26
ISA 55 th Convention, Toronto, March 2014 1 When Security Sector Reform Misfires: The Remaking Public Order in El Salvador By Gaëlle Rivard Piché 1 In 1992, the Chapultepec accords brought to an end the Salvadorian civil war that had made more than 85,000 victims in 12 years. Following the negotiated settlement, El Salvador undertook the reform of its main security institutions. Yet, despite the expansion of the Salvadorian State’s security capacities during the 1990s and the progressive reduction of homicides during the 1990s, violence rose importantly from 2002. By the mid 2000s and until the gang truce in 2012, El Salvador became one of the most violent countries in Central America and the rest of the world (UNODC 2007). Considering that the overarching objective of SSR is to reduce violence to enable economic, political and social development (OECDDAC 2007), this paper explores why SSR has been unable to control armed crime and violence in El Salvador. The link between SSR and violence remains in fact unclear. In El Salvador and other countries, such as Afghanistan (Jarstad 2013; Sedra 2007), Haiti (Muggah and Kolbe 2012; MendelsonForman 2006; Donais 2005) and Kosovo (HeinemannGrüder and Grebenschikov 2006), an upsurge in violence followed the implementation of SSR. I argue that SSR, through its design and implementation, affects how security is provided, who are the main security actors and which rules and norms are applicable. Under these reforms, as the State expands the scope and the quality of its security provision, the coexistence of public and private security actors creates tensions and competition, which can result in higher levels of violence. This paper explores how the SSR process in El Salvador has affected the production of public order and violence at the national level in the aftermath of the civil war. Considering how the war undermined the ability of the Salvadorian State to project its power throughout its territory (Wood and Boyce 1996; Stanley 1999) the end of the conflict did not lead automatically to the reestablishment of the State’s authority through the country. In fact, over the last 20 years, the State has not successfully claim the monopoly over the means of violence. 1 Gaëlle Rivard Piché is a Ph.D. candidate at the Norman Paterson School of International Affaires, Carleton University in Ottawa, Canada. This research project is supported by the Canadian Department of National Defence and the International Development Research Centre.

When Security Sector Reform Misfires: The Remaking of Public Order in El Salvador

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  1  

When  Security  Sector  Reform  Misfires:  The  Remaking  Public  Order  in  El  Salvador    By  Gaëlle  Rivard  Piché1  

In   1992,   the   Chapultepec   accords   brought   to   an   end   the   Salvadorian   civil   war   that   had  

made   more   than   85,000   victims   in   12   years.   Following   the   negotiated   settlement,   El  

Salvador  undertook  the  reform  of  its  main  security  institutions.  Yet,  despite  the  expansion  

of   the   Salvadorian   State’s   security   capacities   during   the   1990s   and   the   progressive  

reduction  of  homicides  during  the  1990s,  violence  rose  importantly  from  2002.  By  the  mid-­‐

2000s   and   until   the   gang   truce   in   2012,   El   Salvador   became   one   of   the   most   violent  

countries  in  Central  America  and  the  rest  of  the  world  (UNODC  2007).  Considering  that  the  

overarching  objective  of  SSR  is  to  reduce  violence  to  enable  economic,  political  and  social  

development   (OECD-­‐DAC  2007),   this  paper  explores  why  SSR  has  been  unable   to  control  

armed  crime  and  violence  in  El  Salvador.    

The   link   between   SSR   and   violence   remains   in   fact   unclear.   In   El   Salvador   and   other  

countries,  such  as  Afghanistan  (Jarstad  2013;  Sedra  2007),  Haiti  (Muggah  and  Kolbe  2012;  

Mendelson-­‐Forman   2006;   Donais   2005)   and   Kosovo   (Heinemann-­‐Grüder   and  

Grebenschikov  2006),  an  upsurge  in  violence  followed  the  implementation  of  SSR.  I  argue  

that  SSR,  through  its  design  and  implementation,  affects  how  security  is  provided,  who  are  

the  main  security  actors  and  which  rules  and  norms  are  applicable.  Under  these  reforms,  as  

the   State   expands   the   scope   and   the   quality   of   its   security   provision,   the   coexistence   of  

public   and   private   security   actors   creates   tensions   and   competition,  which   can   result   in  

higher  levels  of  violence.    

This  paper  explores  how  the  SSR  process  in  El  Salvador  has  affected  the  production  of  

public  order  and  violence  at  the  national  level  in  the  aftermath  of  the  civil  war.  Considering  

how   the   war   undermined   the   ability   of   the   Salvadorian   State   to   project   its   power  

throughout  its  territory  (Wood  and  Boyce  1996;  Stanley  1999)  the  end  of  the  conflict  did  

not  lead  automatically  to  the  reestablishment  of  the  State’s  authority  through  the  country.  

In  fact,  over  the   last  20  years,   the  State  has  not  successfully  claim  the  monopoly  over  the  

means  of  violence.  

                                                                                                                         1  Gaëlle  Rivard  Piché   is  a  Ph.D.  candidate  at   the  Norman  Paterson  School  of   International  Affaires,  Carleton  University   in   Ottawa,   Canada.   This   research   project   is   supported   by   the   Canadian  Department   of   National  Defence  and  the  International  Development  Research  Centre.    

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  2  

From   1993,   the   capacity   and   the   level   of   professionalism   of   the   State’s   security  

institutions   increased,   mainly   through   the   downsizing   of   the   armed   forces   and   the  

redefinition  of  their  mandate,  as  well  as  the  creation  of  the  Policia  Nacional  Civil  (PNC).  Yet,  

the  weakness  of  the  judicial  system  and  the  politicization  of  the  PNC  undermined  the  ability  

of  the  State  to  successfully  claim  the  monopoly  over  the  use  of  coercive  force,  to  establish  a  

strong   social   contract  with   its   population,   and   to   address   effectively   crime   and   violence  

through   sound   public   security   strategies   and   policies.   Hence   the   security   sector   reform  

process  that  was  implemented  after  the  war  did  not  enable  the  Salvadorian  State  to  control  

violence,  through  the  ultimate  imposition  of  a  national  monist  public  order  regime,  or  the  

negotiation   of   a   cohesive   pluralist   regime   with   private   security   actors.   Over   the   same  

period   and   due   partially   to   the   inability   of   the   State   to   impose   itself,   gangs   gained  

momentum  in   terms  of  capacity,  organization  and  territorial  control,   setting   the   table   for  

growing  tensions  with  public  security  actors  from  the  late  1990s.    

Consequently,   the  1990s   saw   the   repositioning  of   forces  able   to   control   the  means  of  

violence,   impose   themselves   as   authority   figures,   and   determine  which   rules   and   norms  

regulate  individuals’  behaviours.  SSR,  due  to  its  technical  nature  and  its  limited  scope,  did  

not  enable   the  State   to  eliminate  competing  security  actors.   In   fact,   it  may  have   led  to  an  

increase  in  violence  in  many  spaces  through  El  Salvador  due  to  competition  and  increased  

tensions  between  the  State’s  security  institutions  and  gangs.    

Building   on   insights   from   legal   pluralism   and   property   rights   theory,   this   paper   first  

discusses  public  order  regimes  and  their  impact  on  violence.  It  then  explores  how  the  SSR  

process  in  El  Salvador,  focussing  strictly  on  the  State’s  security  institutions,  has  not  taken  

into   consideration   how   private   actors   have   emerged   as   central   security   actors   in   the  

aftermath  of   the  war,  and  have  affected   in  an   important  manner  the  production  of  public  

order   in   the  country.  Failure   to  do  so   led   to   important   tensions  between  powerful  public  

and   private   actors.   It   also   significantly   undermined   the   quality   of   public   order   in   many  

spaces   throughout   El   Salvador,   which   is   illustrated   by   rising   levels   of   violence   from   the  

early  2000s.  

1. Literature  review:  the  different  approaches  to  SSR  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  3  

Key  scholars  have  argued  quite  convincingly  that  statebuilding,  through  the  reinforcement  

of  governmental   institutions,   is  critical   to   transition   from  war   to  peace  (see,   for  example,  

Fukuyama   2004;   Krasner   2004;   Paris   2004;   Fearon   and   Laitin   2003).   At   the   core   of   the  

statebuilding  process  come  the  reinforcement  and  the  professionalization  of  security  and  

justice   institutions   to   fulfill   one   of   the  main   state   functions:   security   provision.   Security  

sector  reform  first  appeared  as  a  policy  framework  in  the  1990s.  It  quickly  became  one  of  

the  main  elements  of  the  statebuilding  paradigm  and  has  since  been  implemented  widely  in  

many   countries   including   El   Salvador,   Haiti,   Mali,   Côte   d’Ivoire,   Democratic   Republic   of  

Congo,  Kosovo,  Afghanistan,  Iraq,  Timor  Leste,  and  Liberia.    

In   the   direct   aftermath   of   a   civil  war,   security   is   an  urgent   requirement   as   filling   the  

security   gap   is   necessary   to   the   implementation  of   the  peace  process   (Walter  1997),   the  

control   of   potential   spoilers   (Zahar  2010,   270),   and   the  development  of   a  positive  peace  

(Galtung  1996).  In  that  perspective,  security  sector  reform  aims  at  reducing  armed  violence  

and   crime   to   allow   economic,   political   and   social   development   (OECD-­‐DAC   2007,   10).  

Based   on   the   OECD   DAC   Handbook   on   Security   Sector   Reform   (OECD-­‐DAC   2007),   this  

overarching   objective   should   be   reached   by   providing   basic   security,   improving   the  

governance  of  public  security  institutions,  and  ensuring  the  local  ownership  of  the  reform  

process.  Advocates  of  the  statebuilding  approach  consider  that  improving  the  capacity  and  

the  professionalism  of  the  State’s  security  agencies  will  contribute  greatly  to  a  sustainable  

transition   from  war   to   peace   (see   for   example   and   to   different   extents,   Call   and  Wyeth  

2008;   Paris   2004;   Fearon   and   Laitin   2003),   and   foster   economic   development   and  

prosperity  (Collier  2007;  Fukuyama  2004;  Collier  2003).  

1.1. The  statebuilding  paradigm  and  the  Weberian  State  model  

The  statebuilding  paradigm  conceives  the  Weberian  State  as  the  only  and  ultimate  outcome  

in  terms  of  public  good  provision,   including  security  (Fukuyama  2004;  Rotberg  2003;  see  

also   the   discussion   about   statebuilding   in   Call   and   Wyeth   2008,   8–13).   From   this  

standpoint,  when   the  State  does  not  hold   the  monopoly  over   the  use  of   coercive   force,   it  

creates  an  authority  vacuum  in  spaces  where  state   institutions  are  absent  or  too  weak  to  

impose   themselves,   leading   potentially   to   Hobbesian   anarchy   (Rotberg   2003;   Lake   and  

Rothchild  1998).  The  breakdown  of  the  State’s  authority  and  the  security  dilemma  that  is  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  4  

assumed   to   follow   are   perceived   as   a   direct   cause   of   civil   wars;   re-­‐establishing   state  

authority   throughout   its   territory   becomes   a   priority   for   any   peace   and   statebuilding  

agenda  (Walter  1997;  Posen  1993).  

However,   this   perspective   assumes   that   before   the   escalation   towards   organized  

violence,   the   State   held   the   monopoly   over   the   use   of   coercive   force.   Yet,   before   the  

outbreak   of   an   armed   conflict,   the   State   is   often   only   one   amongst   several   security  

providers.  The  State’s   institutions  are  either  absent  or   too  weak  to   impose   themselves   in  

the   spaces   through   the   country.   In   these   spaces,   other   actors   fulfill   certain   functions  

associated  to  the  Weberian  State,  inclusion  security  provision  and  public  ordering.  Thus,  a  

sovereignty   gap   does   not   necessarily   equate   a   security   and   an   authority   gaps.   Assuming  

that  the  State  does  retain  the  monopoly  over  the  use  of  coercive  force  before  all  civil  wars  

may  be  going  a  step  too  far,  especially  regarding  local  public  ordering  

When  proponents  of  the  statebuilding  paradigm  recognize  the  role  of  private  actors  in  

the  provision  of  public  good  and  especially  security,  they  tend  to  assume  that  these  actors  

are   necessarily   less   effective,   less   accountable,   less   responsible   and   less   respectful   of  

human   rights   than   the   security   institutions   of   the   Weberian   State.   Yet,   in   some   cases,  

informal   actors   may   present   some   of   these   characteristics   that   SSR   seeks   to   develop   in  

state   security   institutions:   accountability,   low   cost,   effectiveness,   legitimacy,   local  

ownership   (G.   Baker   2010).   Thus,   the   statebuilding   paradigm   may   be   ill   fitted   to  

understand  the  public  ordering  and  security  landscape  in  countries  where  public  security  

actors  (the  State’s  agencies)  cohabit,  interacts  and  compete  with  private  actors  (non-­‐state  

security  actors).  

1.2. Hybrid  political  order  

It  might  be  more  fruitful   to  conceive  post-­‐conflict  countries  as  hybrid  political  orders,  

rather  than  failed  states  or  quite  imperfect  examples  of  the  Weberian  State.  They  are  best  

represented  as  spaces  where  multiple  informal,  formal  and  hybrid  spheres  of  power  evolve  

in  parallel  and  interact  together  (B.  Baker  2011;  Boege  et  al.  2008).  Even  during  an  armed  

conflict,   the   breakdown   of   the   State’s  monopoly   over   the   use   of   coercive   force   does   not  

necessarily  mean  that  an  authority  vacuum  is  created  throughout  the  country.  The  conflict  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  5  

will  affect  but  not  necessarily  destroy  forms  of   local  governance.  For  example,  during  the  

civil  war  in  El  Salvador,  following  the  collapse  of  the  State’s  authority  in  certain  parts  of  the  

country,   new  mechanisms   of   local   governance   emerged,   administrated   by   civilians   who  

relied   “on   armed   actors   for   their   coercive   authority,   and   sometimes   legitimacy”   (Wood  

2008,  552).  In  the  absence  of  the  State’s  institutions,  other  public  ordering  mechanisms  will  

be   put   in   place,   imposed   by   some   powerful   and/or   designed   and   managed   by   local  

communities.  

At   the   local   level,   informal,   customary   and   other   non-­‐state   actors   regularly   act   as  

security  providers  and  authority  figures  fulfilling  some  functions  associated  to  the  State.  In  

this  context,  state  agencies,  if  present,  are  only  conceived  by  the  population  as  one  security  

actor   among   others,   often   peripheral   (B.   Baker   2008).   Hence,   when   it   comes   to   SSR,  

security  provision  improvement,  and  violence  control,  we  need  to  ask  who  provide  security  

and  to  whom  are  people  turning  to  for  security,  rather  than  who  should  provide  security  and  

to   whom   should   people   turn   to   for   security   (G.   Baker   2010;   Andersen   2006).   These  

observations  will  provide  important  insights  regarding  authority  and  legitimacy  at  the  local  

level.  

If  SSR  is  implemented  without  taking  into  consideration  these  fundamental  elements  of  

the  security  and  public  ordering  landscape,  the  reforms  tend  to  have  a  disruptive  effect  on  

public  ordering  and  security  provision.  SSR  can  reduce  the  legitimacy  and  the  authority  of  

local   actors   who   are   perceived   as   being   increasingly   associated   to   the   State.   It   can   also  

affect  the  balance  of  power  in  spaces  penetrated  by  newly  reformed  public  actors  who  may  

not   have   the   necessary   legitimacy   to   be   recognized   as   authority   figures   by   the   local  

population.  Finally,  and  related  to  these  first  two  potential  effects,  it  can  lead  people  to  turn  

to   new   private   actors   (militias,   gangs,   vigilantes   or   cartels)   who   are   perceived   as   more  

legitimate   than   the   State   due   to   their   link  with   the   local   community,   and  more   effective  

than  previous  forms  of  local  authority  (Clements  et  al.  2007).    

The  presence  of  multiple  security  actors  relying  on  different  sources  of  authority  does  

not  necessarily  means  a  breakdown  of  public  order.  Public  and  private  security  actors  can  

to   interact   together   through   informal   and   flexible   networks   that   need   to   be   taken   into  

account  by  SSR  programs.  The  control  of  shantytowns  in  Rio  de  Janeiro  (Arias  2006),   the  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  6  

association   between   jihadist   groups   and   religious   figures   in   Northern   Mali   (Bøås   and  

Torheim  2013),  and  the  interaction  between  warlords,  clan  structures  and  state  agencies  in  

Afghanistan  (Schmeidl  and  Karokhail  2009;  Goodhand  2008)  are  prime  examples  of  such  

public  ordering  networks.  The  literature  is  however  mostly  silent  about  the  impact  of  SSR  

on   security  provision,   public   ordering   and  violence   in  hybrid  political   orders.  This   is   the  

objective  of  this  paper,  which  looks  at  the  case  of  post-­‐war  El  Salvador  from  1992  to  2004.    

2. Theoretical  framework  

Change  in  the  structure  of  the  national  public  order  regime  following  the  end  if  the  civil  

war  and  SSR  explains   the  upsurge   in  crime  and  violence  that  El  Salvador  witnessed   from  

the  early  2000s.  A  public  order  regime  is  a  system  of  control  that  regulates  behaviours  and  

assigns  property  rights  over  the  use  of  violence  in  a  given  space.  It  is  composed  of  two  main  

elements:  an  authority  structure  and  a  normative  framework.  The  degree  of  fragmentation  

of   these   two   components   affects   the   regime’s   quality   and   stability,   hence   influencing   the  

level   of   violence   in   the   space   it   regulates.   Two   main   hypotheses   follow.   First,   pluralist  

regimes  (two  or  more  security  actors)   tend  to  be  more  violent   than  monist  regimes  (one  

security  actor).  The  presence  of  several  security  actors  in  one  space  tends  to  feed  tensions  

due  to  potential  competing  claims  over  the  control  of  the  space  and  the  means  of  violence.  

Second,   regimes   under   transition   tend   to   be   more   violent   than   stable   regimes,   due   to  

increased  competition  and  uncertainty  between  security  actors.  

2.1. Hypothesis  1  -­‐  Pluralism  and  violence  

The   authority   structure   of   a   public   order   regime   is   determined   by   the   number   of  

security  actors  who  are  willing  and  able  to  successfully  claim  some  control  over  the  means  

of   violence   in   order   to   regulate   individual   behaviours   in   a   given   space   (Lavigne   Delville  

2004).  Control   is  never   complete  due   to   its   inherent   costs,   but   some  claims  are   stronger  

than  others  based  on  the  amount  of  economic,  social,  cultural  and  symbolic  capital2  owned  

                                                                                                                         2  Rather  than  referring  to  legitimacy,  which  is  often  hard  to  operationalize,  I  use  the  various  forms  of  capital  proposed  by  Bourdieu  and  Wacquant  (1992)  to  evaluate  the  level  of  authority  of    a  security  actor.  I  borrow  the  idea  of  applying  these  forms  of  capital  to  security  actors  in  public  ordering  from  the  work  of  Bruce  Baker  on   security   architecture   in   Africa   (B.   Baker   2011).   Economic   capital   encompasses   physical   and   financial  means;  social  capital  refers  to  the  role  and  position  of  an  actor  in  the  social  structure  of  a  community;  cultural  capital   includes   elements   of   knowledge   and   education;   and   symbolic   capital   is  mostly   related   to   issues   of  prestige  and  honour  in  the  community  where  the  security  actor  evolves.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  7  

by  a  security  actor.  When  powerful  security  actors  are  present  in  the  same  space  and  have  

competing  claims  over  the  control  of  the  regime,  tensions  are  higher  and  violence  tends  to  

increase.   Considering   inherent   uncertainty   and   the   fact   that   information   is   always  

incomplete3  (Furubotn  and  Richter  2005),  violence  is  used  by  security  actors  to  signal  their  

intentions,  reaffirm  their  authority,  and  impose  their  control  over  the  people  living  in  the  

space  regulated  by  the  regime.  Yet,  pluralism  also  creates  opportunities  for  complementary  

and   cooperation,   especially   when   the   authority   of   various   security   actors   derives   from  

different   forms  of  capital.  For  example,  customary  figures  who  rely  on  social  and  cultural  

capital   can   associate   themselves  with   gangs   or  militias  who   have   economic   ad   symbolic  

capital.    

The  normative  framework  of  a  public  order  regime  is  composed  of  one  or  more  sets  of  

norms  and  rules  that  define  acceptable  behaviours  in  the  space  controlled  by  the  regime.  A  

cohesive   normative   framework,   generally   associated   to   a  monist   regime,   is   composed   of  

only  one  set  of  norms  and  rules  usually   imposed  by  one  security  actor.  As  the  number  of  

sets   of   norms   and   rules   present   in   a   regime   increases,   so   does   the   fragmentation   of   its  

normative   framework.   Based   on   the   literature   on   legal   pluralism   (Alston   2012;   Unruh  

2003),  fragmentation  tends  to  impact  negatively  the  quality  of  the  public  order  regime  and  

to   increase  violence.  Multiple  sets  of  rules  and  norms   in  a  given  space  create  uncertainty  

and   facilitate   opportunistic   behaviours.   In   contexts   where   various   forms   of   authority  

impose   competing   sets   of   rules   and   norms,   forum-­‐shopping   becomes   possible   since  

individuals  can  choose  under  which  set  of  rules  and  norms  they  prefer  to  behave  (Unruh  

2003;   National   Research   Council   (U.S.)   2002).   Furthermore,   the   fragmentation   of   the  

normative  framework  may  create  gaps  where  disruptive  behaviours  are  not  regulated  and  

undermine  the  quality  of  public  order.  

Consequently,   pluralist   public   order   regimes   tend   to   be   more   violent   than   monist  

regimes.   The   fragmentation   of   the   authority   structure   and   the   normative   framework  

increases  uncertainty,   feeds  competition,  and   leads   to   the  necessity   for  security  actors   to  

rely   more   heavily   on   violence   to   reaffirm   their   authority   and   signal   their   intentions.                                                                                                                            3  Due  to  inherent  costs  associated  to  the  establishment  and  the  maintenance  of  a  public  order  regime  and  the  limited   resources   available   to   security   actors,   information   is   always   incomplete   and   feeds   uncertainty  (Furubotn  and  Richter  2005,  477).  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  8  

Furthermore,   the   presence   of  multiple   sets   of   norms   and   rules   increase   uncertainty   and  

favours  opportunistic  behaviours  within  the  population.  Hence,  violence  tends  to  be  used  

by  security  actors  to  regulate  behaviours  and  punish  those  who  transgress  enforced  norms  

and  rules.    

Thus,   monist   public   order   regimes   tend   to   be   less   violent   than   pluralist   regimes.  

However,   in   the   latter   case,   negotiated   agreements   between   security   actors   can   reduce  

uncertainty   by   facilitating   information-­‐sharing,   providing   non-­‐violent   means   to   resolve  

conflict,  and  ultimately  building  trust  between  security  actors.  Violence  tends  to  be  lower  

in  a  cohesive  regime  where  an  agreement  has  been  reached  between  security  actors,  than  

in  a  contentious  regime,  where  there  is  not  such  an  agreement.  

2.2.  Hypothesis  2  -­‐  Change  and  transition  

Like  any  other  institutional  change,  regime  transition  tends  to  increase  uncertainty.  In  

the   case   of   public   order   regimes,   it   tends   to   raise   violence   at   least   temporarily.   Change  

occurs   through   two  main  mechanisms:   internal   factors  and  external  shocks.  First,  a   large  

variety  of  endogenous  factors  can  lead  to  a  change  in  the  structure  of  a  public  order  regime,  

such  as  competition  and  economic  performance  (Tilly  1992),  redistribution  of  capital  and  

change  in  the  balance  of  power  between  security  actors  (Boege  et  al.  2008;  Libecap  1989),  

or  rent  maximization  (North  1981).  Incoming  information  can  also  reduce  uncertainty  and  

enable   security  actors   to   reach  an  agreement,   therefore  affecting  positively   the   structure  

and  the  quality  of  the  regime.    

External   shock   can   also   affect   the   structure   of   a   public   order   regime   and   reduce  

momentarily  the  quality  of  the  regime.  An  external  shock  corresponds  for  example  to  the  

penetration  of  the  regime  by  a  security  actor  who  is  potentially  willing  and  able  to  claim  at  

least   partial   control.  When   a   new   security   actor   enters   an   existing   public   order   regime,  

competition  occurs  under  two  conditions.  First,  the  challenger  only  penetrates  a  space  if  he  

expects   net   benefits   from   regime   control,   or   from   the   temporary   intrusion   of   the   space  

controlled   by   the   regime.   Second,   the   established   security   actor(s)   must   be   willing   to  

defend   the   space   under   its/their   control.   As   discussed   earlier,   competition   tends   to  

increase  violence  due  to  higher  degree  of  uncertainty.  Security  actors  need  to  signal  their  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  9  

intentions,  reaffirm  their  control,  and  clarify  the  norms  and  rules  applicable,  often  relying  

on  violence  and  coercion  to  do  so.  Uncertainty  also  feeds  distrust  and  favours  opportunistic  

behaviours.   In   any   transition   where   security   actors   are   willing   and   able   to   compete,  

violence  will  rise  until  one  of  the  security  actors  is  eliminated,  or  an  agreement  is  reached  

between  actors.  Otherwise,  violence  will  remain  high,  considering  the  contentious  nature  of  

the  regime.  

2.3. SSR  as  an  external  shock  

Security  sector  reform  is  an  external  shock.  SSR  implies  more  capable  and  professional  

public  security  institutions,  the  expansion  of  the  State’s  control  over  the  national  territory,  

the  formalization  of  the  rules  and  norms  regulating  daily  life  to  ensure  security,  the  respect  

of   good   governance   principles   (democratization,   accountability,   respect   of   human   rights,  

representativeness),   and   local   ownership.   Doing   so,   effective   SSR   affects   the   authority  

structure  and  the  normative  framework  of  existing  public  order  regimes.  As  conceived  by  

the  statebuilding  paradigm,  SSR  implies  a  transition  from  pluralism  to  monism,  in  order  to  

impose   the   State’s   monopoly   over   the   means   of   violence,   and   the   formalization   of   the  

norms  and  rules  regulating  individual  behaviours  under  the  State’s  authority.    

The  implementation  of  SSR  has  two  important  effects.  On  the  one  hand,  it  increases  the  

capacity   and   the   professionalization   of   public   security   institutions,   and   therefore   their  

ability   to   claim   control   over   public   order   regimes   and   compete   more   intensely   against  

private   security   actors.   On   the   other   hand,   based   on   the   Weberian   state   model,   SSR  

promotes  the  expansion  of  the  State’s  authority  throughout  the  national  territory,  and  thus  

tends   to   increase   the   State’s  willingness   to   claim   the  monopoly   over   the   use   of   coercive  

violence  at  the  national  level.    

When   the   State   enters   a   space   where   it   was   previously   absent,   or   tries   to   eliminate  

competing  security  actors  in  an  existing  pluralist  regime,  tensions  and  competition  tend  to  

increase.  During  the  period  of  transition  where  the  State  tries  to  impose  itself  as  a  security  

actor,   eliminate   contenders,   and   formalize   rules   and  norms   in   the   regime,   uncertainty   is  

higher,  which   feeds  distrust,   facilitates  opportunistic  behaviours,   and   therefore   increases  

violence.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  10  

To  sum  up,  SSR  implemented  in  countries  where  the  State  does  not  retain  the  monopoly  

over  the  use  of  coercive  force  and  faces  powerful  private  security  actors  tends  to  increase  

violence,  at  least  in  temporarily.  If  the  State  is  able  to  impose  itself  and  eliminate  competing  

actors,  upsurges  in  violence  will  be  temporary.  Otherwise,  violence  will  remain  high.  

3. SSR  and  public  order  in  post-­‐war  El  Salvador  

The  early   literature  about  peace  settlement,   state-­‐building  and  security  sector   reform  

identifies  El  Salvador  has  one  of  the  most  compelling  success  stories  of  the  post-­‐cold  war  

period  (Call  2003,  827).  In  January  1992,  facilitated  by  the  United  Nations,  the  right-­‐wing  

Alianza  Republicana  Nacional  (ARENA),  and  the  Frente  Farabundo  Martí  para  la  Liberación  

Nacional  (FMLN),  concluded  the  Chapultepec  accords,  which  put  an  official  end  to  12  years  

of  civil  war.  After  the  1989  intense  clash  in  the  heart  of  San  Salvador  between  the  armed  

forces   and   the   guerrilla,   a   military   victory   appeared   impossible   for   either   side,   and  

pressure  from  the  international  community  led  the  belligerents  to  a  negotiated  settlement.    

Economic   liberalization,   the   democratization   of   the   political   game,   and   institutional  

reforms  were  key  elements  of  the  peace  agreement.  Peceny  and  Stanley  insist  on  how  the  

profound   diffusion   of   liberal   ideas   and   institutions   in   the   country,   and   the   adoption   of  

liberal   practices   by   the   elites   facilitated   the   peace   (Peceny   and   Stanley   2001,   157–158).  

Others  highlight  the  important  role  played  by  the  international  community,  especially  the  

United   Nations,   in   providing   third-­‐party   guarantees   (Walter   2002;  Walter   1997).   Yet,   it  

might   rather   be   a   combination   of   a   wide   variety   of   conditions   that   ensured   the  

sustainability  of  the  peace  process  in  El  Salvador  (Call  2002):  no  possible  military  victory,  

liberal  norms  diffusion,  third-­‐party  guarantees,  the  U.S.  hegemonic  influence,  and  change  in  

the  structure  of  the  international  system  with  the  end  of  the  Cold  War.    

Nonetheless,  the  end  of  war  and  organized  violence  in  El  Salvador  did  not  automatically  

lead  to  the  development  of  a  positive  peace  (Galtung  1996).  The  dynamics  of  the  war  were  

quickly   followed   by   an   increase   in   violence   from   1993   to   1995,   at   least   in   terms   of  

homicides,  as  shown  in  figure  1:    

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  11  

Figure  1.  National  homicide  rate,  El  Salvador,  1993-­‐20124  

 

 

That  first  upsurge,  which  was  attributed  by  many  experts  to  the  security  gap  following  

the  end  of  the  armed  conflict,  resorbed  in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s.  Yet,  as  homicides  

decreased   in   an   absolute  manner,   national   homicide   rates   remained   rather   high   and   the  

culture  of  violence  inherited  from  the  war  and  decades  of  authoritarianism  still  prevailed.  

Narratives   of   crime   and   violence   became   part   of   the   regular  media   coverage,   especially  

through  newspapers  (Moodie  2010,  2).  Crime  was  reported  on  daily   in  a  graphic  manner  

and  gangs  quickly  became  a  central  public  security  concern.  

 

 

                                                                                                                         4  There   are   several   limitations   to   the   statistics   presented   in   figure   1   and   many   researchers   have   already  questioned  their  veracity.  Yet,  I  still  wish  to  present  them  to  get  a  sense  of  the  overall  evolution  of  homicide  in  El   Salvador   after   the  war.   Furthermore,   researchers   in   and  outside  El   Salvador   largely   use   these   statistics.  Hence,  these  statistics  present  a  narrative  usually  accepted  by  the  policy  and  research  communities.  

0.00  

20.00  

40.00  

60.00  

80.00  

100.00  

120.00  

140.00  

160.00  

1990   1995   2000   2005   2010   2015  

homicides/100,000  population  

 

Annual  Homicide  Rate,  El  Salvador,  1995-­‐2012  

Source:  Fiscalía  General  de  la  Republica  (1992,  1994-­‐1995),  Centro  de  Operaciones  y  Servicios  Central  de  Policía  Nacional  Civil  (1996-­‐2012),  El  Salvador.      

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  12  

Figure  2.  National  homicide  rates,  El  Salvador,  2000-­‐2012  

 

 

Ten  years  after  the  end  of  the  armed  conflict,  homicides  rates  started  to  increase  again  

(see  figure  2).  The  government’s  repressive  discourses  and  strategies  to  address  crime  and  

control   violence   failed   to   address   the   upsurge.   If   SSR   in   El   Salvador  managed   to   fill   the  

security  gap  that  followed  the  end  of  the  conflict,  numbers  and  facts  suggest  that  SSR  did  

not  meet  its  ultimate  objective:  reducing  armed  violence  and  crime.  In  this  section,  I  discuss  

SSR,  its  progress,  and  its  impact  on  security  provision.    

3.1. Security  sector  reform:  a  technical  success,  a  political  failure  

The   reform  of   the   State’s   security   institutions  was   a   corner   stone   of   the   Chapultepec  

accords.   Incapable   of   influencing   the   structure   of   the   Salvadorian   economy,   the   FMLN  

prioritized  the  transformation  of  the  security  sector  (Moodie  2010;  Cruz  2006;  Wood  and  

Boyce   1996).   The   Chapultepec   accords   included   provisions   for   the   demobilization   of  

combatants  on  each  side,   including  paramilitary  and  death  squads,   the  downsizing  of   the  

national  armed  forces,  civilian  oversight  of  the  military,  and  the  limitation  of  their  mandate  

to  national  defence.  The  agreement  also  provided  for  the  creation  of  a  new  police  force  that  

would  include  former  members  of  the  military  and  the  guerilla  (limited  to  20%  of  the  total  

0.00  10.00  20.00  30.00  40.00  50.00  60.00  70.00  80.00  

2000  2001  2002  2003  2004  2005  2006  2007  2008  2009  2010  2011  2012  

Annual  Homicide  Rate,  El  Salvador,  2000-­‐2012  

Source:  Centro  de  Operaciones  y  Servicios  Central  de  Policía  Nacional  Civil  (1996-­‐2012),  El  Salvador.      

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  13  

force   of   the   PNC   for   each   side),   but   would   be   dominated   in   terms   of   number   by   new  

recruits  (60%),  and  a  new  intelligence  service  independent  of  the  army.  

Despite   resistance   from   the   armed   forces   and   initial   delays   in   the   implementation   of  

these  reforms,  SSR  as  designed  by  the  peace  accords  made  clear  progress  in  the  five  years  

following  the  end  of  the  conflict  (Call  2003;  Studemeister  2001;  Salas  and  Chinchilla  2001;  

Stanley   1999;   Costa   1995).   The   United   Nations   Observation   Mission   to   El   Salvador  

(ONUSAL)  monitored  the  implementation  of  these  reforms,  which  was  one  of  the  first  SSR  

initiatives  in  the  post-­‐cold  war  era.  The  reform  process  was  mostly  technical,  focussing  on  

the   restructuring   of   the   public   security   institutions   and   their   professionalization.  

Evaluations   of   the   process   based   on   technical   and   short-­‐terms   objectives   are   therefore  

positive.  Such  criteria   include  the  nature  of  the  training  and  formation  to  recruits  offered  

by   the   new   police   academy,   the   Academia   Nacional   de   Seguridad   Publica   (ANSP),   the  

number   of   policemen   trained   and   deployed,   the   strength   of   the   military   forces,   the  

limitation   of   the   mandate   and   powers   of   the   military   forces   to   external   security   and  

national  defense,  etc.  

Yet,  if  the  international  community  perceives  the  peace  process  and  SSR  in  El  Salvador  a  

success   story,   many   Salvadorians   do   not   (Call   2003,   827).   Discussions   and   interviews  

conducted  by  the  author  in  El  Salvador  in  2013  reveal  that  many  Salvadorians  consider  the  

reforms  were  limited  and  undermined  by  decisions  of  the  politic.  Some  even  suggest  that  a  

real   and   profound   transformation   of   the   security   institutions   has   yet   to   be   done.   This  

dichotomy  highlights  how  SSR  can  be  both  a  technical  success  and  a  political  failure.  

Several   impediments  have  prevented  a  real  and  profound  reform  at  the  political   level,  

which  would  have  really  enabled  the  State  to  meet  the  various  goals  of  SSR  (improvement  

of  basic  security  provision,  good  governance  of  security  institutions,  local  ownership)  and  

ultimately  reduce  violence.  First,  political  influence  guided  nominations  in  higher  ranks  of  

the  new  police  organization.  Most  police  commissioners  (31)  were  former  members  of  the  

armed  forces,  while  only  seven  came  from  the  FMLN  (The  UN  Secretary  General  1994).  The  

domination   of   commanding   positions   by   former   military   certainly   questions   the  

independence  of  the  young  PNC  and  the  respect  of  its  civilian  nature  as  prescribed  by  the  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  14  

peace  accords.  Yet,  relying  heavily  on  demobilized  but  seasoned  military  officers  may  have  

been  a  way  to  ensure  the  PNC  early  effectiveness  and  quick  professionalization.  

Besides,   the   necessary   judicial   reforms   were   not   undertaken,   which   resulted   in   the  

inability  of  the  justice  system  to  ensure  the  rule  of  law  in  the  aftermath  of  the  war  (Fariña,  

Miller,  and  Cavallaro  2010;  Popkin  2000).  While  the  security  institutions  were  reinforced,  

especially  the  police,  the  judicial  lacked  the  necessary  resources,  institutional  capacity,  and  

political  support  to  fulfill   its   function.  These  limitations  first  prevented  the  justice  system  

to  prosecute  effectively  those  accused  of  war  crimes,  and  later  deal   in  a  constructive  way  

with  raising  levels  of  crime  and  violence.  The  weakness  and  the  politicization  of  the  judicial  

system  may  in  fact  have  contributed  to  gang  prevalence  and  violence  in  the  2000s  due  to  

inappropriate  responses  discussed  later  (Fariña,  Miller,  and  Cavallaro  2010,  12).    

Yet,  the  factor  that  questions  the  most  SSR  success  is  the  overall  high  levels  of  violence  

that   characterize   the   post-­‐conflict   period,   and   the   raising   concerns   about   crime   in   the  

country  from  the  mid-­‐1990s.  Considering  that  the  control  and  the  reduction  of  violence  is  

the   ultimate   objective   of   SSR,   the   reform  process   in   El   Salvador  was   not   successful.   The  

explanation   for   this   failure   derives   from   the   technical   and   political   evaluations   of   the  

reform  process.  The  SSR  process  in  El  Salvador  only  addressed  parts  of  the  public  ordering  

landscape,  limiting  itself  to  public  agencies  and  actors.  Institutions  were  reinforced,  but  the  

reforms  did  not  1)  eliminate  contending  security  actors  in  order  to  unify  the  national  public  

order  regime,  nor  2)  did  it  provide  for  some  arrangements  with  private  security  actors  who  

had  de  facto  control  over  many  spaces  through  the  country.  Thus,  SSR  has  had  a  disruptive  

effect  on  public  ordering  and  ultimately  violence  in  El  Salvador.    

4. The  ignored  force:  gangs  as  security  actors  

Gangs   are   rarely   considered   as   actors   affecting   public   order   and   security   provision,  

beyond  being  a  threat  to  public  security.  Yet,  In  El  Salvador,  in  peripheral  spaces  where  the  

State   is  either  unable  or  unwilling  to   impose   its  monopoly  over  the  use  of  coercive   force,  

the   role   of   gangs   as   security   actors   has   grown   after   the   war,   influencing   authority  

structures  and  the  rules  and  norms  regulating  daily  life  in  these  spaces.  While  gangs  in  El  

Salvador   can  be   traced  back   to   the  1960s,   they  became  more   active   in   the   late   1980s   in  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  15  

peripheral   areas   of   the   country’s   main   cities,   as   well   as   in   San   Salvador’   lower-­‐class  

neighbourhoods   and   downtown   area   (Cruz   2009,   3).   Gangs   have   been   mostly   a   local  

phenomenon.  They  identify  themselves  to  their  turf  rather  than  some  larger  organization  

and   would   not   maintain   systematic   link   between   local   cliques5  (Cruz   2009).   The   war  

undermined  local  mechanisms  of  governance  (Wood  2008),  creating  space  in  the  authority  

structure  of  these  communities  that  private  actors,  including  gang,  where  able  to  fill.  Once  

the   conflict   was   over,   gangs   remained   largely   in   place,   while   the   State   weht   through   a  

period   of   important   weakness,   due   to   the   demobilization   of   combatants   and   the  

transformation  of  the  public  security  sector.    

Street  gangs  known  as  maras6  emerged  as  a  public  security  phenomenon  in  El  Salvador  

in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s.  Estimating  the  number  of  gang  members  (or  pandilleros)  in  

El   Salvador   is   difficult   as   they   only   started   to   attract   the   attention   of   researchers   in   the  

second   half   of   the   1990s,   mostly   through   a   research   program   at   the   Universidad  

Centroamericana   (UCA)   in   San   Salvador   (see   for   example   Cruz   2001;   Cruz   and   Portillo  

1998).  Furthermore,  later  research  on  gangs  and  violence  in  El  Salvador  refers  to  the  study  

Marcela  Smutt   and  Lisette   Jenny  Miranda’s   study  on  pandillas   in  El   Salvador   (1998)  as  a  

first  point  of  reference  on  this  question.  

4.1.  From  1995:  the  MS-­‐13  and  18th  Street  build-­‐up  

At  the  end  of  the  1990s,  the  PNC  estimated  there  were  between  10,000  and  20,000  gang  

members   in   the   country,  mostly   concentrated   in   urban   zones   (Cruz  2001).   Furthermore,  

while   estimations   about   the   number   of   cliques   through   El   Salvador   vary,   the   degree   of  

organization  of   the   gangs   increased   importantly   after   the  war,   as   local   cliques   started   to  

affiliate  themselves  to  the  MS-­‐13  and  the  18th  Street  Gang  (Smutt  and  Miranda  1998;  Cruz  

                                                                                                                         5  Cliques  and  gangs  can  sometimes  be  used  as  synonyms.  In  the  current  case,  especially  after  the  introduction  of  the  MS-­‐13  and  18th  Street  Gang,  “gang”  is  used  to  refer  to  the  national  phenomenon,  while  cliques  defines  local   groups   controlling   specific   communities   or   corners.   Today,   both   the   MS-­‐13   and   the   18th   Street   are  composed  of  several  cliques  spread  through  El  Salvador  and  who  maintain  more  or  less  cordial  relations.  6  While  maras  or  mara   is   largely  used  by   the  media,  policy  analysts   and   researchers   to  designate   the  Mara  Salvatrucha   (MS-­‐13)   and   the  18th   Street  Gang,   I   prefer   the   generic   term  of   gang,   or   its   Spanish   equivalent,  pandilla.   In  El  Salvador,  mara  gained  a  negative  connotation  through  the  years.  Gang  members  will  not  use  the  term  to  describe  themselves,  or  will  use  it  in  a  negative  way  (“Yo  soy  marero”  means  “I  am  fucked  up”).  Besides,  the  term  mara  is  associated  to  the  MS-­‐13,  where  the  M  is  the  abbreviation  of  mara,  and  is  therefore  mostly  rejected  by  the  18th  Street  gang.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  16  

and  Portillo  1998,  199).  By   the  end  of   the  1990s,  most   cliques   through  El  Salvador  were  

associated  to  one  gang  or  the  other.  

Three  main  factors  contributed  to  increase  the  strength,  the  degree  of  organization,  and  

the  influence  of  gangs  on  the  daily  life  of  many  Salvadorians.  First,  despite  the  opening  of  

the   political   space   made   possible   by   the   Chapultepec   accords,   the   post-­‐war  

democratization  process  did  not   concern  all   Salvadorians.   It   targeted  mostly  members  of  

the   FMLN,   and   the   integration   in   the   elite   circles   of   the   left-­‐wing   leaders.   Politics   and  

security   remained   mostly   driven   by   and   for   elites,   leaving   out   most   of   the   population.  

Peripheral   and  marginalized   communities  won   very   little   from   the   years   of  war   and   the  

following   peace,   which   both   had   a   disruptive   effect   on   local   governance   mechanisms.  

Therefore,  at  the  end  of  the  conflict,  gangs  had  an  important  power  of  attraction  based  on  

their  image,  offering  solidarity,  friendship,  identity  and  prestige  in  peripheral  communities  

where  public  good  provision  by  the  State  was  limited  (Wolfe  2011;  Cruz  2009).    

Second,   the  American   immigration  policy  plays  a  key  role   in  explaining  growing  gang  

membership   from   the  mid  1990s   (Wolfe  2011;  Cruz  2009;  Zilberg  2004).  Over  12  years,  

the   conflict  displaced  more   than  a  million  of   Salvadorians;   approximately  200,000   left  El  

Salvador,  provoking  an  exodus  mostly  toward  the  United  States  (Moodie  2010).  The  end  of  

the   Salvadorian,   Guatemalan   and   Nicaraguan   civil   wars,   as   well   as   a   realignment   of   the  

international  system  after   the   fall  of   the  Soviet  Union   led  to  a  change   in  U.S.  security  and  

immigration   policy   towards   Central   America.   The   Illegal   Immigration   Reform   and  

Immigrant  Responsibility  Act,  passed  in  1995,  “established  that  any  alien  who  was  serving  a  

longer-­‐than-­‐one-­‐year  sentence  would  be  subject  to  removal  from  the  U.S.  after  completing  

the  full  prison  term”  (Cruz  2009,  3–4;  Thale  and  Falkenburger  2006).  While  the  returning  

Salvadorians  were  not  all  already  gangs  members  in  the  U.S.,   they  brought  with  them  the  

knowledge,  the  influence,  and  the  cultural  points  of  reference  of  Los  Angeles’  latinos  street  

gangs,  the  MS-­‐13  and  the  18th  Street.  Salvadorians  with  little  ties  to  their  country  of  origin  

walked   into   marginalized   neighbourhoods   on   the   outskirt   of   El   Salvador’s   main   cities  

where  the  State’s  presence  was  weak.  Gangs,  old  and  new,  often  represented  the  only,  or  

the  most  visible,   social   structure   to  belong   to.  At   first,   sense  of  belonging,   solidarity,   and  

friendship  were  the  main  elements  explaining  attraction  for  gangs.  As  gangs  membership  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  17  

and   control   over   communities   expended,   power,   social   visibility,   and   access   to   drug   and  

money  became  equally  or  even  more  important  factors  in  explaining  the  gang  membership  

and  recruitment  (Wolfe  2011;  Santacruz  Giralt  and  Concha-­‐Eastman  2001).    

Prison  segregation  of  gangs  along  affiliation  to  either  the  MS-­‐13  or  the  18th  Street  gang  

is  a  third  factor  that  reinforced  gang  structure  and  was  key  in  the  development  of  nation-­‐

wide  gangs.  Douglas  Moreno,  former  director  of  the  prison  system  and  public  security  vice-­‐

minister,   acknowledges   that   the   isolation  of   each  gang   in  different  prisons  worsened   the  

gang   issue   in   El   Salvador   in   the   late   1990s   (interview   with   Douglas   Moreno   2013).  

Imprisonment  based  on  affiliation  rather  than  location  enabled  cliques  through  the  country  

to  develop  relationships  and  ties  inside  the  walls  that  were  later  maintained  outside.  It  also  

reinforced   the   animosity   between   the   gangs,   leading   to   a   reinforcement   of   collective  

identity   and   further   polarization   between   the   MS-­‐13   and   the   18th   Street.   Furthermore,  

considering  the  jails  limited  resources,  gangs  were  able  to  take  control  of  prisons’  activities  

and  rule  them  like  their  own  territory.  In  a  sense,  prisons  became  national  headquarters  for  

the  gangs,  enabling  local  and  regional  leaders  to  coordinate  and  share  information.  In  this  

context,  the  repressive  policies  by  the  State  adopted  by  the  successive  ARENA  governments  

to  put  in  jail  any  individual  affiliated  to  a  gang  only  contributed  to  worsen  the  issue,  feeding  

crime  and  violence  in  El  Salvador.    

These  three  elements  have  contributed  to  the  expansion  of  gangs  through  El  Salvador  

from  the  mid  1990s.  It  also  reinforced  gangs’  ability  to  claim  control  over  communities  and  

neighbourhoods   where   public   goods’   provision   by   the   State   was   limited,   especially  

regarding  security.  Furthermore,  the  civil  war  and  its  direct  aftermath  deeply  affected  the  

social   fabric  of   the  Salvadorian  society,  as  well  as   local  governance  mechanisms,  creating  

some  room  for  cliques  to  take  roots  at  the  local  level  and  gain  control  over  communities,  at  

least  partially.  Returning  Salvadorians  with  little  resources  and  ties  to  El  Salvador  brought  

with  them  practices  and  referents  associate   to  gang  culture   in   the  U.S,   transforming   local  

gang  dynamics.  It  also  created  a  recruitment  pool  of  young  men  for  local  gangs,  often  with  

prison   and   criminal   experience,   who   had   already   experienced   marginalization   and  

clandestinity.   Finally,   inadequate   strategies   by   the   State   to   deal   with   gangs   only   further  

reinforced  their  structure.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  18  

5. Public  order  regimes  in  post-­‐war  El  Salvador:  change  and  pluralism  

The  war  and  the  following  peace  process  deeply  affected  the  production  of  public  order  

in  El  Salvador.  A  series  of  external  shocks  (war,  demobilisation  of  combatants,  introduction  

and   growth   of   new   public   and   private   security   actors)   successively   destabilized   the  

national  and  local  public  order  regimes.  SSR  was  an  important  external  shock  as  it  sought  

to  increase  the  capacity  and  the  professionalism  of  public  security  institutions,  as  well  as  to  

expend   state   authority   throughout   the   national   territory.   Based   on   the   state-­‐building  

approach,   SSR   aims   ultimately   at   ensuring   that   the   State   is   the   only   security   provider,  

imposing  a  monist  public  order  regime  at  the  national   level.   In  El  Salvador,   it  was  always  

assumed  that,  once  the  FMLN  was  demobilized,  the  State  would  become  the  only  security  

actor.  Gangs  and  other  mechanisms  of  local  governance  were  kept  out  the  picture.  

Technical  reforms  improved  the  capacity  and  the  ability  of  public  security  institutions  

to  expend  their  control  over   the  national   territory,  and  provide  security.  Yet,  without   the  

necessary  political  will   to   ensure   effective   security  provision   through   the  national   space,  

and  the  required  policies  to  successfully  claim  monopoly  over  the  use  of  coercive  force,  the  

State   was   not   able   to   transform   the   structure   of   the   national   public   order   regime.   The  

delays  in  the  deployment  of  the  new  PNC  and,  most  importantly,  the  selectivity  of  security  

provision  left  many  spaces  out  of  the  State’s  reach.  

At  the  same  time,  the  security  and  the  authority  gaps  created  by  the  end  of  civil  war,  in  

addition   to   a   series   of   social   and   economic   factors   discussed   earlier,   facilitated   gangs’  

activities   and   territorial   control   in   peripheral   spaces   where   public   security   institutions  

were  unable   to   regulate   individual  behaviours.  After  1995,  once  SSR  was  well  underway,  

the   continued   inability   of   the   State   to   impose   itself   as   the  main/only   security   actor   and  

eliminate   contenders   played   a   crucial   role   in   further   strengthening   and   consolidating  

gangs’   structure   and   control   over   marginalized   communities   and   neighbourhoods.   The  

initial  lack  of  opposition  from  public  security  institutions,  and  gangs’  ability  to  access  guns  

and  hence  use  force  (Santacruz  Giralt  and  Concha-­‐Eastman  2001)  certainly  put  them  in  a  

favourable  position  to  impose  themselves  as  security  actors,  and  regulate  behaviours  and  

daily  activities  of  many  Salvadorians.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  19  

As   the   gang   issues   gained   momentum   in   the   media   and   became   the   main   threat   to  

public   security   in   the   late   1990s,   the   Calderon   (1994-­‐1999)   and   Flores   (1999-­‐2004)  

administrations,  both   from   the  political  party  ARENA,  adopted   repressive  and  aggressive  

discourses  advocating  for  gang  elimination  (Fariña,  Miller,  and  Cavallaro  2010).  Yet,  sound  

public  security  strategies  and  policies  to  resolve  the  gang  problem,  by  gaining  control  over  

spaces   claimed  by   cliques   to   preventing   their   consolidation   and   expansion,   did   not   stem  

from  the  rhetoric  adopted  by  these  governments.  The  segregation  between  the  MS-­‐13  and  

the  18th  Street  Gang  in  the  prison  system,  as  well  as  the  adoption  of  the  Mano  Dura  plan  in  

2003,   only  worsened   the   problem   (Fariña,  Miller,   and   Cavallaro   2010).   Under   the  Mano  

Dura,  massive   arrests   and  punctual   crackdowns  on   communities   controlled  by   gangs   fed  

the   vicious   circle   of   violence   that   characterized   interactions   between   gangs   and   public  

security  institutions,  leading  to  contentious  public  order  regimes  in  many  spaces  and  at  the  

national   level.   The   alternative,   reaching   an   agreement   with   private   security   actors   to  

control   violence   and   improve   the   quality   of   public   order,   was   only   considered   almost   a  

decade  later  by  the  Funes  administration.  Yet,  if  a  truce  was  well  brokered  in  March  2012  

between  the  MS-­‐13  and  the  18th  Street  Gang,  the  Salvadorian  government  never  publically  

recognized   its   role   in   the   negotiations   that   took   place   in   the   maximum   prison   of  

Zacatecoluca,  known  as  Zacatraz,  from  2011.    

Disruptive   interactions  between  reinforced  public  security   institutions  and  gangs,  due  

to   the   State’s   inability   to   eliminate   contending   security   actors  or  negotiate   some   form  of  

arrangement   with   them,   have   fostered   violence   in   El   Salvador.   In   that   context,   the   high  

levels  of  violence  in  the  post-­‐war  period  strongly  suggest  that  the  State  does  not  hold  the  

monopoly   on   the   use   of   coercive   force   through   its   territory.  While   gang   activity   in   itself  

certainly   explains   part   of   the   violence,   interaction   between   private   and   public   security  

actors  also  account  for  a  large  portion  of  the  violence.  The  fact  that  the  State  did  not  either  

eliminate   gangs   or   strategize   to   reduce   the   disruptive   effect   of   their   activities   on  

marginalized  communities  has  contributed  to  the  culture  of  violence  and  the  severe  levels  

of   homicides   that   have   undermined   social,   economic   and   political   development   in   El  

Salvador   since   1992.   SSR   programming,   isolated   from   the   post-­‐conflict   context,   did   not  

provided   for   the  necessary   tools   and   strategies   to   include  non-­‐state   actors   and   take   into  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  20  

consideration  local  mechanisms  of  public  ordering,  or  to  impose  by  force  the  monopoly  of  

the  State  over  the  use  of  coercive  force.    

6. Conclusion  

As  conceived  by  the  statebuilding  paradigm,  SSR  tends  to  have  a  disruptive  effect  on  the  

production  of  public  order  in  spaces  where  different  security  actors  with  competing  claims.  

By   increasing  public   security   institutions  capacity  and  expending   the  State’s   control  over  

its   territory   without   taking   into   consideration   already   existing   public   ordering  

mechanisms,  SSR  tends  to  undermine  rather  than  improve  security  for  many  communities.  

From  a   strictly   strategic   point   of   view   in   a   context   of   inherent   uncertainty,   SSR   tends   to  

increase   violence   since   it   creates   tensions   and   competition,   and   generates   ambiguity  

regarding  which  rules  and  norms  are  applicable   in  a  given  space.  The  disruptive  effect  of  

SSR   can   be   mitigated   by   the   State   through   two   main   strategies:   eliminate   competing  

security   actors   in   order   to   impose   a  monist   public   order   regime,   or   reach   an   agreement  

with   other   security   actors   to   establish   a   cohesive   pluralist   regime   that   would   control  

violence.  These  two  strategies  clarify  the  rules  of  the  game  and  reduce  uncertainty.  

In  El  Salvador,  SSR  was  designed  and  implemented  based  on  the  premise  that  the  State  

already  held  the  monopoly  over  the  use  of  coercive  force  once  the  demobilization  process  

was  over.  The  peace  accords  and  the  following  reform  process  only  took  into  consideration  

part   of   the   security   and   public   ordering   landscape.   Despite   the   role   played   by   local  

governances   mechanisms   during   the   war   in   the   administration   of   communities   and   the  

growing  influence  of  gangs  in  peripheral  spaces,  SSR  remained  focused  on  technical  aspects  

and   only   concerned   public   institutions.   Therefore,   once   public   security   institutions  

expended   their   authority,   they   faced   existing   public   order   regimes  where   private   actors  

where  willing  and  able  to  confront  them  to  defend  their  claims.  Furthermore,  the  absence  

of   a   sound   and   sustained   strategy   to   expend   the   State’s   territorial   control   and   face   the  

growing  gang  problem  only  further  worsen  the  violence  problem.  

I  do  not  argue  that  SSR  in  itself   is  a  sufficient  condition  to  reduce  violence  and  enable  

political,   social,   and   economic   development.   Inclusive   and   holistic   SSR   is   however   a  

necessary  prerequisite.  In  order  to  succeed  in  the  long  run,  SSR  needs  to  take  into  account  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  21  

the  deeply  political   nature   of   public   order   and   security  provision.   It   is   necessary   to   look  

beyond   the   Weberian   State   model   and   find   more   fruitful   strategies   to   reduce   violence,  

improve  security  and  ultimately  facilitate  development.  

 Even  if  SSR  takes  into  account  the  whole  public  ordering  picture,  it  may  well  increase  

violence   in   the   short   and   medium   terms   due   to   competition   and   the   disfunctionalities  

associated   to  pluralist  public  order   regimes.  Yet,   bringing   in  private   actors  might  be   less  

damaging  for  public  ordering  and  the  daily  life  of  the  population  than  to  ignore  or  confront  

them   without   the   necessary   resources   and   political   will.   In   sum,   I   suggest   that,   by  

reconceptualising  SSR  and  its  impact  on  public  ordering  in  hybrid  political  orders,  we  can  

better   understand   crime   and   ordinary   violence   in   post-­‐conflict   countries   and   so-­‐called  

fragile   states,   and   identify   more   effective   strategies   to   improve   the   daily   life   of   many  

communities.  

   

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  22  

Bibliography  

Alston,  Lee  J.  2012.  “The  Development  of  Property  Rights  on  Frontiers:  Endowments,  Norms,  and  Politics.”  The  Journal  of  Economic  History  72  (3):  741–70.  

Andersen,  Louise  Riis.  2006.  “When  Security  Is  Found  Beyond  the  State:  Suggestions  for  a  Revised  Approach  to  Security  Reform  in  Fragile  States.”  Forum  for  Development  Studies  33  (2):  305–24.  

Arias,  Enrique  Desmond.  2006.  Drugs  and  Democracy  in  Rio  de  Janeiro:  Trafficking,  Social  Networks,  and  Public  Security.  Chapel  Hill:  University  of  North  Carolina  Press.  

Baker,  Bruce.  2008.  Multi-­‐Choice  Policing  in  Africa.  Uppsala:  Nordiska  Afrikainstitutet.  

———.  2011.  “Justice  and  Security  Architecture  in  Africa:  The  Plans,  the  Bricks,  the  Purse  and  the  Builder.”  Journal  of  Legal  Pluralism  and  Unofficial  Law  63:  25–48.  

Baker,  Gary.  2010.  “The  Future  Is  Non-­‐State.”  In  The  Future  of  Security  Sector  Reform,  edited  by  Mark  Sedra,  Centre  for  International  Governance  Innovation,  208–28.  Waterloo  (On).  

Bøås,  Morten,  and  Liv  Elin  Torheim.  2013.  “The  Trouble  in  Mali—corruption,  Collusion,  Resistance.”  Third  World  Quarterly  34  (7):  1279–92.  doi:10.1080/01436597.2013.824647.  

Boege,  Volker,  Anne  Brown,  Kevin  Clements,  and  Anna  Nolan.  2008.  “On  Hybrid  Political  Orders  and  Emerging  States:  State  Formation  in  the  Context  of  ‘fragility’”.  Berghof  Research  Center  for  Constructive  Conflict  Management.  

Bourdieu,  Pierre,  and  Loic  J.  D.  Wacquant.  1992.  An  Invitation  to  Reflexive  Sociology.  1st  ed.  Chicago:  University  Of  Chicago  Press.  

Call,  Charles  T,  and  Vanessa  Wyeth.  2008.  Building  States  to  Build  Peace.  Boulder:  Lynne  Rienner  Publishers.  

Call,  Charles  T.  2002.  “Assessing  El  Salvador’s  Transition  from  Civil  War  to  Peace.”  In  Ending  Civil  Wars:  The  Implementation  of  Peace  Agreements,  edited  by  Stephen  J.  Stedman,  Donald  S.  Rothchild,  and  Elizabeth  Cousens,  383–420.  Boulder:  Lynne  Rienner  Publishers.  

———.  2003.  “Democratisation,  War  and  State-­‐Building:  Constructing  the  Rule  of  Law  in  El  Salvador.”  Journal  of  Latin  American  Studies  35  (04):  827–62.  

Clements,  Kevin  P.,  Volker  Boege,  Anne  Brown,  Wendy  Foley,  and  Anna  Nolan.  2007.  “State  Building  Reconsidered:  The  Role  of  Hybridity  in  the  Formation  of  Political  Order.”  Political  Science  59  (1):  45–56.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  23  

Collier,  Paul.  2003.  Breaking  the  Conflict  Trap:  Civil  War  and  Development  Policy.  Edited  by  World  Bank.  A  World  Bank  Policy  Research  Report.  Washington,  DC :  New  York:  World  Bank ;  Oxford  University  Press.  

———.  2007.  The  Bottom  Billion:  Why  the  Poorest  Countries  Are  Failing  and  What  Can  Be  Done  about  It.  Oxford ;  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Costa,  Gino.  1995.  “The  United  Nations  and  Reform  of  the  Police  in  El  Salvador.”  International  Peacekeeping  2  (3):  365–90.  doi:10.1080/13533319508413567.  

Cruz,  José  Miguel.  2001.  “Pandillas  Y  Capital  Social.”  In  Estudios  Centroamericanos,  1099–1118.  San  Salvador,  El  Salvador:  Universidad  Centroamericana.  

———.  2006.  “Violence,  Citizen  Insecurity,  and  Elite  Maneuvering  in  El  Salvador.”  In  Public  Security  and  Police  Reform  in  the  Americas,  edited  by  John  Bailey  and  Lucía  Dammert.  Pittsburg:  University  of  Pittsburgh  Press.  

———.  2009.  “Global  Gangs  in  El  Salvador:  Maras  and  the  Politics  of  Violence”  presented  at  the  Global  Gangs  Workshop,  Centre  on  Conflict,  Development  and  Peacebuilding,  May  14,  Geneva.  

Cruz,  José  Miguel,  and  Nelson  Portillo.  1998.  Solidaridad  Y  Violencia  En  Pas  Pandillas  Del  Gran  San  Salvador:  Mas  Alla  de  La  Vida  Loca.  San  Salvador,  El  Salvador:  UCA  Editores.  

Donais,  Timothy.  2005.  “Back  to  Square  One:  The  Politics  of  Police  Reform  in  Haiti.”  Civil  Wars  7  (3):  270–87.  

Fariña,  Laura  Pedraza,  Spring  Miller,  and  James  Cavallaro.  2010.  No  Place  to  Hide:  Gang,  State,  and  Clandestine  Violence  in  El  Salvador.  Human  Rights  Program  Practice  Series.  Cambridge,  Mass:  International  Human  Rights  Clinic,  Human  Rights  Program,  Harvard  Law  School :  Distributed  byHarvard  University  Press.  

Fearon,  James  D.,  and  David  D.  Laitin.  2003.  “Ethnicity,  Insurgency,  and  Civil  War.”  American  Political  Science  Review  97  (01):  75–90.  doi:10.1017/S0003055403000534.  

Fukuyama,  Francis.  2004.  State-­‐Building:  Governance  and  World  Order  in  the  21St  Century.  1st  ed.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press.  

Furubotn,  Eirik  G.,  and  Rudolf  Richter.  2005.  Institutions  and  Economic  Theory:  The  Contribution  of  the  New  Institutional  Economics.  2nd  ed.  Ann  Arbor:  University  of  Michigan  Press.  

Galtung,  Johan.  1996.  Peace  by  Peaceful  Means:  Peace  and  Conflict,  Development  and  Civilization.  SAGE.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  24  

Santacruz  Giralt,  Maria  L.,  and  Alberto  Concha-­‐Eastman.  2001.  Barrios  Adentro:  La  Solaridad  Violenta  de  Las  Pandillas.  San  Salvador,  El  Salvador:  Instituto  Universitario  de  Opinion  Publica  (UCA).  

Goodhand,  Jonathan.  2008.  “Corrupting  or  Consolidating  the  Peace?  The  Drugs  Economy  and  Post-­‐Conflict  Peacebuilding  in  Afghanistan.”  International  Peacekeeping  15  (3):  405–23.  

Heinemann-­‐Grüder,  Andreas,  and  Igor  Grebenschikov.  2006.  “Security  Governance  by  Internationals:  The  Case  of  Kosovo.”  International  Peacekeeping  13  (1):  43–59.  

Jarstad,  Anna  K.  2013.  “Unpacking  the  Friction  in  Local  Ownership  of  Security  Sector  Reform  in  Afghanistan.”  Peacebuilding  1  (3):  381–96.  doi:10.1080/21647259.2013.813179.  

Krasner,  Stephen  D.  2004.  “Sharing  Sovereignty:  New  Institutions  for  Collapsed  and  Failing  States.”  International  Security  29  (2):  85–120.  doi:10.1162/0162288042879940.  

Lake,  David  A.,  and  Donald  S.  Rothchild.  1998.  The  International  Spread  of  Ethnic  Conflict:  Fear,  Diffusion,  and  Escalation.  Princeton,  N.J:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Lavigne  Delville,  Philippe.  2004.  “Registering  and  Administering  Customary  Land  Rights:  Current  Innovations  and  Questions  in  French-­‐Speaking  West  Africa.”  In    Nairoby,  Kenya.  

Libecap,  Gary  D.  1989.  “Contracting  for  Mineral  Rights.”  In  Contracting  for  Property  Rights,  29–50.  Cambridge ;  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Mendelson-­‐Forman,  Johanna.  2006.  “Security  Sector  Reform  in  Haiti.”  International  Peacekeeping  13  (1):  14–27.  

Moodie,  Ellen.  2010.  El  Salvador  in  the  Aftermath  of  Peace:  Crime,  Uncertainty,  and  the  Transition  to  Democracy.  The  Ethnography  of  Political  Violence.  Philadelphia:  University  of  Pennsylvania  Press.  

Moreno,  Douglas.  2013.  

Muggah,  Robert,  and  Athena  R  Kolbe.  2012.  “In  Haiti,  Violence  amid  the  Rubble.”  The  Globe  and  Mail,  March  5.  http://www.theglobeandmail.com/commentary/in-­‐haiti-­‐violence-­‐amid-­‐the-­‐rubble/article550656/.  

National  Research  Council  (U.S.).  2002.  The  Drama  of  the  Commons.  Washington,  DC:  National  Academy  Press.  

North,  Douglass  C.  1981.  Structure  and  Change  in  Economic  History.  New  York:  Norton.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  25  

OECD-­‐DAC.  2007.  The  OECD  DAC  Handbook  on  Security  Sector  Reform  (SSR):  Supporting  Security  and  Justice.  Paris:  Organisation  for  Economic  Co-­‐operation  and  Development.  

Paris,  Roland.  2004.  At  War’s  End:  Building  Peace  After  Civil  Conflict.  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Peceny,  Mark,  and  William  Stanley.  2001.  “Liberal  Social  Reconstruction  and  the  Resolution  of  Civil  Wars  in  Central  America.”  International  Organization  55  (01):  149–82.  doi:10.1162/002081801551441.  

Popkin,  Margaret.  2000.  Peace  without  Justice:  Obstacles  to  Building  the  Rule  Oflaw  in  El  Salvador.  University  Park,  Pa:  Pennsylvania  State  University  Press.  

Posen,  Barry  R.  1993.  “The  Security  Dilemma  and  Ethnic  Conflict.”  Survival  35  (1):  27–47.  

Rotberg,  Robert  I.  2003.  State  Failure  and  State  Weakness  in  a  Time  of  Terror.  Washington,  DC:  Brookings  Institution  Press.  

Salas,  Luis,  and  Laura  Chinchilla.  2001.  “UNDP  Security  Sector  Reofrm  Assistance  in  Post-­‐Conflict  Situations:”  Draft  Report.  New  York:  United  Nations  Development  Program.  

Schmeidl,  Susanne,  and  Masood  Karokhail.  2009.  “The  Role  of  Non-­‐State  Actors  in  ‘Community-­‐Based  Policing’  –  An  Exploration  of  the  Arbakai  (Tribal  Police)  in  South-­‐Eastern  Afghanistan.”  Contemporary  Security  Policy  30  (2):  318–42.  

Sedra,  Mark.  2007.  “Security  Sector  Reform  in  Afghanistan  and  Iraq:  Exposing  a  Concept  in  Crisis.”  Journal  of  Peacebuilding  &  Development  3  (2):  7–23.  

Smutt,  Marcela,  and  Jenny  Lisette  Miranda.  1998.  El  Fénomeno  de  Las  Pandillas  En  El  Salvador.  San  Salvador,  El  Salvador:  UNICEF-­‐FLACSO.  

Stanley,  William.  1999.  “Building  New  Police  Forces  in  El  Salvador  and  Guatemala:  Learning  and  Counter-­‐learning.”  International  Peacekeeping  6  (4):  113–34.  doi:10.1080/13533319908413801.  

Studemeister,  Margarita  S.  2001.  “El  Salvador:  Implementation  of  the  Peace  Accords”.  38.  Peaceworks.  Washington,  DC:  United  States  Institute  of  Peace  (USIP).  

Thale,  Geoff,  and  Elsa  Falkenburger.  2006.  “Youth  Gangs  in  Central  America.  Issues  on  Human  Rights,  Effective  Policing,  and  Prevention”.  WOLA  Special  Report.  Washington,  DC:  Washington  Office  on  Latin  America.  

The  UN  Secretary  General.  1994.  “Report  of  the  Secretary  General  on  the  United  Nations  Observer  Mission  in  El  Salvador”.  Delivered  to  the  Security  Council  U.N.  Doc.  S/1994/561.  United  Nations.  

ISA  55th  Convention,  Toronto,  March  2014  

  26  

Tilly,  Charles.  1992.  Coercion,  Capital  and  European  States:  AD  990  -­‐  1992.  Revised.  Hoboken,  N.J.:  Wiley-­‐Blackwell.  

UNODC.  2007.  “Crime  and  Development  in  Central  America.  Caught  in  Crossfire.”  New  York:  United  Nations  Publication.  

Unruh,  Jon  D.  2003.  “Land  Tenure  and  Legal  Pluralism  in  the  Peace  Process.”  Peace  &  Change  28  (3):  352–77.  

Walter,  Barbara  F.  1997.  “The  Critical  Barrier  to  Civil  War  Settlement.”  International  Organization  51  (03):  335–64.  doi:10.1162/002081897550384.  

———.  2002.  Committing  to  Peace:  The  Successful  Settlement  of  Civil  Wars.  Princeton,  N.J. ;  Oxford:  Princeton  University  Press.  

Wolfe,  Sonja.  2011.  “Street  Gangs  of  El  Salvador.”  In  Maras:  Gang  Violence  and  Security  in  Central  America,  edited  by  Thomas  Bruneau,  Lucía  Dammert,  and  Elizabeth  Skinner,  43–69.  Austin:  University  of  Texas  Press.  

Wood,  Elisabeth  Jean.  2008.  “The  Social  Processes  of  Civil  War:  The  Wartime  Transformation  of  Social  Networks.”  Annual  Review  of  Political  Science  11  (1):  539–61.  doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.8.082103.104832.  

Wood,  Elisabeth  Jean,  and  James  K.  Boyce.  1996.  “The  Peace  Accords  and  Reconstruction.”  In  Economic  Policy  for  Building  States:  The  Lessons  from  El  Salvador.  Boulder,  Co:  Lynne  Rienner  Publishers.  

Zahar,  Marie-­‐Joëlle.  2010.  “SRSG  Mediation  in  Civil  Wars:  Revisiting  the  ‘Spoiler’  Debate.”  Global  Governance  16  (2):  265–80.  

Zilberg,  Elana.  2004.  “Fools  Banished  from  the  Kingdom:  Remapping  Geographies  of  Gang  Violence  between  the  Americas  (Los  Angeles  and  San  Salvador).”  American  Quarterly  56  (3):  759–79.