19
5th ECPR Graduate Student Conference 2014 – University of Innsbruck, 3 - 5 July 2014 Open Section Panel: Case Studies 1 Maximilian Schiffers, M.A. NRW School of Governance • Universität Duisburg-Essen │ email: [email protected] Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence Maximilian Schiffers Abstract: Interest group research is still considered to be a niche field. New approaches advanced our understanding of numerous factors of interest group influence. But it remains somewhat unclear, how these general factors translate into tangible influence. In dealing with this issue, forms of coop- erative politics between government actors and interest groups allow for new insights. They appear to serve as focal point at which formal and informal interactions are pooled. These forms are used e.g. for the German “Energiewende”, the transition from nuclear and conventional energy to renew- ables. This paper develops a comparative approach to identify behavioral patterns within the context of ‘government - interest group’ cooperation. It follows the logic of congruence analysis, using argu- ment- and interest-based theoretical frameworks to interpret energy policy coordination in German states. These patterns are expected to improve our understanding of political context as a condition for interest group influence on government action. Paper outline 1. Introduction: the problem of interest group influence and the relevance of political context 2. An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 3. Constructing the pathway: congruence analysis with interest- and argument-based frameworks 4. Research design and casing: coordinating German states’ energy policy with cooperative politics 5. Concluding remarks

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    7

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

5th ECPR Graduate Student Conference 2014 – University of Innsbruck, 3 - 5 July 2014

Open Section Panel: Case Studies 1

Maximilian Schiffers, M.A.

NRW School of Governance • Universität Duisburg-Essen │ email: [email protected]

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway

to the question of interest group influence

Maximilian Schiffers

Abstract: Interest group research is still considered to be a niche field. New approaches advanced

our understanding of numerous factors of interest group influence. But it remains somewhat unclear,

how these general factors translate into tangible influence. In dealing with this issue, forms of coop-

erative politics between government actors and interest groups allow for new insights. They appear

to serve as focal point at which formal and informal interactions are pooled. These forms are used

e.g. for the German “Energiewende”, the transition from nuclear and conventional energy to renew-

ables.

This paper develops a comparative approach to identify behavioral patterns within the context of

‘government - interest group’ cooperation. It follows the logic of congruence analysis, using argu-

ment- and interest-based theoretical frameworks to interpret energy policy coordination in German

states. These patterns are expected to improve our understanding of political context as a condition

for interest group influence on government action.

Paper outline

1. Introduction: the problem of interest group influence and the relevance of political context

2. An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination

3. Constructing the pathway: congruence analysis with interest- and argument-based frameworks

4. Research design and casing: coordinating German states’ energy policy with cooperative politics

5. Concluding remarks

Page 2: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

2 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

1. Introduction: the problem of interest group influence and the relevance of political context

The question of interest group influence is crucial to political science, yet it suffers from the marginal

status of interest group research within political science. In their much cited review „Researching

Interest Group Politics in Europe and Elsewhere: Much We Study, Little We Know?” (2008: 1103)

Beyers, Eising and Maloney emphasized that it is still regarded a niche field (i.e. Alemann/Weßels

1997, Weßels 2007: 84). Since the mid-1990s research interest has grown steadily, without ever get-

ting close to the number of researchers working in related areas like party or policy research. Yet it is

uncontroversial to argue that interest groups are considered to play a key role in understanding ad-

vanced democracies. On that account, this sub-discipline deals with questions about the system of

interest intermediation (pluralist, corporatist, network), about access to policy makers, as well as

advocacy coalitions and group strategies (Lowery 2013: 1, Dür/De Bièvre 2007: 1-2).

„In both the United States and the European Union (EU), scholars have focused on a whole host of

lobbying-related phenomena – formation, organisation, access, activity – but not influence. This is es-

pecially ironic, since the question of influence is the first thing that comes to mind when anyone con-

siders lobbying in a transatlantic comparison” (Mahoney 2007: 35).

Yet even if this range of phenomena and research topics doesn’t explicitly cover the question of in-

terest group influence, it is still affected in the margins. Recent meta-studies get to quite similar con-

clusions. In his review „Lobbying influence: Meaning, measurement and missing” (2013) David Low-

ery shows that direct lobbying influence on US-Congress decision making is sometimes strong, some-

times marginal and sometimes close to non-existent. These findings match with three central re-

search reviews by Richard Smith (1995), Baumgartner and Leech (1998) as well as Burstein and Lin-

ton (2002). They all show that evidence for interest group influence is inconclusive: some studies

show little or limited influence, some even state that interest groups are influential in less than half

of the observed cases (Hojnacki et.al. 2012: 383-384). Even more telling is that most interest groups

fail to get their issues on the policy agenda. Consequently, uncertainty shapes the interest group and

lobbying environment, especially in regards to goals, means and the relations between the actors

(Lowery 2013: 2). Failing to produce inference between interest groups and the exertion of influence

clearly flies in the face of both common intuition and social sciences’ current knowledge.

"Virtually all sociologists and political scientists publishing in the top journals hypothesize that […] in-

terest groups […] influence public policy, and it is safe to assume that they generally expect the impact

to be substantial. This hypothesis is not as well supported by the data as we might expect"

(Burstein/Linton 2002: 398).

Strong theoretical expectations about the question of interest group influence are mismatched by

contradictory and inconclusive results (Pedersen 2013: 28). One reason grounds in the common re-

search practice that deviating and null results are unlikely to be published and excluded from further

research. As long as these self-made limitations exist, interest group research will keep „‘the dirty

little secret‘ of lobbying literature – that lobbying is often not very effective“ (Lowery 2013: 19).

Page 3: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 3

So, how can new research projects contribute to improve interest group research? Most researchers

recommend focusing on political context. Lacking both methodological and conceptual attention for

the context in which interest groups interact is believed to be a central reason for the current uncer-

tainties in the state of knowledge. With its range of variations, this context sheds light on the implica-

tions of interest groups in policy making. Systematically examining both context and its variations

should improve our knowledge about interest groups and the political process as a whole (Hojnacki

et.al. 2012: 386, 393). Therefore, research should emphasize on „when, why, and to what extent

[interest groups] are powerful on what types of issues“ (Baumgartner/Leech 1998: 134). In dealing

with this issue, forms of cooperative politics between governments and interest groups allow for new

insights. These forms appear to serve as focal point at which their formal and informal interactions

are pooled. From a conceptual perspective, political context shows that influence exertion on policy

outcomes is merely one section of interest group influence as a whole. Studies that only focus on

outcomes are prone to disregard power inequalities in the status quo, biases and the structural pow-

er of single interest groups. Using political context, research designs are able to integrate these dis-

parities and their implications in their scope of work. This conjunction allows researchers “to enter

into the broader scholarly dialogue about representation, much of which neglects groups“ (Hojnacki

et.al. 2012: 393-394). Which elements and factors have to be investigated via political context de-

pends on the theoretical perspective. One way to deal with the challenges of interest group influence

is to identify “mechanisms by which actors seek to exert influence“ (Eising 2008: 20). Political context

should consequently include „positive externalities that are not directly related to policy outcomes”

(Beyers/Eising/Maloney 2008: 1115), e.g. organizational maintenance, reputation and information

management. New approaches can reconnect interest group research with government research to

investigate the interdependence between interest group activity and institutional settings, and how

groups and policy makers collaborate for joint advocacy e.g. in cooperative politics.

This short overview of interest group research depicts two issues to grapple with in order to work the

question of interest group influence. There is quite a range of variation concerning (1) what exactly

to investigate, that is which phenomena to use, and concerning (2) how – based on which concepts

and definitions – to analyze the objects of study. As both of them are intertwined, the paper starts to

take a look at the concepts of power and influence and proposes an indirect concept of influence

(chapter 2). In its main part, the paper outlines a pathway to the question of influence, employing

congruence analysis as a theoretical toolset (chapter 3). The following part takes a brief look at some

thoughts about research design and case selection for the empirical application on the German

states’ energy transition policy (chapter 4).

Page 4: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

4 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

2. An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination

2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and its direct assessment

Despite the niche field status and the numerous challenges to tackle interest group influence, new

approaches have improved our understanding of several factors (i.e. Baumgartner/Leech 1998,

Bouwen 2004, Mahoney 2007, Dür/de Bièvre 2007, Beyers/Eising/Malony 2008, Klüver 2013, Lowery

2013, Pedersen 2013). What actors are influential to which degree is, according to their common

conviction, essential to comprehend the role of interest groups in the policy making process. Over

the decades, several seminal works have outlined both relevance and limits to this research area (e.g.

Truman 1955, March 1955 Dahl 1961, Becker 1983, Salisbury 1984). They all discussed the problems

that come along with defining power and influence, distinguishing universal concepts and theories

from ad-hoc hypotheses and with ultimately operationalizing them (see Dür/de Bièvre 2007). Yet,

none of the methods established any “gold standard” of influence assessment and measurement, let

alone a commonly shared or natural scale of influence (Pedersen 2013: 28-29). In order to get some

structure to the multilayered concepts of influence, Hart (1976: 289-303) suggests to distinguish (1)

„control over resources”, (2) „control over actors” und (3) „control over events and outcomes”. The

first approach focuses on economic and political resources that actors or groups of actors use to

shape decisions. Counting resources seems easy enough to handle, yet it treats all interactions be-

tween actors as black box. It generates results that tend to describe existing power relations prior to

decision making rather than the actual process. According to this approach, researchers charge up

market power of business associations against electoral votes power of labor unions or public mobili-

zation power of NGOs (Reutter/Rütters 2007: 127-131, Schmidt 2011: 114). The second approach is

based on Robert Dahl (1957) and his Max Weber-like concept of power as a broadly defined ability to

alter someone’s action according to one’s will. This approach opens the black box for interactions

and is able to explain changing behavior. Yet it struggles with situations without visible behavioral

changes, concealed interactions between influential actors or processes with multiple causes and

interdependencies. Studies based on his approach depict influence via “inside” and “outside strate-

gies” as well as informal exchange of political commodities between policy makers and interest

groups (cf. Willems/Winter 2007: 40, Binderkrantz 2008). The third approach takes account of inter-

dependencies between actors and spotlights the inference between initial actions and actors’ policy

preferences on one side and events or consequences for specific outcomes on the other side. Hence

it requires much more detailed data and interpretation. Generating comprehensive sets of (most of

all qualitative) data is susceptible for methodological distortion, especially as actors’ statements

about policy positions and interests might be (deliberately) skewed or incomplete. The research re-

view (e.g. Hojnacki et.al. 2012, Lowery 2013) shows that numerous current studies apply a slightly

modified version of this third approach as “control over policy outputs”. Interest group influence

Page 5: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 5

derives from the proximity between the central actors’ initial policy positions and the final outcome

in legislation, respectively maintaining the status quo (cf. Baumgartner et.al. 2009).

The three approaches highlight conflicting priorities for conceptual and methodological issues about

the question of influence. Pritoni (2014) emphasizes the trade-off between the generality of concep-

tualizing influence and its validity for empirical analysis. Following Sartori’s assumption (2011), the

higher the level of generality, the less precise and valid are the empirical indicators (and vice versa).

Pritoni suggests dividing concepts of influence into the direction of lobbying mobilization (pro status

quo, anti status quo) and the applied stage of the policy cycle (agenda-setting; decision-making; im-

plementation) as range of validity. He then employs this typology to evaluate quantitative influence

measurements with regards to status quo maintenance in decision-making. The systematic differen-

tiation allows for a more nuanced description of structures and processes in the scope of interest

group influence. In addition, it equally complies with the multifaceted research practices. Clarity and

transparency of influence approaches are essential to compare and relate different concepts and

methods and consequently help to enhance our knowledge about these phenomena. This way of

thinking corresponds with the pragmatist attitude of interest group research: despite all challenges

and limiting issues, the question of influence isn’t believed to be a “mission impossible” (Pedersen

2013: 29). According to unanimous consent, this question is too crucial for comprehending democra-

cy and the practice of decision-making processes. Therefore researchers should turn their backs on

abstract and non-verifiably concepts in favor of empirically observable effects of influence (i.e.

Baumgartner/Leech 1998: 37, Dür/de Bièvre 2007a: 3, Pedersen 2013: 29-30). In addition, some pro-

pose to combine several methods and data sources to deduce influence by triangulating various re-

sults (e.g. Arts/Verschurent 1999). This pragmatist perspective is more adapted to facilitate meaning-

ful results than the often-employed direct attempt to attribute policy outcomes to a definite and

distinct exertion of influence by interest groups. Chalmers (2011) characterizes this straight attempt

as a dead-end that even improved measurements and refined indicators can’t solve. He rather sug-

gests a „fundamental rethinking of interest group influence itself” (Chalmers 2011: 472). Following

his point of view, this paper explores an indirect concept of influence.

2.2 Interest group influence as policy coordination

Acknowledging the challenges of straight and direct approaches to investigate interest group influ-

ence, this paper proposes an indirect concept of influence focusing on policy coordination. This indi-

rect concept is part of a comparative approach to identify behavioral patterns within the political

context of ‘government - interest group’ cooperation. These patterns are in turn expected to im-

prove our understanding of political context as a condition for interest group influence on govern-

ment action. This influence concept grounds in the main hypothesis, according to which a high de-

Page 6: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

6 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

gree of coordination between governments and key interest groups leads to a low level of conflict.

On that account, participating actors are able to produce joint policy recommendations – as outcome

for cooperative politics. The hypothesis refers to the empirically substantiated correlation between

public attention (“salient issues”) and expended efforts for actors to convey their policy positions

(e.g. Hojnacki et. al. 2012: 385-389). High levels of conflict tend to attract more publicity, leading to a

higher number of diverse actors to engage in the issue. This likely results in growing uncertainty and

complexity which in turn constrains the actors’ relative chance to gain attention for their concerns.

The indirect concept of influence as policy coordination consequently affects the scope of the influ-

ence perception. At this point, the previously mentioned typology of generality and validity for in-

terest group influence (Pritoni 2014) helps to locate the concept within the broadly defined „function

to influence public policy“ (Beyers/Eising/Maloney 2008: 1109). Systematically speaking, the indirect

concept covers a much smaller area than the broad “control over (…)”-approaches. It restrains to a

specific form of cooperative politics and to the ideal-typical stages of the policy-cycle connected to

them. The forms of cooperative politics under study are employed to flank formal legislative pro-

cesses and comprehensive policy change – e.g. to adapt states’ policy to federal energy transition

legislation of the German government. They emphasize primarily on agenda-setting and prearranging

decisions. Thereby, they bring the ideal-typical stages together and visualize coordination processes

at their junctions. Consequently, these flanking forms produce different sorts of results than most

approaches that observe legislative outcomes by „control over policy outputs“. Especially highly

complex and consequential outputs like legislation are subject to a variety of causal factors. As the

current research overview shows, isolating specific interest group related causes from the interde-

pendence of causal elements is extremely difficult. By focusing on flanking policy coordination in

cooperative politics, this concept avoids large parts of the issue of overdetermination. In contrast to

legislation, the routines of cooperative policy coordination are less exposed to media coverage, its

content is well-defined and its interactions are characterized by continuous and long-term relations

between the participating actors. This is why conceptualized influence is less situational and isolated

but rather conceived as patterns of influence. In addition, the concept gets around the widespread

assumption that interest group actions and lobbying are inherently conflictual (cf. Chalmers 2011:

472). The classical lineup describes interest groups as active protagonists and government officials as

mere lobbying recipients. Dropping this oversimplification allows for a more realistic view of ‘gov-

ernment - interest group’ relations. Influence as policy coordination turns towards practices that

include interest groups in government actions e.g. for "political support in election campaigns or

other issues of legitimacy“ (Hassel 2009). It matches the consensual default orientation common to

German politics to incorporate interest groups in formal decision making and to institutionalize in-

teractions between governments and interest groups (Willems/Winter 2007: 36).

Page 7: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 7

Configuring influence as policy coordination consequently means to limit both generality and scope

to a specific object under study. According to this understanding, influence doesn’t cover individual

properties of single actors but rather adapts to collective modes of behavior for policy coalitions or

‘sides’ of an issue. These collective modes of behavior are expected to reveal the patterns of influ-

ence in policy coordination by using congruence analysis with interest- and argument-based theoret-

ical frameworks. On these grounds, actors (or sides/coalitions) are considered influential if they are

able to provide and implement collective coordinative practices.

3. Constructing the pathway: congruence analysis with interest- and argument-based frameworks

3.1 Congruence analysis as theoretical toolset

The study subject to this paper aims to take a closer look at the interactions of governments and

interest groups within institutionalized forms of cooperative politics. It pursues to identify patterns of

influence inside these interactions to coordinate German states’ energy transition policy. The study

uses congruence analysis (CON, i.e. Blatter/Blume 2008, Blatter/Haverland 2012) as a theoretical

toolset to improve our understanding of policy coordination and political context as a condition for

interest group influence. Following CON’s logic, the study employs two rival comprehensive theoreti-

cal frameworks to interpret concrete observations in order to understand the cases under study. The

frameworks, discursive and actor-centered institutionalism (DI and ACI), build on arguments versus

interests to explain coordination. DI suggests that coordination is a result of arguing. Key elements

include enacting consensus, common perceptions and sustained motivation to act. For ACI, coordina-

tion is a result of bargaining, focusing on (non-)exercised vetoes, compromises and mutual trust.

Both theories are compatible with the main hypothesis that a high level of coordination leads to a

low level of conflict, which in turn enables (meaningful) joint policy recommendations.

Congruence analysis (CON) as an approach originated from comparative and case study research that

emphasizes the role of theories and theory-guided investigation. Initially it was developed to con-

tribute to the methodological debate about the quantitatively-oriented template of social science

research, most prominently presented in King, Keohane and Verba’s (KKV) „Designing Social Inquiry“

(1994). Therein, the three authors laid out a strict set of rules and requirements for scientific infer-

ence. Focusing largely on causal explanations, their understanding of causality derives from an ex-

perimental logic that highlights statistical variance to connect factors (KKV 1994: 7-9). The main re-

search goal is testing existing theories, subordinating other goals to the label ‘causal description’

(KKV 1994: 75-77). As a seminal work, KKV started a broad and intense debate that brought out the

relevancy of different research goals (e.g. George/Bennett 2005, Brady/Collier 2010, Mahoney 2010).

Blatter, Blume and Haverland (Blatter/Blume 2008, Blatter/Haverland 2012) differentiate three ap-

proaches for research designs with both specific research goals and focus. Their first big alternative

Page 8: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

8 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

to the dominant Co-Variational Analysis (COV) of the quantitative template is (Causal-) Process-

Tracing (CPT). Instead of testing which variation in explanatory variables leads to different outcomes,

CPT takes an interest in what elements constitute a particular outcome. Therefore, it focuses on

causal configuration, i.e. both sequential and situational combinations of conditions and mecha-

nisms. Thus, CPT’s main research goal is inductive theory development (Blatter/Haverland 2012: 23-

28). As third approach, CON points out both descriptive and explanatory merits of different theories.

Based on comprehensive theoretical frameworks with competing or complementing properties, CON

examines which theory generates new or better insights.

„In the congruence analysis approach (CON), theories are not reduced to single independent variables

(as in the COV approach) but are treated as comprehensive worldviews that are specified through a

set of constitutive and causal propositions. Case studies are used to elucidate and to compare the ex-

planatory merits of competing or complementary theories” (Blatter/Haverland 2012: 24).

Theoretical frameworks correspondingly take on quite an important role in this deductively-oriented

approach. Theories are selected according to their relevance in scientific discourse and the research-

er’s theoretical aspiration. Derived hypotheses and expectations from the theories specify what em-

pirical evidence to observe in order to generate data. As a result, the approach creates a set of con-

firmations and contradictions for the employed theories. Then, researchers draw conclusions from

the differences between theories and their (non-)congruence of theoretical expectations and empiri-

cal observations. These conclusions allow to refine the selected theories or to combine theories for

comprehensive explanation. Unlike statistical generalization of results in COV approaches, CON pro-

motes theoretical generalization. Drawing conclusions about theoretical frameworks and their appli-

cation to the object under study addresses the scientific discourse about the question of interest

group influence and aims for theory elaboration (Blatter/Blume 2008: 325-331, Blatter/Haverland

2012: 28-32).

Starting point for this congruence analysis is the specific theoretical figure of scope-of-action corri-

dors (“Handlungskorridore des Regierens”, e.g. Korte/Fröhlich 2009). As an underlying institutionalist

framework, it defines the room for maneuver and policy discretion available to actors between the

poles of structural and agent-centered elements. It opens up the angle to investigate how actors

(government and interest groups) operate in different institutional settings and thus afflicting change

to these institutions (George/Bennet 2005: 245). Scope-of-action corridors cover institutional, situa-

tional, actor-related and political factors to assess interest group impact on government action. This

theoretical figure serves as a relevancy-filter to reduce the complexity of political context (cf. Saba-

tier 2007: 3-4). Inside this underlying framework, the rival theories of CON are located. Both theories

outline different explanatory approaches to grasp institutionalized policy coordination between gov-

ernments and interest groups. The line of thought of actor-centered institutionalism grounds in

Page 9: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 9

(bounded-)rational actors and interests, while discursive institutionalism attributes to beliefs and

argument-based perspectives. Together they outline an area of conceptual and theoretical tension

that is utilized by congruence analysis.

3.2 Bargaining and arguing in policy coordination of government and interest groups

The actor-centered institutionalism (ACI, Mayntz/Scharpf 1995, Scharpf 2000a) is located on the ra-

tional choice and sociological side of the new institutionalisms (Hall/Taylor 1996). Fritz Scharpf him-

self judged the new institutionalisms as being too deterministic. According to his view, policy making

is able to change even if institutions remain constant, as long as central actors alter their cognitive

and normative orientations (Scharpf 2000b: 770-772). Other scholars have built on ACI’s heuristics to

shift the thematic priority e.g. to strategic government action (e.g. Korte/Fröhlich 2004, 2009). Based

on Scharpf’s evaluation, they developed a broadly defined political rationality composed of policy-,

mediation-, and implementation rationales. Attributing (bounded-) rational actions embedded in an

institutional and agent-centered setting therefore visualizes room for manoeuver and blockades. The

ACI then contains the elements of political pressure, actors, constellations, forms of interactions and

political decisions. Its focus is on informally institutionalized interactions connecting the central deci-

sion making in government, parliament and parties to the actors in field of organized interests and

the media (Korte/Fröhlich 2009: 187-192, 224-226, Florack/Grunden 2011: 20). To assess ‘govern-

ment - interest group’ cooperation, the ACI extends to the structural characteristics of the “negotiat-

ed-competition democracy” (Florack/Grunden/Korte 2008: 67, cf. “administrative arena”

Korte/Fröhlich 2009: 231). It explicitly addresses interest group participation at the intersection of

hierarchy, competition and negotiation. Government, administration and interest groups reach deci-

sions via negotiated agreements and consensus, as reconciling competing interests is considered

more suitable than implementation by hierarchy or majority. The process of decision making remains

deliberately non-public, facilitating compromises and package deals (Korte/Fröhlich 2009: 232).

The „argumentative turn“ of policy-research (e.g. Fischer/Forrester 1993, Nullmeier 1993) gave rise

to ideas, discourses and narratives as explanatory elements. In reference to the new institutionalisms

(Hall/Taylor 1996), the framework of discursive institutionalism (DI) advanced to become its fourth

variety (Schmidt 2008: 304). Vivian A. Schmidt (i.e. 2008, 2010) uses the label to subsume several

different approaches and versions.

“DI simultaneously treats institutions as given (as the context within which agents think, speak, and

act) and as contingent (as the results of agents’ thoughts, words, and actions). These institutions are

therefore internal to the actors, serving both as structures that constrain actors and as constructs cre-

ated and changed by those actors.” (Schmidt 2008: 314).

Page 10: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

10 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

This combination of varying and context-related properties of institutions increases the scope of ac-

tion for actors. Besides ideas and discourses, interest-based behavior still remains part of DI „but it

involves ideas about interests that may encompass much more than strictly utilitarian concerns“

(Schmidt 2008: 316). As an explicit institutionalist theory, DI links communicating ideas and state-

ments to the institutional context where they enter the discourse. Yet, its institutions go beyond the

three older institutionalisms that tend to depict merely their constraining side, e.g. by rational incen-

tives, historical path dependencies or cultural frames. DI simultaneously treads institutions as con-

straining structures and enabling constructs of meaning which are internalized by the actors (Schmidt

2010: 4). Regarding the practice of interaction, DI distinguishes the mode of “coordinative discourse”

between actors of the policy-sphere and the mode of “communicative discourse” between political

actors and the (broader) public. Crucial to the study and its institutionalized cooperation forms are

“coordinative discourses” covering decision makers in parliaments and administration as well as in-

terest groups. Participating actors introduce their policy arguments to the discourse with varying

degrees of influence. They often band together to informal groupings in order to influence agenda-

setting, shaping and adoption of policies (Schmidt 2011: 100). Key approaches merging within DI are

e.g. „discourse coalitions“ (i.e. Hajar 1993), „epistemic communities“ (i.e. Haas 1992) and notably

„advocacy coalitions“ (i.e. Sabatier/Jenkins-Smith 1993, Sabatier/Weible 2007). In its role as relevan-

cy-filter, the coordinative discourse of DI structures ‘government - interest group’ interactions within

the forms of cooperative politics.

3.3 Developing a coherent framework to assess policy coordination in cooperative politics

After outlining ACI and DI, both frameworks need to select theoretical key aspects to analyze the

coordination practices inside of ‘government - interest group’ cooperation. In order to develop a

coherent framework, the study takes into account four issues concerning political context raised by

corresponding approaches. (1) Growing complexity in governance of advanced democracies has in-

creased the level of uncertainty. Systemic and structural challenges limit the decision making capabil-

ities of governments and interest groups. As a result, central actors tend to cooperate to restore

some reliability of expectations. Cooperation facilitates trust building that enables actors to antici-

pate positions and preferences of other participants (Töller 2008: 293-294, Rüb 2011: 75-77). (2)

Long term processes from agenda-setting to implementation require shared perceptions about the

nature of problems and their possible solution. Establishing and maintaining common rationales is

essential for informal groupings and advocacy coalitions in policy sub-systems. Thus, cooperation

helps to orchestrate windows of opportunity by staging media events or by applying public pressure

to deviant participants (e.g. Sabatier/Weible 2007, Rüb 2009: 361-362). (3) Public perception of joint-

ly agreed actions and consensus increases acceptance and legitimacy by appealing to general public

Page 11: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 11

interests. At the same time, incorporating expertise of relevant interest groups helps to create com-

monly accepted knowledge and information, scaling up the persuasiveness of the cooperation as a

whole (i.e. Mahoney 2007: 54, Willems/Winter 2007: 36, Bandelow 2007: 155, Flo-

rack/Grunden/Korte 2011: 194). (4) Finally, any compromises in cooperation are prone to constrain

the participants’ ability to act. By exchanging access for public support and reputation, institutional-

ized cooperation depends on the participants’ willingness to proceed, especially if individual interest

and group interests clash (i.e. Willems/Winter 2007: 40, Bandelow 2007: 153).

Considering these four issues from the theoretical perspectives of ACI and DI, the study concludes its

analytical framework accordingly. Its key elements for the argument-based part include enacting

consensus versus dissent, the presence of common perceptions as well as for sustained motivation to

act. The interest-based part involves the presence of (non-)exercised vetoes, policy concessions ver-

sus minimal consensus and the level of mutual trust. Following the logic of congruence analysis,

these theoretically deduced expectations will be applied to be confirmed or contradicted by empiri-

cal data in order to distinguish relevant interaction principles as anticipated by (or opposing) the

theoretical frameworks.

Page 12: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

12 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

4. Research design and casing: coordinating German states’ energy policy with cooperative politics

After having discussed the theoretical toolset to grasp the question of interest group influence, this

paper presents some thoughts concerning the comparative research design. One of the main issues

of comparative research with smaller-n cases is that case selection and data collection are part of the

same iterative process (e.g. Blatter/Janning/Wagemann 2007: 24). Whether cases are relevant for

comparison depends on data that has to be collected during the research process. In the worst case,

researchers get to a point, where the collected data suggest that the initially selected cases have too

little variation for an informative comparison or even are not comparable at all. The study employs a

method-based approach using qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) to guide case selection, casing

and data collection to ensure both sufficient comparability and variance. It starts with easily collect-

able data like reports and official statistics and funnels step-by-step to less accessible data like expert

interviews.

Casing: institutionalized cooperation in German states’ energy policy adaptation.

Preliminary casing uses the presence of (meaningful) joint policy recommendations as outcome of

coordination. If coordination efforts aren’t successful, the outcomes are most likely to be general

expressions of intention and symbol politics. Cooperative politics between governments and interest

groups from the conventional and/or the renewable energy policy coalition are used in all German

states to coordinate policy after the nuclear catastrophe in Fukushima and the subsequent energy

transition legislation on German federal level in 2011. Casing is therefore focused on new and exist-

ing coordination formats in the period after the external policy shocks, ensuring similar levels of pub-

lic pressure, expectations to react and similar references to public debate.

Both scope and depth of research are affected by the number of cases selected for comparison. The

number of selected cases depends in turn on the research goals and the vision of research the pro-

ject strives to achieve. Following the logic of congruence analysis, the main research goal is theory

elaboration by comparing the descriptive and explanatory merits of the two selected theoretical

frameworks (Blatter/Haverland 2012: 23-24). To ensure sufficient opportunities for theory-based

(non)-congruence of concrete observations, the number of cases shouldn’t be too small. This choice

corresponds to the secondary research goal of classification regarding the patterns of influence (“ty-

pological theory” cf. George/Bennet 2005: 244). Both variance and intimacy to the case are neces-

sary to identify theory-guided patterns of influence in government-interest group coordination. The

project makes a choice for a smaller-n comparison of five to ten cases.

This choice also represents the project’s vision of research to work (relatively) closely on the selected

cases without losing sight of the political context. The participating interest groups and governments

don’t limit their actions to the coordination forms, just as these forms aren’t the only factors in a

Page 13: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 13

state’s policy deliberation. Therefore the project doesn’t restrict the research to one or two singular

cases but aims to include several varying federated states as “case families” for case selection.

Case selection: Multiple Cases – Most-Similar (cases) Different Outcome MSDO

Forms of cooperative politics are used in all German states to coordinate the policy adaptation to the

energy transition. However, the states’ policy reactions vary both in scope and format. As mentioned

before, the study develops a method-based approach using QCA to guide case selection, casing and

data collection in order to assure both sufficient comparability and variance. To limit the number of

cases to a manageable amount, an applicable strategy seems to be to group them to “case families”.

These “case families” are federated states with specific outcomes of their own on the macro level.

The “familiar” property of these groups is in the shared political context of the involved actors of the

cases (e.g. strength of industry, relevance of renewable energy (RE) industry).

In a first step the research looks for policy adaptation in all federated states after the events of 2011.

Using QCA and multiple combinations of conditions, a cluster of three key states, North Rhine-

Westphalia (NRW), Bavaria and Baden-Wuerttemberg, is identified for a more in-depth analysis. All

three states share important features, e.g. high population, a highly industrialized economy, im-

portance of conventional energy and they are among the biggest producers of renewable energy.

According to theory, (1) both conventional and renewable energy coalitions are considered to be

strong in these states, and (2) promoting RE can’t be seen merely as an attempt to stimulate the own

economy as a means of location policy.

In a second step, the actual cases are selected by identifying institutionalized coordination forms

from within the cluster of these three states. All cases belong to the highly institutionalized spectrum

of observable ‘government - interest group’ interactions, but they vary in their outcome. The theo-

retical framework suggests that policy coordination is considered successful when the involved ac-

tors can agree on clear and relevant policy recommendations. In some situations the involved actors

– governments and interest groups from the conventional and/or the renewable energy coalition –

aren’t able to reach a common conclusion. They silently end the coordination process without any

meaningful policy recommendation. Case selection is therefore based on a typology that distin-

guishes coordination outcomes as with/without meaningful policy recommendation. The case selec-

tion follows the “most-similar different-outcome design” (MSDO, Przeworski/Teune 1970, Berg-

Schlosser/De Meur 2009: 21-23; for case list see appendix).

For the third step, this method-based approach helps to reduce the amount of qualitative data to a

more manageable extent. Thus, it decreases the risk to invest research energy in cases that ultimate-

ly don’t make the cut for the final evaluation and analysis.

Page 14: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

14 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

Evidence and data management

Tackling this research puzzle requires a complex and case-oriented view when it comes to data col-

lection and analysis. In this sense, ‘useful’ data helps to understand the specifics of the case. Its col-

lection has to be rather flexible and concept-driven in order to obtain a sufficient level of intimacy

with the cases. Only a limited amount of already compiled material is useful for this project, covering

the macro-level and outcomes on the state level. Most of the relevant information for the interaction

on the meso-level of government and interest group actors has to be gathered during the research

process. In qualitative and case study research, data generation is a crucial task where researchers

need to invest both time and intellectual energy. This is especially true for interest group research in

the context of lobbying, as its main characteristics are discretion and informal arrangements. This

raises the threshold for scientific access to viable information, mostly obtainable via interviews.

Once again, the project follows the logic of congruence analysis. The relevant observations from the

cases deliver information that corresponds to the expectations (propositions, hypotheses, predic-

tions) deduced from theories. Resulting data will be a set of confirmations and/or contradictions for

the two theoretical frameworks that helps to distinguish relevant interaction principles as anticipated

by (or opposing) the theoretical frameworks.

Sources for data generation for these case-oriented observations are official reports and statements

from participating governments and interest groups as well as expert interviews. The interviews will

be conducted with representatives from the three groups – government, interest groups from the

conventional and from the renewable energy coalition – with a total of five to six interviews per

“case family” (federated state). The data will be compiled using scaling qualitative content analysis

(Mayring 2002) to assess differences in the level of congruence between theoretical expectations

and observations. As a conclusion the results should shed some light on the relative importance of

specific aspects of both theoretical frameworks. They might allow for a more comprehensive expla-

nation through combining both theories to a single analytical framework.

5. Concluding remarks

The question of interest group influence is a vivid example that social science is challenged by a com-

plex and highly interconnected world. This paper outlined a double-indirect approach to tackle the

question in a theory-guided context. Using an indirect concept of influence as policy coordination,

the paper elaborated on how to apply congruence analysis to identify behavioral patterns within the

political context of institutionalized cooperation between government and interest groups in German

states’ energy transition policy. By combining interest- and argument-based frameworks (actor-

centered institutionalism and discursive institutionalism), this approach helps to utilize political con-

text as a condition to improve our understanding of interest group influence.

Page 15: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 15

However, this indirect research strategy comes at the cost of limited generality regarding influence

and restricted area of empirical validity. Quantitatively assessing a single, non-controversial value of

influence for specific interests groups in a broadly defined set of varied situations isn’t part of what

this approach is set out to do (or even aspiring to achieve). But with an eye to the current research

review, supposedly simple answers to the crucial question of interest group influence aren’t suited to

overcome the “conceptual, methodological and disciplinary barriers [that] militate against the accu-

mulation of knowledge” (Beyers/Eising/Maloney 2008: 1103). Consequently, the approach aims to

advance the scientific discourse about this question by theoretical generalization according to the

logic of congruence analysis. Data collection, evaluation and interpretation will show to what extend

the results between theoretical expectations and empirical observations are qualified to contribute.

Additional limitations have to be considered that are inherent to a qualitative approach and the ex-

ante selection of cases based on limited knowledge. First, in respect of data quality, the gathered

information might be biased or skewed. All observations need to be mirrored carefully with other

sources or contextual information to increase their validity. Second, due to the limited knowledge

about the discreet surroundings of lobbying-related interactions, the relevant cases can’t be directly

selected based on their coordination principles as anticipated by theory. Even with some evidence

from reports and the varying outcome of the cases within the selected “case families”, there is still

the danger of omitted cases or insufficient variance. Yet, the concept- and method-guided approach

creates sound arguments to justify the pursued course for the proverbial “proof of the pudding” in

the research process.

Page 16: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

16 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

References

Alemann, Ulrich von; Weßels, Bernhard (1997): Verbände in vergleichender Perspektive. Beiträge zu einem vernachlässigten Feld. Berlin.

Arts, B.; Verschuren, P. (1999): Assessing Political Influence in Complex Decision-Making: An Instrument Based on Triangulation. In: International Political Science Review 20 (4), S. 411–424.

Bandelow, Nils C. (2007): Unwissen als Problem politischer Steuerung in der Verkehrspolitik. In: Nils C. Bandelow und Wilhelm Bleek (Hg.): Einzelinteressen und kollektives Handeln in modernen Demokratien. Wies-baden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, S. 139–162.

Baumgartner, Frank R.; Berry, Jeffrey M.; Hojnacki, Marie; Kimball, David C.; Leech, Beth L. (2009) Lobbying and Policy Change. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Baumgartner, Frank R.; Leech, Beth L. (1998): Basic interests. The importance of groups in politics and in politi-cal science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press.

Bandelow, Nils C. (2007): Unwissen als Problem politischer Steuerung in der Verkehrspolitik, in: Nils C. Bandelow, Wilhelm Bleek (Hrsg.): Einzelinteressen und kollektives Handeln in modernen Demokratien, S. 139-162.

Becker, Gary S. (1983): A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence. In: The Quarter-ly Journal of Economics 98 (3), S. 371.

Berg-Schlosser, Dirk; Meur, Gisèle de (2009): Comparativ Research Designs: Case and Variable Selection. In: Benoit Rihoux und Charles C. Ragin (Hg.): Configurational comparative methods. Qualitative comparative analy-sis (QCA) and related techniques. Thousand Oaks: Sage (Applied social research methods series, 51), S. 19–32.

Beyers, Jan; Eising, Rainer; Maloney, William (2008): Researching Interest Group Politics in Europe and Else-where: Much We Study, Little We Know?, West European Politics 31 (6), S. 1103-1129.

Blatter, Joachim; Haverland, Markus (2012): Designing Case Studies: Explanatory Approaches in Small-N Re-search: Palgrave Macmillan.

Blatter, Joachim; Blume, Till (2008): In Search of Co-variance, Causal Mechanisms or Congruence? Towards a Plural Understanding of Case Studies. In: Swiss Political Science Review 14 (2), S. 315–356.

Blatter, Joachim K.; Janning, Frank; Wagemann, Claudius (2007): Qualitative Politikanalyse. Eine Einführung in Forschungsansätze und Methoden. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften | GWV Fachverlage GmbH Wiesbaden.

Bouwen, Pieter (2004): Exchanging access goods for access: A comparative study of business lobbying in the European Union institutions. In: Eur J Political Res 43 (3), S. 337–369.

Brady, Henry E.; Collier, David (Hg.) (2010): Rethinking social inquiry. Diverse tools, shared standards. 2. ed. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield..

Burstein, P.; Linton, A. (2002): The Impact of Political Parties, Interest Groups, and Social Movement Organiza-tions on Public Policy: Some Recent Evidence and Theoretical Concerns. In: Social Forces 81 (2), S. 380–408.

Chalmers, Adam William (2011): Interests, Influence and Information: Comparing the Influence of Interest Groups in the European Union. In: Journal of European Integration 33 (4), S. 471–486.

Dahl, Robert A. (1961): Who governs? Power and democracy in an American city. Yale: Yale Univ. Press.

Dür, Andreas (2008): Measuring Interest Group Influence in the EU: A Note on Methodology, in: European Union Politics, VOL 9, NO 4

Dür, Andreas; De Bièvre, Dirk (2007): The Question of Interest Group Influence, in: Journal of Public Policy 27, 1, 1-12.

Eising, Rainer (2008): Interest groups in EU policy-making, in: Living Rev. Euro. Gov., Vol. 3, (2008), No. 4.

Fischer, Frank; Forester, John (Hg.) (1993): The Argumentative turn in policy analysis and planning. Durham, NC: Duke Univ. Press.

Page 17: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 17

Florack, Martin; Grunden, Timo (2011): Regierungszentralen im Kontext des formalen und informellen Regie-rens. In: Martin Florack und Timo Grunden (Hrsg.): Regierungszentralen. Organisation, Steuerung und Politik-formulierung zwischen Formalität und Informalität. Wiesbaden: VS Verl. für Sozialwissenschaften, S. 7–32.

Florack, Martin; Grunden, Timo; Korte, Karl-Rudolf (2011): Kein Governance ohne Government. Politikma-nagement auf Landesebene. In: Stephan Bröchler und Julia von Blumenthal (Hrsg.): Regierungskanzleien im politischen Prozess. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, S. 181–201.

Florack, Martin; Grunden, Timo; Korte, Karl-Rudolf (2008): No Governance without Government. Political Man-agement at the State Level: The Case of North Rhine-Westphalia. In: Rüdiger Schmitt-Beck, Tobias Debiel und Karl-Rudolf Korte (Hg.): Governance and legitimacy in a globalized world. Baden-Baden: Nomos, S. 75–104.

George, Alexander Lawrence; Bennett, Andrew (2005): Case studies and theory development in the social sci-ences. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press (BCSIA studies in international security).

Haas, Peter M. (1992): Introduction: epistemic communities and international policy coordination. In: Int. Org. 46 (01), S. 1.

Hajer, Maarten (1993): Discourse Coalitions in Practice: The Case of Acid Rain in Great Britain. In: Frank Fischer und John Forester (Hg.): The Argumentative turn in policy analysis and planning. Durham, NC: Duke Univ. Press.

Hall, Peter A.; Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996): Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms. In: Political Studies 44 (5), S. 936–957.

Hart, Jeffrey (1976): Three approaches to the measurement of power in international relations. In: Int. Org. 30 (02), S. 289.

Hassel, Anke (2009): Policies and politics in social pacts in Europe. In: European Journal of Industrial Relations 15 (1), S. 7–26.

Hojnacki, Marie; Kimball, David; Baumgartner, Frank; Berry, Jeffrey M.; Leech, Beth (2012) Studying Organiza-tional Advocacy and Influence: Reexamining Interest Group Research. Annual Review of Political Science, Vol. 15, pp. 379-399, 2012

King, Gary; Keohane, Robert Owen; Verba, Sidney (1994): Designing social inquiry. Scientific inference in quali-tative research.. Princeton, NJ: Univ. Press.

Klüver, Heike (2013): Lobbying in the European Union. Interest groups, lobbying coalitions, and policy change. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Korte, Karl-Rudolf; Fröhlich, Manuel (2009): Politik und Regieren in Deutschland. Strukturen, Prozesse, Entscheidungen. 3. Aufl. Paderborn: Schöningh.

Lowery, David (2013): Lobbying influence: Meaning, measurement and missing, in: Interest Groups & Advocacy (2013) 2, 1–26.

Mahoney, James (2010): After KKV: The New Methodology of Qualitative Research. In: World Pol. 62 (01), S. 120.

Mahoney, Christine (2007): Lobbying Success in the United States and the European Union. In: J. Pub. Pol. 27 (01), S. 35.

March, James G. (1955): An introduction to the theory and measurement of influence. In: The American Politi-cal Science Review 49 (2), S. 431–451.

Mayntz, Renate; Scharpf, Fritz W. (1995): Der Ansatz des akteurszentrierten Institutionalismus. In: Renate Ma-yntz und Fritz Scharpf (Hrsg.): Gesellschaftliche Selbstregelung und politische Steuerung. Frankfurt ;, New York: Campus, S. 39–72.

Mayring, Philipp (2002): Einführung in die qualitative Sozialforschung. Eine Anleitung zu qualitativem Denken. 5., überarb. und neu ausgestattete Aufl. Weinheim: Beltz-Verl.

Nullmeier, Frank (1993): Wissen und Policy-Forschung. Wissenspolitologie und rhetorischdialektisches Hand-lungsmodell, in: Héritier, Adrienne (Hrsg.): Policy-Analyse. Kritik und Neuorientierung, PVS-Sonderheft 24, Op-laden: 175-196.

Pedersen, Helene Helboe (2013): Is measuring interest group influence a mission impossible? The case of inter-est group influence in the Danish parliament. In: Int Groups Adv 2 (1), S. 27–47.

Page 18: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

18 Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence

Pritoni, Andrea (2014): How To Measure Interest Group Influence: Evidence From Italy. In: (forthcoming).

Przeworski, Adam; Teune, Henry (1970): The logic of comparative social inquiry. New York: Wiley.

Reutter, Werner; Rütters, Peter (2007): Mobilisierung und Organisation von Interessen. In: Thomas von Winter und Ulrich Willems (Hg.): Interessenverbände in Deutschland. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwiss., S. 119–138.

Rüb, Friedbert W. (2012): „Regieren“. Was machen Regierungen, wenn sie regieren? In: Björn Egner, Michael Haus und Georgios Terizakis (Hrsg.): Regieren Festschrift für Hubert Heinelt. Wiesbaden, SpringerVS, S. 111-134.

Rüb, Friedbert W. (2011): Regieren, Regierungszentrale und Regierungsstile. Konzeptionelle Überlegungen zum Regierungsprozess in einer sich beschleunigenden Welt, in: Stephan Bröchler, Julia von Blumenthal (Hrsg.): Regierungskanzleien im politischen Prozess, S. 69-101.

Rüb, Friedbert W. (2009): Multible-Streams-Ansatz: Grundlagen, Probleme und Kritik. In: Klaus Schubert und Niels C. Bandelow (Hrsg.): Lehrbuch der Politikfeldanalyse 2.0. 2., München: Oldenbourg, S. 348–374.

Sabatier, Paul A.; Jenkins-Smith, Hank (1993): Policy change and learning: An advocacy coalition framework. Boulder: Westview.

Sabatier, Paul A. (2007): The Need for Better Theories, in: Paul A. Sabatier (ed.) Theories of the Policy Process. 2nd Edition. Boulder, Co: Westview Press, p. 3-17.

Sabatier, Paul A.; Weible, Christopher M. (2007): The Advocacy Coalition Framework: Innovations and Clarifica-tions, in: Paul A. Sabatier (ed.) Theories of the Policy Process. 2nd Edition. Boulder, Co: Westview Press.

Salisbury, Robert H. (1984): Interest representation: The dominance of institutions. In: The American Political Science Review, S. 64–76.

Sartori, Giovanni (2011): Logica, metodo e linguaggio nelle scienze sociali. Bologna: Il mulino (Collezione di testi e di studi.Scienza politica).

Scharpf, Fritz W. (2000a): Interaktionsformen. Akteurzentrierter Institutionalismus in der Politikforschung. Opladen: Leske + Budrich.

Scharpf, Fritz W. (2000b): Institutions in Comparative Policy Research. In: Comparative Political Studies 33 (6-7), S. 762–790.

Schmidt, Manfred G. (2011): Das politische System Deutschlands. Institutionen, Willensbildung und Politikfel-der. 2. Aufl. Bonn: Bundeszentrale für Politische Bildung.

Schmidt, Vivien A. (2012): Scope, Dynamics, and Philosophical Underpinnings. In: The Argumentative Turn Re-visited: Public Policy as Communicative Practice, S. 85.

Schmidt, Vivien A. (2008): Discursive Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Discourse. In: Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 11 (1), S. 303–326.

Smith, Richard A. (1995): Interest group influence in the US Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, Vol. 20, Nr.1, 89-139.

Töller, Annette Elisabeth (2008): Kooperation im Schatten der Hierarchie. Dilemmata des Verhandelns zwischen Staat und Wirtschaft. In: Gunnar Folke Schuppert und Michael Zürn (Hrsg.): Governance in einer sich wandeln-den Welt. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, S. 283–312.

Truman, David B. (1951): The Governmental Process: Political Interests and Public Opinion. New York: Knopf.

Weible, Christopher M.; Sabatier, Paul A.; McQueen, Kelly (2009): Themes and Variations: Taking Stock of the Advocacy Coalition Framework. In: The Policy Studies Journal 37 (1), S. 121–140.

Weßels, Bernhard (2007): Das bundesdeutsche Verbandssystem in vergleichender Perspektive. Politische Spannungslinien und politische Ökonomie. In: Thomas Winter und Ulrich Willems (Hg.): Interessenverbände in Deutschland. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, S. 84–118.

Willems, Ulrich; Winter, Thomas von (2007): Interessenverbände als intermediäre Organisationen. Zum Wandel ihrer Strukturen, Funktionen, Strategien und Effekte in einer veränderten Umwelt. In: Thomas von Winter und Ulrich Willems (Hg.): Interessenverbände in Deutschland. 1. Aufl. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaf-ten, S. 13–50.

Page 19: Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the ...€¦ · An indirect pathway: interest group influence as policy coordination 2.1 The problem of conceptualizing influence and

Cooperative politics as an indirect pathway to the question of interest group influence 19

Appendix: Case selection: Policy coordination in forms of cooperative politics

Form of Cooperative Politics „Case family“ (federated state)

Duration Outcome (joint policy recommendation)

Coordination Group in the Climate Protection Plan

NRW1 since 2012 +

Working groups in the Climate Protection Plan

NRW 2012-2013 +

Working group in "Dialogue creates Future" (formally Alliance for Industry and Sustain-ability)

NRW since 2009/2012

-

(poss.?) Energy efficiency program „NRW saves energy“

NRW since 2007 -

Working groups of „Innovative Energy“

Bavaria 2011 - early 2014

+

Working group "climate protection by saving energy"

Bavaria 2012 +

Forum sustainable hydropower Bavaria 2012-2013 -

BEKO am IEKK Participation format for the energy concept

Ba-Wue2 2012-2013 +

Monitoring-Group “Energiewende” Ba-Wue since 2012 +

WIN Economy Initiative Sustainability Ba-Wue since 2010 -

(poss.?) Council for sustainable develop-ment

Ba-Wue since 2012 -

1 North Rhine-Westphalia, 2 Baden-Wuerttemberg