecasting (including technical trading, experience etc.; private

information matters as well (cf. the microstructure approach). Fundamentals do matter, but the

relative importance changes over time (Cheung and Chinn, 2001), which was also evident from

figure 10 of the relative money supply. Other variables, such as order flow (discussed in chapter

3), matter as well. These results are magnified by the decentralised foreign exchange market and

the low level of transparency (discussed in chapter 2). Hence, both the agents as well as the

structure of the market play an important role for exchange rate determination in the IKE theory.

The IKE theory furthermore elaborates on the preferences of the agents by adding loss aversion

and conservative revisions. Finally, the agents have imperfect knowledge of the economy (i.e.

they do not know the correct model for exchange rate determination) as well as a degree of

uncertainty regarding future events.

In the following section the conclusions from above will be implemented in a IKE version of a

monetary model of the exchange rate. This leads to a discussion of the IKE theory as a possible

solution to the disconnect puzzle.

4.4 IKE and the exchange rate: A monetary model The anomalous behaviour of exchange rates, discussed in chapter 3, has forced economists to

introduce either rational bubbles or non-rational behaviour into exchange rate modelling. That is,

the conventional flexible price monetary model has to rely on large real shocks to explain the

swings away from the fundamental value (i.e., given by PPP) or the existence of the

aforementioned bubbles. The sticky price exchange rate model (i.e. the overshooting model), on

the other hand, can explain only one-time deviations (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 258).

Page 71: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

70

Frydman and Goldberg therefore argue for introducing imperfect knowledge into the models to

account for the anomalies: “We find that as long as agents possess at least some degree of imperfect knowledge,

the monetary models of the exchange rate generate dynamics that are consistent with the anomalous behaviour

observed in the literature” (Frydman and Goldberg, 1996: 870). The solution of Frydman and

Goldberg (1996, 2007) to the exchange rate puzzles is not, therefore, to abandon the monetary

models of the exchange rates altogether, nor introducing irrational agents, but instead to try to

implement imperfect knowledge in the models.

4.4.1 A monetary model with IKE-expectations

In the following I present an exchange rate model13 building on a regular monetary model in the

vein of Dornbusch (1976) or Frenkel (1976) as presented in chapter 3. But with the insights from

the IKE theory discussed in the previous sections. The model consists of a two countries,

domestic and foreign, and three markets: a money market, a goods market and a foreign

exchange market. In the foreign exchange market, the usual assumption of UIP is changed with

the UAUIP, discussed in section 4.3.5 above.

In the following, the exchange rate, the interest rate and the price level are assumed to be

endogenous – the rest of the variables are determined exogenously.

4.4.2 Money markets

Equilibrium in the money markets is based on the same two equations as in section 3.3.1. This

leads to the following equilibrium for the money markets, here in terms of relative (i.e. domestic

minus foreign) magnitudes:

(4.28) t t t tm p y iφ λ= + −

As in section 3.1, m, p and y denote the log-levels of the (relative) money supply, output and

nominal interest rate, respectively. It is, as in traditional monetary models, assumed that supply

and demand for money is in equilibrium.

Rearranging such that the endogenous variables (here pt and it) are kept on the left hand side

yields:

(4.29) t t t tp i m yλ φ− = −

13 The following exchange rate model is primarily based on chapter 14, ”Imperfect knowledge and long swings in the

exchange rate”, in Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 258-291)

Page 72: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

71

4.4.3 Goods markets

In the following it is assumed that domestic and foreign goods and assets are imperfect

substitutes, and hence (excess) demand for goods depends on international prices

competitiveness (given by the real exchange rate), as well as on the interest rate and income levels

(cf. Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 261). Excess demand for domestic goods (relative to foreign

goods) is given by the following equation:

(4.30) ( ) ( )ˆpppt t t tEDG s p q iα η π= − − − −

Here, st is the log of the nominal exchange rate, qppp is the historical benchmark real exchange

rate (given by PPP), and π is the aggregation of agents expectations of relative levels of inflation

prevailing if the goods market cleared. Both qppp and π is assumed to be exogenous and constant.

Furthermore, α and η are the sensitivity of excess demand to movements in the exchange rate

and the interest rate, respectively (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 262).

The movement of goods prices is assumed to depend on both the underlying rate of inflation as

well as excess demand, which allows for a sluggish adjustment of the goods prices.

(4.31) ( ) ( ) ( )1 1ˆpppt t t t t t tp p s p q i p pδ α η π+ +

⎡ ⎤− = − − − − + −⎣ ⎦

The 1tp + is the value associated with goods-market clearing. As discussed in Frydman and

Goldberg (2007: 262-63), the assumption of flexible prices implies PPP if either of the two

following conditions hold: i) that domestic and foreign bonds are perfect substitutes (i.e. η =0) or

ii) that the real rates of interest across countries are assumed equal (i.e. ˆti π= ). If one of these

two conditions hold, and given flexible prices (i.e. ( )1 1t t t tp p p p+ +− = − ), PPP holds:

( ) 0pppt ts p q− − = .

In equilibrium (i.e. excess demand equals zero) the following holds:

(4.32) ( ) ( )ˆpppt t ts p q iη π

α− − = −

Rearranging such that the endogenous variables (pt, st and it) are on the left hand side yields:

(4.33) ˆ pppt t tp i s qη η π

α α+ − = −

4.4.4 Foreign exchange market

In the following, the UAUIP condition and the other assumptions from sections 4.3.4 and 4.3.5

is used. Equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is given by:

(4.34) ( )| 1ˆ ˆ,t t t t t t ts s x s i u+ − − =

Page 73: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

72

Where | 1t ts + is the aggregate of the bulls’ and bears’ forecast of st+1 at time t, given the information

available. This information set is given by xt, which represents both current as well as past

realizations of factors that the agents utilize when making their forecasts (Frydman and

Goldberg, 2007: 263). Here, ˆtu is the uncertainty premium and is the aggregate uncertainty

premium at time t. The premium is discussed in section 4.3.4 above. This premium depends, as

seen in equation (4.35) below, on the degree of loss aversion, λ1, of both the bulls and the bears.

(4.35) ( ) ( )1 | 1ˆˆ 1 ,t t t t tu l s xλ += −

It is once again, see equation (4.15) above, assumed that the point forecast | 1t ts + depend linearly

on both st (the level of the exchange rate – the endogenous part) and xt, (causal variables, e.g.

macroeconomic variables and preferences – the autonomous part).

(4.36) | 1ˆ ˆt t t ts x sβ ρ+ = +

In this context it is, for simplicity, assumed that neither ρ nor β vary over time, in contrast with

equation (4.15) above. It is interpreted as if | 1t ts + is a weighted average of the parameters used by

the bulls and bears to forecast the nominal exchange rate. Normally, though, the IKE theory

assumes that the ˆtβ parameter could change (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 266). In such a case,

the change in tβ would stem from a change in the forecasting strategy for Rt+1, which lead to a

change in the forecasted mean of st+1 (ibid.: 264). Changes in the aggregate forecast, | 1t ts + , will

thus take place either because of i) new realizations of the causal variables (xt) (e.g. positive GDP

data for a given country) and/or ii) new realisations of the spot exchange rate (st) or because of

iii) changes in the autonomous part ( t txβ ) – for example a structural change in the variables in xt

(e.g. agents substituting the interest rate differential with the current account deficit when

forecasting).

The aggregate expected loss – i.e. the bulls’ minus the bears’ expected loss – is building on the

gap restrictions, as discussed in section 4.3.6. The aggregate gap is given by:

(4.37) | 1ˆ ˆHBt t t tgap s s+= −

It is assumed that the revisions of the expected return, Rt+1, is consistent with the gap restrictions,

discussed in section 4.3.6. This motivates the following specification of the uncertainty premium

(Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 264):

(4.38) ( )| 1ˆ ˆ ˆHBt t t tu s sσ += −

Page 74: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

73

Where σ is assumed to be strictly larger than zero, but smaller than one, and sHB represents the

bulls’ and bears’ aggregate historical benchmark level of the exchange rate. That is, an increase in

the gap, equation (4.37), increases the uncertainty premium through equation (4.38). This feeds

into the forecast of the expected exchange rate, given by equation (4.34) above, and thus the

expected return.

The agents’ assessments of the historical benchmark level of the exchange rate are collectively

represented by PPP:

(4.39) ˆ ˆHB PPPt ts q p= +

Solving for the difference between the weighted forecast and the exchange rate, ( )| 1t t ts s+ − using

equations (4.34), (4.38) and (4.39) yields the following:

(4.40) ( ) ( )| 1 | 1ˆ ˆ ˆPPPt t t t t t ts s i s p qσ+ +− = + − −

Now | 1t ts + in equation (4.40) is substituted by ˆt tx sδ+ , using equation (4.36) above. Remember

that β is invariant here (for simplicity), and is therefore unimportant for the result. Rearranging

yields:

(4.41) ( ) ( )ˆ ˆ ˆPPPt t t t t t tx s s i x s p qρ σ ρ+ − = + + − −

Again, rearranging equation (4.41) such that the endogenous variables (pt, st and it) are on the left

hand side yields:

(4.42) ( ) ( )ˆˆ1 , 1 1PPPt t t ti p hs x q hσ σ σ ρ σ− + = − + = − −

Using equation (4.28) and assuming that ˆti π= , the rational expectations steady state solution for

the spot exchange rate, *s , is given by the following:

(4.43) * * PPPt ts m y qφ λπ= − + +

This equation is used later on for the solution to the model.

4.4.5 The social context

As argued by Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 266) the institutional changes in the economy are

relatively infrequent when compared to the frequency of forecast revisions in the foreign

exchange market. Hence it is assumed that the parameters in both the goods and money market

demands, equation (4.31) and (4.28) respectively, are constant. Furthermore, the causal variables

(m, y and the different variables in x) are assumed to move as random walks with drift:

Page 75: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

74

(4.44) 1

1

t t t t

t t t t

M mY g y v

μ ε−

= + += + +

With ε and v being white noise terms, μ and g drift terms. The t subscript on the drift terms

represents that the processes driving the system could change, and hence allow for shifts in the

drift components.

4.4.6 The solution to the model

The system of the money market, equation (4.29), the goods market, equation (4.33), and the

foreign exchange market, equation (4.42), can be written in matrix form as follows:

(4.45) ( )

1 0 0 0 01 01 1 0 0 0 1 0 ˆ

0 0 1 0 01

ˆ

t

tt

tt

t ppp

PPP

my

px

ish q

q

λ φη η

α πασ σσ

⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟

−⎛ ⎞ ⎜ ⎟⎛ ⎞−⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟− = ⎜ − ⎟⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ −⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠ ⎜ ⎟− ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

The model consisting of equations (4.28) to (4.45) then implies the following steady state for the

exchange rate:

(4.46) ( ) ( )( )1 1ˆ ˆ ˆPPP PPPs m y x q qG G G G G

σ η αλα ση λασ α λασ α η αλϕ η π σα

− ++ − − += − + + − +

The calculations for the model can be found in Appendix B. As in the monetary approach, the

exchange rate is determined by macroeconomic fundamentals, here output and money supply, as

well as the causal variables, xt, included in the agents’ forecast. Furthermore, the expected

inflation rate and the PPP levels have an impact on the exchange rate as well. Using equation

(4.43) for the REH solution and rearranging yields:

(4.47)

( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( )

*1

1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ

ˆ0, 1 1 0

a REa REt tt t

RE PPP PPP

s s x sG G

q qG G

G h h h

η αλ σ η λσπ π

η λα σ η λα σπ

α η αλ σ ρ σ

+

+ − −= + − + −

+ +− + −

≡ + + − > ≡ − − >

Here, the RE superscript denotes the rational expectations solution. The solution for the real

exchange rate is given by equation (4.48):

Page 76: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

75

(4.48) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

( )

1

1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ

PPP a REa REt tt t

RE PPP PPP

hq q x s

G G

q qG

η σ η λπ π

ησ π ησ

+

− += + − − −

+ + −

Note that PPP PPPt ts p q= + and t t ts p q− = which implies that PPP PPP

t t ts s q q− = − . This is the

nominal exchange rate level relative to the PPP level (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 269). Using

this on equation (4.48), taking first differences to the equation and rearranging yields equation

(4.49) below. Note that the real exchange rate as well as the inflation rate are assumed to be

exogenous and do not change. Furthermore, for simplicity, I consider the case of flexible good

prices, i.e. q q= (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 269). This leaves us with:

(4.49) ( ) ( ) ( )1

1ˆ ˆPPP a REa

t t tt ts s x sG

η σ+

−Δ − = Δ −Δ

This is one of the key equations of the model, and describes how the difference between the IKE

forecast and the REH forecast results in divergence between the exchange rate and the PPP level.

As can be seen, a change in the causal variable, 1ˆat tx + , will push the nominal exchange rate

away/towards the PPP rate given by PPPts all else equal. In the words of Frydman and Goldberg

(2007: 269): “persistent trends in the causal variables will lead market participants to push the exchange rate

persistently toward or away from PPP”. Furthermore, if the policy environment includes deterministic

trends in m, y and the variables in xt, a persistent swing in the exchange rate away from (or

towards) the PPP level will arise in the model.

Note that if domestic and foreign assets are perfect substitutes (i.e. η =0), the nominal spot

exchange rate does not differ from the fundamental value. The effect from an increase in η on

the exchange rate is ambiguous as the sensitivity parameter affects both the nominator and the

denominator (through G). But overall, increases in the η parameter is assumed to amplify the

movement away from the fundamental value. Furthermore the σ parameter puts a bound on the

movement away from parity. A “high” σ value (i.e. close to unity) implies that the gap effect

weighs heavy on the agents, through equation (4.38), and thus increases the premium required by

the agents for holding a long position. This, in turn, pulls the exchange rate back towards the

fundamental value rather quickly as agents change their expected losses rather fast and hence

their forecasts. A “low” σ value (i.e. close to zero), on the other hand, indicates that the gap

effect has low influence on the uncertainty premium and hence does not act as a (strong)

boundary for movements in the nominal exchange rate away from the benchmark value.

Page 77: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

76

As the change in the agents expectations differ from the rational expectations result, by

definition, this leads to the disconnect between the change in the expected exchange rate and the

rational expectations outcome:

(4.50) ( ) 1 1 11ˆ ˆ , , 0a REat t t tt tE x s x y m− − −+

⎡ ⎤Δ − Δ ≠⎣ ⎦

Using equation (4.50) on equation (4.49) implies that persistent swings will arise in the model; i.e.

the nominal spot exchange rate will diverge from the fundamental exchange rate for long periods

of time. The influence from the gap effect, discussed in section 4.3.6, secures that the exchange

rate is bounded and does not diverge from the fundamental value indefinitely.

The result of the model is discussed further in the next two sections.

4.4.7 The intuition of the result

The agents in the market will, as seen from equation (4.49) above and given deterministic

trends14, persistently push the exchange rate either towards or away from the PPP level. As

concluded in Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 269): “…as long as the representation of forecasting

behaviour presumes imperfect knowledge, and this representation and the policy environment remain unchanged, the

monetary model with flexible goods prices implies a persistent movement of the exchange rate away from PPP”.

Hence, even if the participants’ base their forecast solely on macroeconomic fundamentals, the

imperfect knowledge (implying that the weights in | 1

ˆt t

s+

is different from the weights of | 1

ˆt t

REs+

, cf.

Frydman and Goldberg, 2007: 270) on part of the agents creates the persistent movements. The

intuition of the result is that with imperfect knowledge– i.e. the aggregated expected value of

change in the exchange rate is strictly different from the rational expectation hypothesis expected

value – the aggregate of the point estimates does not equal the PPP exchange rate (as this is given

by the REH). This implies that the exchange rate will be driven either away from or towards the

PPP rate. In the latter instance the exchange rate will, when reaching the fundamental value,

continue its movement away from the PPP value. Furthermore, the long swings occur even if

goods prices are assumed to be fully flexible, as in the model above.

From a theoretical view, this explains the large swings in the exchange rate relative to PPP

discussed in chapter 3.

14 As noted by Frydman and Goldberg (2007:269, note 16) stochastic trends in the variables x, y and m will still lead

to persistent deviations from the PPP value, but on average the divergence will not grow or sink

Page 78: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

77

4.5 IKE and the exchange rate disconnect puzzle As the model set up in section 4.4 shows, adding imperfect knowledge on part of the agents put

forth another possible solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

First of all, as the agents have heterogeneous expectations – and thus use different models and

methods when forecasting the exchange rate – the outcome has to, by definition, be different

from the rational expectations outcome. But this does not imply that the exchange rate moves

about randomly, entirely disconnected from the fundamentals. Since the benchmark value, given

by PPP, is available to all agents in the economy, an increase in the difference between the

nominal exchange rate and the PPP value (e.g. an overvaluation), raises the concern of the bulls’

(in this case) estimation of a possible return to parity and a subsequent capital loss. The agents in

the market therefore take the historical long swings into account when forming their forecast. As

the last thirty years have shown, evident by the charts in chapter 3, the nominal exchange rate can

diverge significantly from PPP for several years. Accordingly, it is rational for the bulls in the

foreign exchange market to utilize this knowledge and (initially) stay long when the exchange rate

moves above its benchmark value. As pointed out by Frydman and Goldberg (2007: 281): “[The

IKE monetary model]… assumes that market participants are aware of the long-swings nature of exchange rate

movements and take this behaviour into account when forming their forecast of the return and potential unit loss

from holding speculative positions in the market”. Frydman and Goldberg (2007b: 6) further exemplifies

this by the falling dollar in the late 2007: “A market participant may well decide that, because the

USD/EUR exchange rate is, say, 30 percent overvalued relative to PPP, as it currently is, she wants to be a net

seller of euros. However, in a world of imperfect knowledge, the gap between the actual and PPP exchange rates is

merely one of many fundamental factors that market participants might reasonably rely on in forming their

forecasts.” This secures that the exchange rate swings can be sustained for longer periods of time,

but also that these swings are bounded by the fundamental value via the gap effect. For the dollar

overvaluation in the 1980s, for example, sticking to a strict fundamental strategy when deciding

whether to invest in the dollar would have lead to an inferior result compared to a simple

technical trading rule. Hence, as a result thereof, the weighting of agents shifted towards more

use of technical trading in the mid 1980s (cf. Frankel and Froot, 1990).

According to the IKE theory the swing away from the benchmark value occurs because of i)

trends in the causal values and/or ii) revisions of forecast strategies (Frydman and Goldberg,

2007: 279). Regarding the former, a trend of positive macroeconomic data support a stronger

currency. Regarding the latter, the conservative behaviour of the agents further reinforces the

protracted movement away from PPP. Only when a certain threshold is breached, the forecasting

strategies are changed and the exchange rate (slowly) reverts to parity. Hence the important

Page 79: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

78

aspect here is not the conditional variance of returns of having a long position in exchange rates,

but instead the current gap between the nominal exchange rate and the benchmark value. As

concluded by Frydman and Goldberg (ibid.: 279), the fundamental PPP value acts as an anchor

for the nominal exchange rate and its movement. If the currency is “too overvalued”, increased

concern of capital loss induces a change in the forecast and thus a reversion of the exchange rate.

As already mentioned, abandoning PPP and other macroeconomic fundamentals when looking at

exchange rate determination is not what the IKE theory suggests. Instead, the macroeconomic

approach is part of the forecasting method used by the agents, and thus an important part of

understanding exchange rate behaviour. But the agents acknowledge that they have imperfect

knowledge and act accordingly; the nominal exchange rate as a result appear disconnected from

the fundamental value for longer periods of time.

On the theoretical level, the IKE theory seems to have a plausible solution for the exchange rate

disconnect puzzle. The question, then, is whether this is verified empirically as well. This is the

subject for next chapter. But first a critical discussion of the IKE theory.

4.6 Critique of Imperfect Knowledge Economics As mentioned in the introduction to this chapter, a central point in opposition to the IKE theory

is that in a world of imperfect knowledge (which implies indeterminacy) certain aspects cannot be

quantified (cf. Papell, 2003: 2). Thus IKE does not, per se, produce restrictions that can be tested

(and falsified) against the rational expectations hypothesis.

The IKE framework, on the theoretical part, synthesizes a theory of expectations consistent with

individual rationality, a part of rational expectations theory which has been criticised from many

sides (e.g. De Grauwe and Grimaldi, 2003: 1). But testing the hypotheses of the IKE theory

seem, at first, problematic. As noted by Papell (2003: 3): “With IKE, the scope of imperfect knowledge is

unlimited and nested tests cannot be constructed to compare IKE with either theories consistent expectations or RE.

In the absence of such tests, the concept of IKE is not empirically falsifiable”. Goldberg and Frydman

(2007:7) disagree: “IKE restricts its models sufficiently to enable an economist to distinguish empirically among

alternative explanations of economic phenomena”. Nonetheless, the IKE theory (as put forth in

Goldberg and Frydman, 2007) puts weight on a “realistic” description of the world, opposite to

the more instrumentalist view of, for example, Milton Friedman (1953: 15): “The relevant question to

ask about the assumptions of a theory is not whether they are descriptively realistic, for they never are, but whether

they are sufficiently good approximations for the purpose in hand. And this question can be answered only by

seeing whether the theory works… which means whether it yields sufficiently accurate predictions” And as argued

by Isard (1995: 182): “This situation [that few believe the behaviour of flexible exchange rates can

Page 80: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

79

be accurately described by a model based on fully rational agents], however, does not imply that

economists should abandon efforts to model how flexible exchange rates would behave in a world of fully rational

and completely informed market participants”. Haavelmo (1944: 31), on the other hand, concludes that:

“To find such a basic system of highly autonomous relations in an actual case is not an analytical process, it is a

task of making fruitful hypothesis as to how reality actually is”. The question, then, is whether to put

weight on the “realistic part” or the “empirical/testable part” – the first being the realism view,

the latter being the instrumental view. The focus of the IKE theory, as mentioned, apparently

puts most weight to the first with emphasis on the qualitative description of the foreign exchange

market. It thus opens up for the aforementioned criticism of proponents of the instrumental

view.

The arguments of Frydman and Goldberg lie end to end with the thoughts of Hayek, as seen

from the introduction to this chapter, who in his Nobel laureate speech concluded (1974: 1):

“Unlike the position that exists in the physical sciences, in economics and other disciplines that deal with essentially

complex phenomena, the aspects of the events to be accounted for, about which we can get quantitative data, are

necessarily limited and may not include the important ones… in the study of such complex phenomena as the

market, which depend on the actions of many individuals, all the circumstances which will determine the outcome of

a process … will hardly ever be fully known or measurable”. This is further supported by Richardson

(1953: 156): “Instead of building models which, while complying with our rigorous canons of verifiability in

principle, fail lamently to pattern the real world, it would be better … to construct theories/models which do

satisfactorily explain the working of our economy”. All that aside, a necessary condition for a theory to

obtain validity is to be empirically testable and hence also falsifiable. A difficult task for theories

based on imperfect knowledge and uncertainty, such as IKE. But, as I will show in chapter 5, it is

possible to test the results and conclusions of the IKE theory by using models with IKE

“features” – in this case uncertainty.

Overall the problem of models with uncertainty, including the IKE theory, is the difficulty of

testing them. But that does not necessarily mean that we should abandon them altogether, as

these models can provide substantial knowledge in regards to exchange rate behaviour.

4.7 Conclusion The main point of the IKE theory is to put imperfect knowledge at the centre of the analysis.

That is, the agents in the economy do not have perfect information of neither the market they

speculate in (in this case the foreign exchange market), nor the different future possible states –

cf. “Knightian uncertainty”. Therefore the agents make use of different “rule of thumbs”

(heuristics) when deciding their actions; i.e. they utilize different models and stick (at least for

Page 81: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

80

some time) to the “best” strategy. This strategy can be a portfolio of models and methods; for

example combining the result of the monetary approach with technical analysis or data on order

flow (if available, that is). Thus, the agents do not behave irrationally, but instead realize that they

cannot fully comprehend the entire economic system - or that it is too costly to obtain the

information, as argued by for example Grossman and Stiglitz (1980). Hence, the aggregate of the

agent’s forecasts differ from the rational expectations result. And this difference will lead to the

persistent movement away from or towards the fundamental value given by PPP. This explains

the first part of the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

The utility function of the agents in the IKE theory is based on the insights from prospect

theory, which assumes that “losses loom larger than corresponding gains” (Frydman and Goldberg, 2007:

161). That is, the value function is steeper for losses than for (comparable) gains. Furthermore,

the utility of either gains or losses depends on a reference level, in our case given by the income

from staying out of the foreign exchange market. The agents are assumed to be heterogeneous,

which is in line with the conclusion of for example Cheung and Chinn (2001). In the text the

agents are assumed to be either bulls or bears, but they could also be “fundamentalists” and

“chartists”, as in Frankel and Froot (1986) or Vigfusson (1997). Equilibrium in the foreign

exchange market is then given by the equality of the bulls’ and bears’ aggregate expected returns

of investing in either foreign or domestic bonds. But in contrast to traditional analysis, the

expected return is adjusted for a greater sensitivity over losses than gains, following the

aforementioned finding from prospect theory. The equilibrium uncertainty premium is thus the

uncertainty premium of the bulls in excess of the bears (Frydman and Goldberg, 2003: 9). The

sensitivity to losses furthermore restrains the movement of the exchange not to follow the

expected exchange one-for-one. This is further magnified by the agent’s conservative revisions of

their forecasts as well as the gap effect. The gap effect is a central aspect, as this makes the

fundamental value (given by PPP) an anchor around which the exchange rate fluctuates. A large

“gap” – i.e. the absolute value of the expected exchange rate minus the benchmark value is large

– increases the loss aversion of the agents (either the bulls or the bears, depending on if it is a

over- or undervaluation) and hence the uncertainty premium, which tends to drive down the

exchange rate. This explains the movement of the exchange rate in the figures in chapter 3: The

exchange rate does move away from the fundamental value, but seem somewhat bounded to the

PPP benchmark – there seems to be an outer threshold15 which the nominal exchange rate does

not cross. Furthermore, a movement “too far” away from the benchmark value eventually leads

the exchange rate to revert back to the fundamental value as the agents change their expected 15 This treshold is normally assumed to be around ±20% of PPP, visible in the charts in chapter 3

Page 82: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

81

gains/losses and forecasts. This is the second part of the theoretical explanation of the exchange

rate disconnect puzzle.

On the qualitative aspect the IKE theory seem to have a rather strong case, which is supported

by different papers (e.g. Kahnemann and Tversky (1992), Cheung and Chinn (2001)). But on the

quantitative side, the IKE theory seems to have some complications. Testing the conclusion of

the IKE theory in itself is a difficult task, given the assumption of both imperfect knowledge and

uncertainty. Furthermore the agents differ and the models the (heterogeneous) agents utilize

differ in ways not specified beforehand. Hence, testing the IKE model against the rational

expectations version is no easy task as Papell (2003) points out.

In the empirical chapter I have chosen to follow the idea of Cumperayotm (2005), who adds

uncertainty to traditional monetary models. The assumptions of this method – uncertainty is an

important aspect that help to describe exchange rate determination alongside macroeconomic

fundamentals – is in line with the IKE theory presented in this chapter.

Page 83: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

82

Chapter 5

Empirical test “Despite extensive efforts to capture and quantify what we perceive as the key macroeconomic

relationships, our knowledge about many of the important linkages is far from complete and, in

all likelihood, will always remain so. Every model, no matter how detailed or how well designed,

conceptually and empirically, is a vastly simplified representation of the world that we experience

with all its intricacies on a day-to-day basis… Moreover, we recognize that the simple linear

functions underlying most of our econometric structures may not hold outside the range in

which adequate economic observations exist”

Alan Greenspan (2004), pp. 5-6

5.1 Introducing the empirical part In this chapter I test a central part of the imperfect knowledge economics theory: The

importance of uncertainty with respect to determination of exchange rates.

The critique of IKE in the previous chapter showed that it can be a rather difficult task to test

the IKE model. First of all, the theory is based on imperfect knowledge of the “true model” of

exchange rate behaviour. Secondly, uncertainty of future states of the economy plays an

important part in the theory, further exacerbating the imperfect knowledge on part of the agents.

Thirdly, the agents in the model are assumed to be heterogeneous and utilise (a range of)

different models at different points in time when forecasting future exchange rate movement.

To circumvent these apparent problems, I have chosen to focus on one part of the theory only,

the aspect of uncertainty. In chapter 3 the microstructure approach showed that private

information plays a significant role in the determination of exchange rates. Combining the result

of the significance of private information with a test of the importance of uncertainty, two central

assumptions of the IKE theory is thus put to test.

The approach in this chapter is mainly based on the idea from the article of Phornchanok

Cumperayot (2003), “Dusting off the Perception of Risk and Returns in FOREX markets”.

Cumperayot (2003) shows that volatility of macroeconomic fundamentals – a proxy for

uncertainty – plays a central part in the determination of exchange rates for Canada, France, Italy,

Page 84: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

83

Japan, the UK and the USA. The volatility – i.e. uncertainty – of macroeconomic fundamentals is

proxied by estimation in a GARCH model, which is discussed below. Testing a simple monetary

model – similar to the monetary model presented in chapter 3 – with the addition of uncertainty

variables points to significant cointegration between the variables in both the short and long run

in Cumperayot (2003). As a side note, the approach of Cumperayot is based on the idea of

Hodrick (1989) who tried to incorporate risk into exchange rate models, but without a useful

result.

In this chapter I have chosen to test the USD/NOK and the USD/JPY currency crosses in two

models: The model of Cumperayot (2003), presented in the next section, as well as an augmented

model which includes interest rates. Furthermore, I test a simple monetary model in line with the

models presented in chapter 3.

The chapter is structured as follows: First the motivation as well as set-up of the model presented

in Cumperayot (2003). Then follows the empirical test, which can roughly be split into three

parts: First a brief discussion of cointegration analysis, followed by a discussion and estimation of

GARCH and finally the cointegration analysis of the models. The test is compromised of both a

test of the flexible price monetary model as well as the model including uncertainty. Following

this is a discussion of the result seen from the perspective of the IKE theory.

5.2 The model: Motivation and set-up The model of Cumperayot (2003) is partly based on the monetary approach discussed in chapter

3, augmented with a gauge of macroeconomic uncertainty given by the volatility of the

macroeconomic data. Regarding the uncertainty of macroeconomic fundamentals, and its

importance for exchange rate determination, Cumperayot (2003: 2) states: “The uncertainty in

macroeconomic fundamentals may influence the perception of risk in the markets, and subsequently through the

risk premium it may price returns on the exchange rate”. Thus, uncertainty is assumed to play a part

alongside the current level of fundamentals and the expectation of future exchange rates – two

factors which the literature normally focuses on in relation to exchange rates (ibid.: 2). An

argument in favour of the importance of fundamental uncertainty is that “fundamental variances may

represent economic circumstances, namely whether the economy is in volatile or tranquil periods, in which the

expectations may be different.” (ibid.: 19). That is, in “turmoil” the variables, such as output growth, is

more volatile, and this feed into the expectations and hence the exchange rate. Following the

theory of imperfect knowledge, periods of high volatility (e.g. a recession) further feeds into the

loss aversion, thereby raising the risk premium and altering the relative weight of bulls and bears.

The expected future fundamentals, which affect the future exchange rate, therefore not only

Page 85: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

84

depend on the current level but on the expected variance of these fundamentals as well. From

this line of argument, the long run solution of the flexible price monetary model with uncertainty

is given by (Cumperayot, 2003: 5)16:

(5.1) 0 1 2 3 , 1 4 , 1t t t m t y ts m y h hβ β β β β− −= + + + +

The exchange rate, st, is thus determined by the current fundamentals, mt and yt, as well as the

conditional variances of the fundamentals given by hi,t.

For the empirical test below, I have chosen to augment the model of Cumperayot (2003) with the

interest rate, it, as this macroeconomic variable seems to have a significant impact on the

determination of exchange rates. The augmented model is given by:

(5.2) 0 1 2 3 4 , 1 5 , 1 6 , 1t t t t m t y t i ts m y i h h hβ β β β β β β− − −= + + + + + +

The reason for including the interest rate in the model is three-fold: First of all, increases in the

uncertainty have direct effect on the interest rate as the agents’ shifts towards (or away from)

more secure income streams, e.g. treasury bills; shifts which then affect the exchange rate.

Secondly, because interest rate changes feed into the expected exchange rate (through the UIP or

UAIP in the IKE theory), as the expected income from investing in dollars, say, changes with

interest rate variations. Thirdly, the interest rates proxy the alternative cost of holding money.

As the empirical survey in chapter 3 showed, macroeconomic fundamentals alone have a hard

time explaining the movements of the exchange rate. By adding macroeconomic risk, here given

by the time-varying conditional variances, the model in equation (5.1) catches the (possible)

significance of uncertainty in exchange rate determination. The time-varying conditional

variances, hi,t, of the macroeconomic fundamentals are based on a GARCH(p,q) (Generalised

Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) model (see Bollerslev, 1987 or Tsay, 2002). The

GARCH(1,1) is given by the following equation:

(5.3) 20 1 1 1 1t t th u hα α β− −= + +

The ht variable is the conditional variance (often denoted by σ in the literature), ut-1 is the error

term, and ht-1 the lagged volatility (the GARCH part). Hence, the GARCH model assumes that

the conditional variance changes over time as a function of both the past errors, ut-1, and the past

conditional variance, ht-1. The GARCH(1,1) model therefore captures shifts in the uncertainty of

the fundamentals. Hence, a volatile (calm) ut-1 and/or ht-1 are expected to be followed by a volatile

(calm) ht (Cumperayot, 2003: note 14; Tsay, 2002: 94). This is also integrated in the IKE theory,

16 Note that I have chosen to use the lagged GARCH variables, since it is unreasonable to assume that increased

volatility affect the exchange rate immediately. The agents in the market, then, observe increased volatility of time t-1

at time t and react on this accordingly. But for the short run model Cumperayot uses the lagged GARCH variables.

Page 86: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

85

which assumes that the conservative behaviour of the agents prolongs the period of

disequilibrium. The concept of a persistent effect from the uncertainty of the fundamentals into

the exchange rate is thus included in the empirical model of equation (5.1) (via the conditional

variances of the macroeconomic fundamentals); i.e. a period of negative news (e.g. a falling GDP)

has negative effect on the exchange rate going forward, and vice versa. The empirical model

presented in this chapter thus assumes some inertia in the development of the exchange rate, in

line with the insight from the IKE theory. As pointed out by Frydman and Goldberg (2007b: 7):

“We find that the exchange rate will undergo a swing either toward or away from PPP in any period of time in

which individuals revise their forecasting strategies in conservative ways and trends in macroeconomic fundamentals

persist.” That is, negative (positive) news of macroeconomic data support a negative (positive)

trend in the exchange rate. Here it is assumed that increased volatility in both directions, i.e. both

falling or growing macrofundamentals, have an effect on the exchange rate.

In the next section, the cointegration method as well as the GARCH method will be discussed in

further detail.

5.3 The model: Specification and estimation

5.3.1 Introducing the empirical test

In this section, the empirical models of equation (5.1) and (5.2) above as well as the flexible price

monetary model will be tested. Before the actual testing commences, the data and the

econometric methods will be discussed.

5.3.2 The data

Two currency crosses are tested in this chapter, the USD/JPY and the USD/NOK. USA is in

both tests the foreign country, and the exchange rate thus measure domestic currency (i.e. JPY or

NOK) per unit of foreign currency (USD). For the money supply M2 is used and for the interest

rates I use 3 months treasury bills. As a proxy for GDP I use industrial production, since it is

difficult to obtain useful GDP numbers on a monthly basis. Furthermore, industrial production is

generally used as a GDP proxy, see for example McNown and Wallace (1994: 399) or

MacDonald and Taylor (1994: 280).

The data covers the period of 1978:2 until 2007:12 and is taken from the EcoWin database. The

estimation has been done in Ox Metrics and CATS 2.1 for RATS. All the data, except for the

interest rates, are in logs.

Page 87: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

86

5.3.3 A brief discussion of multivariate cointegration

The monetary model in equation (5.1) assumes a long-run relationship between the exchange rate

and the macroeconomic fundamentals (here output and money supply). As pointed out by for

example Hendry and Juselius (1999: 1), most economic time series (such as the aforementioned

macroeconomic fundamentals) are not stationary, an assumption of regular econometric analysis.

Conventional regression techniques are therefore rendered useless, or with some risks of bias, as

the assumption of stationarity of the variables is a crucial assumption for the ordinary least

squares (OLS) properties. The properties of the OLS estimator, and the standard deviations, are

no longer valid under the circumstance of non-stationarity, and the inference on the significance

of the variables breaks down. As pointed out by Verbeek (2004: 313-14) as well as Hendry and

Juselius (1999), regressions based on non-stationary variables will lead to meaningless findings

(i.e. spurious regression). One way to avoid this problem is by using cointegration analysis based

on the two-step procedure of Engle and Granger (1987). This rather simple method (discussed in

for example Verbeek, 2004: 314ff.) has several drawbacks, though, one of them being that the

method can, at most, find one cointegrating relationship. This is further discussed in Verbeek

(2004: 328-29). Instead I use the so-called Johansen cointegration procedure (Johansen: 1988;

1991) in this chapter. As the models tested in this chapter are based on more than two variables

using the multivariate Vector AutoRegressive (VAR) method, as suggested by Johansen, is a

useful method. The VAR model tries to find whether there exist cointegrating vectors of the

variables that are stationary. That is, given p I(1) variables (i.e. variables integrated of order 1),

then there may be p–1 linear relationships that are I(0), cf. Verbeek (2004: 324-25). Stationary

cointegrating vectors can then be interpreted as if there exists a long-run relationship between the

variables; i.e. that they share a common stochastic trend. The cointegrating relations, if any, can

then be interpreted as long-run steady states, towards which the process moves over time

(Hansen and Juselius, 2003: 4). Furthermore, using the multivariate VAR model does not

condition on the exchange rate being endogenous. It is, for example, reasonable that changes in

the exchange rate (e.g. caused by changes in the money supply or interest rates) have an effect on

the industrial production, and not exclusively the other way around.

The p-dimensional VAR model in k-lags is given by the following (Hansen and Juselius, 2003;

Hendry and Juselius, 2001):

(5.4) 1 1 1 0...t t k t k t tY AY A Y Dμ ψ ε− − += + + + + +

Where Yt is a px1 vector of stochastic variables and Dt a vector of non-stochastic dummies (either

seasonal or intervention) or weakly exogenous stochastic variables excluded from the

cointegration space. The importance of dummies will be discussed further in the specification of

Page 88: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

87

the models below, as including them can reduce problems with non-normality or autocorrelation.

The GARCH variables estimated below enters into the system as dummy variables, and are

therefore excluded from the cointegration space. The error terms, ε1,… εT, are niid.

Reformulating equation (5.4) to error-correction form allows for distinguishing between

stationarity by linear combinations and by differencing (Hansen and Juselius, 2003: 2):

(5.5) 0 1 1 1 1 1...t t k t k t t tY Y Y Y Dμ ψ ε− − − + −Δ = + Γ Δ + +Γ Δ +Π + +

The hypothesis of cointegration (for a given rank, r) in the system of equation (5.5) is tested by

maximum likelihood on the 1tY −Π part (since the 1 1 1 1...t k t kY Y− − − +Γ Δ + +Γ Δ parts are stationary):

(5.6) ( )1 :H r αβ′Π =

Here β is the matrix of cointegrating vectors, i.e. the long run coefficients, and α the weights by

which each of the vectors enter into the equations in (5.5), i.e. the short-run adjustment

coefficients (Nielsen, 2004: 122). The hypothesis, H1(r), implies that the process YΔ is stationary,

Yt non-stationary, and tYβ ′ stationary (Johansen, 1991). Finding the appropriate cointegration

rank, r, of the matrix Π, after checking for zero and non-zero eigenvalues, is the first step of the

cointegration analysis (Hendry and Juselius, 2001: 20). The rank determines the number of long-

run relations in the model, towards which the process is adjusting itself (cf. Juselius, 2005), and it

is an important part of the cointegration analysis.

For a more thorough discussion of cointegration analysis, please refer to the two introductory

papers of Hendry and Juselius (1999 and 2001), the comprehensive book of Juselius (2005) as

well as the aforementioned papers by Johansen (1989 and 1991).

Before the cointegration specification and estimation, the GARCH part of the empirical analysis

is discussed and estimated.

5.3.4 GARCH(p,q) estimation

As mentioned above, the GARCH(p,q) model suggests that the conditional variance is

determined by q lags of the error term (the innovation parameter) and p lags of the conditional

variance (the persistence parameter). The GARCH model is an augmented version of the

ARCH(q) model, which is given by:

(5.7) 20

1

p

t j t jj

h uα α −=

= +∑

The problem with the ARCH(q) model is that it requires a rather large number of lags to describe

the volatility process (Tsay, 2002: 93). The GARCH model, on the other hand, has been found to

be more flexible, and a GARCH(1,1) is often sufficient for describing the process. The GARCH

model has been found to be a good descriptor of the clustering of volatility as well as the

Page 89: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

88

relatively high kurtosis and fat tails (seen in chapter 2) of (financial) time series data. The

GARCH(p,q) is given by the following:

(5.8) 20

1 1

p q

t j t j j t jj j

h u hα α β− −= =

= + +∑ ∑

In the following, the macroeconomic fundamentals (output, money supply and interest rates) of

USA, Norway and Japan will, separately, be run through a GARCH(p,q) model. The conditional

variances of the estimation will be saved and used in the model for the cointegration analysis in

the next section. Including the GARCH variables endogenously in the models can give some

estimation problems, so they are instead added as dummies.

One has to be aware of potential problems with the GARCH estimation method used on

macroeconomic data on monthly frequency. First of all, several of the macroeconomic time-

series start in the late 1970s to early 1980s, resulting in approximately 360 observations. Thus, the

GARCH model can have problems converging to the true parameter values due to the relatively

short dataset. Secondly, the persistence of volatility is less when looking at monthly data,

compared with daily observations (as touched upon in chapter 2). This adds to the models

problem of finding persistence in the volatility. For this reason the GARCH model did not

converge for the UK macro fundamentals, and hence I chose to test the Norwegian krone

against the US dollar instead. Cumperayot (2003) does not post her results with respect to the

GARCH estimation in the paper, and does not report whether she had any problems with

convergence.

In figures 13–15 below, the differenced variables (money supply, output and interest rates) are

shown for USA, Norway and Japan. By visual inspection some problems appear, especially for

Japan where interest rates have been virtually unchanged (and close to zero) for the period 2002

to 2006. The results from the GARCH estimation is found in appendix C, result 1. All of the

GARCH parts are (highly) significant. As is evident, there have been some problems with the

estimation for some of the variables (e.g. industrial production for Norway and Japan). This has

been solved by adding either a constant or a trend to the model, as well as changing the order of

p and q. Overall, though, the result of the estimation is acceptable, and the models converge in all

9 instances. One problem with the conditional variances is the aspect of multicollinearity, i.e. high

(not perfect) correlation between two (or more) of the independent variables used when

estimating equation (5.2). To check for possible problems with correlation, the correlation

matrices for USD/JPY and USD/NOK are printed in appendix C result 2. As is evident, some

of the variables exhibit rather high correlations, especially the three months interest rates. To

avoid problems with biased estimators (Verbeek, 2004: 44), instrumental variable estimation has

Page 90: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

89

been used on the most correlated variables (in bold). An instrumental variable, z, is uncorrelated

with the error of the model but correlated with the regressor, x (see for example Verbeek, 2004:

133). The error term from regressing two correlated variables against each other is thus a useful

instrument, as the error (by definition) is orthogonal to the regressor. The result of the estimation

is not posted, but the results are significant for all the regressions (JPYm2 against JPYtbill etc.).

The conditional variances (or the instrumental variables) from the estimation are saved and added

to the VAR models estimated in the next section.

5.3.5 Cointegration analysis

The two models below, equations (5.9) and (5.10) respectively, are estimated for USD/JPY and

USD/NOK. An asterisk denotes a foreign variable, in all cases USA. Adding the interest rates,

equation (5.10), is then a test of whether the interest rate has significant impact on the long-run

result.

But before I test the two models, the simple monetary model (FPMM) given by equation (5.11)

below is put to a test for Japan and Norway.

(5.9) Model I: * ** *

0 1 2 3 4 5 , 1 6 7 , 1 8, 1 , 1t t t t t m t y tm t y ts m m y y h h h hβ β β β β β β β β− −− −= + + + + + + + +

(5.10) Model II – with interest rates: **

0 5 6 11 , 1 12 , 1... ...t t t i t i t

s i i h hβ β β β β− −= + + + + + +

(5.11) Monetary approach – FPMM: * *0 1 2 3 4t t t t ts m m y yβ β β β β= + + + +

Before the actual testing I will briefly discuss the models in relation to the cointegration analysis

from the previous section. In equation (5.12) below I assume, for simplicity, that r = 1; i.e. there

is only one stationary relation between the variables in (5.10), and this relation is furthermore

assumed to be the monetary model with uncertainty (i.e. the GARCH variables). Then the last

part of the cointegrated VAR model in equation (5.5) can, for model II above, be written as the

following (for 1 lag) (cf. Juselius, 2005: 99 or Nielsen, 2004: 123):

Page 91: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

90

(5.12) ( ) ( ) ( )1 1

1

2*

3* *

4 1 2 1 7 1*

5

6

* 7

... ...t

t t

t

t

t

t

t t t i t t t

t

sm

m

y s m i b GARCHm GARCHi D

y

i

i

αααα β β ψ μ εααα

− −− − −

⎛ ⎞Δ ⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟Δ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟Δ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ ′⎜ ⎟Δ = + + + + + + +⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟Δ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟Δ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎝ ⎠Δ⎝ ⎠

Here the long-run relation has been normalized on the exchange rate, st. Note that the GARCH

variables enter exogenously into the system and is thus assumed to excluded from the

cointegrating space. Furthermore, I test for whether the GARCH variables lagged one period

have effect on the exchange rate at time t. The exchange rate equation, Δst, from (5.12) is then

given by (still for 1 lag of the model and rank equal 1):

(5.13) [ ] [ ]1 1 1 1 1 1t t t t ts s x b GARCH Dα β ψ μ ε− − −Δ = Γ Δ + + + + +

From the monetary approach discussed in chapter 3 we should expect that β2 = 1 (m), β3 = -1

(m*), β4 < 0 (y), β5 > 0 (y*), β6 > 0 (i), and β7 < 0 (i*) in equation (5.12). But since this is a test of

one of the assumptions of the IKE theory, and not the monetary approach per se, a strict

conditioning on the coefficients could potentially be a flawed method. According to the IKE

theory, the economic fundamentals do matter for the exchange rate but the structure of the

causal relations may change at different points in time and in different ways. The way in which

the fundamentals influence the exchange rate is therefore not prespecified in the IKE model. But

since this is a test of whether uncertainty, as assumed by the IKE theory, plays an important part

in relation to the determination of exchange rates, the sign on the endogenous variables is not

important. I therefore restrict on β2 = 1 (domestic money supply) and β3 = -1 (foreign money

supply) in the tests below, following the assumption of the flexible price monetary model. The

interesting part, in our context, is whether the GARCH variables in equations (5.12) and

(especially) (5.13) have significant effect on the exchange rate, suggesting that uncertainty is

important for the price setting of currencies alongside macroeconomic fundamentals. This is

tested in the last part of section 5.3.7 below. Note that the signs of the GARCH variables are not

prespecified; it is just tested whether they influence the exchange rate at all, compared with the

result from the tests of the simple FPMM.

First the graphs of the individual time series are inspected. Figure 13, 14 and 15 below show the

data in levels and in first differences. For the American data – figure 13 below – the money

supply (lower chart) and output (upper chart) looks trending in levels, but (slightly) mean

Page 92: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

91

reverting in differences. The US 3 months treasury-bills (middle chart) display substantial changes

in the beginning of the 1980s, as the US Federal Reserve Bank tried to combat high

unemployment by lowering the interest rate drastically, then hiking the interest rate in response to

the ensuing inflationary pressure. This is also reflected in the Japanese interest rate in figure 14

below. For Japan, there is a clear shift in the money growth (lower charts) around the beginning

of 1990 – as well as an evident drop in interest rates. This seems to be a regime shift, and has to

be taken into account when estimating the model. For the Norwegian data, figure 15 below, the

interest rate (middle chart) exhibits large changes in December 1992 as the Norwegian central

bank gave up on defending the krone and allowed it to float. Dummy variables taking this into

account seems appropriate. For all three countries the series seem somewhat stationary in

differences, although with some problems. These problems will be sought dealt with below by

including dummies.

Figure 13 – US data in levels and first differences (RHS)

Page 93: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

92

Figure 14 – JPY data in levels and first differences (RHS)

Figure 15 – NOK data in levels and first differences (RHS)

Page 94: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

93

5.3.6 Lag length, residual analysis and dummy variables

Now I turn to the specification of the VAR model. First of all, the lag-length of the VAR model

is determined based on information criteria. As mentioned by Juselius (2005: 88) a VAR(2) is

most often used. The result of the lag-length is found in appendix C result 3. For the two models

for USD/NOK the result points to k = 1, whereas for USD/JPY the lag-length determination is

ambiguous, pointing at either k = 1 or k = 2. I have chosen to specify a VAR(2) model, though,

for both the USD/NOK models and the USD/JPY models, noting that the VAR(1) could be

sufficient for the models. Testing VAR(1) on the models does not change the results below,

though, and I therefore use the VAR(2) for all four models.

Secondly, the VAR model is based on the assumption of multivariate normality, from which it

follows that the model is: i) linear in parameters; ii) has constant parameters and iii) normally

distributed errors (Juselius, 2005: 56). But as Juselius (ibid.: 57-58) points out, this is seldom

satisfied in practice. This can, potentially, be a problem but can be solved by adding dummies to

the model. It is therefore important to perform residual analysis ensuring validity of the VAR

model (cf. Hendry and Juselius, 2001). The results of the residual analysis for the four models

(not shown) point to problems with normality and some ARCH problems, as well as significant

skewness and kurtosis. According to Hendry and Juselius (2001: 6), some degree of both excess

kurtosis and residual heteroskedasticity can be accepted, whereas non-normality is a problem. A

solution to these problems, as already mentioned, can be to introduce dummies of different kind.

As seen from the figures 13-15 above visual inspection points to several troubling periods. For

the Norwegian data, the floating of the krone in late 1992; for the Japanese data the structural

shift in the beginning of the 1990s, marking the start of the deep recession which affected money

growth, interest rates and output; and for the American data, the changes in the interest rate in

the beginning of the 1980s as the Fed tried to combat inflation as well as September 11th 2001.

To address the problems with the residuals, these have been inspected with focus on residuals

above 3.3 (Hendry and Juselius, 2001). For USD/NOK model I, I have chosen to include five

dummies. For Norway a dummy covering the banking crisis in late 1991 and a dummy covering

the free floating at October 1992. Furthermore, I have included a dummy for the May 1986

devaluation of the Norwegian krone. The two dummies covering the devaluation and the free

floating have been set to be impulse dummies, i.e. shifting the system, whereas the other

dummies (including the dummies for USA) have been set to be transitory (i.e. only temporary).

For USA, a May 1980 dummy covering a large change in industrial production, and a “September

11th” dummy have been included in the model. The dummies appear significant, and including

them improve the residual analysis somewhat. But the problems of non-normality and

Page 95: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

94

autocorrelation are still present in the modified model. For USD/NOK model II, the free

floating dummy starts in August 1992 instead, and the US dummy for 1980 starts in March.

Including the dummy in model II once again improves the residuals somewhat, but with some

problems.

For the USD/JPY model I, a dummy marking the beginning of the recession in Japan, 1991:2, is

included. This is set to be an impulse dummy. The September 11th dummy is kept, and so is the

dummy for 1980. The dummies once again improve the model, but the hypothesis of normality is

still rejected. For the USD/JPY model II, a dummy for 1983 is included as well.

Finally, running a new lag-length determination on the four models including the dummies does

not change the lag length for any of the four models, and I keep the VAR(2) specification.

5.3.7 Testing the models

Long run structure – the flexible price monetary models As mentioned above, the determination of the cointegration rank is a crucial part of the empirical

analysis, as it affects the following inference (Juselius, 2005: 157). The rank (r) is equal to the

number of cointegrating vectors in the system (cf. Verbeek, 2003: 329), and the (correct)

determination thereof is thus very important. For finding the correct rank I use the

“top→bottom” procedure following Juselius (2005: 160), in which case we will accept the correct

rank 95% of the time. The rank is determined by the trace test, including a Bartlett correction.

First of all I test the monetary model, given by equation (5.11) above, for both USD/NOK and

USD/JPY. The same dummies, discussed in the previous section, are used and k set to 2. Since

dummies are included in the models, the critical values for the rank tests are simulated in CATS

for all the models in this section (cf. Harbo et al, 1998).

The rank test results for the simple monetary models are found in appendix C, result 4. For

USD/NOK, the rank is set to 1 with p-value of 37.8%. For the USD/JPY monetary model the

rank is set to 1 as well. Setting the rank to 1, the estimated exchange rate equation for

USD/NOK is given by the following:

(5.14) * *0.660 1.211 1.004 0.413t t t t ts m m y y= + − +

As is evident from equation (5.14) the coefficient to the US money supply (m*) is of the wrong

sign, whereas the coefficients on the other three variables are in accordance with what is expected

from theory. The signs are furthermore almost of the same size, and relatively close to one (for

the money supply). But as pointed out by Juselius (2005), the beta coefficients should only be

Page 96: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

95

taken as indicative, not conclusive. For the alpha coefficients, the Norwegian industrial

production seems to have a significant equilibrium correction effect on the system.

For the monetary model for USD/JPY, equation (5.15), the coefficients on both money supply

variables are of the wrong sign. Furthermore, the signs are significantly larger than 1.

(5.15) * *16.706 47.791 1.785 24.566t t t t ts m m y y= − + − +

The result of a cointegration rank of 1 does not necessarily mean that a linear combination of the

variables in the monetary model results in a stationary long-run process. The cointegration of the

system could be any combination of the variables included, so a test with imposed restrictions on

the cointegrating vector is necessary. The H(0) of this test is then whether the restricted linear

combination of the process is stationary; i.e. whether the FPMM is a stationary relation. The

hypothesis on the cointegration vectors is given by the following (Juselius, 2005: 206; Hansen and

Juselius, 2003: 41):

(5.16) , 1, 2,...,i i iH i rβ ϕ= =

Where φi is a si x 1 vector of unknown parameters and Hi a known design matrix p x si. The

design matrices define the number of free parameters in each cointegrating vector. The test then

investigates whether a “known” cointegrating vector lies within the space of β. In the case of the

two monetary models above, the design matrix of the beta vector is given by [s, m, m*, y, y*] =

[1, 1, -1, *, *]. Here, a star denotes a “free” parameter.

The hypothesis of equation (5.16) is tested by the likelihood-ratio test (Juselius, 2005: 210), here

given by:

(5.17) ( )( )

( )2

max 22

max

~CT a

T

L H Rv

L H Rχ

⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟Λ =⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

Where v = rm given by the m restrictions on the r cointegrating vectors; i.e. 3 for both monetary

models since I set the restrictions to 3 and the rank is set to 1 for both models. Rejecting the

hypothesis, according to Juselius (2005: 211), implies that (at least) one of the restricted relations

is no longer significantly mean-reverting; i.e. the relation is not stationary and the restricted

relation is therefore not cointegrating.

The result of the tests of the two monetary models is shown in table 4 below. For both monetary

models the null hypotheses are firmly rejected as the Chi-Square critical value with three degrees

of freedom is 7.81. Apparently the data include a cointegrating relation, but this relation is not

given by the simple monetary model for neither NOK or JPY. This is in line with the conclusion

on the empirical results discussed in chapter 3 and it is not a surprising result.

Page 97: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

96

Table 4 – Test of the simple flexible price monetary models in VECM form for Japan and Norway

USD/NOK FPMM: TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

BARTLETT CORRECTION:

CHISQR(3) = 76.213 [0.000]

CHISQR(3) = 64.522 [0.000]

USD/JPY FPMM: TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

BARTLETT CORRECTION:

CHISQR(3) = 45.802 [0.000]

CHISQR(3) = 36.121 [0.000]

Note: Tested with the restriction on the beta vector [s, m, m*, y, y*] that [1, 1,-1, *, * ]

The question, then, is whether introducing uncertainty proxied by the GARCH variables

estimated in the previous section improves the model result significantly. This is tested in the

next section.

Long run structure – models with uncertainty First of all, the rank is determined for the four models – the results hereof are found in appendix

C result 4. Once again, the critical values are simulated for all four models to correct for the

inclusion of dummy variables in the models. When the rank is determined, the lag-length

determination is run again. This, however, does not change the chosen lag for any of the four

models.

Note that the following results are, initially, based on models with the GARCH variables lagged

one period. With respect to the rank and restriction tests, adding 2, 3, or 4 lags of the GARCH

variables to the models change the result somewhat. For the USD/NOK model II, for example,

where the rank test for two GARCH lags turn borderline significant for r=2 with a p-value of

10.2% compared with a rank of 1 for just one lag of the GARCH. And for the USD/JPY model

II, where the rank is 2 instead of 3 when a GARCH lag length of 2 is included in the model. But

for the other two models the rank determination is not changed by adding more lags of the

GARCH variables. Hence in the following only the result from the simple model with GARCHt-1

is presented. Then I run a test for the USD/JPY model I where I include a second lag of the

GARCH variables, which changes the result. When testing for whether the GARCH variables

enter into the system with significance in the next section, I will test with more lags as well (i.e. 2,

3 and 4).

For the USD/NOK model I the H(1) is accepted with a (corrected) p-value of 97.5%. Looking at

the characteristic roots and the alpha coefficients does not change r = 1, and the cointegrating

relation (see appendix A, figure 6) does look stationary. Furthermore the two charts of the

cointegrating relation (Appendix A figure 6) look rather alike, suggesting that the statistical

Page 98: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

97

analysis is valid (cf. Hansen and Juselius, 2003: 22-23). Thus, for the USD/NOK model I rank =

1 in the further analysis. For the USD/NOK model II, the rank is set to 2 with p-value of 39.4%.

The cointegrating relations, figure 7 in Appendix A, look stationary – but with some problems

around the floating of the Norwegian krone in 1992.

For the USD/JPY model I rank = 1 with a corrected p-value of 75.0%. This is the same result as

Cumperayot (2002: 9)17. Finally, for the USD/JPY model II the rank is set to 3.

The long-run estimated equation for the exchange rate for USD/NOK model I is given by:

(5.18) * *0.617 1.283 1.026 0.406 0.002t t t t ts m m y y t= + − + −

This is more or less in line with the result from the simple monetary model, equation (5.14)

above. The coefficient on the foreign money supply is still of the wrong sign, but rather close to

1 for all variables.

The long-run estimated equation for the exchange rate for USD/JPY model I is given by:

(5.19) * *6.839 29.884 0.302 14.677 0.094t t t t ts m m y y t= − − − +

For the USD/JPY the coefficients on the domestic output variable are of the wrong sign whereas

the money supply signs are correct, but significantly larger than 1, as for the simple FPMM for

USD/JPY in equation (5.15) with a small improvement. But as mentioned above, one has to be

aware of drawing strong conclusions on the beta coefficients.

The tests for whether the linear combination of the variables in the models is stationary changes

somewhat from the test of the monetary model in the previous section (table 4), see table 5 and

table 6 below. For the USD/NOK model I and model II the test soundly rejects H(0). The result

for the USD/NOK models are not changed by adding more lags of the GARCH variables. But it

changes the result for the USD/JPY models below (table 6).

Table 5 – Test of the flexible price monetary model in VECM form with GARCHt-1 for USD/NOK

USD/NOK model I: TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

BARTLETT CORRECTION:

CHISQR(3) = 91.609 [0.000]

CHISQR(3) = 77.830 [0.000]

USD/NOK model II (with interest rates): TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

CHISQR(2) = 23.289 [0.000]

Note: Tested with the restriction on the beta vector [s, m, m*, y, y*, i, i*] that [1, 1,-1, *, *, *, * ]

17 Note, however, that Cumperayot (2003) does not report whether she uses GARCHt or GARCHt-1 in the long-run

test, nor whether the GARCH variables appear endogenously or exogenously in the models.

Page 99: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

98

Table 6 below posts the result for the two USD/JPY models. The null hypothesis is rejected for

model I for Japan, whereas the H(0) is accepted at 95% level for USD/JPY model II.

Thus, according to table 5 and 6, adding the GARCH variables in 1 lag to the model is somewhat

of an improvement over the results from the test of the simple monetary model above (table 4),

at least for Japan model II. Table 6 – Test of the flexible price monetary model in VECM form with GARCHt-1 for USD/JPY

USD/JPY model I: TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

BARTLETT CORRECTION:

CHISQR(3) = 26.832 [0.000]

CHISQR(3) = 20.246 [0.000]

USD/JPY model II (with interest rates): TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

CHISQR(1) = 3.100 [0.078]

Note: Tested with the restriction on the beta vector [s, m, m*, y, y*, i, i*] that [1, 1,-1, *, *, *, * ]

Adding a second lag of the GARCH variables change the result for the USD/JPY model I – see

table 7 below – such that it is accepted at 99% level. Adding a second lag of the GARCH

variables do not change the results for any of the other three models, however. Table 7 – Test of the flexible price monetary model in VECM form with both GARCHt-1 and GARCHt-2

USD/JPY model I: TEST OF RESTRICTED MODEL:

BARTLETT CORRECTION:

CHISQR(3) = 16.169 [0.001]

CHISQR(3) = 10.512 [0.015]

Note: Tested with the restriction on the beta vector [s, m, m*, y, y*, i, i*] that [1, 1,-1, *, *, *, * ]

In Appendix C result 5 the restricted estimated cointegrated equations for the models are posted.

The coefficients on output are larger than 1 for most of the estimated equations (except for

USD/NOK model I) and of the wrong sign (except for USD/JPY model I). But, compared with

the equation for the FPMM above, closer to the acceptable range between zero and 1. Especially

for Japan, where the coefficients of the FPMM were very large; in the model including the

GARCH variables, this is significantly improved.

Overall, the result of the tests seem to be an improvement over the simple flexible price model,

especially for Japan.

In the following I will test specifically whether the GARCH variables in different lags enter

significantly in the equations for the four models.

Page 100: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

99

Testing the GARCH variables – lagged one period Now the specific significance of uncertainty in regards to exchange rates is inspected. First I look

at the models with the GARCH variables lagged one period, then a test with the GARCH

variables lagged two periods included as well. I have also tested with 3 and 4 lags of the GARCH

variables, but this does not change the overall result.

For the model with the GARCH variables lagged one period, I look at the t-statistics from the

cointegration analysis. The coefficients and p-values on the GARCH variables from the four

models are found in table 8 below.

For both USD/NOK models none of the GARCH variables are significant at 95% level. In

model I, though, the Norwegian money supply is significant at 90% level (with a t-value of -1.78).

The overall significance of the GARCH variables seem to increase with the introduction of

uncertainty of the interest rate variables in the NOK/USD model II as the foreign output and

domestic interest rate turn borderline significant (t-values of 1.41 and 1.36). Based on the

coefficients it seem that increased volatility of domestic output and money supply appreciate the

Norwegian krone, with the opposite effect from increased volatility in American output and

money supply. The effect from the increased volatility of the interest rates, on the other hand,

seems to depreciate the NOK overall. Table 8 – Coefficients and p-values on the GARCHt-1 variables from the cointegration analysis

Model hy hy* hm hm* hi hi*

NOK I -0.012 (0.78) 0.001 (0.27) -0.001 (0.07) 0.004 (0.43) - -

NOK II -0.054 (0.27) 0.002 (0.15) -0.00 (0.26) 0.003 (0.50) 0.000 (0.17) 0.017 (0.49)

JPY I -0.00 (0.75) -0.002 (0.11) 0.005 (0.16) -0.005 (0.41) - -

JPY II 0.001 (0.68) -0.003 (0.01) -0.007 (0.60) -0.001 (0.88) -0.014 (0.63) -0.322 (0.02)

Note: An asterisk denotes a US variable for all four models. P-values in brackets. Bold indicates rejection of H0 at 95% level

For the USD/JPY model I none of the GARCH variables are significant in table 8, although the

p-values on the conditional variance of the foreign output (11%) and domestic money supply

(16%) are borderline significant. But for USD/JPY model II the conditional variances of

American output and American interest rates appear significant. Based on the t-statistics it is

rejected at 95% level that increased uncertainty (i.e. volatility) of these two US variables have no

effect on the Yen.

Page 101: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

100

For all four models the results from table 8 show that especially hy*, i.e. the conditional variance

on US output, has an effect on the exchange rates. But the effect is depreciating for the NOK

and appreciating for the JPY. The negative coefficients on the domestic money supply in table 8

(except for USD/JPY model I) could stem from volatility caused by the Central Bank, i.e. due to

intervention to stabilize the economy which then have a positive effect on the future expectation

of the domestic currency (cf. Cumperayot, 2003: 12). It furthermore seems that adding one lag of

the conditional variance of the interest rates to the model increases the influence from the

conditional variance, at least for Japan.

One should be careful to conclude too much on the results from table 8, though. First of all,

most of the variables appear insignificant; and secondly, these are taken from models with the

GARCH variables lagged only one period.

Testing the GARCH variables – lagged more than one period For the models with GARCH lagged more than 1 period, I estimate the exchange rate equation

in error correction form given by the following equation (here for the rank set to 1 and the

GARCH variables lagged 2 periods):

(5.20) ( ) ( ) ( )1 1 1 1 1 ,1 1 ,2 2ˆ

t t t t i t i ts A x x D b GARCH b GARCHα β ψ μ ε− − − −Δ = Δ + + + + + +

Here the 1β is defined as the estimated β from the cointegration analysis and 1 1ˆ

txβ − is thus the

cointegrating relation(s)18. The test is then whether the bi,j on the GARCH variables in equation

(5.20) enter significantly into the model(s). The results from running OLS on equation (5.20) with

2 lags for the four models are found in Appendix C result 6.

Initially, looking at the t-statistics from the OLS the same GARCH variables seem to be

(borderline) significant in both models I and II for Norway as in table 8 above. But for

USD/JPY model II none of the variables appear significant when looking at the t-statistics from

the OLS regression. The same tests has been done for 3 and 4 lags of the GARCH variables (not

shown) as well, and the result thereof does not change much to the result obtained with only two

lags of GARCH. I therefore focus on two lags of the GARCH variables only.

The next step is then to test whether the GARCH variables can be excluded from the model.

This is done with a likelihood-ratio test, similar to equation (5.17) above, which is given by

(Verbeek, 2004: 173):

(5.21) ( ) ( )ˆ2 log logLR L θ θ⎡ ⎤= −⎣ ⎦%

18 Note that I have run the VAR models again with the extra lag of the GARCH variables.

Page 102: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

101

Where Log(θ ) is the unrestricted estimator, i.e. including the GARCH variables in the model,

and Log(θ% ) is the restricted, with (some of) the GARCH variables excluded from the model.

The test is Chi-squared distributed with J degrees of freedom based on the number of restricted

variables. The null hypothesis is that restricting the model does not take change the goodness-of-

fit of the model significantly, i.e. that the extra variables in the unrestricted model do not include

extra information, and subsequently can be left out. The test is thus whether or not the more

complex model, the unrestricted model, fits the dataset significantly better than the simpler

mode, the restricted model, in which (some of) the GARCH variables are left out.

The LR-test has been run three times on the four models with 2 lags of the GARCH variables

against the alternatives of: i) no GARCH variables in the model (NO GARCH), i.e. both 1 and 2

lags GARCH excluded; ii) no first lag GARCH in the model but including second lag GARCH

(NO GARCH_1); and finally iii) no second lag GARCH variables in the model but first lag

GARCH (NO GARCH_2). The result from the LR-tests is found in table 9 below.

For the USD/NOK model I, leaving the GARCH variables out altogether does not take away

much from the model as H(0) cannot be rejected, although it is borderline. But leaving out the

GARCHt-1 variables seem to be an incorrect restriction as the null hypothesis is rejected at 95%

level. The same result is obtained when leaving out GARCHt-219. Apparently, there seems to be

some problems with correlation between the two GARCH variables which affects the overall

result of the LR-test for the model. I have chosen to model the GARCH variables univariately,

not multivariate, and therefore I do not assume that uncertainty on the part of output, for

example, affect the uncertainty of interest rates. This could be the case, of course, but wielding

“Occams’ Razor” I have chosen the simpler version of the model, in line with Cumperayot

(2003). Furthermore there is, as seen from appendix C result 2, some cross-correlation between

the GARCH variables, and this apparently affects the likelihood-ratio test in table 9. This

problem has been sought dealt with by using instrumental variables, but there could still be some

impact between the variables.

For USD/NOK model II a similar result is obtained. The null hypothesis of leaving out the

GARCH variables altogether is not rejected, although it is once again relatively close to the 90%

level. But leaving out GARCHt-1 is clearly too strong a restriction and the null hypothesis of

leaving out GARCHt-2 is rejected at 90% level.

19 Testing the USD/NOK model I with 1 and 2 lags of the GARCH does not change anything with respect to the

rank test or the restricted test from the previous section.

Page 103: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

102

Table 9 – LR-test results on the error correction model with two lags of the GARCH variables

LR-test NOK I NOK II JPY I JPY II

b1 = b2 = 0 (NO GARCH)

13.14 (0.107) 17.23 (0.14) 14.99 (0.06) 21.61 (0.042)

b1 = 0 (NO GARCH_1)

11.7 (0.02) 13.81 (0.032) 5.65 (0.227) 9.52 (0.146)

b2 = 0 (NO GARCH_2)

9.78 (0.04) 11.73 (0.068) 10.27 (0.037) 8.72 (0.19)

Note: Chi-square results from the LR-tests. P-values in brackets. Bold indicates rejection at 95% level

For the USD/JPY model I, the null hypothesis of leaving out the GARCH variables altogether is

rejected at 90% level (p-value of 6%). And GARCH lag 2 appears significant at 95% level,

whereas it seems that GARCH lag 1 can be left out. This is no surprise, since including the

second lag of GARCH variables in the model leads to a near acceptance of the H(0) in the

USD/JPY model I in table 7 (compared with table 6). For the USD/JPY model II, the null

hypothesis of leaving out the GARCH variables is rejected at 95% level. But the result at the

same time points to no inclusion of the individual GARCH variables, although both variables

have relatively low p-values (14.6% and 19%, respectively). Once again it could be that

correlation between the variables influence the tests.

As mentioned above I have run the test (not shown) with the GARCH variables lagged 3 and 4

times as well, and the tests clearly point to a maximum of 2 lags of the GARCH variables in the

models. For example, in the USD/NOK model I with 4 lags of the GARCH variables the LR-

test result of leaving out GARCHt-3 and GARCHt-4 altogether, but keeping GARCHt-1 and

GARCHt-2, gives a Chi-square result of 6.65 (critical value of 15.5) – a clear acceptance of the null

hypothesis. Apparently GARCHt-1 and GARCHt-2 includes most of the information regarding the

exchange rate.

Overall the tests point to some significance of the GARCH variables. For the models with one

lag of the GARCH variables only two variables appeared significant – both in the USD/JPY

model II. But some of the uncertainty variables appeared borderline significant in the other three

models. When adding a second lag of uncertainty, the LR-test pointed to some significance of the

GARCH variables. Leaving the GARCH variables out altogether was thus rejected for both

USD/JPY models but (borderline) accepted for the two USD/NOK models. Individually, five of

the eight tests of the GARCH variables pointed towards a significant improvement of the fit

Page 104: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

103

when including the variables compared with the restricted models leaving the variables out of the

model.

5.3.8 Conclusion

The result from the empirical analysis is somewhat mixed. The restricted linear combination for

the simple flexible price monetary model for both Norway and Japan was tested to be (clearly)

not stationary, a result in line with the empirical survey in chapter 3. The enhanced models,

including the GARCH variables, improved this result to some extent. For Norway the two

models were still rejected, albeit with slightly lower Chi-square results for model II. But for the

USD/JPY model I (with two lags of the GARCH) as well as for the USD/JPY model II it could

not be rejected that the estimated models were stationary relations. Adding the uncertainty

variables, proxied by the conditional variance estimated by the GARCH model, thus seems to

enhance the result compared with the simple monetary models.

The result of the specific tests of the GARCH variables in 1 and 2 lags was somewhat supportive

for the models as well. With one lag of the GARCH variables, several of the parameters were

(borderline) significant in the four models tested. For two lags of the GARCH variables, leaving

the variables out altogether seemed (borderline) acceptable for two of the models. But on the

other hand, leaving out specifically either lag 1 or 2 of the GARCH variables seemed improper

for three of the models. A result which could stem from problems with correlation between the

GARCH variables, as the model assumed no effect between the uncertainty variables. This could,

perhaps, be too simple an assumption.

Overall, though, the idea and result of Cumperayot (2003) that uncertainty is important for

exchange rate determination cannot be rejected by the empirical test in this chapter. Furthermore,

augmenting the model with interest rates seems to be an improvement.

5.4 The result from an IKE perspective The question, then, is whether the empirical result from this chapter support the theory of

Imperfect Knowledge Economics presented in chapter 4.

To begin with, two issues are worth discussing. First of all, the test in the previous section is not

a test of the IKE theory per se, but rather a test of the monetary model of the exchange rate

augmented with a proxy for uncertainty. Thus, the rather mixed result of the test could stem

from the poor performance of the flexible price monetary model seen in chapter 3 and tested in

this chapter. And then, if the test is really a test of FPMM with extra variables, what about the

Page 105: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

104

IKE theory? Here, it is worth noting that the flexible price model is a sub-set of the IKE theory,

and that the IKE theory does not reject the monetary approach. Furthermore, the FPMM

assumes that new information is instantly fed into the exchange rate – which is apparently not the

case when uncertainty variables lagged 2 months can affect the present exchange rate level, as was

the case for the USD/JPY model. Hence, it can be argued that the empirical test is a test of the

IKE assumptions regarding uncertainty; and this assumption seems to be supported by the result

– at least it cannot be rejected that uncertainty has significant effect on exchange rates.

Secondly, the question is whether the GARCH variable is a good proxy for uncertainty. The

problem, of course, is to quantify uncertainty, and the use of the GARCH variable can be

discussed. Furthermore, the model assumed that increased uncertainty of, for example, the

interest rate did not feed into the other uncertainty variables. Both aspects could be themes

worth exploring further.

Overall the result of the test pointed towards including uncertainty to the monetary model

compared with the monetary approach. This, therefore, seems to support the assumption from

the IKE theory that uncertainty plays an important part in the price setting of exchange rates.

5.5 Conclusion The result of this chapter showed that including uncertainty variables, proxied by the conditional

variance of the fundamentals, improved the simple monetary model somewhat. A result in line

with Cumperayot (2003). But the result was ambiguous, with no significant improvement for the

USD/NOK models, but support for the USD/JPY models. Furthermore, the tests did not

decisively support the effect of the GARCH variables on the models. But overall, the result of

the likelihood-ratio tests indicated that the GARCH variables had significant effect on the

exchange rate. Hence uncertainty seems important, to some extent at least, with respect to the

determination of exchange rates. A result in line with the conclusion from the IKE theory in the

previous chapter. Based on the empirical test, it cannot be rejected that including uncertainty

improves the monetary model of exchange rates.

Page 106: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

105

Chapter 6

Conclusion

“It works in practice, but does it work in theory?”

French saying.

This thesis has concentrated on answering the question posed in the introduction to Chapter 1:

“Does Imperfect Knowledge Economics provide a solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle?”. Based on the

theoretical and empirical parts of the thesis, I cannot reject the hypothesis that IKE provides a

solution to the exchange rate disconnect puzzle.

Since the established result of Meese and Rogoff in 1983 the problems of explaining exchange

rate fluctuations have led to some gloom on the account of exchange rate research. Hence, the

imperfect knowledge economics theory, introduced by Roman Frydman and Michael D.

Goldberg, shows a new possible direction for economic research on the subject with less focus

on strictly rational and homogenous agents combined with a significant role for uncertainty.

Seen from a theoretical perspective, imperfect knowledge economics can explain why the

exchange rate is disconnected from the fundamental value. And secondly, why the currency

eventually revert to parity at least for some time. The IKE theory assumes that the economic

agents in the foreign exchange market are heterogeneous and hence use different models and

methods when deciding their individual strategy. This result in an outcome which is strictly

different from the rational expectations outcome given by the mainstream monetary models. The

IKE theory pairs the above assumptions with insight from both prospect theory, assumptions of

gap effects as well as conservative revisions of forecasting strategy. Combined, this explains both

the deviation from fundamental value of exchange rates, as well as the subsequent return.

Furthermore, it is assumed that people acknowledge that they do not have access to all important

information. Thus, the exchange rate disconnect puzzle is solved without neither removing

rationality from the model nor by including (irrational) bubble structures.

The assumption of agent heterogeneity have been thoroughly studied in several articles and it

seems to be a robust finding, as discussed in chapter 2. And the last two assumptions, the

importance of private information and the significance of uncertainty, have been tested and

discussed in chapter 3 and chapter 5: The hypothesis of the significance of private information,

using the order flow variable in a microstructure model, seem supported. Regarding uncertainty,

Page 107: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

106

here proxied by GARCH estimation added to a flexible price monetary model, the hypothesis of

its significance could not be rejected in chapter 5. Thus, the IKE theory thus seems able to, both

theoretically and empirically, explain the exchange rate behaviour of the recent float.

That the model with uncertainty, apparently, can improve the result significantly when compared

with the simple flexible price monetary model is an interesting result. But, obviously, one has to

take caution when interpreting the results due to the result from the residual analysis of the VAR

model. Furthermore, investigating the behaviour of the GARCH variables and their correlation,

as well as allowing for the variables to influence each other, could be the next step. The aspect of

uncertainty and how to proxy it is, therefore, an interesting subject for future research.

But one thing is explaining the fluctuations in-sample. The next question would then be how to

utilise this information in out-of-sample forecasting of exchange rate movements at 1-12 months

horizons. That is, once again putting the Meese-Rogoff result to a test, but with a model

including uncertainty. This has not been the subject of the thesis, but could be an interesting

analysis as well.

Overall, it seems that the imperfect knowledge economics theory could be able to solve the

exchange rate disconnect puzzle. According to this result, future research on exchange rates

should therefore focus on trying to incorporate aspects such as uncertainty, imperfect knowledge

of the economy on part of the agents as well as agent heterogeneity. At least if the goal is to

explain as well as to understand the fluctuations of exchange rates.

Page 108: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

107

Literature

• Abhyankar, Abhay; Sarno, Lucio; and Valente, George (2005): “Exchange rate and

fundamentals: evidence on the economic value of predictability”, Journal of International

Economics, vol. 66, pp. 325-48

• Alexius, Annika (2001): “Uncovered interest parity revisited”, Review of International

Economics, vol. 9, no. 3, pp. 505-517

• Bacchetta, Philippe and Wincoop, Eric van (2006): “Can information heterogeneity

explain the exchange rate determination puzzle?”, The American Economic Review, vol. 96,

no. 3, pp. 552-576

• Bacchetta, Philippe and Wincoop, Eric van (2007): “Random walk expectations and

the forward discount puzzle”, The American Economic Review, vol. 97, no.2, pp. 346-350

• Bank of International Settlements (2007a): “Triennial Central Bank survey of foreign

exchange and derivatives market activity in April 2007”. From www.bis.org

• Bank of International Settlements (2007b): “Quarterly review – International banking

and financial market developments”. From www.bis.org

• Bollerslev, Tim (1986): “Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity”,

Journal of Econometrics, vol. 31, pp. 307-327

• Boothe, Paul and Glassman, Debra (1987): “The statistical distribution of exchange

rates – empirical evidence and economic implications”, Journal of International Economics,

vol. 22. pp. 297-319

• Brock, William A. and Durlauf, Steven N. (2006): “Macroeconomics and Model

uncertainty”, in David Colander (red.) “Post Walrasian Macroeconomics”. Cambridge

University Press.

• Campbell, John Y; Lo, Andrew W., and MacKinlay, A. Craig (1997): “The

econometrics of financial markets”, Princeton University Press

• Cheung, Yin-Wong and Chinn, Menzie D. (2001): “Currency traders and exchange

rate dynamics: a survey of the US market”, Journal of International money and finance, vol. 20,

pp. 439-71

• Cheung, Y.W.; Chinn, Menzie D.; and Pascual, A.G. (2005): “Empirical exchange

rate models of the nineties: Are any fit to survive?”, Journal of International Money and

Finance, vol. 24, pp. 1150-75

Page 109: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

108

• Cheung, Yin-Wong; Chinn, Menzie D.; and Marsh, Ian W. (2004): “How do UK-

based foreign exchange dealers think their market operates?”, International Journal of Finance

and Economics, vol. 9, pp. 289-306

• Cumperayotm, Phornchack (2003): “Dusting off the perceptions of risk and returns in

FOREX markets”, CESifo Working paper no. 904 presented at CESifo Venice Summer

Institute 2002. Also found in “Exchange rate economics: Where do we stand?” By Paul de

Grauwe (ed.). MIT Press (2005)

• Cushman, David; Lee, S.S.; and Thorgeirsson, T. (1996): “Maximum likelihood

estimation of cointegration in exchange rate models for seven inflationary OECD

countries”, Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 15, no. 3, pp. 337-368

• Corrado, Luisa; Miller, Marcus and Zhang, Lei (2007): “Bulls, bears and excess

volatility: Can currency intervention help?”, International Journal of Finance and Economics,

vol. 12, pp. 261-72

• De Bondt, Werner F.M. and Thaler, Richard H. (1994): “Financial decision-making

in markets and firms: A behavioral perspective”. NBER Working Paper series, no. 4777.

• De Grauwe, Paul and Grimaldi, Marianna (2003): “Bubbling and crashing exchange

rates”, Working paper

• De Grauwe, Paul and Grimaldi, Marianna (2006a): “The Exchange rate in a

behavioral finance framework”, Princeton University Press

• De Grauwe, Paul and Grimaldi, Marianna (2006b): “Exchange rate puzzles: A tale of

switching attractors”, European Economic Review, vol. 50, pp. 1-33

• Dornbusch, Rudiger (1976): “Expectations and exchange rate dynamics”, Journal of

Political Economy, 84, pp. 1161-1174

• Dornbusch, Rudiger (1988): “Exchange rates and Inflation”, MIT Press

• Dornbusch, Rudiger and Frankel, Jeffrey (1987): ”The flexible exchange rate system:

Experience and alternatives”, NBER Working Papers, no. 2464

• Edwards, Ward (1968): “Conservatism in human information processing”, in Forman

representation of human judgement by Benjamin Kleinmuth (ed.). John Wiley and Sons

• Ehrmann, Michael and Fratzscher, Marcel (2004): “Exchange rates and fundametals

– New evidence from real-time data”. ECB Working Paper Series, no. 365

• Eichenbaum, M and Evans, C.L. (1995): “Some empirical evidence on the effect of

shocks to monetary policy on exchange rates”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 110, pp.

974-1009

Page 110: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

109

• Engel, Charles, and Rogers, John S. (1996): “How wide is the border?”, The American

Economic Review, vol. 86, no. 5. pp. 1112-1125

• Engel, Charles; Nelson, Mark C.; and West, Kenneth D. (2007): “Exchange rate

models are not as bad as you think”. Working paper prepared for the NBER

Macroeconomics Annual 2007.

• Engle, Robert F. and Granger, Clive W.J. (1987): “Co-integration and error

correction: Representation, estimation and testing”, Econometrica, vol. 55, no. 2, pp. 251-76

• Evans, Martin D. D. and Lyons, Richard K. (2002): “Order flow and exchange rate

dynamics”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 110, pp. 170-180

• Evans, Martin D. D. and Lyons, Richard K. (2007): “Exchange rate fundamentals and

Order flow”. Working paper

• Fama, Eugene (1984): “Forward and spot exchange rates”, Journal of Monetary Economics,

vol. 14, no. 3, pp. 319-38

• Frankel, Jacob A. (1995): “On exchange rates”, MIT Press.

• Frankel, Jacob A. and Froot, Kenneth (1986): “The dollar as a speculative bubble: A

tale of fundamentalists and chartists”, NBER Working Paper, no. 1854

• Frankel, Jacob A. and Froot, Kenneth (1990): “Chartists, fundamentalists, and trading

in the Foreign Exchange market”, The American Economic Review, vol. 80, no. 2. pp. 181-

185

• Frankel, Jacob A. and Rose, Andrew K. (1995): “Empirical research on nominal

exchange rates”, in Handbook of International Economics, vol. III. Edited by G. Grossman and K.

Rogoff, pp. 1690-1729

• Frenkel, Jacob A. (1976): “A monetary approach to the exchange rate: Doctrinal aspects

and Empirical evidence”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 78, pp. 200-224

• Friedman, Milton (1953): “Essays in positive economics”, University of Chicago Press

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (1996): “Imperfect knowledge and

behaviour in thte foreign exchange market”, The Economic Journal, 106, pp. 869-893

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2001): “Imperfect knowledge

expectations, Uncertainty adjusted UIP and exchange rate dynamics”. Working paper,

published in Knowledge, Information and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In honor of

Edmund S. Phelps, eds. P. Aghion, J. Stiglitz and M. Woodford. Princeton University Press

Page 111: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

110

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2002): “Imperfect knowledge, temporal

instability and an uncertainty premium: Towards a resolution of the excess-return puzzle

in the Foreign-Exchange market”. Working paper

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2003): “Imperfect knowledge and asset

price dynamics”. Working paper

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2004): “A new approach to modelling

forecasting behaviour – Imperfect knowledge and premia on Foreign exchange”.

Working paper

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2007): “Imperfect knowledge

economics: Exchange rates and risk”. Princeton University Press

• Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D. (2007b): “The Dollar-Euro exchange

rate and the limits to knowledge”. CCS Working paper no. 20, pp. 1-12

• Gehrig, Thomas and Menkhoff, Lukas (2004): “The use of flow analysis in foreign

exchange: Exploratory evidence”.Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 23, pp. 573-

94.

• Greenspan, Alan (2004): “Risk and Uncertainty in Monetary Policy”. Remarks by

Chairman Alan Greenspan at the meetings of the American Economic Association,

January 3rd.

• Groen, Jan J. (2000): “The monetary exchange model as a long-run phenomenon”,

Journal of International Economiccs, vol. 52, pp.299-319

• Grossman, Sanford J. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1980): “On the impossibility of

informationally efficient markets”, The American Economic Review, vol. 70, no. 3, pp. 393-

408

• Haavelmo, Trygve (1944): “The probability approach in Econometrics”, Econometrica,

vol. 12, Supplement, pp. iii-vi + 1-115

• Hansen, Henrik and Juselius, Katarina (2003): “Manual to Cointegration Analysis of

time series – CATS in RATS”, University of Copenhagen

• Harbo, Ingrid; Johansen, Søren; Nielsen, Bent; and Rahbek, Anders (1998):

“Asymptotic inference on Cointegrating rank in partial systems”, Journal of Business and

Economic statistics, vol. 16, no. 4, pp. 388-399

• Hayek, Friedrich A. von (1945): “The use of knowledge in society”, American Economic

Review, vol. 35, pp. 519-530

• Hayek, Friedrich A. von (1974): “The pretence of knowledge”, Nobel Prize lecture

Page 112: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

111

• Hendry, David F. and Juselius, Katarina (1999): “Explaining Cointegration Analysis:

Part I”. Working paper

• Hendry, David F. and Juselius, Katarina (2001): “Explaining Cointegration Analysis:

Part II”. Working paper

• Hodrick, Robert J. (1989): “Risk, uncertainty and exchange rates”, Journal of Monetary

Economics, vol. 23, pp. 433-459

• Imbs, Jean; Mumtaz, Haroon; Ravn, Morten, and Rey, Helene (2005): “PPP strikes

back: Aggregation and the real exchange rate”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 120, pp.

1-43

• Isard, Peter (1995): “Exchange rate economics”, Cambridge University Press

• Juselius, Katarina (2005): “The cointegrated VAR-model: Methodology and

applications. Oxford Press

• Johansen, Søren (1988): “Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors”, Journal of Economic

Dynamics and Control, vol. 12, pp. 231-54

• Johansen, Søren (1991): “Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in

Gaussian Vector autoregressive models”, Econometrica, vol. 59, pp. 1551-80

• Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1979): “Prospect theory: An analysis of

decision under risk”, Econometrica, vol. 47, no. 2, pp. 263-291

• Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1991): “Loss aversion and riskless choice: A

reference dependent model”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 107, pp. 1039-61

• Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1992): “Advances in Prospect theory:

Cumulative representation of Uncertainty”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, vol. 5, pp. 297-

323

• Keynes, John M. (1936): “The general theory of Employment, Interest and Money”.

• Knight, Frank (1921): “Risk, uncertainty and profit”, Beardbooks

• Kurz, Mordecai; Jin, Hehui and Motolese, Maurizio (2004): “Determinants of stock

market volatility and risk premia”. Working paper

• Lewis, Karen (1995): “Puzzles in international financial markets”, in Handbook of

International Economics, vol. III. Edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, pp. 1914-1971

• Lyons, Richard K. (2001): “The microstructure approach to exchange rates”, MIT Press

• MacDonald, Ronald (1999): “Exchange rate behaviour: Are fundamentals important?”,

The Economic Journal, vol. 109, no. 459, pp. 673-691

Page 113: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

112

• MacDonald, Ronald and Taylor, Mark P. (1994): “The monetary model of the

exchange rate: long-run relationships, short run dynamics, and how to beat a random

walk”, Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 13, pp. 276-290

• Malkiel, Burton G. (1992): “Efficient market hypothesis”, in Newman P., Milgate M.,

and Eatwell, J. (eds.), New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, MacMillan

• Mark, N.C. (1995): “Exchange rates and fundamentals: Evidence on long-horizon

predictability”, American Economic Review, vol. 85, pp. 201-218

• McNown, Robert and Wallace, Myles (1994): “Cointegration tests of the monetary

exchange rate model for three high-inflation economies”, Journal of Money, Credit and

Banking, vol. 26, pp. 396-411

• Menkhoff, Lukas and Taylor, Mark P. (2007): “The obstinate passion of foreign

exchange professionals: Technical analysis”, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. XLV, pp.

936-972

• Meese, R.A. and Rogoff, Kenneth (1983): “Empirical exchange rate models of the

seventies: Do they fit out of sample?”, Journal of International Economic, vol. 14, pp. 3-24

• Murray, Christian J. and Papell, David H. (2005): “The PPP puzzle is worse than you

think”, Empirical Economics, vol. 30, pp. 783-90

• Mussa, Michael (1976): “The exchange rate, the balance of payments and monetary and

fiscal policy under a regime of controlled floating”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, vol.

78, pp. 229-248

• Muth, John F. (1961): “Rational expectations and the theory of price movements”,

Econometrica, vol. 29, no. 3, pp. 315-335

• Nielsen, Heino Bohn (2004): “Has US monetary policy followed the Taylor rule?”. In

“I(1) and I(2) Cointegration analysis: Theory and applications”. Red Series no. 98,

Copenhagen University

• Obstfeld, Maurice and Rogoff, Kenneth (2000): “The Six major puzzles in

international macroeconomics: Is there a common cause?” NBER Macroeconomics Annual

• Pagan, Adrian (1996): “The econometrics of financial markets”, Journal of Empirical

Finance, vol. 3. pp. 15-102

• Papell, David (2003): “Imperfect knowledge expectations, uncertainty adjusted UIP and

exchange rate dynamics: A comment”, in Knowledge, Information and expectations in modern

macroeconomics: In honor of Edmund S. Phelps, Princeton University Press. Also available here:

http://www.uh.edu/~dpapell/frydman.pdf

Page 114: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

113

• Pilbeam, Keith (2006): “International Finance”, 3rd edition. Palgrave Macmillan

• Richardson, G.B. (1953): “Imperfect knowledge and Economic efficiency”, Oxford

Economic Papers, vol. 5, no. 2. pp. 136-156

• Rime, Dagfinn (2000): “Private or Public information in Foreign Exchange markets? An

empirical analysis”. Working paper. Availabe from:

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=239149

• Rime, Dagfinn; Sarno, Lucio; and Sojli, Elvira (2007): “Exchange rate forecasting,

order flow and macroeconomic information”. Working paper. Available from Norges

Bank.

• Rogoff, Kenneth (1996): “The purchasing power parity puzzle”, Journal of Economic

Literature, vol. 34, no. 2. pp. 647-668

• Sager, Michael J. and Taylor, Mark P. (2006): “Under the microscope: The structure

of the foreign exchange market”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, vol. 11. pp.

81-95

• Sarno, Lucio (2005): “Towards a solution to the puzzles in exchange rate economics:

where do we stand?”, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 38, no. 3,

• Sarno, Lucio and Taylor, Mark P. (2002): “The economics of exchange rates”, 4th

edition, Cambridge University Press

• Slovic, Paul (1973): “Behavioral problems of adhering to a decision policy”, presented at

Spring 1973 IQRF Seminar

• Taylor, Mark P. (1995): “The Economics of Exchange Rates”, Journal of Economic

Literature, vol . 33, pp. 13-47

• Taylor, Mark P. and Peel, D.A. (2000): “Non-linear adjustment, Long-run equilibrium

and Exchange rate fundamentals”, Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 19. pp. 33-

53

• Tsay, Ruey S. (2002): “Analysis of financial time series: Financial econometrics”. Wiley

• Verbeek, Marno (2004): “A guide to Modern econometrics”. Wiley. 2nd Edition.

• Vigfusson, Robert (1997): “Switching between chartists and fundamentalists: A Markov-

regime switching approach”, International Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 2, pp. 291-305

Page 115: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

114

Appendix A – Figures Figure 1A – Log returns, weekly observations for USD/GBP, EUR/USD and USD/JPY

Figure 2A – Log returns, monthly observations USD/GBP, EUR/USD and USD/JPY

Page 116: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

115

Figure 3A – Plot of 3 months Treasury rates: USA, Germany and Japan (RHS)

3,5

4

4,5

5

5,5

1.5.96 16.5.96 31.5.96 15.6.96 30.6.96 15.7.96 30.7.96 14.8.96 29.8.96

0,0000

0,0010

0,0020

0,0030

0,0040

0,0050

0,0060

0,0070

0,0080

US Germany Japan (RHS)

Figure 4A – Fitted returns and scaled residuals, DEM/USD microstructure model

Page 117: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

116

Figure 5A – Fitted returns and scaled residuals, USD/JPY microstructure model

Cointegrating relations

Figure 6A: USD/NOK model I – cointegrating relation:

Beta1'*Z1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-0.20

-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

-0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

Beta1'*R1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

Note: The upper panel plots tYβ ′ whereas the lower panel plots the concentrated likelihood function of the rank

regression 0t ktR Rαβ ε′= + (cf. Hansen and Juselius, 2003: 7).

Page 118: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

117

Figure 7A: USD/NOK model II – 1st cointegrating relation:

Beta1'*Z1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

Beta1'*R1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

Figure 8A: USD/NOK model II – 2nd cointegrating relation:

Beta2'*Z1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-0.96-0.80-0.64-0.48-0.32-0.160.000.160.32

Beta2'*R1(t)

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006-1.0

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

-0.0

0.2

0.4

Page 119: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

118

Appendix B – Models

1B: Dornbusch Sticky price model (Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 104-107) The two first equations below is the same as in the text; the third is a Philips curve relation.

(6.1) *s i i= −&

(6.2) m p y iκ θ= + −

(6.3) ( )p s p yγ α μ= + − −⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦&

The money supply is set to be exogenous and at its long-run equilibrium level. The long run

money market equilibrium is given by:

(6.4) *m p y iκ θ− = −

Where overbars denote long-run equilibrium values.Subtracting the long-run equilibrium value

from equation (6.2) yields the following:

(6.5) ( )*p p i iθ− = −

Inserting this into the UIP condition, equation (6.1), then yields:

(6.6) ( )1s p pθ⎛ ⎞= −⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

&

Looking at the goods market equilibrium, given by the Philips-curve in equation (6.3), the long-

run value is obtained for 0p =& , that is:

(6.7) ( ) 0s p yγ α μ+ − − =⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦

Now, subtracting this long-run equilibrium from the Philips-curve, equation (6.3), yields:

(6.8) ( ) ( )p s s p pγμ γμ= − − −&

The two differential equations, (6.6) and (6.8), can then be written as:

(6.9) 10s s s

p p pθ

γμ γμ

⎛ ⎞ −⎡ ⎤ ⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟= ⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥ ⎜ ⎟ −⎣ ⎦ ⎝ ⎠−⎝ ⎠

&

&

As the determinant in the matrix is negative, the system has a unique (and convergent) saddlepath

(cf. Sarno and Taylor, 2002: 106). Given that λ is the (negative) stable root to the system, the law

of motion equation for the exchange rate s must obey:

(6.10) ( )s s sλ= − −&

Inserting this into the differential equation yields the saddlepath equation, which is the same as

equation (3.19) in section 3.2.2 (with β2 = λ).

(6.11) ( )1s s p pλθ

⎛ ⎞= − −⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

Page 120: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

119

2B: IKE monetary model – solution

( ) ( )

( ) ( )

( ) ( )( )

( )

1

1 1 0 0 0 0

1 1 , 0 0 0 1 0 ,

1 0 0 1 0 0

1

1,

1 1

0A B

h

hh h hG G G G G G

hh h hA BG G G G G G

G G G G G G

G h

λ ϕη ηα α

σ σ

ϕ α η σ αλα η λη αλ λασ

ϕ α ασ σ αασ α η α ασ

ϕ α ησ σ η αλα ση λασ α λασ α η αλη σα

α η

σ

⎛ ⎞− −⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟= − = ⎜ − ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟

⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ −⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠

+ −⎛ ⎞+− −⎜ ⎟

⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟− + −−

= − −⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟

+ − +⎜ ⎟+ − − +− −⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠

= + +

( )

( ) ( ) ( )

( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

( ) *

*

ˆ 0

1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ

1ˆ ˆ ˆ

1ˆ ˆ ˆ

:

ˆˆ 1

PPP PPP

PPP PPP

PPP PPP

REa RE RE

h

s m y x q qG G G G G

h h hp m y x q qG G G G G

hh hq s p m y x q q

G G G G G

Define

s s

s

αλ σ

σ η αλα ση λασ α λασ α η αλϕ η π σα

σ αλα η λη αλ λασϕ π

λη σ ησ η σ η α λα σ ηϕ π σ

ρ π

− >

− ++ − − += − + + − +

−+= − + + − +

− +⎡ ⎤− − + −⎣ ⎦≡ − = − − + − + +

= − +

=

( )

( )( )

* * ˆˆ 1 , 1

ˆˆ 1

RE PPP

RE REt

REa RE RE PPP RE

m y q

s s s

s m y q

ϕ λπ

θ θ π θ ρ

ρ ϕ λπ π

− + +

= + − + − =

= − − + + +

Page 121: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

120

( )( ) ( ) ( )( )

( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( )

( )( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )

( )( ) ( )( ) ( )

ˆ ˆ part in :

1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ

1 1 ˆˆ 1

ˆ1 1 1 ˆ1 .....

ˆ ˆ1 1 1 1...,

REa

REa REa

REa RE RE RE

RERE RE

RE RE

Add and subtract s to the x s

x s sG G

s m yG G

s m yG G

sG

σ η αλ σ η αλ

σ η αλ σ η αλρ ϕ λπ π

σ η αλ ρ ση α σ η αλϕ λ ρ π

σ ρ αλ η ρ σ α

− + − +− +

− + − + ⎡ ⎤⇒ = − − + +⎣ ⎦

− + − + + − += − + + − +

− − + − − += ⋅ +

( ) ( )( )

( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( )

( )

( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( )

ˆ1 1 *1 ...,

Rearrange the min # :

ˆ ˆ ˆ1 1 1 * 1

#

RE

RE RE PPP

RE RE RE

add and subtract G h h

h h hs

G

Now insert m y s q

no ator of

h h h

α η λα σ

σ ρ αλ η α η α λα σ

ϕ λπ

αλ σ ρ λα σ ρ ρ σ αλ η ρ ρ σ

= + + −

⎡ ⎤⎢ ⎥− − + + − + − −

= + ⋅ +⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

− = − −

− − − − ⇔ − − + − ⇔ − −

14444444444244444444443

( )

( )( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )

( )( )

* *

*

.

:ˆ1 1 1

ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ

ˆ ˆˆ ˆRe 1 , . .

4.47

RE PPP

REREa RE

RE PPP PPP

REa REa RE RE RE

Now rearrange for and q as well

This yields

s s s x sG G G

q qG G

defining s such that s s i e

This yields equation

αλ η

λπ

σ η αλ ρ ρ σ η αλ η λσπ π

η αλ σ η αλ σπ

ρ π ρ ρ

+

− + − − + −= + + − + −

+ +− + −

= − + =

Page 122: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

121

Appendix C – Empirical results

Result 1C: GARCH estimation for m, y and i for USD, JPY and NOK

GARCH(1,1) – JPY M Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.0236471 0.01080 2.61 0.009

GARCH(Beta1) 0.972534 0.009243 133.0 0.000

GARCH(2,1) – JPY Industrial prod. (Y) Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.015116 0.0059518 2.540 0.0115

GARCH(Beta1) 1.880461 0.050508 37.23 0.0000

GARCH(Beta2) -0.943878 0.054455 -17.33 0.0000

GARCH(1,1) – JPY 3 mths treasury rate (i) Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.876853 0.1379 1.85 0.065

GARCH(Beta1) 0.599847 0.03463 6.59 0.000

GARCH(1,1) – US Industrial prod. (y)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.202951 0.07812 2.27 0.024

GARCH(Beta1) 0.479973 0.1782 2.11 0.035

GARCH(1,1) – US M

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) -0.041537 0.026141 -1.589 0.1129

GARCH(Beta1) 0.825147 0.058983 13.99 0.0000

Page 123: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

122

GARCH(1,1) – US 3 mths treasury rate (i) Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.652518 0.2011 2.61 0.009

GARCH(Beta1) 0.508761 0.07696 4.56 0.000

GARCH(1,1) – NOK M Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.023194 0.0086671 2.676 0.0077

GARCH(Beta1) 0.971850 0.011404 85.22 0.0000

GARCH(2,2) – NOK industrial production (y) Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) -0.007616 0.027475 -0.2772 0.7818

ARCH(Alpha2) -0.050367 0.010895 -4.623 0.0000

GARCH(Beta1) 0.113356 0.055379 2.047 0.0414

GARCH(Beta2) 0.863513 0.054156 15.94 0.0000

GARCH(1,1) – NOK treasury bill (i)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob

ARCH(Alpha1) 0.528283 0.28068 1.882 0.0605

GARCH(Beta1) 0.691429 0.081104 8.525 0.0000

Page 124: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

123

Result 2C: Correlation matrices for the GARCH variables: USD/NOK and USD/JPY

USD/NOK: nokm2 nokgdp noktbill usdm2 usdtbill usdind

nokm2 1.0000 -0.11071 -0.025966 0.10580 -0.33058 -0.33403

nokgdp -0.11071 1.0000 -0.13003 0.16897 0.056048 0.087314

noktbill -0.025966 -0.13003 1.0000 -0.0062130 0.14487 0.12666

usdm2 0.10580 0.16897 -0.0062130 1.0000 0.043690 0.041909

usdtbill -0.33058 0.056048 0.14487 0.043690 1.0000 0.54793

usdind -0.33403 0.087314 0.12666 0.041909 0.54793 1.0000

USD/JPY: jpym2 jpytbill jpyindu usdm2 usdtbill usdind

jpym2 1.0000 0.34024 0.012578 0.18035 0.21071 0.16157

jpytbill 0.34024 1.0000 0.11500 0.15243 0.57640 0.33298

jpyindu 0.012578 0.11500 1.0000 -0.096151 0.096950 0.023640

usdm2 0.18035 0.15243 -0.096151 1.0000 0.043829 0.041923

usdtbill 0.21071 0.57640 0.096950 0.043829 1.0000 0.54793

usdind 0.16157 0.33298 0.023640 0.041923 0.54793 1.0000

Result 3C: Lag-length determination for the four models Model I – USD/NOK: VAR(6) 6 352 70 8429.403 -42.064 -44.377 0.087 0.351

VAR(5) 5 352 61 8399.733 -42.645 -44.661 0.350 0.484

VAR(4) 4 352 52 8363.212 -43.187 -44.905 0.265 0.475

VAR(3) 3 352 43 8306.496 -43.615 -45.035 0.000 0.000

VAR(2) 2 352 34 8244.053 -44.009 -45.133 0.012 0.000

VAR(1) 1 352 25 8169.819 -44.337 -45.163 0.000 0.000

Page 125: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

124

Model II – USD/NOK: Model k T Regr Log-Lik SC H-Q LM(1) LM(k)

VAR(6) 6 352 97 8913.158 -39.332 -43.819 0.015 0.000

VAR(5) 5 352 84 8840.611 -40.436 -44.321 0.221 0.202

VAR(4) 4 352 71 8762.112 -41.506 -44.790 0.095 0.001

VAR(3) 3 352 58 8662.432 -42.455 -45.138 0.001 0.000

VAR(2) 2 352 45 8544.920 -43.303 -45.385 0.000 0.000

VAR(1) 1 352 32 8414.903 -44.081 -45.561 0.000 0.000

Model I – USD/JPY: Model k T Regr Log-Lik SC H-Q LM(1) LM(k)

VAR(6) 6 352 70 9625.154 -48.858 -51.171 0.075 0.272

VAR(5) 5 352 61 9598.407 -49.456 -51.471 0.758 0.642

VAR(4) 4 352 52 9554.930 -49.958 -51.676 0.003 0.129

VAR(3) 3 352 43 9481.519 -50.291 -51.712 0.000 0.000

VAR(2) 2 352 34 9411.326 -50.642 -51.765 0.000 0.000

VAR(1) 1 352 25 9315.651 -50.848 -51.674 0.000 0.000

Model II – USD/JPY: Model k T Regr Log-Lik SC H-Q LM(1) LM(k)

VAR(6) 6 352 96 10780.499 -50.059 -54.499 0.000 0.604

VAR(5) 5 352 83 10703.276 -51.136 -54.975 0.388 0.042

VAR(4) 4 352 70 10615.729 -52.154 -55.392 0.016 0.177

VAR(3) 3 352 57 10512.806 -53.085 -55.722 0.000 0.000

VAR(2) 2 352 44 10421.458 -54.082 -56.117 0.008 0.001

VAR(1) 1 352 31 10195.009 -54.311 -55.745 0.000 0.000

Page 126: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

125

Result 4C: Rank determination – with simulated critical values Model FPMM – USD/NOK: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

5 0 0.253 155.916 151.832 88.554 0.000 0.000

4 1 0.089 52.249 50.899 63.659 0.322 0.378

3 2 0.027 19.164 11.207 42.770 0.969 1.000

2 3 0.017 9.422 5.613 25.731 0.940 0.998

1 4 0.009 3.297 2.613 12.448 0.831 0.905

Model FPMM – USD/JPY: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

5 0 0.276 181.128 176.248 88.554 0.000 0.000

4 1 0.105 66.250 32.308 63.659 0.029 0.983

3 2 0.034 26.924 14.855 42.770 0.688 0.997

2 3 0.029 14.535 8.936 25.731 0.619 0.955

1 4 0.012 4.144 2.693 12.448 0.721 0.898

Model I – USD/NOK: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

5 0 0.249 138.950 135.572 96.345 0.000 0.000

4 1 0.057 36.853 36.008 72.451 0.969 0.975

3 2 0.026 15.842 14.588 50.172 0.999 0.999

2 3 0.014 6.372 5.601 30.391 0.999 0.999

1 4 0.004 1.529 1.166 15.914 0.991 0.996

Model II – USD/NOK: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

7 0 0.325 309.841 306.804 163.556 0.000 0.000

6 1 0.218 170.043 168.634 130.647 0.000 0.000

5 2 0.093 82.711 82.151 100.205 0.377 0.394

4 3 0.078 48.150 47.896 73.732 0.755 0.764

3 4 0.034 19.135 19.063 51.123 0.991 0.991

2 5 0.016 6.790 6.775 31.877 0.998 0.998

1 6 0.003 1.001 1.001 16.654 0.997 0.997

Page 127: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

126

Model I – USD/JPY: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

5 0 0.206 156.153 152.257 93.668 0.000 0.000

4 1 0.090 74.213 44.732 67.396 0.014 0.750

3 2 0.071 40.655 35.374 47.100 0.173 0.373

2 3 0.035 14.586 11.883 29.568 0.716 0.870

1 4 0.005 1.845 1.622 14.554 0.964 0.974

Model II – USD/JPY: p-r r Eig.Value Trace Trace* Frac95 P-Value P-Value*

7 0 0.266 311.063 298.795 160.271 0.000 0.000

6 1 0.202 201.032 188.037 127.096 0.000 0.000

5 2 0.146 120.890 111.827 96.840 0.001 0.004

4 3 0.107 64.551 36.545 72.140 0.156 0.971

3 4 0.032 24.286 17.440 49.719 0.920 0.995

2 5 0.025 12.642 9.279 30.765 0.864 0.970

1 6 0.010 3.633 3.233 15.733 0.827 0.864

Result 5C: The estimated equations from the restricted test of the models

USD/NOK model I: BETA(transposed)

S USM2 USY NOKY NOKM2

Beta(1) 1.000 -1.000 -3.156 0.660 1.000

(.NA) (.NA) (-4.351) (1.855) (.NA)

USD/NOK model II (with interest rates): S USM2 USY USTBILL NOKY NOKM2 NOKTBILL

Beta(1) 1.000 -1.000 -5.379 -0.064 -0.829 1.000 -0.384

(.NA) (.NA) (-54.934) (-1.143) (-1.983) (.NA) (-8.177)

Page 128: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

127

USD/JPY model I: S USM2 USY JPY JPM2

Beta(1) 1.000 -1.000 1.933 -5.679 1.000

(.NA) (.NA) (3.657) (-4.410) (.NA)

USD/JPY model I with 2 lags of the GARCH: S USM2 USY JPY JPM2

Beta(1) 1.000 -1.000 2.938 -8.518 1.000

(.NA) (.NA) (4.365) (-5.259) (.NA)

USD/JPY model II (with interest rates): S USM2 USY USTBILL JPTBILL JPY JPM2

Beta(1) 1.000 -1.000 -3.285 -0.077 -0.098 9.582 1.000

(.NA) (.NA) (-5.986) (-4.436) (-3.584) (9.254) (.NA)

Page 129: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

128

Result 6C: Result from OLS on the ECM, equation (5.20) (with GARCH lagged 1 and 2 periods) Note: The season- and dummy variables have been removed from the results below to obtain a higher

degree of readability.

USD/NOK model I – with GARCH lag 1 and 2 included (rank = 1)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob Part.R^2 deltas_1 -0.0182966 0.06472 -0.283 0.7776 0.0002

deltausm_1 0.698618 0.9933 0.703 0.4823 0.0015

deltausy_1 -0.377790 0.2533 -1.49 0.1368 0.0068

deltnokm_1 -0.107744 0.1169 -0.922 0.3573 0.0026

deltanoky_1 -0.0153218 0.05325 -0.288 0.7737 0.0003

usdnok_1 -0.0151984 0.01133 -1.34 0.1806 0.0055

betaxt_1 0.0267313 0.04203 0.636 0.5253 0.0012

garchnokm -0.00373487 0.001152 -3.24 0.0013 0.0314 garchnokgdp 0.0248382 0.1188 0.209 0.8345 0.0001

garchusdm -0.00107685 0.006366 -0.169 0.8658 0.0001

garchusdy 0.00293097 0.001298 2.26 0.0246 0.0155 garchusy_2 -0.00185606 0.001276 -1.45 0.1466 0.0065

garchusm_2 0.00456801 0.006264 0.729 0.4664 0.0016

garchnokm_2 0.00328394 0.001148 2.86 0.0045 0.0246 garchnoky_2 -0.00580293 0.1171 -0.0496 0.9605 0.0000

R^2 0.160249 F(31,324) = 1.994 [0.002]**

log-likelihood 779.987 DW 2.02

no. of observations 356 no. of parameters 32

Page 130: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

129

USD/NOK model II – with GARCH lag 1 and 2 included (rank = 2)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob Part.R^2 deltas_1 -0.0210265 0.06484 -0.324 0.7459 0.0003

Constant -0.00424407 0.1001 -0.0424 0.9662 0.0000

deltausm_1 0.610285 1.019 0.599 0.5495 0.0011

deltausy_1 -0.306898 0.2649 -1.16 0.2475 0.0042

deltnokm_1 -0.119859 0.1176 -1.02 0.3087 0.0033

deltanoky_1 -0.0126254 0.05466 -0.231 0.8175 0.0002

usdnok_1 -0.0117838 0.01341 -0.879 0.3802 0.0024

betaxt1_1 0.0158675 0.03668 0.433 0.6656 0.0006

betaxt2_1 0.00273289 0.005307 0.515 0.6070 0.0008

garchnokm -0.00458189 0.001343 -3.41 0.0007 0.0353

garchnokgdp 0.0193226 0.1208 0.160 0.8730 0.0001

garchnoktbill -8.15115e-005 0.0005413 -0.151 0.8804 0.0001

garchustbill 0.0500393 0.03607 1.39 0.1664 0.0060

garchusdy 0.00482626 0.001892 2.55 0.0112 0.0200

garchusm -0.00127418 0.006479 -0.197 0.8442 0.0001

garchnoktbill_2 0.000451454 0.0005285 0.854 0.3936 0.0023

garchusy_2 -0.00302475 0.001824 -1.66 0.0983 0.0086

garchusm_2 0.00509965 0.006354 0.803 0.4228 0.0020

garchustbill_2 -0.0305858 0.03474 -0.880 0.3793 0.0024

garchnokm_2 0.00409883 0.001366 3.00 0.0029 0.0275

garchnoky_2 0.0113336 0.1205 0.0941 0.9251 0.0000

sigma 0.0284855 RSS 0.258032906

R^2 0.168353 F(36,318) = 1.788 [0.005]**

log-likelihood 779.031 DW 2.01

no. of observations 355 no. of parameters 37

Page 131: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

130

USD/JPY model I – with GARCH lag 1 and 2 included (rank = 1)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob Part.R^2 deltas_1 0.0209497 0.05524 0.379 0.7047 0.0004

Constant -0.254139 0.2337 -1.09 0.2776 0.0036

deltajpy_1 0.0964622 0.3224 0.299 0.7650 0.0003

deltajpm_1 -1.50755 0.9182 -1.64 0.1016 0.0082

deltausy_1 -0.0488726 0.3489 -0.140 0.8887 0.0001

deltausm_1 2.41638 1.272 1.90 0.0583 0.0110

usdjpy_1 -0.0241005 0.01159 -2.08 0.0384 0.0131

garchusm 0.00133149 0.01025 0.130 0.8967 0.0001

garchusy 0.000879951 0.001561 0.564 0.5733 0.0010

garchjpy -0.00198297 0.006255 -0.317 0.7514 0.0003

garchjpym 0.0213338 0.009852 2.17 0.0311 0.0142

garchusm_2 -0.00812774 0.01007 -0.807 0.4202 0.0020

garchusy_2 -0.00351405 0.001398 -2.51 0.0125 0.0191

garchjpy_2 0.00170759 0.006249 0.273 0.7848 0.0002

garchjpym_2 -0.0176534 0.009840 -1.79 0.0737 0.0098

betaxt_1 0.00132937 0.0009028 1.47 0.1419 0.0066

sigma 0.0343583 RSS 0.3836598

R^2 0.0894027 F(30,325) = 1.064 [0.380]

log-likelihood 711.119 DW 2

no. of observations 356 no. of parameters 31

Page 132: D Pedersen Imperfect Knowledge Economics

131

USD/JPY model II – with GARCH lag 1 and 2 included (rank = 2)

Coefficient Std.Error t-value t-prob Part.R^2 deltas_1 0.00684266 0.05595 0.122 0.9027 0.0000

Constant -0.208858 1.706 -0.122 0.9027 0.0000

deltajpy_1 0.0916255 0.3244 0.282 0.7778 0.0002

deltajpm_1 -1.47575 1.179 -1.25 0.2115 0.0049

deltausy_1 -0.0563921 0.3610 -0.156 0.8760 0.0001

deltausm_1 2.17195 1.292 1.68 0.0937 0.0088

usdjpy_1 -0.0287478 0.01585 -1.81 0.0707 0.0102

betaxt_1 0.00169142 0.001376 1.23 0.2200 0.0047

betaxt2_1 0.000291642 0.004134 0.0706 0.9438 0.0000

garchusm 0.00372217 0.01053 0.354 0.7239 0.0004

garchustbill 0.0578529 0.09256 0.625 0.5324 0.0012

garchusy 0.000936347 0.002512 0.373 0.7096 0.0004

garchjpy -0.00293045 0.006353 -0.461 0.6449 0.0007

garchjpym 0.0186926 0.03766 0.496 0.6200 0.0008

garchjpytbill -0.0859020 0.4101 -0.209 0.8342 0.0001

garchusml2 -0.00851043 0.01028 -0.828 0.4084 0.0021

garchustbill2 -0.0266271 0.08691 -0.306 0.7595 0.0003

garchusy2 -0.00441672 0.002491 -1.77 0.0772 0.0097

garchjpy2 0.00289187 0.006325 0.457 0.6478 0.0007

garchjpyml2 -0.0136210 0.03737 -0.364 0.7157 0.0004

garchjpytbill2 -0.116313 0.4260 -0.273 0.7850 0.0002

sigma 0.0342891 RSS 0.376237437

R^2 0.107019 F(35,320) = 1.096 [0.332]

log-likelihood 714.597 DW 1.97

no. of observations 356 no. of parameters 36