23
Bankruptcy Equilibrium: Secured and Unsecured assets Aloisio Araujo a,b and J. Mauricio Villalba a a IMPA, b FGV Rio de Janeiro - Brazil February, 2016 Preliminary version Abstract Economies with lack of commitment have been extensively studied us- ing instruments like collateral to back promises and market exclusion to avoid default. We study an economy with secured and unsecured assets, where the last ones play an important role in allowing interstate and in- tertemporal transfers. Bankruptcy punishment is the seize of a fraction of agent’s income, this leads to lack of convexity in the budget set. If the return matrix has ex ante full rank we can implement the Arrow Debreu allocation (AD) with a large enough seizure rate, indirectly proving equi- librium existence. Key words: Bankruptcy, seizure rate, debt constraint, contagion. 1 Introduction Debt is an important financial tool to transfer wealth among dates and to insur- ance among different states of nature. We can separate debt into two categories: Secured debt, as mortgage loan, is backed by some collateral; it played an im- portant role during the last financial crisis [14]. Unsecured debt as credit card debt and student loans, is not backed by collateral, this does not mean there is no default punishment, actually its punishment (established by a bankruptcy law) might be hard. Although most debt is secured, the role of unsecured debt is still important in the economy, especially for people who lack of collateral. It also depends on demographic variables. As can be seen in [12], unsecured debt is more impor- tant for people under 35 years old. Also, in the case of firm debt [9] shows that unsecured debt moves procyclically and tends to lead the GDP, while the secured debt is acyclical. 1

BankruptcyEquilibrium: SecuredandUnsecured assets › Documents › DepartmentsCentres › ...JXsec j=1 (θj −ϕj)min p s1r j;p s2C j + JXunsec j=1 (zj)+κjps1r′j. Where κj s

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • Bankruptcy Equilibrium: Secured and Unsecured

    assets

    Aloisio Araujo a,b and J. Mauricio Villalba a

    aIMPA, b FGV

    Rio de Janeiro - Brazil

    February, 2016Preliminary version

    Abstract

    Economies with lack of commitment have been extensively studied us-ing instruments like collateral to back promises and market exclusion toavoid default. We study an economy with secured and unsecured assets,where the last ones play an important role in allowing interstate and in-tertemporal transfers. Bankruptcy punishment is the seize of a fractionof agent’s income, this leads to lack of convexity in the budget set. If thereturn matrix has ex ante full rank we can implement the Arrow Debreuallocation (AD) with a large enough seizure rate, indirectly proving equi-librium existence.

    Key words: Bankruptcy, seizure rate, debt constraint, contagion.

    1 Introduction

    Debt is an important financial tool to transfer wealth among dates and to insur-ance among different states of nature. We can separate debt into two categories:Secured debt, as mortgage loan, is backed by some collateral; it played an im-portant role during the last financial crisis [14]. Unsecured debt as credit carddebt and student loans, is not backed by collateral, this does not mean thereis no default punishment, actually its punishment (established by a bankruptcylaw) might be hard.Although most debt is secured, the role of unsecured debt is still important inthe economy, especially for people who lack of collateral. It also depends ondemographic variables. As can be seen in [12], unsecured debt is more impor-tant for people under 35 years old. Also, in the case of firm debt [9] showsthat unsecured debt moves procyclically and tends to lead the GDP, while thesecured debt is acyclical.

    1

  • For secured debts, the collateral constraint imposes a debt limit; individualscannot take large amounts of secured debt because at the same time they needto constitute the collateral requirement, which is some durable commodity withlimited supply. For unsecured debt, we need to introduce a maximum amountof debt. Consider an individual who goes to a financial institution to ask fora loan, the bank usually makes a credit analysis of the individual in order todetermine the agent’s ability to repay the debt, and determines a credit limit asthe maximum amount of money that the bank should lend the individual [21].For simplicity, we do not model the way this limit is estimated and we assumethat this limit is exogenously established by some intermediate agent or a reg-ulator.1

    When the regulator defines the limit of credit, he might not have all individual’srelevant information, or might have incomplete information about future eventsand fails to determine a limit of credit below which the debtor always honorsher debts. So in certain scenarios the debtor agent might not be able to repayher debt, in this situation we say that she goes bankruptcy.Allowing for bankruptcy brings some technical difficulties, agent’s feasible set(including consumption and portfolio) is no longer a convex set, so it is possiblethat the best response correspondence is not convex, this prevents us to use theclassical fixed point theorems to prove equilibrium existence. To overcome thisdifficulty, two seminal papers on the subject [6] and [25] work with a non-atomicset of agents2. In a dynamical economy, this approach has been used to studysome policy implications of a change in the Bankruptcy legislation [13].Bankruptcy is idiosyncratic; each agent decides how much to delivery, thiscould create a cascade effect. Agents might default by contagion. Portfoliosdefine a lending network among agents, creating a framework to study sys-temic risk. There are several studies about network stability (see for exam-ple [1–3, 11, 16, 19, 27]) and its dependence on shocks and network structure.Most of these works assume that links and portfolios are exogenously given,implying that a more stable network is always preferred. Allowing a greaternumber of defaults (less stability) might be better when prices and portfoliosare endogenous. In an exogenous framework, defaulting asset is overvalued ifthe shock that leads to default is large enough (lender is paying too much foran asset that defaults). An endogenous price reflects default probabilities, solender pays a fair price.In this paper, we address an economy with finite agents (or finite types). Thereare two dates and agents can transfer resources among dates and states of natureby negotiating a set of secured and unsecured assets. In bankruptcy, the seizurerate defines how much of the income is confiscated. This hybrid model combinesthe collateral model studied in [7, 17] and the model of unsecured claims and

    1In [23] this credit limit is endogenous. It is defined as an optimal choice for the lendermanager. Because of private information, bankruptcy probability might be positive.

    2When introducing a set of continuous agents, the economy turns out to be convex, in thesense that the aggregate best response correspondence is convex valued, and, except for sometechnical details, equilibrium existence can be proved in a similar way as in an Arrow-Debreueconomy.

    2

  • bankruptcy studied in [6, 25]. Assuming that there is a finite type of agentswe can prove equilibrium existence when agents choose a convex combination ofoptimal strategies. This can be interpreted in two ways: 1) there is a continuumof agents of each type, meaning that in equilibrium identical agents can takedifferent choices, or 2) agents choose mixed strategies. In either case, the proofis quite standard, we only need to replace the best response correspondence byits convex hull.Without the convexification approach, we can prove equilibrium existence byimplementing the Arrow Debreu allocation. We are interested in study condi-tions that ensure its implementation with a mix of secured and unsecured assets.In [20] with permanent exclusion, equilibrium might be Pareto ranked. In a sim-ilar context, [8] shows that the Arrow Debreu allocation can be implementedwith partial exclusion and strong risk aversion. In our setting, if the vector ofindividual state transference is contained in the span of the payoff matrix, thenwe need to check if the collateral constraint is satisfied. In case it is not, wecan add unsecured assets without changing the matrix span. Next, in orderto ensure that in equilibrium this span is not changed, we need to consider aseizure rate high enough to avoid bankruptcy in equilibrium; this does not ruleout the possibility of default on some of the secured assets.A necessary condition to implement the Arrow Debreu allocation is a mono-tonicity relation3 similar to [5]. This condition is necessary for the collateralconstraint and it is sufficient if we implement with only one secured asset. Inthe pure secured model [5,17], the collateral constraint implies that individualscannot make any temporal transfers, they are net savers. Introducing unse-cured assets relaxes this and individuals can transfer resources between datesand states of nature without worrying about the collateral constraint. This isvery important when there is lack of collateral; also, it is important for individ-uals with low income, some of them probably still young and looking for studentloans that does not require collateral.Paper is organized as follows: next we study the hydrid model of secured andunsecured assets are characterize conditions to implement the Arrow DebreuAllocation without bankruptcy.

    2 Implementing the Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

    with a mix of secured and unsecured assets.

    2.1 The Model

    We consider an economy with two periods t = 0, 1 and S possible states ofnature s ∈ S = {1, · · · , S} in t = 1.In each state s ∈ S∗ = {0, 1, · · · , S} (s = 0 represents period 0), there are spotmarkets for two commodities l = 1, 2. Commodity l = 1 is perishable whilel = 2 is durable, this means that consuming one unit of the durable good in

    3The value of net consumption should be larger in states with higher relative prices.

    3

  • t = 0 guarantees a consumption of one unit of this commodity in the next pe-

    riod. The vector of prices is p = (p0, p1, · · · , pS) ∈ R2(S+1)++ , where psl is the

    price of commodity l in state s for l = 1, 2 and s ∈ S∗.There is a set I = {1, · · · , I} of agents with strictly increasing, concave and

    continuous utility functions ui : R2(S+1)+ → R. They are also characterized by

    their endowments wi = (wi0, · · · , wiS) ∈ R

    2(S+1)++ .

    There is a set of assets that can be negotiated in t = 0 and promise returns int = 1. In this set of assets we consider secured and unsecured assets.Let Jsec = {1, · · · , J

    sec} be the set of secured assets. A secured asset j promisesrjs units of the perishable commodity in state s. They differ on the collateralrequirement Cj to back the promises. An agent selling one unit of the securedasset j should constitute Cj > 0 units of the durable good. We assume thatdebtor holds the collateral and it can not be used to back other promises. Agentdefaults if the value of the debt is greater that the value of the collateral. So, asecured asset with collateral requirement Cj returns min

    {

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    in states.On the other hand, there is a set Junsec = {1, · · · , J

    unsec} of unsecured as-sets. Their promises are not backed by collateral, which does not imply thatagents can default without suffering any penalty. Creditors are protected by abankruptcy law that establishes the bankruptcy procedure.We assume that all unsecured assets are numeraire, they pay in units of theperishable good, a unit of the unsecured asset j promises to pay r′js units of theperishable commodity. If an agent i holds portfolio z ∈ RJ

    unsec

    , the total debtin state s is4

    j(zj)−ps1r

    ′js . Debtor might file for bankruptcy, in that case all

    debt is forgiven (excluding secured debt), but the judge can seize some of thedebtor income to partially repay the creditors.Debtor’s income is composed by non financial and financial income. Non finan-cial income is the value of the endowment psw

    is and the value of the durable good

    consumed in t = 0, ps2x02. If the agent holds a portfolio (θ, ϕ) ∈ RJsec

    + ×RJsec

    + (θrepresents long positions and ϕ short selling) of secured assets, then her financialincome is:

    Jsec∑

    j=1

    (θj − ϕj)min{

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    +

    Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)+κjsps1r

    ′js .

    Where κjs ∈ [0, 1] is the delivery rate, defined in equilibrium according todebtors’ deliveries.The bankruptcy procedure states that secured debt have senior priority up tothe value of the collateral, after paying the secured debt up the collateral value,all financial income can be garnished. But only a fraction γ ∈ [0, 1] of the

    4For any number a we call (a)− = max{0,−a} and (a)+ = max{0, a} the negative andpositive part of a.

    4

  • endowment can be garnished. So, in case of bankruptcy, judge can seize5:

    γpswis + ps2x02 +

    Jsec∑

    j=1

    (θj − ϕj)min{

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    +

    Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)+κjsps1r

    ′js ,

    so, the delivery of unsecured debts will be:

    Dis = min{

    Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)−ps1r

    ′js ;

    γpswis + ps2x02 +

    Jsec∑

    j=1

    (θj − ϕj)min{

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    +Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)+κjsps1r

    ′js }.

    Let (qsec, qunsec) ∈ RJsec

    ++ × RJunsec

    ++ be the vector of asset prices in t = 0, agenti’s budget constraint in t = 0 is

    p0(x0 − wi0) + q

    sec(θ − ϕ) + qunsecz ≤ 0 (1)

    and the collateral constraint for secured assets

    x02 ≥Jsec∑

    j=1

    ϕjCj (2)

    In t = 1, state s, the budget constraint is

    ps(xs−wis−(0, x02))+D

    is ≤

    Jsec∑

    j=1

    (θj−ϕj)min{

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    +Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)+κjsps1r

    ′js

    (3)So, given commodities and asset’s prices and delivery rate, the budget setfor agent i, Bi(p, qsec, qunsec, κ) consists on all vectors of consumption andportfolio satisfying (1),(2), (3) and a bounded short selling constraint for un-secured assets zj ≥ −m with m ≥ 0 for all j ∈ Junsec. We say that aconsumption bundle x is affordable if there is a portfolio (θ, ϕ, z) such that(x, θ, ϕ, z) ∈ Bi(p, qsec, qunsec, κ)6.

    5We could consider a more general punishment, but in order to study the seizure rate γwe’ve chosen this form. Also notice that by the collateral constraint this term is non negative,with a more general punishment rule we can not assure this, so we should consider only thepositive part.

    6The budget set Bi(p, qsec, qunsec, κ) could be written as the union of 2S convex sets, eachof them defines the states of nature in which agent i defaults in the unsecured debt. Oneof such sets is the non bankruptcy region in which for all states of nature, the followingconstraints hold:

    Dis =Junsec∑

    j=1

    (zj)−ps1r

    ′js .

    5

  • If agent i hold a positive unsecured debt∑Junsec

    j=1 (zj)−ps1r

    ′js > 0, the delivery

    for each asset is proportional to the value of the debt:

    Dis,j′ = τis(zj′ )

    −ps1r′j′

    s ,

    with

    τ is =Dis

    ∑Junsec

    j=1 (zj)−ps1r

    ′js

    The proceedings are distributed proportionally among all creditors. Thedelivery rate adjusts to match the total delivery of debtors with creditors returnsfor each unsecured asset j ∈ J unsec and state s:

    κjsps1r′js

    i∈I

    (zij)+ =

    i∈I

    Dis,j (4)

    Definition 2.1 An equilibrium7 for the economy with secured and unsecuredassets is a vector of prices p, qsec, qunsec, delivery rates κ and an allocation ofconsumption and portfolios

    (

    xi, θi, ϕi, zi)

    i∈I, such that:

    • For each i, xi is affordable with the portfolio (θi, ϕi, zi) and is optimal inthe set of all affordable consumption bundles in Bi(p, qsec, qunsec, κ).

    •∑

    i∈I

    (

    xi0 − wi0

    )

    = 0.

    • For each s ∈ S:∑

    i∈I

    (

    xis − wis − (0, w

    i02))

    = 0.

    •∑

    i∈I zi = 0

    •∑

    i∈I(θi − ϕi) = 0

    • (4) holds.

    We would like to compare this equilibrium with the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium,so we proceed to define it.

    Definition 2.2 An Arrow-Debreu equilibrium (AD) is a vector of allocations(xi)i∈I and a vector of prices p such that:

    • For each i, xi is optimal in the set of all y ∈ R2(S+1)+ with

    ∑S

    s=0 ps(ys −

    wis)−∑S

    s=1 ps2y02 ≤ 0.

    •∑

    i∈I

    (

    xi0 − wi0

    )

    = 0.

    • For each s ∈ S:∑

    i∈I

    (

    xis − wis − (0, w

    i02))

    = 0.

    7We refer to the appendix for a proof of equilibrium existence when each i ∈ I chooses aconvex combination of optimal strategies. This could be interpreted as an equilibrium withrandom strategies or a type of continuum agents such that in equilibrium identical agentsmight choose different strategies.

    6

  • 2.2 Some Implementation Results

    A first question to ask: When is AD allocation implementable for the economywith secured and unsecured assets? Even though it is hard to find conditionsthat are necessary and sufficient, we can find a necessary condition associatedto the seizure rate.

    Proposition 2.1 Let(

    (xi)i∈I , p)

    be the AD equilibrium. If xi is affordable inthe non bankruptcy region for all agents, then seizure rate satisfies:

    γ ≥ γ∗ = max(s,i)∈S×I

    [

    1−psx

    is

    pswis

    ]+

    Proof Let mi =(

    ps(xis − w

    is)− ps2x

    i02

    )

    s∈S∈ RS be the vector of transferences

    between states of nature. Since xi is affordable in the non bankruptcy region,then there are an unsecured and secured portfolios zi and (θi − ϕi) such that:

    mis =

    Jsec∑

    j=1

    (θij − ϕij)min

    {

    ps1rjs; ps2C

    j}

    +

    Junsec∑

    j=1

    zijps1r′js ,

    where we have set the delivery rate κ equal to one. Also for xi to be affordablein the non bankruptcy region:

    −mis ≤ γpswis + ps2x

    i02,

    so, for all agents i and states s:

    γ ≥

    (

    1−psx

    is

    pswis

    )

    implying that γ ≥ γ∗.

    If Junsec = 0, in [17] it is showed that a necessary condition to implement theAD equilibrium with secured assets is

    ps(xis − w

    is) ≥ 0 (5)

    This condition implies that individuals can not transfer endowments from onestate to another, the value of consumption must be always at least equal to thevalue of the endowment. As in [5], we say that J CC ⊂ Jsec is a set of completecollaterized assets if for each state s, there is some secured asset j ∈ J CC withps1 = ps2C

    j (assuming that rjs = 1 for all secured assets). In [5] it is shown anecessary condition to implement an AD equilibrium with secured assets J CC :

    Proposition 2.2 Given an AD equilibrium (p, (xi)i∈I), a necessary conditionfor there to exists an equilibrium with complete collaterized assets with the sameallocation is that for all agents i and all pairs of states s and s′ with ps2

    ps1> ps′2

    ps′1:

    1

    ps1ps(x

    is − w

    is) ≥

    1

    ps′1ps′(x

    is′ − w

    is′ ) ≥ 0. (6)

    7

  • It turns out that this condition is also sufficient for two states of nature and ifagents preferences does not depend on the durable commodity in t = 0.One of the main issues of the pure secured model is that the collateral constraintis too hard for debtors, actually if we consider the durable good as another wayof saving, then all agents are net savers.The existence of the set of secured assets J CC is guarantee if we assume that allagents have identical homothetic preferences. With this, equilibrium commodityprices depends only on aggregate terms, so if the AD allocation is implementable,then prices should be the same. After computing AD prices we can computethe collateral requirements necessary to construct the set of secured assets J CC .Generically, the S×S return matrix will be of full rank8, so all transfers ps(x

    is−

    wis − (0, xi02)) are attainable for some secured portfolio. Nevertheless, those

    portfolios might violate the collateral constraint and in an equilibrium withpure secured assets some assets might not be traded and equilibrium will notbe Pareto efficient (although it might be Pareto constraint).One way to weaken condition 5 is to introduce unsecured assets. They donot require collateral and allow agents to transfer endowments among states ofnature. If the return matrix of the unsecured assets is equal to the J CC securedassets, then we might be able to implement an AD equilibrium with a mix ofsecured and unsecured assets. As the combined return matrix is already of fullrank, in order to keep the full rank property the seizure rate established by thebankruptcy law should be large enough to avoid default on unsecured assets.The next result formalizes our observation for the case of two states of nature

    Proposition 2.3 Let (p, (xi)i∈I) be the AD equilibrium when S = 2. Suppose,without lost of generality, that β = p12

    p22− p11

    p21> 0. If the seizure rate satisfies

    γ ≥ γ∗ = max(s,i)∈S×I

    (

    1−psx

    is

    pswis

    )+

    .

    Then, there is a debt constraint m such that the AD allocation is feasible for allagents if, and only if, one of the following conditions holds:

    a) For all i:

    1

    p11p1(x

    i1 − w

    i1)−

    1

    p21p2(x

    i2 − w

    i2) ≥ 0

    b) For all i:

    1

    p11p1(x

    i1 − w

    i1)−

    1

    p21p2(x

    i2 − w

    i2) ≤

    β

    p11

    (

    p2(xi2 − w

    i2) + p22x

    i02

    )

    .

    Proof The claim on the seizure rate is due to proposition 2.1.

    8Generically the price ratios ps1/ps2 are different for all s, we concentrate in this case.

    8

  • a) We implement the AD equilibrium using the secured asset with collateralrequirement C1 = p11/p12 and the unsecured asset with returns (p11, p21).The collateral constraint is equivalent to:

    xi02 + zi1C

    1 ≥ 0

    Let mi =(

    ps(xis − w

    is)− ps2x

    i02

    )

    s∈S∈ RS be the vector of transferences

    between states of nature.

    Define

    τ =1

    p11p1(x

    i1 − w

    i1)−

    1

    p21p2(x

    i2 − w

    i2),

    then,

    τ =1

    p11(mi1 + p12x

    i02)−

    1

    p21(mi2 + p22x

    i02)

    The secured and unsecured portfolios span all transfers, so

    mi1 = p11zi1 + p11z

    i2

    mi2 = p22p11p12

    zi1 + p21zi2,

    so

    τ =p12p21 − p11p22

    p11p21(xi02 + z

    i1C

    1)

    Then, τ ≥ 0 if, and only if, the collateral constraint is satisfied.

    b) In this case we implement the AD equilibrium with the secured asset withcollateral requirement C2 = p21/p22 and the unsecured asset with returns(p11, p22p11/p12). The collaretal constraint is equivalent to

    xi02 + zi2C

    2 ≥ 0

    Define

    τ∗ =1

    p11p1(x

    i1 − w

    i1)−

    1

    p21p2(x

    i2 − w

    i2)−

    β

    p11

    (

    p2(xi2 − w

    i2) + p22x

    i02

    )

    ,

    The return matrix is the same as in the previous item, so

    τ∗ =p12p21 − p11p22

    p11p21(−zi2C

    2 − xi02)

    then, τ∗ ≤ 0 if, and only if, the collateral constraint is satisfied.

    The first condition is similar to (6), it preserves the order, but it doesn’t requirenon negativeness. With this, the AD allocation is feasible with the securedasset with the lowest collateral requirement and the unsecured asset. The secondcondition is new to our knowledge and it says that even if the monotone relation(6) fails, the AD allocation is still feasible if the failure of (6) is not too large. Inthis case, the AD allocation is feasible using the secured asset with the largest

    9

  • collateral requirement.Compared to the pure collateral economy, Proposition 2.3 enlarges the sets ofeconomies (endowments) for which the AD allocation is implementable. In thisproposition at least one asset is secured, even if those conditions are not satisfied,we still can implement AD, but we will need both assets to be unsecured.Proposition 2.3 shows conditions that guarantee feasibility of the AD allocation,but it does not say anything about optimality. Recall that debtors who holdsthe unsecured asset might file for bankruptcy and deliver less than the promise.The budget set can be decomposed as the union of convex sets, one of themis the set of consumption bundles and portfolios such that agent does not filefor bankruptcy. Proposition 2.3 actually shows that consumption bundles inthis sets are contained in the Arrow Debreu budget set, but it is still possibleto find another consumption bundle in the other sets (sets in which agent fillsfor bankruptcy at least in one state) that improves her utility (see the 2x2example).Next proposition establishes that if the AD allocation is feasible, then it isoptimal, provided a high enough seizure.

    Proposition 2.4 If the Arrow Debreu Allocation (xi)i∈I is feasible in the nonbankruptcy region and if for all agents, preferences are represented by a C1

    utility function ui that satisfy Inada condition

    limmin{xsl}→0

    u′i(x) = +∞.

    Then, there is some γ∗∗ < 1 such that the Arrow Debreu allocation is an equi-librium for the non commitment economy for all γ ≥ γ∗∗.

    2.2.1 2× 2 Model

    We borrow a parametric version of an example given in [5] to point out how toimplement the AD allocation with a mix of secured and unsecured assets andthe relevance of the latter. AD allocation might not be implementable with apure secured asset market when durable good is unevenly distributed, we needto introduce at least one unsecured asset. The unsecured asset used dependson durable preferences and distribution. Also, the interstate shock plays an im-portant role when the interstate shock gets larger, agents need larger portfoliosto attain these hedging.There are two agents with identical homothetic preferences and two equal prob-ably states of nature

    α log(x01) + (1− α) log(x02) +1

    2

    2∑

    s=1

    (α log(xs1) + (1− α) log(xs2)) ,

    where α denotes the preference for the perishable good. Endowments are asfollow

    wi = (wi01, ηiw02, w

    i11, 0, w

    i21, 0).

    10

  • Agents receive an endowment of the durable commodity only in t = 0, ηi rep-resents the fraction of the durable commodity that belongs to agent i.Since utilities are homothetic, commodity prices are independent on the endow-ment’s distribution. Arrow Debreu prices are

    p =

    (

    1, 2(1− α)

    α

    w01w02

    ,w012w11

    ,(1− α)

    α

    w012w02

    ,w012w21

    ,(1− α)

    α

    w012w02

    )

    ,

    where wsl =∑

    i wisl.

    Notice that durable price is the same in both states of nature. This equality isdue to equal probabilities and because agents receive durable endowments onlyin t = 0.Endogenous collateral requirements are

    Cs =α

    1− α

    w02ws1

    .

    The return matrix for the J CC secured assets (if w11 > w21, asset 1 is thesub-prime and asset 2 is prime)9,10is

    R =w012w11

    (

    1 11 w11

    w21

    )

    ,

    which is clearly a full rank matrix, so all transfers are possible, but the neededportfolio might not meet the collateral constraint.The collateral constraint depends on durable consumption:

    xi02 = αw022

    (

    wi01w01

    − 2ηi +wi112w11

    +wi212w21

    )

    + ηiw02.

    We can also compute portfolios for assets 1 and 2:

    zi1 =α

    2w11

    (

    wi01w01

    + 2(1− α)

    αηi +

    wi112w11

    +wi212w21

    )

    − w11wi11 − w

    i21

    w11 − w21,

    zi2 =wi11w21 − w

    i21w11

    w11 − w21= −

    p11wi11 − p21w

    i21

    p11 − p21

    The collateral constraint:

    ∆i = xi02 − C1(zi1)

    − − C2(zi2)− ≥ 0,

    its sign is independent of durable endowment. Both durable consumption andcollateral requirement are proportional to durable endowment, so the sign of thelast expression will be independent of it. To fix ideas lets fix some numericalvalues:

    w1 = (4, 4(1− η), 4, 0, 4, 0)

    9The case w11 < w21 is analogous and if there is equality, the return matrix is singular.10Sub-prime asset is the one with highest default probability. In our context (as in [5] ) the

    sub-prime asset is the one with the lowest collateral requirement.

    11

  • 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    α

    η

    η − 1 +α(1+9α)15(1−α)2 ≤ 0

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    α

    η

    η ≥35

    α

    1−α

    a) b)

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    α

    η

    00.2

    0.40.6

    0.81

    00.2

    0.40.6

    0.810

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    αη

    γ

    c) d)

    Figure 1:

    w2 = (2, 4η, 6, 0, 2, 0),

    agent 1 endowment is deterministic, she has a long position on the sub-primeasset and a short position on the prime asset.Collateral constraint for agents 1 and 2 are, respectively, equivalent to:

    1− η −α(1 + 9α)

    15(1− α)2≥ 0 (7)

    η −3

    5

    α

    1− α≥ 0. (8)

    If at least one asset is unsecured, the seizure rate necessary to implement theAD allocation must be at least:

    γ ≥ γ∗ = max

    {

    0;1

    10−

    3

    2

    (1− α)

    α(1− η);

    1

    3−

    5

    3

    (1− α)

    αη

    }

    (9)

    γ∗ is a non decreasing function of α and it is concave on the durable distribution.Given a preference parameter, the seizure rate needed to implement AD attainsits minimum when the durable is more fairly distributed.Figure 1 (above) shows the values of α and η for which the collateral constraintare satisfied. The left (right) one corresponds to collateral constraint when onlythe prime (sub-prime) asset is secured. c) shows the values of α and η for whichthe AD allocation can be implemented using secured assets only. In d) we showthe minimum seizure rate that implements the AD allocation when at least oneasset is unsecured.

    12

  • 2.2.2 Feasibility does not imply optimality

    If η = 0 and α = 0.2, agent 1 holds all the durable, the AD allocation is

    x1 = (5.52, 3.68, 9.20, 3.68, 5.52, 3.68)and x2 = (0.48, 0.32, 0.80, 0.32, 0.48, 0.32).

    The required portfolios are z1 = (9.20,−4.00) and z2 = (−9.20, 4.00). Agent 2is poor in the first date and borrows heavily on asset 1, but she does not satisfythe collateral constraint: x202 − (z

    21)

    −C1 = −0.6. The AD allocation is notfeasible with two secured assets. The trade off agents face is choosing betweenincreasing consumption today and reducing risk in t = 1. Clearly asset 2 isbetter for risk sharing, but since agent 2 is too poor and have high preferenceson consuming the durable good, then she prefers to choose asset 1 with thelowest collateral requirement.If asset 1 were unsecured, agents 1 and 2 would be able to choose portfolios z1

    and z2, respectively. Agent’s 2 total debt in both states is (z21)−ps1r

    1s = 2.76.

    She will honor her debt as long as the seizure rate is large enough:

    mins=1,2

    {

    γps1w2s1 + ps2x

    202 + z

    22ps1

    }

    ≥ 2.76

    then agent 2 does not default in the unsecured asset and the Arrow Debreuallocation is attainable.For this example γ∗ = 0.33. We also need a constraint for the maximum amountof unsecured debt, otherwise agent 2 could take an arbitrarily large amount ofdebt in the unsecured asset and attain an unbounded utility. For this examplewe take a debt constraint m = 9.2, that is just enough to allow portfolio z2.For this example, condition b) of proposition 2.3 holds, so the AD allocation issupported with the secured asset with the largest collateral constraint (asset 2)and an unsecured asset with the same payoff of secured asset 1.As we mentioned, γ∗ only guarantees that the AD allocation is feasible andis optimal in the non bankruptcy subset. We should check whether there isanother consumption bundle in the bankruptcy region that improves the utilityof agent 2 (the seller of the unsecured asset).Budget set can be written as the union of four convex sets:

    1. The Non bankruptcy region.

    2. Bankruptcy only in state s = 1.

    3. Bankruptcy only in state s = 2.

    4. Bankruptcy in both states.

    Table (1) shows optimal consumption bundles and portfolios for each case. No-tice that in order to keep her promise agent 2 must buy some amount of thesecured asset. In the bankruptcy regions she could reduce her long position onthe secured asset, this will reduce her income in t = 1 and she won’t be ableto keep her promise, her consumption in the bankruptcy state will reduce, butshe increases her consumption in t = 0. If the reduce of her income (associated

    13

  • Case x01 x02 x11 x12 x21 x22 z θ ϕ Utility1 0.48 0.32 0.80 0.32 0.48 0.32 -9.20 4.00 0.00 -3.07292(s = 1) 0.63 0.28 0.80 0.32 0.51 0.34 -9.20 5.20 0.82 -3.05753(s = 2) 0.56 0.47 0.93 0.37 0.26 0.17 -3.20 0.00 2.80 -3.17384 1.50 0.84 0.80 0.32 0.27 0.18 -9.20 0.00 5.01 -2.6643

    Table 1: Agents optimize in the full bankruptcy region.

    to γ) is small enough, then her extra consumption in t = 0 more than offsether losses in t = 1, this way she can get an utility greater than with the ADbundle. As can be seen in the table her best choice is to file for bankruptcy inboth states, so the AD allocation (even being feasible) is not an equilibrium.Nevertheless, as proposition 2.4 says, if we increase further the seizure rate,then agent 2 income losses for bankruptcy have a greater (negative) effect thanthe consumption increases in t = 0. Our numerical experiments shows that itsuffices to take a seizure rate γ ≥ 0.46.This example shows the relevance of unsecured assets when collateral con-

    straints are too tight. Unsecured debt provides a way of transferring endow-ments between states without worrying about the correct amount of durableconsumption. Whats more, to avoid unsecured default, the seizure rate doesnot need to take too large values, avoiding draconian penalties of default.

    2.2.3 A Numerical Exercise with social mobility

    Through this example, we show how the seizure rate needed to implement theAD allocation reduces as the social mobility increases. Agents in the lowersquartiles borrows on unsecured assets, if in the next period there is a reasonablechance to end up in one of the uppers quartiles, then they have more chances torepay their debts. The reduction on the default probability reduces the seizurerate (default punishment) needed to implement the AD allocation.As in [5], there are 4 agents, endowments roughly match US income and wealthdistribution [15]. Data on social mobility [18] shows that agents in the lowersquartiles jump to the upper ones with positive probability. To keep thingssimple we consider 3 states of nature:

    1. Agents remain in the same quartile.

    2. Agent 1 jumps to quartile 2; agent 3 jumps to quartile 4 and vice verse.

    3. An state with more social mobility: agents in quartiles 3-4 jump to quar-tiles 1-2 and vice verse.

    State 3 represent the state with more social mobility, its probability is ǫ > 0.State 1’s probability is π.After normalizing, endowments distribution is as follow:

    14

  • Agent 1 agent 2 agent 3 agent 4w01 0.61 0.22 0.12 0.05w02 0.84 0.12 0.04 0w11 0.63 0.21 0.11 0.05w12 0 0 0 0w21 0.21 0.63 0.05 0.11w22 0 0 0 0w31 0.11 0.05 0.63 0.21w32 0 0 0 0

    Agents preferences are identical and homothetic.

    α log(x01) + (1− α) log(x02) +

    3∑

    s=1

    πs (α log(xs1) + (1− α) log(xs2)) .

    In [28] they estimate α = 0.8.In the AD equilibrium each agent consumes xi = αpwi/2 of each commodity ineach state of nature; where:

    pwi = 1 + 21− α

    αwi02 + π(w

    i11 − w

    i21) + w

    i21 + ǫ(w

    i31 − w

    i21),

    is increasing with more social mobility for poor agents (3 and 4).The vector of inter temporal and interstate transfers for each agent is:

    mi = (πs(xi − wis1))s=1,2,3.

    Consider 3 Arrow securities paying on the perishable commodity. Return matrixwill be:

    R =

    π 0 00 1− π − ǫ 00 0 ǫ

    .

    Portfolios are:zi = xi1− wi1,

    where 1 is a column vector of ones and wi1 is agent i’s endowment of the per-ishable commodity in t = 1.Asset 3 plays an important role for poor agents, they would like to short sell itand pay in the state in which they have more endowment. If it were securedagents would not be able to meet the collateral requirements.Following [5], the endogenous collateral requirement is C = α/(1− α) (it is thesame for the three assets because there is no aggregate risk).Numerical exercises11 shows that assets 2 and 3 need to be unsecured to imple-ment the AD allocation.

    11Let µ = (µ1, µ2, µ3) such that µj = 1 if asset j is secured and 0 otherwise. We can writethe collateral constraint for each agent as a function of probabilities π, ǫ and µ:

    ∆i(π, ǫ, µ) = xi −α

    1− αµ(zi)−.

    15

  • 00.1

    0.20.3

    0.40.5

    0.6

    00.2

    0.40.6

    0.810

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    επ

    γ0.5 0.55 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8

    Figure 2: Minimum seizure rate for AD feasibility. The gray region representscombinations of π and ǫ that satisfy the collateral constraint.

    The minimum seizure rate for AD allocation’s feasibility is:

    γ ≥ γ∗ = max(s,i)∈{2,3}×I

    [

    1−pei

    2wis1

    ]+

    .

    Which is decreasing with ǫ when it is low enough as can be seen in figure 2.Since asset 1 is secured, we also need to check the collateral constraint. Thecombinations of probabilities that satisfies it are given by:

    mini=1,··· ,4

    [

    1 + 21− α

    αwi02 − (2− π)w

    i11 + (1− π − ǫ)w

    i21 + ǫw

    i31

    ]

    ≥ 0.

    3 Conclusions

    We have studied an economy with bankruptcy, showed conditions to implementthe AD allocation with a mix of secured and unsecured assets and providedconditions to guarantee equilibrium existence.In a pure secured economy AD allocation might not be implemented even if the

    For each µ we define the set:

    Lµ ={

    (π, ǫ) ∈ [0, 1]2 : π + ǫ ≤ 1,∆i(π, ǫ, µ) ≥ 0 for all i = 1, · · · , 4}

    .

    We estimate the set Lµ for the 8 possible values of µ and verify that except for µ = (0, 0, 0)and µ = (1, 0, 0) the set is empty. Since we try to use the lest quantity of unsecured assetsthen we keep with µ = (1, 0, 0)

    16

  • return matrix has full rank, individuals are not able to meet the collateral con-straints. In this situation it is useful to introduce unsecured without changingthe return matrix. Agents do not need to worry with the collateral constraint,nevertheless to guarantee that individuals do not default on unsecured debt,preserving the return spam, the seizure rate should be large enough. We alsoprovided and example with social mobility in which today poor agents can bor-row using an unsecured asset and if the probability of ending up in the firstquantiles (more social mobility) is positive, then we can implement AD alloca-tion.

    References

    [1] Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A., and Salehi, A. T. Systemic risk andstability in financial networks. Working Paper, 2014.

    [2] Allen, F., and Babus, A. Networks in finance. Survey, 2008.

    [3] Allen, F., and Gale, D. Financial contagion. Journal of PoliticalEconomics 108, 1 (2000).

    [4] Araujo, A. P. General equilibrium, preferences and financial institutionsafter the crisis. Economic Theory 58, 2 (2015), 217–254.

    [5] Araujo, A. P., Kubler, F., and Schommer, S. Regulating collateral-requirements when markets are incomplete. Journal of Economic Theory147, 2 (2012), 450 – 476.

    [6] Araujo, A. P., and Páscoa, M. R. Bancruptcy in a model of unsecuredclaims. Economic Theory 20, 3 (2002), 455–481.

    [7] Araujo, A. P., Páscoa, M. R., and Torres-Mart́ınez, J. P. Col-lateral avoids ponzi schemes in incomplete markets. Econometrica 70, 4(2002), 1613–1638.

    [8] Azariadis, C., and Kaas, L. Endogenous credit limits with small defaultcosts. Journal of Economic Theory 148, 2 (2013), 806–824.

    [9] Azariadis, C., Kass, L., and Wen, Y. Self-fulfilling credit cycles. 2015.

    [10] Berge, C. Topological Spaces. Oliver and Boyd LTD, 1963.

    [11] Blume, Lawrence, Easley, D., Kleinbergv, J., Kleinberg, R.,and Tardos, E. Which networks are least susceptible to cascading fail-ures? In 52nd IEEE Annual Symposium on Foundations od ComputerScience (2011), pp. 392–402.

    [12] Bureau, U. C. Survey of income and program participation. Tech. rep.,U.S. Census Bureau, 1996-2008.

    17

  • [13] Chatterjee, S., Corbae, D., Nakajima, M., and Ŕıos-Rull, J.-V.A quantitative theory of unsecured consumer credit with risk of default.Econometrica 75, 6 (2007), 1525–1589.

    [14] Demyanyk, Y., and Van Hemert, O. Understanding the subprimemortgage crisis. Review of Financial Studies 24, 6 (2011), 1848–1880.

    [15] Di, Z. Growing wealth, inequality, and housing in the united states. Tech.rep., Harvard University’s Joint Center for Housing Studies, 2007.

    [16] Freixas, X., Parigi, B. M., and Rochet, J.-C. Systemic risk, in-terbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank. Journal ofmoney, credit and banking (2000), 611–638.

    [17] Geanakoplos, J. Collaterized asset markets. 2007.

    [18] Hertz, T. Understanding mobility in america. Tech. rep., Center forAmenrican Progress, 2006.

    [19] Jackson, M. O. A survey of models of network formation: Stability andefficiency. Survey, 2003.

    [20] Kehoe, T. J., and Levine, D. K. Debt-constrained asset markets. TheReview of Economic Studies (1993), 865–888.

    [21] Leippold, M., Vanini, P., and Ebnoether, S. Optimal credit limitmanagement under different information regimes. Journal of Banking &Finance 30, 2 (2006), 463–487.

    [22] Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., and Green, J. R. Microeconomictheory. Oxford University press, 1995.

    [23] Mateos-Planas, X. Credit limits and bankruptcy. Economics Letters121, 3 (2013), 469–472.

    [24] Poblete-Cazenave, R., and Torres-Mart́ınez, J. P. Equilibriumwith limited-recourse collateralized loans. Economic Theory 53, 1 (2013),181–211.

    [25] Sabarwal, T. Competitive equilibria with incomplete markets and en-dogenous bankruptcy. Contributions to Theoretical Economics (2003).

    [26] Villalba, J. M. Bankruptcy in general equilibrium: Existence, Efficiencyand Contagion. PhD thesis, IMPA, 2016.

    [27] Vivier-Lirimont, S. Contagion in interbank debt networks. WorkingPaper, 2006.

    [28] Yao, R., and Zhang, H. H. Optimal consumption and portfolio choiceswith risky housing and borrowing constraints. Review of Financial studies18, 1 (2005), 197–239.

    18

  • [29] Zame, W. R. Efficiency and the role of default when security markets areincomplete. The American Economic Review 83, 5 (1993), 1142–1164.

    4 Appendix A

    Mixed Strategy EquilibriumWe will call a mixed equilibrium an equilibrium in which each agent ı ∈ Ichooses a convex combination of optimal strategies in the budget set.

    To prove a mixed equilibrium we proceed as follows: first we define a trun-cated economy, associated to it there is a generalized game, whose equilibriumis proved using the Kakutani fix point theorem after defining an adequate cor-respondence. Then we show that this fixed point is an equilibrium for the trun-cated economy as the boundaries get larger. Finally, by lower hemi-continuityof the budget set correspondence we prove that the sequence of truncated equi-librium converges to a mixed equilibrium for the original economy.

    4.1 The truncated Economy

    For each n ∈ N we define a truncated economy.

    Let

    Kn = [0, n]2(S+1) ×

    [

    0,In

    C

    ]Jsec

    ×[

    0,n

    C

    ]Jsec

    × [−2m, 2Im]Junsec

    ,

    with C = minj∈Jsec

    Cj .

    LetP = ∆2+j

    sec+Junsec−1+ ×

    (

    ∆2−1+)S,

    be the space of prices. We define the truncated budget set

    βin : P× [0, 1]SJunsec

    ⇒ Kn,

    as βin(p, q, κ) = Bi(p, q, κ) ∩Kn.

    Using standard arguments we prove the following12

    Lemma 4.1 For n large enough, βin is continuous.

    12To prove upper hemi-continuity its enough to notice that Bi has a closed graphic andKn is compact. Since βin has no empty interior, it is easy to prove that β̊

    in is lower hemi-

    continuous, then¯̊βin is lower hemi-continuous too. It remains to prove that β

    in =

    ¯̊βin, which

    can be proved for n large enough as in [24]

    19

  • 4.1.1 A Generalized Game

    In the generalized game we consider all agents i ∈ I, the market and an addi-tional player that defines the equilibrium delivery rates. We proceed to defineeach player optimization problem and constraints.

    Each agent ı ∈ I solves:

    max(x,θ,ϕ,z,τ)∈βi

    n×[0,1]S

    U i(x)−1

    2

    s∈S

    τ is∑

    j∈Junsec

    ps1rsj(zij)

    + −Dis

    2

    (10)

    Letψin : P× [0, 1]

    SJunsec

    ⇒ Kn × [0, 1]S

    be agent i’s optimal choice for 10. Consider the function w : R2(S+1)+ ×R

    Jsec

    + ×

    RJsec

    + ×RJunsec × [0, 1]

    S→ R

    2(S+1)+ ×R

    Jsec

    + ×RJsec

    + ×RJunsec

    + ×RJunsec

    + ×RSJunsec

    +

    as(x, θ, ϕ, z, τ) → (x, θ, ϕ, z+, z−, τ ◦ z),

    with τ ◦ z = (τsz+j ; (s, j) ∈ S × Junsec).

    Next we consider the compact set:

    ∇n = [0, n]2(S+1)

    ×

    [

    0,In

    C

    ]Jsec

    ×[

    0,n

    C

    ]Jsec

    ×[0, 2Im]Junsec

    ×[0, 2m]Junsec

    ×[0, 2m]SJunsec

    .

    And define13:

    Ψin = Conv w ◦ ψin : P× [0, 1]

    SJunsec

    ⇒ ∇n, (11)

    By the Berge maximum theorem [10] and the fact that w is a continuous functionand convex combination preserves upper hemi-continuity we have

    Lemma 4.2 The correspondence Ψin is upper hemi-continuous, with convex,compact and non empty values.

    Given an allocation (xi, θi, ϕi, zi1, zi2, y

    i)i∈I ∈ ∇In, the market player solves:

    max(p,q)∈P

    p0∑

    i∈I

    (xi0−ei0)+q

    sec∑

    i∈I

    (θi−ϕi)+qunsec∑

    i∈I

    (zi1−zi2)+

    s∈S

    ps∑

    i∈I

    (xis−eis).

    (12)Delivery rate player solves:

    maxκ∈[0,1]SJ

    unsec−

    (s,j)∈S×Junsec

    ps1rsj

    [

    κsj∑

    i∈I

    zi2j −∑

    i∈I

    yisj

    ]2

    ; (13)

    13Conv refers to the convex hull of a set.

    20

  • Let µ1 and µ2 be the best response correspondence for the market and the de-livery rate players, respectively.

    A mixed equilibrium for the generalized game is characterized by a fix pointof the following correspondence:

    µ =∏

    i∈I

    Ψin × µ1 × µ2 : ∇In × P× [0, 1]

    SJunsec

    ⇒ ∇In × P× [0, 1]SJunsec

    ,

    by Kakutani fix point theorem we have the following

    Proposition 4.3 The Generalized game has a mixed equilibrium.

    4.1.2 Equilibrium for the truncated economy

    Now we prove the following proposition

    Proposition 4.4 For n large enough, a mixed equilibrium for the generalizedgame is an equilibrium for the truncated economy.

    Proof By definition all agents choice a convex combination of optimal strate-gies, so we only need to check market clearing conditions and the equilibriumdelivery rate.

    Given a fix point(

    (

    xi, θi, ϕi, zi1, zi2, y

    i)

    i∈I, p, q, κ

    )

    . For each agent there are

    indexes li = 1, · · · , N14 such that:

    (

    xi, θi, ϕi, zi1, zi2, y

    i)

    =

    N∑

    li=1

    αli

    (

    xili , θili, ϕili ,

    (

    zili)+,(

    zili)−, τ ili ◦ z

    ili

    )

    ,

    with αli ≥ 0,∑

    αli = 1 and(

    xili , θili, ϕili , z

    ili, τ ili)

    ∈ ψin(p, q, κ).

    By 13 we have that κ satisfy the equilibrium delivery rate equation 4:

    ps1rsj

    [

    κsj∑

    i∈I

    li

    αli(zilij)− −

    i∈I

    li

    αliτilis

    (zilij)−

    ]

    = 0.

    To prove market clearing we first notice that by adding agents budget con-straint in t = 0 we have:

    p0∑

    i∈I

    (xi0 − ei0) + q

    sec∑

    i∈I

    (θi − ϕi) + qunsec∑

    i∈I

    zi ≤ 0, (14)

    and by the market optimization problem 12:(

    i∈I

    (xi0 − ei0),∑

    i∈I

    (θi − ϕi),∑

    i∈I

    zi

    )

    ≤ 0. (15)

    14By Carathéodory’s theorem we can fix N = 2(S+1)+2Jsec+Junsec+S+1 for all agents

    21

  • Adding up the budget constraint in t = 1, using 15 and the delivery rate equa-tion:

    ps(∑

    i∈I

    (xis − eis − Y e

    is)) ≤ 0 (16)

    and by 13 we have that

    i∈I

    (xis − eis − Y e

    i0) ≤ 0. (17)

    15, 17, the collateral constraint and the short selling constraint on unsecuredassets implies that consumption and portfolios are uniformly bounded (inde-pendent of n). So, for n large enough the optimal choice is in the interior ofKn, this implies two things: 1) Prices are strictly positive and 2) the budgetconstraints in t = 0, 1 hold with equality. This means that 14 and 16 holdswith equality, and since prices are strictly positive 15 and 17 also holds withequality.

    4.2 A mixed equilibrium

    We proceed to prove:

    Theorem 4.5 Under the hypothesis made on preferences, endowments and as-set structure, there is a mixed equilibrium for the economy.

    Proof We have a bounded sequence of equilibria(

    (

    xin, θin, ϕ

    in, z

    in1, z

    in2, y

    in

    )

    i∈I, pn, qn, κn

    )

    ,

    with

    (

    xin, θin, ϕ

    in, z

    in1, z

    in2, y

    in

    )

    =N∑

    li=1

    αnli

    (

    xinli , θinli, ϕinli ,

    (

    zinli)+,(

    zinli)−, τ inli ◦ z

    inli

    )

    ,

    and(

    xinli , θinli, ϕinli , z

    inli, τ inli

    )

    ∈ ψin(pn, qn, κn).

    We can extract a sub-sequence, such that

    (

    xinli , θinli, ϕinli , z

    inli, τ inli

    )

    →(

    xili , θili, ϕili , z

    ili, τ ili)

    ,

    and(pn, qn, κn) → (p, q, κ).

    Feasibility, market clearing conditions and the equilibrium seizure rate equationholds (because it holds for each n), so to prove equilibrium existence we haveto prove that

    (

    xili , θili, ϕili , z

    ili, τ ili)

    is optimal when prices are (p, q, κ).

    Take any (x, θ, ϕ, z) ∈ Bi(p, q, κ).

    For n large enough (x, θ, ϕ, z) ∈ βin(p, q, κ).

    22

  • By lower hemi-continuity, there is a sequence (xm, θm, ϕm, zm, pm, qm, κm)converging to (x, θ, ϕ, z, p, q, κ) with (xm, θm, ϕm, zm) ∈ β

    in(pm, qm, κm) for m

    large enough. For m ≥ n large enough (xm, θm, ϕm, zm) ∈ βim(pm, qm, κm), so

    U i(ximli) ≥ Ui(xm),

    taking limits we obtain:U i(xili) ≥ U

    i(x),

    which proves optimality.

    23