6
7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 1/6 Recommendations  of  the  Panel on  Cost-Effectiveness in  Health  and  Medicine Milton  C.  Weinstein,  PhD;  Joanna  E.  Siegel,  ScD;  Marthe  R.  Gold,  MD, MPH;  Mark  S.  Kamlet,  PhD; Louise  B.  Russell,  PhD;  for  the  Panel  on  Cost-Effectiveness  in  Health  and  Medicine Objective.\p=m-\To develop  consensus-based  recommendations for  the  conduct  of cost-effectiveness  analysis  (CEA).  This  article,  the  second  in  a  3-part  series,  de- scribes the basis for recommendations  constituting the reference  case  analysis,  the set  of  practices  developed  to  guide  CEAs  that inform societal  resource allocation decisions,  and the  content  of these  recommendations. Participants.\p=m-\The Panel  on  Cost-Effectiveness  in  Health and  Medicine,  a nonfederal  panel  with  expertise  in  CEA,  clinical  medicine,  ethics,  and  health  out-$ comes  measurement,  was  convened  by  the  US  Public  Health  Service  (PHS). Evidence.\p=m-\The panel  reviewed the theoretical  foundations  of  CEA,  current practices,  and  alternative  methods  used  in analyses.  Recommendations  were de- veloped  on the basis  of  theory  where  possible,  but  tempered  by  ethical  and prag- matic  considerations,  as  well  as  the needs  of  users. Consensus  Process.\p=m-\The panel  developed  recommendations  through  21/2 years  of  discussions.  Comments  on  preliminary  drafts  prepared  by panel  working groups  were  solicited  from federal  government  methodologists,  health agency of- ficials,  and  academic  methodologists. Conclusions.\p=m-\The panel's methodological  recommendations  address (1)  components  belonging  in  the  numerator  and  denominator  of  a  cost\x=req-\ effectiveness  (C/E)  ratio;  (2)  measuring  resource  use  in  the  numerator  of  a  C/E ratio;  (3)  valuing  health consequences  in  the  denominator of  a  C/E  ratio;  (4)  esti- mating  effectiveness  of  interventions;  (5)  incorporating  time  preference  and dis- counting;  and  (6)  handling  uncertainty.  Recommendations  are  subject  to  the "rule of  reason,"  balancing  the  burden  engendered  by  a practice  with  its  importance  to a study.  If  researchers follow  a  standard  set  of  methods  in  CEA,  the  quality  and comparability  of  studies,  and  their  ultimate  utility,  can  be  much  improved. JAMA.  1996:276:1253-1258 COST-EFFECTIVENESS  analysis (CEA)  has  emerged  as a  basic  tool  in the  evaluation  of health  care practices. Despite  widespread application,  there  r e¬ main  disparities  in  the  methods  that investigators employ.1  Some of these dis¬ parities  can  be  traced  to  a  misunder¬ standing  of the  principles  of CEA,  while others  reflect  divergent  views  on key methodological  choices.  For example,  an investigator who fails  to  account  for  im¬ portant negative  side effects of a therapy in  estimating  effectiveness  is  making  a clear  error,  while  investigators  who  in¬ clude  or  exclude  the  financial  costs  of lost  productivity  that  accompany  ill¬ ness  are reflecting different  views of how productivity  should  be  accounted  for  in a CEA. The divergence of methods used to con- duct  CEA interferes  with  the  ability  of decision  makers  charged  with  resource allocation  to make  appropriate  compari¬ sons  of  cost-effectiveness  (C/E)  ratios across programs.  As described in the first article  of  this  series,2  this  concern about lack  of standardization  has  led  the  Panel on Cost-Effectivenessin Health and Medi¬ cine to  develop  a  set  of recommendations for the  practice  of CEA  that  can  serve as a point  of reference for  investigators who seek comparability with other analyses  in the literature.  The  panel  refers to this  set of  methodological  practices  as the  refer¬ ence  case. The reference  case will  not  address all types  of  questions  regarding  the  cost- effectiveness  of interventions.  In  some cases, depending on the goals of the analy¬ sis,  the author  may  prefer to  highlight  an analysis  based  on  a  slightly  different  set of  principles,  or  one  based  on quite  dif¬ ferent assumptions. In the interest of com¬ parability, however,  we urge that the ref¬ erence  case  set  of  assumptions  and practices  be  included in  every  CEA that is  designed  to permit broad  comparisons across interventions  or that might be used for this  purpose. The  recommendations  outlined  here, together  with  others  that  provide  more detailed methodological guidance,  are ex¬ panded  in  the  full  report  of the panel.3 While this  article  focuses  on  the  refer¬ ence  case recommendations,  we also  de¬ scribe  a  few  recommendations  that  are intended to improve the conduct of analy¬ ses  but  that  are  not  explicitly  incorpo¬ rated  within the  reference  case. RATIONALES  FOR RECOMMENDATIONS Reference  case analyses  are intended to  inform  resource  allocation  decisions and,  as described in the first article of this series,  are  conducted  from  the  societal perspective  for this reason.2  Specific  ree- From the Departments  of  Health Policy  and Man- agement  (Dr  Weinstein)  and  Maternal  and  Child Health (Dr  Siegel),  Harvard  School  of  Public  Health, Boston, Mass;  Office of  Disease  Prevention and Health Promo- tion,  US  Public  Health  Service,  Washington,  DC  (Dr Gold);  Heinz School,  Carnegie  Mellon  University,  Pitts-$ burgh,  Pa (Dr Kamlet);  and  the  Institute for  Health, Health  Care  Policy,  and Aging  Research,  Rutgers  Uni- versity,  New Brunswick,  NJ (Dr Russell). A complete  list  of  the  Panel  on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine membership  and  staff appears at the  e nd  of  this article. Corresponding  author: Marthe  Gold,  MD, MPH,  Of- fice of  Disease Prevention  and  Health  Promotion,  200 Independence  Ave  SW,  Room 738G,  Washington,  DC 20201. wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

1996 Recommendations of the Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine

Citation preview

Page 1: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 1/6

Recommendations  of the   Panelon   Cost-Effectivenessin  Health  and   MedicineMilton   C.  Weinstein,  PhD;  Joanna   E.  Siegel,   ScD;   Marthe   R.  Gold,   MD, MPH;   Mark  S.   Kamlet,  PhD;

Louise   B.  Russell,   PhD;   for   the   Panel   on   Cost-Effectiveness   in   Health   and  Medicine

Objective.\p=m-\Todevelop consensus-based recommendations for the conduct of

cost-effectiveness  analysis (CEA).  This article,   the  second   in   a 3-part series,   de-

scribes the basis for recommendations constituting the  reference case analysis, theset  of  practices developed to guide  CEAs  that inform societal   resource   allocation

decisions,  and the  content  of  these  recommendations.

Participants.\p=m-\ThePanel   on   Cost-Effectiveness   in   Health and   Medicine,   a

nonfederal  panel  with expertise   in CEA,  clinical  medicine,  ethics,  and  health  out-$

comes   measurement,   was  convened  by the   US   Public  Health  Service (PHS).Evidence.\p=m-\Thepanel   reviewed   the   theoretical   foundations   of  CEA,   current

practices, and  alternative methods  used   in analyses.  Recommendations  were de-

veloped   on the basis  of theory where possible,   but tempered by ethical  and prag-matic considerations,   as  well   as  the  needs  of   users.

Consensus   Process.\p=m-\Thepanel  developed   recommendations   through   21/2

years of  discussions.  Comments   on  preliminary drafts prepared by panel working

groups  were solicited   from federal government methodologists,   health agency of-ficials,   and  academic methodologists.Conclusions.\p=m-\Thepanel's methodological   recommendations   address

(1)   components   belonging   in   the   numerator   and   denominator   of   a   cost\x=req-\

effectiveness   (C/E)   ratio;   (2)  measuring   resource   use   in   the   numerator  of   a  C/E

ratio;  (3) valuing   health consequences   in  the  denominator of   a  C/E  ratio;  (4)  esti-

mating  effectiveness   of  interventions;   (5)   incorporating   time  preference   and dis-

counting;  and (6)  handling uncertainty.  Recommendations   are subject to  the "rule

of reason," balancing the  burden engendered by   a practice  with   its importance to

a study.   If   researchers follow   a   standard   set   of  methods   in CEA,   the  quality  and

comparability of  studies,   and  their   ultimate utility,   can   be   much  improved.JAMA.   1996:276:1253-1258

COST-EFFECTIVENESS   analysis(CEA)   has emerged   as   a   basic   tool   inthe  evaluation  of health   care practices.

Despite widespread application, there  r e¬

main  disparities   in   the   methods   that

investigators employ.1 Some of these dis¬

parities   can   be   traced   to   a   misunder¬

standing of the principles of CEA, whileothers   reflect divergent   views   on keymethodological  choices. For example,  an

investigator who fails  to  account for im¬

portant negative side effects of a therapyin estimating effectiveness   is making   a

clear  error,  while investigators who  in¬clude   or   exclude   the   financial   costs   oflost  productivity   that   accompany   ill¬

ness   are reflecting different  views of howproductivity  should  be  accounted  for in

a CEA.The divergence of methods used to con-

duct   CEA  interferes   with   the  ability  ofdecision  makers  charged   with   resource

allocation   to make appropriate compari¬sons   of   cost-effectiveness   (C/E)   ratiosacross programs. As described in the firstarticle  of this series,2 this   concern  aboutlack of standardization  has  led  the  Panelon Cost-Effectivenessin Health and Medi¬cine to develop  a  set  of recommendationsfor the practice of CEA  that   can   serve   as

a point of reference for investigators whoseek comparability with other analyses inthe literature. The panel refers to this setof methodological practices   as   the  refer¬ence   case.

The reference   case will not address all

types   of  questions   regarding   the   cost-effectiveness   of   interventions.   In   some

cases, depending on the goals of the analy¬sis, the author may prefer to highlight  an

analysis based   on   a slightly different  setof principles,   or   one  based   on quite   dif¬ferent assumptions. In the interest of com¬

parability, however,  we urge that the ref¬erence   case   set   of   assumptions   and

practices be  included in  every CEA thatis designed  to permit broad comparisonsacross interventions  or that might be usedfor this  purpose.

The   recommendations   outlined   here,together  with  others   that provide   more

detailed methodological guidance, are  ex¬

panded   in   the   full   report   of the panel.3While this   article   focuses   on   the   refer¬ence   case recommendations,   we also de¬scribe   a   few  recommendations   that   are

intended to improve the conduct ofanaly¬ses   but   that   are   not explicitly  incorpo¬rated   within the   reference   case.

RATIONALES  FORRECOMMENDATIONS

Reference   case analyses   are  intended

to   inform   resource   allocation   decisionsand,  as described in the first article of this

series,   are   conducted   from   the   societal

perspective for this reason.2 Specific  ree-

From the Departments  of   Health Policy   and   Man-agement (Dr Weinstein) and  Maternal and  Child Health

(Dr Siegel),  Harvard   School   of   Public  Health, Boston,Mass;  Office of  Disease  Prevention and  Health  Promo-tion,   US   Public   Health   Service,  Washington,   DC   (DrGold);  Heinz School, Carnegie  Mellon University,  Pitts-$

burgh,   Pa (Dr Kamlet);   and   the   Institute for   Health,Health  Care Policy,  and Aging  Research, Rutgers  Uni-

versity,   New  Brunswick,   NJ (Dr  Russell).A complete list of the  Panel   on  Cost-Effectiveness in

Health and Medicine membership and  staff appears at

the  e nd   of   this article.Corresponding   author:  Marthe  Gold,   MD, MPH,   Of-

fice  of  Disease Prevention   and   Health  Promotion,   200

Independence Ave  SW,  Room 738G, Washington,   DC20201.

wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Page 2: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 2/6

mmendations for conducting CEAs frome   societal perspective   were based   on   a

umber of considerations, including   eco¬

omic and decision theory; consistency ine accounting of costs and consequences;hical concerns; pragmatic concerns; and

eeds   of  users   of analyses.   In   some   in¬ances, where neither theory  nor theseher considerations led to   a clear choice,e  panel   recommended   a  conventional

actice for the sake ofconsistency across

udies.Where possible, recommendations were

ased on theoretical considerations in  or¬

er   to provide   a defensible,  logical,   andonsistent framework for methodologicalhoices. At   one level,  CEA   can  be  based

olely   on   the   mathematical   theory   ofptimization."4   In that formulation,  the

ecision  maker  is   free   to  select any   ob¬

ctive to maximize (eg, life-years or qual¬y-adjusted  life-years  [QALYs]) and   to

pecify the particular resource constraintnder  which

  allocations  must   be   made

g, national health  care costs). However,is  framework   alone provides   no guid¬ce   on key issues   that  arise  from   a   so¬

etal perspective, such  as  which costs toclude   in   the  analysis,  how   to   measure

osts,   and  whose   values   to  incorporateto the definition of health consequences.herefore,  drawing   from   recent   litera¬re suggesting a link between CEA andelfare  economic theory,5   the  panel   re¬

ed   on  economic theory   for many of thecommendations  for  the  reference   case.

addition to economic theory, principlesdecision theory were invoked to  definee  basis  for  individual preferences.Some recommendations were dictated

y the need to maintain  a logical account¬

g of  costs   and   health   effects.   For   ex¬

mple,   theoretical  considerations,  alongith a basic presumption about the  defi¬tion of   the   C/E   ratio,2   led   to   a   clear

ecision concerning the  placement  of allealth  effects   in the  denominator of the/E   ratio.  Then,   the  "accounting" prin¬ple   that   no   cost   or   effect   should   be

ounted twice disallowed the inclusion ofealth effects—even in

monetaryform—

the  numerator of   the C/E  ratio.The implications of welfare  economics

ere   often   modified   in   the   interest ofoducing   recommendations   that   were

oth pragmatic and ethically acceptable.he practicalneed to obtain data on healthtcomes,  utilization of services and unit

sts, and weights for health-related qual-y-of-life (HRQL) states led to such  com¬

omises.   For   example,   while   medicalces   are  not   an  exact  reflection  of the

ue value of resources, pragmatism sug¬ests that prices be used to approximate

sts except where   distortions   are likelybe  significant   and   important   to   thealysis.Ethical considerations sometimes tem-

pered   recommendations   based   on   eco¬

nomic theory   or were decisive in  choices

among alternatives.  Most fundamentally,the  decision  to   use QALYs   as  the  effec¬tiveness   measure   reflects the   ethicalstance that QALYs accruing  to differentpeople or at different stages in life shouldbe valued equally,   even though  welfareeconomics   implies   that   health benefitsshould be weighted by willingness to pay.

Where   theory   did   not   offer   a   clearchoice, the panel based  some recommen¬

dations   simply   on   the   need   for   a   clearconvention   to  which analysts  would   ad¬here in the reference   case. In some cases,the   recommendation   was somewhat   ar¬

bitrary. For example, the choice of a stan¬dard time discount rate, while guided bytheory and data, is  fixed by the  need fora  standard practice.

Finally, needs of the potential   users ofCEAs   influenced several   recommenda¬

tions, playing   a particularly  great role inthe

 panel's recommendations for  the   re¬

porting of CEAs   as described in the  thirdarticle of this  series.6 They  also  enteredinto  the  recommendations regarding theevidence of effectiveness used in analysesand the treatment of uncertainty. For ex¬

ample, sensitivity analyses,which explorethe  implications   of   alternative   assump¬tions and data, are  often recommended  so

that  decision makers   can gain confidencein  the  conclusions of  a n analysis   or  iden¬

tify   areas   for  further investigation.While   some  of the  reference   case rec¬

ommendations address   common  errors in

the practice  of CEA,  many   more repre¬sent   the panel's  view  of the  best  amongseveral defensible choices. The task of de¬

veloping  CEA  standards is  analogous  tothe formulation of the   consumer price in¬dex   (CPI),   which   is   used   to   adjust   forinflation  based   on   the prices  of  a typicalmarket basket of goods and services. Thechoice of what items go  into that marketbasket,  and  how they   are weighted,   re¬

flects judgments  made by  the  Bureau ofLabor Statistics and  its advisors. Legiti¬mate   opposing   views   exist.7  However,there   is   an

implied  consensus   that   the

CPI   will  be   used   so   that industry,   gov¬ernment, and consumers can have a shared

understanding   of   the   inflation   rate.   In¬

deed, flows of resources,  such  as  the levelof  Social  Security   payments,   depend   in

part   on the  CPI. While this country doesnot base policy directly   on  C/E ratios   as

it  does with   the CPI,   it   is important formany   decision  makers   to be  able   to relyon   a dependable yardstick for measuringcost-effectiveness  of health  services.

RECOMMENDATIONS

The   panel's   recommendations falllargely  into   8  categories:   (1)   the   natureand   limits   of  CEA  and of the   reference

case;   (2)   components  belonging   in   the

numerator and the denominator of a C/Eratio; (3) measuring terms in the  numera¬

tor of  a  C/E  ratio (costs); (4) valuing thehealth   consequences in   the denominatorof   a   C/E   ratio;   (5) estimating  effective¬ness of interventions; (6) time preferenceand discounting; (7) handling uncertaintyin CEA; and (8) reporting guidelines. Thefirst group  of recommendations, regard¬ing   the   nature   and   limits   of  CEA,   has

been described in  the  first article  of thisseries.2 The last group, regarding report¬ing guidelines, is  the subject of the  thirdarticle.6 Additional recommendations   re¬

garding   research   to  develop   improveddata for CEA  and improved methods   are

described  in  the   full report of the panel.8This article  summarizes the  remaining 6

categories of recommendations.

Components Belonging   in   theNumerator  and   the   Denominatorof   a  C/E   Ratio

Cost-effectiveness analysisrestson

theproposition that  a  decision maker wishesto select programs  so as to maximize some

desired   objective subject   to   a   resource

constraint.   In   practice,   CEA  in   healthcare  has  been based   on the premise thathealth  benefits   are the  objective that   so¬

cietal decision makers wish to maximize,subject to  a  constraint   on health   care   re¬

sources.   This  formulation   leads  directlyto the construction of a C/E ratio in whichthe   net expenditure   of   health   care   re¬

sources (a monetary measure) goes in thenumerator and   the   net improvement   in

health (a nonmonetary measure) goes inthe   denominator.

Unfortunately, however, this definitionis incomplete.   It leaves  open   to questionwhether  certain  costs  and  consequencesshould be thought of  as  health   care  costsor savings (numerator),   or health decre¬ments   or improvements  (denominator),and it completely ignores nonhealth costsand effects, such as those associated witheconomic productivity, the environment,or education. Therefore, ifanalyses  are tohandle such issues consistently, the choicebetween numerator

(resource impact)and

denominator   (HRQL   impact)   must   fol¬low an established convention. In any case,the  societal perspective  dictates   that all

important impacts   on human  health andon   resources   must   be   included   some¬

where,   either   in   the   numerator   or   thedenominator. With this principle in mind,the  panel  reached   the  following   recom¬

mendations regarding the distinction be¬tween  costs  and health   consequences.

By  convention,   the denominator   of   a

C/E   ratio   is   reserved   for   the   improve¬ment in  health   associated  with   an   inter¬

vention. Thus,  effects of an   interventionon length of life and  o n morbidity,  includ¬

ing   the   full   value   of HRQL   to patients,should be incorporated in  the  denomina-

wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Page 3: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 3/6

tor.   In   order   to   avoid   double   counting,monetary values for lost life-years shouldnot be imputed in CEA and should not beincluded in  the  numerator of the  C/E   ra¬

tio. For a reference  case analysis, HRQLshould be captured by a   measure that, ata minimum,   implicitly  incorporates   theeffects of morbidity   on productive  timeand   leisure.  When  instruments   used   tomeasure health states  ar e silent  concern¬

ing   the consideration  of lost income,   weassume   that  financial  effects   have  beenconsidered by the respondent and that itis therefore not necessary  to  account forthese   effects   in   the   numerator.  Prefer¬ences  for health  states ideally should  beelicited using health status  measures that

explicitly  invite respondents to  considerthe   full   range   of impacts   of   the healthstatus   change,   including   loss   of   incomeand   leisure  activities.

Currently,   some   instruments   used   tomeasure health  states explicitly excludeconsideration  of lost  income.

 Moreover,methods that  measure changes in HRQLin monetary   terms,   such   as contingentvaluation (willingness  to  pay),  have  alsobeen  used.   While   these   approaches   are

technically valid,   a  CEA   in  which   these

practices were used would not constitutea   reference   case analysis.

The numerator of a C/E  ratio captureschanges  in   resource   use   associated  withan  intervention.  The major categories ofresource   use  that  should be  included   are

costs of health   care services; costs  of pa¬tient time expended for the intervention;costs  associated with caregiving (paid   or

unpaid);   other   costs   associated   with   ill¬

ness,   such   as   child   care   and   travel   ex¬

penses; economic costs borne by employ¬ers,   other   employees,   and   the   rest   of

society, including  so-called   friction   costsassociated with absenteeism and employeeturnover8; and  costs associated with   non-

health impacts  of the   intervention,   suchas  on the educational system, the criminal

 justice system,   or the  environment.The handling  of patient   time   in  CEA

presents  challenges   and   is   the   focus   ofseveral reference case recommendations.Time spent by individuals seeking healthcare   or undergoing   an  intervention   is   a

component of  the  intervention, and   thusit   should   be   valued   in monetary   termsand incorporated   into   the   numerator  ofthe C/E ratio. Time spent sick (morbiditytime) is part of the  health  outcome   mea¬

sured in  the denominator of the CEA,  as

described above.   In   some   instances (eg,when recuperating   from  surgery),   timecould  be categorized either   as morbiditytime (valued in the denominator)  or  as  a n

input   to   the   intervention   itself  (costed

out  in  the  numerator);   as   a general rule,this   time   should   be  considered   as   mor¬

bidity time. These recommendations  a re

not based  on any fundamental theoretical

consideration,  but   are   made   for   consis¬

tency   across  reference   case analyses.

Measuring  Terms   in  the  Numeratorof   a  C/E  Ratio (Costs)

A change in the use of a resource caused

by a health intervention should be valuedat its opportunity cost, which is the  valuethe resource could have produced if it were

spent in its best available alternative  use.

In  economics,   this  principle   is   the   basisfor valuing  resource flows in society.

Several implications arise from the  op¬portunity   cost  principle.  First,   it   is   thedifference   in   resource   use   between   an

intervention   and   the   intervention   withwhich it is being compared that should beincluded  in  the  numerator of the  C/E   ra¬

tio.  That is,  costs should reflect the   mar¬

ginal  or incremental  resources consumedor saved,   rather   than   total   resources.

Fixed costs—costs unaffected by the levelof  implementation   of   an  intervention—should

  generally  be   excluded   from

consideration.  However,   resource   costsshould be measured from  a long-term per¬spective, which implies that  many  coststhat  may  be  fixed in  the  short   run  (suchas most of what is usually considered over¬

head   in   the   financial   accounts   of hospi¬tals and  other health   care providers)   are

in fact variable in the long run and  shouldbe included in  CEAs.

Direct   measurement   of  opportunitycosts is  difficult  and  often impossible. Tothe  extent that market prices of health¬care inputs reflect opportunity costs, they

provide  an appropriate means for valuingchanges   in   resources. According   to   eco¬

nomic theory, prices in  competitive   mar¬

kets reflect opportunity costs of resources.

However,  when prices do not adequatelyreflect opportunity costs because of mar¬

ket  distortions, they   should  be adjustedappropriately.  Examples of adjustmentscommonly used in  CEAs  include the   use

of ratios  of  cost   to charge (RCCs)  to   ad¬

 just hospital prices,   the   use  of  manage¬ment   accounting   systems   to   estimate

costs, and the use ofthird-party paymentsto

 providers in   lieu of fees to  reflect

 pro¬vider  opportunity   costs.  When  substan¬tial  bias   is present  in prices  and adjust¬ment is not feasible, the panel recommendsthat   more   suitable  proxies   for  opportu¬nity costs be considered, includingthe pos¬sibility of conducting "microcosting" stud¬ies  within provider organizations.  (Suchstudies collect information on the range of

inputs  to   a service,  such   as  the nursingcare, supplies, and ancillary services  con¬

stituting   a day of hospital care.)Costs should be  measured  in  constant

dollars,   that  is,  in   the  dollars  of   a   fixed

year.  When the original data   are for dif¬ferent  years,  the effect of price  inflationmust be removed, either by inflating thedata from   an   earlier  year   to the   chosen

year  or by deflating the data from   a later

year. Dependingon whether the resources

being valued   are   more representative of

goods and services in the economy at largeor  in the  medical   care  sector,  either   theCPI   or   its medical   care component(s)   issuitable for inflation adjustment in CEAs.

Transfer payments (such as cash trans¬fers from taxpayers to welfare recipients)associated  with  a  health intervention   re¬

distribute  resources   from   one   individualto another. While administrative costs  as¬

sociated with such transfers  could  be  in¬cluded   in  the   numerator  of   a  C/E   ratio,the   transfers   themselves   should   not be

since, by  definition,   their impact   on   thetransferor   and   the   recipient   cancel   outfrom   the  societal perspective.

Time  costs for individuals in the laborforce  should generally  be  valued by   the

wage   rate   as   an acceptable   measure   of

opportunity   cost   of   time.   The   referencecase recommendation is to  us e wages  cor¬

responding to   the

  age and

 gender  com¬

position   of  the target  population.   How¬

ever, group-specific wages may influencethe  conclusions of an analysis in ethicallyproblematic ways. For example,  a policy¬maker might object   to having  the  wagedifferential between   men and   women   re¬

flected in  the   results  of  a  CEA.   In these

instances,  sensitivity analyses   should  beconducted   to explore  the  specific  natureof this  influence.  Because of such ethical

concerns,  and  because  of practical prob¬lems in obtaining data   on wages by char¬acteristics other than age and gender, the

panel  does  not   recommend using  wagesspecific  to target groups defined by race,ethnicity,   or  other   characteristics.

Wage rates generally do not adequatelyreflect   the  value  of time   for persons   en¬

gaged primarily   in   leisure—such   as re¬

tired  persons—or  in  activities   for which

they are notcompensated—such as house¬hold activities. Average age- and gender-specific  wages  among  persons   in   the   la¬bor force may  be applied to approximatethe opportunity  cost  of  time   for  personsof similar age and gender not in the  laborforce.

Should   health   care   costs   that   resultsolely   from   the   fact   that   a successfullytreated patient lives longer be attributed

to the  health intervention? Which futurecosts should  be   included  in   a  CEA?   For

example,   a  cost-effective analysis  of   an-

tihypertensive therapy found that exclud¬

ing noncardiovascular disease costs in fu¬ture years would reduce the C/E ratio by5% to  20%, with the greatest impacts   on

the ratios for younger population groups.9To clarify the  issues,   we define  5 catego¬ries of induced costs that may   or may  not

be germane in  a  CEA. These are (1) costsfor intervention-related diseases incurredin years oflife that would have been lived

anyway; (2)   costs   for  unrelated   diseases

wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Page 4: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 4/6

hat are incurred in years of life that wouldave been  lived   anyway;   (3) health   care

osts   for related   diseases   that   ensue   in

ears   of life   added   (or subtracted)   as   a

esult of the intervention, (4) health   care

osts for unrelated diseases that   occur in

ears oflife added (or subtracted) by the

ntervention, and (5) nonhealth care costs

ypified by commodities such  as  food andhelter  that   occur in  years  of life  added

or subtracted) by  the   intervention.The handling of   some  of these catego¬

es  of  costs   is   uncontroversial.  Costs  ofelated   diseases  in   the original  life   spanlearly  must be   included  in  the  analysis.

For example,   costs   and  savings  associ¬ted with treatment of strokes and myo-ardial   infarctions   must   be   included in

nalyses ofhypertension programs.  Costsf treating  adverse effects  of  treatment

must  be   included   as   well.   On   the  other

and, because unrelated health and   non-

ealth   care   costs  occurring throughouthe

 expected years lived without the  in¬

ervention would  cancel   from   the   incre¬mental cost calculation in  the  numerator

f  the   C/E   ratio,   these   may  be   omittedom the analysis. It may actually bepref¬rable   to omit  these  unrelated  costs  be¬ause their measurement may  add to  er¬

or   in   the estimation   of  costs   with   andwithout  the   intervention.

Costs for intervention-related diseaseshat   occur in added years of life   are typi¬ally included in  CEAs. For example, if a

atal myocardial   infarction   is  delayed   5

ears by   a coronary bypass operation   or

cholesterol-lowering regimen, the costsf   treating   coronary   events   ensuing

hroughout   the   5  years   should  be,   and

sually  are,  included. Similarly,   costs  ofn ongoing   therapy   throughout   added

ears   of life,  such   as lifelong antihyper-ensive treatment and its medication side

ffects,   are always  included.Costs  of  diseases  unrelated   to the   in¬

ervention and ensuing as a result of added

ears of life have been the   source of more

ebate.4,5,10"12  Difficulties  with the   choiceo include  o r exclude them  ar e illustrated

y the

 example of a

cholesterol-loweringntervention. The analyst might decide toxclude  all  unrelated  costs  occurring   in

ears   of life gained  because  of  the   pro¬ram.  In this  case, costs of illnesses suchs arthritis and Alzheimer disease woulde excluded. However, age-specific "back¬

round" costs of coronary heart disease—hat   is,   the level   of  disease   that   would

ccur among people   who   are   not   candi¬ates for the  intervention—are also "un¬elated"   to   the   intervention   and  shouldlsobe excluded. To neglect to do so would

rovide   an   uneven playing field for   com¬

arisons of interventions affecting differ¬nt diseases: life-prolonging heart disease

nterventions  would be encumbered withll   future   costs   of heart   disease   even

though they only target   an excess risk,while suicide prevention programs wouldnot. To avoid the practical and conceptualproblems in disengagingthe "related" and"unrelated" elements of costs for "related"

diseases,   it   would   be   preferable   to   in¬clude all these costs. However, this choicewould   impose   a  burden   on   the  analystfrequently not warranted by  the  impor¬tance of future   costs.

Because there  are unresolved theoreti¬cal and empirical questions  and  becausehealth care costs in added years of life  are

typically  small compared with the  othercosts  in   an analysis,   the panel   concludedthat   the   reference   case may   either   in¬clude   or  exclude   these   costs.   Wheneverthe investigator has reason to believe thatinclusion or exclusion offuture health care

costs   may  make   a significant  differenceto   the   analysis,   a sensitivity   analysisshould be performed to   assess the effecton   the C/E   ratio.

We   now consider nonhealth   care costsin  added life-years. Although there  is   no

precedent   in   CEA   for  including   these

costs,   one  could reasonably argue that ifhealth   care   costs   in   added  years   can  be

included,   future   expenditures   on food,clothing,   and   shelter   should   also   be   in¬cluded. The theoretical answer is that thenet economic burden of survivors   on  therest  of society (consumption minus  pro¬ductivity) should indeed be included  a s a

cost.  However,   if   these   nonhealth   care

costs   are truly   "unrelated,"   then   theirconsistent inclusion   or  exclusion  would

only add   or subtract   a constant from theC/E ratio.5 Whether nonhealth  care costsare   in   fact   "unrelated,"   or   at   least   ap¬proximately  so,  is   an unresolved empiri¬cal question. Nonetheless, on the assump¬tion   that   these   costs   can reasonably  beconsidered   to be  unrelated  and  to avoid

placing an unnecessaryburden on the ana¬

lyst,   the  panel   does   not recommend   in¬

cluding future nonhealth care costs in ref¬erence   case analyses.

Valuing  the   Health Consequencesin   the Denominator  of  a  C/E  Ratio

As  discussed in the   first article of thisseries,2   a reference   case analysis  shouldmeasure health effectiveness in  terms of

QALYs.   These   QALYs   incorporatechanges in survival and changes in HRQLby weighting years   of Ufe to  reflect   thevalue of the HRQL during each year.13,14In order to be consistent with the QALY

construct,   the  quality weights   must   bemeasured by   or  transformed  into  the  in¬terval  scale   on  which optimal health  hasa  value  of   1   and death  has   a  value  of  0.

The weights used in QALYs should be

based   on a health-state classification sys¬tem that   reflects health-related  domains(attributes) that are important for the par¬ticular analysis.   In order   to qualify   as   a

reference   case analysis,  the  CEA  shoulduse   a generic   health-state   classification,that is,   a classification that appliesbroadlyacross  diseases   and  conditions.  Disease-

specific health-state classifications  are ap¬propriate for a reference case analysis pro¬vided that they are designed to bemappedonto   or   embedded  within   a generic   sys¬tem.   Some  examples  of commonly  usedhealth-state   classification   systems   that

may   be   suitable   for   CEA   include   theHealth Utilities Index,14,15 the EuroQol,16the Quality of Well-Being Scale,17 and theYears   of  Healthy   Life   measure.18   TheHealth Utilities Index, for example,   con¬

sists of 8 domains (vision, hearing, speech,dexterity, mobility, cognition, emotion, and

pain),  each  of  which   is   classified   into   ei¬ther  5   or   6   levels.   Each   combination   oflevels   is assigned   a weight,  using   a   for¬mula based on multiattribute utility theoryand   a community preference survey.13,14

The weights used in QALYs should bebased on

 preferencesfor health states. In

a reference   case analysis,  these weightsshould   be based   on community  prefer¬ences, rather than those of patients, pro¬viders,  or investigators. The rationale for

community   preferences   has   been   de¬scribed in   the   first article  of this  series.2Health  status   scales that   are  not prefer¬ence weighted,  such   as the  Medical Out¬comes Study Short-Form Health Survey(SF-36),19   are   not   suitable   for   CEA   intheir present form.   Use  of patient pref¬erences to  value health  states is  accept¬able in a reference case analysis only when

adequate  information   is   unavailable   re¬

garding community preferences.The weights assigned to  health  states

should   be   interval   scaled;   that   is,   themethod of measurement should be  o ne inwhich   the   ratio of  differences betweenvalues   is   meaningful.   (By analogy,   the

Fahrenheit, Celsius, and Kelvin scales  are

equivalent  and appropriate   measures  of

temperature,   because   the   intervals   be¬tween degrees reflect meaningful differ¬ences   in temperature.) According   to de¬cision theory, preferenceweights obtainedfrom standard

 gamble questions and, un¬

der certain conditions, time trade-offques¬tions satisfy the interval property. At thesame time, psychometric   research   sug¬

gests   that rating  scales   can produce  in¬terval   data. These   claims   are  mutuallyinconsistent, since there is apparently nota linear relationship between rating scalesand   standard   gambles   or   time   trade¬offs.20,21

It remains   an open question whetherstandard  gambles,   time  trade-offs,   rat¬

ing  scales,   or   other   measures   such   as

person  trade-offs22 produce   the   closest

approximation   to   the   type   of  interval-scaled weights needed  for QALYs.  For

example,   some   research  suggests   that

respondents  may  introduce  distortions

wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Page 5: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 5/6

into responses   to utility questions  suchas   the  standard gamble,   compromisingtheir theoretical desirability. Therefore,the   panel   does   not   recommend   one

source   of weights   over   the  others;   forpurposes  of the reference  case, prefer¬ence weights   can   come   from   measure¬

ment systems  that rely   on any  of these

techniques. The discrepancies associatedwith   different   measurement strategiespose  a problem for  standardization  thatwill   be important   to  address   in   futureresearch.

To   date,   most   CEAs  using  QALYshave  assumed   that   a year of life gainedby an intervention is valued at 1.0 QALY.In fact, people   are rarely in  the  state ofoptimal health that a full QALY implies;the  u se of a value of 1.0 for years that lifeis prolonged will therefore  overstate   an

intervention's   effectiveness   and under¬estimate the   true  C/E ratio.   The panelrecommends   that,   when   calculating

QALYs gained from  a

life-extending  in¬tervention,   estimates   of age-   and   sex-

specific HRQL   should  be applied   to the

years of extended  life—even if the inter¬vention itself has  no  effect on HRQL. Simi¬larly, when estimating QALYs gained byameliorating  disease symptoms,   a   re¬

turn to average rather than optimal HRQLshould be credited. It should be noted thatthis   use  of average quality  of life   in  ref¬erence   case analyses   means   that studies

using   ratios of   cost   per   year   (unad¬ justed)   of   life   saved   will   not be   compa¬rable   to  reference   case   results.

Sociodemographic characteristics, suchas age,   sex,   or race,   are  associated  with

HRQL.  When the QALYs produced byan   intervention  vary   as   a result of these

sociodemographic differences, referencecase results  a re affected in ways that maybe ethically problematic. For example, an

intervention  that extends the lives of 80-

year-olds may appear less cost-effectivethan an equally effective intervention ap¬plied   to 20-year-olds,   not only   becausefewer years   are gained, but  also becausethe average quality of those years  is  less.

In these  instances,  sensitivity analysesshould   be   conducted   to   indicate  explic¬itly  how   results   are   affected.

Estimating   Effectivenessof Interventions

The quality  and validity of  a  CEA  de¬

pend crucially   on   the  quality  of the   un¬

derlying data that describe the effective¬ness   of interventions   and   the   course   ofillness   without   intervention.   Data   maybe obtained from primary data collectionefforts specifically intended to  inform theCEA or from secondary data sources. The

appropriatenessof various  sources of datawill depend on the purpose of a CEA. The

consequences   of   misestimation   of   cost-effectiveness may   be regarded   as   more

serious by some decision makers than byothers.  For example, the  Food and DrugAdministration  might   desire   a  greaterlevel   of  certainty   in   distinguishing   thecost-effectiveness  of  very  similar drugsfor the   purpose   of reviewing marketingclaims than   a formulary manager mightdemand  in adopting   a   new drug.

For  the   purpose   of   a   reference   case

analysis,  acceptable  data   for  estimation

of effectiveness  may  come from  a varietyof   sources:  randomized   controlled  trials,observational   studies,   uncontrolled   ex¬

periments,  or descriptive series. The  ana¬

lyst  should  select  outcome probabilitiesfrom the best-designed (and least-biased)sources that   are relevant to the questionand  population   under  study.  There   are

often trade-offs between the  internal   va¬

lidity   of  data   (optimized   in randomizedtrials)   and   their   external  validity   in   ac¬

tual practice. Meta-analysis and other syn¬thesis methods can be used when no single

study has sufficient power  to  detect  ef¬fects   or when studies produce conflictingresults. Expert judgment should be used

only   as placeholders  where   no adequateempirical data exist,   or when the  param¬eter ofinterest plays only  a minor role inthe  analysis.

Modeling is  a  valid and necessary sci¬entific procedure   for   estimating   effec¬tiveness  for  CEA. Typically,  data  fromrandomized trials  a re combined with ob¬servational data  and public  health   sta¬tistics   in  models   that   are  used   to   esti¬mate   changes   in   life expectancy   and

quality-adjusted  life expectancy.   Mod¬els may incorporate features  such  a s lo¬

gistic  regression   to  estimate   incidenceof  disease   or   death  contingent   on   risk

factors;  Bayesian analysis   to  estimate

posttest   probabilities   of   disease   fromdata   on sensitivity,   specificity,   and

prevalence; and  life-table analysis to  es¬

timate   life expectancy   from   survivalcurves.   Models   include  population   andcohort models, deterministic and proba¬bilistic   models,   decision   analysis   andstate-transition  models. Because of lim¬

ited   time   horizons   and  selected  studypopulations in  clinical studies, failure touse  models to extrapolate from primarydata   can   lead   to greater   error than themodels   themselves   would introduce.Models should be  used   as complementsto, not substitutes for, direct primary or

secondary empirical evaluation of effec¬tiveness. Readers   are   referred   to   thefull report of  the panel for   more  discus¬sion   of the   roles   of particular  types   ofdata  and   models   in  CEA.3

Time Preference  and   Discounting

Interest   rates   reflect people's prefer¬ence forhaving money and material goodssooner rather than later. Similarly, people

value  health   outcomes   that   occur   in   dif¬ferent  time periods differently.   In CEA,time preference for  resources is reflected

by  discounting   future   costs   to  presentvalue. Discounting the value of future  ex¬

penditures requires that health effects ex¬

perienced in the future also be discountedat the   same rate. This conclusion is basedon  the observation   that people   have   op¬portunities to exchange money for health,and vice versa, throughout their Uves. Fail¬ure to  discount health  effects will lead   toinconsistent   choices   over time;   for   ex¬

ample, it will appear that delaying invest¬ments   will always   result   in   a program'sbecoming more cost-effective. For this rea¬

son and based   on other evidence and  con¬

siderations  outlined in its   full report,3 the

panel recommends that   costs  and  healthoutcomes occurring during different time

periods should be discounted to their pres¬ent   value   and   that   they   should   be   dis¬counted   at the   same   rate.

Although   a   wide  variety   of   discountrates are used in the literature and  ca n be

defended,   a   convention   is   needed   toachieve consistencyacross analyses. Theo¬retical   considerations suggest   that   thereal   (inflation-adjusted)   discount   rateshould  be  based   on   time preference,  thedifference in value people assign to events

occurring  in   the  present   vs   the   future.

Further,  economic theory suggests   thattime preference is reflected in  the  rate ofreturn   on riskless,  long-term   securities.

Empirical evidence is consistent with thisrate's being in  the  vicinity of  3%  per   an¬

num (net of inflation). Direct evidence  o n

time preferences   for  health   outcomes   isalso consistent with a discount rate of 3%.

The panel   therefore   recommends   theuse   of   a real,   3%   discount   rate   in thereference   case.   Before   discounting,   allcosts should be adjusted for inflation. Be¬cause many published CEAs have used a

discount rate of5%, future analyses shouldinclude   sensitivity analysis using  5%   as

well   as other  rates in the  range  of 0%   to7%. The discount rate should be reviewedand possibly   revised  periodically,   to   re¬

flect important changes in  economic  con¬ditions.  To   ensure   that analyses will   re¬

main comparable, however, both 3%  and5% should continue to be used for at leastthe   next   10 years.

Handling  Uncertainty   in   CEA

Cost-effectiveness analyses are subjectto uncertainty  with regard   to estimatesof   effectiveness,   the   course   of   illness,HRQL   consequences   and   preferences,and health   care utilization and  costs.  Us¬ers   of analysis   need  information   on   the

degree  to  which CEA  conclusions mightchange   with changes   in  assumptions   or

values.

Sensitivity analysis   is   an appropriatetool  with which   to   respond   to this   need.

wnloaded From: http://jama.jamanetwork.com/ by a New York University User on 06/04/2015

Page 6: Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

7/21/2019 Costo efectividad en salud y medicina

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/costo-efectividad-en-salud-y-medicina 6/6

The   simplest  method,   which   should   besed in  all  CEAs, is   a univariate (1-way)ensitivity analysis, in which estimates  or

ssumptions   are changed   one   at   a   time.hese establish where uncertainty or lackf agreement about some key parameter'salue   could   have   substantial   impact   on

he   conclusion   of   a   CEA.  They suggestreas  where  efforts   to  obtain   additionalata might be warranted in  terms of  im¬

act   on  decisions  and, conversely,   areas

where additional precision would  be   un¬

kely to change results. For example, thestimated  cost-effectiveness  of thrombo-

ytic therapy  in   older patients  with   sus¬

pected myocardial  infarction   was  showno be stable when the efficacy of therapy,he  prevalence   of myocardial  infarction,

or the incidence of stroke was varied, thus

uggesting that further research to evalu¬ate the risks and benefits of streptokinasen   this  age group   was  not warranted.23

One-way  sensitivity   analyses   under¬

tate the overall uncertainty in

 the C/E

atio; therefore, analysts should also  con¬

uct  multivariate (multiway) sensitivityanalyses,  in  which   several estimates   or

assumptions   are changed   at   the   same

me,   for   important   parameters.   If pos¬sible,  a  reasonable confidence interval   or

credible interval for  the C/E ratio shouldbe  estimated  based  either   on  statisticalmethods   or   on   simulation. The value   ofmultivariate sensitivity analysis is great¬est  when there   is   reason   to believe thatestimation  errors for key parameters are

correlated,   for  example,   if   studies   that

overestimated the effectiveness of throm-bolysis  also tended  to  underestimate the

associated  risk of stroke.  Several  meth¬ods for performing such statistical analy¬ses and  simulations   are described  in  the

panel's  full report.3CONCLUSION

The panel recognizes that many of therecommended methodological approachesare  not broadly practiced at present, andthere   may  be  gaps   in   the  availability  of

data   to satisfy the  criteria   for the  refer¬ence  case. For example, there is  no  broadconsensus on which health-state classifi¬cation systems   are suitable for CEA, andvalues   of community-based weights   forsome systems   are  not publicly available.The ability to weight years of life by popu¬lation averages of community preferenceweights   is  limited by  the   lack  of  appro¬priate (age-  and  sex-specific) populationdata   for   some   systems.   In   the   area   ofcosts,   there   are   no  well-accepted  meth¬ods  for  determining   time  costs   for   indi¬

viduals outside the labor

 force, and  few

good-quality data on resource use, reflect¬

ing costs rather than charges and clearlyapplicable to the populations under study,are readily available   to analysts.

The intention of these recommendationsis to move the field of CEA  closer to stan¬dardization in   the   near term where  pos¬sible   and   to  identify   desirable   practicewhere optimal methods  are  not currentlyfeasible. All of these recommendations forthe reference  case, and  for CEAs in  gen¬eral,   are subject   to   a   "rule   of   reason."When   a parameter  estimate   or   an   ele¬

ment of the analysis is unlikely to have  an

appreciable   effect   on   the  result,   then   it

may be acceptable to  us e shortcuts  to ob¬tain them; expert opinion may  be used toassess them;   or they   may   be   excludedfrom   the  analysis altogether. Examplesmay include the weightsassigned to short-term   and   mild   impairments   of  HRQL,costs   of  unrelated health   care   in   added

years  of life,   or  the  incidence   or  costs  ofminor side effects of treatments. The ruleof   reason applies   if the   cost  of obtainingmore precise estimates of the parameterin   question   would   exceed   the   value   of

achieving more precision in the final cost-effectiveness   result.  However,   the   bur¬den is  on the analyst to justify suboptimalmethods  of parameter  estimation   or   ex¬

clusion of effects   from   an analysis.Ifresearchers endeavor to follow a stan¬

dard set of methods in CEA and to obtainthe required inputs fortheir studies, muchwill have been accomplished toward   im¬

proving the  utility of this   form  of analy¬sis. It is hoped that the recommendationscontained   here   will   stimulate

  rapidprogress   toward availability  of  the   nec¬

essary data and tools,  so that the practiceof CEA   can soon  become   as  establishedas many other forms of scientific inquiry.

The Panel   on  Cost-Effectiveness   in Health   andMedicine membership  and   staff:   Norman   Daniels,PhD;   Dennis   G.  Fryback,   PhD;   Alan   M.   Garber,MD, PhD;   Marthe   R.  Gold,   MD,  MPH;   David   C.

Hadorn,   MD;   Mark   S.   Kamlet,   PhD; JosephLipscomb,  PhD;   Bryan   R.   Luce,   PhD;   Jeanne   S.

Mandelblatt, MD, MPH;   Willard   G.  Manning,  Jr,PhD;   Donald   L.   Patrick,  PhD;   Louise   B.  Russell,PhD; Joanna  E.  Siegel, ScD; George  W.  Torrance,PhD;  Milton   C. Weinstein,  PhD.

We thank Kristine   I. McCoy, MPH, for coordina¬

tion, research, and  editorial assistance in  associationwith   this project.

References

.  Udvarhelyi S,   Colditz GA,   Rai  A,  Epstein  AM.Cost-effectiveness and   cost-benefit analyses in themedical  literature:   are the  methods being used   cor-

ectly?   Ann  Intern   Med.  1992;116:238-244..   Russell   LB,   Gold   MR, Siegel   JE,   Daniels   N,

Weinstein MC, for the  Panel  on  Cost-Effectivenessn   Health  and  Medicine. The   role  o f cost-effective-

ess analysis in  health  and  medicine.  JAMA.  1996;76:1172-1177..   Gold MR, Siegel JE, Russell LB, Weinstein MC,ds.  Cost-Effectiveness   in   Health and   Medicine.

New  York,   NY: Oxford  University Press;  1996.

.   Weinstein MC, Stason WB.  Foundations of cost\x=req-\ffectiveness analysis  for  health  and  medical  prac-ces.  N  Engl  J  Med.  1977;296:716-721..   Garber  AM,  Phelps   CE.   Economic   foundationsf   cost-effectiveness  analysis.   J   Health   Econ.   In

ress..  Siegel JE, Weinstein MC, Russell LB, Gold MR,or the   Panel   on  Cost-Effectiveness  in  Health  and

Medicine. Recommendations for reporting cost-ef-ectiveness  analyses.   JAMA.   In  press..   Newhouse JP. Medical   care   costs:   how   much

welfare   loss?  J  Econ  Perspect.  1992;6:3-21..  Koopmanschap MA,  Rutten  FFH,   van   Ineveld

BM,   van Roijen   L.   The   friction   cost   method   for

measuring indirect costs of disease. J Health  Econ.

1995;14:171-189.9.   Weinstein   MC,   Stason   WB.  Hypertension:   A

Policy Perspective.  Cambridge, Mass: Harvard Uni-versity  Press;   1976.10.   Drummond   MF,  Stoddart  GL,  Torrance   GW.Methods for   the  Economic  Evaluation  of  HealthCare Programmes. Oxford, England:  Oxford   Uni-versity  Press;   1987.11.   Russell   LB. Is   Prevention Better   Than   Cure?

Washington,   DC:  Brookings   Institution;   1986.12.   Meltzer DO. Accounting for future costs in medi-

cal cost-effectivenessanalysis.J Health Econ. In press.13.   Torrance  GW,  Feeny  D.   Utilities  and  quality-$adjusted   life   years.   Int   J   Technol   Assess   HealthCare.  1989;5:559-575.14.   Patrick   DL,   Erickson   P.   Health   Status andHealth Policy: Allocating Resources to Health Care.New   York,  N Y:  Oxford  University Press;   1993.15.   Torrance GW, Boyle MH, Horwood  SP.  Appli-cation   of  multiattribute utility   theory   to   measure

social preferences for health states. Operations Res.

1982;30:1043-1069.16.   EuroQol Group. EuroQol:  a  new facility for themeasurement of health-related quality of life. HealthPolicy.   1990;16:199.

17.   Kaplan   RM,   Anderson   JP.   A  general   healthpolicy model: update and applications. Health  ServRes.   1988;23:203-235.18.   Erickson   P,   Wilson   R,   Shannon   I.   Years   ofHealthy Life. Hyattsville, Md:  Centers  for DiseaseControl and Prevention, National Center for HealthStatistics;   1995. Dept   of Health   and Human   Ser-vices publication (PHS)  95-1237.19.   Ware  JE Jr, Sherbourne CD. The  MOS 36-ItemShort-Form Health Survey, I: conceptual frameworkand   item selection.   Med  Care.   1992;30:473-483.20.   Torrance   GW.   Social   preference   for   health

states:   an empirical  evaluation   of three   measure-

ment techniques.   Socio-economic  Plann Sci.  1976;10:129-136.21.   Read   JL,  Quinn   RJ,   Berwick  DM,   FinebergHV,   Weinstein   MC.   Preferences   for   health   out-$comes: comparison   of  assessment   methods.   MedDecis Making.  1984;4:315-329.22.   Nord  E.  Methods for quality adjustment of life

years.   Soc Sc i   Med.  1992;34:559-569.23.   Krumholz  HM,  Pasternak RC,  Weinstein MC,et   al.   Cost   effectiveness   of thrombolytic therapywith   streptokinase   in  elderly  patients   with   sus-

pected  acute myocardial  infarction.  N Engl J Med.

1992;327:7-13.