32
Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business

McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 2: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-2

Market Competition & Social Economic Efficiency

• Social economic efficiency• Exists when the goods & services that

society desires are produced & consumed with no waste from inefficiency

• Two efficiency conditions must be metProductive efficiencyAllocative efficiency

Page 3: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-3

Productive Efficiency

• Exists when suppliers produce goods & services at the lowest possible total cost to society

• Occurs when firms operate along their expansion paths in both the short-run & long-run

Page 4: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-4

Allocative Efficiency

• Requires businesses to supply optimal amounts of all goods & services demanded by society• And these units must be rationed to individuals

who place the highest value on consuming them

• Optimal level of output is reached when the MB of another unit to consumers just equals the MC to society of producing another unit• Where P = MC (marginal-cost-pricing)

Page 5: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-5

Social Economic Efficiency

• Achieved by markets in perfectly competitive equilibrium• At the intersection of demand & supply,

conditions for productive & allocative efficiency are met

• At the market-clearing price, buyers & sellers engage in voluntary exchange that maximizes social surplus

Page 6: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-6

Efficiency in Perfect Competition (Figure 16.1)

Page 7: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-7

Market Failure & the Case for Government Intervention

• Competitive markets can achieve social economic efficiency without government regulation

• But, not all markets are competitive, and even competitive markets can sometimes fail to achieve maximum social surplus

• Market failure• When a market fails to achieve social economic

efficiency and, consequently, fails to maximize social surplus

Page 8: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-8

Market Failure & the Case for Government Intervention

• Six forms of market failure can undermine economic efficiency:• Monopoly power• Natural monopoly• Negative (& positive) externalities• Common property resources• Public goods• Information problems

Page 9: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-9

Market Failure & the Case for Government Intervention

• Absent market failure, no efficiency argument can be made for government intervention in competitive markets

Page 10: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-10

Market Power & Public Policy

• Firms with market power must price above marginal cost to maximize profit (P > MC)• These firms fail to achieve allocative efficiency,

which reduces social surplus Lost surplus is a deadweight loss

• Allocative efficiency is lost because the profit-maximizing price does not result in marginal-cost-pricing At the profit-maximizing point, MB > MC Resources are underallocated to the industry

Page 11: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-11

Louisiana White Shrimp Market (Figure 16.2)

Page 12: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-12

Market Power & Public Policy

• When the degree of market power grows high enough, antitrust officials refer to it legally as monopoly power• No clear legal threshold has been

established to determine when market power becomes monopoly power

Page 13: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-13

Promoting Competition Through Antitrust Policy

• A high degree of market power (or monopoly power) can arise in three ways:• Actual or attempted monopolization• Price-fixing cartels• Mergers among horizontal competitors

Page 14: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-14

• Firms may be found guilty of actual monopolization only if both of the following conditions are met:• Behavior is judged to be undertaken for the

sole purpose of creating monopoly power• Firm successfully achieves high degree of

market power

• Firms can also be guilty of attempted monopolization

Promoting Competition Through Antitrust Policy

Page 15: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-15

Natural Monopoly & Market Failure

• Natural monopoly• When a single firm can produce total

consumer demand for a good or service at a lower long-run total cost than if two or more firms produce total industry output

• Long-run costs are subadditive

Page 16: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-16

Subadditive Costs & Natural Monopoly (Figure 16.3)

Page 17: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-17

Natural Monopoly & Market Failure

• Breaking up a natural monopoly is undesirable• Increasing number of firms drives up total

cost & undermines productive efficiency

• Under natural monopoly, no single price can establish social economic efficiency

Page 18: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-18

Regulating Price Under Natural Monopoly (Figure 16.4)

Page 19: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-19

Natural Monopoly & Market Failure

• With economies of scale, marginal-cost-pricing results in a regulated natural monopoly earning negative economic profit

• Two-part pricing is a solution that can meet both efficiency conditions & maximize social surplus

Page 20: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-20

The Problem of Negative Externality

• Externalities• When actions taken by market participants

create either benefits or costs that spill over to other members of society

• Positive externalities occur when spillover effects are beneficial to society

• Negative externalities occur when spillover effects are costly to society

Page 21: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-21

• Externalities undermine allocative efficiency• Market participants rationally choose to

ignore the benefits & costs of their actions that spill over to others

• Competitive market prices do not capture social benefits or costs that spill over to society

The Problem of Negative Externality

Page 22: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-22

• Managers rationally ignore external costs when making profit-maximizing production decisions • Social cost of production:

Social cost = Private cost + External cost

or

Social cost – Private cost = External cost

The Problem of Negative Externality

Page 23: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-23

Negative Externality & Allocative Inefficiency (Figure 16.5)

Page 24: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-24

Pollution as a Negative Externality (Figure 16.6)

Page 25: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-25

Finding the Optimal Level of Pollution (Figure 16.7)

Page 26: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-26

Optimal Emission Taxation (Figure 16.8)

Page 27: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-27

Nonexcludability

• Two kinds of market failure caused by nonexcludability:• Common property resources• Public goods

Page 28: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-28

Common Property Resources

• Resources for which property rights are absent or poorly defined• No one can effectively be excluded from

such resources• Without government intervention, these

resources are generally overexploited & undersupplied

Page 29: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-29

Public Goods

• A public good is nonexcludable & nondepletable

• The inability to exclude nonpayers creates a free-rider problem for the private provision of public goods• Even when private firms supply public

goods, a deadweight loss can be avoided only if the price of the good is zero

Page 30: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-30

Information & Market Failure

• Market failure may also occur because consumers lack perfect knowledge• Perfect knowledge includes knowledge

about product prices, qualities, and any hazards

• Market power can emerge because of imperfectly informed consumers

Page 31: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-31

• Consumers may over- or under-estimate quality of goods & services• If they over-value quality, they will demand

too much product relative to the allocatively efficient amount

• If they under-value quality, they will demand too little

Information & Market Failure

Page 32: Chapter 16: Government Regulation of Business McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved

16-32

Imperfect Information on Product Quality (Figure 16.9)