471
THE IMPACTS OF THE FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY PROGRAM ON STATE AND LOCAL HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES by LEONARD SHERMAN S.B., Massachusetts Institute of Technology (1971) S.M., Massachusetts Institute of Technology (1971) Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology February, 1975 A Signature of Author. . . . . . . Department of Civil Engineepng, January 22, 1975 Certified by . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Th9sis Supervisor Accepted byI..I...... Chairman, Departmental Committwon Graduate Students of the Department of Civil Engineering A P F 17

the impacts of the federal aid highway program on state and

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

THE IMPACTS OF THE FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY PROGRAM

ON STATE AND LOCAL HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES

by

LEONARD SHERMAN

S.B., Massachusetts Institute of Technology(1971)

S.M., Massachusetts Institute of Technology(1971)

Submitted in partial fulfillment

of the requirements for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

at the

Massachusetts Institute of Technology

February, 1975A

Signature of Author. . . . . . .Department of Civil Engineepng, January 22, 1975

Certified by . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Th9sis Supervisor

Accepted byI..I......Chairman, Departmental Committwon Graduate Studentsof the Department of Civil Engineering

A P F 17

2

ABSTRACT

THE IMPACTS OF THE FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY PROGRAM ON

STATE AND LOCAL HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES

by

LEONARD SHERMAN

Submitted to the Department of Civil Engineering onJanuary 22, 1975 in partial fulfillment of the

requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

This thesis investigates the impacts of the Federal Aid Highway Programon State and local highway expenditures. Our concern throughout theconduct of the research is to focus on this issue from a national policyperspective. Several recent events have led to an increasing interestin restructuring the Federal role in highway finance, most notably thecontroversy surrounding the passage of the 1973 Federal Aid Highway Actand the debate over post-Interstate System highway policy. Accordingly,the motivation of this research is a consideration of the design of andresponse to Federal Aid highway financing.

The starting point is a review of the mechanics of State and Federalhighway finance. Special attention is given to the unique aspects of theFederal Aid Highway Program (FAHP) and the attendant implications forempirical modelling. The thesis then proceeds to develop a theory ofState highway expenditure behavior. Our purpose here is to draw atten-tion to the premise that State highway expenditure behavior depends notonly on the level of available Federal grants-in-aid, but on the struc-tural characteristics of the grant program as well. The theoreticalmodels suggest that for the Interstate program, Federal grants havestimulated State expenditures that would most likely have not been madein the absence of the grant program. This behavior is contrasted withthe experience on the non-Interstate Federal Aid programs where thetheoretical models suggest that Federal grants have had a relativelyinsignificant impact on States' expenditure levels.

The theoretical hypotheses of State expenditure behavior are thenvalidated with econometric models designed to explore the factorsinfluencing States' total highway expenditure levels and the alloca-tion of States' highway budgets amongst alternative expenditure cate-gories. The models are estimated using a pooled data sample compris-ing the forty eight mainland States over a fourteen year analysisperiod.

3

Evaluation of the empirical results from the expenditure models suggestseveral basic policy recommendations for future Federal highway policy.Most notably, it is recommended that the U.S. Department of Transporta-tion undertake a grant consolidation program, eliminate existinggrant matching provisions, and restructure current apportionment factorsand Interstate Highway Trust Fund revenue mechanisms.

Thesis Supervisor: Marvin Lee Manheim

Professor of Civil EngineeringTitle:

4ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Throughout the course of this research, I have benfitted from theadvice, encouragement and assistance from many individuals. The contri-butions of Professor Marvin L. Manheim, my thesis advisor to the devel-opment of this study extend far beyond his valuable suggestions on par-ticular phases of the research. In a larger sense, he has been singlu-larly influential in stimulating my interest in the anlysis of trans-portation policy issues. Professors Paul Roberts, Wayne Pecknold,and Moshe Ben-Akiva, as members of my doctoral committee providedseveral valuable ideas and suggestions that aided in both the develop-ment of the theoretical analyses and in the writing of the final manu-

script. I would also like to express particular appreciation to Pro-fessor Richard Tresch of Boston College. I have benfitted greatly fromreading his own research in this field. And as a member of my doctoralcommittee, Professor Tresch's advice and encouragement have contributedgreatly to the development and presentation of the ideas in thisdissertation.

Several individuals in the U.S.Department of Transportation alsodeserve special mention for their role in assisting in the conductof this research. Ira Dye of the Office of Transportation PlanningAnalysis is gratefully acknowledged for his constant encouragementand for arranging the financial support by DOT that allowed this studyto be undertaken. Arrigo Mongini and George Wiggers, also in theOffice of Transportation Planning Analysis have been extremely helpfulin contributing numerous keen insights throughout the conduct of thisresearch. In addition I would like to express my appreciation to EdGladstone and Bill McCallum of the Federal Highway Administration forfreely giving of their time, advice and encouragement during the for-mative stages of this research.

To my friends and colleagues at M.I.T., in particular Frank Kop-pelman, Uzi Landau and Steve Lerman, I would like to express my thanksfor their constant help alon the way. Bronwyn Hall of the HarvardBureau of Economic Research must also be acknowledged for jer assis-tance in ironing out problems encountered in using the computer forthe econometric analysis phases of this research.

And finally, my thanks go to the numerous people who contributedgreatly to the preparation of the final document: Carol Walb, CharnaGarber, Charlotte Goldberg, Rebecca Lord and Shulamit Kahn.

5

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

TITLE PAGE...........................

ABSTRACT.............................

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS.....................

TABLE OF CONTENTS....................

LIST OF FIGURES... ..............

LIST OF TABLES.................

CHAPTER I: Introduction and Summary..

I.1 Motivation for Research

1.2 Summary of Previous Studies

1.3 Modelling Strategy

1.4 Theoretical Models of State

1.5 The Empirical Study

1.6 Summary and Conclusions

1.7 Organization of the Thesis

Expenditure Behavior

CHAPTER II: The Mechanics of Highway Finance: AFactual Settin ........................

II.1 Introduction

11.2 Historical Development of the Federal AidHighway Program

i. The Early Federal Aid Highway Acts

ii. The Federal Aid Primary System

iii. The Federal Aid Secondary System

iv. Urban Extensions of the Primary andSecondary Systems

v. The Federal Aid Urban System

1

2

4

5

11

15

18

18

22

28

33

36

45

47

50

50

52

52

64

65

66

66

6

Page

vi. Traffic Operations Projects to IncreaseCapacity and Safety 69

vii. The Federal-Aid Interstate System 69

viii. Structural Revisions to the FAHP Incor-porated in the 1973 Federal-Aid HighwayAct 71

11.3 The Mechanics of the Interstate HighwayTrust Fund 74

i. Program Structure 74

Source of Federal Funds 74

Total Expenditure Levels 74

Expenditure Restrictions 77

Local Recipients of Federal Funds 79

Authorization Cycle 79

Apportionment Method 79

Matching Provisions 80

Sources of Local Matching Funds 80

ii. Time Lag Structure 87

iii. Aspects of Trust Fund Taxation 97

Definitions of the Revenue Terms 98

Income Redistributive Propertiesof the IHTF 100

Equity Considerations in Admini-stering the IHTF 112

II.4 Comparison of the Federal-Aid Highway ProgramWith the Federal Public TransportationAssistance Program 119

Sources of Federal Funds 119

Total Expenditure Levels 119

Authorization Cycle 120

Apportionment Method 120

Matching Provisions 121

Expenditure Restrictions 121

7

Page

Local Recipients of Federal Funds 122

Sources of Local Matching Funds 122

11.5 Summary and Conclusions 124

CHAPTER III: The Federal-Aid Highway Program: The Ana-lytics of Design and Response................ 129

III.1 Introduction 129

111.2 Fiscal Federalism - The Normative Aspects ofFederal Highway Grant Program Design 133

i. The Theory of Intergovernmental Grants 134

ii. Functional Grants as Solutions 138

iii. Practical Limitations of the ExternalBenefit Criterion 142

iv. Additional Goals of the Federal AidHighway Program 146

v. Theoretical Aspects of Policy Evaluation 150

111.3 The Analytics of State Responses to FederalGrants 153

i. The Basic Model 154

ii. Addition of a Conditional Matching Open-Ended Grant 156

iii. Analysis of Conditional Matching Close-Ended Grants 162

iv. Evaluation of Other Grant Program Structures 169

v. Summary of the Responses to AlternativeGrant Structures 174

vi. Qualifications of the Theoretical Analyses 181

111.4 The Analytics of State Responses to FederalGrants: The Benefit/Cost Investment Model 186

i. A Hypothetical Example 186

ii. A liagrammatic Description 193

8

Page

iii. Conclusions from the Benefit/CostInvestment Model 195

111.5 Observed Expenditure Patterns: The Impact ofthe ABC and Interstate Programs 198

i. Data Analysis of the ABC Highway Program 199

ii. Data Analysis of the Interstate HighwayProgram 203

111.6 Summary and Conclusions 208

CHAPTER IV: Development of the Total Expenditure Model.... 211

IV.1 Introduction 211

IV.2 Derivation of the Model 213

IV.3 Estimation Techniques for the Total Expen-diture Model 218

Error Component Analysis 222

IV.4 The Data Set and Modelling Considerations 229

i. The Socio-Economic Descriptors 231

ii. The Measurement of Highway Capital Stocks 239

iii. Descriptors of Financing Conventions andInstiutional Characteristics 247

iv. The Highway Grant Terms 248

v. The Price Deflators 251

IV.5 Research Strategy and Conseiderations forModel Interpretation 253

i. The Total Expenditure Model: Consider-ations for Model Interpretation 253

ii. Data Set Stratification 256

IV.6 Empirical Results 258

i. The Federal Grant Terms 263

ii. Differences in Grant Term CoefficientsBetween the Two Data Subsets 271

9

Page

iii. Interpretation of the Coefficient Estimatesof the Socio-Economic and InstitutionalDescirptor Variables

State Size Variables

The Income Measures

Institutional Characteristics

The Existing Inventory Measure

iv. The Deflated Data SEt

v. Tests of Equality Between Coefficients inthe Two Data Subsets

IV.7 Summary and Conclusions

CHAPTER V: Development of the Short Run Allocation Model..

V.1 Introduction

V.2 Derivation of the Short Run Allocation Model

V.3 Statistical Properties and EstimationProcedures

V.4 Modelling Considerations and Data Requirements

Equation 1 - The Interstate Construc-tion Share

Equation 2 - The Primary System Con-struction Share

Equation 3 - The Secondary System Con-

struction Share

Equation 4 - The Non-Federal-Aid Sys-stem Construction Share

Equation 5 - The Maintenance Expendi-ture Share

Equation 6 - The "Other" ExpendituresShare

V.5 Empirical Results - Parameter Estimates of theSRAM

V.6 Evaluation of the Elasticities and DerivativesFrom the Short Run Allocation Model

272

272

275

275

277

277

280

285

289

289

292

307

313

318

320

321

323

324

326

327

339

-

10

Page

V.7 Integration of the Results From the TotalTotal Expenditure Model and the Short RunAllocation Model: Long Run Responses 351

i. Socio-Economic Charactersistics 362

ii. Highway System Charactersistics 363

V.8 Summary 366

CHAPTER VI: Summary and Conclusions...................... 368

VI.1 Summary of the Thesis 368

VI.2 Policy Implications of the Empirical Findings 373

VI.3 Limitations of the Empirical Approach andDirections for Further Research 380

Bibliography............................................ 383

Biographical Summary ................................ 390

Appendix A: Estimated Parameter Values of the Long RunRevenue Policy Model...................... 391

Appendix B: Derivation of Derivatives and Elasticitiesfrom the Expenditure Models................427

Appendix C: Derivatives and Elasticities from theTwo Expenditure Models....................440

11

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure Title Page

1.3.1 State Highway Investment Behavior........... 29

1.4.1 The Total Expenditure Model ..................... 37

1.4.2 The Short Run Allocation Model................. .. 39

1.4.3 Elasticities of the Categorical Expenditures.... 42

11.2.1 State Expenditures on the Federal AidSystems......................................... 62

11.3.1 States Having Anti-Diversion Consti-tutional Amendments............................. 86

11.3.2 Frequency Distribution of InterstateObligations..................................... 90

11.3.3 Frequency Distribution of ABC Obligations ....... 91

11.3.4 Federal Aid Highway Program Lag Structure ....... 94

11.3.5 Interstate Highway Trust Fund Expendituresand Receipts.................................... 96

111.2.1 Internal and External Highway Benefitsand Costs.................................... 136

111.3.1 Highway Investment Indifference Curves.......... 155

111.3.2 Analysis of Conditional Matching Open-Ended Grants............... .............. 157

111.3.3 Grant Responses for Alternative PriceSubsidies....................................... 160

111.3.4 Analysis of Conditional Matching Close-Ended Grants.................................... 163

111.3.5 Affect of Grant Ceilings and PriceSubsidy Levels................................ 168

12

LIST OF FIGURES (Continued)

Figure Title Page

III.3.6 Analysis of Conditional, Non-MatchingClose-Ended Grants.............................. 170

III.3.7 Analysis of Responses to Grants for FunctionsNot Previously Undertaken by StateGovernments................................... 173

111.3.8 Summary of State Responses to AlternativeFederal Grant Structures........................ 175

111.4.1 Illustrative Example of the Benefit/CostInvestment Model.............................. 188

111.4.2 Diagrammatic Illustration of the Benefit/Cost Investment Model.......................... 194

IV.4.1 The Total Expenditure Model..................... 230

IV.4.2 Lorenz Curves................................... 237

IV.4.3 Depreciation Functions.......................... 246

IV.6.1 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SUl............................... 259

IV.6.2 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SU12............................... 260

IV.6.3 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SU6............................... 261

IV.6.4 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number TUl2............................... 262

IV.6.5 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SU21.............................. 264

IV.6.6 Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SU31............................. 265

LIST OF FIGURES (Continued)

Figure

IV.6.7

IV.6.8

IV.6.9

V.2.1

V.2.2

V.4.1

V.5.1

V.5.2

V.5.3

V.5.4

V.5.5

V.5.6

V.5.7

V.5.8

Title

Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel NumberS .........................

Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number 5D21.. ......................

Estimation Results, Total ExpenditureModel Number SD3l .........................

Constrained Estimation Form for theShort Run Allocation Model................

Corner Solutions in the SRAM...............

The Short Run Allocation Model.............

48 State Sample, OLS SRAM Product FormEstimation Results.........................

48 State Sample, GLS SRAM Product FormEstimation Results.............................

7 State Sample, OLS SRAM Product FormEstimationResults.....................

7 State Sample, GLS SRAM Product FormEstimationResults .......................

41 State Sample, OLS SRAM Product FormEstimation Results..................

41 State Sample, GLS SRAM Prodcut FormEstimation Results..........................0

48 State Sample OLS SRAM LExponential FormEstimation Results.....,...................

48 State Sample. GLS SRAM Exponential FormEstimationResults ........................

Page

256

267

268

300

304

316

329

330

331

332

333

334

335

336

14

LIST OF FIGURES (Continued)

Figure Title Paje

V.6.1 48 State Sample Short Run Model Derivatives..... 343

V.7.1 48 State Sample Long Run Model Derivatives...... 356

V.7.2 48 State Sample Long Run Model Elasticities.... 359

15

LIST OF TABLES

Table Title Page

11.2.1 Year in Which First State-Aid Law Passedand Highway Department Created.............. 54

11.2.2 Date of Authorization or Creation ofState Highway Systems........................... 58

11.2.3 Factors Employed in Apportioning FederalAid System Funds (Prior to Federal AidHighway Act of 1973) ....................... 67

11.2.4 Current Factors Employed in ApportioningFederal Aid System Funds...................68

11.3.1 Trust Fund Revenue Sources............ ...... 75

11.3.2 Interstate Highway Trust Fund Revenue BySource - Calendar Year 1970............... 76

11.3.3 Interstate Highway Trust Fund Receipts andAuthorizations................. .......... 78

11.3.4 Variable Matching Percentage for States WithMore Than Five Percent of Public Lands.......... 81

11.3.5 State Highway Finance: Highway Bond Sales,1961-1971...................................... 83

11.3.6 Distribution of Person Miles by Incomeand Type of Transport....................... 102

11.3.7 Distribution of Auto Travel Patterns byHousehold Income Levels.........................104

11.3.8 Relationship of Mode Choice and HouseholdIncome for Home-to-Work Trips................... 105

11.3.9 Relationship of Average Commute Time for Home-to-Work Trips by Household Income............... 106

16

LIST OF TABLES (Continued)

Table Title Page

11.3.10 Comparison of Estimated State Paymentsto the Highway Trust Fund with StateReceipts from the Highway Trust Fundand Federal Aid Apportionments; FiscalYears 1957-1970............................... 108

11.3.11 Distribution of 1968 Mileage of TravelOn and Off Federal Aid Systems byFunctional System in Urban Areas byPopulation Group.............................. 114

11.3.12 Incremental Costs of Rush Hour Travelby Various Modes.............................. 116

11.3.13 Total Federal Trust Fund ExpenditureAllocation versus Tax Payments.................. 118

111.3.1 Summary of Equilibrium Expenditure Patterns..... 158

11.3.2 Comparison of Equilibrium Points forAlternative Grant Structures Shown inFigure 111.3.4................................ 165

11.3.3 Summary of Grant Responses.................... 180

111.5.1 State Expenditures Over and Above MinimalMatching Requirements Expressed as aFraction of Total Expenditures on"ABC" Systems................................. 200

111.5.2 ABC System Expenditures/Grants: New York,1963........................................ 204

111.5.3 State Expenditures Over and Above MinimalMatching Requirements Expressed as aFraction of Total Expenditures onthe Interstate System.......................... 206

IV.4.1 Percent of Population Residing in Urban PlacesWith More Than 5000 Residents.................... 234

17

LIST OF TABLES (Continued)

Table Title Page

IV.4.2 Measures of Income Inequality, 1963............. .240

IV.4.3 Consumer Price Index........................... 252

IV.6.1 Direction of the Influence of theExplanatory Variables on Total StateHighway Expenditures...........................278

IV.6.2 Tests of Selected Subset CoefficientEqualities.................................... 284

18CHAPTER I

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY

I.1 Motivation for Research

This study is concerned with the impact of Federal aid financing on

the highway expenditures of State and local governments. Tne moti-

vations for this research are numerous. First, it is aimed at provi-

ding useful input to the ongoing debate over structural changes in the

Federal aid highway program. Although Federal responsibility for the

financing of highway facilities has been increasing in recent years,

both in terms of the extent of activity and the amounts of money

involved, the basic principles upon which the Federal aid highway

program operates was established over 50 years ago in the Federal-Aid

Act of 1916. For the first time proposals have been advanced which, in

one case will allow Federal monies to be used for non-highway urban

mass transit systems,I and in another, would establish non-modally

aligned block funding for a broad spectrum of transportation activities

(including non-capital expenditures).2 In order to evaluate the con-

sequences of these, and other program variants, it is first necessary

to assess the impacts of the existing Federal grant-in-aid program.

By any measure, the Federal aid highway program represents a large

expenditure of funds. Its magnitude, combined with its singular status

as a restricted trust fund, provide a second motivation for

As embodied in the Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973.2As embodied in S.1693: the Special Transportation Revenue Sharing Actof 1969.

19focusing this analysis on the Federal aid highway program. Federal

expenditures for highways in 1970 amounted to $4.84 billion,I second

only to Federal welfare payments ($6.47 billion2). Moreover, Federal

highway outlays account for a large percentage of total (by all units

of government) highway expenditures,, averaging 27% nationwide, and

over 60% in some States (1970).3 Consequently, changes in the struc-

ture of the Federal aid highway program (e.g., amounts of Federal

money available, changes in the matching provisions, etc.) may cause

significant changes in State and local governmental highway invest-

ment behavior. Viewed in this perspective, the structure of the

Federal aid highway program is a significant policy tool with which

the U.S. Department of Transportation can influence the pattern of

highway investments. 4 To exploit this potential, an understanding

of the dynamics of State and local transportation investment be-

havior is essential.

A third motivation for focusing this investigation on the

Federal aid highway program as opposed to the broader question of

IFederal Highway Administration, HIGHWAY STATISTICS, 1970.

2Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, STATE-LOCALFINANCES: SIGNIFICANT FEATURES AND SUGGESTED LEGISLATION, 1972 ed.

3ibid.

4In this regard, the federal aid highway program has been used asa tool to counteract cyclical fluctuations in the Nation's economy.During the recession of the late 1950's, Congress appropriated$600 million (the so-called "D" funds) in addition to the appropri-ations for the Interstate and "ABC" programs, for the purpose ofstimulating governmental expenditures. For a description of theState response to the D fund program, see Friedlaender, A.F., "TheHighway Program as a Public Works Tool," pp. 93-101, in Ando, A.,

1 20intergovernmental fiscal relations (in all functional areas ), is that

it allows for a more detailed analysis of the complexities involved in

State and local investment decision-making behavior. There exists

ample evidence to suggest that States' expenditure responses to Federal

functional grants (e.g. highways, welfare, education, etc.) exhibit

more significant trade-offs amongst expenditures within a particular

function than between different functions. Federal grants for public

assistance provide one example. Since their inception in 1935, these

grants have been restricted to specific categories of needy people,2

leaving general welfare payments as the sole responsibility of States

and metropolitan areas. The experience has been that the States were

liberal in expanding the welfare programs in the Federally eligible

categories, and parsimonious in spending for general (non-aided) relief.3

et al., STUDIES IN ECONOMIC STABILIZATION, The Brookings Institution,1968.

In this thesis, we will be more concerned with the allocativeimpacts of the Federal aid highway program than with the use of Federalfunds in conjunction with a stabilization policy. We will raise theissue of whether Federal aid stimulates State expenditures (i.e. overand above the amounts required to simply match Federal funds).

IFor a general discussion on the characteristics of the variousfunctional Federal aid programs, see: Break, G.F., INTERGOVERNMENTALFISCAL RELATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES, The Brookings Institution, 1967;Maxwell, J.A.,, FINANCING STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS, The BrookingsInstitution, Revised Edition, 1969.

2There are currently five major Federal aid welfare programs: Old AgeAssistance, Aid to the Blind, Aid to the Permanently and TemporarilyDisabled, Aid for Dependent Children, and Medicaid.

3Maxwell, J.A.,"Federal Grant Elasticity and Distortion," National TaxJournal, Vol XXII , No. 4, pp. 550-552

Highways present perhaps an even more striking example where 21

State/local responses to Federal grants are more manifest in expen-

diture adjustments between particular highway categories, than in

overall adjustments to the State budget. Here too, Federal grants

are directed at designated types of highways,I leaving expenditures

on other highway-related activities to the discretion of the States.

Moreover, State restrictions on the use of their own trust fund

monies2 indicate that there is minimal interaction between investment

decisions in the highway "sector" and other sectors (e.g. welfare,

health, education, etc.) of the State budget.

In short a basic premise of this research is that investigation

of the impacts of the functional Federal grants in aid must explicitly

consider State/local expenditure responses within the aided function.

Thus, we will be more concerned with the magnitude of State highway

expenditures and the allocation of these expenditures amongst various

highway programs, than in attempting to trace the overall State/local

budget responses to Federal grants in terms of broadly defined

functions.

IFor example, Federal aid highway programs include capital grants forInterstate, Primary ("A"), Secondary ("B"), Urban Extension Roads("C").

2Twenty eight States have "anti-diversion" (State) constitutionalamendments. In all but four of the 50 states, gas tax and motorvehicle revenues are earmarked exclusively for highway relatedexpenditures.

1.2 Summary of Previous Studies 22

Whether we approach the subject from a normative or a postive

stance, the central issue is an analysis of the consequences of al-

ternative congressional actions. From a normative perspective, we

must know how the marketI reacts to various program structures so that

we can choose a policy which in some sense optimizes public sector

decision making. From a positive analysis stance, we must establish

a framework for predicting how the market will react to specific

policies (in particular, the existing program structure), so that we

can determine directions for incremental changes in program structure.

Thus, the central issue is a consideration of the design of, and the

response to Federal aid highway financing.

These questions have not gone totally unanswered in the lit-

erature, (although few researchers have chosen to focus their efforts

specifically on the highway sector). And yet, despite the formidable

array of recent statistical articles which purport to measure the

affects of federal grants on State/local spending, we do not as yet

have conclusive answers to such questions as: Have increasing levels

of Federal highway aid stimulated additional State/local spending, or

have Federal grants served mainly as a substitute for State expen-

ditures? How will the recently increased Federal share of "ABC"2

In this context, we make use of the term "market" to signify theinvestment pattern of State and local transportation decision-makingunits.

2The Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1970 stipulated that as of fiscal year1974, the Federal share of Primary, Secondary, and Urban Extension ("ABC")expenditures would increase from 50% of project cost to 70% of projectcost.

23road expenditures affect the allocation of highway investments in

Wisconsin? Will this behavior differ significantly from that of West

Virginia (or any other State for that matter)? If so, what factors --

social, economic, demographic, and political will temper their separate

reactions?

Our task would be relatively simple if we can address these

questions by simply adapting existing empirical studies to an investi-

gation of highway investment behavior. This is not the case however,

because neither of the two general approaches to estimating State/local

expenditure models advanced to date are appropriate for our purposes.

The first, and most common approach found in the literature has

been advanced by Sacks and Harris, Osman, and researchers.I The basic

method here is to estimate a model of State and Local expenditures in

a variety of functional categories, as a function of Federal grants and

socio-economic indicators. The National Tax Journal, which has served

as a forum for these articles since 1957, has published each new study

on the basis of the:

1) introduction of a new variable which apparentlyincreases the explanatory power of the models

Sacks, Seymour, and Richard Harris, "The Determinants of State andLocal Government Expenditures and Interfovernmental Flow of Funds,"National Tax Journal, Vol. XVII, No. 1Osman, J.W., "The Dual Impact of Federal Aid on State and LocalGovernment Expenditure," National Tax Journal, Vol XIX, No. 4Gabler, L.R., and J.I. Brest, "Interstate Variations in Per CapitaHighway Expenditures," National Tax Journal, Vol. XX, No. 1Fisher, Glenn W., "Interstate Variations in State and Local GovernmentExpenditures," National Tax Journal, Vol. XIV, No. 2

242) incorporation of different structural model forms -- e.g.

log-linear as opposed to linear

3) discussion of a new technique for including grants-in-aid as explanatory variables.

The basic problem with these studies is that they proceed with-

out an underlying model of individual State preferenczs. No account

is taken of the States' budget constraint, and as such, the essential

interdependence between functional activities (i.e. that a decision

to increase expenditures on one function must simultaneously by

compensated by reduced expenditure on others, or an increase in taxes)

is ignored. A second weakness with these approaches is their failure

to distinguish between long and short run State responses. In all but

O'Brien's study,1 a single year cross section of State expenditures

is regressed against explanatory variables (including Federal grants)

of the same year. This raises two immediate questions, both related

to inferring time series information from cross section data. First

we must question the validity of assuming (as the previously cited

studies implicity do) that States and localities react fully and

Kurnow, Ernst, "Determinants of State and Local Expenditures Reexamined",National Tax Journal, Vol. XVI, No. 3Fisher, Glenn W., "Determinants of State and Local Government Expen-ditures: A Preliminary Analysis," National Tax Journal Vol.XIX , No.3Bishop, George A., "Stimulative Versus Substitutive Effects of StateSchool Aid in New England," National Tax Journal, Vol.XVII , No.2Pogue, Thomas F., and L.G. Sgontz, "The Effect of Grants-in-Aid onState-Local Spending," National Tax Journal, Vol.XVIII, No. 1O'Brien, T., "Grants-in-Aid: Some Further Answers," National Tax Jour-nal, Vol. XXIV, No. 1Sharkansky, Ira, "Some More Thoughts About the Determinants of Govern-ment Expenditures," National Tax Journal, Vol.XXII , No. 4

1op cit

25immediately to changes in the explanatory variables. And second, we

must question the value of "one-shot" cross section models in light of

the likelihood of inter-temporal instability of the cross section

estimates.

These questions will be considered in greater detail in Chapter

V. We raise these issues here in order to stress the inadequate

treatment of the impact of Federal grants-in-aid on State and local

highway expenditures advanced to date. In summary, our basic objec-

tion to these studies (and at the same time, a starting point for the

methodology to be advanced by this study) are:

1) they fail to distinguish intra-(highway) functionallocation tradeoffs from the less significant inter-function State allocation decision-making process

2) they fail to account explicitly for the influence of aconstrained budget on allocation choices

3) no distinction is made between short and long run ex-penditure responses

4) a limited data set - usually a single year cross sectionis employed in the estimation of models.

Some of these objections are overcome in the second general

approach that has been taken in estimating the affects of Federal

grants-in-aid on State and local expenditures. The common theme of

the studies advanced by Henderson1, Gramlich2, and Tresch3 , is that

IHenderson, James M., LOCAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES: A SOCIAL WELFAREANALYSIS, Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, University of Minnesota, 1967.

2Gramlich, Edward M., "Alternative Federal Policies for StimulatingState and Local Expenditures: A Comparison of Their Effects,"National Tax Journal, Vol. XXI, No. 2.

3Tresch, Richard W., ESTIMATION OF STATE EXPENDITURE FUNCTION, 1954-1969, Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, M.I.T., 1973.

States' expenditure decisions can be described in a manner analogous 26

to the (individual) consumer utility maximization framework. Thus,

the starting point of these analyses is the specification of the

States' utility function (in terms of the variety of functional activ-

ities, i.e. expenditure categories) and a budget constraint. The actual

demand relations for public good consumption which are empirically

estimated are derived from first order utility maximization conditions.

Our criticism here is not so much with the theoretical under-

pinnings of these models1, as with their treatment of the highway

expenditure question. Neither the Henderson2 or Gramlich3 study dis-

aggregate State and local expenditures by functional (in particular,

highway) category. As such, their results are not germane to the

questions which motivate the present study.

The Tresch thesis was the first study to employ both cross

It is important, however, to recognize that adoption of the State-as-utility-maximizer framework implies rather heroic assumptionson the political and administrative realities of State expenditurebehavior. In particular, the use of social indifference maps implythe existence of a well defined, consistent set of preferences forpublically provided goods. If we choose to regard these preferencesas belonging to a governmental body, then we must assume that thelegislature accurately expresses societal preferences. Furthermore,we must assume that the often conflicting preference orderings ofdifferent governmental agencies can be subsumed into one -- in somesense "final" -- utility mapping. See chapter III.

2Henderson's model is directed towards explaining the factors in-fluencing inter-county differences in per-capita total county govern-ment spending. His data set is a single year 3080 county crosssection.

3Gramlich uses a time series formulation on quarterly national account(all State aggregate) data. As such, his results explain neither

inter-function, nor inter-State expenditure behavior.

section and time series data in estimating State expenditures in a 27

variety of functional areas (including highways) within a utility

maximizing model framework. He correctly addresses the second and

fourth weaknesses (cited on page 25 ) of the previous studies by ex-

plicitly accounting for the influence of the States' budget constraint

on the provision of publically provided goods, and testing for the

stability of his cross section estimates over time. But he fails to

distinguish between intra and inter-function expenditure tradeoffs,

and ignores possible time lagged expenditure responses. These omis-

sions are particularly serious for the highway sector.I

The structure of Tresch's model "explicitly recognizes the

,2simultaneous nature of State expenditure decisions, whereas we have

argued that the States' highway budgeting and decision making insti-

tutions operate quite apart from other State functional expenditure

decisions. Because the underlying structure of his model assumes an

expenditure interaction which is not relevant, it is not surprising

for Tresch to conclude that "the transportation equation is most

notable for what is missing, rather than the single variable (per-

centage of State population living in urban areas) that entered

significantly."3

1Tresch focuses his research on State welfare expenditure behavior.Since these expenditures are financed from States' general taxrevenues (as are other non-highway expenditures), and Federal grantsare provided on a year-to-year basis (i.e. there is no "grace period"for grant obligation analogous to the highway program), his assumedstructure seems reasonable. The problem is that he applies thisstructure to the estimation of highway expenditure response.

2Tresch, op cit, page 21

3ibid, page 374. Variables that proved insignificant include: drivingage population, Federal Highway grants, population growth rates, allincome variables, and ratio of debt to total revenues.

281.3 Modelling Strategy

The basic premise of this research is that States' highway invest-

ment behavior can be separated from the overall State budgetary process.

In this context, it is useful to distinguish between State highway

revenue (or total expenditure) policy -- i.e. long range fiscal planning,

and allocation policy -- i.e. short range project programing. In the

simplest sense, we can say that policy decisions in the first category

determine the level of State highway expenditures over several years,

while the second policy determines the allocation of a (predetermined)

budget amongst alternative geographical areas and highway projects

within the State on a year-to-year basis.

Figure I.1 summarizes the hypothesized structure of highway

investment behavior that will be adopted in this study. The depicted

structure is recursive in nature, wherein the determination of highway

revenue is non-project specific, and allocation policy reflects project

selection given a fixed budget.

The fiscal planning policy model is based on the States' widespread

use of Needs Studies.I Perceived needs (expenditures), K are deter-

mined by design standards (d), traffic and socio-economic indicators

(A), institutional characteristics and financing conventions (I), and

the age and mix of the existing highway stock (K). Given the gap

Needs Studies develop a State's perceived highway expenditure levelnecessary to provide road service at a level consistent with currentstandards. All States have conducted Needs Studies, both for fiscalplanning purposes, and in conjunction with the FHWA's NationalHighway Needs Study.

29

STATE HIGHWAY INVESTMENT BEHAVIOR

{I} + REVENUE/FISCAL

{d} + {G}PLANNING POLICY

F]+{A} + KI {T},B3 + [R] +[ET]

{A}

{GF [{E}] ALLOCATIONPOLICY

{K} {I} {A}

NOTATION

* +

{dJ E

{A} E{I} {K} B

K*

GFGF

{T} B

B

[R)

(E9E

{GF} F

{E} B

vector of values of bracketed term

decision stage

desired value of variable

design criteria (standards)

socio-economic descriptorsinstitutional characteristics

mix and age of existing highway stock

desired highway plant ("needs")

total amount of Federal highway grants

highway-related State tax rates

amount of bond obligation assumed

highway-related revenue

total highway expenditures

program components of Federal aid

highway expenditures on each of several categories

Figure 1.3.1

30between perceived (desired) highway stock K , and available revenues --

determined by existing tax rates CT), tax base, (A), approved bond

issues B, and Federal grants, GF -- the State exercises its adopted

revenue policy by adjusting tax rates, seeking new bond issues, and

possibly effecting transfers to or from State general tax revenues.

These policy decisions ultamiately determine available highway revenues

R, and total State highway expenditures ET'

While the administrative and political realities of altering tax

rates and debt obligation inhibit quick adjustments to changes in costs

and demand 1, the project selection (programming) process operates on a

relatively short cycle time.2 In figure I.1, allocation policy is

reflected by the choices of expenditure levels (E), i.e. the component

categories (Interstate, Primary, Secondary, and maintenance, etc.) of

highway expenditure. These choices are influenced by the categorical

provisions of Federal aid (GF), the fixed State highway budget R

(as determined by revenue policy), and the traffic and socio-economic,

and institutional characteristics of the State.

The specification of the empirical models of total expenditure

and allocation policy that are empirically estimated in this thesis

follow the block recursive structure shown in figure I.1. In its

simplest form, the total expenditure model asserts that:

IBond approval is usually issued over a two to five year period. Theaverage duration between tax rate adjustments is even longer -- some-what over ten year during the 15 year period 1951-1965.

2We refer here to the time required to obligate funds for particularprojects (in response to changes in Federal aid, travel demand, etc.),not the construction time to complete individual projects.

31

(1) TOTAL STATE HIGHWAY GAP BETWEEN EXISTING AMOUNTS OFEXPENDITURES FROM = f AND DESIRED HIGHWAY , FEDERAL H/WOWN RESOURCES STOCK GRANTS REC'D.

The allocation model builds on the study of Treschl where the

States' highway investment demands for each expenditure category are

derived as first order conditions2 from a utility function and budget

constraint (where the budget constraint is determined in the revenue

policy model) specification. We argue in chapter III that adoption of

the utility maximization framework does not necessarily impose an un-

realistic assumption on the motivations of State highway investment

behavior. In fact, the fundamental premise of our model specification

is simply that States allocate their fixed highway budget so as to

maximize their derived benefits (utility)3 .

To state the allocational process formally, let Ei represent

State expenditure on category i; ET represent total expenditures from

the State's own resources; GF represent total Federal aid received by

the State. The model asserts that States allocate their budget so as

to maximize their utility, U:

lop cit2We refer to the optimization conditions that requires marginalutility to equal marginal cost for each investment alternative.

31t should be noted here that this study is largely limited toallocational problems, and questions of economic efficiency. Wewill not dwell on the distributional implications of specifichighway tax systems or investment decisions. Nor will we raisethe issue of whether the States' investment behavior trulyrepresent the preferences of a voting polity, or simply repre-sent a set of decisions made by an isolated bureaucratic agency.

32(2) max U = U(EI , E2,..., En)

subject to

Ei = ET + GF

We are not directly concerned with the utility function itself but

with first order maximization conditions which provide the investment

relations:1

(3)EXPENDITURES STATE SOCIO- TRANSPOR- FEDERAL TOTALDEVOTED TO = g ECONOMIC AND TATION AID FOR HIGHWAYCATEGORY i INSTITUTIONAL CHARAC- CATE- REVENUE

CHARACTERISTICS, TERISTICS, GORY i,

The essential structure of the revenue policy model and the

allocation policy model have been presented in this chapter in their

simplest form. We have ignored for the moment, specification of

appropriate dynamic structures, the distinction between the price and

income effects of Federal grants, and the specification of a capital

stock adjustment process. These details are left for later chapters.

Our purpose in briefly outlining the model structure here is to indi-

cate the differences in the approach that will be followed in this

thesis from the previous studies in this area.

IThe derivation of these first order condition relations requiresan assumption on the fom of the utility function. The derivationis discussed fully in chapter V.

331.4 Theoretical Models of State Expenditure Behavior

One of the major findings of this research is that both the

level and structure of Federal grant programs influence State expend-

iture behavior. It is useful to characterize a grant structure

according to the following provisions:

--categorical vs. non-categorical--matching vs. block funding--open-ended vs. close-ended

The first distinction relates to whether the grant is restricted to

expenditure on specific activities. The second classification dis-

tinguishes grants requiring specified matching funds from grants with

no matching provision. Finally, the open vs. close-ended classifica-

tion distinguishes grant programs with predetermined authorization

ceilings from those programs placing no limit on available Federal

Aid. The current Federal Aid Highway Program (FAHP) is an example

of categorical, matching close-ended grants. A transportation reve-

nue sharing program would exemplify non-categorical, close-ended

block funding.

While the empirical models employed in this research are

perfectly general (in the sense that they may be used to assess the

expenditure impacts of any grant structure) , the fact is that the

structure of the FAHP did not change over our analysis period (1957-

1970). For this reason, it is important to develop theoretical

models that enable the formulation of hypotheses describing the

expected State expenditure responses to various structural variants

of the FAHP.

Two theoretical models of State expenditure behavior are 34

advanced in this thesis -- one based on an application of consumer

allocation theory and the other based on a simple benefit/cost

investment criterion. Although these theoretical analyses apparently

differ with respect to their underlying assumptions, in fact the con-

clusions drawn from both approaches are quite similar. Both the

models draw attention to the rice and income effects introduced by

Federal grants, and proceed to demonstrate how State responses will

differ according to the presence of one or both of these grant charac-

teristics.

In simplest terms, a price effect refers to the allocational

responses to grants which effectively reduce the perceived price (or

benefit/cost ratio) of a particular aided function. An income effect

describes changes in expenditure patterns resulting from grants which

increase States' available resources, but do not alter the prices of

alternative highway facilities. The importance of the theoretical

models is to demonstrate the relationship between the structural

characteristics of a grant (e.g. matching vs. non-matching) and the

corresponding price and income effects of the grant in State expendi-

ture behavior. The major findings here are twofold. First, grants

providing price subsidies on specific highway categories will induce

a more significant reallocation of State highway expenditures (both

in terms of concentrating expenditures on the aided function and

increasing total expenditure levels) than grants (of like amount)

that serve solely as income subsidies. Second, it was shown that

grants which are ostensibly characterized by matching provisions may

in fact be (allocationally) equivalent to income subsidies. That is,

35the notion of marginality was introduced to distinguish between non-

binding matching grants and grants which effectivel serve as price

subsidies.

The latter finding is particularly germane to the evaluation of

the Federal Aid Highway Program. It is shown that although both the

ABC and Interstate programs are characterized by matching provisions,

ABC grants are not of sufficient magnitude to serve as price subsidies

at the States' investment margin. Accordingly, the theoretical models

indicate (and the emperical models validate) that changes in the level

of Interstate grants will have a greater allocational impact on the

States' highway investments than changes in the level of ABC grant

funding.

A complete typology of alternative Federal highway grant struc-

tures and the theoretical modelling framework to assess their relative

impacts is presented in chapter III.

1.5 The Empirical Study 36

The empirical models developed in this research attempt to

explain the factors influencing States' total highway expenditures

(the total expenditure model - TEM) and allocation decisions (the

short run allocation model - SRAM ), amongst alternative highway

expenditure categories. The data set employed in the estimation of

the empirical models consists of a fourteen year time series (1957-

1970) of a 48 State cross section.Thus the pooled time series/cross-

section data set yields 672 (14 years x 48 States) observations of

State highway expenditures, Federal grant availability, and socio-

economic, institutional and highway inventory descriptors.

While it would have been desirable to estimate separate expen-

diture models for each State (i.e. as forty eight separate time

series), lack of sufficient time series data precluded this approach.

Accordingly, both the total expenditure model and the allocation

model were estimated using the pooled (time series plus cross-section)

data set. In addition to the use of the full pooled data set, sev-

eral estimations were performed on selected subsets of the data --

for example singling out those States with conspicuously low Inter-

state expenditures over and above minimal matching requirements.

Several alternative specifications of the total expenditure

model were estimated using both price deflated and undeflated data.

The basic form of the TEM is presented in figure 1.2. The first eight

explanatory variables in the model correspond to the set of socio-

economic and institutional characteristics which influence a States'

perception of "desired" highway capacity (c.f. equation 1). The

37

THE TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

RU= a0 + a 2*SPOP + a2*UFAC + a 3*PCY + a4*GINI + a 5*RLTOT

+ a6*TOLPCT + a7*BIPTCX + a 8*KSTK + ag*AVNIGP

+ a10*AVIGP + u

ere: Ru = State expenditures on highways exclusive ofFederal per capita grants

a 0= constant terms

a = estimated coefficients

SPOP = State population

UFAC = percent of population residing in urban areas

PCY = per capita State income

GINI = index of income inequality

KSTK = present discounted value of highway capital stockper capita

RLTOT = percent of total expenditures (all units ofgovernment) contributed by local (i.e. countyand municipal) governments

BIPTCX = percent of total capital expenditures providedfor by debt financing

AVNIGP = apportioned "ABC" grants (three year movingaverage) per capita

AVIGP = apportioned Interstate grants (three year movingaverage) per capita

u = error term

Figure 1.5.1

wh

38variable KSTK serves as a proxy for existing highway inventories.

Finally, the availability of Federal highway aid is represented by

AVNIGP and AVIGP -- a three year moving average of non-Interstate and

Interstate grants respectively.1

The short run allocation model actually consists of six dis-

tinct structural equations -- one for each expenditure category --

although the estimation technique employed explicitly accounts for

the joint interaction between shares.2 The estimated form of the

SRAM is reproduced in Figure 1.3. As indicated, the six shares con-

sidered in this analysis consist of expenditures on the Interstate

System, Primary System, Secondary System, non-Federal Aid System

construction, maintenance and a miscellaneous expenditure category.

The dependent variable in each of the equations of the SRAM

represents the share of total expenditures devoted to a particular

highway expenditure type. Similar to the total expenditure model,

the explanatory variables fall into three categories; socio-ecunumic

and highway system characteristics (SPOP, UFAC, GINI, PCY, KSTK,

PCCRMT, PCMF, KSTK), institutional characteristics (TOLPCT, RLTOT)

and the highway grant terms (AVIG, AVNIG, AVPG, AVSG and AVTG).

IThe use of three year moving averages was employed to account for twofactors. First, since Federal aid highway grants are actually avail-able for obligation over a three to three and one-half year period,inclusion of just a single years' grant would not accurately reflectthe multi-year grant availability. Second, the use of moving aver-ages partly accounts for the fact that States may not fully and im-mediately adjust to changes in Federal grant availability.

21n effect, the six equations are not independent. Since the sum ofthe shares must equal 1.0, an increase in expenditures on one cate-gory must be accompanied by a decrease in expenditures in one ormore of the remaining share categories ( in conformance with thebudget constraint).

THE SHORT RUN ALLOCATION MODEL

ESoal 1 a. 2 a1 T a14 a15 a 16SHARE 1: E= a SPP UFAC 2 KSTK %OLPCTaAVIGa5AVNIG

ET 1

SHARE 2: E aaSPOPa21UFACa 22KSTKa23AVPGa24AVIGa26

SHARE 3: SOa30P 31UFAC 32GINI33TSPMR 34PCCRMT 35AVSG 36AVIG 37

T

SHARE 4: EN 40UFAC 41 PCCRMT 42 RLTOT 43AVIG 4 4

SHARE 5: EM a a51 KSTKa52PCMFa 53RLTOT a54AVTGa55rE=Ta50

SHARE 6: E5 = a6 SPa61PCY a62KSTKa62RLTOT a63AvrGa64Tir 5

Figure I.5.1

w4

40EI = total State Interstate expenditures (State and Federal)

EP = total. Primary System expenditures

ES = total Secondary System expenditures

EN = non-Federal-Aid System construction expenditures

EM = maintenance expenditures

E= "other" expenditures (administration, grants to local govts.,miscellneous expendi Lures)

ET = total expenditures: sum of the above expenditures

SPOP = State population

UFAC = percent of population residing in urban areas

KSTK = present discounted value of highway capital stock

TOLPCT = percent of total State revenues raised on State-administeredtoll roads

AVIG = apportioned Interstate grants (three year moving average)

AVNIG = apportioned "ABC" grants (three year moving average)

AVPG = apportioned Primary System grants (three year moving average)

AVSG = apportioned Secondary System grants (three year moving average

AVTG = apportioned total grants (three year moving average)

GINI = index of income inequality

TSPMR = State rural primary system mileage

PCCRMT = percent of rural primary system mileage carrying more than10,000 ADT

PCMF percent of total primary system mileage carrying more than5,000 AD

RLTOT = percent of total expenditures (all units of govt.) contributedby local governments

PCY = State per capita income

aij = estimated coefficients

Figure 1.5.1 (contd.)

It should be clear that the total expenditure model and the 41

short run allocation model may be evaluated in a complementary fashion.

The TEM serves to predict the effect of Federal grants (among other

factors) on total State highway expenditures while the SRAM predicts

how the total budget will be allocated amongst alternative expenditure

categories. It is not our purpose here to provide a detailed descrip-

tion of the estimation results. However, a convenient means to sum-

marize the most important emperical findings is contained in figure 1.4.

The entries in this figure represent the elasticities of the expendi-

tures in each of the six highway categories with respect to each of

the variables in our analysis.' Perhaps the most striking finding

in light of our research objective to assess the expenditure impacts

of the Federal Aid Highway Program (FAHP) is that States have viewed

the Federal "ABC" grant program as a substitute for their own expen-

ditures as contrasted with Interstate grants which has served to

stimulate States' own highway expenditures. This is evident from

1Chapter VI derives the simple result that

TEjfXk = ET/Xk + rSj/Xk

where "Ej/Xk = elasticity of category jexpenditures w.r.t. variable Xk

nET/Xk = elasticity of total expendituresw.r.t. variable Xk (derived asa function of the estimatedparameters of the TEM)

lSj/Xk = elasticity of the share of ex-penditures devoted to categoryj w.r.t. variable Xk (derivedas a function of the estimatedparameters of the SRAM)

ELASTICITIES OF THE CATEGORICAL EXPENDITURES

Forty Eight State Sample

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

INTERSTATEVARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

SHARE

PRIMARY

0.943

-0.198

0.623

-0.029

0.214

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

0.023

0.028

-0.057

0.534

-0.045

SECONDARY

1.117

-0.287

0.623

0.302

0.127

0.277

0.026

-0.001

0.023

0.028

-0.074

-0.176

0.261

Figure 1.5.3

42

0.330

0.396

0.623

-0.029

-0.067

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

-0.059

0.028

1.232

-0.070

-0.002

43

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

SHARE

MAINT

0.497

-0.042

0.623

-0.029.

0.387

0.031

-0.011

0.007

0.923

-0.043

0.440

u 062

t001

NONFASYST.

1.662--

-0.890

0.623

-0.029

0.127

-0.031

0.183

-0.001

0.023

-0.489

0.198

-0.130

-0.026

Figure 1.5.3 (contd.)

OTHER

1. 987

-0.042

1.440

-0.029

0.034

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

0.023

0.026

-0.146

-0.226

-0.066

the elasticities in figure 1.4 which indicate that a 1% increase in 44

Primary or Secondary grants leads to less than a 1% increase (.53% and

.26% respectively) in total expenditures on these systems while each

dollar increase in Interstate grants have tended to increase total

Interstate expenditures by more than the amount of the grant (elas-

ticity = 1.23). A more complete discussion of the impacts of the

FAHP (as well as other explanatory factors) in both total highway

expenditure and expenditure allocation is developed in Chapters IV

through VI. Suffice it to say here that the true value of the econo-

metric models is to allow us to isolate the effects of Federal grants

on State highway expenditures. Clearly there are factors other then

Federal grants -- socio-economic, demographic and institutional char-

acteristics -- that influence State highway expenditure behavior.

The total expenditure model arid the short run allocation model dev-

eloped in this thesis evaluate the influence of each of these factors

in States' highway expenditures.

451.6 Summary and Conclusions

This study develops a methodology for assessing the impacts of

the Federal Aid Highway Program on State expenditure behavior. Unlike

several previous studies in this area, the empirical work conducted in

this thesis builds upon a behavioral representation of State highway

investment decision making. As such, it has been possible to develop

several hypotheses, based on theoretical models, of the expected

State responses to numerous structural variants to the Federal Aid

Highway Program. Most importantly, it was shown that not only the

level, but the structure of a grant program influence State expendi-

ture behavior.

In general, the findings from the empirical research corrob-

orate the theoretical hypotheses. Interstate grants have been shown

to have a more significant impact on both the total expenditures and

allocation of States' highway budgets than the non-Interstate grant

programs. These results were reported in terms of the stimulatory

impact of the grants on States' own expenditure levels. The empir-

ical models clearly demonstrate that ABC grants have been viewed as

a substitute for expenditures the States would have undertaken in

the absence of grants. Contrastingly, the Interstate program has

been characterized by expenditure stimulation.

These results have important policy implications for the US

Department of Transportation. This research has shown that (for the

ABC program)) whereas the Federal government provides categorical

grants, presumably in those types of activities for which it per-

46ceives a national interest in stimulating expenditures (i.e. inducing

construction that may not have been undertaken in the absence of

grants), the net result may be the expansion of expenditures (or con-

traction through tax relief) in other (non-aided) areas in which the

Federal government has no officially stated interest. The major pol-

icy implications of this finding are twofold. First, if essentially

the same expenditure pattern as currently exists can be achieved with

grants devoid of categorical restrictions and specific matching pro-

visions, the administrative requirements of the FAHP are ineffective

and wasteful. Secondly, to the extent that the Federal Aid Highway

Program (and specifically the ABC component of that program) has not

achieved a significant reallocation of States' resources, it raises

the fundamental question of the objectives accomplished by the Federal

role in highway finance. While it may be argued that the chief rat-

ionale for the FAHP is to accelerate the construction of highway

systems that serve the national interest, the evidence developed in

this research indicates that at least some components of the FAHP

singularly fail to meet this objective.

1.7 Organization of the Thesis 47

This thesis has attempted to develop a series of econometric

models derived from an explicit representation of highway investment

decision making behavior. Accordingly, the elements of State highway

planning and programming procedures are presented in chapter II. The

intent here is to provide a factual setting for development of empir-

ical models. In this vein, the mechanics of Federal highway financing,

and a comparison of the highway program to the Federal role in other

modal areas are also discussed.

Chapter III sets forth a series of theoretical models which

address the question of the impacts of Federal grants-in-aid on State

and local transportation investments. We begin with models drawn from

consumer theory and applied to State highway investment behavior. We

choose to present these models for several reasons. First, as men-

tioned above, our State highway allocation models are based on con-

sumer theory. Second, this theory provides the basis for normative

statements on the design of Federal highway grant programs. And third,

consumer theory provides a convenient framework with which to evaluate

a wide variety of questions concerning State responses to Federal

grant availability. Thus, accepting the assumptions which the con-

sumer theory imposesl, we can investigate the differences in the

"idealized State" response to matching as opposed to block grants.

IThese assumptions will be itemized in full, and discussed in viewof the description of actual State highway planning and program-ming procedures presented in chapter II.

48

Similarly the analysis can be applied to the questions of "distortion"

(i.e. whether Federal matching grants cause unsubsidized highway serv-

ices to be neglected relative to subsidized activities), and the

effects of the grant program specificity (i.e. the allocational con-

sequences of restricting Federal grants to narrowly defined highway

categories). Next, a modelling framework based on a simple benefit/

cost investment criterion is presented to further clarify the dis-

tinction between the price and income effects characterizing Federal

highway grants. Chapter III concludes with an application of the

benefit/cost investment model to the Interstate and ABC grant programs.

Needless to say, we would like to assess the expenditure im-

pacts of the Federal Aid Highway Program with empirical analyses as

well. This is the purpose of chapters IV - VI. Chapter IV develops

an econometric model designed to explain the States' total expenditure

responses to the Federal Aid Highway Program. Because we are using

a pooled data set of time series and cross sectional observations,

careful attention must be given to the correct specification of

error variance - covariance matrix. A recent technique developed by

Theil and Goldberger is applied to our estimation problem to develop

generalized least squares estimates of the total expenditure model.

Chapter V develops an econometric model of the second dimension

of States' highway expenditure behavior, namely budget allocation. A

six category share model is estimated using data covering the forty

eight Mainland States over a fourteen year analysis period. Here too

special attention must be given to the proper econometric treatment

of the model structure. A generalized least squares technique is

49advanced to account for the joint interaction between expenditure

shares.

Chapter V also attempts to unite the empirical findings of the

SRAM with TEM developed in the previous chapter. In particular, the

analysis shows how to derive the elasticities'and derivatives of

highway expenditures as a function of the estimated parameters of the

total expenditure and short run allocation models. These emprirical

measures of the impacts of the Federal Aid Highway Program are compared

to the theoretical hypotheses of State highway expenditure behavior

advanced in chapter III.

Finally, chapter VI presents a summary of-the major findings

developed in this thesis. The policy implications of the theoretical

and empirical models are discussed and related to directions for future

fruitful research.

50

CHAPTER II

THE MECHANICS OF HIGHWAY FINANCE: A FACTUAL SETTING

II.1 Introduction

Any attempt to model the highway investment behavior of State

governments must take careful account of the institutional, political,

and administrative realities of the Federal-Aid Highway Program (FAHP).

The purpose of this chapter is to summaraize the major features of the

FAHP, and draw attention to the issues that will be addressed in the

theoretical and empirical analyses that follow.

Although not all of the material described in Chapter II is

directly required for the development of the empirical models of State

highway investment behavior, the presentation of a detailed description

of the FAHP provides a useful perspective for the evaluation of the

Federal highway programs in following chapters.

The Federal-Aid Highway Program has evolved in an incremental

fashion. Although the recently enacted Federal-Aid Highway Act of

1973 established several new Federal policies, the fundemental prin-

ciples upon which the FAHP operates were established in the germinal

highway legislation of 1916. Section 2 of this chapter traces the

historical development of the Federal-Aid Highway Program with partic-

ular emphasis on landmark legislation in the years 1916, 1921, 1944,

1956, and 1973. In each of these years, new Federal-Aid Systems were

incorporated into the FAHP starting with the Primary System in the

earliest acts, through the Interstate System of the 1956 act, to the

mass transit-inclusive Urban System of the 1973 act. Each Federal

Aid System is described in detail with respect to categorical restric-

tions, Federal matching provisions and authorization levels.

Section 3 focuses on the mechanics of the Interstate Highway

Trust Fund (IHTF). Particular attention is paid to tracing out the

flow of Federal funds from the point of initial Congressional authori-

zation to the actual receipt of funds by State Highway Departments.

In addition, this section includes a discussion of highway taxation

to show the various aspects of regressiveness and inequities inherent

in the IHTF revenue measures.

Section 4 presents a comparison of the FAHP to the Federal mass

transit assistance program in order to highlight the singular aspects

of the Interstate Highway Trust Fund. The IHTF is unique not only

by virtue of its magnitude of expenditures, but becuase of the mech-

anics of its operation as well. The comparison between the Federal

aid programs in these two modal areas is presented in terms of the

sources of Federal funds, total expenditure levels, authorization

cycles, apportionment methods, matching provisions, expenditure

restrictions, local recipients of Federal funds, and the sources of

local matching funds.

Chapter It concludes with a summary of findings, with particu-

lar emphasis on the major considerations for empirical models of

State expenditure response to the Federal-Aid Highway Program.

52

11.2 Historical Development of the Federal-Aid Highway Program

The Federal interest in transportation has its origin in

the Constitution, which enpowers the United States Government to

regulate interstate commerce, to provide for the general welfare

and the common defense, and to establish post roads. Obviously,

the evolution of the national transportation policy has undergone

innumerable changes since the original mandate of 1787, most

notably in the area of Federal highway policy.

Road development in the United States began slowly, with the

first major Federal highway capital investment program coming in

1916. At that time, Congress established the fundamental princi-

ples upon which the Federal-Aid Highway Program (FAHP) still oper-

ates today. These principles - namely that the States would act

as financial intermediaries in the planning, construction and main-

tenance of roads, receiving Federal aid in the form of matching

grants - have been refined in land-mark legislation in the years

1921, 1944, 1956, 1970, and 1973.

i. The Early Federal-Aid Highway Acts

The provision of roads in the United States was almost

entirely under local jurisdictional control before the turn of the

century. Although several States began organizing State Highway

Departments (SHD) in the early 1900's in response to a growing aware-

ness of the inadequacy of existing road networks in light of the

rising popularity of the automobile, a major stimulus for creation

53

of SHD's came with the passage of the Federal-Aid Road Act of 1916.

This act - the first Federal-aid highway legislation, stipu-

lated that each State seeking a grant was required to establish a

State Highway Department as well as meet Federal standards of road

construction and management. Although Federal aid under this Act

was minimal,1 the States responded immediately in establishing SHD's.

As shown in table 11.2.1 all States had legislated the creation of

State Highway Departments by 1917.

Four fundamental principles were established by the Federal-

Aid Road Act of 1916 which still dictate the operation of the FAHP:

1) The conditional, matching 2grant in aid would be the

sole instrument of Federal financial assistance for the

provision of highways.

2) Federal funds would be restricted to expenditure on

construction.

1. The total 1917 appropriation under this Act was only $5 million.By the time this appropriation was apportioned to the States,Delaware received scarcely more than $8000. Moreover, this aidwas restricted to the improvement of rural post roads. A Statecould receive no Federal funds for bridges greater than 20 feetin length, and were limited to a maximum of 10,000 Federal dollarsper road mile.

2. Conditional grants-in-aid refer to the requirement that funds arerestricted to particular categories of expenditure (e.g. ruralpost roads). Matching grants require States to furnish fundsfrom their own sources (in some fixed matching ratio) in order toqualify for Federal funds. A complete taxonomy of grant charac-teristics will be presented in chapter III.

54

YEAR IN WHICH FIRST STATE-AID LAW PASSED AND

HIGHWAY DEPARTMENT CREATED

YEAR DATE OF ESTABLISHMENT OF FIRST STATEFIRST HIGHWAY DEPARTMENTSTATE STATE-AIDLAW YEAR REMARKS

J-_PASSED

Al abamaArizonaArkansasCalifornia

Colorado

Connecticut

Delaware

FloridaGeorgiaIdahoIllinois

Indiana

Iowa

Kansas

Kentucky

LouisianaMaine

Maryland

Massachusetts

Michigan

Minnesota

MississippiMissouri

1911190919131895

1909

1895

1903

1915190819051905

1917

1904

1911

1912

19101901

1893

1892

1905

1905

19151907

1911190919131907

1909

1895

1903

1915191619131905

1917

1904

1917

1912

19101907

1898

1892

1901

1905

19161907

State Department of Engineering,Highway Commission created in 1911.

Originally to administer aid to coun-ties only.

Commission of 3 members; single com-missioner provided for in 1897.

Organization to administer State-aid;present organization created in 1917.

First commission provided for roadstudy; State Highway Departmentcreated in 1913.

Held unconstitutional same year;present organization created in 1919.

Iowa State College designated ascommission; in 1913 a 3-man commissionprovided.

State department with limited powersfor administration of Federal-aid.

Commissioner with advisory powers only;State Highway Department created in1920.

Present highway board created in 1921.Commissioner to supervise State-aidroads; law of 1913 establishedcommission.

Highway Division of geological survey;commission established 1908.

Preliminary commission for studies;in 1893 new commission established.

Highway committee appointed; StateReward Law in 1905.

Commission authorized in 1898; enactedinto law in 1905.

Engineer advisory to county officials;Hiqhway Commission created in 1913.

Table 11.2.1

55

YEAR IN WHICH FIRST STATE-AID LAW PASSED AND

HIGHWAY DEPARTMENT CREATED

YEAR DATE OF ESTABLISHMENT OF FIRST STATEFIRST RIGHWAY DEPARTMENT

STATE-AIDSTATE LAW YEAR REMARKS

PASSED

MontanaNebraskaNevadaNew Hampshire

New Jersey

New Mexico

New York

North Carolinaaorth Dakota

OhioOkiahomaOregonPennsyl vaniaRhode Island

South CarolinaSouth DakotaTennesseeTexasUtahVermontVirginiaWashingtonWest 'irniniaWisconsin

Wyoming

1913191119111903

1891

1909

1893

19011909

19041911191319031902

1917191119151917190918921898190519091911

1911

1913191119171903

1894

1909

1898

19151909

19041911191319031895

1917191319151917190918981906190519091907

1917

Commissioner appointed in 1905after study by engineer conission.

Aid to counties in 1891 underackninistration of board of agri-cul ture.

Territorial road commission; StateHighway Conmission created in 1912.

Appropriation for State-aid approvedby state engineer and surveyor.

"Good roads experiment station";State Highway Commission createdin 1913.

Advisory until 1910.

Report of Board of Public Roadsapproved by legislature, and acommissioner appointed.

Present department created in 1917.

Board provided for.Commissioner; a bureau provided in 1913.Work by geoloqical survey; commissioncreated in 1911

Source: U.S. Bureau of Public Roads-e-"HIGHWAY STATISTICS, Summary

Table 11.2.1

to 1945

(contd.)

56

3) The States would act as financial intermediaries in

the expenditure of Federal highway funds.

4) The States would be legal owners of Federal aid roads,

in that the responsibility for planning, constructing and

maintaining these roads would be "the duty of the States,

or their civil subdivisions, according to the laws of the

several States."'

The second major piece of Federal-aid Highway legislation

was passed in 1921, with the purposes of increasing the minimal

existing Federal authorizations, designating a primary system on

which all Federal aid would be spent, and establishing a floor on

minimal State appropriations. With passage of the Federal Road

Act of 1921, Congress established two more fundamental principles

(in addition to the four principles of the 1916 Act) which still

guide the FAHP:

5) Federal-aid would be accorded to specific road categories

on designated Federal-Aid Systems. Each Federal-Aid System

would be defined according to operating and design criteria

established by the Bureau of Public Roads.

6) Apportionment of national highway authorizations to the

States would be made according to a formula which weights the

1. Section 7, 39 Stat. 355

57

States' population, land area, and existing road mileage.

No State would receive less than .5% of the total yearly

authorization.

States were quick in responding to the Federal requirement

of designating a primary road system. As shown in Table 11.2.2

all States had designated their primary systems by 1924.

Al though the expenditure of Federal funds on secondary and

urban roads was permitted on a limited scale during the depression,

the official creation of the Federal-Aid Secondary and Federal-Aid

Urban systems was first stipulated in the Federal-Aid Road Act of

1944. The Federal-Aid Secondary (FAS) program provided matching

grants for "principal secondary and feeder roads, including farm-to-

market roads, rural free delivery mail, and public school bus routes."1

Federal-aid urban extension funds were provided for portions of

primary roads which passed through urban areas.

The 1944 Act served to establish what has since become known

as the "ABC"program. 2 The total Federal aid ABC authorization was

(and still is) divided in the ratio of 45 percent FAP, 30 percent

FAS, and 25 percent urban extension. Only minor modifications have

been made to the provisions of the ABC program as stipulated in 1944.

1. Federal-Aid Road Act of 1944.

2. "A" refers to the Federal Aid Primary (FAP) system, "B" theFAS system, and "C", urban extensions of FAP and FAS.

58

DATE OF AUTHORIZATION OR CREATION

OF STATE HIGHWAY SYSTEMS

STATE [YEAR REMARKS

AlabamaArizona

ArkansasCalifornia

Colorado

Connecticut

Delaware

Florida

GeorgiaIdaho

Illinois

Indiana

IowaKansas

Kentucky

LouisianaMaine

Maryland

MassachusettsMichigan

Minnesota

MississippiMissouriMontanaNebraska

19151910

19231902

1917

1913

1917

1915

19191915

1913

1917

19131918

1912

19211913

1908

18931913

1921

1924191719131921

Tentative State system laid out in 1910by State Highway Department.

Legislative enactment.Constitutional amendment empowered legis-

lature to establish State system; systemlaid out in 1910.

System of State routes for present andfuture improvement approved by legislature.

Map of trunk lines prepared in 1901 but notapproved by legislature until 1913.

System designated as a result of planningto expend Federal-aid funds.

State Highway Department authorized todesignate system; revised system adoptedby legislative enactment, 1923.

Legislative enactment.Legislature directed commission to desig-nate trunk highway system.

Law provided for the systematic laying out of16,000 miles of State-aid roads.

System of main market highways provided bylegislative enactment.

Inter-county road system designated.System designated as a result of planning

to expend Federal-aid funds.Primary system established by legislature as

"Inter-county seat system."

Complete system, including trunk lines, State-aid, and "3rd Class", roads designated.

State system established to be improved withstate bond issue. Roads classified about 1899.

Trunk-line system established limiting stateroad mileage in each county.

Trunk-line plan presented to legislature in1919; in effect May 1, 1921.

System designated as a result of planning toexpend Federal-aid funds.

Table 11.2.2

59

DATE OF AUTHORIZATION OR CREATION

OF STATE HIGHWAY SYSTEMS

STATE YEAR REMARKS

NevadaNew HampshireNew JerseyNew Mexico

New YorkNorth CarolinaNorth DakotaOhioOklahoma

Oregon

PennsylvaniaRhode IslandSouth Carolina

South DakotaTennesseeTexas

UtahVermont

Virginia

Washington

West VirginiaWisconsinWyoming

1917190519171912

19071915191719111913

1917

191119031917

191919151917

19121917

1918

1905

191719171919

I I

Certain roads designated "inter-county",later called "State highway."

State engineer's map adopted by legislature.

Map of State system included inof commissioner.

Authority granted dommission toState routes

annual report

designate

System designated as a result of planning toexpend Federal-aid funds.

Trunk road system provided for.Commission provided to plan system.System designated as a result of planning to

expend Federal-aid funds.Selected by commission.System designated as a result of planning to

expend Federal-aid funds.System designated as a result of planning to

expend Federal-aid funds.System in isolated units. Primary highway

designated by legislature in 1913.

Trunk highway system selected.

Source: U.S. Bureau of Public Roads

HIGHWAY STATISTICS, Summary to 1945

Table 11.2.2 (contd.)

60

"C" funds are now accorded to extensions of the secondary as

well as the primary system (1954 Federal-Aid Road Act). Further-

more, States now are allowed to transfer up to 201 percent of

their appropriation in any one Federal-Aid System to any other

System (1956 Federal-Aid Highway Act).

In historical perspective the 1944 Federal-Aid Road Act was

perhaps even more significant for its germinal role in establishing

the Interstate Highway System. Culminating six years of cooperative

study by the Bureau of Public Roads (BPR) and individual SHD's, the

1944 Act directed the BPR to designate a "National System of Inter-

state Highways." Although no special funds were appropriated at

this time, the Interstate network did become an established compo-

nent of the Federal-Aid System.

The Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1956 carried with it the most

sweeping reforms in the history of the Federal-Aid Highway Program.

Building on the six fundamental principles of FAHP operation estab-

lished in previous legislation, two final principles were added by

this landmark Act:

7) The National System of Interstate and Defense Highways would

be established as a distinct Federal Aid system with separate

authorizations, apportionment formulas, and matching ratios.

1. Changed to 40% by the Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973.

61

8) The Interstate system as well as other Federal Aid

systems would be financed from the Interstate Highway Trust

Fund (IHTF). This Fund would be composed of excise taxes on

motor fuel, auto-related parts and oil, and truck use. Fur-

thermore, the IHTF would be restricted solely for the dis-

bursements of grants to States for the construction of roads

on the Federal-Aid System.

Since its inception in 1956, the Interstate program has domina-

ted the Federal-Aid Highway Program, with over $43 billion of Federal

funds obligated as of the end of calendar year 1972 (approximately

73% of the total Federal highway aid over this period). Although

the States' share of the Interstate program is at most 10 percent,

State funds devoted to Interstate construction represent a sizeable

fraction of total yearly SHD budgets as shown in figure 11.2.1. In

fact, in the mid-1960's, State expenditures on the Interstate system

exceeded expenditures on the ABC system.

More recently, Federal-aid legislation has given increased

emphasis (i.e. funding) to urban road systems. Without changing the

structure of the FAHP, new functional classes have been added to the

already existing ABC and Interstate programs. In particular, the

Federal Aid Highway Act of 1968 initiated the Traffic Operation Pro-

gram to Increase Capacity and Safety (TOPICS) funded at $100 million

per year. In the next highway bill (1970) Congress authorized funding

for the Urban (arterial) system which provided $100 million in addition

STATE EXPENDITURES ON THE FEDERAL AID SYSTEMS

375C-CI,

14

- r27NV- I20

0

c

o Iso

'75C> I

560 --4

ft 5 ll 'Ns 51 '60 'Vi '62 '65 'C4IC 68 '6 '61 'O '6 '70 YEAR

4

oce55

0

0 -4 -15 6 '~ 6 '5 '4 '6f '~ '6 6 61 '0 YA' /5 -4

F5I

Figure 11.2.1

62

63

to the extant urban extensions (of FAP and FAS) program. With

passage of the 1968 and 1970 Federal Aid Highway Acts, the over-

all level of funding for urban road systems increased from 25

percent to 33 percent of non-Interstate authorizations.1

The current Federal Aid Highway Program is administratively

structured in terms of several distinct Federal Aid Systems. Each

System is characterized by a separate biyearly authorization, and

a distinct set of factors employed in apportionment formulas. The

design and operating characteristics of each Federal Aid System are

broadly defined in various pieces of enabling legislation described

previously in this section.2 However, the legislative definitions

of the Federal Aid Systems are intended to provide only general

guidance as to the Congressional intent in stimulating the construc-

tion of particular class of roads. Ultimately the States, in coop-

eration with the Federal Highway Administration are responsible for

1. Prior to the 1968 Act, urban road funding (exclusive of Inter-state) was limited to the "C" program, where ABC authorizationswere divided on a 45/30/25% basis. For FY 1972 urban road systemauthorizations included $275 million for urban extensions, and$100 million for each TOPICS and urban arterial comprising 33%of the total $950 million non-interstate authorization.

2. Sections II.2.i through II.2.vii inmediately following will traceout the characteristics of the FAHP as of the end of calendaryear 1972, and thus are relevant for the empirical analysesfound in chapters III, IV and V (the empirical analyses coverthe period 1954-1970). Section II.2.viii outlines the changes inthe FAHP introduced by the Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973.

64

the specific assignment of roads to a particular Federal Aid

System.

ii. The Federal Aid PrimarySystem (the "A" System)

The Federal Aid Primary (FAP), first established in 1921,

is the oldest of the Federal Aid Systems. The FAP is defined as

"an adequate system of connected main highways" not to "exceed 7

per centum of the total highway mileage of each ... State."1

Although the ultimate size of each State's FAP appears to have

been limited by law, this is not the case. Provision has been made

to increase the relative size of the FAP whenever the 7 percent

ceiling is approached. As a matter of practice, no State has had

to forfeit FAP grants because of the mileage restriction.

FAP authorizations are normally made from the Interstate

Highway Trust Fund every two years by two means: as a fixed percen-

tage of total ABC authorizations, and (possibly) as a supplemental

authorization. Forty five percent of the total ABC funds are dedi-

cated to the Primary System. In addition, Congress may authorize

funds over and above the ABC percentage Primary share.2

Apportionment of FAP authorizations to the States is derived

from the following formula:

1. 103(b), Subpart A, Title 23, U.S.C.

2. For example, in the Federal Aid Highway Act of 1970, Congressauthorized $1.1 billion for the ABC System (yielding $495 millionfor the FAP), as well as a supplemental $75 million FAP (rural)grant for each of fiscal years 1971 and 1972.

65

1) one third of the total apportioned on the basis of a

State's land area relative to the total U.S. land area

2) one third of the total apportioned on the basis of a

State's population relative to total U.S. population

3) one third of the total apportioned on the basis of a

State's rural postal route mileage relative to the U.S.

total of such mileage

4) no State to receive less than 0.5% of the total appor-

tionment

iii. The Federal Aid Secondary System (the "B" System)

The Federal Aid Secondary System includes farm-to-market

roads, rural mail routes, public school bus routes, local rural

roads, county roads, and township roads. As the legislative

guidelines indicate, the FAS consists of projects on a smaller

scale than the FAP. There is no mention of connectivity (as in the

legislative guidelines for FAP). The secondary system is intended

to provide a series of routes of secondary Statewide significance

linking markets to urban centers or to other FAS or FAP highways.

The method of authorization and apportionment for FAS is

very similar to the FAP System. Thirty percent of the total ABC

authorization from the IHTF is dedicated to the Secondary System.

66

Additional funds for rural sections of the FAS may be authorized.1

The apportionment formula is identical to the provisions of

the FAP formula, except that rural rather than total population is

used as an apportionment factor (see summary Tables 11.2.3, and

11.2.4).

iv. Urban Extensions of the Primary and Secondary Systems(the "C" System"

This system consists of projects on approved extensions of

the Federal Aid Secondary and Federal Aid Primary Systems in urban

areas. In practice, this System is merely an administrative classi-

fication, since urban roads can be Federally financed from "A,"

"B," or "C" funds. Federal funds for FAP/FAS urban extensions are

set at 25 percent of the total ABC authorization. Apportionment to

States is based on each State's relative population living in urban

places with population over 5000.

v. The Federal Aid Urban System (FAU)

The FAU program was established by the Federal Aid Highway Act

of 1970 as a distinct system of urban roads. That is the FAU and

"C" systems conform to different project selection criteria, authori-

zations, and apportionment factors. The FAU system is intended to be

"so located as to serve the major centers of activity, and designed

taking into consideration the highest traffic volume corridors, and

1. For example, the Federal Aid Highway Act of 1970 authorized $50million for this purpose.

67

FACTORS EMPLOYED IN

APPORTIONING FEDERAL AID SYSTEM FUNDS

(as of December 31, 1972)

1. FEDERAL AID PRIMARY ("A" FUNDS)*

One third on land area

One third on total State population

One third on rural postal route mileage

2. FEDERAL AID SECONDARY ("B" FUNDS)*

One third on land area

One third on rural State population

One third on rural postal route mileage

3. PRIMARY AND SECONDARY URBAN EXTENSIONS ("C" FUNDS)*

Population in urban places over 5000

4. FEDERAL AID URBAN SYSTEM

Population in urbanized areas over 50,000

5. TOPICS

Population in urban places over 5000

6. FEDERAL AID INTERSTATE

Federal share of the estimated cost of completing the

the Interstate System in each State

* No State to receive less than one half of one percent of thetotal ABC apportionment

Table 11.2.3

68

CURRENT FACTORS EMPLOYED IN

APPORTIONING FEDERAL-AID SYSTEM FUNDS1

Pursuant to the Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973

1. FEDERAL AID PRIMARY ("A" FUNDS)*

One third on land**

One third on population of rural areas

One third on the mileage of intercity mail*;outes whereservice is performed by motor vehicles

2. FEDERAL AID SECONDARY"B"FUNDS***

Same as primary apportionment formula

*

3. PRIMARY AND SECONDARY URBAN EXTENSIONS ("C" FUNDS)

Population in urban places over 5000

4. FEDERAL AID URBAN SYSTEM

**

Population in urban places over 5000

5. FEDERAL AID INTERSTATE

Federal share of the estimated cost of completing theInterstate System in each State

* No State to receive less than one half of one percent of thetotal ABC apportionment

** Apportionment formula has changed from previous legislation

Table 11.2.4

69

the longest trips within such (urban) area."I

Authorizations from the IHTF are made every two years.2

Apportionment to States is on the basis of each State's relative

population living in urbanized areas (population over 50,000)

vi. Traffic Operations Projects to Increase Capacity and Safety

(TOPICS))3

The TOPICS program is intended to stimulate the construction

of projects "designed to reduce traffic congestion and to facilitate

the flow of traffic in the urban areas.4 Of all the Federal Aid

Systems, TOPICS projects are generally of the smallest scale. Exam-

ples of TOPICS improvements include grade separation of intersections,

widening of lanes, channelization of traffic, traffic control systems,

and loading and unloading ramps.

Authorization from the IHTF for TOPICS are made every two years.

Apportionments are made in the same basis as for the FAU system

(see Table 11.2.3).

vii. The Federal Aid Interstate System

The Interstate System (FAI) is different in several important

1. 103 (d), Subpart A, Title 23, United States Code.

2. For example, the 1970 Highway Act authorized $100 million foreach fiscal years 1972 and 1973

3. The TOPICS program was discontinued as of the beginning of fiscalyear 1974

4. 135 (a) Subpart A, Title 23, U.S.C. TOPICS was established bythe Federal Aid Highway Act of 1970

70

respects from the other components of the Federal Aid System.

First, the FAI is the only System that is close-ended in terms of

both total System mileage and required completion date. Current

legislation limits the mileage of the Interstate System to

41,200 miles,l and stipulates completion of the FAI by the end of

fiscal year 1979.2

Secondly, unlike the other Federal Aid Systems, the Bureau of

Public Roads played a major role in the selection of corridors for

future Interstate development. As early as 1944, a 41,000 mile

Interstate network (excluding urban sections) was established. Thus,

the major policy option exercised by the States was simply the pro-

gramming3 of Interstate investments on the approved network.

A third innovation of the Interstate System is in its method

of financing. The Federal/State matching ratio on the Interstate

is 90/10, compared with the 50/50 matching ratio on other Federal

Aid Systems. Interstate authorizations are established for the entire

1. As of December 31, 1972, total expenditures on completed Interstateprojects amounted to $49.3 billion, 65% of the 1972 estimatedcost of $76.3 billion for the entire Interstate system.

2. Future Federal Aid Highway Acts may extend this completion deadline.

3. In this context, programming refers to the scale of the projects(i.e. number of lanes), and the timing of Interstate investments.

4. The Federal Aid Highway Act of 1970 increased the Federal sharepayable on non-Interstate projects to 70% beginning with fiscalyear 1974. The new matching ratio also applies to funds unobli-gated from previous apportionments.

duraction of the FAI program. Thus unlike the biannual cycle for 71

other Federal Aid Systems, new Interstate Authorization levels are

set only when the duration of the Interstate program is extended.I

Finally, the method of Interstate apportionment differs from other

Federal Aid System apportionment in that it is based on the estimated

Federal share of the total cost to complete the FAI in each State,

rather than on State socio-economic characteristics (see table 11.2.3).

viii. Structural Revisions to the FAHP Incorporated in the

1973 Federal Aid Highway Act2

The Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973, signed into law on

August 13 of that year introduced perhaps the most sweeping policy

revisions since the inception of the Federal-Aid Highway Program in

1916. The revisions reflected the increasing awareness on the part

of Congress and various interest groups of the shortcomings of the

FAHP (see Section III.2.iii). In fact, Congressional debate on the

proposed measures carried past the end of the 1972 legislative session

representing the first time in more than two decades that a highway

bill was not signed on a biennial basis.

The majority policy revisions incorporated into the Act are:

- diversion of gracts from the Interstate Highway Trust Fund

to urban mass transit facilities are allowed for the first

1. For example, the 1973 Highway Act established FAI authorizationsfor 6 years covering 1974 through 1979.

2. Public Law 93-87. An excellent description of the specifics ofthe 1973 Act is contained in the pamphlet HIGHWAYS, SAFETY ANDTRANSIT: AN ANALYSIS OF THE -FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY ACT OF 1973,.published by the Highway Users Federation for Safety and Mobility,Washington, D.C.

72

time beginning in fiscal year 1975

- greater emphasis is placed on the upgrading of non-Inter-state systems

- significant expansion of the Federal-Aid Urban System iscalled for

- for the first time States are directed to channel Federalurban planning monies directly to authorized metropolitanarea planning agencies

- grants designated for construction on the Interstate Systemmay, under certain conditions be used instead as mass transitaid

- a major realignment of the Federal-Aid highway systems iscalled for. In addition, three new systems are established:Priority Primary Routes, the Special Urban High Density jrafficProgram, and Economic Growth Center Development Highways

The most significant message imparted by the Federal-Aid Highway

Act of 1973 is the increased flexibility incorporated into the

Federal-Aid Highway Program. Although the Act did not go to the

extreme of dropping all categorical restrictions on the use of Federal

aid (as embodied in S. 1693 - the Special Transportation Revenue

Sharing Act of 1969), several features of the 1973 legislation allow

1. The major thrust of the Federal-Aid highway system realignment isto redesignate routes eligible for Federal assistance on the basisof anticipated future functional usage. The greatest change effectedby the Act will be on the Federal Aid Secondary System where the636,000 miles of the 1972 System is expected to be reduced to275,000 miles (as reported in the Federal Highway Administration'sReport on Functional Classification, 1972). The intent here isto concentrate Federal aid on those segments of the nation's roadnetwork with the greatest regional significance. For a concisedescription of the characteristics of the three new Federal-Aidsystems, see the Highway Users Federation pamphlet (oo. cit.)

73

the States greater latitude in tailoring the use of Federal highway

aid to neet the particular needs of their highway and transit

investment program. The diversion provisions on the use of FAHP

grants for mass transit, the increase in the allowed fund transfer

between non-Interstate systems from 20% to 40% (see Section II.2.i),

and the recent increase (stipulated by the 1970 Act) in the Federal

share payable in all non-Interstate systems from 50% to 70% of

total project cost, all signal a relaxation in the specificity of the

categorical restrictions which characterized previous FAP legislation.

Despite the numerous innovations introduced in the 1973 Federal-

Aid Hinhway Act, the Interstate !irghway Trust Fund (tt!TF) continues to

serve as the primary vehicle of Federal highway finance. The IHTF is

a unique Federal finance program, not only by virtue of its magnitude

of expenditures, but because of the mechanics of its operation as

well. The next section will detail the operation of the Trust Fund.

74

11.3. The Mechanics of the Interstate Iliqhway Trust Fund

i. Program Structure

It is convenient to summarize the program structure of the

Interstate Highway Trust Fund in terms of the following major

characteristics: source of Federal funds, total expenditure levels,

authorization cycle, apportionnent method, matching provisions,

expenditure restrictions, local recipients of Federal funds, and

3ources of local matching funds.

)ource of Federal Funds

Since the 1956 Highway Act, all Federal disbursements for

expenditures on the Federal-Aid Systems have been made from the

Interstate Highway Trust Fund (ITF). The IHTF is an institutional

iechanisrn designed to serve as the respository for all earmarked

Federal user charges associated with road use.

The major sources of IHTF revenue are shown in table 11.3.1.

3y far the greatest contribution to the Trust Fund comes from the ex-

cise tax on gasoline. In calendar year 1970, for example, highway-

related consumption yielded over $3.67 billion, or 70% of the total

IHTF revenues (see table 11.3.2).

IHTF revenues have been growing at an average rate of 9.2%

through the late 1960's (fiscal years 1966-1971), currently yielding

)ver $5.5 billion dollars.

Total Expenditure Levels

The Federal-Aid Highway Program represents by far the largest

75

TRUST FUND REVENUE SOURCES

SOURCES

Motor Fuel

Trucks, buses, and trailers

Inner tubes

Tread rubber

Truck and bus parts

Lubricating oil

Vehicle use

TAX RATE

4 per gallon

10% of manufacturers wholesale price

10 per pound

5 per pound

8% of the manufacturers wholesaleprice

6 per gallon

$3.00 per 1,000 lbs. (gross vehicleweight) for trucks weighing morethan 26,000 lbs.

Source: page 56, HIGHWAY STATISTICS 1970,

Federal Highway Administration

Table 11.3.1

76

INTERSTATE HIGHWAY TRUST FUND

REVENUE BY SOURCE

CALENDAR YEAR 1970

Source Inount(billions of dollars)

Motor Fuel

Trucks, buses andtrailers

Inner Tubes

:lotor Vehicle Use

Parts and Accessories

Lubricating Oil

Tread Rubber

$3.673

.655

.585

.141

.085

.065

*028

5.232

Percent of Total

70.1

12.4

11.2

2.89.

1 .69.

1 .39.

0.69.

1.00%

Source: Tables FE-205, FE-206HIGHWAY STATISTICS 1970,Federal Hiqhway Administration

Table 11.3.2

77

Federal public works grant program. In fact, of the more than 500

categorical grant programs administered by the Federal government,

the FAHP ranks second (to the welfare program) in expenditure of

funds. The latest FAHP authorization allows for a total expenditure

o01 $16.7 billion dollars (over the three year period 1974-1976)

divided among the Federal Aid Systems as follows: $8.75 million FAI,

$3.42 billion FAU, Urban High Density Routes and urban extensions of

FP/FAS, $1.19 billion FAS, and $2.127 billion FAP. Authorization

levels over the 10 year period 1961-1971 are shown in Table 11.3.3.

Expenditure Restrictions

Federal-Aid Highway Program funds are restricted to expendi-

ture on preliminary engineering,I right-of-way acquisition, and

construction of Federal-Aid Systen roads. Federal disbursements on

each Federal-Aid System are limited to the amounts specifically appor-

tioned with the exception that States may reapportion up to 40% of

their funds for any one System to any other System. 2

1. Preliminary engineering includes surveys and other elements of alocation study, and detailed designs and other plans, specifica-tions and estimates covering the construction on a selected location.

2. It's interesting to note that as of 1972, only 11 isolated casesof reapportionment have been exercised by the States. The reluc-tance to transfer funds among systems is partly explained by theflexibility in employing FAHP grants. For example, "C" projectsmay be funded from "A", "B", or "C" funds, without the need forformal reapportionment.

78

INTERSTATE HIGHWAY TRUST FUND

RECEIPTS AND AUTHORIZATIONS

1961-1971

REVENUES(in billionsof dollars)

2.799

2.956

3.293

3.539

3.670

3.924

4.455

4.428

4.690

5.469

5.725

AUTHORIZATIONS 1

(in billions ofdollars)

2.725

3.125

3.325

3.550

3.675

3.800

4.000

4.400

4.800

5.425

5.425

FISCAL CONTROL TOTALS{tin billions of dollars)

4.769

5.000

4.600

Sources: (1) pp. 11-153, FEDERAL LAWS, REGULATIONS

MATERIAL RELATING TO THE FEDERAL HIGHWAY

ADMINISTRATION, FHWA, 1971.

(2) TABLE 1, PROGRNI PROGRESS, FHWA memo dated

1/19/73

Table 11.3.3

Funds administered by the Bureau of Public Roads

YEAR

1961

1962

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

1971

79

Local Recipients of Federal Funds

The States are the sole recipients of Federal Highway capital

grants. No money is directly channeled to lower units of government,

although States are free to enter into agreement with their subdivi-

sions to financially cooperate on particular Federal-Aid projects.

In any event, the States maintain sole responsibility relative to

plans, specifications and estimates (PS & E), surveys, contract

awards, design, inspection, and construction of all projects on the

Federal -Aid Systems.

Authorization Cycle

FAHP funds for all Federal-Aid Systems except the FAI are

normally authorized every two years.1 These authorizations are

included in a biennial Highway Act enacted at least one-half year

before the States are allowed to use Federal funds. For example, the

Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1970, passed December 31, 1970, authorized

I11TF expenditures for fiscal years 1972 (beginninr July 1, 1971)

and 1973.

Interstate authorizations are determined for the duration of

the FAI program. The Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973 authorized FAI

funding through FY 1979.

Apportionment Method

Apportionment refers to the amount of Federal Aid made avail-

able to each State for each of the Federal-Aid Systems. As shown in

1. The Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973 departed from the biennialpattern of highway legislation. This Act authorized funds for threefiscal years.

80

Tables 11.2.3 and 11.2.4, each Federal-Aid System is associated

with a specific apportionment formula, expressed in terms of

State demographic and geographic characteristics. Ordinarily, the

apportionment of IHTF funds among States would be derived directly

from the approved authorization levels. However, between 1969 and

1973, the Office of Management and Budget (0MB) imposed restrictions

on Federal highway expenditure levels, in an effort to curb govern-

ment expenditures. Consequently, the amounts apportioned to the

States in these years were actually derived from the 0MB-imposed

Federal highway fiscal control totals. (see Table 11.3.3)

Matching Provisions

The Federal-Aid Interstate Systems is characterized by a

90/10 Federal/State matching ratio, All other Federal-Aid Systems

are subject to a 50/50 matching ratio. States Hith a large piblic

land holding are entitled to a larger Federal share of highway funds,

as determined by a "sliding scale" formula which increases the Federal

share in proportion to the amount of State land in the national

public domain. Thirteen States qualify for an increased Federal

highway share as shown in Table 11.3.4.

Sources of Local Matching Funds

Although all levels of government assume some responsibility

for collecting and disbursing funds for highway-related activities,

the States are by far the largest contributor in the FAIP. For

example, in calendar year 1970, the States' highway expenditures

81

VARIABLE MATCHING PERCENTAGE

FOR STATES WITH MORE THAN

FIVE PERCENT OF PUBLIC LAND

Federal Share Federal Share on otherState on Interstate Federal-Aid Systems

,laska -------- 95.00 (max)

Arizona 94.39 71.96

California 91.62 58.09

Colorado 91.31 56.57

Idaho 92.30 61.50

lontana 91.31 56.54

:evada 95.00 (ceiling 83.740.0level)837

:lew Mexico 92.58 62.91

Oregon 92.38 61.90

South Dakota 91.71 55.83

Utah 94.88 74.42

Uashington 90.71 53.54

Vyoning 92.87 64.36

Source: flurch, P.1., HIGHWAY REVENUE AND

EXPENDITURE POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES

Table 11.3.4

1. Other States subject to 90/10 Interstate share, and 50/50share on other Federal-Aid Systems.

82(10.55 billion), were greater than the combined highway expenditures of

the Federal government (4.96 billion), county governments (1.43 billion),

and municipal governments (2.39 billion).

3esides the sheer magnitude of their financial commitment to

the FAHP, the States play a central role in highway finance for two

more reasons. First, Federal grants-in-aid for highways are received,

programmed, and expended by States. In this context, Federal highway

"expenditures" can be considered as State highway revenue. Second,

all States have estab. ;hed some form of shared tax or grant-in-aid

mechanism with their civil subdivisions. As such, the State influ-

ences the expenditure pattern of the counties and municipalities.

State highway revenue derive from four major sources: Federal

highway grants, State taxes on motor fuel and motor vehicles, pro-

ceeds from bond sales, and appropriations from State general tax re

revenues.1 Motor fuel/vehicle tax revenue is the largest component

of State highway revenue, yielding about 60% (nationwide average) of

total SHD revenue in 1970. Highway bond sales represent varying

degrees of importance in different States. At one extreme are the

11 States that have not resorted to bond financing of either toll or

free roads (see Table 11.3.5) over the ten year period 1961-1970.

At the other extreme are 5 States which have established debt financing

1. In addition, several States derive revenue from the collection oftolls. For the purposes of this thesis, activities concerningtoll facility construction and operation will not be discussed.

83

STATE HIGHWAY FINANCE:

HIGHWAY BOND SALES, 1961-1971

Category I: States which have not issued bonds for toll or free roads

Arkansas

Colorado

Idaho

Iowa

Kansas

Category II: States which have

California

Illinois

Mi ssouri

iontana

levada

South Dakota

Utah

Wyoming

issued bonds solely for toll roadconstructi on

Indiana Texas

Louisiana Virginia

Category III: States which have issued (free and toll) hiqhwaybonds at irreqular intervals

Kentucky

Nai ne

Maryl and

Michigan

Minnesota

Oregon

Pennsylvania

South Carolina

Mitsissippi

Nebraska

New Hampshire

New Jersey

New riexi co

Washington

West Virgina

Wisconsin

Table 11.3.5

New York

North Carolina

North Dakota

Ohio

Oklahoma

Tennessee

Vermont

Alaska

Arizona

Florida

Georgia

Hawaii

84

STATE HIGHWAY FINANCE:

HIGHWAY BOND SALES, 1961-1971 (contd.)

Category IV: States which have issued free road bonds every year

Alabama

Connecticut

Del aware

Massachusetts

Rhode Island

Table 11.3.5 (contd.)

85

as a regular component of their highway finance program. These

States (see Table 11.3.5) have issued free road bonds in each of

the ten years 1961-1970. The remainder of the States have resorted

to bond financing on an irregular basis, presumably to meet perceived

short-term highway "needs" that could not be financed out of current

revenue sources.

Appropriations to State Highway Department programs from State

general tax revenues do not represent significant amounts of money,

nor are these transfers performed on a regular basis for the great

majority of the States. The notable exceptions to this rule are the

so-called general fund States: Delaware, New Jersey, New York and

Rhode Island. In these four States, all highway user tax revenues

are deposited in the State General Treasury, and thus technically all

appropriations for highway activities come from a non-earmarked

general fund. In practice, even in these States, yearly highway appro-

priations tend to nearly equal highway user tax revenues. For the

remainino States, all highway user revenues are set aside in State

Trust Funds, earmarked exclusively for highway-related expenditures.

Of the 46 "Trust Fund States" 28 States are subject to anti-diversion

Constitutional Amendments (see Figure 11.3.1). The remaininn States

have either established expenditure restrictions by State Statute or

simply through historical practice.

STATES HAVING ANTI-DIVERSION CONSTITUTIONAL AMENDMENTS

"*Fly

-States having anti-diversion constitutional amendments - 28

Figure 11.3.1

wat

I

1

Irv ar

--f I F-4 I

-1I LA I F-

I F--l I

-L r771If[_-

T

*. I t:!J f EfTEI rim H I FH r-H+r4'

IF-4 I RIL

V"lr

L wis

644mlj4 -1 1 go -THI

%Ora-

PAI P41.1a -Um I F-i I ILL

U-AT I F- wall= w DC L

7-L COL4-T V- IHIi =: I -i I I

I MH 1 -41 1 1

J 1-i I H.11 NCI -T L-

0 kX A121C sc

LA

t

-07mH

87

ii. TimeLag Structure

From the time that highway-related revenue is deposited in

the Federal Treasury account for the IHTF, to the time States

receive Federal reimbursements for completed work on Federal-Aid

Systems, Trust Fund monies pass through a series of stages at the

Federal and State level.

These stages can be defined as:

authorization - the Congressional allotment of Federal funds to

each of the Federal-Aid Systems

apportionment - the division of Federal funds on each of the

Federal-Aid Systems among each of the 50 states

obligation - a contracted agreement between a State and the

Federal governnent to commit funds to a particular

Federal-Aid System project

reimbursement - the actual transfer of Federal funds to a State

based upon a State's current billing of contracted

highway construction

In practice, there is a contracted stream of funds passing

between the IITF and the States. However, the actual reimbursement

from a given annual authorization nay take as long as 15 years.I In

order to trace the dynamics of the intergovernmental transfer of

highway funds, we represent the lag structure in five distinct steps.

1. That is, a State may receive a reimbursement from funds authorized15 years prior to the fund transfer.

88

Lag 1:Authorization-to-Aportionment

As previously noted, Congressional authorization of highway

funds precedes apportionment by at least six months.

Lai 2:_Apportionment-to-Programming

This lag relates to the time required by States to develop

highway programs for submittal to BPR review. The duration of this

lag is somewhat uncertain, varying for different project types, and

from State-to-State (for a given project type). Since the level of

Federal highway aid has been nrowing at a fairly steady rate since

the inception of the IHTF, States are well aware of the amounts of

rrants they can expect to receive. Accordingly, the States have tried

to "keep one step ahead" of the apportionment process by developing

programs containing enough projects to fully obligate their apportion-

ment levels.

In practice however, States have encountered varying degrees

of corrunity opposition to proposed projects. The result has been a

lag between the initial availability of Federal-Aid apportionments,

and subnittal of an approved program of Federal-Aid System projects.

Friedlaender has estimated that the apportionment-to-programming

lag was usually on the order of four to six weeks in the late 1950's.

In recent years, the increasing difficulty in negotiating community

1. Friedlaender, Ann, F., "The Federal Highway Program as a PublicWorks Tool," in Ando, A. et al, STUDIES IN ECONOMIC STABILIZATION,The Brookings Institute, 1968.

89

acceptance of highway projects has led to a significant increase in

the duration of the apportionment-to-programming lag. In fact, there

has been one case where a State,1 was unable to program its highway

apportionment before the deadline for obligating Federal funds was

reached.

Each State is given two years beyond the year for which funds

are authorized to obligate its highway apportionment. Figures 11.3.2

and II.3.3 show that most States are, in recent years programming

projects from previous years' apportionments. Figure 11.3.2 presents

the frequency distribution of State obligations for Interstate appor-

tionments. Midway through fiscal year 1973, four States were still

obligating 1971 funds, nine States were obligating 1972 funds, and

the remaining thirty eight States had obligated some portion of their

current apportionment.2 Taking the nation as a whole, only 17% of the

then current Interstate apportionment had been obligated by December 31,

1972.

Figure 11.3.3 shows the frequency distribution of ABC apportion-

ments obligated as of December 31, 1972. Relative to the Interstate

program, a higher percentage of current ABC apportionments have been

obligated. Only one State was still obligating 1971 funds, twelve

1. Actually, the "State" was ashington, D.C., which for the purposesof highway apportionments receives Federal funds in the same manneras States.

2. States always obligate their "oldest" apportionments first. Thus,any State obligating current apportionments has already completelyobligated its previous apportionments.

Frequency Distribution of Interstate Obligations

Number of States ObligatingVarious Percentages of TheirInterstate Annortionments

10

10 20 30 40percent

50 60 70obligated

80 90100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100percent obligated percent obligated

1971 Apportionments 1972 Apportionments 1973 Apportionments

Figure 11.3.2

U.S.Average

9

8

7

6

5

4

3

2

Frequency Distribution of ABC Obligations

Number of States ObligatingVarious Percentages of TheirABC Apportionments

U.S. Average3 -------------

2A

8

1_________

27 _______________

NN

10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80percent obligated percent obligated

1971 Apportionments 1972 Apportionments

90 100.10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100percent obligated

1973 Apportionments

Figure 11.3.3

ko

92

States were obligating 1972 funds, and the remaining thirty nine

States were obligating current ABC apportionments. The U.S.

average of ABC apportionments obligated by mid-fiscal year 1973

was 32%. It may be concluded from these two figures that the appor-

tionment-to-programming lag is greater for the FAI program than for

the ABC program. Moreover, it is apparent that this lag has lengthened

significantly since Friedlaender's estinate in the late 1950's.

Several States have been unable to program potentially funded Federal-

Aid System projects for 2 1/2 years or loncier. The nationwide average

lag between apportionment and programming appears to he on the otder

of ten months.

Lag 3: Pronramming-to-Approval

Following a State's submission of a highway project to the

BPR, the District Engineer reviews the plans, specifications End

estimates detailed in the State aprlication. The review process can

take anywhere from one month to more than a year, depending on the

complexity and scale of the project. For example, a simple rural

resurfacing project may be approved within one or two morths, while

a large Interstate section with several complex drainage and [ridge

structure requirements would take several months to review.

The culmination of the BPR review is an approved project agree-

ment, allowinr States to obligate the use of Federal funds.

Lag 4: Obliiation-to-Contract Lag

An obligation does not involve an actual flow of funds. At

this point, a State has merely obtained the approval of the BPR to

93

seek bids on an approved project. The State now proceeds to enter

the project into its ongoing construction program. The State's

decision as to when to advertise a contract for construction is in-

fluenced by its capital budgeting status. Assuming a State advertises

a contract immediately upon signing a project agreement with the BPR,

there is usually a minimum of a three to four week period before

sealed Lids are opened. After the low bidder is determined, the

State must obtain the BPR's final approval on the contractor's quali-

fications. Thus, the minimum lag between initial BPR approval, and

the finel signing of a construction is typically on the order of one

month.

Lag 5: Contracts-to-Federal Reimbursement

ITF monies are disbursed to States on a reimbursement basis.

Thus, the final lag in this process involves the time required for the

contractors to mobilize their work force and submit the first month's

expense voucher, and for the State to verify that the work has been

done, and submit a record of expenses to the BPR office in Washington.

The lag here could be anywhere from one to two months.

Summary: La9 Structure on the Federal-Aid Highway Program

Figure 11.3.4 traces the FAHP lags from initial Congressional

authorization to the time that Federal funds actually enter the income

stream as construction expenditures. Two alternatives sequences are

shown, one with a total lag of one year, and the other with a two

year total lag. The major source of variation between these two lag

FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY PROGRAM LAG STRUCTURE

1- ~pzproximatJy -A yr

6 moa. II rI

Figure 11.3.4

I l. yrsI I I I I

z yrs

Leoendrnl AtlorisnrioM W[ A Inii'oV oj conract

A Eim1( ieam rsrnenf frm I HT

H Fh3rammir1 O f cc4-.F id &prem consfructoN ®...G Lae vou rae ,A )Fi flpoual oj AnS

r

95sequences is in the apportionment-to-programming lag, which may

take anywhere from one month to several years.

It should be noted that the total authorization-to-reimbursement

lag for those States who are still programming prior years' FAHP

funds, will generally be longer than the lag for States who are pro-

gramming current apportionments. In other words, States with a

relatively large unobligated portion of FAHP funds will not react

fully and immediately to changes in present FAHP apportionment levels.

Taking the nation as a whole, total highway obligations have

been running fairly close to the OMB-imposed fiscal control limitation

on IHF expenditure levels, as shown in figure 11.3.5. The total lag

between project approval (obligation), and Federal reimbursement is

represented by a horizontal line connecting the obligation and expen-

diture lines on figure 11.3.5. For example, at the point marked A,

this lag appears to be approximately 18 months.

96

FEDERAL-AID HIGHWAY PROGRAMINTERSTATE HIGHWAY TRUST FUND

EXPENDITURES AND RECEIPTS

Di

26

24

22

20

18

16

4

2

*IS71/65 FY 1q7o 7/1/70 FY --197-1 7/-1/71 F)Y -197Z 7/1/72 FY Y-Iq73 7/1/73

0=43, 847.1Source: FHWA Memo Dated 1/19/73,

"Progress of the FederalAid Highway Program"

Figure 11.3.5

Allars (millions)

.01elol --0 -

/.11

0

97

iii. Aspects of Trust Fund Taxation

The previous sections have detailed the mechanics of the

Feleral-Aid Highway Program as it has evolved since the early

1900's. While the focus of this chapter - in fact of the entire

thesis - is an investigation of how States react to the availability

of Federal highway grants, an underlying issue that deserves some

attention is the tz.xation conventions associated with the Interstate

Highway Trust Fund.

It is somewhat paradoxical that while the IHTF has come under

serious scholarly and Congressional scrutiny in recent years, the

use of Trusts Funds as a mechanism to finance transport facilities

has been introduced to other modal areas. In particular, the Airport

andi Airway Developnent Act of 19702 established tickeL tax-based

trist funds to finance the development of aviation facilities, and

sinilar proposals have been raised in regard to the inland waterway

system.

Perhaps the strongest argument in favor of a trust fund finan-

cing approach is in facilitating the orderly long-range planning and

implementation of public facilities by guaranteeing a stable level of

Federal financial assistance. Nonetheless, the practice of establish-

ing a set of earmarked user charges in the use of transport facilities

1. As manifest by the prolonged debate over passage of the 1973Federal-Aid Highway Act.

2. Public Law 91-258, Titles I and II, enacted May 21, 1970.

98

represents an intervention into the private market sector, and

carries with it impacts on equity, efficiency and redistribution of

income. This section will attempt to evaluate the economic consequen-

ces of the IHIF with particular attention paid to the aspects of

trust fund taxation.

Depending on one's viewpoint, the revenues raised for the

Interstate Highway Trust Fund are variously referred to as indirect

excise taxes, user charges, or prices for the use of the publically

provided road system. Some unambiguous definitions of these and

related key terms are essential if this analysis is to proceed on a

conmon ground. 1

De'initions of the Revenue Terms

Prices - a cost-based charge for the consumption of a scarceresource

User Charges - a revenue-raising levy, not necessarily based onthe real economic cost incurred in producing a(public) good

Taxes - a pure revenue measure which bears no explicit relationto the cost of providing public goods.2

In general, a tax is associated with a pure revenue objective,

an I evaluated in terms of its regressiveness/progressiveness (the

relative burdci of the levy on various income classes). User charges

1. The definitions presented here are drawn from "The Public FinanceAspects of the Transportation Sector," A Staff Paper prepared bythe Office of Policy and Plans Development, U.S. Department ofTransportation.

2. In fact, the inherent nature of a pure public good (e.g. nationaldefense) renders an explicit pricing system infeasible.

99

are cornonly associated with an equity goal - the concept that

users should pay a fair share for their consumption of a service and

prices are normally related to the concept of economic efficiency.

The importance of these distinctions between taxes, prices and user

charges is more than a mere semantic issue. The fundamental question

relates to goals of the Interstate Highway Trust Fund revenue measures.

For if the IHTF is to be viewed as a price system, then those prices

must be justified on the basis of Vie real costs incurred by an

individual user (driver) of the Federal-Aid Syteras. Conversely, if

the IHTF revenue measures are to serve as user charges, then a valid

concern is whether those charges meet an equity criterion. Finally,

to view the IHTF as a pure revenue mechanism raises the question of

the relative regressiveness of the revenue measures.

It would be difficult to argue the case for the IHTF as a

mechanism to foster efficient use of scarce highway resources. No

claim was originally made that the Trust Fund was to be financed

through a price (as previously defined) system.1 The revenue sources

(see Table 11.3.1) simply represented a pragmatic means to provide an

assured stream of revenues for highway construction.

Because the IHTF revenue sources have the properties of (excise)

1. Referring to Table 11.3.1, it is clear that the revenue sourcesof the IHTF do not fit our definition of prices. The levies ontires, tread rubber, oil, new trucks, buses and trailers, partsand accessories, gasoline, diesel and special fuels may be con-sidered as either user charges or (excise) taxes.

100

taxes and user charges, it is important to assess the impacts of the

program in terms of income redistribution and equity.

Income Redistributive Properties of the IHTF

The income redistributive properties of the IHTF can be viewed

in terms of either an individual driver, or in terms of the fifty

States. In the former case, we are concerned with the burden of the

IHTF revenue measures on an individual driver relative to his income.

In the latter case, the focus is on the amounts of FAHP aid received

by each State relative to their per capita income. In either case

the IHTF revenue measures may be defined as:

progressive - a wealthier individual (State) pays more (receivesless) in both absolute and proportional terms thana poorer individual (State)

proportional - a wealthier individual (State) pays more (receivesless) in only absolute terms than a poorer indivi-dual (State)

regressive - a wealthier individual (State) pays less than or anequal amount (receives more than or an equal amount) asa poorer individual (State).

In general, excise taxes tend to be proportional, or in some

casesI even regressive. This is true as long as consumption of an

item by individuals tends to grow less than proportionately with

1. Excise taxes will be regressive if the taxed item is an inferiorgood - i.e. an individual's consumption of the item decreases withincreasing income. For a general note on the regressivity ofexcise taxes see Due, J.F. and A.F. Friedlaender, GOVERNMENT FINANCE,Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Fifth Edition, 1973, page 384.

101

increases in personal income. Thus, for an evaluation of the

rergressivity of the IHTF revenue measures, in terms of the burden

on the individual driver, the issue is to determine the relative case

of the automobile (and thus the relative amount of the IHTF levy) by

individuals with differing income levels.

Ta!le 111.3.6 displays the distribution of person miles by

income class anr' type of transport based on a 1967 nationwide survey.

The survey was restricted to trips involving overnight stops away from

home and/or journeys in excess of 100 miles each way. Thus, we may

infer that the data is indicative of travel patterns for vacation ani

business travel rather than journey-to-work travel. The most striking

finding indicated by the table is that the percent of households in

each income class using auto for vacation or business travel tends

to decrease with increasing household income. Thus for example, while

auto accounted for 06% of the total person miles of travel by house-

holds with income $6000 - 7499, the corresponding figure for the

highest income group ($15,000 and over) is only 51.7%. The difference

in the intensity of auto usage between income groups for trips in

excess of 100 miles derives primarily from the marked increase in the

patronage of commercial air service by higher income households. The

choice of the air mode varies from a low of 8.5% of total person miles

of travel by the lowest household income category to a high of over

41% commercial air patronage1 by the highest income households.

1. The percentages reported here do not indicate the frequency withwhich one mode or another is chosen, but only the percent of totalmiles traveled on each mode. Thus one transcontinental car trip mayaccount for more mileage than dozensFf auto trips of a shorter distance.

102

Distribution of Person-Miles by Income

and Type of Transport

(For Overnioht Journeys and/or Trips in Excess of 100 Miles One Way)

Percent of Households in Each Income Class Choosing Each Mode

Source: Bureau of the Census, 1967 CENSUSOF TRANSPORTATION, Volume 1,July, 1970, pp. 35-36 (Table 12)

Table 11.3.6

Annual Household Primary Node of ravelIncome Auto Bus rain Coimercial Air Combinations and Other

Under $4000 79.0 6.1 4.4 8.5 2.0

$4000-5999 84.8 2.8 2.6 9.0 0.8

$6000-7499 86.0 1.0 1.9 9.4 1.7

$7500-9999 82.9 1.2 1.4 13.3 1.2

$l0,000-14,999 74.8 0.7 1.1 21.1 2.3

$15,000 and over 51.7 0.6 1.6 41.1 5.0

Income notreported 74.0 1.7 j25 18.6 3.2

All income groups 77.3 1.9 2.0 16.8 2.3

103

The data is indicative, if not conclusive of the phenomenon

that consumption of auto travel for relatively long trips may be

considered an inferior good. Further insight into this question is

provided by Table 11.3.7 which combines the modal split information

of Table 11.3.6 with data describing total person miles of travel

across all modes by income class. Tie last column of this table lists

the auto person-miles per household as a function of household income.

The pattern that emerges is that auto travel per household increases

yith income, but less than proportionately, except for the highest

income level where auto travel decreases sharply. Note that travel

by all modes increases uniformly with (column 4, Table 11.3.7)

income, indicative that vacation/business trips per se are superior

economic goods. Nonetheless, auto travel exhibits the characteristics

of decreasing patronage with increasing income.

Since the IHTF is (partly) financed through an excise tax on the

sale of casoline, the tax burden on an individual household is directly

re"ated to the intensity of auto usage. Given the above findings on

the pattern of auto usage for relatively long trips, it is clear that

IHTF taxation is regressive.

A similar pattern emerges for home-to-work auto trips. Data

supporting the contention that IHTF taxation is regressive with

respect to commuting is found in Tables 11.3.8 and 11.3.9. The

first table displays the modal split of home-to-work trips as a

Distribution of Auto Travel Patterns by Household Income Level

(For Overnight Journeys and/or Trips in Excess of 100 Miles One Way)

Source: Bureau of the Census, 1967

CENSUS OF TRANSPORTATION,

Volume 1, July, 1970, pp. 17, 35-46

Table 11.3.7

Annual Household Number of Number of Person-Miles Percentage of Auto PersonIncome Households Person-Miles Per Household Person-Miles Miles Per

(Millions) (Billions) Per Year by Auto Household

Under $4000 7.3 35.0 4790 79.0 3790

$4000-5999 6.8 46.0 6770 84.8 5740

$6000-7499 5.2 42.9 8270 36.0 7110

$7500-8999 6.5 58.6 9020 82.9 7490

$l0,000-14,999 5.7 65.9 11570 74.8 8660

$15,000 and over 2.6 34.8 13400 51.7 6920

Income not reported 4.0 28.6 7170 74.0 5300

All income groups 38.1 311.8 8180 77.0 6300

__

Relationship of Mode Choice and Household Income

for home-to-Work Trips

_,utombi_____Mode of Transportation

Automobil e ___

Annual Househol d Driver Passenrer Total Public Walking OtherIn comQ Transportation

Under $3000 25.5 20.1 45.7 12.8 11.9 29.6

$3000-3999 29.7 18.8 48.5 12.5 12.7 26.3

$4000-4999 34.7 21.4 56.1 11.6 7.0 25.3

$5000-5999 45.2 13.5 63.7 9.4 5.5 21.4

$6000-7499 46.4 20.3 67.2 6.9 5.3 20.6

$7500-9999 49.8 20.5 70.3 5.9 4.5 19.3

$10,000-14,999 54.9 19.2 74.1 5.1 2.9 17.9

$15,000 and over 58.8 16.4 75.2 6.5 3.3 15.0

All 48.4 19.1 67.5 7.2 5.0 20.3

Percent of employedjpersons in each household income groupby mode of home-to-work transportation (1%69)

Source: U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration,NATIONWIDE PERSONAL TRANSPORTATION STUDY, HOME-TO-WORK TRIPS ANDTRAVEL, Report No. 8, August, 1973.

Table 11.3.80m-

106

Relationship of Average Commute Time for

Hone-to-Work Auto Trips and Household Income

Annual Household

Income

Average Commute Time

(in minutes)

Figures represent 1970 data

Source: U.S. Department of Transportation,Federal Highway Administration,NATIONWIDE PERSONAL TRANSPORTATIONSURVEY, HOnE-TO-WORK TRIPS AND TRAVEL,Report No. 8, August, 1972

Table 11.3.9

Under $3000 18

$3000-3999 18

t4000-4999 20

$5000-5999 22

$0000-7499 19

$7500 -9999 20

$10,000-14,999 20

$15,000 and over 21

Pll income groups 20

107

function of income, based on a 1969-1970 nationwide survey.1 As

might be expected, the choice of auto for the journey-to-work tends

to increase as household income increases. However, it should be

noted that this increase is less than proportional: the range in

household income varies by a factor of more than five to one, while

auto patronage increase by only slightly more than two to one.

Sore indication of the average trip distance for journeys-to-

work by income groups is given by Table 11.3.9. The Nationwide

Personal Transportation Survey did not directly report on the varia-

tion in trip distance by income group. However, it is apparent from

the striking uniformity of corruting travel time across different

income groups, that travel distance for journeys-to-work cannot vary

appreciably across income classes.

The conclusion from these data is that the total auto mileage

devoted to journey-to-work trips (and thus the corresponding burden

imposed by the IHTF tax levies) increases less than proportionately

to increases in household income. Accordingly, with respect to this

trip purpose, the IHTF represents proportional tax system.

In addition to the income redistributive consequences of the

IHTF revenue measures on individual drivers, the FHAP effects on

explicit redistribution of income among States. We refer to the fact

1. The Uationwide Personal Transportation Survey conducted by theBureau of the Census.

Comparison of Estimated State Payments to the Highway Trust Fund with State Receipts fromthe Highway Trust Fund and Federal-Aid Apportionments, Fiscal Years 1957-1970

Estimated Pa entstothe H wa

rust und(Millions of Dollars)

Federal AidApportionments

For Each Dollar the StatePaidiito the Higwa TrustTrust fnd 75pto7/70,State was Apportioned

State PerCapita In-come 1963

Al abaaArizonaArkansasCaliforniaColoradoConnecticutDelawareFloridaGeorgiaIdahoIllinoisIndianaIowaKansasKentuckyLouisianaMaineMarylandMassachusettsMichiganMinnesotaMississippiMissouriMontanaNebraska

833451539

4,766561624143

1.5001 ,152

2242,3581,372

780674744800258768

1,0832,089

938555

1,258235448

1,006682539

4,102647692180

1,0321,008

3612,5081,188

747613930

1,124291799

1,0731,7781,157

6381,279

627463

$1.211.511.00

.861.151.111 .26

.69

.881.61.1.06

.87.96.91

1.251.401.131.04

.99

.851.231.151.022.671.03

166922201625**29932479*31132994*2141 **1878**20452911*2467229923981840183919572678*2774**25812365*14342360*22632273

Source: Federal Highway Administration, 1972 National Highway Needs Study Project C-i.

Table 11.3.10C)

State

Comparison of Estimated State Payments to the Highway Trust Fund with State Receipts fromthe Highway Trust Fund and Federal-Aid Apportionments, Fiscal Years 197-1970 (Continued)

Estimated Payments Federal Aid For Each Dollar the State State Perto the Highway Apportionments Paid into the Highwa Trust Capjgjncome

Trust Fund Fund 7/S to 7/7, State 1963(Millions of Dollars) was Aportioned

Nevada 155 352 $2.27 3235*New Hampshire 169 246 1.46 2343*New Jersey 1,514 1,238 .82 2960New Mexico 340 583 1.71 2048New York 2,897 2,718 .94 3009North Carolina 1,234 719 .58 1801**North Dakota 176 349 1.98 1999Ohio 2,442 2,689 1.10 2508*Oklahoma 776 668 .86 1990**Oregon 593 820 1.38 2471*Pennsylvania 2,424 2,311 .95 2437Rhode Island 185 251 1.36 2510*South Carolina 606 494 .82 1576**South Dakota 207 428 2.07 1908Tennessee 939 1,156 1.23 1772Texas 3,192 2,579 .81 2102**Utah 276 601 2.18 2210Vermont 110 320 2.91 2013Virginia 1,056 1,369 1.30 2093Washington 804 995 1.24 2618*West Virginia 394 804 2.04 1778Wisconsin 963 706 .73 2375Wyoming 147 469 3.19 2412** States with higher than average per capita income who are apportioned more than they contribute to

the Trust Fund** States with lower than average per capita income who are apportioned less than they contribute to the

Trust Fund

Table HI.3.10 (contd.)

a'0

110that the various apportionment formulas described in section 11.2,

determining the relative amounts of Federal-Aid System grants to be

given to the States result in several States contributing more to the

IHTF than they receive in the form of grants (and vice versa).

Table 11.3.10 indicates the extent of income redistribution

resulting from the Federal-Aid Highway Program apportionment formulas.

Of the thirty-one States which were apportioned more than they con-

tributed to the Trust Fund (over the period 1957-1970), fourteen

had higher than average per capita income.1 Conversely, the same

amount as they contributed to the IHTF, eight had a lower than average

per capita income. Both of these instances are examples of perverse

income distribution. It is not surprising to find that the formulas

used to apportion FAHP grants result in several cases (22 out of the 48'

mainland States) of States with higher than average per capita incomes

receiving proportionately higher income transfers in the form of highway

grants (and vice versa), since the enabling legislation did no

consider income distribution as an espoused goal of the Federal-Aid

Highway Program.2 None of the apportionment formulas described in

Tables 11.2.3 and 11.2.4 take account of per capita income, fiscal

capacity tax effort, or similar measures of State Wealth. Nonetheless,

as has been shown, the fact that a Federal grant program does not

l.The average per capita income in 1963 was $2287. Income data isshown for 1963 because this represents the meddle of the 1957-1970sample period for which apportionment data is presented.

2. For a good discussion of the debate over the selection of factorsto be incorporated into apportionment formulas, see Burch, P. op.cit.

111

address an explicit income redistribution goal, does not imply that

the program will be distributionally neutral.I

In summary, two aspects of the income redistributive impacts

of the Interstate Highway Trust Fund have been explored. First,

the excise taxes used to finance the IHTF tend to be regressive or

proportional, depending on individual drivers' trip purposes. Secondly,

the formulas employed in apportioning IHTF revenues among States

result in a mildly progressive redistribution of income. One more

point should be stressed with regard to the latter conclusion. The

low value of the correlation coefficient between per capita income

and apportionments (see footnote 1 below) reflects the fact that

there are nearly as many States exhibiting perverse income distribu-

tion with respect to the FAHP grants, as there are States emblematic

of the "commonly accepted" goals of income distribution. 2

1Taken as a whole, the FAHP appears to be mildly progressive. The

correlation coefficient between apportionments and per capita incomein 1970 was -0.1965. However, it is still the case that for morethan 20 States, the FAHP results in perverse income distribution.

2It should be noted that the Federal government does administer

several grant programs -- most notably the general revenue sharingprogram, and the welfare grant program -- which are structured toaccomplish explicit income distribution goals. Pursuant to the Stateand Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972 (general revenue sharing),States with lower per capita income and/or higher tax effort receiveproportionately higher Federal aid. And in the welfare grant programs,States with relatively large numbers of welfare recipients (and thuspresumably those States with relatively low per capita income), receiveproportionately higher amounts of Federal welfare assistance.

112Equity Considerations in Administering the IHTF

The issue of equity deserves some attention if for no other rea-

sen than that it has been the primary argument espoused by proponents

of continuing the trust fund approach to financing roads. This justi-

fication follows the general principle that those who use roads often

should ppy more than those who use them little. The obvious extension

of this principle -- often referred to as the benefit principle -- is

that those who do not use the road system (e.g. transit patrons) should

neither pay for, nor receive aid fron a highway trust fund. Although

the concept of equity inevitably involves the vagaries inherent in

deciding on what constitutes a "fair" distribution of the tax burden,

some general conclusions on the equity characteristics of the

Interstate Highway Trust Fund can nonetheless be established.

On an elementary level, it is indisputably true that the excise

tax on gasoline sales guarantees a rough measure of equity in that

those who drive more pay more. But the more sophisticated treatment

of equity examines both aspects of IHTF taxation: the distribution

of the tax burden and the distribution of benefits derived from the

IHTF. It is not s-fficient to conclude that the IHTF assures equity

based only on examination of the revenue side of the IHTF. Since

Federal highway grants are restricted to expenditure on roads comprising

the Federal Aid System, a more rigorous test of equity would require

that the tax burden assessed on individual users be distributed

according to the intensity of their use of the Federal-Aid System.

If all people drove in exactly the same proportion on the different

Federal-Aid highways as well as on roads off the Federal-Aid System,

113(FAS), then the policy of spreading the costs of the FAS over all

drivers would be justified. But as long as all drivers do not use the

various highway systems equally, inequities are bound to result. More

succintly, the driver who never uses the Federal-Aid System will effec-

tively subsidize a person who predominately does.

Table 11.3.11 provides evidence that drivers in different size

cities tend to make disproportionate use of roads on and off the Federal-

Aid Systems. The pattern that emerges is that the percent of travel

on all Federal-Aid Systems classified as principal and minor arterials

tends to decrease monotonically with increasing city size. For example,

while drivers in cities in the smallest population group devote 95.6%

and 86.1% of their vehicle miles to principal arterials and minor

arterials respectively on the Federal Aid System, the corresponding

figures for cities in the highest population group are only 80.7% and

66.7%. Thus for each mile driven (and thus for each Federal excise

tax dollar collected per vehicle mile), the population in smaller

cities get greater use from Federally financed roads than their coun-

terparts in larger cities.

In addition, there exists an equity issue with respect to the

relative use of roads within-the Federal-Aid System. In particular,

the Interstate System carries only 27.2% 1 of the total vehicle miles

on all Federal-Aid Systems in 1968, while accounting for 72% of the

total Federal apportionments in the same year. Accordingly, users

1As reported in the 1972 National Highway Needs Report (op cit)

Distribution of 1968 Mileage on Travel on and Off Federal"AidSystems by'Functional System in Urban Areas by Population Groups

114

Percent of Travel on Federal Aid Systems

Population Group

5,00010,00025,00050,000

100,000250,000500,000

1,000,000

Principal Arterial Systems

- 9,999- 24,999

49,999- 99,999- 249,999- 499,999- 999,999and over

95.694.293.391.086.487.983.880.7

Minor Arterial Systems

86.182.278.176.572.874.270.266.8

Source: Part II of the 1972 National Highway Needs Report,House Document No. 92-266 (Table 111-2, page 111-8)

Table 11.3.11

115of the Interstate System are heavily subsidized by drivers on the other

Federal-Aid Systems.

Two other examples of inequitable financing within the Federal

Aid Highway Program may be cited. Again, the rigorous test of equitable-

ness employed here relates the use of specific classes of highways

relative to the tax burden faced by specific types of highway users.

Along these lines, it has often been cited th&t peak-hour highway

users in urban areas are heavily subsidized by off-peak drivers. The

point was made as early as 1959 by Professor William Vickrey in testi-

fying before the Jiont Committee on Washington Metropolitan Problems.

Table 111.3.12 is condensed from Exhibit 51 of these hearings.

The data attempt to separate out the capital cost required in

implementing alternative transportation plans solely due to peak hour

traffic. The major finding here is that single occupant peak-hour

arivers require an incremental investment of $63 per round trip per

year (i.e., over and abive the investment required to provide adequate

capacity for off-peak auto use). While the exact figures reported

by Professor Vickrey might be subject to question, it is nonetheless

true that the IHTF revenue measures average costs over peak and off-

peak users alike, while peak users are responsible for the greater

share of the costs.I This is clearly an inequitable distribution

of the costs for the provision of urban highway facilities.

This issue also involves efficiency considerations, since thegasoline taxes do not serve as cost-based prices. In fact it maybe argued that the result has been as an overexpansion of urban high-ways, since it is not at all clear that peak-hour drivers would bewilling to pay the true social costs of their auto use.

Incremental Costs of Rush Hour Travel by Various Modes

Investment Costs Per Round Trip Per Person

Investment Per RoundTrip per Year ($)

Mode

Rate of CapitalCharge (percent)

Cost PerRound Trip

Operating CostsPer Round TripPer Person ($)

Totai CostsPer Round TripPer Person ($)

Express Bus

Rail

Private Automobile:1 PersonRoads and Vehicles

Out of Pocket OperatingCost

Parking

Total Auto I PersonTotal Auto 2 Persons

Source: Transportation Plan forWashington Metropolitanp. 478.

the National Capitol Region, Hearing Before the JointProblems, Congress of the United States, Eighty-Sixth

Committee onCongress, 1959,

Table 11.3.12

2.70

4.20

15

10

63.00

0.40

0.42

0.35

0.19

5 3.15

10.00

73.0036.50

8

0.75

0.61

3.15

0.30

1.00

4.452.23

0.80

3.951.98

0.30

0.20

0.500.25

117One final example of inequities inherent in the IHTF is provided

by the Federal Highway Administration's 1969 study on the Allocation of

Highway Cost Responsibility and Tax Payments. The major findings from

this tudy are summarized in Table 11.3.13. These data estimate the

total IHTF tax payments assessed on various highway users (automobiles,

buses, and trucks) as compared to the costs of providing the Federal

Aid Highway Systems attributable to each of these users. The apparent

conclusion from these data is that buses andmedium-sized trucks are

subsidizing automobile and heavy truck users of Federal-Aid roads.

Whether the subsidies (inequities) cited in this section are

desirable or not ultimately depends on value judgments as to the rela-

tive merits of different types of travel. Inevitably, the choice of

a financing mechanism for the provision of highways calls for compro-

mises and political_judgment. Thus for example, the explicit subsidy

of the Interstate System by drivers on the other FAS might be justified

on the basis of the particular importance of the Interstate System for

the national defense, and interstate commerce. While the other instances

of inequities inherent in the IHTF -- rural vis-a-vis urban, peak user

vis-a-vis off peak user and auto vis-a-vis turck users -- might be

harder to justify, the complexity involved in administering a

"perfectly equitable" user charge mechanism must be weighed in deciding

upon any changes that would reduce these inequities.

I The allocation of cost responsibility was based on the trafficvolume, vehicular weight and vehicle size of each of the highway userclasses. Heavier and/or larger vehicles require Ipecial structuralconsiderations in the design of highway facilities (thicker pavements,taller overhead structures, etc.).

118

Total Federal Trust Fund ExpenditureAllocation vs. Tax Payments 1969

Type of Vehicle Total Costs Allocated(Millions $)

Total TaxPayments(Millions $)

Ratio ofPayments toCosts

Automobiles

Buses

2 Axle-4 Tire Trucks

Other SingleUnit Trucks

Heavy TruckCombinations

Other

Total

2914

39

329

267

922

7

2742

59

546

480

702

11

4540

.94

1.51

1.66

1.80

0.76

1 .57

4540

Source: Allocation of Highway Cost Responsibility and Tax Payments1969, U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal HighwayAdministration, Bureau of Public Roads, p. 74, Table 25.

Table 11.3.13

119

11.4 Comparison of the Federal Aid Highway Program with theFederal Public Transportation Assistance Program

In order to provide further insight into some of the unique

aspects of the Federal-Aid Highway Program (FAHP) it is interesting

to compare its operation with the Federal Public Transportation

Assistance Program (FPTAP). The FPTAP differs in several important

respects from the FAHP. A convenient framework for comparing the

Federal roles in these two nodal areas is to summarize the FPTAP in

terms of the same program descriptions used to characterize the FAHP

(see Section I1.3.i).

Sources of Federal Funds

There is no FPTAP trust fund analogous to the previously

described Interstate Highway Trust Fund. Federal funds for transit

assistance derive from United States Treasury general tax revenues.

/n important consequence of this characteristic is that Federal authori-

zation levels are subject to Congress general budgetary review. Au-

thorizations in years of "tight money" may be limited. This is in

contrast to the IHTF whose financing is relatively automatic and

"painless", determined primarily by the total revenues accruing to the

Trust Fund.

Total Expenditure Levels

The magnitude of Federal financial effort in highway transpor-

tation dwarfs the FPTAP. Since the first Urban lass Transportation

Assistance Act (1964), Federal Transit grants have totaled $1.215

hillion (FY 1965-1971), only 3.85% of the total FAHP funds over the

120

same period. The most recent FPTAP bill, the Urban Mass Transpor-

tation Assistance Act of 1970 (as amended by Title III of the

Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1973) authorizes $6.1 billion through

fiscal year 1976.

uthorization Cycle

There is apparently no fixed authorization cycle in the FPTAP

analogous to the 2-year Federal highway authorization process. The

first significant Federal financial commitment to public transpor-

tation began with the Urban Mass Transportation Act of 1964 which

authorized funds for the three fiscal years 1965-1967. Public Law

0-562 provided additional grants for the two fiscal years 1968-1969.

Funds for the single FY 1970 were authorized by 701 of Public Law

90-448. Current authorizations derive from Public Law 91-152 which

provides funding for at least five years (FY 1972-1976).

Apportionment2ethod

Unlike the FAHP, Federal transit funds are not apportioned

anong States or local areas on a formula or other prespecified basis.

Federal grants are awarded on a project by project basis. A metro-

politan area or public transportation agency may apply for as many

Federal grants as it chooses. The only apportioning limitation is

that no State (i.e., the aggregate of all grant-receiving agencies or

municipalities in a State) may receive more than 12 1/2% of the

cumulative national level of grants obligated since the beginning of

121

FY 1971.1 An interesting consequence of this apportionment restric-

tion is that a State which embarks on an ambitious transit capital

improvement program may have to wait until other cities "catch up"

before qualifying for additional funding.

' tch i nProvisions

Grants for any type of qualifying public transportation project

are provided at a single matching rate -- a Federal share payable of

00% of the net project cost.2 UNet project cost is defined as the

estimated portion of the cost of a project which cannot be reasonably

financed from farebox revenues. It is clear that the stated matching

provisions give transit agencies the incentive to build relatively

high capital cost projects.

Expenditure Restrictions

Similar to the FAHP, the FPTAP is based upon Federal conditional,

matchin grants. In both programs, the conditional grants are

1. An exception is that any State which has received more than two-thirds of its grant limit may qualify for additional funding froma discretionary account which amounts to 15% of the total cumula-tive EPTAP authorization.

2. The initial determination of net project cost is made on the basisof estimates of total project cost and anticipated revenues derivedfrom engineering studies, studies of economic feasibility, anddata showing the nature and extent of the expected utilization ofthe project facilities and equipment. The actual amount of theFederal grant is determined at the completion of the project onthe basis of the actual net project cost. Further information onthe mechanics of Federal transit aid may be found in CAPITAL GRANTSFOR URBAN MASS TRANSPORTATION: INFORMATION FOR APPLICANTS, distribu-ted by the Urban Mass Transportation Administration (June, 1972).

122

restricted to financing capital expenditures. Grant-eligible public

transit projects include land acquisition, (re)-construction of

transit-related facilities, and the purchase of buses, rail rolling

stock, and related equipnent.

Local Recipients of Federal Funds

A fundamental difference between the FAHP and the FPTAP is

tat the latter deals with municipalities and transit line agencies.

The only State involvement with the acdiinistration of transit grants

is in a general advisory capacity. Applications by local governments

or transit agencies for Federal transit grants must be preceeded by

a State and local review process as stipulated 1by 0MB circular A-95

and other Federal proceedural requirements. In comparison, the FAHP

is administered exclusively through the States, with netropolitan

areas acting solely in an advisory/review capacity.

Sources of Local 1atching Funds

The definition of transit net project cost implies that local

agencies must provide some external (i.e. beyond operating revenues)

means of financing their share of Federally-aided public transportation

systems. Just as there is no established Trust Fund at the Federal

level, very few cities have chosen to enact Trust Funds at the local

level.1 The traditional means of local financing is through a two

1. An exception is found in Minnesota where the Twin Cities Metropoli-tan Transit Commission is empowered to set aside a levy of $1.00on all automobiles registered in Minneapolis-St. Paul for develop-ment and operation of mass transit systems.

123

layer bond issue: local property tax-supported bond issues for

fixed plant, and revenue bonds for the purchase of rolling stock.

However, there are several structural varients in the method of

transit financing in different metropolitan areas.

It is interesting to note that the necessity to obtain bond

issues to finance transit construction gives the local electorate

(where referenda are required to ratify bond issues) or State

legislatures virtual financial veto power. Several cases have

arisen where transit bondin9 referenda have been defeated (e.g.

Seattle (1969), Atlanta (1970), and New York (1972)), resulting in

at least a temporary delay in project construction. In contrast,

t:he FAHP is not characterized by an analogous veto process at the

State level. Although several States have provided for local veto

power over proposed highway projects, this control is not exercised

through restrictions on the use of public funds.

124

11.5 Summary and Conclusions

This chapter has provided a factual setting necessary for the

development of empirical models designed to assess the impacts of

the FAHP on State highway expenditure behavior. Of particular im-

portance is the finding that highway finance employs a trust fund

approach at both the Federal and State levels. The modelling im-

plication here is that the evaluation of alternative Federal highway

grant policies can proceed without a complete analysis of State

budgetary processes across functional areas outside the transport-

ation environment. In other words, since nearly all States finance

highway construction and maintenance from earmarked excise taxes,

we can restrict our modelling attention to how the FAHP affects long

range highway revenue policy, and short run highway programing

(allocation).

The highway financing environment stands in contrast to

financing conventions employed in the provision of other types of

State services (e.g. welfare assistance, health facilities, education

facilities) wherein all expenditures are made from a common budget.

In these areas, changes in Federal grants (e.g. for education) would

be expected to influence expenditure decisions on all functions

other than highways due to the effect of a State's budget constraint.1

1. For an empirical analysis of the interaction between expenditurebehavior on various State functional areas, see Tresch, R., op cit.

125The interaction between highway expenditure behavior and the perform-

ance of other State functions is minimal, and thus this research

will restrict the analysis to the highway sector. 1

A second major finding with regard to the development of

empirical models of expenditure behavior relates to the dynamics

of the Federal-Aid Highway Program. As discussed in Section 11.3,

Federal highway grants are available for abligation by States over

a period of up to three and one half years. This raises the issue

of a time lagged response to the FAHP -- i.e., States may not react

fully and immediately to the availability of any one year's highway

authorization. In fact, the amount of Federal highway grants

available to a State in one year is not simply that years' apportion-

ment. The empirical models presented later will employ a three

year moving average on Federal grants to account for this character-

istic of the FAHP.

A third major characteristic of highway finance which must

be accounted for in empirical models concerns the organization of

the FAHP into several distinct Federal-Aid Systems. The implication

here is that an important aspect of the highway expenditure behavior

is the decisions on the aliocation of a State's highway budget be-

tween alternative Federal Aid Systems (as well as expenditures on

1. Some interaction between highway and other functional areaexpenditure behavior may exist in those States with legis-lation limiting debt ceilings. In these cases, the decisionto sell binds for construction of a State University (forexample) might limit the debt service available for highwayconstruction. Since debt financing does not constitute amajor source of highway revenue for most States this type ofinteraction will be ignored.

other highway categories). Several previous studiesI have simply 127

attempted to model the effect of total Federal highway grant avail-

ability on total State highway expenditures. The problem with this

approach is that it fails to distinguish between the separate expend-

iture effects of Federal grants for each of the Federal-Aid Systems

(each characterized by distinct authorization levels, matching pro-

visions, etc.). The research strategy adopted in this thesis explicitly

accounts for the possibility of distinctly different State expenditure

responses to each of the major Federal-Aid System grants.

Finally, the discussion of highway finance presented in this

chapter serves to illustrate the two fundamental dimensions of State

highway investment behavior: revenue policy and allocation policy.

The former issue deals with the question of which factors influence

a State to raise a greater or lesser amount of (earmarked) highway

revenue. The second issue concerns the analysis of the factors that

determine how a State allocates its highway budget amongst candidate

expenditure categories. In this research the major focus is on the

effects of Federal grants on these two dimensions of State highway

expenditure behavior. Accordingly the empirical models presented

1. For example, O'Brien, T., op.cit., Gabler, L.R. and J.I.Brest, op cit.

128

in this research will explicitly deal with the behavioral bases for

long run re venue policy formulation and short run allocation policy

determination.I

1. The distinction between revenue policy as a "long run"phenomenon and allocation policy as a "short run" phenomenonderives from the fact that changes in the determinants ofState highway revenue (e.g. tax rates, bond sales, etc.)tend to be infrequent relative to the expression of aState's allocation policy (e.g., year-to-year capital budget-ing decisions.)

129

Chapter III

THE FEDERAL AID HIGHWAY PROGRAM: THE ANALYTICSOF DESIGN AND RESPTNSE

III.1 Introduction

Economists have developed an extensive set of theoretical

and analytical tools that have been applied with some measure

of success in analyzing the operation and performance of the

private sector. Attempts to extend these economic tools to the

analysis of the public sector cannot boast of similar success.

This is particularly true of recent research into the nature of

the impacts of Federal grants - in-aid on State and local

governments.

This chapter will set forth a series of theoretical

models that serve to illustrate the expected consequences of a

variety of Federal aid program structures. It should be

stressed at the outset that there are several obstacles to a

fruitful theoretical analysis of the impacts of the Federal aid

highway program.

An inmediate issue is whether to approach the analysis

from a normative (prescriptive) or positive (descriptive) per-

spective. Indeed, in studies of the private sector, the norma-

tive analysis of, for example an optimal pricing policy, is

often facilitated by rather simple assumptions on the objectives

of the economic agents in the system (for example, profit

130

maximization by a firm). Section 2 of this chapter discusses the

difficulty of inferring a set of goals guiding the Federal

government's role in highway finance. Despite the fact that the

Federal objectives in administering the highway grant program

are neither easily identifiable, non-conflicting or static,

Section two does attempt to develop a series of possible ra-

tionales for Federal participation in the provision of the

national highway system. For each rationale, the appropriate

design of the Federal aid highway program is presented.

Section three adopts a descriptive analytic framework.

A basic allocation model is presented based on the economic

theory of the consumer (i.e. the State is viewed as a consumer

of highway facilities), to develop the expected expenditure

responses of States to a variety of Federal-aid program struc-

tures. Needless to say, the results reported here are relevant

only to the extent that the assumptions underlying the alloca-

tion model accurately describe the decision-making calculus

employed by the States. Here too, an obstacle to fruitful

theoretical analysis is the lack of an easily identifiable set

of objectives defining the criteria by which States determine

the level and allocation of their transportation budget.

Nonetheless, section three proceeds on the basis of a somewhat

simplistic decsion rule: a State will allocate its transporta-

tion budget so as to maximize its perceived benefits (utility).

131

Qualifications to the analyses of State responses to a variety

of grant types (open and close ended, categorical and non-cate-

gorical, and matching and block type grants) are discussed in

subsection vi of section three.

Section four presents a different approach to analyzing

State responses to Federal grants. The concept of the benefit/

cost ratio of candidate highway projects is introduced as the

basic investment criterion used by States. Although the theo-

retical analyses of sections three and four apparently differ

with respect to their underlying assumptions, in fact the con-

clusions drawn from both approaches are quite similar. Both

sections draw attention to the price and income effects intro-

duced by Federal grants, and proceed to demonstrate how State

responses will differ according to the presence of one or

both of these grant characteristics.

Section five extends the analysis of the preceding

section with an investigation of historical grant and expendi-

ture levels of the Interstate and ABC highway programs. It is

shown that for the Interstate program, Federal grants have

stimulated State expenditures that would most likely have not

been made in the absence of the grant program. This result is

contrasted with the experience in the ABC program, where it is

shown that Federal grants have had a relatively insignificant

impact in determining total expenditure levels on an allocation

132

within the ABC system.

Section six summarizes the theoretical findings of

chapter three. The relationship between the response to Federal

grants, and the structural characteristics of the grants is

discussed. The similarity of findings between the consumer allo-

cation model (Section 3) and the benefit/cost investment model

(Section 4) are drawn, and related to the empirical evidence

presented in Section 5. Finally, the importance of validating

the theoretical findings in this chapter with econometric models

of succeeding chapters is stressed.

133111.2 Fiscal Federalism -- The Normative Aspects of Federal Highway

Grant Program Design

A logical starting point for an evaluation of the consequences

of the Federal Aid Highway Program (FAHP) is to consider the Federal

role in highway financing in the broader context of Fiscal Federalism.1

Viewed in this perspective, the immediate questions to be addressed

relate not so much to a detailed examination of the merits of one or

another apportionment formula or matching ratio, as to an ex ante

discussion of the justification for any Federal involvement in highway

finance. The distinction we wish to draw is simply this: proposed

changes to the existing structure of the FAMP may be called for because

the initial justification for the Federal role in highway finance is no

longer (or has never been) valid, or because the structure of the FAHP

is not compatible with the accepted goals of the Federal role in high-

way finance. The former issue is clearly normative. Although Congress-

ional debate over highway policy is not normally conducted at an abstract

level, it may be inferred that current Federal highway legislation does

recognize a need for Federal involvement in highway finance, and is in-

tended to, inter alia,-stimulate State expenditures on the Interstate

Highway System.

1. Fiscal Federalism is a generic title for the study of the dis-tribution of fiscal responsibilities in a decentralized- systemof governmental units. See Musgrave and Musgrave, PUBLIC FINANCEIN THEORY AND PRACTICE, McGraw-Hill Boook Company, 1973, chapters26,27, and Due and Friedlaender, GOVERNMENT FINANCE, Richard D.Irwin, Inc., 1973 (5th Edition), Chapter 19.

134

Accepting this policy statement for the moment, the often ex-

pressed criticisms that the current FAHP has stimulated State ex-

penditures on the Inter-State system beyond economically justifiable

levelsi is directed not so much against the provisions of the FAHP

as against the implicit national goals from which the FAHP is derived.

On the other hand, if the provisions of the FAHP did not stimu-

late Interstate Highway expenditures2 (again accepting this policy

for the moment), then there may be ample justification for realigning

the provisions of the FAHP. Thus the argument comes full circle.

there is a clear distinction between stated (or implicit) national

highway policy, and the characteristics of a particular highway

program designed to implement that policy. In the broadest sense,

the normative issue is to gain consensus on both of these aspects of

the Federal Aid Highway Program.

i. The Theory of Intergovernmental Grants

Theoretical considerations can give some indication of the ap-

propriate policy goals to be served by a program of intergovernmental

grants. In general, there are three factors inherent in a decentral-

ized system governmental jurisdictions that call for Federal fiscal

1. For example, see Testimony of Robert E. Gallamore, Director ofPolicy Development, Common Cause, Before the Subcommittee onRoads of the Senate Public Works Committee, February 15, 1973.

2. This would be the case if the States' Interstate Highway ex-penditures would have been at the same level in the absence ofFederal grants. In this instance, it may be argued that Federalfunds are primarily diverted to other expenditure categories in-cluding tax relief in which the Federal government has noofficially stated interest.

135

intervention. The first factor relates to the existence of signifi-

cant benefit spillovers, i.e., the incidence of benefits (or disbene-

fits) beyond the boundaries of the jurisdictions responsible for

financing public projects. In the case of highway investment, it is

clear that at least part of the benefits derived from the provision

of road services in any one State are enjoyed by residents of other

states. To the extent that one state provides an adequate system of

highways, adjoining states benefit from reduced over-the-road inter-

state transport costs, and increased personal mobility for vacation

and business travel.

The problem here is when some of the benefits are external, the

level of highway activity provided by any one state is likely to be

too small relative to the interests of the country as a whole, if

highways are financed locally, and decisions about the quantity to

produce are left solely in local hands. Formally, this problem can

be stated as follows. Consider a level of highway production Qi in

State i and the associated costs C%, and benefits B (internal bene-

fits) and Be (external benefits).1 In abstract terms, we represent

highway costs and benefits as continuous functions of the level of

highway production as shown in Figure 111.2.1. Borrowing the calculus

of economic production theory, the optimal scale of highway production

1. This example is solely for illustrative purposes. It is notnecessary at this time to distinguish between direct and in-direct benefits, nor between benefit incidence on subgroupswithin the population of a given state. The main thrust here issimply to investigate the allocative consequences of fragmentedjurisdictional highway investment ecision-making.

136

INTERNAL AND EXTERNAL HIGHWAY BENEFITS AND COSTS

,00 000A

.0

a-~

//

-

/

/

- A

-S -

Figure 111.2.1

137

in the absence of external incentives. Qi is determined as that point

where the marginal cost of highway production is equal to marginal

highway benefits. In particular, if each jurisdiction bases its in-

vestment decisions solely on the basis of benefits accruing to residents

within its boundaries, we have the optimal production scale condition:

1 1 (1)aQi aQi

Graphically, the optimal level of highway production is indicated by

the point Q. where the slope of the cost curve and benefit curve are

equal. Note that in this solution, no account has been taken of

the benefits accruing outside of State i.

If the residents of each jurisdiction were to base expenditure

decisions upon benefits to the entire country rather than to their

own areas alone, the optimal scale for provision of highways would

be guided by the condition:

aBT aBe 9BB aCi (2)

where BT = total highway benefits (BT = B + Be)

In this case, the optimal level of production is Q resulting in net

benefits, Bi(QI) - C(Qi) indicated by line segment cd (see figure

111.2.1). This latter solution results in an expansion of highway

138

production in State i from Qi to Q7 and more importantly, an increase

in net benefits from ab to cd.

Simply stated, the issue is this: in the absence of external

financial incentives, it is unrealistic to assume that individual

jurisdictions (e.g. states) will pursue a highway investment policy

that systematically accounts for benefits accruing beyond their

boundaries. In cases where significant benefit spillovers occur,

the consequences of this atomistic behavior is an underinvestment in

highway facilities.

ii. Functional Grants As Solutions

The above comments serve not only to outline a valid concern for

Federal intervention in highway finance, but serve to indicate the

appropriate structure for remedial Federal action. Short of an out-

right transfer of all highway investment activi es to the Federal

government,1 the Federal objective is to prov de a set of financial

incentives that will encourage lower level j isdictions to account

for benefit spillouts in their investmen -decisions. 2

To illustrate the mechanics of the appropriate program structure

to meet this objective, assume the federal government assumes a

1. By definition, a nationalized highway investment program wouldinternalize benefit spillouts effects.

2. Clearly, counteracting the adverse effects of benefit spilloutson state investment behavior is not the only objective of aFederal Aid Highway Program. In fact, there exist other, con-flicting federal objectives. These will be discussed in thefollowing sections.

139

(matching) share of the cost of the ith state's highway program as

determined by the ratio of external to total benefits accruing from

the provision of highways in State i. Returning to our initial model

of optimal highway production scale where State i considers only in-

ternal benefits in its investment calculus, we get the optimality

condition:

,C C C )

Q 1BT (3)

where C' = State i's share of the cost of highway production.11

Assume for the moment that the external benefits Be are some

fixed proportion of internal benefits Bij, i.e.:

Bi = f(Qi) (4)

Be = af(Q.)

then condition (3) reduces to

6T 'Bi jB Be B aci (5)

B i Qi BQi Bi Qg Qi

1. C1 represents the total cost of highway construction in State i.Ifthe federal government assumes a share of highway cost equal

Beto the ratio of external to total benefits, i.e., , the States'

highway cost is just -C (see figure 11I.2.1.).

140

But assumption (4) also implies:

B dB. "BB

(6)Bi i Q Q

Thus, optimality condition (3) takes the form:

- B1 Be SDBT Ci--- + - (7)

DQi 3Qi DQi qQi

The important conclusion that can be drawn from the above

derivation is that the consequences of a federal highway matching

grant program in situations where individual states consider only

internal benefits in their investment calculus is allocationally

equivalent to the highway production scale implied by states' ex-

penditure decisions (in the absence of grants) based upon benefits

accruing to the nation as a whole. Moreover, the production scale

implied by optimality condition (2) or (3) represents the most ef-

ficient level of highway production.1

Thus, to the extent that the provision of highways results in

significant benefit spillovers which are not accounted for in in-

dividual states' investment decisions, economic theory suggests a

justifiable federal policy role in highway finance intended to in-

crease the allocational-efficiency of highway investments. Moreover,

1. In the terms of figure 111.2.1, conditions (2) or (3) imply aproduction scale Q*. The net benefits associated with Q*,BT(Q*) - C(Q*) > BT(Q) - C(Q) V Q /

141

the economic theory dictates the appropriate program structure of

financial incentives designed to implement this policy. In parti-

cular, solely on the grounds of allocational efficiency,1 the federal

government should administer grants with the following program

characteristics.

conditional

The grants should be restricted to those classes of highways

that are characterized by significant external (interstate)

benefits.

matching ratios

The grants should be offered on a matching ratio basis. The

matching provisions are determined by the nationwide signifi-

cance of a particular highway class. Thus, for example, the

federal government should assume a larger share of the cost of

routes of major interstate importance than the share assumed

for highways of primarily local or regional significance.

open-ended

The grants should not be limited by a fixed grant ceiling. In

light of the theoretical considerations discussed above, open-

grants do not imply that States will expand their highway

1. It is again stressed that there are other criteria dictatingthe appropriate structure of the federal highway program. Someof these criteria will be discussed in the following sections.

142

investments arbitrarily. On the contrary the theory suggests

that open-ended grants with the appropriate] matching provisions

will encourage states to expand their highway investment pro-

gram only to the point where net (nationwide) benefits are

maximized.

iii. Practical Limitations of the External Benefit Criterion.

Although theoretical considerations point to the use of condi-

tional, open-ended, matching grants as a means to internalize

benefit spillouts,2 there are several limitations to the practicality

of this approach. Needless to say, the investment criteria discussed

in the previous section were somewhat simplistic. And cavalier re-

ferences to "benefits" quantified as a continuous function of "the

quantity of highways" ignores the facts that:

a) highway benefits cannot be quantified by a single measure;

b) nor can we make a neat distinction between benefits which are

internal or external to a given state;

c) the benefits derived from the provision of highways is not de-

finable over a continuum of the scale of highway investment;

d) The determination of internal and total highway benefits--

however measured--is exceedingly difficult; for any one state,

1. We refer here to an adjustment of the matching ratio to reflectthe ratio of external to total highway benefits.

2. These grants are often called "optimizing grants."

143

these measures are conditioned on the level of highway invest-

ment undertaken in adjoining states.

Taken together, these facts suggest that any practical applica-

tion of optimizing grants will of necessity involve compromises and

deviations from a rigid adherence to economic theory. The Federal

Aid Highway Program described in Chapter 2 may be viewed as one such

compromise. In light of the numerous criticisms that have been

levied against this program, it is necessary to question whether

the complaints constitute a general indictment of grants as an inter-

governmental fiscal device, or merely identify inherent structural

defects which must be balanced against the benefits of the FAHP.

It has been charged thatl there are too many separate highway

programs imposing excessively complex eligibility requirements and

using unduly complicated apportionment formulas. Others claim that

the FAHP has misdirected state and local expenditure allocation,

rigidified state budgetary processes, and curtailed local autonomy.

All of these charges are, to varying degrees, true. Take for

example the alleged distortion of the allocation of local funds

among different highway programs. Poorly designed grant programs

will have this effect--i.e., to the extent that the matching pro-

visions of the existing FAHP do not reflect the actual distribution

I See for example, Break, George F., INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCALRELATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES, Brookings Institution, 1967,Chapter 3, for a good summary of arguments against federalcategorical grants.

143

these measures are conditioned on the level of highway invest-

ment undertaken in adjoining states.

Taken together, these facts suggest that any practical applica-

tion of optimizing grants will of necessity involve compromises and

deviations from a rigid adherence to economic theory. The Federal

Aid Highway Program described in Chapter 2 may be viewed as one such

compromise. In light of the numerous criticisms that have been

levied against this program, it is necessary to question whether

the complaints constitute a general indictment of grants as an inter-

governmental fiscal device, or merely identify inherent structural

defects which must be balanced against the benefits of the FAHP.

It has been charged thatl there are too many separate highway

programs imposing excessively complex eligibility requirements and

using unduly complicated apportionment formulas. Others claim that

the FAHP has misdirected state and local expenditure allocation,

rigidified state budgetary processes, and curtailed local autonomy.

All of these charges are, to varying degrees, true. Take for

example the alleged distortion of the allocation of local funds

among different highway programs. Poorly designed grant programs

will have this effect--i.e., to the extent that the matching pro-

visions of the existing FAHP do not reflect the actual distribution

1 See for example, Break, George F., INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCALRELATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES, Brookings Institution, 1967,Chapter 3, for a good summary of arguments against federalcategorical grants.

144

of internal and external highway benefits, allocational inefficiencies

are bound to occur. However, properly designed grant programs will

have the opposite effect: these grants will simply serve to finance

a level of highway construction activity commensurate with the bene-

fits accruing to the notion as a whole. Related to this question is

the criticism that the FAHP has curtailed local autonomy. Here.too,

while this charge may be perfectly valid for the existing FAHP pro-

gram structure, an appropriately designed optimizing grant program2

will not shift state policy responsibilities to Washington, but

rather will remove the burden of state taxation for the financing of

benefits the states do not directly receive.

It is true of course that the present system of highway grants

does complicate the planning and administration of state highway in-

vestment programs. Grants are made available for some highway

activities (e.g., Interstate Highway construction) but not others

(e.g., road maintenance). Each grant comes with restrictions on road

1. This criticism stems partly from the assertion that federalhighway funds far exceed transit grant availability. Conse-quently, the local incentives for transit system improvementsare curtailed. This criticism does not indict federal grantsper se, but serves to underline the need for a realignment ofthe existing FAHP/transit grant program. If grants for bothof these modes were made available on an open-ended basis, suchthat each recipient could choose the extent of its own partici-pation in highway and transit programs, these criticisms wouldno longer be valid.

2. Implicit in this discussion is an equity issue. Since theintent of the optimizing grants is to finance the provision ofexternal highway benefits, these grants should be derived fromtaxes on states as determined by the net spill-in highway bene-fits they enjoy.

V

145

design standards, labor hiring practices, and planning and admini-

stration process guidelines. While economic theory may provide the

rationale for a federal highway grant program in simplistic terms,

it is undoubtedly true that in the inherently complex political and

social environment in which they operate, rjgid grant procedures,

carried out in isolation, no longer yield acceptable solutions.

In a tightly integrated society, where the consequences of

one functional grant program directly effect states' performance of

other functional activities and where actions taken in one locality

or state have widespread impact, a premium is placed on effective

fiscal cooperation among all levels of government. In light of the

issues raised in the preceeding pages, it is clear that while func-

tional grants are an important instrument for effecting highway in-

vestment allocational efficiency, there are numerous ancillary

consequences of a Federal grant program that must be considered as

well.

Ultimately the normative issues of grant program design must

explicitly account for the political and institutional consequences

of a system of intergovernmental grants. Although the allocative

impacts of specific highway grant programs will be the central focus

of this thesis, we will address the institutional questions in a

later chapter.

146

iv. Additional Goals of the Federal Aid Highway Program

In section III.2.ii, it was shown that a system of conditional,

open-ended, matching grants were the appropriate fiscal policy tool

to address the problem of benefit spillovers. There are other reasons

why the Federal government may desire to influence the investment

behavior of lower level governments. One example is the case of merit

goods1 -- that is those services deemed to be sufficiently meritorious

as to encourage the Federal government to offer incentives for their

provision. Implicit in the notion of merit goods is an element of

coercion. A Federal program of merit good incentives is intended to

redirect states' consumption oatterns in those instances where it is

considered that states systematically underestimate the value of the

services to themselves. 2

Putting it differently, merit goods may be considered as a

special case of Federal fiscal intervention to ensure a certain mini-

mum standard for the provision of public goods. 3 Arguments for merit

good subsidies have been frequently aired for non-transportation ser-

vices, particularly for health and old age care services (e.g.,

1. Musgrave and Musgrave, op.cit., page 612.

2. This stands in contrast to benefit spillover situations wherestates are assumed to systematically underestimate the value ofhighway services to the nation as a whole.

3. To be more specific, of a national consensus on the minimallyacceptable quality of a public service is achieved, Federal meritgood subsidies play the role of protecting the interests of theminority in a particular locality where majority decision pro-vides for a substandard level of public services.

147

Medicare, Medicaid, and Old Age Assistance programs). However, to

extend these arguments to the provision of highways is hardly defen-

sible as it would imply that over-the-road transport is an especially

meritorious means of travel relative to the service offered by com-

peting modes.

While this rationale for Federal fiscal intervention is not par-

ticularly relevant to the transportation sector,1 it should be noted

that conditional, close-ended, matching or block grants are best

suited to serve as merit good subsidies. This program structure as-

sures that the grants are selective (i.e., limited to specifically

identifiable merit goods) and supportife of only the minimum accept-

able level of merit good provision.

In addition to the fiscal objectives of correcting for benefit

spillovers, and subsidizing the provision of merit goods--both pri-

marily allocative objectives--the Federal government may wish to

pursue a grant program to meet explicit distributive goals. To be

sure, grant programs designed to meet reallocative goals are also

characterized by distributive consequences, and vice versa. However,

there is a clear distinction between grant programs whose rationale

is primarily allocative, and those whose rationale is primarily dis-

tributive.

1. On a limited scale one could present a case for highway grantsin the guise of merit good subsidies on the grounds that:-- safety considerations demand aicertain minimal level of highway

design standards--new modal technologies appear particularly promising, but local

authorities are adverse to experimenting with untried techniques.

148

In the latter case, the Federal government would pursue measures

which tend to equalize interstate fiscal strength without interfering

with their preferences among alternative public (e.g., highway) ser-

vices. 1 As in our previous discussion, the important point here is

that the design of a particular grant program is strongly related to

the adopted set of Federal objectives. In the instance where the

Federal goal is strictly distributive, the appropriate federal action

is the institution of unconditional, non-matching grants apportioned

on the basis of the differences between fiscal need and fiscal capa-

city among the states.2 Grants under the general heading of "revenue

sharing" have these program characteristics.

The advisability of these grants ultimately rests on the existence

of significant interstate differences in fiscal capacity and fiscal

needs. The highway sector presents a special case where the interstate

variations in fiscal strength are minimal, since both fiscal need and

fiscal capacity correlate positively to the level of automobile travel.

Given the existing method of gasoline taxation, states with relatively

1. That is, grants designed to meet distributional goals would notalter the perceived prices of specific public goods. This is incontrast to the previously discussed matching grants which playthe role of price subsidies for specific public goods.

2. This program calls for a measure of fiscal need--i.e., the costof providing a given level of (highway) services, and of fiscalcapacity--i.e., the tax rate required to raise a given level ofrevenue. The intent of this type of grant would simply be toequalize the tax rates required in various states to render agiven level of highway services.

149

high levels of automobile use (and presumably with correspondingly

high capital and maintenance investment requirements) will also enjoy

relatively high levels of available taxable income. This relationship

stands in contrast to government activities where the level of fiscal

need is inversely related to fiscal capacity.1 While it is simplistic

to presume that redistributive-oriented grant programs play no allo-

cative role (and vice versa2 ), there is little justification of

the need to structure the highway grant program to meet explicit fis-

cal equilization objectives.

1. Welfare assistance programs are one example. In this case thefiscal requirements of welfare programs are highest in thosestates and localities with the lowest fiscal capacities. Tosome extent this relationship holds for the provision of transitservices as well, in the sense that transit ridership (and theassociate of transit investment requirements) are inversely re-lated to income (see Wells, J.D. et al., ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICSOF THE URBAN PUBLIC TRANSPORTATION INDUSTRY, Institute for De-fense Analyses, February, 1972, Chapter 4).

2. For example, federal aid highway apportionments in fiscal year1970 were mildly redistributive. The coefficient of correla-tion between apportionments and state per capita income was-0.1965.

150

v. Theoretical Aspects of Policy Evaluation

As is evident from the previous discussion, attempts to

address the normative issues of Federalhighway grant program

design along the lines of the underlying economic and institutional

structure of the national highway system are not particularly

fruitful. We have argued that the traditional rationales for Federal

fiscal intervention -- correction for benefit spillover, merit good

provision, and fiscal equalization -- are not demonstrably applica-

ble to the existing highway investment environment.

What is clear is that highway policy has developed as an

evolutionary process. The highway environment of the early 1900's,

when the initial federal-aid highway legislation was passed, was

characterized by significant benefit spillover and to some extent

merit good and fiscal equalization problems.I The policies that have

evolved since the Federal Road Act of 1916 (see Chapter 2) have

consisted primarily of additions to extant policy (e.g., new Federal-

Aid Systems, new institutional and planning requirements). The end

result has been an ever increasingly complex system of detailed

provisions governing the conduct of numerous federal aid grant programs.

1. See Burch, op.cit., for a good discussion of the evolution ofhighway investment policy.

151

Against this setting, it is extremely difficult to

extract an identifiable set of national highway investment goals.

From a normative standpoint, the design of the Federal Aid

Highway Program must confront two basic issues:

- can we achieve a consensus on the objectives ofthe Federal government's role in the provisionof highways?

- if these objectives can be achieved by the imple-mentation of a Federal grant-in-aid program, whatprogram design would Lest serve the Federal goals?

Political realities preclude a meaningful and conclusive

response to the first question. Policy formulation at the

Federal level is not a static process. Perceptions and priori-

ties change over time. Moreover, in any given year, Congressional

declarations of policy1 are expressed in vague terms, rather than

the operational statement of objectives required to pursue a

normative analysis of grant program design. In short, the

inherent complexity of the intergovernmental finance framework

discourages meaningful normative analysis.

Accordingly, the primary focus of this research is in the

framework of positive analysis -- a detailed investigation of the

consequences of the existing program structure, and an evaluation

1. As inferred from Federal highway legislation

152

of selected (incremental) changes to the existing structure.

A theoretical model of grant program design is presented in

the following section.

111.3 The Analytics of State Responses to Federal Grants 153

This section presents a basic model for use in analyzing how a

variety of highway grant programs could be expected to influence the

short run expenditure patterns of recipient governments. The analy-

sis framework focuses on the highway investment decision-making body

-- be it a State Highway Department (SHD), legislature, governor, or

a combination of these institutions. In any case, the decision-making

body is considered to represent a behavioral unit (BU) in the sense

that it exhibits a consistent set of preferences among alternative

transportation goods. The preference structure of the BU can be re-

presented by an indifference map among any combination of the trans-

portation goods.I Furthermore, we assume that the BU seeks to maxi-

mize the utilities inherent in that set of preferences, subject to

given prices and the resources available to it. The resources consist

of the sum total of all revenue earmarked for transportation expendi-

ture, plus the funds the BU receives from external sources in the form

of federal grants. Without loss of generality, resources may represent

funds dedicated solely to highway expenditure (i.e., a BU Highway

Trust Fund) or a multimodal trust fund. The analysis does presume

however that the budgetary and investment functions of the BU operate

1. The analysis is analogous to the consumer theory of an individual'sresource allocation. Thus we assume that our indifference mapsare convex to the origin and non-intersecting. These maps are notnecessarily assumed to represent the true preferences of thevoting polity, and thus do not derive from a "social welfare func-tion." Throughout the discussion, references to maximizing utilityare in the context of the utility of the. BU, whether or not thisutility truly reflects societal welfare.

154

independently of the BU's decision-making activities for non-transpor-

tation functions.

i. The Basic Model

Formally, the investment model takes the form:

max U = U(E , E2, ... E) (8)

nsubject to E. < R

i =1~

where U is the utility derived by the BU for a given allocation of

expenditures amongst transportation goods E1, FE2, ... EnI and R is

the total resource availability. For clarity, we focus the analysis

on the level of expenditure devoted to one specific hiphway category,

X, relative to the resources available for all non-X transportation

expenditures.

Thus in figure 111.3.1, we display the indifference map of the

BU, with the units of X on one axis (e.g. lane miles), and resources

for all other transportation uses, Y (in dollar terms) on the other.

Each indifference curve represents a distinct set of combinations of

X and Y for a given level of utility, i.e.,

U = U = U(X, Y) (9)

where Ui = i th level of utility.

1. These expenditure categories may represent distinct classes ofhighways, for example the various Federal Aid Systems.

155

HIGHWAY INVESTMENT INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Y4 -

0'

44

a ~ ;z;1 Cz9x3 4

Figure 111.3.1

156

Figure 111.3.1 depicts an indifference map at four distinct levels of

utility (U1 - UQ).

Given an initial resource level Y. , and the price of highway

commodity X, we can define a budget line B (in the absence of any

grants) as:

Y = Y. - pX (10)

Taken together, the indifference map and the budget lines define an

expansion (income-consumption) path of equilibrium resource allocation

(00' on figure 111.3.1). Each equilibrium point e = (x , y) satisfies

the condition of tangency between the budget line and indifference

curve:

9U = P

ii. Addition of a Conditional Matching Open-Ended (CMO) Grant.

Figure 111.3.2 reproduces the original, pre-grant equilibrium

point e2 = (x2, Y2). In this case, the RU is devoting y2Y2 dollars to

highway type X, and Oy2 dollars to all other highway expenditure cate-

gories. Assume now that the federal government has agreed to bear a

fixed percentage g bf the--costs of the local program for highway

commodity X. In terms of our initial expenditure model, a grant of this

type reduces the BU's perceived price of highway commodity X to the

157

ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL MATCHING OPEN-ENDED GRANTS

/

ej t

O0 K1 K j3 K

Figure 111.3.2

6z

158

level (1-g)p . This is shown in figure 111.3.2 by a shift in the bud-

get line from Y2J to Y2K. Note that the new budget line has pivoted

around 0oint Y2, reflecting the fact that a CMO grant does not in-

crease the resources available to the BU if no expenditures on high-

way commodity X are undertaken. Furthermore, it is easy to show that

the federal matching share g is represented on the figure by the

ratio L.

The equilibrium expenditure pattern along the post-grant budget

line B' is indicated by point e = (x, yb). More units of X have

been purchased, but at lower cost to the BU out of its own funds.

In particular, the post-grant expenditure pattern takes the form sum-

marized in Table 111.3.1

Table 111.3.1

Line Expenditure Descriptor

Units of X

Expenditure on X outof own funds

Expenditure on Y outof own funds

Grant money received

Total expenditure on X

Toti expenditure on Y

Pre-Grant Post-Grant

0x2x,Ox2 O2x

Y2y 2 Y2 y

-- y5Y2

y2 2 2 2 O

0y2 Oy2

Charge:Post-Grant minusPre-Grant

x2x2 (+

y Y 2

2 2

y2y2 (+

0Y2 OYf1. The post-grant price of X is = (1-g)p =(1-g) .

03 -OK x03-03Thus g= 1 OJ OK - wOJJK

K OK OTK'

1

2

3

4

5

6

159

From the last two lines in this table, it is clear that the

CMO grant has resulted in increases in total expenditures on both X

and Y. But reference to lines 2 and 3 of Table 111.3.1 indicates that

in terms of the allocation of the BU's own resources, expenditures on

X have decreased relative to the expenditure on non-aided highway

commodities (Y). In other words, the net result of the conditional

(on X) matching open-ended grant has been a shift of y2y' dollars

(formerly devoted to expenditure on highway commodity X) to expendi-

ture on non-X highway activities.

This is not necessarily the case however. The response of the

recipient government to the CMO grant will depend in general upon the

BU's expressed demand for highway goods, and in particular upon its

demand for the grant subsidized activity. More specifically, the

response will be a function of the B's price elasticity of demand

for the aided activity.

The generalized grant response is shown in figure 111.3.3 where

we have again indicated the initial pre-grant equilibrium point

e2"(x2, Y2), as well as the equilibria corresponding to CMO grants

with two different matching ratios.I These alternative- equilibria

trace out a price-consumption curve Y2Q describing expenditures on

X and Y for given grant matching ratios.2 In the declining portion

1. For clarity, the indifference curves have been omitted from thefigure. Budget line B2 in figure 111.3.3 is identical to B5 infigure 111.3.2.

2. Each point on the price-consumption curve represents apoint oftangency between a specific budget line and indifference curve.

160

GRANT RESPONSES FOR ALTERNATIVE PRICE SUBSIDIES

y

-PECR~eASIQ PICE AS PEPCEIJE>OY~Z ..0Q- Y TH E J

ERICE ELASTICITYoF "HI6'HWAY CeflOPfTY X

Figure 111.3.3

161

of the price consumption curve, the demand for highway commodity X is

price elastic: a decrease in price by g% (i.e., the federal share

of a grant for X) will result in a greater than g% increase in con-

sumption of X. In other words, federal grants in this region will

stimulate greater levels of expenditures on X from the BU's own resources.

This is clear from the comparison of the pre-grant equilibrium

point e2= 2y2) and the equilibrium point e'(x', y') resulting from

a CMO grant with matching ratio L (figure 111.3.3). In the latter

case, the BU's own expenditures on X have increased from y2Y2 to

yj'Y2-- the precise amount that expenditures on non-aided highway

activities have decreased. In fact, the equilibrium e' corresponds

to the unit-elastic point on the price consumption curve (see lower

portion of figure III.e.3). CMO grants with federal shares greater

than )L -- as represented by budget line B" -- will result in a sub-Ofstitution nf expenditures on X for Y. In this region of the price-

consump io: cui ve,the demand for highway commodity X is inelastic with

respect to post-grant price.

Summarily, the theoretical analysis indicates that conditional,

matching open-ended grants may result in a stimulation of the BU's

own allocation of resources to the aided highway function, or sub-

stitution of expenditures from the aided to non-aided functions de-

pending on the price elasticity of the subsidized commodity.

162

iii. Analysis of Conditional , Matching Close-Ended (CMC) Grants

The analysis of expenditure response to conditional, matching,

close-ended grants proceeds in a manner analogous to the previous

section. In this instance, we assume that the federal government

agrees to bear g% of the costs to provide highway commodity X up

to a fixed grant ceiling level. The graphical representation of this

grant structure is shown in figure 111.3.4, where the pre-grant

equilibrium point is indicated by e2=(x2 , y2 and the CMC grant has

a matching ratio of JK Suppose for example the federal government

has agreed to share in the cost of OxDI units of X--or equivalently

has invoked a grant ceiling of Y2Z1 dollars.1 The budget line facing

1. This equivalence can be demonstrated in terms of figure 111.3.4as follows:The total cost of OxDI units of X is given by line segment Z0ZI

If Y2Z = federal share of this total cost, then

2Z 1 Tg Z0 1

z0Y2 _ Qy2 z0z 1 -OzI

But Z% OK , and Z % Oi

Y2z1 O 1 Oz01 2 1D12 0KThus -- Z =Z Kz 0z1 Z1 1Oil<0 Z10OK O

Q.E.D.

163

ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL MATCHING CLOSE-ENDED GRANTS

z5

0AO

z2Z2

2,

I \ 4

Xt X2

I \?\\\ 3

Figure 111.3.4

164

the BU is given by Y2D1J1, with consumption of highway commodity X

beyond OXDl units costing the full market price 2 . Under these con-

ditions equilibrium resource allocation is indicated by point D0 where

the income consumption line intersects the budget line. Note that in

this case, where the break or "deflection"' point in the budget line

falls to the left of the income consumption path, the CMC grant, and

an unconditional non-matching, close-ended (UNC) grant of equivalent

magnitude (as indicated by budget line Z1DJ1 ) are allocationally

equivalent. Thus, in terms of figure 111.3.4, CMC grants with sta-

tutory ceilings up to Y2z2 dollars yield the same expenditures on

highway commodity X as equivalent dollar amount UNC grants.

Beyond this grant ceiling, CMC grants result in greater X

expenditures than an equal amount UNC grant, but less than an open-

ended matching grant with the same matching ratio as the CMC grant.

For example a CMC grant withceiling Y2Z3 yields the equilibrium point

D3, which involves a greater expenditure on highway commodity X than

the equilibrium point D' associated with the equivalent amount UNC

grant but less X expenditure than the equilibrium point D4 associated

with an equivalent matching ratio CMO grant (see Table 111.3.2).

For a given matchinq ratio, the grant ceiling ultimately reaches

a level at which it is no longer binding on resource allocation. In

particular, beyond the grant ceiling Y2Z4 where the CMC budget line

1. See Wilde, James A., "The Expenditure Effects of Grant-in-AidPrograms," NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL, VOL. XXI, Number 3.

TABLE 111.3.2

COMPARISON OF EQUILIBRIUM POINTS FOR ALTERNATIVE GRANT

STRUCTURES SHOWN IN FIGURE 111.3.4

[1] [2]

Equilibrium with

Grant CMC Grant ,Ceiling (Matching Ratio O)

[3]

Equilibrium withUNC Grant

[4]

Equilibrium withCMO Grant

(Matching Ratio !)

[5]

Change inExpenditure

on X([3]-[2])

[6]

Change inExpenditure

on X([4]-[2])

Y2Z1 ODOD (+)y2zI D0 D90D40

Y2Z2 D2 D2 D 0 (+)

Y2Z3 D3 D3 04 (-)

y9294 D4D D4 (-) 0

Y2Z5 D4 D5 D4 () 0

atjCF)

166

intersects the price-consumption curve (point D4), CMC grants are al-

locationally equivalent to CMO grants. Thus increases in the grant

ceiling beyond the level Y2Z4 will in no way alter the highway expen-

diture pattern of recipient governments.

In general, the greater the federal matching share of expendi-

tures on highway commodity X, the greater is the upper limit on the

binding grant ceiling level. This relationship is shown schematically

by curve OP' in figure 111.3.5. The shaded area A. above OP' repre-

sents the region in which increases in the statutory grant ceiling for

a given matching ratio (for example moving from point III to

point IV ) will not alter the BU's allocation of resources between

X and y. Conversely, the area in B to the right of curve OP' re-

presents the region over which increases in the federal matching share

for a given grant ceiling (for example, movement from point III to

IV ) will not effect changes in the BU's consumption of X and Y.

Finally, the area C between curves OP' and OP' describes the region

over which changes in either the matching provisions, or the statutory

ceiling of a CMC grant will result in a reallocation of the BU's re-

sources amongst highway commodities X and Y. I The actual allocation

1. In terms of our schematic representation of the allocative impactsof CMC grants in figure 111.3.4, regions A , B , and C aredefined as follows:region A --break point in the budget line lies to the right of

the price-consumption curve Y 0region B --break point in the budget ling lies to the left of the

income-consumption curve 00'region C --break point in the budget line lies between the price-

consumption and income-consumption curves.

167

of the BU's resources between X and Y in this region is uniquely de-

fined by the deflection point in the post-CMC grant budget line.

The preceding analysis has served to demonstrate three distinct

response patterns to conditional, matching, close-ended grants. In one

pattern of CMC grant response, what is nominally conditional matching

aid, may in fact have only the influence of an unconditional block

grant. This behavior is manifest in region B of figure 111.3.5, and

is readily observable ex post facto in cases where the recipient govern-

ment devotes more than enough of its own resources to highway commodity

X than the amount required simply to match the federal highway grant.

The allocative impact of grants of this type is to induce a shift in

the resources the BU would have devoted to highway commodity X in the

absence of the CMC grant, to non-aided highway activities.

In those instances where the BU is observed to provide for expen-

ditures on X enabling them to qualify for only part of the total avail-

able federal grant, the CMC grant is allocationally equivalent to a

conditional, matching, open-ended arant. This behavior is represented

in figure 111.3.5 by region A , and may result in a greater or lesser

expenditure of theBU's own resources on highway commodity X, depending

on the price elasticity of the aided function at the pre-grant price

level.

Finally, the behavior response manifest in region C results in

a greater total expenditure on hiohway commodity X than equal amount

non-matching grants, but less than an open-ended grant with the same

168

AFFECT OF GRANT CEILINGS AND PRICE SUBSIDY LEVELS

OPPER LiuiTS oP8O1PWOM GRANT CEiLiAJ&.

...

I / 1~

Lit-FFPEVL rAThflMiA)& 5 HeIRE OFEMENtJiTARSS OJ Hi1HLJAyCOMoPtT X.

Figure 111.3.5

/ P/

169

matching ratio. Allocation of the BU's own resources between X and

Y in this situation again depends on the price elasticity of the BU's

demand for highway commodity X. This response pattern is readily

recognizable ex post facto where the BU just matches the full federal

CMC grant.

iv. Evaluation of Other Grant Program Structures

It should be evident that the analysis framework presented in

the three previous sections may be used to evaluate a wide range of

alternative grant program structures. For completeness, this section

will briefly evaluate the allocative consequences of two additional

cases: conditional, non-matching, close-ended (CNC) grants, and CMC

grants applied to situations where the BU has not previously allocated

any resources to the aided function.

The former case is illustrated in figure 111.3.6, with the pre-

grant equilibrium a point e2 (x2, Y2). Assume now that the federal

government introduces a non-matching grant of y3y4 dollars which is

restricted to expenditure on hgihway commodity X. This grant is re-

presented by budget line y3dJ, indicating that the CNC grant will

wholly finance up to OK1 units of X. Equilibrium in this case is at

point e =(x, y') (where the income-consumption curve 00' intersects

the budget line y3dJ), the allocational equivalent of an unconditional

non-matching grant of the same (y3y4) dollar amount. It follows that

the specificity characteristic of this CNC grant is not allocationally

significant: expenditures on X and Y are the same whether or not the

170

ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONAL NON-MATCHING CLOSE-ENDED GRANTS

C X '

Figure 111.3.6

171

grant is restricted to expenditure on X. This situation occurs wherever

the post-grant consumption of highway commodity X exceeds the statutory

grant ceiling--i.e., expenditures on X include the~BU's own resources.

Moreover, it is clear that this grant has increased expenditures on

non-aided highway functions by the amount y2yA. Thus although the grant

was nominally restricted to expenditure on X, a fraction -*was

y3y4actually diverted to other uses.

The response to CNC aid will be quite different in cases where the

grant ceiling is sufficiently large so as to cause the break point in

the post-grant budget line to fall to the right of the income-con-

sumption curve. For example, a CNC grant ceiling of y3y6 dollars will

produce budget line y3e434 with equilibrium occurring at the break point

e4. In this case, the BU shifts all of its pre-grant expenditures

on highway commodity X to the non-aided functions, using only federal

grant money for expenditure on the aided function. Thus CNC aid with a

sufficiently high grant ceiling results in a greater total expenditure

on highway commodity X than an equivalent amount unconditional grant.

This situation can be easily identified, since none of the BU's own

resources would be observed to support the aided highway function.

The analysis of conditional, matching grants (both open and close-

ended) presented in sections III.3.ii and III.3.iii assumed that the

BU's pre-grant equilibrium included positive levels of consumption of

highway commodity X, and other highway functions Y. This section con-

cludes with a discussion of the response to CMC and CMO grants in cases

172

where the BU has not previously allocated any resources to the aided

function.

In terms of figure 111.3.7, we assume an initial equilibrium at

e3=(O,y3). This solution obtains if the indifference curves (U1, ... U4)

are everywhere less steep than the budget line y3J, i.e.:

S9U9X < P V X > 0

3Y

Introduction of a conditional matching, open-ended grant is represented

by the budget line y3K, and yields a new equilibrium at e4=(x4, y4)i

Expenditures on highway commodity X in this case total y0y5 dollars.

Of this amount, yy3 dollars derive from the BU's own resources, re-

presenting a diversion of expenditures originally devoted to the non-

aided function. The remainder of the total post-grant expenditures on

X, y3y5 are supplied by the federal government.

If the grant had been of the CMC variety, equilibrium would occur

at either e4 or the break point in the CMC budget line, whichever comes

first. It should be noted that of all the grant structure/response

patterns discussed in the previous sections the case presented here is

the only one in which the post-grant reallocation of the BU's resources

always involves an increase in expenditures on the aided function

from the BU's own revenues

1. Assuming that the slope of the indifference curve 04 at y3 issteeper than the new budget line y3K.

173

ANALYSIS OF RESPONSES TO GRANTS FOR FUNCTIONS

NOT PREVIOUSLY UNDERTAKEN BY STATE GOVERNMENTS

Ye.

X6 7 K

Figure 111.3.7

v. Summary of the Responses to Alternative Grant Structures 17

In the preceding sections, an attempt has been made to

provide a descriptive theoretical framework for the analysis

of State Highway expenditure responses to alternative Federal-

Aid grant structures. While it is clear that the model

presented here presumes a degree of economic "rationality" that

ignores the administrative and political realities of State High-

way investment decision making, the analyses do advance a set

of hypotheses that may be modified to account for specific quali-

fications.1 To the extent that a relaxation of the underlying

assumptions do not alter the fundamantal logic of the models, these

analyses serve to place bounds on the expected pattern of State High-

way expenditure behavior.

Figure 111.3.8. a summarizes the relative impacts of alter-

native grant structures on State Highway expenditures. The horizon-

tal axis measures the magnitude of Federal grants, while the vertical

axis describes the post grant total (Federal + State) expenditures

on highway commodity X. It follows that point E describes the BU's

pre-grant expenditure level on X.

In comparing the responses to various grant programs, it is

useful to distinguish between two different behavioral patterns:

expenditure stimulation and expenditure substitution. The former

1 A discussion of the critical assumptions of the preceding analysesand possible modifications to the model results is presented atthe end of this section vi.

175

SUMMARY OF STATE RESPONSES TO ALTERNATIVE FEDERAL GRANT STRUCTURES

$I

TiTAL (sTare +FEDERAL) fKPeAJpiTU0A HIGH L)6AYCOMMODITY

EC: CMC grant response locusEI: CMO grant response locusEJ: UNC grant response locusEH: CNC grant response locus

Figure III.3.8.a

r

expenditurestimulation j

expenditurea substituion

'2

ToTAL AVAILABLEFEDERAL A(P

BXPENDITUARESor x and y

or I ~ 4W 0+01g

I

-. Sb

a

Figure III.3.8.b

I

A f1s,

If-E0 4

case obtains when the effect of the Federal grant is to increase 176

State expenditures on the aided highway function from own sources.

In other words, in these situations the State reallocates resources

from non-aided functions to expenditure on the aided highway cate-

gory. The contrary case, expenditure substitution obtains whenever

total post-grant expenditures on the aided function increase by

less than the amount of the Federal grant. The allocational con-

sequence here is a decrease in the level of State expenditures on

the aided function with a commensurate increase in expenditure

on non-aided functions. In terms of figure III.3.8.a, the expen-

diture stimulation and expenditure substitution response patterns

are indentified by the regions lying to the left and right respec-

tively of the line EF.

It is evident that of the four grant responses shown in figure

III.3.8.a only conditional matching (either open or close-ended) may

induce expedditure stimulation on the aided function. The curve

EG traces the expenditure response to succeeding by higher levels

of CMC grant funding (at a matching ratio of CD ). We assume thatAD

at the pre-grant price of highway commodity X (Af_ ),the BU was in theAC--

elastic portion of its demand for X.i For grant levels below OP.

dollars, the CMC grant is allocationally equivalent to the equiva-

lent amount UNC grants, (c.f. section III.3.iii) and thus curve EC

begins along the same locus as EJ in the expenditure substitution

1 This is indicated in figure III.3.8.b by the negative slope ofthe price consumption curve OB' at the pre-grant equilibrium Z0.

177region. Beyond the grant ceiling OP, the CMC grant yields equili-

bria at the break points along line segment Z5Z1 (figure III. 3. 8.b),

with expenditures on highway commodity X from the BU's own re-

sources increasing at the margin. When the grant ceiling reaches

the level 0P2, the BU's expenditures on highway commodity X net of

grants equals its pre-grant allocation to X (as indicated by point

Zl). Thus, above this level of Federal aid, the CMC grant serves

as an expenditure stimulant. Expenditures on X from the BU's own

revenues exceed their pre-grant level, ultimately reaching a maxi-

mum increase of G dollars at a grant ceiling of OP3. Beyond the

grant ceiling OP3, no further reallocation of expenditures between

highway commodity X1 and other functions Y occurs.

In a similar fashion, we can construct the curve EI to suggest

the locus of expenditure responses to conditional, matching, open-

ended grants with succeedingly higher matching ratios. In this case,

the higher the Federal matching ratio of the CMO grant, the greater

will be the amount of Federal money expended by the BU. Moreover,

since the BU was assumed to be initially in the elastic portion of

its demand for highway commodity X, expenditures on the aided func-

tion begin in the expenditure stimulation region above the threshold

line EF. Unitary price elasticity corresponds to aid OP3 (matching

ratio C), beyond which X expenditure substitution obtains at theAD

margin. Ultimately, beyond Federal aid levels of OP5 dollars

(matching ratio CE),the CMO grant yields an expenditure substitution 178

AE

response, with post-grant expenditures on X from the BU's own sources

falling below their pre-grant level. The limiting case here is a

CMO grant with a 100% Federal share--in other words a conditional

non-matching grant. Thus, as the Federal share payable approaches

100%, the curve El approaches the response locus EH associated

with conditional, non-matching close ended grants.

The response to unconditional block (i.e. non-matching) grants

exhibits the most significant expenditure substitution behavior.

In this case, a fraction of the UNC grants would be expected to be

devoted to highway commodity X as a direct substitute for the BU's

own X expenditures. The curve EJ traces the response locus to UNC

grants with succeedingly higher grant ceilings. This curve lies

entirely in the expenditure substitution response region, its slope

depending on the BU's marginal propensity to consume highway com-

modity X with higher levels of income.1 For UNC aid beyond the level

OP4 dollars, the BU substitutes its entire pre-grant expenditures

on X to non-aided activities Y, exclusively using Federal aid to

purchase highway commodity X.

1 The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is defined as the inverseslope of the income-consumption curve AA'. Two limiting casesserve to place bounds on the UNC response locus Ed. If theincome-consumption curve is vertical (MPC=0), then each Federal-aiddollar is substituted one-for-one with the BU's own expenditureson X. The UNC grant response locus in this case is defined by EKin figure III.3.8.a. Conversely, if the MPC=co(income-consumptioncurve horizontal), then each Federal-aid dollar is fully expended onhighway commodity X with pre-grant X expenditures remaining fixed.

The case is represented by the UNC grant response locus EF.

179The expenditure response to conditional, non-matching, close-

ended grants is similar to the UNC grant response. As shown by

response locus EH, CNC grants are allocationally equivalent to UNC

grants below the funding level EP4 dollars. At that point, leakage

of grant money into non-aided highway activities (as measured by HIH2,

the vertical distance between EH and the 450 line OH) has reached

the level of pre-grant expenditures on highway commodity X (OE).

Further leakage is prevented as additional levels of CNC funding

is wholly devoted to X at the margin, and response locus EH diverges

from Ed.

Table 111.3.3 summarizes the most significant findings of the

preceding analysis. Of paramount importance is recognition of the

fact that changes in the structure of a Federal-aid grant program

may result in fundamental changes in the recipient government's

allocation of resources among alternative transportation commodities.

In this context our analysis framework can be used to address ques-

tions such as:

1) What is the least expensive means for the Federal government to

achieve a specified target expenditure by the recipients on

the aided highway functions?

2) For a given ceiling on Federal highway aid, which grant program

stipulations would be most favored by the recipient government?

Grant Response Pattern180

Response Locus(Figure III.3.8.a)

For relatively bigh matching ratios EI approaches EH at highand large grant ceilings, the allo- Federal grant levels

cative difference between condition-al matching and non-matching grantsare insignificant.

IL

Conditional close-ended matching Segment EG2 on responsegrants may be allocationally equi- locus EGvalent to unconditional block

2 grants for sufficiently low grantceilings. In these cases, thegrants result in expenditure sub-stitution on the aided function.

Only conditional matching grants Segment EI, on response(either open or close-ended) can locus EI.

3 be expectdd to increase expendi- Segment G3G on responsetures on the aided function by locus EGmore than the amount of the grant.

Unless the grant ceiling is not Response locus EG, andbinding, CMC grants have a lesser segment EG on responsestimulatory impact than a CMO locus EIgrant with the same matching ratio.

The specificity requirement on a Segment EHI on response5 conditional non-matching close- locus EH

ended grant may have no alloca-tive significant

6 Expenditure stimulation will be Not shownbreatest where CMO grants are ap-plied to highway functions notpreviously undertaken.

SUMMARY OF GRANT RESPONSES

Table 111.3.3

It is not surprising to note that the answers to these two 181

questions indicate a conflict in the preferences of the donor and

donee governments. If one of the goals of the Federal government

is to maximize the "return" on their grant (in terms of achieving

the greatest expenditure on the aided function for a given level

of Federal aid), they will always prescribe matching provisions

on their highway grant programs. The States, on the other hand,

would alwaysl find unconditional or block grants preferable to

conditional grants with the equivalent ceiling.

Another related finding of our theoretical analysis is that

under certain circumstances grant programs with categorical restric-

tions are allocationally equivalent to block grants (c.f. lines

1,2 and 5 of table 111.3.3). In these instances, the grant pro-

grams should be evaluated in terms of their income-redistributive

characteristics (e.g. whether they channel higher levels of aid

into poorer States), rather than in terms of their allocative ef-

ficiency characteristics. These issues will be discussed in greater

detail in section 111.4.

vi. Qualifications on the Theoretical Analyses

The validity of the theoretical findings derived in the pre-

ceding sections ultimately rests on the practicality of the under-

lying assumptions of our model. Basically, there are three crucial

assumptions upon which our theoretical analysis rests:

1 Except under certain restrictive conditions. See line 2 oftable 111.3.3.

1821) There is an identifiable behavioral unit at the State level

that expresses a consistent set of preferences among alterna-

tive transportation services.

2) These preferences may be represented by a map of continuous

indifference curves

3) Grant money receives no special treatment beyond the stipula-

tions made by the Federal government.

The first of these assumptions is perhaps the most difficult

to justify. Clearly, our reference to a "behavioral unit" ignores

the existence of the numerous political agencies and private forces

whose choices among alternative transportation projects often con-

flict. It is certainly true that on any given transportation pro-

ject, it would be simplistic to presume that a single individual

or a monolithic agency solely determines the investment decisions.

However, our model deals with overall budget behavior--that is,

decisions on the level of expenditure to be devoted to generic

transportation activities. We do not distinguish between the scale

or location of individual highway projects, but only between the

overall expenditure levels on aided and non-aided highway activities.

In this context, our assumption boils down to an assertion that a single

State agency (e.g. a State Highway Department/Commission or Depart-

ment of Transportation) sets forth an investment policy determining

the allocation of revenues amongst transportation investment alter-

natives in broad, generic categories. 1 183

It is nonetheless the case that in any given year, these cate-

gorical investments are comprised of a finite set of discrete pro-

jects whose individual cost may represent a sizable fraction of the

total investment. The implications here relate to the second as-

sumption of our analysis, that the indifference curves are continuous

functions of categorical highway expenditures. To the extent that

the demands for alternative highway commodities are expressed in

terms of discrete investment levels, the indifference curves will

be piecewise linear rather than continuous. We assume that this

qualification does not fundamentally alter the expenditure response

patterns indicated by our models.

The validity of the third assumption is not testable in any

empirical sense. However, there are two reasons to suspect that

the receipt of grant money may have the effect of shifting the

recipient government's indifference map. 2 The first reason is the

commonly held notion that it is "bad politics" to turn down a

Federal grant. This view argues that Federal grants are "some-

I For example, this policy might be expressed in terms of decisionsto spend a certain fraction of revenues on maintenance, another frac-tion on the State Primary Highway System, and a third fractionon the State Secondary Highway System. In some States these"decisions" are actually dictated by statute. In others, a Statehighway agency makes these decisions on a (multi-) year to (mlti-)year basis.

2 It should be noted that an indifference map describes the trade-offs amongst alternative goods irrespective of the prices of thosegoods. As discussed in the previous sections, changes in the pricesof the aided highway functions enter into our model through shiftsin the budget line, not the indifference map.

184thing special," or "free money," to be spent at all costs. Clearly,

if this is the case, the States will behave differently than our

models predict.

There is another possible explanation for a deviation from

our models'predictions which relates to "spin-off effects." Sup-

pose a State must choose between a major intercity freeway projectl

costong $100 million, and an arterial route costing $10 million.

After weighing the costs and benefits, assume the arterial route were

strongly preferred. At this point, however, the Federal government

offers to pay 90% of the freeway costs. With the costs equalized,

the State would choose between the two projects solely on the basis

of benefits. Let us assume that the State still prefers the arter-

ial project. If that were the extent of the decision, the grant offer

would be declined. However, this decision could be reversed by a

broader view of benefits. In a macro-economic context, the freeway

project has the advantage of bringing an additional $90 million into

the State's economy (which translates into increased income and

employment). Thus the macro-economic context for aid recipients

may be a vital factor in expenditure decisions and grant response.

The implication of the "free money" or "spin-off effect"

arguments is that Federal highway grants may induce a greater expen-

diture stimulation response than our models would predict. But

in order for this to be the case, we would have to observe the

IThis exapfple is placed in the setting of project selection, butthe same arguments apply to the broader question of overall bud-get allocation.

185States making expenditures on the aided highway functions less than

or just equal to amount required to match a full close-ended Federal

matching grant (see section III.3.v). Our model would appear to

be valid in cases where an expenditure substitution response is

associated with the Federal grant. In cases where our model pre-

dicts an expenditure stimulation response to a Federal highway

matching grant, the arguments advanced above indicate that the

model results may understate the expenditure levels on the aided

highway functions. As will be discussed in detail in section 111.4,

the majority of States exhibits an expenditure substitution response

to Federal highway grants.

186

111.4 The Analytics of State Responses to Federal Grants:The Benefit/Cost Investment Model

The previous section discussed the analytics of State

responses to Federal grants in terms of the allocation of

highway resources amongst alternative expenditure categories.

The basis of this discussion was that States allocate resources

so as to maximize their perceived benefits (utility).

The question of highway resource allocation can be

approached from a somewhat different perspective. In particular,

this section will present a benefit/cost investment model which

focuses on the level of resources raised from a States own

sources, in response to a variety of Federal highway grant

structures.1

i. A Hypothetical Example

Assume that a particular State has developed a set of

candidate highway projects, and is prepared to expend funds on

these projects up to the point where the benefit/cost ratio on

the "last" project is just equal to 1.0. More explicitly, we

assume that the State has ranked the projects in order of

1. For an application of this approach, see Miller, Edward,"The Economics of Matching Grants: The ABC Highway Program,"National Tax Journal, Vol. 27, No. 2, June, 1974.

187

decreasing benefit cost ratio as shown in figure 111.4.1.2

For the hypothetical values displayed in figure 111.4.1

the State is willing to expend a total of $10 million to imple-

ment projects 1 through 10. At this point, assume the Federal

government steps in and offers a grant of $G with the provision

that this grant must be matched dollar for dollar by the State

government (i.e. the matching rate is 50%). It may be argued

that there are three possible responses to the presence of the

Federal grant, depending on the size of the grant G:

Case I. $0< G 4$5M: Pure Income Effect

This case applies where the sum of the Federal grant G

and the State's matching share is less than the total amount the

State was apparently willing to expend on highways in the absence

of Federal grants. For example, assume the Federal grant

offered is $3.M After providing for the required matching

share, the State has expended $6.M This leaves a remainder of

2. It has often been noted that optimal project selection doesnot necessarily simply consist of those projects with thehighest benefit/cost ratios. (For example, see Pecknold,Wayne M., Evolution of Transport Systems: An Analysis of Time-Staged Investment Strategies Under Uncertainty, UnpublishedPh.D. Thesis, M.I.T. Department of Civil Engineering, 1970,and Newman, Lance, A Time-Staged Strategic Approach to Trans-portation System Planning, Unpublished S.M. Thesis, M.I.T.Department of Civil Engineering, 1972). In the presentationthat follows, we nonetheless make the assumption that Stateswill not choose to implement projects whose perceived B/Cratio is less than unity.

ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE188

OF THE BENEFIT/COST INVESTMENTMODEL

Project No. B/C Total Cost (Millions of Dollars)

1.6

2.3

.7

10.0 - Cost of projects withB/C > 1.0

1.2

.6

.3

5.0 - Cost of projects with.5 .6 B/C( 1.0

.9

1.1

1.0

5.0 - Cost of projects withB/C 4.5

Figure III.4 1

1

2

Region I

10

7.6

6.9

1.0

11

12

Region 2

17

18

19

.97

.84

.50

.46

.41

Region 3

24 .23

189

projects costing $4M whose B/C ratio exceeds unity. Since, the

Federal grant has been exhausted there is no incentive to expand

the highway program beyond the previously determined level of

$10.M Thus, the net effect of the $3M Federal grant has been to

reduce the level of resources expended from the State's own

sources. Total highway expenditures remain unchanged, as the

State's own expenditures are reduced by just the amount of

Federal grant. This situation represents the case of a pure

income grant, where the close-ended grant is not of sufficient

magnitude to create a perceived price reduction at the margin.

As far as the State is concerned, the grant has had the effect

of providing an additional $3M of income to be expended on other

State services or "spent" on tax relief.

Admittedly, this conclusion presents a somewhat extreme

case. While the overall characterization of this type of grant

as an income subsidy remains valid, realistically it is not

necessarily the case that State expenditures on highways would be

reduced dollar for dollar by the amount of the Federal grant.

For one thing, it should again be noted that because of the

indivisibility and "lumpiness" of highway investments, the

presence of additional highway revenue might substantially alter

the project mix (and therefore the total expenditure level) of

an optimal highway investment program. Another mitigating

factor here is the restriction in most States against expenditure

190

of earmarked highway revenue on non-highway projects. The

consequence of this restriction (and particularly in the short

run where changes in State revenue raising sources - e.g. tax

rates, are not possible) is that at least part of the additional

revenue may be expended on the aided highway category, thus

increasing total expenditures on this function.

More importantly however, is the fact that any expansion

in total expenditures on the aided highway category results from

the chosen allocation the additional income derived from the

grant as opposed to any perceived price reduction on the aided

function. By the same token, it is likely that expenditures

on non-aided (highway) functions will be increased from the

additional income afforded by the grant.

Case II. $5M< G4$7 .5M Price Plus Income Effect

For the hypothetical situation depicted in figure 111.4.1,

once G exceeds the level of $5 million, the grant introduces both

a price and income effect on the State's allocation decisi3ns.1

1. A price effect refers to changes in the allocation of re-sources deriving from a change in the perceived price of oneor more expenditure items. Allocational shifts also derivefrom an income effect where the State allocates additionalincome on highway commodities whose perceived prices remainunchanged. A grant may introduce a pure income effect ora combination of a price effect and income effect. For amore detailed discussion of these concepts see Henderson J.M.and R.E. Quandt, Microeconomic Theory: A MathematicalApproach, McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York, 1958.

191

To see this, assume the Federal grant offered, G is $7 million.

Since the State was apparently willing to expend $10 million

from its own sources, it is clear that at least $5 million of

the grant will be used. At this point total expenditures amount

to $10 million, all projects with B/C greater than one have been

programmed, and $2 million of Federal grants remain available.

The remaining Federal grant has the effect of reducing the cost

of additional highway construction to the State by one-half.

In other words, the perceived B/C ratio of projects remaining

on the candidate list increase by a factor of two. Since the

B/C ratio of projects in Region 2 (see figure 111.4.1) fall in

the range 0.5 to 1, the availability of Federal grants increase

the perceived B/C ratio of these projects over unity.

Following the simple criterion that all projects with

(perceived) B/C 1 will be prograrrned, it is clear that the

State will employ the remaining Federal grant, bringing total

expenditures on the aided function to $14 million. Once the

entire Federal grant has been employed, there is no longer any

incentive for expansion of the highway program, since the State

must now bear the full cost of projects whose B/C ratio is less

than one.

While the net effect of this grant has been to increase

total expenditures, for a Federal investment of $7 million, total

expenditures increase by only $4 million (from $10 million in the

192

absence of grants to $14 million with the grant). The expendi-

ture increase derives from the price effect of the matching grant

at the margin (i.e. at the point where the State decides to

program projects in region 2 of figure IIM.4.1). It should also

be noted that total expenditures from the State's own sources

decrease from $10 million in the pre-grant situation to $7 million

in the post-grant situation. As in Case I, the saving in State

resources may be spent on other services, or translated into tax

reductions.

Case III G>$ 7 .5M: No Effect at the Margin

Following the same reasoning as presented in Case II, it

is clear that the State will not have an incentive to employ

Federal grants in excess of $7.5 million. Since all projects in

region 3 of figure 111.4.1 have a B/C ratio less than 0.5, the

availability of 50% Federal matching grants will not bring the

perceived B/C ratio of region 3 projects over one. Thus, for

this hypothetical example, the maximum grant level that will

willingly be employed by the State is $7.5M (this amount will

cover half the costs of all projects in region 1 and region 2).

At this grant level, total expenditures on the aided function

amount to $15M divided evenly between State and Federal funds.

This situation represents an increase in total expenditures by

$5M, but a decrease in State's own expenditures by $2.5

193

ii. A Diagrammatic Description

These three cases can be summarized diagrarnatically as

in figure 111.4.2. We assume that the State expresses a demand

for highway construction represented by the demand schedule

D1D1. Thus, for the full price of highway construction (i.e. in

the absence of grants), the State will purchase Q1 units of

highway at a total cost of ObcQ1 dollars. Case I of our previous

discussion is represented by the price line arsp. In particular,

50% matching grants are available up to a ceiling of Q0 highway

units. Beyond this level of highway expenditure, the State again

faces the full price of highways. As previously noted, the

State response to this grant is to maintain its previous produc-

tion scale of Q, units. Total expenditures from the State's own

sources is indicated in the figure by area OarQ1 (the full cost

borne by the State of highway construction up to the level Q).

This represents a decrease in State expenditures by Q0 rdQ1 dollars.

For the larger grant ceiling described in Case II, the

relevant price line is depicted by aefp, The response in this

instance is to expand production up to Q2 highway units at a

total cost to the State of OaeQ2 dollars. As in the previous

situation, State expenditures decrease from the pre-grant situa-

tion - in this case by the difference between areas abcd and

QadeQ2 '

Finally, the price line corresponding to Case III is

194

DIAGRAMMATIC DESCRIPTION OF THE BENEFIT/COST INVESTMENT MODEL

ufir PRfaC oFIGNLwI F-Acikrits

1 p4

e -C

P

'In A-

TZz

,trr'K VC i 4*

0 QQ( 3 PMWW+ 1 Cp0f4t~OiO Gi Qz Q ~~q(AA13?rTl OF HiR~n &MS s o

5TA~Tr EKftOPWUtES 10_ _E AbwkcZ oF &RSwT

-4TtWE~eEAPD(TI(&sArTCR aN6Ars.

Figure 111.4.2

0

/

/

7

/7

///

/

/7

7/

//

4-

/

- a -

firz z -m-4T T X V 'lr"r

ILlI I %

0

195

shown as amkp. Since this price line intersects the demand

schedule D1D,, the State will expand its highway program only as

far as Q 3 units, leaving Q3gmQ4 dollars of the Federal grant un-

expended. Total State expenditure in this case is OagQ3, a

decrease of abcd - QdgQ3 from the pre-grant situation.

M11. Conclusions From the Benefit/Cost Investment Model

An immediate conclusion that can be reached from the

preceding analysis is that:

Whereas the Federal government provides categoricalgrants presumably for those types of activities inwhich it perceives a national interest in stimula-ting expenditures (i.e. in inducing construction thatmay not have been undertaken in the absence of thegrant), the net result may be the expansion ofexpenditures (or contraction through tax relief) inother (non-aided) areas in which the Federal govern-ment has no officially stated interest.

This conclusion derives from the income effect of

close-ended matching grants, which under certain conditions such

as Case I of the preceding analysis, serve only as a non-cate-

gorical income subsidy to the States.1 In fact, in the preceding

hypothetical example, regardless of the ceiling of a 50% Federal

matching grant, post-grant State expenditures decrease from their

pre-grant level (and thus the savings incurred may be expended in

1. As described in Section 111.3, as long as the grant ceilingof a close-ended matching grant is low enough so as to benon-binding on the States investment calculus, the categoricalrestrictions of the grant are irrelevant. The allocationalconsequences of a grant of this type are identical to a simpleblock grant of like amount.

196

other areas).

This expenditure response pattern need not have been the

case however. As shown in figure 111.4.2 (and in the analysis

describing figure 111.4.1), the States demand for highway facili-

ties, expressed by the schedule D301 represents inelastic demand.

That is, a decrease in price by one-half results in less than a

doubling of total expenditures. It is entirely possible that a

State's expressed demand for highway construction may be elastic,

for example as depicted by the schedule D2D2 in figure 111.4.2.

In this case total State expenditures following the offer of a

50% Federal matching grant with a ceiling in excess of OahQ4

dollars exceed pre-grant expenditures by the amount QdhQ4 -

abcd (c.f. Section III.3.ii). However, regardless of the

elasticity properties of the State's expressed demand for highway

facilities, if the Federal grant in question has the properties

described in Section III.4.ii as Case I, the unambiguous conclu-

sion is that the categorical restrictions of the matching grant

are non-binding, resulting in a stimulation of State expenditures

on non-aided functions. For grants with ceilings sufficiently

large to fall into the categories described as Case II and

Case III, State expenditure response indeed depends on its

elasticity of demand for highway construction. For these cases,

elastic (inelastic) demand will result in a increase (decrease)

of State expenditures frpm their pre-grant levels.1 In the

next section, a brief analysis of actual highway expenditure

data will be presented to illustrate the conclusions discussed

above.

1. Several factors influence the price elasticity of a State'sdemand for highway construction including the level andgrowth in traffic on State roads, and tax capacity of theState (i.e. the propensity of the State to tap additionalrevenue sources or the willingness to increase levies onexisting revenue sources. In the context of the illustra-tive examples presented in this section, the price elasticityas expressed by the State's response to a Federal matchinggrant is determined solely by the number of projects inregion 2 of figure 111.4.1. Specifically, if in developinga list of mutually exclusive candidate projects for itshighway investment program, a State perceives numerousprojects marginally unattractive in benefit/cost terms (i.e.projects with B/C slightly less than one), then a relativelysmall Federal price subsidy may elicit a large expansion inthe State's highway investment program (representing priceelastic demand for highway facilities).

197

198

111.5 Observed Expenditure Patterns: The Impact of theABC and Interstate Programs

The analysis in Section 111.4 proceeded on the basis of a

State developing a highway investment program in the absence of

Federal highway grants, and then altering their investment

decisions in response to the offer of Federal matching grants.

Three possible response patterns were described (Cases I, II

and III), each dependent on the matching provisions and magni-

tude of the grant offer.

In examining data indicating the States' total expenditure

levels on Federal Aid System construction and Federal highway

grant availability, it is clear that we are merely observing

the States' expenditure responses to Federal highway grants

rather than - in any direct fashion - observing how expenditure

decisions changed due to the existence of Federal grants.

However, by simply comparing the magnitude of Federal

grant availability, and the level of expenditure from the State's

own resources (on Federal Aid Systems), it can be straightfor-

wardly inferred which of the three previously cited expenditure

response patterns obtain (c.f. Section III.4.ii).

For grants which have a pure income effect (Case r), we

should observe a State consistently expanding their own highway

expenditures beyond that level minimally required to match avail-

able Federal grants. In this case, the size of the grant is not

199

of sufficient magnitude to introduce a perceived price reduction

at the investment margin. By inference, this type of grant

simply provides additional non-categorical income to the State,

which may be expended on any highway function.

If on the other hand, the data indicate that State

expenditures consistently just equal the minimal amount required

to match available Federal grants, then a price plus income

effect may be inferred. In this case (Case II), the grant has

had the effect of stimulating additional expenditures on the

aided category, and increases in the size of the Federal grant

may be expected to further stimulate State expenditures. 1

Finally, if the data indicates that States consistently

do not exhaust all available Federal Aid, then it is clear that

Case III obtains. It should be noted that we can imediately

rule out the relevance of Case II since in only one isolated

instance has a State (actually, "State" in question was

Washington, D.C., who forfeited a portion of available Inter-

state aid in 1971) failed to obligate the entirety of available

Federal highway grants.

i. Data Analysis of the ABC Highway Program

Table 111.5.1 displays (for each of the 48 mainland

1. As opposed to (small) increases in Case I - type grants. wheretotal expenditures on the aided function would not be expectedto increase significantly.

EXCESS FRACTIONSTATE

ALAARIZARKCALICOLOCONNDELFLORGEOIDAILLINDIOWAKAN SKENTLOUSME.MD.MASSMICHMINNMISSMSRIMONTNEB.NEV.N.H.N.J.N.M.N.Y.N.C.N.D.OHIOOKLAORE.PENNR.I.S.C.S.D.TENNTEX.UTAHVER.VA.WASHW.V.WISCWYo.

0.2895070.3751060.2353340.6368630.1889150.6450650.3604640.5785870.1965940.0862080.1428460.1221150.4729780.2378510.4016870.5190690.2034550.6934030.4549650.3872450.3597320.3146450.3890250.0535280.1097970.1932990.3214080.2450890.1282080.5305050.2635330.0338980.5451560.2555550.3644900.5325040.1976070.2762880.2700030.4216650.3917980.1944220.2932340.5163240.4779080.5739080.4309310.157235

TIME PERIOD: 1954-1970

Source: Yearly Editions of HIGHWAY STATISTICS (1954-1970),U.S. Bureau of Public Roads, Washington, D.C.

Table 111.5.1

STATE EXPENDITURES OVER AND

ABOVE MINIMAL MATCHING

REQUIREMENTS EXPRESSED AS

A FRACTION OF TOTAL EXPENDI-

TURES ON "ABC" SYSTEMS

200

201

States, over the time period 1954-1970) expenditures over

and above minimal matching requirements, expressed as a fraction

of total expenditures on "ABC" systems. More significantly, each

table entry is defined as:

ef = (ETPF) I[ 1 -F HPF (12)MF

ET

where: ef = excess fraction (i.e. the table entries)

ET = total expenditures by a given State overthe 17 year sample period on ABC Systems(State and Federal monies)

1MF = Federal matching share for a given State

PF= Payments of Federal ABC monies from theHighway Trust Fund to a given State overthe 17 year sample period

The term in brackets in equation (13) expresses the expen-

diture level from the States' own sources required to qualify for

receipt of PF Federal Aid dollars. Thus, the numerator expresses

1. As shown in figure , the Federal share payable is notequal for all States. The 13 Public Land States receiveABC grants with Federal shares payable ranging from 53.5%(Washington) to 95.0% (Alaska). The remaining States allare subject to 50/50 ABC grants. Additionally the Federalshare of grants to Public Land States change slightlfrom year to year in response to these States 'totalacreageof National Parks, Indian Reservations, etc. The data infigure 111.5.1 employed the Federal share payable in 1962 -the median year in the 17 year sample period.

202

the States' own excess expenditures beyond minimally required

matching monies.

The excess expenditure fractions in table 111.5.1 range

in value from 3.4% in North Dakota to 69.4% in Maryland. In

the latter case, of the total (State plus Federal monies ABC

system investment by Maryland, between 1954 and 1970 nearly

70% represented expenditures net of minimal matching require-

ments.

In fact, only three of the forty eight States (Idaho,

Montana and North Dakota) had excess expenditures totaling less

than 10% of the their total ABC expenditures. The inescapable

conclusion here is that for the great majority of States, the

ABC grant program has served the role of non-categorical

income subsidies. Neither the categorical restrictions, nor

the matching provisions have been allocationally significant.

In terms of the States' investment calculus, the determination

of total ABC system expenditures have been based on the full

cost of the marginal project rather than a price subsidized

(50%) cost. Inferentially, it makes little difference whether

the Federal share payable were 50% or some higher value - say

70%.l To see this, consider the example of New York's ABC

1. In fact, the Federal share payable on ABC systems wasincreased from 50% to 70% effective July 1, 1974.

203

system expenditure and grant availability in 1963 (table 111.5.2)

Given a 50% Federal matching share, it would cost New York

$60,315,000 to match the Federal payments made available. But

considering that New York was willing to expend over $200 million

on ABC system construction (from its own sources), it makes

little difference whether the first $60 million or the first $26

million went towards matching available Federal funds. Only the

price at the margin is important. Thus it is apparent that for

New York and most other States, we should expect increases in

ABC grants to have a relatively small impact (through an income

effect) on total ABC systems expenditures.

ii. Data Analysis of the Interstate Highway Program

As discussed in Section 11.2 , the Interstate highway

program differs in three important respects from the ABC

highway program. In magnitude, Federal grants for the Interstate

program exceeded ABC grants over the period 1954-1970 by

231%. Additionally, the basic Federal share payable for the

Interstate program amounts to 90% as compared to a 50% share

payable towards ABC projects. But perhaps the most fundamental

difference - at least in terms of States' expenditure responses

to Federal grants - is the fact that, unlike the ABC program,

the Interstate program represents a closed system. Total system

mileage and general corridor locations for the system were

204

ABC System ExpenditureslGrants

New York: 1963

(1000's of dollars)

50% Federal 70% FederalShare Share

Federal payments 60315

Required State matching funds 60315 25849

States' own expenditures 200964

"Excess expenditures" 140649 175115

Percentage excess expenditure 53.8% 67.0%

Table 111.5.2

205

determined years before the first Federal dollar was expended on

the system. Moreover, Federal Interstate grants are awarded

to the States on the basis of the relative cost to complete their

portion of the approved system, unlike ABC grants which are

fixed without regard to the level of investment chosen by the

State.

For these reasons, it may be inferred that States have

little incentive to expand Interstate highway construction sig-

nificantly beyond the level provided for by the Federal grants.

This expectation is borne out by the data in table 111.5.3 indi-

cating the States' expenditures over and above minimal matching

requirements, expressed as a fraction of total expenditures on

the Interstate system over the period 1954-1970 (refer to

equation 13). The excess expenditure fractions range from a

low value of 0l (North Dakota) to a high value of 37.7% in

Rhode Island. It is immediately clear that relative to expendi-

tures made on the ABC system, most States expend little more

than the minimally required amount necessary to qualify for

1. The negative value appearing for North Dakota indicates anerror in the data reported in HIGHWAY STATISTICS. Note thatan excess expenditure fraction less than zero would suggesta State not meeting its minimal matching requirement forthe receipt of Federal Funds. We shall assume that theexcess expenditures for North Dakota are essentially zero.

EXCESS FRACTION

ALAARIZARKCAL ICOLOCONNDELFLORGEOIDAILLINDIOWAKANSKENTLOUSME.MD.MASSMICHMINNMissMSRIMONTNEB.NEV.N.H.N.J.N. M.N. Y.N. C.N. 0.OHIO KLAORE.PENNR.I.S.C.S.D.TENNTEX.UTAHVER.VA.WASHW.V.WISCWYO.

0.0337060.1416950.0421720.2602110.0937790.1058660.1195800.1135270.1166680.0672190.0570980.1163340.1750110.0655200.0718060.0568500.0553360.0956720.1662040.1121190.0671620.0551570.0000280.0036780. 081 9410.0768830.0380500.0815530.0946870.071708

-0. 0433320.0285620.0971820.0922770.0428530.0936730.3769950.0251380.0472250. 0411910.1043520. 1746130.0263710. 0097040.1049550. 0968520.1508280.055882

TIME PERIOD: 1954-1970

Source: Yearly Editions of HIGHWAY STATISTICS (1954-1970),U.S. Bureau of Public Roads, Washington, D.C.

Table 111.5.3

STATE EXPENDITURES OVER AND

ABOVE MINIMAL MATCHING

REQUIREMENTS EXPRESSED AS

A FRACTION OF TOTAL EXPENDI-

TURES ON INTERSTATE SYSTEMS

STATE 206

207

receipt of Interstate grants. Fully thirty three out of the

forty eight States devote less than 10% of their total Interstate

investment towards expenditures beyond the minimal matching

requirement. And with the exception of California and

Rhode Island, all States exhibit an excess expenditure fraction

less than 20%.

Thus, it may safely be concluded that for the vast

majority of States, Interstate grants have been characterized

by a price and income effect. Following the analysis of Section

111.4., we may infer that Interstate grants have induced State

expenditures on projects that would not have been made in the

absence of grants. And by the same token, small increases in

the level or price subsidization of Interstate grants may be

expected to stimulate additional expenditures on the Interstate

system from the States' own resources.

208

III.6 Summaryand Conclusions

This chapter has attempted to define both the normative

and positive analytic issues involved in an investigation of the

Federal Aid Highway Program (FAHP). Two related findings merit

particular attention:

- the design of the FAHP should be related to the objec-tives the Federal government hopes to accomplish throughits grant program

- States' expenditure responses depend significantly onthe structural characteristics of Federal grants.

The former finding derives from the discussion in Section

2 on the normative aspects of the Federal Aid Highway Program.

Summarily, it should be noted that the selection of the appropri-

ate mathcing ratio - indeed the very choice of a Federal matching

grant as opposed to a block grant must be related to the perceived

fiscal problem the grant attempts to rectify. This type of per-

spective gives direction to arguments for and against alterations

to the existing FAHP. For example, it may be argued that the

stipulations in the 1973 Federal Aid Highway Act allowing for the

construction of mass transit facilities under the same grant

provisions as the Urban (highway) System1 is not the appropriate

form of transit aid.

The relevant issue here is that the primary rationale for

1. Close-ended categorical matching grants with a Federal sharepayable of 70%

209

Federal highway grants is entirely different from the rationale

fore transit aid. In the former case, the existence of signi-

ficant interstate benefit spillovers call for external financing

to move towards an efficient allocation of highway resources. In

the latter case, it is primarily the fiscal disparity between

different cities (i.e. the ability of a city to raise sufficient

revenue to provide for a given level of transit service) that

indicates the need for Federal financing. As discussed in Section

2, in the one instance, Federal matching grants are in order; in

the other, block funding is more appropriate.

The second major finding of this chapter is the relationship

between State expenditure responses, and structural characteris-

tics of Federal grants. It has been shown that categorical match-

ing grants will always stimulate greater expgnditure levels than

non-categorical block grants of like amount. In fact, Section 5

presented evidence that the ABC program has failed to serve as a

stimulus for additional construction on the aided systems. In

light of this finding it is important to question the objectives

of the ABC highway grant program. If the intent of Federal

grants for the ABC system was to "accelerate the construction of

Federal-aid highway systems .... since many of such highways or

portions thereof, are in fact inadequate to meet the needs of

local and interstate commerce"I, the program has apparently failed

1. Subpart A, Title 23, United States Code, Chapter 1, Section101(b): Declaration of Policy.

210

to do so. By the same token, the ABC grant program does not

appear to be necessary to ensure a minimal level of provision of

such systems (c.f. Section III.2.iv), since the great majority of

States invest funds far in excess of their minimal matching require-

ments. Indeed, the primary consequences of the ABC grant program

appears to be merely to have provided the States with additional

highway revenue - an outcome that could be achieved in a more

straightforward manner by the institution of non-categorical block

grants. 1

Needless to say, it is important to verify the theoretical

findings in this chapter with empirical evidence. The remaining

chapters of this thesis will discuss a series of econometric models

designed to assess the impacts of the Federal Aid Highway Program

on State highway expenditures.

1. Although this assertion reraises the initial question posedin this section: What are the objectives to be accomplishedby the FAHP.

CHAPTER IV 211

DEVELOPMENT OF THE TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

IV.l Introduction

There are two fundamental dimensions of States' highway expendi-

ture behavior: long run revenue or total expenditure policy

formulation, and short run allocation (programming) determination.

The distinction between revenue policy as a "long-run" phenomenon

and allocation policy as a "short-run phenomenon derives from the

fact that changes in the determinants of State highway revenue(e.g.,

tax rates, bond sales, etc.) tend to be infrequent relative to the

expression of a State's allocation policy (e.g., year-to-year capital

budgeting decisions). The empirical models developed in this

research attempt to explain the factors influencing States' total

highway expenditures, and allocation decisions amongst alternative

highway expenditure categories. Naturally, the central focus of

the research is an evaluation of how Federal grants have affected

States' expenditure behavior.

In this chapter, the development of the total expenditure model

(TEM) is presented. Attempting to build on the common use of "Needs

Studies" as a long run fiscal planning device, Section 2 presents

a derivation of the TEM based on capacity utilization theory. The

major focus of this model is to trace States' total highway expenditure

responses to the presence of Federal highway grants.

Following the derivation of the model, Section 3 explores the

estimation problems inherent in the use of a pooled data set.

212While it would have been desirable to estimate the TEM for each State

individually -- as 48 separate time series -- lack of sufficient

historical data precluded this approach. Accordingly, we describe a

practical approach to estimating the model with both time series and

cross sectional data.

Section 4 describes the definitions and sources of data employed

in our TEM estimation. In many instances, data which would have been

desirable from a theoretical standpoint was not directly available.

The use of proxy information is fully described in this section. Next,

a short discussion is presented on considerations for interpreting

the empirical results. Hypotheses to be tested are discussed in terms

of the signs and magnitudes of specific parameter estimates.

Section 6 describes the actual estimation results of the total

expenditure model. Several alternative specifications are presented

and applied to an 2xperiment where the entire sample was divided into

two distinct subsets. The results convincingly demonstrate the States'

differing expenditure responses to the Interstate and ABC grant programs.

Finally, the major results and policy implications derived from

the estimation of the total expenditure model are set forth in

Section 7.

213IV.2 Derivation of the Model

It is convenient to conceptualize States' highway expenditure

behavior in terms of two dimensions:

1. decisions relating to the determination of the magnitudeof the States' highway budget in any given year, and

2. decisions relating to the allocation of that budget amongstalternative types of highway expenditure categories (e.g.Interstate, Primary System, maintenance, administration, etc.)

In fact, it may be argued that this analysis perspective is not

merely an artificial construct. While the administrative and political

realities of altering tax rates and debt obligation (and thus altering

total expenditure levels) inhibit quick adjustments to changes in

costs and demand,I the program selection (programming) process

operates on a relatively short cycle time.I

We focus here on the derivation of a model to explain the

derivation of a model to explain the first of the two dimensions of

State behavior: the determination of total highway expenditures.

An immediate starting point is an examination of the "Needs Study"

process. The highway needs process has been incorporated into the

U.S. Department of Transportation's biennial National Transportation

Studies, required of all States as of 1968. But prior to this time

to this time several States conducted explicit internal highway needs

studies for their own fiscal planning purposes at varying intervals.

In its simplest terms, a (highway) needs study involves the

Highway bond sales are usually issued over a two to five year period.The average duration between tax rate adjustments is ever longer.Over the fifteen-year period, 1951-1965, the average duration betweenthe States' tax rate adjustments was somewhat over ten years.

determination of the desired ("needed") level of highway physical 214

plant based on structural and functional deficiencies in existing

inventories, present and future design standards, traffic growth rates,

and anticipated highway functional classification. Highway needs

studies do not represent a radically innovative methodology to guide

States' investment behavior. In fact, conceptually the needs study

process may be considered as a specific application of the general

economic theory explaining the investment behavior of a behavioral

unit (be it a firm, industry or State Highway Department).

This is an important point, since we are attempting to model the

highway investment behavior of States, regardless of whether they

conducted explicit needs studies during the course of our analysis

period (1957 - 1970). The most general statement of the factors

influencing total highway investment behavior (of which a needs study

is one application) may be expressed by:

(1) Rt = f(Kt - Kt-)

where R = total revenues devoted tohighway expenditure(State plus Federal funds)

K* = desired capital stock inyear t

Kt-1 = actual capital stock at the

end of year t-l

Equation (1) asserts that the level of (total highway) investment

in a given year t is a function of the gap between a "desired level

of highway plant" at the end of year t and the existing level of

capital stock at the beginning of year t.

The conceptual basis of this investment relation has been 215

advanced under the general heading of "capacity utilization theories."

Most commonly, the dependent variable is expressed in terms of (a

firm's) investment in capital stock. In our application, we are

more interested in a State's total (capital plus non-capital)

highway investment. However, equation (1) remains perfectly general.

We would expect higher levels of total highway investment to be

associated with higher "gaps" between desired and existing highway

plant. Note that Rt in equation (1) is just the sum of the States'

own resources R and the amount of available Federal highwayt

grants Gt

(2) Rt = R0 + Gt tBut Gt is equal to the sum of unexpended Federal grants in years t-1,

t-2, . . . and Federal grants made available in year t:

(3) Gt = UBGt-1 +gt

where UBGt-1 = unexpended balance ofFederal grants as of theend of year t-l

gt = highway grants madeavailable in year t

Substituting equations (2) and (3) into equation (1) yields:

(4) Rt = f(K* - Kt-1 ) - (UBGt 1 +

which expresses the revenues raised for highway expenditure in a

For a good summary of the various applications of these theories,see Kuh, Edwin, CAPITAL STOCK GROWTH: A MICRO-ECONOMETRICAPPROACH, North Holland Publishing Company, 1971, especiallyChapter 2.

216

State in year t as a function of the gap between desired and actual

highway capital stock and Federal grants.

The capacity utilization theory expressed by equation (4) has a

clear relationship to the classical Needs Study Process of long run

fiscal planning. In effect, we are arguing that States adjust their

long run highway investment policy in response to their perception

of highway "needs" (K* in our terminology), the existing inventory

(Kt-I) of highways, and the available level of external funding

(Gt). Needless to say, the empirical measurement of "desired"

(and even actual) capital stock represents a formidable conceptual

problem.

Several factors influence a State's perception of highway needs1

(desired capital stock), including traffic and congestions levels,

demographic characteristics, and a variety of institutional char-

acteristics. Symbolically, we assume desired capital stock -- "needs" --

can be expressed as:

I It should be emphasized that our modelling framework does notassume that State highway expenditures will be adjusted to meetthe cost perceived highway needs from year to year. On the con-trary, the expenditure model employed here explicitly recognizesthe continuing existence of a "jap_" between perceived needs andactual highway capacity. It is the existence of this discrepancybetween desired and actual highway plantthat influences State de-cisions on the magnitude of total highway investment. Presumably,the greater the gap between "needs" and existing inventory in anygiven year, the greater will be the expenditures in that year.

(5) K = Kt (SEC, IC) 217

Where SEC= a vector of socio-economiccharacteristics of a State(e.g., urban density, pop-ulation, traffic conges-tion levels, per capitaincome, and various Stategrowth measures)

Where IC= a vector of institutionalcharacteristics describinga State's hi hway financingconventions e.g., the ex-tent of local participationin highway maintenance andconstruction, the extent oftoll road finance, and thedegree of debt-servicefinancing

Introducing equation (5) into (4) leads to the basic form of the

total investment model estimated in this study:

(6) Rt = f(Kt (SEC, IC) - Kt 1) - g(UBG + gt

where f and g are assumed to be linear functions of thearguments

Note that the last term above is written as a function, rather than the

simple sum of UBGt-1 and gt as in equation (4). The reason for the more

general specification here is to allow for an explicit test of the ef-

fect of Federal grants. In other word, equation (6) permits an assess-

ment of the impact of Federal grants on the level of total hig wa

expenditures derived from States' own sources. The major hypothesis

to be evaluated empirically is relative degree of expenditure stimulation

resulting from Interstate versus non-Interstate grants. In the hypo-

thetical model presented in Chapter III, preliminary data analysis in-

dicated that Interstate grant increases would most likely be associated

with increases in States' own expenditures. This behavior was contrast-

218

ed with the ABC grant program, where it was hypothesized that States

would view increases in ABC grants as a substitute for their own

expenditures on these Federal Aid Systems. The empirical results

presented in Section IV.6 will validate the theoretical hypotheses.

218%s

IV.3 Estimation Techniques for the Total Expenditure Model

While it would have been desirable to estimate the total

expenditure model (TEM) for each State individually (i.e. as

forty-eight separate time series), lack of sufficient historical

data precluded this approach. The specification of the TEM incor-

porated as many as twelve explantory variables (including the con-

stant term). Given only fourteen years in our analysis period (1957-

1970), individual State estimation is clearly infeasible.

Accordingly, the possibility of grouping our observations in

a pooled data set consisting of time series and cross-sectional

data merits special attention. One of the first investigations of

this problem was advanced by Theil and Goldberger,I who demonstrated

that the estimation of time series parameters can be designed to

incorporate additional information oabtainable from cross-sectional

data.

In principle, the reasons for pooling data ar - s mpl3: provided

that we cna take proper statistical account of individual regional

and/or time effects that may be present in the data, the use of

pooled data (by virtue of the large increase in available degrees

of freedom) yields more effecient model paramter estimates. In

our application, the use of pooled data increases the number of

available observations from 14 (years) to 672 (14 years x 48 States).

Theil, Henri, and A.S. Goldberger, "On Pure and Mixed StatisticalEstimation in Economics," International Economic Review, Volume II,No. 1, January, 1961

To clarify the statistical problems inherent in estimating 219

models employing pooled data, let us rewrite equation (6) of

Section IV.2 in matrix form to stress the fact that an observation

is specific to a particular State and year:

R0

R0

1R~'

(7) R0 = = X + u

0R

R0RNT

X - - X(K)ku11 11 11

XO) -.-. - X(K) u1T 1T 1T

+

O)x(K) uNINl ll kiNI

NT NTuNT

220

where:

N = number of States (48) in the sample

T = number of years (14) in the sample

K = number of explanatory variables in the model

R = a vector of observations (NTxI) of total highwayexpenditures from State n's own sources in year t

Thus we have observations on N (=48) States, n = 1, 2 . .,'N

taken over T (=14) years, t = 1, 2, . . . T. Our dependent variable

R is assumed to be explained by K truly exogenous varibales X.

The statistical properties of our parameter estimates B, and indeed

the very meaning of our model is determined by what we assume about

the properties of the residual vector U.

The standard assumptions of econometric theory (i.e. if ordinary

least squares (OLS) are to yield best linear unbiased parameter

estimates) are that the residuals are distributed with mean 0 and

variance a I. However, if a model is estimated with pooled data, there

are strong reasons to suggest that these assumptions are not valid.

When cross section and time series observations are combined in the

estimation of a regression equation, it is likely that certain

systematic shift effects are present in the data. Specifically,

we refer to the presence of factors not explicitly accounted for by

the included explanatory variables which nonetheless influence the

dependent variable.

221Two categories of "extraneous influences" may be present. One

relates to the presence of pure regional effects -- i.e. factors

outside the model which serve to determine the behavior of individual

States. Growth rate policies, political culture variables, "belief

in the future,"2 and auto/transit biases are examples of factors

that, although important in determining individual State expenditure

behavior, are difficult to explicitly model at the aggregate level of

analysis considered in this thesis. A second extraneous influence

relates to the presence of time dependent shifts -- i.e. those factors

which may affect all States at any given point in time, but vary

from year to year. The most obvious examples of this affect are

macro-economic influences: interest rates, degree of inflation/

regression, unemployment rates, etc.

A common method to account for these "extraneous influences" is

to introduce explicitly into the equation individual shift variables.

The rationale for this approach is that the observations contain an

additive effect specific to the individual State or year.

To account for such effects, dy variables corresponding to

1Kuh, Edwin, and J.R. Meyer, "How Extraneous are Extraneous Estimates,"The Review of Economics and Statistics, Volume 39 (November, 1957).

2The importance of this factor was discussed by Mead, Kirtland, DESIGNOF A STATE WIDE TRANSPORTATION SYSTEM PLANNING PROCESS: AN APPLICATIONTO CALIFORNIA, Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, M.I.T. Civil EngineeringDepartment.

each State or yearI may be explicitly introduced into the model. 222

The problem with this approach is that it reduces the degrees of

freedom by N without adding in any real sense to the explanatory

power of the model. Moreover, it is often found that the dummy

variable approach "overcompensates" for the individual effect by

drastically reducing the magnitude and significance of the

explanatory variables. 2

Error Component Analysis

Another technique to account for the.presence of individual State

and/or time shift effects is with error component analysis.3

Since we are assuming the presence of economic forces specific to

an individual State and/or year, not otherwise accounted for in our

model specification, it is reasonable to expect that these forces

"show up" in the residual term. To state this formally, we assume

1Obviously it would not be possible to introduce a specific dummyvariable for each State and for each year. The most common practiceis to focus on the presece of regional effects by introducingexplicit State dummy variables. For an example of this approach, seeBalestra, Pietro, and M. Nerlove, "Pooling Cross Section and TimeSeries Data in the Estimation of a Dynamic Model: The Demand forNatural Gas," Econometrica, Volume 34, Number 3 (July, 1966).

2This is particularly true of those variables that vary significantlyfrom State to State, but exhibit little variance in any givenState over time. The dummy variable approach was attempted in thisresearch and abandoned for the above reason. For a further discussionof this point, see Balestra and Nerlove, op. cit., especially pages590 - 593.

3Balestra and Nerlove, op. cit., Theil and Goldberger, op. cit.,Kuh, op. cit.

223each residual Unt may be decomposed into three statistically independent

components: an individual State effect 1n, a time shift effect

t , and a remainder vnt :(8) u nt Pn + t1 +

Since the residuals are assumed to tve zero mean, and the

components of untare independently distributed, it must also be

true that:

(9) E[pn] = E[6t] = E[vnt1 = 0

We further assume that there is no serial correlation among the

error components, and that they are independent from one State and

year to another:

E[v ntlin] = 0

(10) E[vnt6t] = 0

E[vn6t] = 0

E[vntvn't'10

2Ef lip,]

E[6t6tII 16

if n=n' and t=t'

otherwise

if n=n'

otherwise

if t=t'

otherwise

Accordingly, we may express the variance-covariance (an NTXNT matrix)

0 of the residuals (ant) by:

E[untuntw2

w 2

w 2

1

w2

w2-

224where:

S0 - 0

0 T 0

0 0

P = (12/IG2

= S/2

*6

Equation (11) follows directly from our assumption that the

covariance of all the cross products of the error components are

identically 0. Note that the variance-covariance matrix .11 has

a repetitive block structure. The diagonal blocks are T x T, and

represent the variance-covariance structure of the individual State

effect and remainder error component. The off-diagonal blocks, also

T x T are all diagonal matrices, whose single parameter T represents

the time shift effect.

It is clear from the form of equation (11) that the variance- 225

covariance of the residuals derived from estimation on pooled data

is not scalar. Accordingly, although ordinary least squares estimates

of the coefficients would be unbiased and consistent, they would

not be the most efficient (i.e. least variance estimators. In fact,

the best linear unbiased estimators are the generalized least squares

parameter estimates GLS which explicitly incorporate the non-scalar

variance-covariance matrix:

(12) GLS = (X'Q'X)'1 X'2'R0

A straightforward technique for deriving generalized least

square estimators where the error term structure assumes the form of

equation (8) has been advanced by Zellner.I Essentially, the

technique involves a two-step estimation procedure: first estimate

the model with ordinary least squares (OLS), and use the OLS residuals

and equation (11) to determine the parameters of J1. Second, a

generalized least squares estimation is performed by making the

appropriate transformation of the original data.

In our application, a simplified generalized least squares esti-

mation procedure was adopted. Specifically, no account was taken of

the separate time effect 6t . This error component was dropped for

two reasons. First, allowing for a time shift effect would "greatly

Zellner, A., "An Efficient Way of Estimating Seemingly UnrelatedRegressions and Tests for Aggregation Bias," Journal of the AmericanStatistical Association, Volume 57 (1962).

.226complicate the analysis without adding any essential generality."

It is obvious from the form of equation (11) that the development of

generalized least squares estimators requires inverting an NTXNT

matrix. Although the form of 2 inclusive of 6t is sparse (c.f.

equation (11)], the inverse matrix Q-1 does not assume or simple

pattern.2 In fact, inversion of a 672X672 matrix proves to be

unwieldy and expensive.

A second reason for dropping the individual time shift effect

is that when estimations were performed using time shift dummy

variables, the parameter estimates of these dummy variables did not

prove to be significant. In short, the most important "extraneous

influence" in our estimation problem was the presence of an

individual State shift effect.

The application of our simplified error component estimation

procedure was straightforward. Following the notation of equation

(11), we now assume that:

0 o - - 0(13) Q = a2 * *

0 0 01

Balestra and Nerlove, op.cit., p.504.

2That is, there was no simple (and inexpensive) way to invert

Remembering that each T x T matrix w is specified in terms of a 227

single parameter p, it may be shown that - can be estimated as a

function of OLS residual estimates:?

N T

(14) -_ n~ti - a2(=n=t= t'= t ' n=l t=l nt

N T (T-1) 62

where: Uj = OLS residuals for State nnt (=1,... ,N) in year t ,=l,...,T)

82 = estimated variance of the OLSregression

The actual estimation of generalized least squares (GLS) estimates

involves OLS estimation on suitably transformed data. The first step

is to determine the Choleski decomposition2 h of Q-1 defined as:

(15) h'h = -1

The original observations X and R are then premultiplied by the

Choleski decomposition matrix to define X and P

(16)( = hX

R = hR

Equation (1941 simply expresses the average value of all thoseelements of ulu' corresponding to where p appears in our assumedstructure of 02

2For an operational algorithm for determining Choleski darnos nmatrices, see Faddeev, D.K., and Fadeeva, V.N., COMPUTATIOAL M ODSOF LINEAR ALGEBRA, W.H. Freeman, San Francisco, 1963.

It follows directly that OLS estimation on the transformed data 228

yields GLS estimates of our model coefficients.1

In summary, the estimation of the total expenditure model

followed a simplified error component analysis which explicitly

allows for the presence of individual State shift effects in our

pooled data set. Once the structure and properties of the residuals

are specified [equation ( 8)], GLS estimation involves a straight-

forward application of a two-step procedure employing OLS residuals

to estimate the parameter of an assumed structure of the non-scalar

variance-covariance matrix.

I aOLS = (' '~'R= (X'h'hX)alX'h'hRoBut from (15), h'h =-1

Thus BOLS = (X'Q'lX)-lX'Q-IRO = SGLS

IV.4 The Data Set and Modelling Considerations

Returning to the basic form of the total expenditure model

derived in Section IV.2, we noted that States' own highway expenditures

were functionally related to perceived investment needs, existing

highway inventories and Federal grant availability:

(17)

While equation (17) suggests the basic explanatory relationship, the

problem remains to specify the socio-economic factor (SEC), and

institutional characteristic (IC) arguments of the highway needs term

Kt. Moreover, a practical means of representing existing inventories

Kt-1, and Federal grant availability must also be determined. This

section will discuss the definitions end sources of each of the

variables incorporated into the estimated total expenditure model.

Several alternative specifications of the total expenditure

model were estimated in this research using both deflated and

undeflated data. The basic form of the model is presente in

Figure IV.4.l. The first eight variables in the model correspond

to the set of socio-economic and institutional characteristics

which influence a State's perception of "desired" highway ca;acity.

The variable KSTK serves as a proxy for existing highway inventories

[i.e. the measure of Kt-i in (17)]. Finally, the availability of

That is, expenditure levels, Federal grants and per capitaincome variables were deflated by the consumer price index.

229

THE TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL 230

0 MFCR a0 + a1I*SPOP + a2 *UFAC + a3 *GPOP + a 4 *PCY

VMT

+ a 5 *GINI + a6 *RLTOT

+ a7 *TOLPCT + a8 *BIPTCX + a9 *KSTK

+ a10 *AVNIGP + a11 *AVIGP + U

where

R 0= State expenditures on highways exclusive of Federal percapita grants

a-ao = constant term

a1 = estimated coefficients

VMT = State vehicle miles of travel

SPOP = State Population

MFC = State motor fuel consumption

UFAC = percent of population residing in urban areas

GPOP = State population growth rate

PCY = per capita State income

GINI = index of income inequality

KSTK = present discounted value of highway capital stock per capita

RLTOT = percent of total expenditures (all units of government)contributed by local (i.e., county and municipal) governments

BIPTCX = percent of total capital expenditures provided for by debtfinancing

AVNIGP = apportioned "ABC" grants (three year moving average) percapita

AVIGP = apportioned Interstate grants (three year moving average)per capita

U = error termFigure IV.4.1

231Federal highway aid is represented by AVNIGP and AVIGP -- a three-year

moving average of non-Interstate and Interstate grants respectively.

i. The Socio-Economic Descriptors

Five variables were employed to describe the socio-economic

characteristics of each State: a basic State size variable (SPOP

or MFC or VMT), a measure of urbanization (UFAC), an indicator of

State growth (GPOP), and two income characteristics (per capita income

PCY, and income distribution GINI).

a. SPOP, MFC and VMT

It is reasonable to expect that, ceteris paribus, State

expenditures should increase with increasing levels of traffic demand.

For one thing, higher traffic levels will generate increasing levels

of earmarked State highway revenue. But more fundamentally, higher

levels of auto use require increased construction, maintenance

policing and aministrative expenses.

Three alternative measures of State size were employed as a

proxy for the scale of auto travel. The first indicator, State

population (SPOP), was derived from yearly editions of the Survey of

Buying Power.1 SPOP was entered into the model with a one year lag --

i.e. State expenditures during year t were related to population at

Sales Management, SURVEY OF BUYING POWER, 1950 - 1970 (YearlyEditions), Bell Brothers Publications.This publication is the only source of year-to-year, State-by-State socio-economic descriptor data. The Census Bureau doesnot publish population, income or growth indices for each Stateon a yearly basis. The Survey of Buying Power's data base isadjusted to conform with the decennial census data.

233the end of year t-l. Two alternative State size variables were also

tested in the TEM estimations. Vehicle miles of travel (VMT) is

perhaps the most direct measure each State's traffic levels. The

only source of this information is from yearly editions of the

Federal Highway Administrations HI3HWAY STATISTICS. Two problems

are encountered in the use of this data. First, the data itself is

not directly observed or collected, but estimated from gasoline sales

statistics, and assumptions on average vehicle mix (i.e. truck/auto

split) and gasoline consumption rates. Secondly, the data, is not

published on a yearly basis. Over the course of our fourteen year

analysis period, the FHWA published VMT data for only four years (1959,

1962, 1965 and 1968). For our purposes, intermediate (yearly)

values of the VMT data were determined by simple straight line

interpolation.

Motor fuel consumption (MFC), the third alternative State size

measure, was also derived from the FHWA Highway Statistics yearly

publications, The data was entered into the model net of fuel

deployed for agricultural, marine or aviation use. As with the two

previous measures, a simple one year lag was employed.

b. UFAC

The degree of urbanization (UFAC) is an important factor

in determining highway investment behavior (i.e. in terms of explaining

perceived highway investment needs K) for several reasons. First,

it is a measure of the "compactness" of a State as it serves to

distinguish between largely rural/agricultural/sparsely populated

States and densely populated urban/industrialized States (see

234

PERCENT OF POPULATION RESIDING IN

URBAN PLACES WITH GREATER. THAN 5000 RESIDENTS_(1970)

UrbanizationIndexState State

UrbanizationIndex

AlabamaArizonaArkansasCaliforniaColoradoConnecti cutDelawareFloridaGeorgiaIdahoIllinoisIndianaIowaKansasKentuckyLouisianaMaineMarylandMasSdchusettsMichiganMinnesotaMississippiMissouriMontana

587448867576667556508264566447b55272827365426953

NebraskaNevadaNew HampshireNew JerseyNew MexicoNew YorkNorth CarolinaNorth DakotaOhioOklahomoOregonPennsylvaniaRhode IslandSouth CarolinaSouth DakotaTennesseeTexasUtahVermontVirginiaWashingtonWest VirginiaWisconsinWyoming

Source: Sales Management, SUlBrothers Publication

RVEY OF BUYING POWER 1970, Bill

Table IV.4.1

607557877284424173666371844243547977405868406563

b-

235Table IV.4.1). Secondly, it serves to identify States with highly

concentrated urban areas where per lane mile construction costs are

relatively high.

On balance, we would expect the degree of urbanization to

negatively influence States' per capita highway expenditures.

There are two reasons for this. The first reason relates to the

indivisibility and "lumpiness" of highway investments. As a State's

population decentralizes (e.g. to previously unpopulated places),

the need for highway route mileage increases. However, even the

minimal provision of two lane rural roadways incurs a relatively

large capital outlay.I

Secondly, the more urbanized States have been subject to an

increasing presence of community opposition to urban roadway construc-

tion.

The urbanization index UFAC is defined as the percent of a

State's population residing in areas with greater than 5000 residents.

The data was derived from yearly editions of the Survey of Buying Power

and was entered into the TEM with a one year lag.

1That is, highway construction is charaterized by high fixed costs.Moreover, highway construction and maintenance rise less thanproportionately to increases in the number of lanes (for a givenroute distance).

236c. GPOP

As an indicator of the rate of State growth, a measure of

yearly population change was computed from the basic population

data described in Section IV.4.i.a. Ceteris paribus, one would

expect higher population growth rates to be associated with higher

highway investment levels. As it turned out, the population growth

rate data was characterized by extreme variability and proved to be

a poor explanator of highway investment behavior.

d. PCY and GINI

Two separate measures of State income--per capita income and

a measure of income inequality--were employed in the estimation of

the total expenditure model. Per capita income (PCY) is correlated

positively with auto usage (See Section II.3.ii), and thus we

should expect increasing State income to lead to increasing State

highway expenditure levels. PCY data was derived from yearly

editions of the Survey of Buying Power.

The GINI Index of Income Inequality is derived from Lorenz

income distribution curves.1 As shown in Figure IV.4.2, the Lorenz

curves describe the degree of homogeneity in household income within

a State. If each household earned exactly the State average income

level, then the Lorenz curve would be a straight line rising at 450

from the horizontal (i.e. 20% of the households earn 20% of total

income, 40% of households earn 40% of total income, etc.)

As the Lorenz curve plots the percentage of households, ranked

1Samuelson, Paul, ECONOMICS, McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York, 8thEdition, 1970.

237

LORENZ CURVES

Percent ofTotal StateIncome

IJA

-Lorenz Curves

Figure IV.4.2

238fromypoorest up on the horizontal axis and the percentage of income

they earn on the vertical axis, it is clear that as the degree of

income inequality increases, the Lorenz curves become increasingly

concave.

This suggests a measure of income inequality related to the area

between a Lorenz curve and the 450 (perfect income homogeity) line

(e.g. see the shaded area in Figure IV.4.2). In particular the GINI

Index of Income Inequality (GIII) is defined as

area bounded b a Lorenz curve(18) GIII = and the 45 line

area under the 450 line

The GINI index varies between 0 and 1 with higher index values indicat-

ing a greater degree of income inequality.

The actual GINI indices developed for this research were

constructed from piecewise linear Lorenz curves. The Survey of

Buying Power data described the number of households in each State

(and each year in the 14 year sample period) in each of five income

categories -- $0 - 2499, $2500 - 4999, $5000 - 7499, $7500 - $10,000

and $10,000 and over.

The GINI index serves to indicate two characteristics of the

States. First the GINI index provides a measure of the number of

low income households in each State. For a given level of per capita

income, a State with a high GINI index value would have a relatively

large number of low (and high) income households. Thus we are

accouting for the possibility that the average income level as well as

the distribution of income in a State will affect the level of auto

239usage (and thus ultimately affect the level of State highway expendi-

ture). The GIII also conveys a rough measure of regional characteris-

tics. From Table IV.4.2, which displays the GINI index for each of

the forty-eight mainland States in 1963 (the mid-year in our 14-year

sample period), southern/agricultural/rural States tend to have a

higher degree of income inequality than northern/industrial/urbanized

States.

ii. The Measurement of Highway Capital Stocks

The development of time series information on a State's

highway capital stock presents a formidable task. An imediate

problem is to select the units to describe the capital stock, and the

economic conventions to be employed in measuring the change in value

productivity of vintage stocks over time.

On theoretical grounds, it is clear that the best measure

of capital stock is output capacity. In terms of evaluating highway

investment behavior, it may be argued that a State's investment

decisions are based, at least in part, on the perceived gap between

the demand for existing highway service (e.g. vehicle miles of travel),

and the existing supply of the highway plant. Implicit in this

decision-making process is the notion of level of service. Herein

lies the problem in measuring highway physical plant. The capacity

of a highway system, and the quality of the output (i.e. level of

service) are inherently related. This relationship stands in contrast

to the capital stock measurement problem of manufacturing production

processes where output is normally of uniform quality. The only

240

MEASURES OF INCOME INEQUALITY1963

State Gini Index of Income Inequality

Oklahoma 43.1Florida 42.8Kentucky 42.5Alabama 42.3Louisiana 42.0Tennesee 41.9Texas 41.6Arizona 41.6Deleware 41.3Virginia 40.5New Mexico 40.2Iowa 40.2Mississippi 40.1Georgia 39,9North Carolina 39.8Oregon 39.7Vermont 39.1Minnesota 39.0Missouri 38.9Kansas 38.9Washington 38.7West Virginia 38.5South Dakota 38.4New York 38.4Nebraska 38.3Nevada 38.2Ohio 38.1Maine 37.8Pennsylvania 37.7Illinois 37.6Indiana 37.5Maryland 37.4Michigan 37.4Rhode Island 37.3South Carolina 37.3Colorado 37.3Massachusetts 37.2

Table IV.4.2

241

State Gini Index of Income Ineuality

North Dakota 37.0Idaho 37.0Wisconsin 36.8Arkansas 36.4Connecticut 36.1New Jersey 36.1New Hampshire 35.6Utah 35.2Montana 35.0Wyoming 34.8California 32.0

Table IV.4.2 (contd.)

242practical problem in capital stock measurement in this case is the

selection of an appropriate depreciation formulation to measure the

declining value productivity of older capital stocks.

From the above remarks, it is clear that a complete descrip-

tion of highway capital stock requires knowledge of the highway

system's value-in-use -- ie. a comprehensive inventory of the

physical (e.g. roadway width, surface quality, geometric design,

etc.) and operating characteristics (i.e. speeds over the roadway at

existing demand levels) of the highway system.

Unfortunately, this data is not available on a time series

basis. Moreover, for the few years in which comprehensive inventory

data exists,1 the data set is excessively unwieldy, as it represents

a large sample, section-by-section description of all State-adminis-

tered highway mileage. Considering the fact that this type of

information has been largely unavailable to State planners and

decision-makers on a year-to-year basis, the relevant question for

this analysis is to find a relevant proxy measure for value-in-use

highway capital stock, drawing on available time series data.

The primary source of highway mileage data examined in

this study is drawn from the yearly editions of Highway Statistics,

IHighway system inventory data has been collected as part of indivi-dual State Highway Needs Studies (HNS). The Federal governmentrequired HNS of all States as of 1968. Prior to the time, severalStates conducted HNS on their own at irregular intervals.

243published by the U.S. Bureau of Public Roads. Unfortunately, the

organization of this data does not lend itself inediately to

proxy measures of highway capital stock suitable for investment

analyses. The most important data gap is the lack of information on

the vintage distribution of the States' highway plant. Thus, it is

not immediately apparent how to depreciate the value-in-use of

existing capital. Moreover, yearly additions to States' highway

route mileage are reported in units of route mileage rathern than lane

mileage, with no distinction made between projects on new rights-of-

way, and projects designed to improve existing rights-of-way (e.g.

major resurfacing of existing mileage, lane widening, addition of new

lanes to existing ROW, etc.).

Clearly, any attempt to measure capital stock in terms of

capacity output requires data in lane mileage, rather than route

mileage terms. The data on total existing lane mileage is sketchy.

In all cases, the mileage figures are reported in discrete categories--

2 lanes, 3 lanes, and 4 lanes or more--so that the data are imprecise

in the highest lane category. Attempts to identify lane mileage figures

with specific Federal-Aid Systems is complicated by lack of data on

Federal Aid Secondary lane mileage. The lane mileage (LM) data is

broken down into Interstate LM, Federal-Aid Primary LM, and State

Primary System IM. The latter category includes portions of all of

the Federal Aid System mileage as well as State system mileage not

1For example, the number of vehicles per day that can be accomodated onthe State-administered road system at a given average speed.

incorporated on the Federal-Aid Systems. 244

In summary, attempts to employ mileage data as a proxy

measure of highway capital stock is complicated by a lack of

information on the vintage distribution of highway plant, and an

incomplete stratification of lane mileage by Federal and non-Federal-

Aid System.

Given the above-mentioned difficulties in applying mileage

data to the task of measuring capital stock, it is desirable to

investigate the use of historical capital expenditure data as a

proxy measure of existing highway stock. An immediate issue in

applying expenditure data is the proper accounting of the decline of

capital productivity over time. As it turns out, the proper treat-

ment of expenditure data as a capital stock proxy measure is far

less difficult than the use of the available mileage data. The

methodology for constructing highway capital stock measures requires

some attention to the choice of an appropriate depreciation

methodology.

Depreciation refers to the loss in value of a currently

held asset. Two types of depreciation functions are commonly found

in the literature: market value functions and efficiency loss

functions. The former measure indicates the decline in resale value

1The benefits of using physical measures of capital stock (i.e.elimination of price delator affects, and the ease of identifyingstock retirements) are obvious. Nonetheless, the investmentbehavior literature is replete with studies employing capitalexpenditure proxies of capital stock. The main reason for theuse of expenditure data is that it is generally more readilyavailable than physical measures of capital.

of fixed plant over time, while the latter measure reflects the 245

losses in efficiency due to wear on the fixed plant. The more

relegant measure for highway investment studies is the efficiency

loss function.

The techniques for deriving depreciated highway capital

stock measures in this study were based on methodology developed by

Jack Faucett Associates.1 The methodology involves applying an

efficiency loss depreciation function (ELDF) to the time series of

State highway expenditures. The Faucett study hypothesizes that the

efficiency loss of highway systems increases over time (i.e. as a

highway approaches the end of its service lifd2 The actual ELDF

employed takes the form of the lower segment of a rectangular

hyperbola:

(19) D(t) = SL tSL -at

where D(t) = percent of a highway system's remainingproductivity

t = the age of a highway

SL = the service life of a highway

a = a parameter of the effciency lossdepreciation function (Otacl)

This formula generates a family of depreciation functions

as a function of the parameter a (See Figure IV.4.3). Following the

conventions of the Jack Faucett study, a 20-year service life was

Jack Faucett Associates Inc., CAPITAL STOCK MEASURES FOR TRANSPORTA-TION, Volume 1, Report No. JACKFAU-71-04-1, 1971.

As manifested by the increasing level of required maintenance expendi-tures and/or the decreasing level of highway productivity (as measuredby vehicle capacity).

246

DEPRECIATION FUNCTIONS

percent ofremaining increasingproductivity values of a

D(t)

D(t) =SL-tSL-at

Figure IV.4.3

was assumed for State highway system construction expenditures, 247

and the ELDF parameter (a) was set to 0.8.

The efficiency loss depreciation function was applied to a

thirty-four year time series1 of State highway system expenditures to

generate the depreciated highway capital stock measures per capita

(KSTK)for each State and each year in the 14-year sample period.

iii. Descrigtors of Financing Conventions and InstitutionalCharacteristics

Three descriptors of State hiqhway financing conventions were

employed in this study: the extent of local participation in highway

finance (RLTOT)2, the importance of toll roads in generating State

highway revenues (TOLPCT)3, and the degree of debt service highway

financing (BIPTCX).

Since the dependent variable in the total expenditure model

exclusively measures State highway expenditures, we should expect

that higher degrees of local participation (as measured by RLTOT) in

the provision and maintenance of highway facilities will be

associated with lower expenditure levels from State resources. In

1The expenditure time series covered the period 1937 - 1970. Expen-diture data was derived from yearly editions of HIGHWAY STATISTICS.2RLTOT is defined as the ratio of municipal and county highway expendi-tures to total (all units of government) highway expenditures.

3TOLPCT is defined as the percentage of a Stage's highway revenuederived from highway tolls.

4BIPTCX is defined as the ratio of bond interest to State highwayconstruction expenditures.

other words, to the extent that a State delegates its highway 248

authority to lower units of government, State highway expenditures

should decrease.

The other two indicators of institutional characteristics,

TOLPCT and BIPTCX, reflect the degree of flexibility in the States'

highway finance program. For a given State gas tax rate, the

increasing use of toll road or debt service financing allows a State

greater opportunity to raise higher levels of highway revenue. Thus

we should expect TOLPCT and BIPTCX to positively influence State

highway expenditure levels.

Each of the three financing convention variables, RLTOT,

TOLPCT and BIPTCX, were derived from yearly editions of the FHWA's

HIGHWAY STATISTICS.

iv. The Highway Grant Terms

Two important characteristics distinguish the treatment of

the Federal highway grant terms in our total expenditure model from

previous empirical highway expenditure studies (See Section 1.3)

First, the Federal-Aid Highway Program was broken down into two

distinct components: Interstate System grants, and grants on the

non-Interstate ("ABC") Systems. The theoretical analyses of

Chapter III indicated the strong likelihood of differing State

expenditure responses to these two grant types. In fact, it

was hypothesized that the Interstate program grant structure would

most likely induce expenditure stimulation in contrast to the

hypothesized expenditure substitution response to ABC grants. The

modelling emplications of these hypotheses are twofold. First, it

was considered desirable to explicitly test these hypotheses by 250

separating out the two distinct grant types. Second, it was

considered likely that the simple inclusion of a total grant term

would "wash out" any empirically identifiable grant response.I

A second characteristic distinguishing this study from

previous research is in the treatment of the multi-year grant

availability problem. As discussed in Chapter II, Federal highway

grants are made available over a "grace period" extending from one-half

year before the beginning of the fiscal year of the authorization to

two years beyond the end of that fiscal year. The use of three year

movingaverages on the grant terms was employed to represent the

grace period FAHP feature. Moreover, the use of moving averages partly

accounts for the fact that States may not fully and immediately

adjust to changes in Federal highway grant availability.

The basic Federal grant data was obtained from yearly

editions of HIGHWAY STATISTICS. Apportionments for the years 1969

and 1970 were adjusted downward in accordance with the imposed

OMB fiscal control totals (See Section IV.2). The grant terms were

1All of the studies cited in the literature survey of Chapter Iincluded only a total highway grant term. Several estimations ofour TEM were conducted with a single total grant term. As expected,the estimated grant parameter was extremely small and had a largestandard error (See Section IV.6).

2Specifically, the three year moving averaged grant terms Gt werecomputed as

-1Gt= j(Gt+Gt-1 t-2) for t = 1954, . . ., 1970

where Gt = States' grant apportionments in year t.

251

expressed as averaged Interstate grants per capita (AVIGP) and

averaged non-Interstate grants per capita (AVNIGP).

v. Price Delflators

This study conducted estimations on both (price)

deflated and und2flated data. Specifically, all of the terms in

the total expenditure model whose units are expressed in dollars

were adjusted by the consumer price index (See Table IV.4.3)

according to the following relationship:

(20) d CPI

where: Vd = price deflated variable

V = value of variable in absoluteterms

CPI= consumer price index

In addition to deflating the dependent (highway expenditure)

variable, the following explanatory variables were deflated by the

Consumer Price Index: per capita income (DEFPCY), highway capital

stocks (DEFKSTK), Interstate grants (DEFIG), non-Interstate grants

(DEFNIG), and total grants (DEFTG).

252

Consumer Price Index

(1970 base)

Consumer Price Index

.689

.700

.725

.745.751.762.771.779.788.799.812.835.859.896.944

1.000

Source: U.S. Department of Transportation, 1974NATIONAL TRANSPORTATION STUDY: HIGHWAY PLANNINGPROGRAM MANUAL, Table 11-3

Table IV.4.3

Year

1955195619571958195919601961196219631964196519661967196819691970

253IV.5 Research Strategy and Considerations for Model Interpretation

i. The Total Expenditure Model: Considerations forModel Interpretation

As indicated in the previous section, the basic form of

the total expenditure model describes the relationship between

States' own per capita highway expenditures, and a set of variables

representing States' socio-economic and institutional characteristics

(serving as proxies for the "desired" level of highway inventories),

a measure of existing highway plant (with a one-year lag) and

measures of available Federal highway grants (divided into Interstate

and non-Interstate categories). Before presenting a discussion of

the emprical results, it is important to clarify the hypotheses

which the total expenditure model can address.

Consider first the estimated coefficients of the Federal

grant (per capita) terms (refer to Figure IV.4.1 ). Following the

discussion presented in Chapter III, it is clear that sign and

magnitude of these coefficient estimates will serve to distinguish

the substitution or stimulation effects of Federal highway grants.

To see this consider the following possible values of the grant

term (a ) coefficient estimates:1

The following comments are relevant to the analysis of both theInterstate and non-Interstate grant terms.

2541. a (- 1-9--

A value of a less than one would indicate that States

reduce their own highway expenditures by more than one

ddllar for each additional grant dollar received. This

type of behavior is highly improbable as it would imply

that Federal highway grants have served to reduce total

highway expenditures.

2. a9 = - 1.0

This case is symbolic of perfect expenditure substitution

wherein each additional dollar of Federal grants is

associated by exactly a one dollar reduction in the level

of the States' own expenditures. It follows that, in

this instance, total highway expenditures (State plus

Federal funds) do not change in response to changes in the

level of Federal grants.

3. - 1 ( a (0

Coefficient values in this range represent an expenditure

substitution response. Like the previous situation, States'

own expenditures decrease in response to increases in

Federal grants, but in this case not on a dollar for dollar

basis. In other words, a coefficient estimate in the

range - 1 to 0 indicates that total expenditures will

255

increase but by less thanI the amount of Federal grant

increases.

4. a > 0

This grant response is characteristic of expenditure

stimulation. In other words, each additional dollar of

Federal highway grant elicits an increase in States'

own expenditures. It is only for this range in

coefficient values (i.e. a 9-0) that total highway

expenditures can be expected to increase by more than

increases in the level of Federal grant funding.

A second hypothesis to which the total expenditure model

can be addressed is a test of the effect of the level of current

highway inventories on total highway expenditures.

It is commonly found that the higher the existing stock of

capital goods, the lower will be the current desired and actual level

of capital investment. While this behavior may pertain in our case,

it should be noted that the dependent variable in the empirical model

measures capital (i.e., highway construction expenditures) as well as

non-capital (e.g. maintenance, administration, highway police and

safety, etc.) expenditures. In general, non-capital expenditures

tend to increase with increasing levels of existing highway inventory.

Thus, the single coefficient of the existing inventory variable

1Except if a is identically 0 in which case, total expenditureswould incregse by exactly the amount of Federal grant increase.

256(KSTK) does not distinguish between capital and non-capital expenditure

responses to changes in KSTK. For this reason it is entirely

possible to obtain a positive coefficient estimate for the highway

inventory variable.

One final note of the form of the model pertains to the

interpretation of the parameter estimates of the socio-economic descriptor

variables. Since the dependent variable in our model is expressed

in terms of expenditures per capita, it is not necessarily true that

a negative coefficient on a socio-economic variable implies that

total expenditures decrease with increasing levels of that variable.

For example, a negative sign on the population variable (SPOP)

might indicate that highway expenditures do not increase at the same

rate as population increases (and thus per capita expenditures

decrease). Nonetheless, such a coefficient estimate may still imply

that total highway expenditures would increase in absolute terms

in response to population increases.

ii. Data Set Stratification

The theoretical analysis developed in Section III. 4

advanced the hypothesis that the stimulatory impacts of the Federal

Aid Highway Program would be greaest in those cases where States

expend little more than the minimally required highway matching

funds. It was for this reason that the TEM included separate

terms for Interstate and non-Interstate grants (the latter grant

type less binding than the former). But even within each grant

program there exists some variation in the extent to which States

257exceed minimal matching requirements. (For example, see Tables 111.5.1

and 111.5.3).

To further test the notion that (ceteris paribus) the

magnitude of Federal highway grants relative to State expenditure

levels plays an important role in influecning State investment behavior,

we divided our data set into two distinct groups. In particular,

one subset was defined as the seven States with conspicuously low

Interstate highway expenditures over and above minimal Interstate

System matching requirements. These seven States whose "excess"

Interstate expenditures amounted to less than 4% of their total

Interstate investment over the fourteen-year analysis period 1957 -

1970, were Alabama, Missouri, Montana, New Hampshire, North Carolina,

North Dakota, South Carolina, Cermont and Virginia (Table 111.5.3).

The second data subset set was comprised of the 41 remaining States.

Thus each of the alternative total expenditure model specifications

was estimated on the full pooled data set and two data subsets.

In terms of the estimated parameters of the TEM, the

hypothesis that States experiencing more binding Federal highway

grants exhibit stronger stimulatory expenditure responses would be

borne out if the coefficient of the Interstate grant term is larger

for the seven State sample than for the 41 State sample. The

empirical models do validate this hypothesis as will be described in

in the next section.

258IV.6 Empirical Results

In general, the empirical results of the total expenditure

model estimations corroborate the theoretical hypotheses advanced in

sections 111.5, and IV.4. A total of 34 alternative specifications

of the total expenditure model were estimated in this research,

representing the inclusion of different sets of variables the use

of both deflated and undeflated data, the representation of Federal

aid by a single total grant variable or as two terms stratified by

grant type, and the estimation of the model on the entire data sample

as well as two distinct data subsets. Appendix A presents a complete

listing of the estimation results. The purpose of this section is to

highlight the major findings of the model estimations, and integrate

the empirical results with the theoretical hypotheses advanced

earlier.

In the figures that follow, each regression run is described

by a four character model number 11 12 ni n2 where:

S - grant terms stratified by type (Interstate and

11 = non-Interstate)

IT - single total grant term

12 = U- undeflated data set

ID - price deflated data set

(1 - 48 State/14 year pooled sample

n, j 2 - 7 State/14 year pooled sample3 - 41 State/14 year pooled sample

n2 = 1,2, ... - model specification number

Figures IV.6.1 through IV.6.4 present the results of the

generalized least squares estimation of the TEM using undeflated

data on the full 48 State/14 year sample. In particular, Figure

IV.6.2 considers the addition of one explanatory variable -- the

ElltAIll.-RU3wULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

GfRE RALlZEDt-LlASf-2LIARL

EzUjAIL.ELJi&t.b) 2L 5a~2l&)------ S~ I

FSTTIMAYF VA IJF

STANDFAR'l ERPR-

T-STATI STIC

rySrTrPT \IVAtIUF

STtNiDApfl CPPOR

T-ST\TTSTTC

-2 AL A --52IL --- S ------UEA----QY------G1N1L

9.A6 -0.650F-96 9.468 -0.601 0.019 '.635

5.58 0.732F-17 1.124 0.031 0.001 0.124

1.78 8.74 8.41 19.53 17.94 4.8

21- TOT-0.'31

0. o 36

8.96

TO. PC T0.457

0.069

6.62

A.YN IGP p-1.146

0.091

12.55

AVIOP(.6 19

0.0 43

14.39

Figure IV.6.1

E5 TJ M AL _U31LI-S

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

aQ !LS.3'1-Za1

.GENLAU2.-.LA-SQUAELS

E=.SAIS il L ii-=J&U2-=_ . _ . .

ESTIMATE VA LUE

STANDARD FPQ(IP

T-STATISTIC

cST IMATF VALUF

STANOAQD E2RAIR

'-STATISTIC

P LA-------ELY-----N

.9P -&.597E-06 10.639 -0.599 0.0117 0.613

5.55 0.796F-)7 1.206 0.03' 0.001 0.123

1.62 7.51 8.82 19.61 17.26 4.97

Q[LTQ T

.fl 37

8.95

TfL PCT0. 355

.0 'I

4.917

AVNIGP-1.123

0.097

11.61

AVIGP0.608

0.043

14. 14

arIP rx(0. 088

9.955

I.58

Figure IV.6.2r.-)a')C0

- - - - - - - - - - -

Wppmumm-pmmm

P.%LIt AI l-RLLLS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

.DEL-UaALLb

G5,NF. ALILfEQ-LI Aall -. 5QUARfi

- .QSAK-- S1A 1 --------- - L----.-----------------1---

ESTIMATF VALUE 10.01 -0.137E-33 9360 -0.600 0.018 0.696

STAnAPf FPOqR 5.66 J0173F-04 1.12S 0.031 J.001 0.126

T-cTTTISrTTC 1. 77 7.91 8.30 19.16 17.73 4.81

RLTnT TOLPCT AVNIGP AVI~G

;ST!"A T E VALUF -0.3AG 3.410 -1.135 0.620

STtNPAP) F2P'R 0.036 .070 0.093 0.043

T-sTATISTIC .17 9.83 12.?? 14.25

Figure IV.6.3

N3-- A

EL.Ih1OL-SULL5

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

_!MQlEl . ,_ TU12

GENEBALILE EASI.S2UA&REi

-~ ~

ESTIMATF VALUE

STINOAnD FPRCR

T-STATISTIC

FSTIMATF VALIJF

STANDAPF EPROR

T--S TA'I STTC

-. ENU.AUL-SE E l UE!-

20.84 -0.314E-J6 16.553 -C.458 0.013 O.A-7

6.C4 C.844F-07 1.814 C.032 0.001 0.135

3.45 3.72 9.13 14.C7 12.79 2.950

PL TfT-0.418

I 3.t?

TOL PCT3.178

0. 098

1.83

AVTGP0.039

0.C35

1.11

BI pO.?59

0.056

4.40

Figure IV.6.4

N)

Nl")

on= mm No, am. 4pdw - A-6.206-d=6 .-a owl. -Aw-

263

degree of debt service financing to the basic set of nine right hand

side variables included in Figure IV.6.1.1 Figure IV.6.3 employs

vehicle miles of travel instead of population as the measure of State

size. And Figure IV.6.4 includes only a single Federal aid term -

total available highway grants, rather than the stratified grant terms

employed in the previous specifications.

The total expenditure model was also estimated for two

subsets of the full pooled data set. Specifically, Figure IV.6.5

presents the estimation results of one specification of the TEM for

the seven states with conspicuously minimal Interstate expenditures

over and above required matching funds (c.f. section IV.5). Figure

IV.6.6 presents the corresponding model estimation results for the

forty one other States.

The remaining estimation results derive from the use of price

deflated data on all variables whose units are expressed in dollar

terms. Specifically, Figures IV.6.7 through IV.6.8 represent the

basic nine variable specification (c.f. Figure IV.6.1) of the price

deflated TEM for the full pooled data set, the 7 State sample and the

41 State sample respectively. The most important empirical findings

from the total expenditure model are presented in summary fashion

below.

i. The Federal Grant Terms

The most striking finding from the total expenditure model

is that the ABC grant program has elicited a significant expenditure

1See section IV.4 for a definition of the variables listed in the

following fugures.

E511AI12 S.AL15

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

G E FNE R ALIZ.E -L EA.S!.5.UA dF -S AI ..-El_9.._nB-=.-ti216.-L..- ..5 - ..1 5 - - -- Q-.2 .2.

------------ -- - -- -- -- -- ------------

FSTIMATE VALUE

STANDAPO ERROR

T-C TATTST IC

FSTIMATF VALUF

ST ANDAP0 FFP1R

T-CTATISTIC

S iIMC22-2..---KU-UE AC.J ILL--

97.82 -0.668E-06 0.209 -1.340 0.006 .542

8.94 f.737E-06 fl.307 0.227 0.002 0.114

IC.90.91 0.69 5.90 3.66 4.74

_LTCT

-. e 127

1.41

TA PCT2.772

0.492

5.64

AVNIGP-0.310

0.161

1.92

C.657

0.061

10.75

Figure IV.6.5

Ei.lmAll2 NEEM5AIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

-!aJE LJVLa.AII31

.GENEtALtLLDLA.L-SQUARL&

F-STAT: Ffl0.964) = 241.3I SFF = 5.14 RSO = (794

rSTIMATF VALUE

STANOARD FRROR

T-STATTSTIC

ESTTMATF VALtIF

STANUAPD ERROR

T-STATIST TC

16.15

5.55

2.91

U 31-t *5?4-,1. r 4l~or41

12.75

-0.478F-06

.724E-07

6.60

TOL PCT0.368

3*171

5.21

Figure IV.6.6

N)-1,

..AIEAU..

-0.637

C.034

18.50

PC V

0.018

3.001

17.32

GIN?

0.693

0.122

5.67

S.?74

1.032

8.02

AYNIGP-0.856

0 e 114

7.51

0.439

C.057

7.68

a-* -ALJ6-.AJ6.w- .-.F- ---- o .-.

LUIA.MA12Ui_&L.2IS.

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

M-2DEL-N.-I DI

iENEAL.EDLSA._LQU A a

F-STAT: Ft 9.66?) r '48.72 SEE = 6.92- RSO = 0.772

FSTIMATE VALIJE

STANDARD ERPrlR

T-STAT!STIC

CCBSIA NI

[2.12

7.16

1669

--- j.El --.- _

-0.85TE-06

O.943E-07

9.039

ESTIMATE VALHE

STANDAP) FOPoFR

T-STATISTIC

Figure IV.6.7

n.LEa5.I&

8 .028

1.050

7.65

-0.738

0.040

18.66

12EEEfmlX.

0.O22

0.001

17.52

0.771

0.159

4.84

"LTT

-C.4?0

0.046

9.27

TPLPCT0.598

U.089

6.75

DEFGf-1.103

0.092

14.43

DE F IQ9.642

0.045

12.03

Am. AM Aw - -oubL426JON6 .w.'JWm.& Lmmd6 801,4 dw- am.& - -Jm&AL-WL own

_________-0- m-.- ---

-.0 W--ddmvmmmmmmmmp

E$LL IAIL26L..EiUUS.

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

L .fUELDAQ.SDJ21

GENEALJLEDL EA SIS.QUARE S

F-S TM:AFT9 l288) 28.00 SEE = 7.5 RS = 0 741

CONSTANT

FSTIMATF VALUE

STANPAPD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

FSTIMTF VALIuE

STANAPD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

121.10

9.36

12.93

RLTOT-o .185

06.nit

t.*81

Spnp

-0.623E-06

0.879E-06

3.71

TOLPCT3.590

0.532

7.15

Figure IV.6.8

tIFAC

-1.783

0.236

7.56

F PC Y

0.010

0.002

4.97

DEFKSTK

0.776

0.368

2.10

DE FNIG-0.295

0 .132

2.24

-1NL.

-0.679

0.099

6.87

0.666

0.058

11.50

. _k-0-A _-60- -_w _mm 4140 _1__ _ _ _ _ _ _-o b4MW Mmmvo nwapmbon&AA Mnnoit 9A 4 "

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

-;A -Am L _ _ "- _ U_- -_A d-- _ -- wm- _ - -mm

JESILfAII l&.ES.ULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

frQQL-h.&HjA31

JRALL IQE AS-iUARL

F-STAT: Ft 9.5641=236.03 SEE 6.60- RSQ =O.9L

ESTTMATF VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

19.62

7.10

2.76

-0.648F-06

0.928E-07

6.98

.E.SKI&

8.696

1.065

8.16

ESTTMATE VALUE

STANDARD EPROR

T-STATISTIC

Figure IV.6.9

00

-0.778

0.044

17.64

.DEE.EC.

0.023

0.001

17.01

0.869

0.157

5.55

RLTCT-0.686

0.053

12.99

T1L9PCT0.444

0.091

4.87

DEFNIG-0.867

0.116

7.48

DEF IQ0.440

0.060

7.33

. wm. .mm _W .W m o

P--......-........_4- - -dm.40--..

.. .......... -ww.wm

269

substitution response amongst the States, as opposed to the Interstate

grant program which has been associated with expenditure stimulation.

Taking the nation as a whole, the coefficients of the non-Interstate

grant terms in all of the specifications employing undeflated data

fall in the range -1.123 to -1.146 (Figures IV.6.1-IV.6.3). In light

of the discussion in the previous section, where it was indicated

that grant coefficient values less than -1 represented highly

implausible behavior, each of these coefficients were tested for the

statistical significance of their difference from a value of exactly

-1.0.1 In none of the cases, did the coefficient values differ

significantly from a value of -1.0 (at the 5% significance level).

Thus for all practical purposes, the total expenditure model indicates

that the States exhibit a perfect expenditure substitution response

to Federal ABC grants. It is clear that this type of behavior does

not characterize the response to Interstate grants. Again referring

to figures IV.6.1 through IV.6.3, it can be seen that the Interstate

grant coefficients are all significantly greater than 0, ranging in

value from .608 to .630. Taking the nation as a whole, this would

indicate that an increase in Interstate grants by one dollar would

elicit an increase in State expenditures by approximately 60.

'The test involves the formulation of the following t statistic:

a - 1.0

9 where se is the standard error of the grant coefficient.se (a )

For example, using the values given in Figure IV.6.2 for the estimate

of the AVNIGP coefficient, t = 1.123-1.0- = 1.27 < 1.64 = t.05,662

(single tailed test) 0.097

270

The same behavioral pattern is evident from an examination

of the estimation results employing price deflated data (Figure

IV.6.7). In fact, the estimated values of the grant terms from

the deflated and undeflated data sets are remarkably similar. For

the full 48 State/14 year price deflated data set, the coefficients

of the non-Interstate grant terms were all slightly less (but not

significantly different) than -1.0, while the Interstate grant

coefficients assumed values around 0.60.

The inclusion of just a single grant term AVTGP representing

a three year moving average of total per capita highway grant

availability did not yield significant results. From Figure IV.6.4,

the estimated coefficient of the total grant term is 0.039 (indicating

mild expenditure stimulation) but this value is not significantly

different from 0 at the 5% significance level. These results are

not surpirsing in view of our findings that Interstate and ABC grants

have essentially opposite effects on State highway expenditure

behavior.

It is interesting to note that previous empirical studies

of State expenditure behavior have failed to distinguish between

different highwaygrant types. For example in a 1971 study by

O'BrienI employing a 48 State/9 year (1958-1966) pooled data set,

the estimated coefficient of total highway jrants was also found to

be mild by stimulative (0.067) but not significantly different from

O'Brien, Thomas, "Grants-In-Aid: Some Further Answers," NationalTax Journal, Vol. XXIV, No. 1 (March, 1971)

2710. The more interesting conclusion however is not that increasing

total Federal grant availability has induced higher State expenditure

levels, but that highway grants with significantly different

structural characteristics have been associated with significantly

different State expenditure responses.

ii. Differences in Grant Term Coefficients Between theTwo Data Subsets

It was hypothesized in chapter III of this research summary

that the potential of a grant to stimulate expenditures from States'

own sources is greatest in cases where the matching and appointment

provisions of a grant are "bindinq."1 To test this hypothesis, the

full sample of observations was divided into two groups (see IV.5.ii)

From Figures IV.6.5 and IV.6.6, it is evident that the seven States

exhibiting the lowest excess Interstate expenditures were more

sensitive to increases (or decreases) in Interstate grant funding

than the remaining forty-one States. Specifically the Interstate

grant coefficient for the seven State sample assumed a value of

.657 compared to a value of .439 for the remaining forty-one State

sample. 2

While all of these parameter estimates exemplify expenditure

stimulation, it appears that increases in Interstate grants to States

coming closest to minimally matching available Federal (Interstate)

aid will elicit a greater expenditure response than the response from

In the sense that State is found to minimally meet its requiredmatching expenditures.

2A similar pattern was indicated for the runs employing the datasubsets with deflated values (see Figures IV.6.8 and IV.6.9).

272

other States. Perhaps even more striking a result along these lines

is the difference in the non-Interstate (i.e. ABC) grant term

coefficients between the two data subsets. For example, comparing

Figures IV.6.5 and IV.6.6 the coefficient of the non-Interstate

grant term assumed values of -.31 (seven State sample) and -.86

(forty-one State sample). One of the reasons for the stronger

expenditure substitution response manifested by the forty-one State

sample is that, on average they were characterized by a higher

"excess fraction" (see section I11.5) of ABC System expenditures

than the States comprising the seven State sample. Referring to

Table 111.5.1, 33% of the total ABC System investment by the 41 State

sample represented expenditures over and above minimal ABC matching

requirements as compared to a figure of 29% for the seven State

sample.

iii. Interpretation of the Coefficient Estimates of the

and Institutional Descriptor Variables

a. State Size Variables

Results from the total expenditure model indicate that

per capita highway expenditures (from States' own sources) decrease

with increasing State population (SPOP) and urbanization (UFAC).

This pattern runs throughout the estimation results presented in

Figures IV.6.1 to IV.6.9. For example, the TEM estimation using

undeflated data on the full pooled data set indicates that (Figure

IV.6.1):

And thus, following the reasoning of Section III, would be more proneto view ABC grants as a substitute for their own ABC Systemexpenditures.

274

(21) R0PC = 9.96 - 0.65.10-6 SPOP - 0.60 UFAC + . . .

Thus, an increase in State population by one million or an

increase in urban density1 by one percent is associated with

approximately a 60t per capita decrease in State highway expenditures.

This does not imply that total (i.e. not per capita) highway

expenditures (R0) decrease with increasing population. We can express

total State highway expenditures R0 as:K

(22) R = RPC. SPOP = (a0 + 2 - a)SPOP + Iakk=2

where a = estimated constant term= estimated coefficient of

the population variable

The change in total (own) State highway expenditures with respect to

SPOP is qiven by:

K(23) D R = a + 2a * SP0p + lak

SPOP k=2

Thus the change in total expenditures with respect to SPOP will be

positive as long as:

K(24) a + 2a * SPOP + Yak> 0

k=2

Using the estimated coefficients in figure 4 and the average value

of the variable SPOP2 yields:

(25) a R = 9.96 - 2 *0.65 *10-6 . 0.38* 107 +- -. +3 SPOP

= 4.94 > 0

1Percent of a State's population residing in urban places greaterthan 5000 persons.

20ver the 14 year sample period, the 48 State average populationwas 3.8 million.

275This implies that population increases increase States' own highway

expenditures by $4.94 per person.

b. The Income Measures

Two separate measures of State income--per capita income

and a measure of income inequality--were employed in the estimation

of the total expenditure model. Per capita (State) income (PCY) is

correlated positively with auto usage and thus we should expect

increasing State income to lead to imcreasing State highway

expenditure levels. This hypothesis is borne out by the estimation

results. For example, referring to fiqure IV.6.1, an increase in per

capita income by one dollar would be associated with a 1.8* increase

in per capita State highway expenditures.

As discussed in section IV.4, the second income measure

employed in this study -- the GINI index of income inequality--

provides an indication of both the distribution of State income, and

a rough measure of regional characteristics.1 The estimation results

indicate that higher levels of income inequality are associated with

higher per apita State highway expenditures. For example, referring

to figure IV.6.1, an increase in the GINI index by one unit would

lead to a 61* per capita increase in State highway expenditures.

c. Institutional Characteristics

Three descriptors of State highway financing conventions

were employed in this study: the extent of local participation in

highway finance (RLTOT), the importance of toll roads in generating

1Namely that States with greater income inequality (higher levels ofGINI) tend to be Southern/rural/agricultural in nature.

276

State highway revenues (TOLPCT), and the degree of debt service

highway financing (BIPTCX).

Since the dependent variable in the total expenditure model

exclusively measures State highway expenditures, we should expect

that higher degrees of local participation (as measured by RLTOT) in

the provision and maintenance of highway facilities will be associated

with lower expenditure levels from State resources. In other words,

to the extent that a State delegates its highway authority to lower

units of government, State hiahway expenditures should decrease.

The other two indicators of institutional characteristics,

TOLPCT and BIPTCX reflect the degree of flexibility in the States'

highway finance program. For a given (State) gas tax rate, the

increasing use of toll road or debt service financing allows a State

greater opportunity to raise higher levels of highway revenue. Thus

we should expect TOLPCT and BIPTCX to positively influence State

highway expenditure levels.

These hypotheses were borne out by the estimation resilts

of the total expenditure model. For each percentage increase in the

ratio of local to total expenditures, State per capita highway

expenditures decrease by more than 304 (see Figure IV.6.1 - IV.6.4).

Increases in the percentage of toll road financing induce as much as

a 47t (per 1% increase in TOLPCT) increase in per capita State

highway expenditures. And the use of debt service financing was

associated with higher per capita highway expenditures--on the order

of a 64 increase for each percentage increase in BIPTCX (see Figure

IV.6.2).

277d. The Existing Inventory Measure

The estimation results indicate that higher levels of

existing inventory at the beginning of a year lead to higher levels

of expenditure on highways during that year. For example, referring

to figure IV.6.1, an increase in depreciated capital stock per

capita of $1.00 would lead to a $9.48 increase in State per capita

highway expenditures.

There are two explanations for this finding. First, the

higher the level of existing capital stocks, the higher will be the

required level of non-capital expenditures (e.g. maintenance, admini-

stration, highway police and safety etc.) to support the existing

facilities. Second, it may be hypothesized that the increasing

provision of highway facilities tends to divert and attract additional

auto ridership which in turn leads to higher levels of highway expen-

diture.

In summary, the estimation of the total expenditure model

generally confirmed the behavioral hypotheses advanced earlier.

Most significantly, it was shown that states have viewed the Federal

"ABC" grant program as a substitute for their own expenditures as

contrasted with the Interstate highway program which has served to

stimulate States' own highway expenditure levels. Table IV.6.1

summarizes the effects of each of the variables included in the TEM

on State highway expenditure levels.

iv. The Deflated Data Set

It is common practice in empirical studies dealing with

time series information to express all monetary data in real dollar

278

Variable

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

RLTOT

TOLPCT

BIPTCX

AVNIGP

DIRECTION OF THE INFLUENCE OF THE EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

ON TOTAL STATE HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES

Direction of Influence on

Total State Highway Expenditures

+

+

+

+

+

+

AVIGP +

+: indicates that increasing levels of the variable are associated withincreased highway expenditure levels

-: indicates that increasing levels of the variable are associated withdecreased highway expenditure levels

Table IV.6.1

279terms for two reasons. First, price deflation converts expenditure

data to a common base, indicative of the fact that one dollar of

highway investment in 1957 differs from a one dollar investment in

(for example) 1970 in terms of corresponding physical output.

Secondly, price deflation introduces some notion of the price of the

provision of highway facilities in models where it is difficult or

infeasible to include an explicit price term.

In our application, the choice of an appropriate price

deflator was complicated by the fact that inflation rates differed

significantly among the various highway activities undertaken by

States. For example, over the last two decades price increases'

have been more rapid for Federal aid highway construction than for

maintenance and operational activities. 1 Moreover the structure of

the total expenditure model does not distinguish between individual

expenditure items; the dependent variable merely measures total

highway expenditures. As described in section IV.5, a somewhat

simplistic approach to price deflation was adopted in this research.

All data whose units are expressed in dollar terms were deflated by

the Consumer Price Index.

Examples of estimation results using deflated data are shown

in Figures IV.6.7 - IV.6.9.2 The results do not differ significantly

1Federal Highway Administration (FHWA) Notice HHO-34, "Highway Main-tenance and Operation Cost Trend Index," 12/14/72. FHWA Office ofHighway Operations, PRICE TRENDS FOR FEDERAL-AID HIGHWAY CONSTRUCTION,Second Quarter, 1973.

2These Figures correspond to the undeflated model runs shown inFigures IV.6.1, Iv.6.5 and IV.6.6 respectively.

280from the estimation runs on the undeflated data set. All of the

variables maintained the same sign and roughly the same magnitude,

the largest difference occurring in the coefficient of the population

variable. Most significantly, estimation of the TEM with the price

deflated data set again corroborated the basic finding that the ABC

grant program has been associated by expenditure substitution, while

the Interstate grant program has induced State expenditure stimula-

tion.1

v. Tests of Equality Between Coefficients in the TwoData Subsets

The empirical results reported in the previous paragraghs

have been based on the use of a pooled 48 State/14 year data set

as well as two data subsets comprising seven and forty one States

(over 14 years) respectively. This raises two related statistical

issues:

- the validity of pooling our seven State sample with theforty one State sample, and

- the significance of the difference between the estimatedcoefficients (taken as a whole) from the seven and fortyone State samples

In effect, while we have attempted to account for individual

State preferences by the GLS error component procedure (section IV.3),

it may nevertheless be the case that as a group, our seven State

sample exhibits significantly different behavior than the 41 State

IFor example, referring to Figure IV.6.7 representing estimation ofthe TEM on the 48 State deflated data set, the coefficient of theABC grant term (DEFNIG) was - 1.103, while the coefficient of theInterstate grant term (DEFIG) assumed the value . 642

281

sample. To state this premise formally we wish to test the null

hypothesis H0:

(26) 1 = B2

where: 6 = the set of regression coefficients

from a sample with T1 (=7 States x 14 years

= 98) observations

62 = the set of regression coefficients from

a second sample with T2 (=41 States x 14

years = 574) observations.

The null hypothesis leads directly to the specification of a

restricted model where no allowance is made for differing values

of 6.1 and s2

(27) Ro = 1R XIU1 = Xs + u

2 X ju2j

where i refers to the subset of T observations

on own expenditures R, explanatory variables Xi.1

and residual terms u.

In an obvious extension of (27), the unrestricted model with explicit

allowance for differing 61 and 62 may be written as:

In fact the restricted model (and notation) referred to here is justour original model specification presented in equation (17).

282

R0 X 0 8u

(28) R- = [; 0I VJ hR L 2 L2 2j

where u. = residuals from the unrestric-model

The test of the equality (in the statistical sense) between

H and B2 may be expressed by an F-statistic and is presented

here without proof:I

(u'u - u*'u*) / k- (29) F(k,T1+T2 -2k) = __________

u*I'u / (T1+T2 - 2k)

where k = the number of variables inour model

u'u = the sum of squared residualsfrom the restricted model

u*'u* = the sum of squared residualsfrom the unrestricted model

T. = number of observations insample i

F(k,T1+T2-2k) = the computed F-statisticwith parameters (degrees offreedom) k and T+T2-2k

In our application, construction of the relevant F-statistic

is straightfoward. The sum of squared residuals (SSR) from

Fisher, Franklin M., "Tests of Equality Between Sets ofCoefficients in Two Linear Regressions: An Expository Note,"Econometrica, Vol. 38, No. 2 (March, 1970)

283

the unrestricted model derives from summing the squared resid-

uals from the separate regression runs on the two data subsets.

Thus for example, referring to Figures IV.6.1, IV.6.5, and-IV.6.6,

where the Standard error of estimate (SEE) from the 48

State (restricted) sample, and the 7 and 41 State (unrestric-

ted) sample are 5.37, 6.57, and 5.14 respectively,1 the

corresponding F-statistic is computed as:

19450 - (4230 + 15164)

F(10,652) = 10 - 0.18

19394

652

Since this computed value of F is significantly less than the

critical value of the F distribution at the 5% significance

level (F 05 (l0,l000) = 1.84), we are unable to reject the

null hypothesis that 6l = g2. In other words, the practice

of pooling our observations -- at least in terms of com-

bining our 7 and 41 State sample for the given specification

of the TEM (Figure IV.6.1) on the undeflated data set appears

valid. The computed F-statistic for each of the alternative

specifications explored in this thesis is prsented in Table:

IV.6.2

1As presented in the Figures, the sum of squared residuals isequal to SEE squared times the number of observations in thesample.

284

TESTS OF SELECTED SUBSET COEFFICIENT EQUALITIES

(Table entries represent computed F-statisticsfor the model numbers appearing in Appendix A)

Undeflated Data

Model No. F-Stat

Deflated Data

Model No. F-Stat

Stratified Grant Terms SUlI 0.18* SDll 355SUl2 1.75* SD12 1.44*

Total Grant Term Only TUll 6.94 TDl 4.26

TUl2 4.93 TDl2 5.48

*not significant at the 5% level

Table IV.6.2

285

IV.7 Summary and Conclusions

The estimation results of the total expenditure model (TEM)

generally confirmed the previously advanced theoretical hypotheses

regarding the differing impacts of the Interstate and non-Interstate

gramt programs, the expected responses among States whose expenditures

are low relative to Federal grant availability, and the influence of

the socioeconomic and institutional characteristic variables.

While the data set used in calibrating the models describe condi-

tions over the fourteen year period 1957-1970, the empirical finding

may be interpreted in the broader sense of suggesting guidelines for

future Federal-Aid Highway Program (FAHP) policy. Toward this end, we

have shown that a major component of the FAHP has not been significantly

influential in stimulating State highway expenditures. To the extent

that States view a grant as a substitute for their own expenditures, one

must view the Federal-aid from the perspective of its value as a tax-

relief program rather than its merits in accomplishing an explicit

reallocational goal. Along these lines we have shown (see chapter II)

that the Interstate Highway Trust Fund is financed by non-progressive

excise taxes, and apportioned in a somewhat arbitrary fashion which

fails to accomplish a significant redistribution of State income.

In conjunction with the theoretical analyses of chapter III, the

empirical results of this chapter demonstrate that substitutive vs.

stimulative impacts of Federal aid (at least for aid in the form of

close-ended, conditional matching grants) depend critically on the level

of Federal grants in relation to State expenditures on the aided system.

286We have focused on the differing structural characteristics between

the Interstate and non-Interstate grant programs and the corresponding

differences in State expenditure responses. But these results have

general applicability. Close-ended, conditional matching grants whose

provisions are not binding on current or projected State expenditure

levels may be expected to be viewed as a substitute for States' own

i nvestments.

From a Federal policy stand points the empirical findings in this

chapter raise several important points. First, with our clearer

understanding of the dynamics of State expenditure responses to Federal-

aid, the fundemental issue of the objectives of the Federal Aid

Highway Program is called into question. In effect, the imposition of

Federal highway taxes and the pursuant distribution of categorical

highway grants represents an explicit expression of Federal policy.

It is not the intent of this research to argue the economic viability

of the Federal governments support for particular highway facilities.1

For example, our findings demonstrate the success of the Interstategrant program in "accelerating" the construction of Federal AidSystems (as measured by increasing State highway expenditurelevels), if in fact the intent of the this program was to stimulatehighway expenditures. However, it remains open to question whetherthe ensuing expenditure response to the Interstate grant programrepresents an economically viable investment of funds by benefit/cost or other relevant investment criteria. Our concern has beento merely trace expenditure responses, not to evaluate their economicconsequences, as this latter point has been adequately treatedin the literature. Se for example Friedlaender, Ann F., THEINTERSTATE HIGHWAY SYSTEM, North Holland Publishing Company,Amsterdam, 1965, especially chapter 3.

287

Suffice it to say that the restrictions on the use of Federal funds

for only certain types of facilities tends to identify those projects

whose provision is deemed to be in the national interest. Guaranteeing

a minimally acceptable provision of important transportation facilities

or stimulating road construction necessary for interstate commerce are

valid Federal objectives. But we have shown that for the ABC program,

the former objective may not be appropriate, and the second objective

is not being accomplished.

To be sure, the Federal Aid Highway Program is characterized by

other (non-allocational) consequences--ensuring adherence to Federal

labor and contracting regulations, promoting the implementation of

transportation planning and process guidelines, and redistributing

income. An in fact, we are arguing that greater attention needs

to be paid to these "ancillary" impacts in view of the failure of

specific components of the FAHP to effect a significant increase in

State highway expenditures. Our results indicate that restructuring

the FAHP with a relaxation of the specificity of the categorical

restrictions, and eliminating the built-in matching provisions would

not significantly alter State expenditure levels. In fact, over our

analysis period, the ABC program has effectively operated as a non-

categorical block grant system.

As described in section II.2.viii, the 1973 Highway Act has

incorporated several provisions designed to reduce the specificity of

the FAHP, most notably in terms of increasing the allowable fund

transfers between distinct Federal Aid Systems, and providing Urban

System aid for transit as well as highway construction. The logical

288

extension of the 1973 provisions would be to completely remove all

categorical and matching provisions from those components of the FAHP

where it is either not the intent or not a reasonable expectation

(given projected State expenditure levels and Federal grant availa-

bility) for Federal grnats to stimulate State expenditure levels.

289

CHAPTER V

DEVELOPMENT OF THE SHORT RUN ALLOCATION MODEL

V.1 Introduction

In this chapter, we present a model to explore the factors

influencing States' highway budget allocation. We have already

traced the impacts of Federal grants and socio-economic and

institutional characteristics on total highway expenditures. The

empirical analysis of chapter IV has been useful in verifying our

hypotheses on the substitution and stimulation effects of Federal

highway grants. Now w: turn our attention to the issue of the

determinants of expenditure levels devoted to specific types of

highway activities. Again, the central focus of the research is

the evaluation of how Federal grants have affected States' expenditure

behavior.

The short run allocation model (SRAM) developed here can be used

to asses for example the impacts of Interstate grants on Interstate

highway expenditures. Alternatively, we can investigate whether

increasing Federal highway grant availability on any of the Federal

and highway systems has been associated with increases or decreases

in highway maintenance or State highway system construction. In

short, the SRAM allows us to explore the dynamics of States'

expenditure behavior in terms of decisions relating to the allocation

of a fixed budget amongst alternative types of highway expenditures

categories (e.g. Interstate, Primary System, maintenance,

administration, etc.).

290Section 2 develops the derivation of the short run allocation

model, building on the consumer allocation theory presented in section

111.3. The derivation discusses the appropriate treatment of

alternative grant structures, and fixed State highway budget

constraints. The resulting estimatable equations take the form of a

share model with six distinct structural equations -- one for each

expenditure category. Section 3 discusses the statistical problems

inherent in estimating a share-type model. Essentially, since the

sum of the expenditure shares must equal 1.0, the six equations are

not independent. This section develops an estimation technique

which explicitly accounts for t'e joint interaction between shares.

Section 4 presents the definitions and sources of data employed

in the SRAM. Much of this data was also used in the estimation of

the total expenditure model (Chapter IV). Thus particular attention

will be given to data not previously described. The estimation

results from the SRAM are presented in section 5. As with the

empirical analysis of total expenditures, estimations of the SRAr

were performed on a full pooled 48 State/14 year data set as well as

two selected data subsets representing differing Interstate

expenditure behavior.

The empirical results from the SRAM are not easily or directly

interpretable. Accordingly, section 6 discusses the application of

derivatives and elasticities to explain State highway expenditure

behavior. This section presents a derivation of the derivative and

elasticity measures as functions of the estimated SRAM coefficients

and evaluates the behavioral implications of the actual results.

291An obvious extension of the previous section is to incorporate

the findings from the total expenditure model (TEM) into the empirical

analysis of allocation behavior. At this point we are able to

explain both dimensions of State highway expenditure behavior:

- decisions relating to the determination of the magnitude ofStates' highway budget in any given year, and

- decisions relating to the allocation of that budget amongstalternative highway activities.

Accordingly, section 7 presents the results from the TEM and SRAM in

terms of derivatives and elasticities of expenditures on each of the

six highway categories, as a function of the explanatory variables

employed in the analysis. The results of this analysis are

contrasted with the hypotheses advanced in the theoretical models of

State highway expenditure behavior developed in chapter III.

Finally, section 8 presents the conclusions and policy

irplications stemming from the empirical analyses developed in

Chapters IV and V.

292V.2 Derivation of the Short Run Allocation Model.

Before setting forth the analytical derivation of the short run

allocation model, it is important to describe the nature of the

decision environment we are attempting to model. It is convenient

to conceptualize States' highway expenditure behavior in terms of two

dimensions: the determination of total highway expenditure levels,

and decisions relating to the allocation of total expenditures

amongst broadly defined highway activities (e.g. Interstate

construction, maintenance, etc.) It should be clear at this point

that we are not attempting to explain the decision process governing

project selection at the aggregate level of analysis adopted in this

research. In modelling States' expenditure behavior, our data does

not distinguish between decisions to implement a construction or

maintenance project in a specific reqion within a State. Indeed, it

may well be argued that the complexity of individual project

evaluation -- from decisions relating to corridor determination to

detailed location studies and the formulation of specific construction

versus maintenance policies -- requires an analysis at a more

detailed level than that adopted in this research.

Nonetheless, the expression of States' investment behavior in

terms of generically defined highway activities remains a valid and

important analysis issue. This is particularly true from the

perspective of the Federal government. The Department of

Transportation administers several highway grant programs restricted

to use on a variety of broadly defined highway activities. Our

interest in developing the short run allocation model is to explain

293the impact of the FAHP on States' expenditure levels on aided and

non-aided highway activities rather than investigating the dynamics

of the decision process governing individual project selection.

In light of these observations, we may assert that States

allocate their fixed highway budget with consideration of existing

traffic levels, highway stock in place, socio-economic and

institutional characteristics, and available Federal aid, so as to

maximize their perceived benefits (utility).

The formal statement of this behavioral representation takes

the form:

(1) max U <J (E ,E2 ...Ent t' t'_t t)

nsubject to Z E? = Rt

where E = expenditures on highway category i inyear t

Ut = utility derived from the allocation ofexpenditures amongst the n highwayactivities

Rt = the available resources for highwayexpenditure in year t.

Although equation (1) is a perfectly general statement, the

representation of a State as a utility maximizer implies rather

heroic assumptions on the political and administrative realities of

State highway expenditure behavior. In particular, the use of

social indifference maps imply the existence of a well defined and

consistent set of preferences for publically provided goods.

Furthermore, we must assume that the often conflicting preference

orderings of different governmental agencies can be subsumed into

294one -- in some sense "final" -- utility mapping. These maps are not

necessarily assumed to represent the true preferences of the voting

polity, and thus do not derive from a "social welfare function".

Throughout the derivation, references to maximizing utility are

expressed in the context of the utility of a behavioral unit

("BU" -- a State Highway Department, Leislature, Department of

Transportation, etc. [see chapter III] ), whether or not this utility

truly reflects societal welfare1 . Finally, we must assume that the

existence of Federal highway grants alter a BU's resource allocation

strictly through price and/or income effects. In other words, we

ignore the possibility of shifts in the utility function due to

"spin-off effects" or "free money perceptions" introduced by highway

grants (see section III.3.vi).

1. Here again we emphasize the aggregate level of analysis adoptedI> this research. We do not attempt to trace the dynamics ofproject selection involving the resolution of conflictingpreferences among several decision-makers. Only the aggregatelevel of expenditures on all Interstate projects or maintenanceprojects are considered here. Moreover, the analysis is notnormative in the sense that no attempt is made to reflect societalpreferences.

295Accepting these provisions, we may proceed to derive estimatable

highway investment functions from our generalized utility speci-

fication. Specifically, we are not direcly concerned with the

utility function itself, but with the conditions under which this

function 4s maximized. Adopting a Cobb-Douglas utility function

specification and dropping the subscript t represting time (for

clarity), we may rewrite equation (1) as:

nmax U = U(E 1 , E2 ,...E ) = T En i=l

n(2) s.t. E R

where = parameters ("weights") of the utilityfunction

First order maximization conditionsI may be determined by the

Lagrange multiplier technique. Thus defining:

(3) TI = II- X( Z Ej - R) ,

the function U will be maximized when:

DU = al - =0

S = a - X = 0(4) rU

= E - R = 0

Forming the ratio of any two of the first n equations of (4) yields

1 The second order maximization conditions on the function U are

guaranteed by our assumption of utility funCtions convex to theorigin.

296

-or- E. - E. for i=l,...,n(5) a E 1 a j

Summing over the index i, we get

(6) Za.E. = E.= R1 (a. 3

Rearranging terms, we may write:

(7) E

E.a.

i=1

From (7) it is immediately apparent that at optimality, the States'

observed expenditure shares (the left hand side of equation 7) are a

function of their utility function parameters a. . In fact, for

the special case of utility functions homogeneous to degree one, the

model has the property that the parameters of the utility function

are just equal to the shares of each expenditure category

The basis for the development of estimatable investment

relations is that the parameters of the utility function, a.

represent "weights" -- i.e. the relative importance a State attaches

to expenditures on each of the highway categories. Thus we may

consider each a to be a function of several exogenous variables

describing traffic patterns, existing highway stock, socio-economic

1 Tresch (op.cit.), in his study of State expenditure behaviorestimated investment functions based on utility functionshomogeneous to degree one. We will not make any a prioriassumptions on the homogeneity properties of the States' utilityfunctions.

297and institutional characteristics, and Federal grant availability.Formally:

(8) = f (Z, U.) V

where Z = set of independent variables in function f

U = error term in f.

Using the functional representation of (8) in equation (7), we may

write the jth expenditure share s. as

(9) S. = E = f(zU)

Ef i (Z,9U )i=1

So far the derivation of the SRAM has centered on the rationale

for the general form of the model. Equation (9) represents the

basic structural equation of our model. The left hand side of the

equations are the directly observable highway expenditure shares in

each State and year. And the right hand side factors are a set of

exogenous explanatory variables. However as written, equation (9)

is highly non-linear, and therefore unsuitable for OLS or GLS

estimation. Rather than employing costly non-linear estimation

procedures, we may perform a simple transformation on our structural

equations to put them in the form of a linear system. Specifically,

we "normalize" each share s. by a selected share sk

(10) S. E. f.(Z,U.)

skEk k(Zk

Taking the logarithms of both sides of equation (10) leads to:

in i ) = in [ f.(Z,U.) ] - in [ fk(ZUk(k k

298The last step in our derivation requires an assumption on the

functional form of f.. In our research, the SRAM was estimated for

two alternative forms of f., product form:

(12) = LH Z 1 U.if.3 1 i

and exponential form:

(13) feji e j

i f.

It should be clear that substituting either of the two functional

forms of f. into equation (11) leads directly to an estimatable

specification of the short run allocation model:

(14) E,.Inl. n Z.. lnZ +U. - U

(E k J1 j E ki ki + a ki4j ick

(product form specification of f.)

-or-

(15) E.In = E .. Z.. - Z 3 k Zki + U.-U

(E k) i- 1 i i c ki ki J kiEJ isk

(exponential form specification of f.)

In this form, our n basic structural equations (see equation 9)

have been transformed into n-l log-linear equations. The variables

of the "normalizing share" k appear identically in each of the

remaining n-l equations. In order to determine a unique set of

parameter estimates for the kth share we must constrain the Bl

to be euqal in each of the remaining shares. This may be

accomplished by performing a constrained estimation as represented

by the matrix form in figure V.2.1.'

Two more problems must be addressed before proceeding to the

actual estimation of the short run allocation model. First of course

is the selection of the exogenous variables to be incorporated in the

analysis. The discussion has thus far been concerned only with the

form of the model. And in fact, the theory does not dictate which

variables should comprise the functions f.. Section V.4 will

discuss the a priori reasoning behind the specification of each of

our share equations.

The second analytical issue relates to the proper treatment of

Federal grants in constructing the dependent (share) variables. In

chapter III, we presented a detailed discussion on the price and/or

income effects associated with alternative types of Federal grants.

In terms of our empirical analysis, modelling alternative grant

structures requires the correct specification of the numerator and

denominator in our expenditure share terms. To see this, we may

rewrite the budget constraint of equation (1) of this section in

terms of prices and physical output measures, rather than in the

form of expenditures E. on alternative highway activities:

1 Figure V.2.1 is displayed for the exponential form specification.

299r fI

CONSTRAINED ESTIMATION FORM FOR THE SHORT RUN ALLOCATION MODEL

1 Z1 ,2 0 0 --- --- 0s i

in -Sk

s 2In -

n n-1s k

0 0 *-- 0

0

0 0

z k, Zk,2

Zk1 Zk,2

0 -- Z 1z -2 *-Zkl Z -k--

Figure V.2.1

06)CC

f

z 2,1 2,2 ------ . 01

$11

f12

2122

n-12

-1

k2

+

Ul-Uk

U2-Uk

t-i uk

CONSTRAINED ESTIMATION FORM FOR THE SHORT RUN ALLOCATION MODEL

--- e

0

0

(16) n = 0EE. =Z p.X. = R

i=1' i= 1 1

where P= price of highway activity i

X. = some physical output measure of highwayactivity i (e.g. lane miles)

R= states' own highway resources (i.e.exclusive of Federal grants)

Equation (16) expresses a budget constraint in the absence of

the availability of Federal grants, so that expenditures E and

resources R0 represent States' own funding. The introduction of a

Federal grant will alter the form of the budget constraint (and the

corresponding expenditure shares) in one of two ways, depending on

the structure of the grant.

Conditional Matching Grants - Open Ended

In this case the price of the aided category is reduced by the

Federal share payable. Assume for example that an open ended

matching grant is provided for highway commodity 1, with the Federal

government assuming g% of all expenditures on this function.

Budget constraint (16) now takes the form:1

This follows from tracing through the derivation presented inequations (2) through (7). Tresch (op.cit.) presents a gooddiscussion of these points in chapter 2 of his thesis.

301

(17) p1X (1-g) + pn X0302i=2

The first term in (17) represents States' own expenditures on the

aided category. Thus, the budget constraint is still satisfied

strictly in terms of States' own resources R0. It can be shown that

the derivation of our SRAM in this case would lead to a specification

of the numerator in the first expenditure share in terms of States'

own expendi tures. I

Block Grants - Close Ended

This type of grant does not alter States' perceived prices of

highway activities. However the total resources available to a

State are increased by the amount of the grant. Thus

(18) n n = R0 + GZ E. Z p.X.i=l 1 1il

where G = the level of Federal grant funding.

As is evident from equations (14) and (15), our normalizingprocedure renders the dependent variable in the estimatable SRAMequations in terms of a ratio between expenditure categories. Sincewe never deal explicitly with allocation shares, our task here isto determine the proper form for representing the share numerators-i.e. expenditures on each highway category. This task boils downto determining whether these expenditures should enter the modelexclusive or inclusive of Federal grants.

303Proper representation of expenditure shares in this case calls

for the specification of expenditures inclusive of-Federal grants.

The type of Federal highway grant encountered in this research,

close-ended conditional matching grants is, in a sense a hybrid of

our two above cases. We have detailed the argument (section 11I.3.V)

that as long as States exceed minimal grant matching requirements, a

close ended conditional matching grant is allocationally equivalent

to a like amount conditional block grant. Moreover, we have shown

that for the ABC program, and to a lesser extent for the Interstate

program as well, State expenditures have in fact far exceeded minimal

matching requirements (see figures 111.5.1 and 111.5.3).

Accordingly, we have chosen to model the dependent variables in the

SRAM as if Federal highway aid were provided on a conditional block

grant basis (i.e. States expenditures enter the model inclusive of

Federal grants).

For the Interstate grant program, our modellinq convention may

be somewhat suspect. In certain States, Interstate expenditures

have apparently been set at a level indicative of a "corner solution"

(see figure V.2.2). In other words, when State expenditures just

equal minimal grant matching requirements (as indicated in figure

V.2.2 by the tangency of utility curve UU1 at the break point in the

close-ended matching grant budget line R a R/ ), it is unclear

whether small changes in the level of Interstate grant funding would

result in States reacting along the locus of budget line R bR 1 (as2 2(as

our modelling convention assumes) or R bR2/

304

CORNER SOLUTIONS IN THE SRAM

LA

Figure V.2.2

305Fortunately our convention of modelling Interstate grants as

conditional block grants should not create any major problems. All

States have exceeded minimal Interstate matching requirements over

the course of our fourteen year study period. Although these

"excess" expenditures are often relatively small, it should be noted

that the Federal matching rate for the Interstate program -- as high

as 95% -- approaches conditional block funding (100%) in any event.

It is useful at this point to summarize our development of the

short run allocation model. The model is appealing for several

reasons. First it derives from an explicit representation of State

expenditure behavior that takes explicit account of the joint inter-

action between expenditure shares. The incorporation of a budget

constraint in our analysis recognizes the fact that the decision to

increase expenditures in one activity must be compensated with

reduced expenditures in at least one other activity. Second it

provides a convenient framework for evaluating any number of

allocation categories. For example, while we have not chosen to

divide our highway construction categories (e.g. Interstate, Primary,

Secondary Systems) into urban and ruralcomponents, dividing aggregate

categories into several subcategories is easily facilitated. Finally,

the SRAM takes explicit account of alternative grant structures.

In fact our adoption of a utility function with no a prioriassumptions on homogeneity properties guarantees that theexpenditure shares sum to one regardless of the parameterestimates of the SRAM.

306

Although our application was restricted to the representation of

Federal aid as conditional block grants, the analysis framework is

perfectly general in the way it treats differing grant structures.1

For example, Tresch (op.cit.) employed a model similar to the

SRAM to evaluate the impacts of open-ended conditional matchingWelfare grants.

307V.3 Statistical Properties and Estimation Procedures

In the derivation of the short run allocation model presented

in the previous section, care was taken to account for the joint

interaction between State highway allocation decisions. Specifically,

our explicit representation of a States' highway budget constraint

implies that the decision to increase highway expenditures on one

activity (share) must be "compensated" by a decrease in expenditures

devloted to at least one other activity. The choice of this analysis

framework places special requirements on both the manner in which the

individual structural equations enter the model, and the proper

estimation techniques to ensure efficient, unbiased parameter

estimates.

We have already briefly discussed the former issue. Because

the sum of a States' expenditure shares must equal 1.0, it is clear

that the individual share equations are not independent.

Operationally, this implies that it is not possible to separately

estimate each share equation. In fact, as displayed in figure

V.2.2, the entire set of expenditure shares are estimated in one

equation. This matrix representation of the SRAM ensures proper

treatment of the joint interaction between allocation decisions, and

provides a unique set of estimates for the coefficients of the

"normalizing share"

While the structure of the short run allocation model has

appealing theoretical properties, it is clear that our behavioral

assumptions create inherent problems in obtaining efficient and

unbiased parameter estimates. Specifically, in light of the inter-

308action between shares, it is generally not appropriate for the

estimation procedure to ignore these interrelationships as ordinary

least squares must necessarily do.)

To clarify the statistical problems inherent in estimating the

SRAM, it is convenient to rewrite the error term specification in

figure V.2.2 as Unts to emphasize the representation of our individual

observations in terms of a specific State, year and share. In this

notation:

n = 1, ...N = State number

t = 1, ...T =year

s -1, ...S = share number

In the pooled data set where the 48 States and 14 years are combined

in a single regression, the variance-covariance matrix of the

residual terms may be written as:

(19) = E[untsunts]

The "interrelationships" between shares imply a covariance betweenthe residuals of our individual structural equations. Thus thevariance-covariance matrix of the error terms is not scalar, andordinary least squares estimation is not appropriate.

309

~~1 C 12 Gs

21 22 2s

si s2 Wss

where: .. - an NTxNT matrix of variances andcovariances between the residualsof the N States over T years forshare i (i=1,...S)

= an NTxNT matrix of covariancesJ between the residuals of share i

and share j for N States and Tyears.

Following the discussion of the previous section, it is

reasonable to assume that within a State in a given year, errors

across expenditure categories (shares) are correlated. This

statement merely expresses in econometric terms the basic SRAM

premise that allocation decisions are interrelated. As a

computational necessity, we have been forced to qualify the above

statement by assuming that errors are independently distributed

across States and years and inter-share covariance terms are

distributed identically for all States and years:

310(20) ( %, if n=n' and t=t'

E[Untsun'nt's] = 0 if n/n' and/or tjt'

$ss if n=n' and t=t' and s=s'

While the simplification in the assumed error structure represented

by equation (20) may be questioned, it must be remembered that we are

dealing with an extremely large variance-covariance matrix. The

ultimate use of generalized least squares estimation requires the

inversion of the NTSxNTS matrix G. In our application where M=48,

T=14 and S=5, S1 (3360x3360) contained over 11 million elements. We

have attempted to model the most significant behavioral interactions

in keeping with an operation estimation procedure. 2

1 Actually, the short run allocation model incorporated six distinctexpenditure categories. But as discussed in section V.2, our"normalizing" procedure transforms transforms the basic structuralspecification into a single regression equation with S-1 shares

2 Perhaps the most dubious assumption inherent in equation (20) isthat within a given State, errors are distributed independentlyover time. It may also be hypothesized that (at least forbordering States) within a given year for a given share (particular-ly for the Interstate share), errors between States are correlated.We have actually tried to explicitly model these interactions.These experiments proved to be exceedingly expensive and impractical.

Substituting the assumptions inherent in equation (20) in 311

equation (19) yields the basic structure of the variance-covaraince

matrix of the SRAM residual terms. Using the notation of equation

(19) we may now assert the basic form of Q :

(21)

(22)

wss

wss

ss

0

0

Ess'

0

0

0 -

$ss

0 -

Ess'.

0

ss

-'-0

.0'0

0 * -ss

The development of generalized least squares parameter estimates,

given the assumed structure of the variance-covariance matrix

(equations 21 and 22) is straightforward. Following the procedure

outlined in section IV.3, we first perform an OLS estimation of the

short run allocation model. Using the OLS estimates of the residual

terms Unts, and the assumed structure of the variance covariance

312

matrix, we may derive the parameters of a by:

N T(23) $ss = unts s=1,..S

n=l t=1

1 N T(24) Yss' =untsunts

SS N T n =l t=l ^n s t ' s 1-2 , ... ,2S

The estimates of Sss and Ess, are then employed in determining

the Choleski decomposition of 2 (see equation (15) of chapter IV).

Finally, our original data set is transformed by the Choleski

decomposition matrix and another regression is performed to produce

generalized least squares parameter estimates.

In summary, we have attempted in this section to derive an

operational procedure for estimating efficient and unbiased

parameter estimates of the short run allocation model. Particular

attention has been given to the proper econometric treatment of the

assumed interaction between expenditures on individual highway

activities. The next section presents the actual specification of

variables employed in the SRAM that was estimated in this research.

Equations (23) and (24) express the average value of all elements

of Unts ts corresponding to where$s or s appear in our

assumed structure of Q.

313V.4 Modelling Considerations and Data Requirements

The short run allocation model consists of six distinct structural

equations corresponding to expenditures devoted to Interstate System

construction, Primary System construction, Secondary System construc-

tion, non-Federal-Aid System construction, maintenance activities

(an all road systems) and on "other" category capturing State

expenditures administration, highway police and safety, bond interest

and grants to local governments. These six shares are representative

of the three major Federally aided highway activities, and the three

major non-aided State highway functions. As such, we are able to

trace not only how a Federal grant effects expenditures on the aided

functions, but the resulting tradeoff and complementary allocation

responses among all major activities as well.

The dependent variable in each of the SRAM (structural)

equations represents the share of a State's total expenditures devoted

to a particular highway activity. The explanatory variables, as in

the total expenditure model (Chapter IV) fall into four categories:

socio-economic indicators (e.g. population and per capita income),

highway system characteristics (e.c. highway capital stocks and

congestion levels), institutional characteristics (e.g. local govern-

ment participation and toll road financing conventions), and Federal

grant availability.

The actual form of the short run allocation model is displayed in

Figure V.4.1 for the product form specification.1 Several

A similar specification of variables was also employed inestimating an exponential form model (c.f. equation 13).

characteristics of the SRAM are immediately apparent. First, we 314

have represented Federal highway grant availability in terms of each

of the major Federal-Aid-Systems - Interstate, Primary and Secondary.1

Contrastingly, the total expenditure model of the previous chapter

disaggregated grant availability only in terms of an Interstate and

non-Interstate designation. A second characteristic of the SRAM

is that individual constant terms have been incorporated in all but

one of the share equations. The exclusion of a constant from the

maintenance equation (which in fact was chosen as our "normalizing

share") was dictated by the fact that in a shares-type model

specification the matrix of explanatory variables will not be of

full column rank if a particular variable appears in each structural

equation.2

Finally, it should be noted that in estimating the short run

allocation model, the maintenance equation was chosen to normalize

each of the five remaining shares in the manner described by

equation (10). The choice of a particular normalizing share will

Grants for extensions of the Federal Aid Primary and SecondarySystems in urban areas ("C" funds) were added to terms representingPrimary-andSecondary System grant availability. This modellingconvention reflects the fact "C" funds may be used for eitherPrimary or Secondary system construction.

2 Thus it may also be noted that the population variable, SPOPappears in all but the share representing constructionexpenditures on non-Federal-Aid Systems (see Figure V.4.1).

315in general affect the empirical results.1 Ultimately, the mainten-

ance equation was selected as the normalizing share for no other

reason than that expenditure data on this function appeared to be

less reliable than for the remaining categories.2

Before presenting the estimation results derived from the

SRAM, it is useful to set forth a brief description of the variables

employed in each of the expenditure shares. Figure V.4.1 displays

the form of the entire set of SRAM equations.

Regardless of which equation is chosen as normalizing share, ourestimation procedures should provide efficient and inbiased para-meter estimates. Nonetheless, for a given data sample, we mayexpect small differences in the estimated model parametersdepending on the choice of a normalizing share.

2 Some variability exists in the States' data reporting conventions.A project considered to be a maintenance activity in one Statemight be reported as a construction expenditure by another State.

THE SHORT RUN ALLOCATION MODEL

E T

E p

a a,, a a a. aa 10SPOPIIUFACIz KSTK 13 TOLPCT 14AVIG 1 5 AVNIG 16

a 20SPOPa21UFACa22KSTKa23AVPGa24AVIGa26

- a SPOPa 31UFACa32GINIa33TSPMRa34PCCRMTa35AVSGa36AVIGa37ET 30

EN= a4UFACa41PCCRMTa42RLTOTa43AVIGa44L T 40

EM a SPOPa51 KSTKa52FPCMFa53RLTOTa 54AVTGa55E T 50

r = a6 SpP0 a61 PCY a62KSTKa62RLTOT a63AVGa64

T

Figure V.4.1

L&)

SHARE I:

SHARE 2:

SHARE 3:

SHARE 4:

SHARE 5:

SHARE 6:

E = total State Interstate expenditures (State and Federal) 317

E = total Primary System expenditures

ES = total Secondary System expenditures

EN = non-Federal-Aid System construction expenditures

EM = maintenance expenditures

E0 = "other" expenditures (administration, grants to local govts.,mi scel'Idneous expenditures)

ET = totai expenditures: sum of the above expenditures

SPOP = State population

UFAC = percent of population residing in urban areas

KSTK = present discounted value of highway capital stock

TOLPCT = percent of total State revenues raised on State-administeredtoll roads

AVIG = apportioned Interstate grants (three year moving average)

AVNIG = apportioned "ABC" grants (three year moving average)

AVPG = apportioned Primary System grants (three year moving average)

AVSG = apportioned Secondary System grants (three year moving average

AVTG = apportioned total grants (three year moving average)

GINI = index of income inequality

TSPMR = State rural primary system mileage

PCCRMT = percent of rural primary system mileage carrying more than10,000 ADT

PCMF percent of total primary system mileage carrying more than5,000 AUi

RLTOT = percent of total expenditures (all units of govt.) contributedby local governments

PCY = State per capita income

aij = estimated coefficients

Figure V.4.1 (contd.)

I318

Equation 1 - The Interstate Construction Share'

Six variables in addition to a constant term were employea in the

Interstate construction expenditure share equation. State size and

urban density are characterized by the variables SPOP and UFAC

respectively. With regard to the latter variable, we may expect

higher levels of urban density to positively influence Interstate

expenditure allocations, in light of the sharply increased costs of

urban versus rural highway construction of Interstate standards.2

A measure of existing highway stock in place is afforded by the

variable KSTK, derived accordina to the conventions Presented in

section IV.3. An institutional characteristic bearing particular

importance on a States' Interstate expenditure behavior is the

extent of toll road financing, TOLPCT. In the early years of the

Throughout the following presentation, unless otherwise indicatedthe definitions and sources of data employed in the SRAM are thesame as previously described in the development of the totalexpenditure model (see section IV.3).

2 The relatively high costs of urban Interstate construction stem fromthe marked difference between ROW acquisition costs in urban andrural areas. Moreover, Interstate expenditures are particularlysensitive to land costs, since this System's design standardsrequire more ROW than other highway systems.

Interstate program, several States chose to finance Interstate 319

highway construction through the use of revenue bonds based on toll

road operation. In fact the responsibility to construct and maintain

these Interstate route segments was often delegated to a quasi-public

Turnpike Authority.1 As such, all toll-financed Interstate

activities are not reported in our data as State expenditures.

Accordingly, we should expect the extent of toll-road financing

(TOLPCT) to negatively influence a States' allocation of resources

to construction on the Interstate System.

The final two variables in the Interstate equation reflect

Federal grant availability on the Interstate (AVIG) and non-Inter-

state (AVNIG) Systems. Results from the total expenditure model

(TEM) indicate that Interstate grants tend to stimulate State (total)

expenditures. The SRAM allows us to determine the extent to which

these grants have increased States' allocations specifically to

Interstate construction. The States' Interstate expenditure

response to the presence of non-Interstate grants may actually take

one of two directions. On the one hand, we might expect increasing

levels of non-Interstate grants to "draw away" resources that would

otherwise have been devoted to Interstate construction. However, as

we have shown in chapter IV, the ABC grant program has been viewed

by the States as a substitute for their own ABC expenditures. In

1 It should also be noted that toll-financed Interstate roads arenot eligible for Federal aid as stipulated by Title 23, UnitedStates Code, Section 301.

320

this perspective, increasing levels of ABC grants may "free up" State

resources that may be allocated on Interstate construction as well as

other State highway activities. In the SRAM, we will appeal to the

data to verify the latter hypothesis.

Equation 2 - The Primary System Construction Share

This equation contains the same socio-economic and highway

capital stock measures employed in the Interstate equation. However,

we should expect the States' Primary System expenditure responses to

these variables to differ from the expected responses expressed by

the Interstate share equation. For example, the urban density

measure should not exhibit as marked a positive influence on Primary

System expenditures because of the previously noted difference in

Primary System and Interstate System right of way requirements.

Federal aid availability in this equation was represented by two

terms -- the level of Primary System grants (AVPG) and the level of

Interstate System grants. The direct effect of Primary System

grants on State Primary System expenditures must be positive.1

1 Note that the dependent variables in the SRAM reflect total expen-diture levels inclusive of Federal arants. Even assuming thatStates need not raise their expenditure levels on the PrimarySystem to match increasing Federal Primary System grant availability(because current State expenditure levels far exceed minimalmatching requirements), it is extremely unlikely that States woulddecrease their own resource allocation to the Primary System by morethan the amount of Federal grant increases. This point will becomeclearer in section V.6 where elasticity measures are presented forthe SRAM. Suffice it to say here that we expect small increases inPrimary System grant availability - say 1% - to increase States'Primary System expenditure allocation, but most likely by an amountless than 1% (indicative of a substitutive grant response).

321The more irportant question is how these grants have influenced

States' own resource allocation on the Primary System. The empirical

results presented in the following sections will serve to verify our

previous hypotheses on the substitutive expenditure impacts of Primary

System grants. As for the States' Primary System expenditure res-

ponse to Interstate grants, we should expect a negative influence.

That is, our findings to this point suggest that the Interstate grant

program has increased State highway investment levels. The SRAM

estimation results will indicate the extent to which these increased

investment levels have come at the expense of resource allocation to

other State highway activities.

Equation 3 - The Secondary System Construction Share

Eioht variables (including the constant term) were used to

express the factors influencing States' Secondary System allocation

decisions. Since the relative importance of the Secondary System in

a State's highway network is greatest in the predominantly rural/

agricultural States,1 we should expect the population variable SPOP,

and the urban density measure UFAC to negatively influence Secondary

System expenditure allocation. By the same reasoning the GINI index

of income inequality (which was shown to be highest in rural/agricul-

tural States -- see figure IV.4.2) should relate positively to

Secondary System expenditure levels.

1 As noted in section II.2.iii, the Federal-Aid Secondary Systemcomprises farm-to-market roads, rural mail routes, public schoolbus routes, local rural roads, county roads, and township roads.

322In addition to these socio-economic indices, two descriptors of

the States' rural highway systems were included in the Secondary

System SRAM equation. The first, total State rural highway mileage

(TSPMR), indicates the scale of the existing rural highway network.

A second measure, PCCRMT provides a measure of the level of congestion

on the States' rural roads.2 Specifically, this variable represents

the percent of a State's rural highway mileage carrying more than

10,000 vehicles per day. We should expect hinher levels of rural

highway traffic to influence a State to increase Secondary System

construction expenditures.

1 This variable describes total State (i.e. exclusive of roads undercounty or municipal jurisdiction) highway mileage. Data werederived from yearly editions of the Federal Highway Administration'sHIGHWAY STATISTICS (op. cit.)

2 HIGHWAY STATISTICS (op. cit.) reports traffic volume data in termsof seven distinct ADT categories, ranqing from a State's mileagecarrying less than 5000 ADT to the number of miles bearing greaterthan 40000 ADT. The variable PCCRMT was derived from this sourceby dividing the rural mileage carrying greater than 10000 ADT, bytotal rural mileage.

323The final two variables in the Secondary System share equation

describe Federal grant availability for the Secondary (AVSG) and

Interstate (AVIG) Systems. The expected expenditure responses in

this instance should follow our discussion of hypothesized grant

response in the Primary System equation. Specifically, increased in

Federal Secondary aid should raise States' Secondary expenditures,

but by an amount less than a grant increase. Interstate grants on

the other hand may be expected to decrease States' Secondary

expenditure levels.

Equation 4 - The Non-Federal Aid System (MFAS) Construction Share

In addition to their construction of Interstate, Primary and

Secondary System highways, States also (wholly) finance the

construction of roads apart from the Federal-Aid System designation.

This activity represents a relatively minor expenditure of funds

(averaging less than 10% for our 48 State/14 year sample), and most

commonly represents rural highway construction. Four variables

(and a constant term) were included in this expenditure share.

Perhaps the most significant factor explaining the level of non-

Federal-Aid System expenditures is the degree of local highway

participation in highway finance (RLTOT). States differ markedly

in the extent to which counties and municipalities assume the

authority to construct and maintain local road networks. Since the

SRAM is structured strictly in terms of State activities, we would

expect RLTOT to negatively influence (State) expenditures on non-

Federal Aid System roads. The parameter estimate of the urban

density measure, UFAC should also be negative, reflecting the high

incidence of non-Federal Aid System construction in rural areas. 324

Our discussion so far provides the basis for the expected signs

of the parameter estimates of the two remaining variables included in

this expenditure share -- the degree of rural road congestion (PCCRMT)

and Federal Interstate grant availability (AVIG). Again noting the

relatively high incidence of NFAS construction in rural areas, we

should expect the presence of rural road congestion to induce higher

expenditure levels on this activity. Increases in Interstate grant

availability should, on the other hand decrease State expenditures on

NFAS construction, as States devote an increasing share of their

highway budget to expenditures on the aided function.

Equation 5 - The Maintenance Expenditure Share

The maintenance expenditure share contains five explanatory

variables -- State population (SPOP), depreciated highway capital

stocks (KSTK), a highway congestion measure (PCMF), the extent of

local participation in highway finance (RLTOT) and the level of total

Federal grant availability (AVTG). As in the previous share

equation, to the extent that a State delegates highway authority to

county and municipal governments, (State) maintenance expenditures

should decrease. That is, we should expect a negative coefficient

for the RLTOT term.

Although we might expect both of the highway system

characteristics variables, KSTK and PCMF to positively influence

States' maintenance expenditures, this response pattern need not

necessarily pertain. We refer here to the differing State policies

regarding the performance of highway maintenance activities. If all

States practiced a uniform maintenance policy,1 then increasing 325

congestion levels and/or increasing highway capital stocks would

increase highway maintenance requirements. But we may also observe

that some States adopt a highway policy favoring construction (as

opposed to maintenance) expenditures. Thus, relatively high levels

of existing capital stock actually (may) signal an explicit policy of

constructing highway facilities "at the expense" of maintenance

operations.2 Similarly, higher congestion levels may induce States

to increase construction expenditures rather than maintenance

operations. The SRAM allows for a specific test of these

conflicting hypotheses.

We have also included a term in the maintenance share equation

representing total Federal highway grant availability. The intent

here is to assess whether the presence of Federal aid has tended to

divert State expenditures from non-aided (i.e. maintenance) highway

activities.

For example, attempting to implement a specific policy to maintainuniform road surface quality. See Findakly, H.K., A DECISION MODELFOR INVESTMENT ALTERNATIVES IN HIGHWAY SYSTEMS, Unpublished ScDThesis, Department of Civil Engineering, Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology, September, 1972.

2 As reported in our data, a major resurfa project would berecorded as a construction expenditure. Maintenance expendituresare reported for patching, sealing and filling of road surfaces.

326Equation 6 - The "Other" Expenditures Share

The final share in our SRAM formulation captures expenditures on

all other State highway activities not included in the first five

equations. Specifically, this category is comprised of expenditures

on administration, highway police and safety, debt service payments,

and grants to local governments. Five variables (plus a constant

term) were incorporated in this SRAM equation. The first three,

SPOP, PCY and KSTK should all positively influence "other"

expenditures since States with relatively high populations, per capita

incomes and existing highway networks can be expected to support

relatively large highway-related administrative organizations ( e.g.

State Highway Departments and State Departments of Transportation).

As in our previous share equations, the delegation of highway

authority to lower units of government should decrease the

administrative requirements of State highway organizations. This

effect is captured in the variable RLTOT, which should be associated

with a negative coefficient estimate. Finally, a total Federal-aid

term was included (AVTG) to evaluate the impacts of Federal highway

grants on the performance of States' administrative and other

higheay activities.

327V.5 Empirical Results -- Parameter Estimates of the SRAM

As in the empirical analysis of the total expenditure model, lack

of sufficient time series data precluded statistically reliable State

by State estimation of the short run allocation model. Thus three

separate pooled data regressions were performed,1 corresponding to:

- the entire set of observations on the 48 States over 14

years (1957-1970).

- a subset of time series observations on the seven States

exhibiting the lowest level of Interstate expenditures over

and above minimum matching requirements, and

- the subset comprising observations on the 41 remaining

States over the 14 year period 1957-1970.

As described in section V.2, estimation of the SRAM was performed

for two alternative specifications of the individual structural (share)

equations - a product form model, and an exponential form model.

These data-set stratifications are similar to the modelling strategyfollowed in chapter IV. The seven States with conspicuously low"excess" Interstate expenditures were Missouri,'Montana,: NorthCarolina, North Dakota, South Carolina, Vermont and Virginia.

328The complete set of estimation results from the short run

aallocation model are reproduced in Figures V.5.1 - V.5.8. In these

figures, the results are displayed for each of the six expenditure

shares.I In each share equation, the figures indicate the individual

parameter estimates, standard errors and t-statistics in that order.

Figures V.5.1 and V.5.2 display the model parameters from the

product form specification on the full pooled data set using OLS and

GLS estimation respectively. The next four figures correspond to OLS

and GLS estimation of the two data subsets of the SRAM in the product

form specification. Finally, Figures V.5.7 and V.5.8 display the

respective OLS and GLS estimations of the exponential form SRAM on the

full pooled data set.

The empirical results from the short run allocation model are

most easily interpreted in terms of elasticities and derivatives of

the categorical expenditures with respect to the explanatory variables

incorporated in our analysis. This will be our task in the next two

sections of this chapter.

1 The notation used in the figures to denote expenditure shareequations is as follows: INT- Interstate construction, PRI - PrimarySystem construction, SEC - Secondary System construction, NON - non-Federal Aid System construction, MNT- maintenance, and OTH - allother expendi tures.

SHARE MODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRESSION METHOD:F-STAT: F(37,3323)=25.97

ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES6 SEE= 1.037 RSQ= 0.200

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK TOLPCT AVIG AVNIG-0.36E 01 -0.14E 01 0.46E 00 -0.59E 00 -0.78E-01 0.98E 00 -0.27E-01

INT 0.15E 01 0.17E 00 0.17E 00 0.16E 00 0.28E-f1 0.33E 00 0.22E 00-2.51 -8.49 2.72 -3.76 -2.73 2.93 -0.12

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK AVPG AVIG-0.42E 01 -0.12E 01 -0.83E-C3 -0.40F 00 0.66E 00 0.13E 00

PRI 0.14E 01 0.16E 00 0.17E 00 0.16E 00 0.21E 00 0.33E 00-2.95 -7.48 -0.00 -2.55 3.07 0.38

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC 61I1 TSPMR PCCRMT AVSG AVIG-0.17E 01 -0.11E 01 -0.15E 00 -0.86E-01 0.26E 00 0.67E-02 0.45E 00 -0.58E-01

SEC 0.19E 01 0.13E 00 0.18E 00 0.32E 00 0.10E 00 0.42E-01 0.19E 00 0.34E 00-0.88 -7.87 -0.85 -0.27 2.49 0.16 2.35 -0.17

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RLTOT AVIG-0.97E 01 -0.77E 00 0.21E 00 -0.49E 00 -0.89E-01

NON 0.12E 01 0.17E 00 0.34E-01 0.66E-01 0.50E 00-7.91 -4.38 6.20 -7.42 -0.18

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0.86E 00 -0.14E 00 0.37E-01 -0.97E-UI 0.21E 00

MNT 0.10E 00 0.93E-01 0.30E-01 0.34E-01 0.49E 00-8.54 -1.55 1.22 -2.88 0.43

CONSTANT-0.10E 02

OTH 0.19E 01-5.41

SPOP-0.1OE 03.

0.15E 00-6.78

PCY0.94E 000.22E no

4.23

KSTK-0.75E 00

0.19E 00-3.95

Figure V.5.1CA)ro

RLTOT0. 11E-010.65 E-01

0.16

AVTG0.54E 000.51E 00

1.06

%J I L- %-f I 1 9 %.# V% I I w 1 11 6 1 4 'k %Lf S.F %0 %d I - I I %.R %-A L- L-

SHARE MODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRESSION METHOD: GENERALIZED LEAST SQUARES

F-STAT: F(37,3323)=56.815 SEE= 0.!q7 RSQ= 0.354

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK TOLPCT AVIG AVNIG-0.70E 01 -0.15E 01 0.44E 00 -0.19E (0 -0.82E-01 0.12E 01 0.15E 00

INT 0.16E 01 0.24E 00 0.89E-01 0.19E 00 0.14E-01 0.25E 00 0.14E 00-4.52 --6.27 L.92 -1.03 -5.72 4.84 1.09

-CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK AVPG AVIG-0.58E 01 -0.63E 00 -0.16E 00 0.86E-01 0.71E 00 -0.92E-01

PRI 0.14E 01 0.16E 00 0.74E-01 0.13E 00 0.99E-01 0.16E 00-4.12 -4.01 -2.10 0.69 7.14 -0.57

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC GINI TSPMR PCCRMT AVSG AVIG0.27E 01 -0.541 00 --0.24E 00 0.33E 00 0.31E 00 0.3EE-01 0.31E 00 -0.11E 00

SEC 0.17E 01 0.9E-01 0.78E-O1 0.14E CO 0.46E-01 0.18[-01 0.77E-01 0.81E-011.56 -7.94 -3.13 2.31 6.7-4 2.07 3.97 -1.34

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RLTOT AVIG-0.48E 01 -0.85E 00 0.19E 00 -0.52E 00 0.23E 00

NON 0.12E 01 0.34E 00 0.60E-01 0.11E 00 0.36E 00-4.06 -2.48 3.21 -4.57 0.63

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0.90E 000.23E 00

-3.91

0.26E 000.18E 00

1.46

0. 78E-020. 26E-01

0.30

-0. 71E-010. 23E-01

-3.10

KSTK-0.93E-010.71 E-01

-1.31

RLTOT AVTG-0,18E-02 -0.25E 000.22E-01 0.73E-01

-0.79 -3.44

Figure V.5.2

MNT

CONSTANT-0.14E 02

OTH 0.11E 01-8.02

SPOP0.23E 000.55E-01

4.18

PCy0.82E Co0. 85E-01

9.66

0.57E 000.37E 00

1.51

waL46)C0

SHARE MODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPEC I F I CA TIOtN: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRTS[9N METHOD:F-STAT: F(37, 453)=12.44

ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES9 SEE:= 0. 793 RSQ= 0. 468

CONSTANT-0.35E 01

INT 0.48E 01-0.74

CONS TANT-0.13E 01

PRI 0.47E 01-0.28

SPOP UFAC-0.18E 01 0.48E-0)0.34E 00 0.56E 00

-5.22 0.09

S POP-0.13E 01

0.33E 00-4.13

KSTK TOLPCT AVIG AVLN Q-0. 20F 00 0.31E-01 0,81E 00 0.30E 000.31E 00 0.60E-01 0.79E 00 0.47E 00

-0.64 0.52 1.03 0.64

UFAC KSTK AVPG AYIG0.58E 00 -0.iOE CO 0.64E 00 0.73E-020.56E 00 0.31E 00 0.44E 00 0.77E 00

1.04 -0.34 1.45 0.01

CCONSTANT0.35E 0]

SEC G.54E 010.64

SPOP-0.14E 01

0.36E 00-3.99

UFAC Giii0.14E 01 -0.28E 000.64E 00 0.95E 00

2.18 -0.29

TSPMR PCCRWIM0.]7E 01 -0.12E 000.77E 00 0.14E 00

2 23 -0.86

AVSG AVIQ-0.59E 00 -0.14E-010.79E 00 0.82E 00

-0.?5 -0.02

CONSTANT UFAC.0.34E 01 -0.t2E 01

NON C.51E 01 0.56E 000.6E -2.12

MNT

PCCRMT RTOT AVIG0.49E 00 -0.28E 00 -0.91E 000.10E 00 0.15E 00 0.13E 01

4.84 -1.93 -0.72

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOF AVTG-0.79E 00 0.50E-02 0.54E-01 -0.85E-01 0.18E-010.22E 00 0.13E 00 0.74E-91 0.76E-01 0.12E 01

-3.68 0.03 0.73 -1.13 0.02

CONSTANT SPOP0.18E 01 -0.10E 01

0TH 0.48E 01 0.29E 000.38 -3.53

PCY0.70E-010.60E 00

0.12

KSTK R .TOT0.27E 00 -0.55E-010.40E 00 0.14E 00

0.66 -0.38

Figure V.5.3

AVTG0.75E-010.12E 01

0.06

CoCO

SHARE MODELESTIMATIONRESULTS

SPECIFICATION: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRESSION ME1HOD: GENERALIZED LEAST SQUARES

F-STAT: F(37, 453)=17.321 SEE= 1.039 RSO= 0.550

CONSTANT-0.94E 01

INT 0.64E 01-1.48

SPOP-0.16E 01

0.29E 00-5.37

CONSTANT-0.31E 01

PRI 0.62E 01-0.50

SPOP-0.80E 00

0.22E 00-3.63

UFAC0. 61E 000.26E 00

2.31

KSTK AVPG AVIG.19E 00 0.48E 00 -0.18E 00.18E 00 0.21E 00 0.38E 001.06 2.25 -0.49

CONSTANT0.80E 01

SEC 0.70E 011.15

SPOP-0.10E 010.19E 00

-5.59

UFAC0.97E 000.28E 00

3.51

GINI-0.19E 000.41E 00

-0.46

TSPMR0.13E 010.33E 00

3.94

PCCRMT AVSG AVIG-0.24E-01 -0.32E 00 -0.73E-010.60E-O1 0.34E 00 0.32E 00

-0.40 -0.94 -0.23

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RkTOT AVIG0.24E 01 -0.62E 00 0.36E 00 -0.35E 00 -0.13E 01

NON 0.66E 01 0.11E 01 0.18E 00 0.25E 00 O.13E 010.36 -0.59 1.99 -1.38 -1.02

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTO AVTG-0.69E 00 0.32E 00 0.12E 00 -0.58E-01 -0.62E-01

MNT 0.24E 00 0.18E 00 0.51E-01 0.48E-01 0.77E 00-2.84 1.78 2.42 -1.22 -0.08

-CONSTANT_.SPOP PCY_ 1 KYTK RLQTh_ AVT G0.97E 00 -0.32E 00 0.28E 00 0.45E 00 -0.94E-01 -0.22E 00

OTH 0.65E 01 0.15E 00 0.20E 00 0.16E 00 0.49E-01 0.43E 000.15 -2.21 1.37 2.87 -1.92 -0.51

Figure V.5.4

UFAC0.12E 000.33E 00

0.35

KSTK0.13E 000.23E 00

0.59

TOLPCT0. 22E-010. 36E-01

0.60

AVIG0.R1E 000.50E 00

1.62

AVNIG0.14U 000.29E 00

0.47

SHARE MODELEST IMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRESSION METHOD:F-STAT: F(37,2833)=19.81

ORDI'iARY LEAST SQUARES7 SEE= 1.058 RSO= 0.183

CONSTANT SPOP VFAC KSTK TOLPCT AVIG AVNIG-0.34E 01 -0.12E 01 0.32E 00 -0.57E 00 -0.13E 00 0.94E 00 -0.15E 00

INT 0.16E 01 0.20E 00 0.19E 00 0.18E 00 0.34E-01 0.37E 00 0.25E 00-2.16 -5.80 1.71 -3.09 -3.92 2.53 -0.60

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK AVPG AVIG-0.44E 01 -0.10E 01 -0.16E 00 -0.44E 00 0.68E 00 0.11E 00

PRI 0.15E 01 0.18E 00 0.19E 00 0.18E 00 0.24E 00 0.37E 00-2.88 -5.81 -0.85 -2.45 2.78 0.30

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC GINI TSPMR PCCRMT AVSG AVIG-0.23E 01 -0.94E 00 -0.44E 00 0.33E-01 0.25E 00 0.32E-01 0.56E 00 -0.93E-01

SEC 0.21E 01 0.15E 00 0.20E 00 0.34E 00 0.11E 00 0.46E-nl 0.22E 00 0.38E 00-1.10 -6.30 -2.14 0.10 2.18 0.70 2.59 -0.24

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RLTOT AVIG-0.11E 02 -0.73E 00 0.1SE 00 -0.45E 00 0.73E-01

NON 0.13E 01 0.20E 00 0.36E-01 0.73E-01 0.56E 00-8.24 -3.70 5.07 -6.17 0.14

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0.80E 00 -0.19E 00 0.23E-01 -0.56E-01 0.28E 00

tiNT 0.11E 00 0.10E 00 0.34E-01 0.37E-01 0.55E 00-7.05 -1.82 0.69 -1.51 0.51

CONSTANT SPOP PCY KSTK RLTOT AVTG-0.94E 01

OTH 0.21E 01-4.46

-0.90E 000.17E 00

-5.20

0.72E 000.24E 00

2.94

-0.77E 000.21E 00

-3.59

-0 .96E-030.73F-01

-0.01

0.59E 000.56E 00

1.05

Figure V.5.5 GaGaGa

SHARE MODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: PRODUCT FORM MODEL

REGRESSION METHOD: GENERALIZED LEAST SQUARES

F-STAT: F(37,2833)=49.481 SEE= 1.000 RSQ= 0.359

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KST K TOLPCT AVIG AVNIG-0.79E 01 -0.11E 01 0.26E 00 -0.25E 00 -0.14E 00 0.11E 01 0.96E-01

INT 0.17E 01 0.22E 00 0.87E-01 0.18E 00 0.16E-01 0.25E 00 0.14E 00-4.71 -4.72 3.02 -1.37 -9.27 4.60 0.69

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK AVPG AIIG-0.70E 01 -0.53E 00 -0.30t 00 -0.53F-02 0.81E 00 -0.44E-f1

PRI 0.15E 01 0.16E 00 0.84E-01 0.14E 00 0.11E 00 0.18E 00-4.72 -4.2f: -3.62 -0.04 7.18 -0.25

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC GIUI TSPMR PCCPMT AVSG AVIG0z25E 01 -0.51F 00 -0.39F 00 0.38E 00 0.32E 00 0.40E-01 0.30F 00 -0.48F-01

SEC 0.19E 01 0.72E-01 0.SfE-01 0.15E 00 0.50E-01 0.20E-01 0.89E-01 0.93E-011.33 -7.07 -4.39 2.48 6.54 2.02 3.35 -0.52

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RLTOT AVIG-0.47E 01 -. 71E 00 0.16E 00 -0.49E 00 0.48E 00

NON 0.12E 01 0.39E 00 0.66E-01 0.13E 00 0.45E 00-3.84 -1.82 2.51 -3.87 1.08

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0-64E 00 0.12E 00 -0.40E-01 -0.21E-01 0.63E 00

MNT 0.21E 00 0.17E 00 0.26E-C1 0.23E--02 0.37E 00-3.05 0.74 -1.56 -0.92 1.69

CONSTANT SPOP PCY KSTK RLTQT AVTG-0.13E 02

OTH 0.19E 01-G.98

0.21E 0E00.64E-01

3.21

0.63E 000.90E-01

6.99

-0. 78E-010. 79E-01

-1.000.24E-01

-0.47

-0.12E 000. 91E-01

-1.34

wtW'

Figure V.5.6

SHAREMODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: EXPOPENTIAL FORM MODELREGRESSION METHOD:

F-STAT: F(37,3323)=23.745ORDINARY LEAST SQUARES

SEE= 1.046 RSO= 0.186

CONSTANT SPOP-0.29E 00 -0.32E-06

INT 0.20E 00 0.43E-07-1.44 -7.47

UFAC0.88E 000.32E 00

2.72

KST(K0.37E 000.17E 00

2.14

TOL PC',--0.66E 01

0.11E 01-6.07

AVIG AVNIG0.48E-08 -0.10E-070.13E-07 0.16E-07

0.36 -0.63

CONSTANT SPOP0.13E 00 -0.35E-06

PRI 0.20E 00 0.47E-070.65 -7.35

UFAC-0.59E 000.32E 00

-1.86

KSTK-0.59E-010.17E 00

-0.34

AVPG0. 29E-070. 23E-07

1.27

-0. 16E-080.13E-07

-0.12

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC GINi TSPMR PCCRMT AVSG AVIG-0.27E-01 -0.37E-06 -0.12E 01 -0.16E 00 0.14E-04 -0.30E 01 0.24E-07 0.15E-08

SEC 0.35E 00 0.4?E-07 0.33E 00 0.80E 00 0.79E-05 0.86E 90 0.2E-07 0.13E-07-0.08 -8.94 -3.73 -0.21 1.80 -3.54 0.86 0.11

CONISTANT UFAC ?CCRMT RLTOT AVIG-0.14E 31 -0.14E 01 0.33E 01 -0.55E 31 -0.95E-08

NON 0.20E 00 0.33E 00 0.81E 00 0.46E GO 0.13E-07-6.93 -4.22 4.01 -11.97 -0.72

^POP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0.29E-0F -C.43E-O1 -0..39E 00 -0.13E 01 -C.22E-08

MNT 0.24E-07 0.10E 00 0.19E 00 0.24E 00 0.13E-07-12.14 -0.42 -2.05 -5.50 -0.17

CONSTANT $POP PCY K$TK RLTOT AVTG-0.41E 00 -0.33E-06

OTH 0.20E 00 0.34E-07-2.09 -9.78

0. 18E-030.81E-04

2.22

-0.32E 000.20E 00

-1.61

0.74E 000.47E 00

1.59

0. 21E-080.13E-07

0.16

Figure V.5.7WA

w,

SHARE MODELESTIMATION RESULTS

SPECIFICATION: EXPONENIAL FRM MODELREGRESSION METHOD: GENERALIZED LEAST SQUARES

F-SrAT: F(37,3323)=41.469 SEE= 1.003 RSQ= 0.285

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK TOLPCT AVIG AVNIG-0.45E 00 -0.18E-06 0.90E 00 0.62E 00 -0.67E 01 0.27E-07 0.13E-07

INT 0.20E 00 0.46E-07 0.18E 00 0.21E 00 0.64E 00 0.12E-07 0.13E-0/-2.28 -3.92 4.88 3.02 -10.49 2.34 1.04

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC KSTK AVPG AVIG0.59E 00 -0.13E-06 -0.72E 00 0.44E-01 0.46E-07 0.13E-07

PRI 0.21E 00 0.36E-07 0.15E 00 0.15E 00 0.14E-07 0.86E-082.88 -3.65 -4.70 0.28 3.37 1.51

CONSTANT SPOP UFAC GITJI TSPMR PCCRfIT AVSG AVIG-0.57E 00 -0.97E-07 -0.10E 01 0.40E 00 0.16E-04 -0.23E 01 0.26E-07 0.62E-08

SEC o.33E 00 0.14E-07 0.15E 00 0.36E 00 0.35E-05 0.35E 00 0.11E-07 0.27E-08-1.70 -7.04 -6.86 1.12 4.65 -6.56 2.45 2.29

CONSTANT UFAC PCCRMT RLTOT AVIC-0.58E 00 -0.98E 00 0.15E 01 -0.53E 01 0.24E-17

NON 0.19E 00 0.64E 00 0.14E 01 0.81E 00 0.13E-07-3.05 -1.S4 1.01 -6.56 1.78

SPOP KSTK PCMF RLTOT AVTG-0.15E-06 0.22E 00 -0.39E 00 -0.12E 01 0.20E-07

VINT 0.41E-07 0.19E 00 0.15E 00 0.17E 00 0.12E-07-3.56 1.15 -2.53 -Ii.83 1.75

CONSTANT SPOP PCY KSTK RVTOT AVTG-0.14E 01

OTH 0.19F 00-7.35

-0. 24E-070. 13E-07

-1.82

0.39E-030.31E-04

12.64

-0.51E 000. 79E-01

-6.46

0.46E 000.16E 00

2.83

0.36E-080.25E-08

1.44

Figure V.5.8

337However, several properties of the actual regression results

should be noted here. Our generalized least squares estimation

technique significantly improved the efficiency of the parameter

estimates. For example, comparing figures V.5.1 and V.5.2 the

Standard Error of Estimate (as noted by SEE in the figures) decreased

from 1.037 in the OLS estimation to 0.997 for GLS estimation. More

importantly, 25 of the 37 parameters in the SRAM had higher t-statistics

in the GLS estimation than in OLS estimation.

The signs of the parameter estimates proved to be generally

consistent with the a priori hypotheses advanced in section V.4. For

example, referring to the third share equation in Figure V.5.2, it

was found that a State's Secondary System expenditures tend to

decrease with population, urbanization and Interstate grant

availability, and increase with the level income inequality, rural

highway mileage and congestion levels, and Secondary System grant

availability.1 A full discussion of the implications of the entire

set of SRAM parameter estimates will be deferred to the next section.

Finally, it should be noted that the product form specification

of the SRAM provided somewhat more efficient parameter estimates than

the exponential form specification. Comparing Figures V.5.2 and

V.5.8, it may be seen that the F-statistics, Standard Error of

Estimate, R-squared, and 24 of the 37 paramters' t-statistics

1 These findings may be compared with our a priori hypotheses advancedin section V.4

338

were higher for the product form SRAM specification. For this

reason, further analysis of the exponential form SRAM was abandoned.

Estimations of the exponentail form model were not performed on ourtwo data subsets. Furthermore, the policy implications of theSRAM regression results found in the next two sections are all basedon the findings from the product form model.

V.6 Evaluation of the Elasticities and.Derivatives From theShort Run Allocation Model

The estimation results from the short run allocation model

are not immediately interpretable in a direct or simple fashion.

Our immediate concern is not with the estimation coefficients

themselves but with how the model predicts changes in expenditure

allocation with respect to the variables incorporated in the

analysis. A convenient way to describe these changes is with

derivatives and elasticities.

In our application, the derivative of an expenditure share

with respect to a variable in the SRAM may be defined as:

(25) = .( .a -2 af (Z,E)

axk 1Hk if,)

ax k

where s = expenditure share j

Xk = explanatory variable k

a = parameters of the utility function

f. = structural (share) equation in the SRAM

The second and third terms of this equation follow directly

from our derivation of the SRAM (c.f. equation 9). For our

purposes here, the form of equation (25) has two important

characteristics. First, it is clear that the derivatives are

expressed as a function of the parameter estimates of the short

run allocation model. And second, it may be seen that the

variables included in any one share will have an effect on the

derivatives (and elasticities) of all the shares in the SRAM.

339

340

Formally, this statement may be expressed as:

(26) S as.(26)s.~p = 0 * ki=.1 k

where S (=6) = number of shares in the SRAM

Equation (26) emphasizes the tradeoffs inherent in a State's

resource allocation decision process. Given a fixed budget, the

decision to increase expenditures on one activity must be

compensated by a decrease in the resources devoted to at least one

other highway function. For example if an increase in Interstate

grants stimulates additional State expenditures on Interstate

construction (as indicated by a positive derivative of the

Interstate share with respect to Interstate grants), then expendi-

tures on some other function(s) must decrease (as indicated, for

example, by a negative derivative of the non-Federal-Aid System

expenditure share with respect to Interstate grants). '

Appendix B develops a detailed derivation of the derivatives

and elasticities of the short run allocation model. Our purpose

here is to highlight the more significant policy implications of

the SRAM. It should be remembered that at this point we are

concerned only with allocation decisions.

The same comments apply to the interpretation of the SRAM

elasticities. The elasticities of the SRAM n are defined as= as. X

DXk s

341

from Figure V.6.1 that in the short run (i.e. fixed State budget),

a one dollar increase in Interstate grant availability is associated

with a $1.11 increase in total (State plus Federal) expenditures on

that system. However, it is also apparent that the same one

dollar increase in Interstate grants results in a decrease in

expenditures devoted to all other categories except maintenance.

Moreover, Figure v.6.1 indicates that Interstate grant increases

effect a more significant reallocation of State resources than

grants for the Primary and Secondary Systems. In particular, note

that the derivative of Secondary System expenditures with respect

to Secondary grants is only 1.04. If States matched Secondary

grants dollar for dollar, ithen we would expect to find a derivative

of 2.0. It appears then that in the short run, States only

minimally increase their own Secondary expenditures in response to

increasing Secondary System grant availability.

To a lesser extent, the States' short run reaction to

increases in Primary System grant availability is also character-

ized by less than a dollar for dollar matching response, as

indicated by the derivative value of 1.72. Both these findings

substantiate our earlier comments on the non-binding nature of

ABC grants. In particular, since States have been expending more

1We have previously noted that Secondary (and Primary) grants are

provided on a 50% Federal matching basis. In the Interstate

grant program, the Federal government assumes 90% of project costs.

342

In the next section, we will intergrate the results of the SRAM with

the total expenditure model to describe the impacts of Federal

grants and other factors on both total State highway expenditures

and interfunction allocation.

We begin our analysis of the SRAM with a presentation of the

model derivatives. Figure V.6.1 displays the derivatives from the

product form SRAM estimated (GLS) on the full 48 State/14 year

data set. Each column represents a highway activity, and the row

entries correspond to each of the explanatory variables in the

SRAM.I

The most striking finding from this figure is that changes

in the level of grants on a given Federal-Aid System affect not

onl the State's expenditures on that System, but significantly

alter the expenditure shares of other Federal-Aid Systems and the

remaining highway activities as well. For example, it is clear

See Figure V.4.1 for a definition of the explanatory variables.

The column headings are defined as INTERSTATE-Interstate System

construction expenditures, PRIMARY-Federal-Aid Primary System

construction expenditures, SECONDARY-Federal-Aid Secondary System

construction expenditures, NONFASYST-non-Federal-Aid System con-

struction expenditures, MAINT-maintenance expenditures, and

OTHER-administrative and other miscellaneous expenditures.

343

FORTY-EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VAR IADLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

P CM F

TO L PUT

R LTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

-0.105E 02

0.402E 08

-0.474E 04

-0.524E '7

-0.172E 08

-0.221E 03

-0.17?E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.61E 07

0.111E 01

-0.317E 30

-0.17OE-01

PRIMARY

-0. 753E

-n.136E:

-0. 335E

-0. 371E

O.808E

-0. 157E

-0.122E

-0. 281E

0.287E

0.468E

-0.374E

0.172E

-0.354E

00

08

04

07

P7

03

08

06

08

07

00

01

00

SECONDARY

0.578E

-0. 100E

-0.170E

O.167E

0.940E

0.77E

0.147E

-0.142E

0.145E

0.237E

--C.iS7E

-0. 286E

0.1041"E

00

08

04

c8

06

03

08

06

08

07

cc

00

01

Figure V.6.1

344

FORTY-EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIlAnLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

IPMtF

TO L PUT

R L T OT

AVIG

APG

AVSG

I NTERSTATE

-0.105E 02

0.4O2E 08

-0.474C 04

-0.5241E '7

-0.172E 08

-0.221E 03

-0.172E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.661E 07

0.111E 01

-0.317E 30

-0.17CE-01

PRIMARY

-0. 753E

-n.136-:

-0. 335E

-0.371E

O.808E

-0. 15 7E

-0.122E

-0. 281E

0.287E

0.468E

-0.374E

0. 172E

-0. 354E

00

08

04

07

..7

03

08

06

08

07

00

01

00

SECONDARY

0.578E

-0. 100E

-0.1 70E

0.167E

0.940E

0.737E

0.147E

-0. 142EE

0. 145E

0.237E

-C.1SIE

-0.286E

0. 1041E

00

08

04

c 8

06

C3

0 f

06

08

07

c0

00

01

Figure V.6.1 (contd.)

345

than the minimal matching requirements for these Systems, they

need not increase their own expenditures in order to satisfy the

matching requirements of additional ABC aid. And, in fact, our

results indicate that short run expenditure increases on the

Primary and Secondary Systems do not match (dollar for dollar)

increases in ABC grants.

Contrastingly, our SRAM results indicate that the short run

state response to increasing Interstate aid is to increase their

own expenditures by slightly more than the minimally required state

matching share. Referring to figure v.6.1, the derivative of total

(State plus Federal) Interstate expenditures with respect to

Interstate grants is 1.11. Thus, for each dollar increase in

Federal Interstate grant availability, we can expect (in the short

run) an eleven cent increase in State resources devoted to Inter-

state construction.

In addition to the direct effect of Federal aid, (that is the

effect of a Federal-Aid System grant on expenditures on the same

System), Federa'-aid also influences short run expenditures on

other highway activities. To begin with, Figure V.6.1 indicates

that each dollar increase in Interstate grant availability

induces a 37 cent and 20 cent decrease in short run expenditures

on the Primary and Secondary Systems respectively. Similarly,

increases in Primary (or Secondary) System grants result in a

decrease of States' resource allocation to the Interstate and

346

Secondary (or Primary) Systems. These "cross-derivatives"I are

useful in suggesting the complementary and substitutive allocation

characteristics manifest in States' highway expenditure behavior.

For example, Figure V.6.1 indicates that (in the short run):

-- Interstate grant increases induce greater decreases in

Primary System construction expenditures than in

Secondary System expenditures (i.e. States view

Interstate roads as a closer substitute for Primary

System roads than Secondary System roads).

-- Primary System grant increases have tended to draw

approximately equal resources from Secondary and

Interstate System expenditures. ("cross-derivatives"

equal to -.317 and -.286 respectively.)

-- Secondary System grant availability has had the least

reallocational impact of any of the Federal Aid

System grants. This is particularly true of the

effect Secondary grants on Interstate System expendi-

tures. From Figure V.6.1, it may be seen that each

dollar increase in Federal-Aid Secondary System grant

availability decreases States' Interstate expenditures

by less than two cents.

1 That is, the derivative of State expenditures on one activity

with respect to Federal grants on another highway activity.

347

-- Interstate grant increases have tended to increase

States' maintenance expenditures at the rate of

approximately five cents per grant dollar. This is an

interesting finding in light of the often expressed

hypothesis that Federal aid availability has resulted

in a decrease in States' expenditures on non-aided

activites,1 (e.g. maintenance). In fact, Interstate

grants have tended to accelerate Interstate construction,

which in turn has led to increasing maintenance require-

ments. Maintenance standards on the Interstate

System are measurably higher than on other road types.

This is because the Interstate System is designed for

higher driving speeds and thus require maintenance of

smooth roadys, wide rights-of-way and modern traffic

service devices (signs, lighting).

Several other findings concerning States' short run expendi-

ture behavior may be inferred from Figure V.6.1. In each of the

paragraphs below, the model implications are followed by the

relevant derivative from Figure V.6.1 in parentheses.

-- State maintenance expenditures increase with

increasing levels of existing highway inventory, KSTK

(.138 x 107), the level of highway congestion, PCMF

1For example, see Maxwell, J.A., "Federal Grant Elasticity andDistortion", National Tax Journal, Volume XXII, Number 4(December , 1969).

348

(.122 x 107) and the amount of Federal Interstate

grants (.495).

-- The share of the States' budget devoted to the non-

aided expenditure categories (non-FederalMid System

construction, maintenance and "other") tends to

decrease with increasing levels of any of the Federal

Aid System grants.1 This is particularly true of the

change in administration, highway police and safety

and other miscellaneous (i.e. "other") expenditures

in response to increases in the grant availability

on the Interstate (-.561), Primary (-.899) and

Secondary (-.637) Systems.

-- Increasing levels of urbanization tend to increase

State expenditures on the Interstate System

(.402 x 108) and decrease expenditures on the Primary

(-.136x108), Secondary (-l.OOxlO8) and non Federal-

Aid (-.118x108) Systems. The explanation here is that

the relatively large right of way requirements of the

Interstate System, and the high price of urban (versus

rural) land result in significantly higher Interstate

The important exception of the effect of Interstate grants onmaintenance expenditures has already been noted.

349

System costs in densely populated states. As might be

expected, State expenditures on the rural-oriented

road systems (the Secondary and non-Federal-Aid

Systems) decrease with higher levels of urbanization.

-- State expenditures on maintenance and non-Federal-Aid

System construction decrease with increasing levels of

local participation in highway finance (derivatives

equal -.146x108 and -.445x1&7 respectively.) These two

activities are commuonly delegated (to a greater or

lesser degree) to county and municipal highway

authorities. Thus to the extent tht lower govern-

mental agencies assume the financial responsibility for

maintenance and local road construction, State

expenditures on these activities decrease. By the same

token, the resources "freed up" by the delegation of

highway responsibility to lower governmental units

result in increasing State expenditure levels on those

functions under exclusive State control (as evidenced

by the positive derivatives of expenditures on the

Federal-Aid Systems with respect to RLTOT).

-- The SRAM results substantiate the hypothesis advanced

in section V.4 that the degree of toll road financing

(as measured by the variable TOLPCT) would negatively

350

influence States Interstate expenditures. In fact,

of all the expenditure categories in the SRAM, only

the Interstate share had a negative derivative

(-.103x109) with respect to TOLPCT.

In summary, this section has explored short run State highway

resource allocation behavior. The derivatives of the short run

allocation model generally corroborated the hypotheses advanced in

section V.4. Most notably, it was found that Primary and Secondary

System grants do not induce a dollar for dollar matching response

by the States in the short run. Here again we have drawn attention

to the fact that although the ABC grant program is characterized

by matching provisions, these provisions are not binding on States

allocation behavior. Contrastinoly, it was shown that the

Interstate grant program has induced States to expend slightly more

than the monomally required 10% State share, substantiating our

earlier coments on the more binding nature of the Interstate

grant program's matching provisions.

A more complete listing of the derivatives and elasticities

derived from the short run allocation model is presented in

Appendix C.1

The empirical results in this section were discussed in terms ofSRAM derivatives. The elasticities of the SRAM corroborate ourgeneral findings. In the next section where we investigate States'long run highway allocation behavior, our empirical results willbe evaluated both in terms of model derivatives and elasticities.

351

V.7 Integration of the Results from the Total Expenditure Modeland the Short Run Allocation Mode: Lon9 Run Responses

This section extends the analysis of the previous section by

considering the derivatives and elasticities of expenditures on each

of the six highway categories with respect to the variables employed

in both the short run allocation model and the total expenditure model.

We refer here to long run derivatives (or elasticities) since the

analysis allows for the influence of each of the variables on short

run allocation as well as total expenditure levels. For example,

the results of the short run analysis in section V.6 indicated that

the share of Interstate expenditures increases in response to increasing

Interstate grant levels. 1 But we have also seen from our total ex-

penditure model (Chapter IV) that Interstate grant increases have

tended to increase States' total expenditure levels. Thus to measure

the total effect of Interstate grants (or any other variable), we must

apply the predicted shifts in (short run) allocation shares to the

predicted change in (long run) total expenditures. In short, this

section attempts to integrate our findincs from the short run alloc-

ation model and the total expenditure model.

The two models of State highway expenditure behavior developed in

this thesis take the form:

More specifically, we have shown that Interstate grants have increa-sed short run State Interstate expenditures. Given the fixedbudget consumption of our short run analysis, it follows that theStates' share of resources devoted to Interstate construction hasincreased.

352short run allocation model (SRAM)

E. f-(27) s =R =

R gg

where s=

E. =

R =

f i

share of expenditures devoted to category j

expenditures on category j

total (State & Federal) expenditures

structural equation in the SRAM

total expenditure model (TEM)

(28) R0pc = o+ E8 Xmm

where R0 =

Xm

States per capita highway expendituresexclusive of Federal grants

TEM explanatory variables

m = TEM parameter estimates.

It may be noted that the dependent variable in the TEM (Rp) ispc

related to the form of the total expenditure term R in the short run

allocation model. The former represents States' own per capita

highway expenditures whereas the latter term is simply total highway

expenditures (inclusive of Federal payments). Thus, by definition:

(29) R = SPOP (R+pc + Fpc)

where SPOP = State population

Fpc = per capita Federal payments to the States.

353Assuming that States ultimately expend all Federal grants made

available, any differences between Federal highway payments Fp and

Federal highway grants can be attributed to short run, transient

responses. In the long run, it can be assumed that Federal payments

will eventually "settle down" to the rate of Federal grant availa-

bility. Thus in a long run static situation:

(30) FPC = GPC

where GPC = per capita Federal grant availability.

But per capita highway grants were included as an explanatory variable

in the total expenditure model. Thus employing the conventions of

equations (29) and (30) in equation (27), we can rewrite the total

expenditure model as:

(31) R = ( + ZmXm + (1+Gpc SPOP

exclusiveof grantterms

where R = total (inclusive of Federal grants)State highway expenditures

e = TEM parameter estimate of the Federalgrant terms

GPC= per capita Federal highway grants.

Equation (31) transforms our original TEM specification which served

to predict States' own per capita highway expenditures, into a form

which describes States total (inclusive of Federal grants) highway

Particularly if Federal grant availability does not significantlychange from year to year.

354expenditures R. In fact, the definition of R in equation (31) is

precisely the required form for interpretation of our allocation model.

Thus, rewriting equation (27), we get

(32) E= Six R

where s.= a highway expenditure share as defined in' the SRAM

and R = total State highway expenditures as definedby the transformation of the TEM representedby equation (30).

Finally, given the form of equation (32) we can define the long run

derivatives of our expenditure categories E. with respect to the

explanatory variables Xk:

(33) 3E

aXk

aR as.= s X + R

The corresponding long run

Xk9 Ei/Xk is simply:

3 Xk=. ~X F(34.) = _E xkTEAk axk r j

elasticity of E. with respect to variable

kXk (s R R )s.

_ i sj + R Xk3. k 3

as

ax

X 3E. RI k

X aR _sXk R Wak s. axk

3

- R/Xk + qsj/Xk

From the form of these equations, it is apparent that long run

expenditures on a particular highway category E increase in response3

to a change in an explanatory variable Xk if: 355

- the share of expenditures devoted to category j increased by

more than an attendant percentage decrease in total

expenditures,

- total expentirues increase (in percentage terms) by more than

an attendant decrease in the expenditure share devoted to

highway category j, or

- both total expenditures and the share of expenditures devoted

to category j increase.

Figure V.7.l1 displays the long run derivatives derived from the

two expenditure models. The interpretation of the derivatives of

expenditures with respect to the Federal grant variables deserve

particular attention since these results provide strong evidence on

the substitution/stimulation impacts of the Federal-Aid Highway

Program. It is apparent that of the three Federal grant programs

evaluated in this thesis, only the Interstate grant program had the

effect of increasing State expenditures by more than the minimally

required State matching share. Specifically, our results indicate

that each dollar increase in Interstate aid is associated with a

$1.57 increase in total Interstate expenditures, implying an increase

in States' own Interstate expenditures by 57t. In fact recalling

1 The derivatives in this Figure were derived from the parameterestimates of the "SUll" specification of the total expendituremodel (see Figure IV.6.1) and the GLS estimation of the SRAM(see Figure V.5.1).

356

FORTY-EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AV I G

AV PG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

0.507E 01

0.395E 08

0.147E 05

-0.460E 07

-0.686E 07

-0.221E 03

-0.172E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.627E 07

0.157E 01

-0.317E 00

-0. 170E-01

PRIMARY

0.103E 02

-0.140E 08

0.104E 05

-0.325E 07

0.154E 08

-0.157E 03

-0.122E 08

-0.281E 06

0.290E OF

0.444E 07

-0.516E-01

0.172E 01

-0.354E 00

SECONDARY

0.615E 01

-0.103E 08

0.526E 04

0.170E 08

0.464E 07

0.707E 03

0.147E 08

-0.142E 06

0.147E 08

0.225E 07

-0. 336E-01

-0.286E 00

0.104E 01

Figure V.7.1

357

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GI NI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AV I G

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

0.507E 01

0.395E 08

0.147E 05

-0.460E 07

-0.686E 07

-0.221E 03

-0.172E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.627E 07

0.157E 01

-0.317E 00

-0. 170E-01

PRIMARY

0.103E 02

-0.140E 08

0.104E 05

-0.325E 07

0.154E 08

-0.157E 03

-0.122E 08

-0.281E 06

0.290E 08

0.44 4E 07

-0.516E-01

0.172E 01

-0.354E 00

SECONDARY

0.615E 01

-0.103E 08

0.526E 04

0.170E 08

0.46 4E 07

0.707E 03

0.147E 08

-0.142E 06

0.147E 08

0.225E 07

-0. 336E-01

-0.286E 00

0.104E 01

Figure V.7.1 (contd.)

358the results of our total expenditure model analysis, and the short run

allocation model analysis, our findings here are representative of a

State response to increasing Interstate aid wherein States increase

both their own total highway expenditures, and the share of those

expenditures devoted to Interstate construction.

This behavior stands in contrast to the States' response to

increasing Secondary System grant availability. Note from Figure

V.7.1 that the derivative of Secondary System expenditures with

respect to Secondary System grants is only 1.04. The implication

here is that each additional Federal Secondary System grant dollar

increases State expenditures by only four cents -- far less than the

increase that would pertain if States were matching increasing Federal

Aid on a dollar-for-dollar basis.I

In a similar fashion our results concerning the States' reaction

to increasing Primary System aid suggest a less than a dollar-for-

dollar expenditure matching response. The relevant derivative value

here indicates that each dollar increase in Primary System aid induces

only a 724 increase in States own expenditures on that System

(derivative value equal to 1.72). These results reflect our findings

from the empirical analysis of the total expenditure model (see

section IV.6). That is, the increases in Primary and Secondary

System expenditures in response to additions to grants on these

1 We again note that over our analysis period, Primary and SecondarySystem grants were provided on a 50% Federal, 50% State matchingbasis.

359

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

!NT ERSTATE

0.330

0.396

0.623

-0.029

-0.067

-0.031

-0.011

-0. 001

-0.059

0. 028

1.232

-0. 070

-0.002

PRIMARY

0.943

-0.198

0.623

-0. 029

0.214

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

0.023

0. 028

-0.057

0.534

-0.045

SECONDARY

1.117

-0.287

0.623

0.302

0.127

0.277

0. 026

-0. 001

0.023

0. 028

-0.074

-0.176

0.261

Figure V.7.2

VAR I ABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

P CMF

TOLPCT

RLTOI

AVI G

AVPG

AVS G

360

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

NONFASYST

1.662

-0.890

0.623

-0.029

0.127

-0. 031

0.183

-0. 001

0.023

-0. 489

0.198

-0. 130

-0.026

MAINT

0.407

-0.042

0.623

-0.029

0.387

-0.031

-0.011

0.007

0.023

-0.043

0.440

-0.062

0.001

OTHER

1.987

-0.042

1.440

-0.029

0.034

-0. 031

-0.011

-0.001

0.023

0.025

-0. 146

-0. 226

-0.066

Figure V.7.2 (contd.)

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

G I N I

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

361

Systems stem not from increases in States' own total expenditures,1

but from increases in the share of a States' resources devoted to

these Systems. Contrastingly, additional Interstate System aid has

had the effect of increasing both the States' total expenditures, and

the share of their expenditures devoted to Interstate construction.

The same general findings are evident from an examination of

Figure V.7.2 showing the long run elasticities from the two

expenditure models. It may be seen that a one percent increase in

Interstate grants leads to a 1.23% increase in long run State

Interstate expenditures. In other words, the fraction of total

expenditures representing Federal grant decreases with increasing

levels of Interstate aid. Conversely, the direct elasticities of

Primary and Secondary expenditures with respct to grants for these

Systems are less than one. These elasticities -- .53 for the

Primary System and .26 for the Secondary System indicate that Federal

grants comprise an increasingly larger fraction of total (State plus

zederal) expenditures on these Systems. Thus, on the Primary and

Secondary Systems, States' own expenditures have increased at approxi-

mately only one-half and one-fourth of the respective percentage

In fact, we have shown that the States' response to ABC grants ischaracterized by expenditure substitution. That is each additionalABC grant dollar is associated with a decrease in States' ownexpenditures by one dollar.

362

rate increases in Federal aid (for these Systems).1

The elasticities (or derivatives) of categorical highway

expenditures with respect to the other variables included in the

expenditure models generally conform with expected State behavior.

The indicated responses to each of these variables are summarized

below.

Socio-Economic Characteristics

As expected, increasing levels of State population (SPOP) and

per capita income (PCY) positively influence the expenditure levels

on all the highway categories. Highway travel within a State

increases with population and personal income. Therefore, we

should expect higher levels of SPOP and PCY to increase the States'

construction, maintenance and administrative expenditure requirements.2

It should be kept in mind in interpreting the results that elastici-

ties express percentage changes in the expenditure levels on each

highway category. Thus for example, while the elasticity of main-

tenance expenditures with respect to population increases (.497) is

1 Note that States' own Interstate expenditures have increased at agreater percentage rate than increases in Interstate aid. Thesefindings are all the more significant when it is recalled that forseveral years in our analysis period, States own Interstate expen-ditures exceeded their ABC System expenditures (see Figure 11.2.1)and the States' required matching share is lower on the Interstatethan on the Primary or Secondary Systems.

2 Moreover for a given gas tax rate, increasing highway travelprovides States with higher levels of earmarked highway revenue.

363greater than the corresponding elasticity for the Interstate System

(.3i0), in absolute terms increases in Interstate expenditures (in

response to changes SPOP) exceed those for highway maintenance.I

The measure of urbanization (UFAC) positively influenced Inter-

state System expenditures, reflecting the sharply increased cost of

Interstate highway construction in urban areas. The elasticity of

the remaining five shares with respect to UFAC were all negative, most

notably for the "lower order" (Sconary and non-Federal Aid) Systems.

GINI, the indicator of State income distribution had a positive

elasticity only for Secondary System expenditures. This result

reflects the fact that the rural States tend to have the greatest

degree of income inequality, and thus commit relatively higher

expenditure levels on the rural-oriented Secondary System.

Highway System Characteristics

Two measures of existing highway inventories (KSTK-depreciated

highway capital expenditures and TSPMR - State rural highway mileage)

and two indicators of highway congestion levels (PCCRMT--percent of

heavily traveled rural mileage and PCMF--percent of heavily traveled

total mileage) were incorporated in the analysis. As might be

expected, increasing levels of highway inventories positively

influenced maintenance and "other" (non-capital) expenditure levels.

In fact only Interstate expenditures exhibited a negative elasticity

1 As manifested by the corresponding derivative values (FigureV.7.1) of 5.07 for the Interstate category and 3.65 for themaintenance category.

364with respect to KSTK. Secondary System expenditures exhibited a

positive elasticity with repsect to rural highway mileage; again

indicating the rural orientation of the Secondary System.

Although the measures of highway congestion did not prove

particularly significant, the elasticities with respect to PCMF and

PCCRMT indicate reasonable expenditure responses. In particular

expenditures on the predominantly rural highway systems (Secondary

and non-Federal Aid Sustems) exhibited a positive elasticity with

respect to the level of rural highway congestion (PCCRMT). And

maintenance expenditures were positively influenced by the general

measure of State-wide concestion (PCMF).

Institutional Characteristics

The variable measuring the extent of local participation in

highway finance (RLTOT) exhibited neaative long run elasticities for

the non-Federal Aid System and maintenance expenditure categories.

Thus higher expenditure levels (presumably on highway maintenance

and non-Federal Aid System construction) by counties and municipali-

ties has the effect of "freeing up" (State) resources for the

performance of exclusive State highway functions (Federal

Aid System construction and administrative and other activities).

The second indicator of State highway financing conventions--the

extent of toll road financing (TOLPCT) did not appear to signifi-

cantly influence the allocation of State resources. However, the

results indicate that increasing use of toll roads has tended to

decrease Interstate expenditures while increasing the level of

expenditure on all other highway categories. As noted earlier,

365

this finding stems from the common State practice of delegating

Interstate System financing responsibility to quasi-public toll-

financed Turnpike Authorities.

366V.8 Summary

This chapter has presented an empirical analysis of the State

highway allocation behavior in both a short run and long run context.

The empirical model of short run highway allocation was derived from

a utility maximization representation of State expenditure behavior.

The model has the desirable property of explicitly accounting for State

budget constraints and thus focuses on the inherent tradeoffs States

must face in programing expenditures on alternative highway

activities. A generalized least square estimation technique was

developed to take proper statistical account of the joint interaction

between States highway expenditure shares.

The short run analysis explored allocation behavior under the

assumption that State budget levels were fixed. The results demon-

strated the relative importance of the Interstate grant program in

influencing States allocation decisions. The results from the short

run allocation model were then integrated with the empirical findings

of the total expenditure model (Chapter IV) to develop measures of

States' long run highway allocation behavior. The results demon-

strate that Federal grants for the Primary and Secondary Systems

have not significantly increased States' own expenditures on these

Systems. Specifically, it was shown that States have not had to

increase their own expenditures on a dollar-for-dollar matching basis

with increased Federal funding. This behavior contrasted with State

responses to the Interstate grant program, where it was shown that

increasing Federal aid has increased both total State expenditures

and the share of the States' budgets devoted to Interstate

367construction.

It was also shown that increases in Federal grant availability

have generally decreased State expenditures on non-aided activities.

One exception of interest was the finding that Interstate grant

increases have led to increases in States' maintenance expenditures,

indicative of the relatively large maintenance requirements associ-

ated with that system.

The predicted expenditure responses to changes in the State

socio-economic indicators, highway system characteristics and

institutional characteristics generally corroborated our a priori

hypotheses. The policy implications of our empirical findings

will be explored in the next chapter.

368

CHAPTER VI

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

VI.l Summary of the Thesis

This study has investigated the impacts of the Federal Aid

Highway Program on State highway expenditures. Our concern through-

out the conduct of the research has been to focus on this issue

from a national policy perspective. In simplest terms, the moti-

vation of the research was a consideration of the design of, and

response to Federal and highway financing.

Our starting point was a review of the mechanics of State and

Federal highway finance. Special attention was given to the

unique aspects of the Federal Aid Highway Program (FAHP) and

the attendant implications for empirical modelling. First, we took

note of the widespread use of earmarked Trust Funds at both the

Federal and State levels. This finding allowed us to restrict

our modelling attention solely to the dynamics of State higway

expenditure behavior.1 Second, our review of the highway finance

environment pointed out the significant differences between the

structural characteristics of the various Federal highway grant

programs--most notably between the Interstate and ABC highway

grant programs. The modelling implications here were twofold.

1 That is, unlike other State activities financed from general taxrevenues, we have been able to "separate out" highway expendi-ture decisions from the overall State budgetary process. Thismodelling convention is discussed in detail in Chapter II.

369

First, it became apparent that the models of State expenditure

behavior should explicitly account for the possibility of differ-

ing State responses to the availability of grants on the Inter-

state and ABC highway Systems.1 And second, the existence of

several distinct highway grant types suggested the importance of in-

vestigating the inherent tradeoffs States must face in programing

expenditures on alternative highway activities. In other words,

it was deemed important to trace the impact of the Federal Aid

Highway Program on both the total level of States' highway expendi-

tures and the allocation of State resources amongst Federally

aided and non-Federally aided highway activites.2

Following the review of the Federal and State highway finance

environment, we proceeded to develop a theory of State highway

expenditure behavior. Our purpose here was to draw attention

to the premise that State highway expenditure behavior depends

not only on the level of available Federal grants-in-aid, but on

the structural characteristics of the grant programs as well.

rowards this end, Chapter III started out with a normative dis-

This convention represents a departure from previous analytical

analyses in this area. None of the studies cited in the liter-ature review in Chapter I chose to evaluate the separate Stateexpenditure responses to grants on the different Federal AidHighway Systems. In section IV.6.1, we argue that failure toaccount for differing State responses to the Interstate vis-a-visABC highway grant programs obscures a fundamental characteristicof the Federal Aid Highway Program, and indeed yields misleadingresults.

2 Here too, our modelling convention differs from previous empirical

studies. As noted in Chapter I, the existing literature containmany examples of evaluations of States' total expenditure respon-ses to grants or States' allocation behavior. This thesis has at-tempted to present an integrated treatment of the impacts of theFAHP on both dimensions of State expenditure behavior.

370cussion of the considerations involved in designing a Federal

highway grant program to achieve specific national objectives. A

distinction was drawn between proposing changes to the existing

structure of the FAHP because the initial justification for the

Federal role in highway finance is no longer (or hasanever been)

valid, or because the structure of the FAHP is not compatible

with the accepted goals of the Federal role in highway finance.

While the normative analysis was not conclusive,1 the thesis does

argue that the issues involved in the design of a Federal grant

program are not simply a matter of political expediency. The

adoption of a revenue sharing program (for example) will have

significantly different allocational consequences than the pro-

vision of Federal aid on an open-ended categorical, matching grant

basis. Thus the normative analyis stresses the importance in

gaining a better understanding of the dynamics of State expendi-

ture responses to alternative Federal aid grant structures.

Accordingly, the remainder of Chapter III was devoted to the

development of a theory of State highway expenditure behavior. A

typology of alternative grant types was introduced, and evaluated

in terms of their impact in stimulating State expenditures on

aided functions or in effecting a substitution response wherein

States would reduce their own highway expenditures in response to

1 The normative analysis is limited by the difficulty in ascer-taining a unique, consensual national highway policy. Congres-sional debate is not normally conducted at an abstract (policy)level. Moreover, Federal highway objectives are not static.

371

increasing levels of Federal aid. Two modelling frameworks were

introduced, one based on an extension of consumer allocation theory,

and the other deriving from an application of a simple benefit/cost

investment criterion. Although these two models ostensibly differed

with respect to their underlying assumptions, in fact the conclu-

sions drawn from both approaches were quite similar. That is, both

analyses stressed the notion of price and income effects introduced

by Federal grants, and proceeded to demonstrate how State expendi-

ture responses differ according to the presence of one or both

of these grant characteristics. The theoretical models were then

used to investigate the historical grant and expenditure levels

on the Interstate and ABC highway programs. The theoretical analy-

ses suggested that for the Interstate program, Federal grants have

stimulated State expenditures that would most likely not have

been made in the absence of the grant program. This behavior was

contrasted with the experience in the ABC program, where it was

hypothesized that Federal grants have had a relatively insignificant

impact in determining States' total expenditure levels.

The theoretical models were useful in suggesting both the

appropriate framework for structuring the empirical models and the

expected empirical results. Our purpose in the remainder of the

thesis was to validate our theoretical hypotheses with econometric

models. Two models were advanced, treating in turn the impacts

of the FAHP on total State highway expenditures, and on the allocation

of States' highway budgets. The total expenditure model (TEM)

derived from a capacity utilization investment theory relating

372

States' highway investment levels to existing highway capital stocks,

proxy measures of desired highway capital stocks, and the availa-

bility of Federal aid. The empirical results strongly corroborated

the theoretical hypotheses regarding the differential impacts of

the Interstate and ABC highway grant programs.

The empirical model dealing with the second dimension of State

highway expenditure behavior--the short run allocation model (SRAM)

was derived from a utility maximization representation of State

decision making. The results demonstrated the differential im-

pacts of the various grant programs on States' short run budget

allocation amongst Federally aided and non-aided highway activities.

Finally, the empirical results from the short run alloca-

tion model were integrated with the findings of the total expendi-

ture model to develop measures of the States' long run highway

allocation behavior. These results were consistent with our a priori

hypotheses of State highway expenditure behavior.

373

VI.2 Policy Implications of the Empirical Findings

As the main focus of this thesis was to explore the impacts

of the FAHP on State expenditure behavior, we begin our discussion

here with the policy implications of estimation results of the Feder-

al grant terms included in the two expenditure models. We have

shown that the Interstate grant program has effected more signifi-

cant State expenditure responses than the ABC grant program.

Specifically, we have traced the responses to Federal grants in

terms of both States' total expenditure levels and short run

State budget allocation amongst aided and non-aided highway activi-

ties. For the former dimension of State behavior, the empirical

models have demonstrated that the Interstate programs have been

associated with increases in total (State plus Federal) expendi-

tures by more than the amount of increases in Federal Interstate

aid. Thus we concluded that the Interstate grant program has had

the effect of stimulating State highway expenditures.1 This response

pattern was contrasted with the ABC program, where the theoretical

and empirical models have demonstrated that States have substituted

their own highway expenditures for the receipt of increasing levels

of Federal ABC aid.

Regarding the second dimension of State highway expenditure

behavior, we have demonstrated that the various Federal grant pro-

grams have had a differential impact on States' allocation of their

1 Furthermore, we have shown that the resulting increase in States'total highway expenditures derive mainly from increasing resourceallocation to Interstate construction and maintenance activities(presumably in large measure in the Interstate system).

374

highway resources. Although all of the Federal highway grant

programs considered in this thesis were shown to stimulate States'

short run budget allocation to Federal-Aid System construction

activities, our results indicate that short run impacts of Primary

and Secondary System grants exhibit a less than dollar-for-dollar

matching response by the State.I Contrastingly, the Interstate

grant program was shown to increase States' short run Interstate

expenditures by more than the minimally required matching share.

In fact, based on our theoretical analyses (see Chapter III),

none of our empirical findings were unexpected. The empirical analy-

ses served to validate our a priori hypotheses, and placed dimen-

sions on the pattern of State responses to the FAFP. More important-

ly perhaps, the empirical research provides evidence which suggests

policy recomnendations for altering the present structure of the

Federal-Aid Highway Program.

Specifically, with our clearer understanding of the dynamics of

State expenditure responses to Federal aid, the fundamental issue

of the objectives of the Federal Aid Highway Program is called into

question. The imposition of Federal highway taxes and the pursuant

distribution of categorical grants represents an explicit expression

I Since the matching ratio of ABC aid over our analyses period was50% (except for the "public land States"; see Chapter II), ourresults indicate that even in the short run, States can "absorb"additional Federal aid without having to increase their ownexpenditures by the required State matching share. In Chapter II,we demonstrated that this response pattern could obtain only ifStates were histocially expending more than their minimallyrequired matching share on the Federal-Aid Systems.

375

of Federal policy. In particular, the restrictions on the use of

Federal funds for only certain types of facilities serves to iden-

tify those projects whose provision is deemed to be in the national

interest. It may well be argued that guaranteeing a minimally ac-

ceptable provision of important transportation facilities or stimu-

lating road construction necessary for interstate commerce are

valid Federal objectives. But we have shown that for the ABC pro-

gram, the former objective may not be appropriate, and the second

objective is not being accomplished. In short, our results indi-

cate that restructuring the Federal Aid Highway Program with a

relaxation of the specificity of the categorical restrictions, and

eliminating the built-in matching provisions would not significant-

ly alter State expenditure levels. Since the ABC program has

(over our analysis period) effectivejy operated as a non-categorical

block grant system, the detailed provisions (matching ratios,

categorical restructions, etc.) of the FAHP are unnecessary and

wasteful.

To be sure, the FAHP is characterized by other (non-allocation-

al) consequences--ensuring adherence to Federal labor and contracting

regulations, promoting the implementation of transportation planning

and process guidelines, and guaranteeing that Federally-funded

roads conform to certain safety standards. None of these "ancil-

lary" impacts are tied to the particular structure of the FAHP.

They are merely conditions States must satisfy in order to be eligible

for the receipt of Federal highway monies. Indeed, we are arguing

376

that greater attention needs to be paid to exploiting these

"ancillary" benefits in view of the failure of specific components

of the FAHP to achieve significant allocational goals.

We have already noted (section II.2.viii) that the Federal

Aid Highway Act of 1973 has incorporated several provisions de-

signed to reduce the specificity of the FAHP, most notably in terms

of increasing the allowable fund transfers between distinct Federal

Aid Systems, and providing Urban System aid for transit as well as

highway construction. The logical extension of the 1973 provisions

would be to completely remove all categorical and matching provisions

from those components of the FAHP where it is either not the intent

or not a reasonable expectation (given projected State expenditure

levels and Federal grant availability) for Federal grants to stimu-

late State expenditure levels.

As we noted in Chapter III, categorical matching grants are

most appropriate in situations where the Federal government perceives

a national interest in promoting investment on specific types of

highway facilities. Thus we argue that the criteria to be considered

in the design of the structure of the FAHP (specifically in terms

of the provision of categorical aid) is the existence of identifiable

investment needs1 on specific highway facilities. The analyses

I The Interstate System was a case where States would not haveheavily invested on this System in the absence of Federal cate-gorical grants. Moreover, it may be argued that the InterstateSystemis characterized by significant "benefit spillovers" (seeChapter III) due to its value in enhancing interstate commerceand national defense. Thus, grants for the Interstate System maybe viewed as a case where categorical aid was appropriate. Other

377

developed in this thesis suggest that categorical aid for broadly

defined functional highway classes, for example the Federal Aid

Primary System is not justified.

A related issue is the question of the advisability of the

existing taxation scheme and distribution formulas characterizing

the existing FAHP. We have shown that the gasoline excise tax

is at best proportional (for journey to work travel) and at worst

regressive (for vacation and business intercity travel). Moreover,

the analyses in Chapter II suggests that the apportionment formulas

currently in effect fail to accomplish a significant redistribution

of income from wealthier to poorer States. While the FAHP's

main objectives are not directly related to achieving more desirable

income redistribution,1 the generally recognized importance of

transport systems in promoting economic growthand regional develop-

ment suggests that more attention needs to be given to income dis-

tributive properties of FAHP apportionment formulas. In line with

our conclusion that the numerous highway categorical matching

instances where categorical grants might be appropriate includehigh risk/new technology projects where categorical "demonstration"grants serve to overcome States' reluctance to invest in un-tested technology, or, more generally any instance where theFederal government perceives a national interest in acceleratingexpenditures on specific project types (e.g., TOPICS, and the"Priority Primary Routes" designated in the 1972 Highway Act).

I There are more efficient Federal policies to achieve significantincome redistribution, for example direct transfer payments(Revenue Sharing) with income-based distribution formulas.

378

grants be consolidated into a block grant system, it is recommended

that the Department of Transportation give consideration to a

restructuring of the FAHP apportionment formulas. Towards this end,

the income and tax effort-based distribution formulas of the Federal

government's General Revenue Sharing program merit particular im-

portance.

The second aspect of income inequality inherent in the current

FAHP--the gasoline excise tax--also deserves DOT's attention in de-

veloping future Federal highway policy. The issue here involves

the income distribution characteristics, the revenue potential

and the price distortion characteristics of alternative taxation

schemes. While the gasoline tax possesses undesirable income dis-

tribution characteristics, it nonetheless represents an efficient

and relatively stable revenue source,2 and connotes a rough measure

of equity. 3 In order to mitigate its perverse income distribution,

DOT should consider supplementing the existing gasoline tax with

an excise tax on automobiles where the tax rate would be progressive-

ly higher for larger engine vehicles. This scheme would have the

I Since the FAHP apportionment formulas are currently administeredon a System-by-System basis, a grant consolidation program wouldrequire a change in apportionment policy in any event.

2 In the sense that demand for gasoline/auto travel is price in-elastic.

3 In the sense that the tax burden on an individual is proportionalto his usage of highway facilities.

379

merits of promoting progressive taxation and enhancing the Federal

government's objective of reducing gasoline consumption.

380

VI.3 Limitations of the Empirical Approach and Directions forFurther Research

The empirical analyses conducted in this thesis could be ex-

tended in several fruitful directions. First, more attention

could be given to investigating the specifics of the variation in

highway investment behavior between States. Data limitations

precluded the possibility of applying our expenditure models (the

short run allocation model and the total expenditure model) on a

State-by-State basis. While we did take proper statistical account

of interstate behavioral variation in the pooled data sample, more

research is necessary to investigate causal factors underlying

differences in State behavior. Along these lines, more attention

could be given to political and institutional factors. Does a

State's highway expenditure behavior change significantly after

it has formed a multimodal Department of Transportation? Are

there significant cultural and regional effects present--that

is for example, do Southern States express a different outlook on the

provision of public services that the New England States and is

so, why?1 Is there a difference in expenditure behavior that is

attributable to differing State political organization, as for

example between States where the Legislature exerts strong highway

policy influence and States where the Executive branch (Governor)

1 Some of these questions were examined in our highway expendituremodels through the use of "dummy variables." None of theseexperiments produced conclusive results.

381

assumes a major role in highway policy formation?

These are all important questions that can only be addressed

by adopting a more disaggregate analysis framework than the one

applied in this thesis. The approach we did adopt reflected a

focus on the highway investment issue from a national polic p2er-

spective.

A second area where future research would be fruitful involves

exploring the validity of the assumptions underlying our empirical

models. Our models have assumed States exhibit "rational economic

behavior" in the sense that allocation and expenditure decisions

are based on the desire to maximize States' perceived utility (or

benefit). While this view of the motivations for State decision-

making is quite general and non-restrictive, it would be instruc-

tive to conduct in-depth interviews with responsible State highway

officials to validate our assumptions. Such interviews would be

useful in both gaining further insight into the factors (variables)

to be included in future model development and checking the reason-

ableness of our empirical results.1

Finally, our modelling approach could be extended in a fore-

casting environment to assess the impacts of future Federal policy

alternatives. Along these lines, the policy recommendations ex-

pressed earlier in this chapter (grant consolidation and an alteration

1 The Federal Highway Administration has reviewed the majorempirical results developed in this research, and has indicatedgeneral agreement with our findings based on their own in-houseanalyses.

382

in the taxation and grant distribution characteristics of the

FAHP) as well as other alternative program variants could be

evaluated against baseline predictions of the consequences of con-

tinuing the existing FAHP.

BIBLIOGRAPHY 383

Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, STATE-LOCALFINANCES: SIGNIFICANT FEATURES AND SUGGESTED LEGISLATION, 1972Edition

Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, SPECIAL REVENUESHARING: AN ANALYSIS OF THE ADMINISTRATION'S GRANT CONSOLIDATIONPROPOSALS, December, 1971

Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, IMPACT OFFEDERAL PROGRAMS ON LOCAL GOVERNMENT, ORGANIZATION AND PLANNING,1962

Ainsworth, K.G., "Comments on Monypenny's Federal Grants-in -Aidto State Governments: A Political Analysis," National Tax Journal,Volume XIII, Number 3 (September, 1960)

Balestra, P., and M. Nerlove, "Pooling Cross Section and TimeSeries Data in the Estimation of a Dynamic Model: The Demand

for Natural Gas," Econometrica, Volume 34, Number 3

Barr, J.L. and O.A. Davis, "An Elementary Politidal and EconomicTheory of Expenditure of Local Governments," Southern Economic

Journal, Volume 34, Number 1 (October, 1966)

Birkhead, Guthrie S., METROPOLITAN ISSUES: SOCIAL, GOVERNMENTAL,FISCAL, Brookings Institution Reprint Number 61, Washington, D.C.,1962

Bishop, George A., "Stimulative Versus Substitutive Effects of StateSchool Aid in New England," National Tax Journal, Volume XVII, Number

2 (June, 1964)

Break, George F., INTERGOVERNMENTAL FISCAL RELATIONS IN THE UNITED

STATES, The Brookings Institution, (Studies of Government Finance),

Washington, D.C., 1967

Burch, P., HIGHWAY REVENUE AND EXPENDITURE POLICY IN THE UNITED STATES,Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, New Jersey, 1962

Dearing, C.I., and W. Owen, NATIONAL TRANSPORTATION POLICY, The Brook-ings Institution, Washington D.C., 1949

DeGarmo, E. Paul, ENGINEERING ECONOMY, The MacMillan CompanyNew York,New York, 1960

384

Dorfman, Robert, PRICES AND MARKETS, Foundations of Modern EconomicsSeries, Prentice-Hall Inc., Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, 1967

Dresch, S.P., "An 'Alternative' View of the Nixon Revenue SharingProgram," National Tax Journal, Volume XXIV, Number 2 (June, 1971)

Due, John F. and A.F. Friedlaender, GOVERNMENT FINANCE: ECONOMICSOF THE PUBLIC SECTOR, Richard D. Irwin Inc., Homewood, Illinois,

Fifth Edition, 1973

Faddeev, D.K. and V.N. Faddeeva, COMPUTATIONAL METHODS OF LINEAR

ALGEBRA, W. H. Freeman Inc., San Francisco, California, 1963

Ferman, Gerald, OUTPUT ANALYSIS: THE DISTRIBUTION OF GRANTS-IN-AID 1957-1967, Working Paper Number 10, Denter for the Study ofFederalism, Temple University, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, 1974

Findakly, H.K., A DECISION MODEL FOR INVESTMENT ALTERNATIVES IN

HIGHWAY SYSTEMS, Unpublished ScD Thesis, Department of Civil

Engineering, Massachsuetts of Technology, September, 1972

Friedlaender, A. F., THE INTERSTATE HIGHWAY SYSTEM, North Holland

Publishing Co., Amsterdam, 1965

Friedlaender, A.F., "The Federal Highway Program as a Public Works

Tool," in Ando, A. et al, STUDIES IN ECONOMIC STABILIZATION, TheBrookings Institution, Washington, D.C., 1968

Gabler, L.R., and J.I. Brest, "Interstate Variations in Per CapitaHighway Expenditures," National Tax Journal, Volume XX, Number 1(March, 1967)

Gallamore, Robert E., (Reprint of) Testimony Before the Subcomit-tee on Roads of the Senate Public Works Committee, February 15, 1973

Gramlich, E.M., "Alternative Federal Policies for Stimulating State

and Local Expenditures: A Comparison of Their Effects," NationalTax Journal, Volume XXI, Number 1 (June 1968)

Haskell, M.A., "Notes and Memoranda: Federal Grants in Aid-TheirInfluence on State and Local Expenditures," Canadian Journal ofEconomics and Political Science, Volume XXX, Number 4 (November, 1964)

385

Haveman, R.H., and J. Margolis (editors) PUBLIC EXPENDIUTRES AND

POLICY ANALYSIS, Markham Publishing Company, Chicago, Illinois, 1970

Henderson, J.M. and R. E. Quandt, MICROECONONIC THEORY: A MATHE-

MATICAL APPROACH, McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1958

Highway Research Board, HIGHWAY FINANCING: 10 REPORTS, Highway

Research Record Number 20, 1963

Jack Faucett Associates Inc., CAPITAL STOCK MEASURES FOR TRANSPOR-

TATION, Report Number JACKFAU-71-04-1, Volumes I, II, and III,Chevy Chase, Maryland, June, 1972

Johnson, D.W.,.and C.M. Mohan, "Revenue Sharing and the Supply of

Public Goods," National Tax Journal, Volume XXIV, Number 2 (June, 1971)

Kuh, Edwin, CAPITAL STOCK GROWTH: A MICROECONOMETRIC APPROACH, North

Holland Publishing Co., Amsterdam, 1971

Kurnow, Ernest, "Determinants of State and Local Expenditures Recon-sidered," National Tax Journal, Volume XVI, Number 3 (September, 1963)

McFarland, W.F., ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY IN HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES, Unpub-lished PhD Thesis, Tulane University, New Orleans, Louisiana, 1970

McMahon, W.W. and C.M. Sprenkle, "A Theory of Earmarking," NationalTax Journal, Volume XXIII, Number 3 (September, 1970)

Maxwell, J.A., "Federal Grant Elasticity and Distortion," NationalTax Journal, Volume XXII, Number 4 (December, 1969)

Maxwell, J.A., FINANCING STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS, The BrookingsInstitute, Washington, D.C., 1969

Miller, Edward, "The Economics of Matching Grants: The ABC HighwayProgram," National Tax Journal, Volume XXVII, Number 2 (June, 1974)

Miller, Edward, "Short Run Responses to Changes in the Availability

of Federal Funds," Unpublished Department of Transportation Paper

(TPI-10), 1972

Miller, Edward, "Effects of Federal Grants in Aid on Local Expenditures,"Unpublished Department of Transportation Paper (TPI-10), 1972

386

Miller, Edward, "The Effects of the Revenue Sharing Pass Through inLarge Urban Areas," Unpublished Department of Transportation Paper(TPI-10) 1972

Miller, Edward, "Impacts of the ABC Program on Highway Investment,"Unpublished Department of Transportation Paper (TPI-10) 1972

Miller, Edward, "Differences in Returns by Road System," UnpublishedDepartment of Transportation Paper (TPI-10) 1972

Mogulof, M.B., "Regional Planning, Clearance, and Evaluation: A Lookat the A-95 Process," American Institute of Planners Journal, Volume37, Number 6 (November, 1971)

Monypenny, P., "Federal Grants-in-Aid to State Governments: A Politi-cal Analysis," National Tax Journal, Volume XIII, Number 1 (March, 1960)

Musgrave, R.A. and P.B. Musgrave, PUBLIC FINANCE IN THEORY ANDPRACTICE, McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1973

Musgrave, R.A..(editor), ESSAYS IN FISCAL FEDERALISM, The BrookingsInstitution, Washington, D.C., 1965

Neuman, Lance, A TIME STAGED STRATEGIC APPROACH TO TRANSPORTATIONSYSTEM PLANNING, Unpublished SM Thesis, Department of Civil Engineering,Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1972

Oates, W.E., "The Dual Impact of Federal Aid on State and Local Govern-ment Expenditures: A Comment," National Tax Journal, Volume XXI,Number 4 (November, 1968)

O'Brien, T., "Grants-in-Aid:Some Further Answers," National Tax Jour-nal, Volume XXIV, Number 1 (March 1971)

Osman, Jack W., "The Dual Impact of Federal Aid on State and LocalGovernment Expenditure," National Tax Journal, Volume XIX, Number4 (December, 1966)

Osman, Jack W., "On the Use of Intergovernmental Aid as an Expendi-ture Determinant," National Tax Journal, Volume XXI, Number 4(December, 1968)

Pecknold, Wayne M., EVOLUTION OF TRANSPORT SYSTEMS: AN ANALYSIS OFTIME STAGED INVESTMENT STRATEGIES UNDER UNCERTAINTY, Unpublished PhDThesis, Department of Civil Engineering, Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology, 1970

387

Quandt, Richard E. and K.H. Young, "Cross-'Sectional Travel DemandModels: Estimates and Tests," Journal of Regional Science, VolumeIX, Number 2 (1969)

Roth, G.J., A SELF FINANCING ROAD SYSTEM, Institute for EconomicAffairs, London, 1966

Sacks, Seymour and R. Harris, "The Determination of State and LocalGovernment Expenditure and Intergovernmental Flow of Funds,"National Tax Journal, Volume XVII, Number 1 (March, 1964)

Scott, A.D., "The Evaluation of Federal Grants," Economica, VolumeXIX, Number, 76 (November, 1952)

Smerk, George M. , URBAN TRANSPORTATION; THE FEDERAL ROLE, IndianaUniversity Press, Bloomington, Indiana, 1965

Smith, A.H., "State Payments to Lcoal Governments in Wisconsin,"National Tax Journal, Volume XV, Number 3 (September, 1962)

Smith, D.L., "The Response of State and Local Governments to FederalGrants," National Tax Journal, Volume XXI, Number 3 (September, 1968)

Stanford Research Institute, BENEFIT/COST ANALYSIS OF HIGHWAY IMPROVE-MENT PROJECTS, SRI Project MU-7362, Stanford, California, December, 1969

Stockfisch, J.A., "Fees and Service Cahrges as a Source of CityRevenues," National Tax Journal, Volume XIII, Number 2 (June, 1970)

Strotz, R.H., "The Empirical Implications of a Utility Tree, Econo-metrica, Volume 25, Number 2

Teeples, R.K., "A Model of a Matching Grant-in-Aid Program WithExternal Tax Effects," National Tax Journal, Volume XXII, Number4 (December, 1969)

Theil, Henri, OPTIMAL DECISION RULES FOR GOVERNMENT AND INDUSTRY,North Holland Publishing Co., Amsterdam, 1964

Theil, Henri and A.S. Goldberger, "On Pure and Mixed StatisticalEstimation in Economics," International Economic Review, Volume 2,Number 1 (January, 1961)

388

U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1967 CENSUS OF TRANSPORTATION, Volume 1,National Travel Survey, Washington, D.C., July, 1970

U.S. Bureau of the Census, GOVERNMENTAL FINANCES IN 1953-1954(Yearly editions to 1969-1970), Washington, D.C.

U.S. Bureau of the Census, STATE GOVERNMENT FINANCES IN 1950 (Yearlyedition to 1970), Washington, D.C.

U.S. Bureau of Public Roads, HIGHWAY STATISTICS 1950 (Yearly editionsto 1970), Federal Highway Administration, U.S. Department of Transpor-tation, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Department of Transportation, Office of the Assistant SecretaryFor Policy and International Affairs, 1972 NATIONAL TRANSPORTATIONREPORT, Washington, D.C., 1972

U.S. Department of Transportation, NATIONWIDE PERSONAL TRANSPORTATIONSTUDY: HOME-TO-WORK TRIPS AND TRAVEL, Volume 8, Washington D.C.,

August, 1973

U.S. Department of Transportation, ALLOCATION OF HIGHWAY COST RESPON-

SIBILITY AND TAX PAYMENTS, Washington, D.C., 1969

U.S. Federal Highway Administration, FINANCIAL BACKGROUND FOR THE

1972 HIGHWAY NEEDS STUDY, Unpublished Report C-1, Washington, D.C., 1972

U.S. Federal Highway Administration, HIGHWAY FINANCE MANUAL, Washing-ton, D.C., 1972

Urban Mass Transportation Administration, CAPITAL GRANTS: FOR URBANMASS TRANSPORTATION: INFORMATION FOR APPLICANTS, Washington, D.C.,June, 1972

Wells, John D. et al, ECONOMIC CHARACTERISTICS OF THE URBAN PUBLICTRANSPORTATION INDUSTRY, Institute for Denfense Analyses, Arlington,Virginia, February, 1972

Wilde, J.A., "Grants-in-Aid: The Analytics of Design and Response,"National Tax Journal, Volume XXIV, Number 2 (June, 1971)

Wilde, J.A., "The Expenditure Effects of Grant-in-Aid Programs," Na-

tional Tax Journal, Volume XXI, Number 3 (November, 1968)

389

Winch, D.M., THE ECONOMICS OF HIGHWAY PLANNING, University of TorontoPress, Toronto, Ontario, 1963

Young, K.H., "The Synthesis of Time Series and Cross-Section Analyses:Demand for Air Transportation Service," Journal of the American

Statistical Association, Volume 67, Number 339

, "The Public Finance Aspects of the Transportation Sector, AStaff Paper Prepared by the Office of Policy and Plan Development,U.S. Department of Transportation, Washington, D.C., May, 1971

, FINANCING STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS, Proceedings of theMonetary Conference, Nantucket Island, Massachusetts, June 14-16, 1970

,Sales Management 's SURVERY OF BUYING POWER, (Yearly editions1950-1970), Bill Brothers Publications, New York, New York

390

Biographical Summary

Dr. Sherman was born in New York City on June 22, 1948. He pursuedundergraduate studies at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology,receiving a Bachelor of Science degreee in Aeronautical and Astro-nautical Engineering in February, 1971. Dr. Sherman received aMaster of Science degree in Transportation Systems Analysis fromM.I.T. in June, 1971. His S.M. thesis was entitled "The AirportAccess Problem: A Case Study Approach." Dr. Sherman remained atM.I.T. for his doctoral research, concentrating in the field oftransportation economics. He submitted his Ph.D. dissertation en-titled "The Impacts of the Federal Aid HIghway Program on State andLOcal Highway Expenditures," in January, 1975.

Dr. Sherman's research interests include a wide range of topicsrelating to transport economics. He is currently employed as aSenior Research Associate for Charles River Associates, Inc., wherehe is conducting research on Federal energy and environmental policyalternatives, and developing imporved methods for predicting urbantravel demand patterns. He has worked as a consultant to the govern-ment of Venezuela, assisting in the development of capital budgetingprocedures. Dr. Sherman has also consulted to the U. S. Departmentof Transportation in a variety of areas including developing proce-dures for assessing urban mobility, and assisting in the design ofthe National Transportation Study.

391

Appendix A

Estimated Parameter Values of the Long Run Revenue Policy Model

392

This appendix presents a complete listing of the regression runs

performed on the total expenditure model (TEM). In the figures that

follow, each regression run is described by a four character model

number, 1112nln2 where:

= 4

12

ni= {n2 =

S - grant terms stratified by type (Interstate andnon-Interstate

T - single grant term

U - undeflated data set

D - price deflated data set

1 - 48 State/14 year pooled data sample2 - 7 State/14 year pooled data sample

3 - 41 State/14 year pooled data sample

1,2,..., - model specification number

E3JAlL2ULESULLS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

!QE_" .QLNhSU

SENE RAL1ZfLLLEAS.I2UARtS

E-:AIt.1- %k2tk12L55a&z------S LE--.2s3L---89502

a~--- aa~a -

F STI MA T E VALUE

STANPAPO ERRPP

T-STATISTIC

FSTrATE VALUE

STANflAP) E PPOR

T-STATTSTIC;

'.A6 -0.650E-06

5.58 0.732F-O7

1.78 8.74

R I. TOT-0.319

0.f'36

8.86

TO L PCT0.457

0.069

6.62

PrY C HNT

-0.601

0.031

19.53

0.018

0.001

17.94

9.468

Ie.24

8.41

A VNIGP-1.146

3.091

12.55

0.605

0.124

4.88

0.6 19

0.043

14.39

w~

-

m

EU AlL2E.ULUis

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

.ENERA2 IL.LAi QUAEl

F-STAT: F(10.661) = 238.10 SEE = x3 ~RS0 0 .182

CON STM'NT

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD FP9PII

T-STATISTIC

FSTTMATF VALIIF

STANOARD EQRDR

T -STATISTIC

8.9P

5.55

1.62

RLTOT

J . 37

a03 7

SPOW

-0 .597E-06

0.796F-37

7.51

TOLPCT0.355

0. C8

4.3?

0.017

0.001

17.26

0.613

0.123

4.97

10 .639

1.206

8.8?

AVNIGP-1 *123

0.097

11.61

-00599

0.030

19.61

AVIGP

0.608

0.043

14.14

BI PTCX0. 088

0.055

1.58

ko

. " -.w .M WA.M-f mom .-~fi.A --_ _ _ -_ _ _ _ _ _6 _6 M M

- - - - - - - - - - -

-W - - -0..- -00 - qwft --M. om. -wpm

awmmlmmpwmompommom

EU.1_ ALL2 La.EaULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

EQL.Na.sul3

GEN-rALIL.ED-LEAi.SQUARES

F-STAT: F(1066I1) 231 5FF = 5.-34 R&D = 0.781

CONISTANT cpnp. - ---- o- la -- -MO- ------

FSTIMATF VLIF

STANOAPD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

rSTIMATF VALUCf

STANARDF EROR

T-STATISTIC

6.73

5.70

1.18

RLTOT-0.333

0 r 36

9.1?

-0 .649E-96

0*728'-07

8.91

TOLPCT0.407

0.372

5.68

K STK IJFAC

0.018

0.001

17.98

&ILE.

0.656

0.125

5.24

q.872

t .t39

8.66

AVNIGP-1.146

0.091

12.61

-o .ss7

0.031

18.83

AVIGP0.607

0.043

14.08

GOP-3.402

3. 172

2.34

cLn

.d& M -1&d _6mw .. mum.- _ ._ - - - - _ _ - __ A&_-J6A

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

.- -MN.- - _

US Ilt ALi22-HEUL S

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

!QEt-tU~A' Ift

IEUEALELLLEAS1-iQUARLS

E= IiELi h -- 2 --- -- 5 1 --- 5 -- 2 3

CONSTANT-

C~STTMATF VAIIF

STANnAPI) FRPOR

T-STATISTIC

RSTYM-TF VALUIE

STANrAF9 ERROR

T-STATTSTIC

4.20

QLTDT

-I?47

0.037

6.68

-S pr-. 6CRE-06

O.758F-i7

8.02

TiLPCT

C. 784

0.086

3.29

12.852

1.193

10.76

AVNIGP

-1.179

0.093

12.71

ALLEAL -

-0.652

0.031

21.05

AVIGP

0.530

0.042

12.62

0.016

).001

15.51

B I PTAX

0.059

0.053

1012

0.20

0.120

6.9?

GPQP

-0,.508

0.164

3.10

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

wiLw.EmwM- w1w -w-dmmo~ 49- -M 4M. At L.L.61 J9..w6 o64,64 .1p. -w. . . " ma.L-w. -.. . . -

mwmppmv

EiLLMALI22t-SaTS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

ENE39AL LLL.DEAiIsQUA&LS

=SAI- L2Th kztL_2-4LI2 R--$UE &-5fl-___Z2--1

E[STIMATE VALUF

STA"FA' ERPPIP

T-STAT! STTC

ESTIMATP VALIIF

cTANOAP D EP PR

T-STATI 5TIr

CQ 2ArL--BE C.-.-E E---!EAC---_ 1---GL

7.93 -0 .153E-05 9.315 -0.602 '.018 0.659

5.67 C.l04F-)6 1.130 0.031 0.001 0.126

1.4" 7.49 8.24 19.17 17.62 17.62

PL TCT

-0.324

o. C 37

5.23

TfL PCTJ.401

V0071

8.84

AVNIGP-1. 11

0.093

5.68

AI!GP0.621

0,044

12.03

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

G AF E1L.. .. suiEEALiLJEA ST_QUARE

F-STAT3!1 F( 9.h? = '50.79 SEE= ~R&QE2~iItI Aaaa4 =1 -.--. - -_2 _ _ _ _ -- -- _--"- - Ek

.C&N]iA.I_

ESTIMATE VALUE

STMPANA ERPOR

T-STATISTYC

PSTIMATE VALUE

STtNDAPD FRROR

T-STATISTIC

10.01

5.66

1.77

RLTOT-0.330

0.036

9.07

-0.137E-33

0.173F-04

7.9'

TOLPCT3.410

0.070

5.83

A5!K..

9.360

1 * 128I

8.30

AVNIGP-1.9135

0.093

12.22

.UEA.Q..

-0.600

0.031

19.16

0.018

0.001

17.73

AVIG0.620

0.043

14.25

0.606

0.126

4.81

.... Mo -- G kflI M- .O--.- -...4. - - .. MwoO- -W

... d-

TOTAL EXPE NDITURE MODEL

-MQQN.A..S21

ENESALIZEID-L EASiQUAR i

F-SrAr: E 9. RRI 2018 SF16 SEE 6.57

fllN A NT c pnp K CIK

FSTIMATE VALUE

STANDAPP ERRIR

T-CTATTST T

FSTIMATE VALIUE

STANQAP FPRfR

T-STATISTIC

97.82

8.94

1 0.95

RLTCT-0.127

x cqo

1.41

-0.668E-06

0.737E-06

0.91

T9LPCT2.772

0.492

5.64

RSO = 2m20

iFAC ECV . TMT

-1.340

0.227

5.90

0.006

0.002

3.66

0.209

0.307

0.69

AVNIGP-0.311)

0.161

1.92

-0.542

o.114

4.74

0.657

0.061

10.75

WA

1 x _ - - . _ _ -

-. - - - - - -- - - --. IN- _ - - - _ _ _

M

15LUAltl&ESiUUL

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

-I24LN-SU22

.G2 f3AU LL.EDLLAi1hS2UAES

E-STAT: FIC'. 87) = 15.24 SEE = 6.11 RSQ = .697

FSTIMATF VALUE

STANPAPf EPROR

T-STATISTIC

%-STIMTE VALUE

STANOArD FRROR

T-STATISTIC

73.5R -O.178E-O5 3.166 -0.616 0.003 -0.416

9.02 0.A65F-36 0.133 0.147 0.002 0.194

8.16 2.O 1.24 4.19 l.41 2.14

PL T'lT

-0.032

3.090

o.91

T')L PC T1.400

u.490

2.86

AVNIGP-0.379

0.208

1.8?

AVIGP0.571

0.091

6.26

9i PTCX0.484

0.491

0.99

a

.646 -;m .m6.&ibdl -U = _L _ _-m Wm__ _ _ _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ __o _ _

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

W-

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

.GENEALI LElA.IA QUAfli

F-STAT!F( fl.AS41 = 24t.3t SEE = 5 14 RSQ 0.794

--- ----- -- -- ----- - - -----

CONSTANT-

PSTIMATF VALUE

STANDARD FRROP

T-STATTSTIC

E STIMATE VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTTC

16.15

5.55

2.91

RLTOT--<.524

0 .C41

12.75

SPpp

-0.478E-06

2.724E-07

6.60

TOLPCT0.368

0.T71

5.21

.OJEAL.-

-0.637

0.034

18.50

0.018

0.001

17.32

KSTK-

8.?74

1.032

8.02

-0.856

0.114

7.51

0.693

0.122

5.67

0.439

0.057

7.68

-Pb

q U

."- .0- -.. I.-wo now.-ma-mm AN& JWMA-amx

a-

EULMA2N-REULIi

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODFI

fQODL-Nia_.a2

GENE ALILE!LJEA.SSQUARfS

RSQ = 0.799

FSTIMATE VALUE

STANDAPD EfRlP

T-STATIST IC

L2N.IAN2I.

16.24

5.48

2.96

-0.5C8E-06

0.783E-37

6.49

ES T !NATF VALUE

STANDAPD EPROR

T-STATISTIC

10.050

1.125

8.93

-0.9631

0.034

18.53

3.018

0.001

16.99

RLTOT-2.534

0.043

12.32

0.683

0.121

5.65

TCL PCT0.393

0.086

4.55

AVNMI-GP-0.919

0.120

7.64

0.415

0.057

7.30

-0.05?

0.056

0.93

-ME-M- 4 A&= AlOWNEWO - 4M d aWW4 aNW- --- AML-OL-L-.dt-.d6-

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

-. U- . - --PON-- dL-.-401W d

...S

t~jMAUI.tLR3E.SU 15

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

fzESERAL QJZEJLEA2.1 UAEES

F-ST AT: Ff 8,66b3) z 2)l496 SE E _ .0 ERS z0.JZ Z

ESTIMATE VALUE

ST NPARD ERROP

T-STATISTIC

FSTIMATE VALUE

STANnAPD ERROR

T-STAT1STIC

-CO ANI-IiSEQ._M--K... EAINL...0-

24.1? -0.454E-06 13.640 -0.454 0.014 3.307

6.17 0.807E-07 1.655 0.033 0.001 0.138

3.90 5.62 8.24 13.69 13.01 2.21

RLTOT-0.488

0.038

12.84

TOLPCT0.482

3.378

6.14

A VT &P0.038

3 .03?

1.17

CD)

m.w_ _A -

- - - - - - - - - - - - - -

Ellbal N....ESals

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

LAUDE. TXUU12

.iGENEAL.LLEA I.5$QUARtS

E=IAIJ1.EU. LE..QA........ .--.-..--

ESTIMATF VALUE

STANDAPD FPRR

T-STATISTIC

20.84

6.34

3.45

-0.3 14E-)6

C.844F-OT

3.72

FSTIMATF VALIJF

STANDkPn EPROR

T-STA T ISTTC

16.553

1.814

9.13

-0.458

C .032

14.C7

0.013

0.001

t2.?9

0.337

0.135

2.50

RL TOT-0.418

0.C3g

13.6?

TOLPCT0.178

0.098

1.83

AVTGP0.039

0.035

1.11

B! PT c0.?59

0.056

4.40

0.

ampdolm- ---ad- 4 - -1dbAUW..m.m -

E5iLeAllMQmESULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

EfELALuQ12Uf

' ENERALLLEDLWA AB

F-STAT: F( 9.662) = 199.56 SE E= 5.93 RSQ = 0.731

ESTIMATF VALIE

STANPARn FRROR

T-STATISTIC

E ST IMAlI E VA UE

STANDARD ERROp

T-STATISTIC

19.96

6.23

3.19

RLTfT-0.Sfl?

0.038

13.18

52- 2E------ESTK

-0.455E-)6 16.177

0.795E-7 1.756

5.72 9.21

TOLPCT0.388

0.081

4. 80

AVTGP-0.004

0.033

0.11

.JIEAL.

-0.461

0.033

12.96

0.015

0.001

13.30

.o 355

0.138

2.57

GPOP-0.543

0.191

2.85

4:0C:)

.- . t_ -- lgM SZo -mo-fd4mJ-rJ ---m--kfA-M 6&6L- -K LJPC.L

__-_.------... _.. _I_.W--

E5IefAlL.ESULT

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

.QDELQ..JUA

F-NEHAUSTLLESSQUARSi

F-STAT: F(10.6611 = 113.72 SEE = _5.7B RSO = 0.143

ESTIMATE VALAE

STANa)4P ERROR

T-STATISTIC

FSTIMATC VALUF

STANnAPQ ERROR

-S T A TI'ST r

_LN MAhl__ QI2__EI___UEA_---U0-----G- 8

36.41 -0.32?E-2i6 11.084 -0.534 0.012 0.618

6.9O 0.835E-07 1.411 0.034 0.001 0.136

5.27 3.86 7.85 15.66 10.74 4.53

RITOT-0.374

0.041

q,.16

TOL PCT11.178

0.098

1.81

AVTGP0.080

0.032

2.52

B IPT.X0.252

0.058

4.33

-0.554

0.186

2.98

4P'b0)

-M*-MoM Aw -dlkb..E-.dLIL-dg-MJ6 m dmmw-dr- AM =Mmp - dM-146 A. A6 mg--

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

0 W-91-

LM A2 L&JUEUj.S

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

tullE l-N...-l02

.G.ENE A1.E LWAI.lQUA5E

F-STAT: Ff Ro R9) = I 9SFF = 7a1l RSQ = 0.9RD

STITMATF VA LUE

STNPAon FRRnRp

T-SrTATJSTIC

CNiIANI.

p9.12

11

8.81

3.31 7F-05

0.1 16E- J5

2.74

T 1MAT F VA LUF

ST ANFAPf ERROR

T -STATISTIC

.AVLi..

2.680

0.611

4.38

.ALUEA..

-1.331

Pi. 216

6.06

ml---

0.001

).002

0.42

RL T G0T

7. 6 r

2.9C6

-0.647

0.208

3.10

TOLPCT1.641

0. 189

8.67

0.725

* 101

7.15

0 l

, --, I -JL. Abdll;,JLAd Z -W.- Amin... LJ.AL3L bd.A ALIb-

- -- - -0- ,

iSIl!Ali~t-.ZLill

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

1ED2EL.-Z Iu22

UNERALl E LtA.iQUAfE

F-ATT F q pI= 1 56 SEE = 7m15

CPnp KS TKa~a~~-a- -a a~- - ~aa~ a - a~ --

rSTIMATF VALUE

STJANAFD F RP IR

T-STATISTIC

CSTIMATE VAL(UF

STANfAPD FRRIR

T-CTAT!STTC

101.40

9.79

10.35

RL T CT-13304

3.088

3.45

0.716E-06

'.338E-06

0.76

TOL PcT3.?90

0.546

6.03

RSO = 2

1fF AC PC v (INYV

-1.720

0.241

7.12

0.006

0.002

2.85

0.255

D0135

1 . 88

AVT GPC' .583

0.089

6.49

-0.416

0.218

1.91

BI pTn 0 085

0.096

0.89

0

-AL- - - - J-J6 -w- -- , -

.

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

M112111. 11!3

GESETAFMO*DUL48 aSM2I 5A37

c-STAT: F( 8.565) = ?43.48 5FF = 5.37 RSO = 0.775

FSTIMATF VALIF

STANPAPD ERR2P

T-STATISTIC

PS TIMATF VAlUt E

STANfnADO FQPOR

T-CTATISTIC

28.27 -G.357E-06 9.880 -0.528 0.015 0.458

5.60 J.739E-37 1.182 0.034 0.001 0.125

5.05 4.82 8.36 15.79 14.68 3.66

RL TOT--. 643

0. C4')

16.17

T JL PCT. 391

0.374

5.30

0.013

0.028

0.45

P-

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

MFDEL..Qa5U3Z

tE5ERAU Zt2.LEAS L.3SUA&ES

F-STAT! Fl 9.5641 = 21R.R5 5FF = S.34 RSO = 0.777

CTIMATF V ALLF

STANDAP ERRR

T-STAT!STIC

ESTYMATE VALIUE

STANDAR') EQPCR

T-STATISTTC

?6.46 -).322E-06 10.556 -0.529 0.015 0.482

1.6 J.788E-07 1.239 0.034 0.001 0.124

4.7? 4.38 8.52 15.80 14.19 3.88

RLTlT-0.617

044

14. OC

TOLPCTI0.315

0.990

3.49

AVTGP0.018

0 .032

0.56

fBIPTQ0.068

0.057

1.20

C

P-

Ej1ALL2-_RtES&LLis

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

- 2 1~L L2t-2 .5S9 =2 2---S-2x..

F I6MA TF V41 hF

'fTANI f9Q f t F;-IQ

T - T A fI 5T IC

LST IMAT E VA[III3

SI TAN f) A P' 9 FVfPP

T-S 1 t T J c j j

&CB~tat 5.L ..-- DttE1 L- EAffi----QEEBEL - -- GNI

12.1? -0.857F-06 8.028 -p.738 9.o? 0.771

7.16 Q.94 3F-07 1 .050 0.04J 0.001 0.159

1.69 9.09 7.65 18.66 17.52 4.84

jL I '31-C .4%0

0 .O4t

9.7

InI- PCT0. 598

U.089

6.75

OF FNI-1.103

0.092

14.43

DE F (0.642

0.045

17.03

E1A112lQLEiUJJ&

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

B-E12LWN...L.112

LfJERE ALU2E.LJE 5_QUARE

E-zMA~Lft12adt uIt3-2 fBl ---_L..-3k2t-----a&Q3&iL.

Cfl TAFJT

ESTIMATF VALUE

STANDARD ERRfP

T-STATISTIC

CSTIMATE VALUIE

STANDAPO E"ROP

T-STAT!STIC

n E FK ITK

11.33 -0.791F-06 11.286

7.04 0.101E-06 1.247

1.61 7.81 9.05

RL TDT-' . 395

0.047

8.40

TOLPCT3.421

0.112

3*75

DEFNJG-1.123

0.096

11.60

-0.730

0.039

18.81

DEFIG0.606

0.044

13.70

.ELE.LY.

0.022

0.001

16.95

RI l-PTCX-3.118

0.071

1.67

0.790

0.156

4.80

40b

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

--- -_ _ _.& -mw.

Nw.

EalL! Al12!LRESUi

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

LEN BALI ZEDIA&U1UABLS

F-STATz Fff0.AF 11 = 233.26 SFF = A.Rfl RSO = .-779

EST[MATF VALUE

STANDARD FPRPR

T-STATISTIC

8.3?

7.26

1.15

-0.361E-06

0.927F-07

9.28

flEEtESI&

10.389

1.167

8.90

DEFPCY GINI--. JA aa.---------. .U ..

-0.715

0.040

18.03

0.023

0.001

17.74

3.808

0.129

5.07

FSTIMATE VALIUE

STANDAPO FRROR

T-SrTATISTC

RLTfOT-0.442

0.046

qe.54

TOLPOT0.494

0.091

5.39

DEFNIG-16148

0.091

12.59

DEFIGo .607

0.044

13.67

GPOP-0.530

0.218

2.43

0-4L43

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

----m- ,-,-

E ilT 12UItEEULLS.

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

mF-TT l O EF L - 644

E=STAT: E~lo6601 3222.67 SEE = 6.44 RSO = 0.R802

ESTIMATE VALUF

STANDAPO ERROR

T-STATISTIC

-CC IANlI

33.23

7.64

4.34

-0 . 796E-06

0.963E-07

8.27

.2EEZI.

13.677

1.220

11.21

FSTIMATE VALUF

STANDARD FPQJR

T-STATI ST IC

-0.801

0.039

20.44

.DEELX.

0.020

0.001

15.03

1.040

0.153

6.8!

RLTOT

-1.323

r.047

6.98

TOLPCT

0.327

0.110

2.97

DEFNIG

-1.167

0.092

12.65

DEFIG

0.520

0.043

12.04

BI PTCX

0.087

0.067

1.30

GP9P

-0.619

0.207

2.99

.- 441; Jo. As.- -.t- .. .aA.. --b

_ j _ 4 0M_____ .----

-.0 mom-w..-wmm-wmmmmmwmw... Mwww

EiLLoAI1MLSES.uLu

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

ENERALZE-LEASit.SQUAREI

F-' TAT: Ft Qo AR) = 28m00fl SEE= 7.50 RSO = O 741. ZI- a 1 -- .na a--n-..-.- ABe- ---------- ee M

FSTIMATF VALUE

STANPAQD FRROR

T-STATISTIC

121.10

9.36

12.9

-0.623E-06

0.F79E-06

3.71

-12EK1&

0.776

0.368

2.10

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANPARO ERROR

T-STATIST IC

.IEA!L..

-1.783

0.236

7.56

0.010

0.002

4.97

-0.679

0.099

6.87

RLTOT-0.185

0.101

1. *83

TOLPCT3.590

0.502

7.15

DEFNIG-0.295

0.132

2.24

DEFl0.666

0.058

11.50

4C"

mvdmpM-dw-dw -.--W -mv-

.00 mmmlw.-M

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

NQELNQ(3-S 1222

GE&EBALLLQLA.SESQUA5E

F-STAT: Ff10. 871 = 17t73 5FF = 7.46

I A^r'

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD FPROR

T-STATISTIC

%-STIMATF VALUE

STANDAPR F RP

T-STATISTIC

87.41

10.94

7.99

RLT.T0.092

0.10 q

0.84

-0. 179E-05

0 a 106F-05

1.68

TOLPCT1.789

0.456

3.76

RSO = 0.77

- r- Dr v r TM T

0.005

0.002

?.07

0.056

O .16c:

0.34

OFFNIG-0.433

0.206

2.10

-0.419

0.231

1.82

-0.859

0*176

4.88

9 FF It;0.624

0.087

7.17

B! PTQX0.492

0.549

0.90

-Jb

a)

-.- a-m-AL a;- -- I J A- dM6Jd-JL -go- - ' ' MIL -AL- Aw M J06 Jklw- - %up ..m - -wm w

I--ELuC NI .

ESIlfAlItLRE.SULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

2iE 9iEALEQWi S UA t

F-STAT: F( 9.5641 = 236.03 SEE = 6.60- RSO = 0.790

rfnlNczTANT

ESTTMATE VALIE

STANPARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

ESTTMATE VLUE

STANDAPO FPRFR

T-STATIST IC

19.62

7.10

2.76

RLTCT-0.686

0.053

12.99

-0.648F-06

0.928E-37

6.98

TDLPCT0.444

0.091

4.87

nF FKI C TKt

-0.778

0.044

17.64

I)EE-ec.

0.023

0.001

17.01

&nfa _

0.869

0*157

5.55

8.696

1 .065

8.16

DEFNIG-0.867

0.116

7.48

DE F IQ0.440

0.060

7.33

4'zb

.immommaw-11116-d6w 6 A I ' -at A -M - .- mm A& 3bK -ML. -- "-Mo-mmw _,-

-----

om

11FCar

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

tQ0F EL..NA SD2

GENERALLIED-EASE-SiLAEAES

F-STAT: F(10.5631 = ?16A5 SEE = 6.55 RSO = 0.794

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANPAP Y FRROR

T-STATISTIC

CDNSJ.AU

195

7.C4

2.78

-0.676E-06

0.101E-06

6.72

ESTIMATE VALUF

STANDAPD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

DEEEKSI&

10.153

1. 152

8.81

SUEAC.-

-0.771

0.044

17.60

DEER.YZ

0.023

0.001

16.57

0.861

0.155

5.55

-0.*697

0.056

12.44

TOL PCT0.468

0.111

4.21

DEFNIG-0 .908

0.122

7.44

DEF IG0.415

0.060

6.94

81 PTCX-0.053

0.072

0.73

4 :b..- j00

- - - - - - - - - - -

M -.- d- -_-__.NM-_d-----

go

F-STAT: Ft R 6631

Eii L1fAUlQ!LBE&ULLS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

= 21533 SEE = ltl -R&SQ _fQAZ Z_

ClNSTANT DE FKSTK.

ESTIMATE VALuE

STANDAP) EPQPR

T-STATISTIC

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

30.59

7.81

3.92

RLTOT-0.638

0.048

13.27

-0.62 OE-06

0. 102E-06

6.06

TOLPCT0.576

0.100

5.76

SPOP UFAC. OE EPC-Y

14.757

1.711

8.62

-GINI

-0.551

0.042

13.11

0.018

0.001

12.92

0.359

0.175

2.04

DEFTG0.017

0.033

0.52

Imw - - -

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

- N . - - --Z= L -m-- -A -11 - -_ _ _ _ _ _ _ .P A AL --- A M.=. -0 -.-96an A- w

-P

FiE LALTDL&E&LuLIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

.MDELJ.Q.STJ2LZ

2ENEaRAU..2 L l.SzJAafia

F-STAT Ff 9.aA2) = 203mA SFF = 7.o46 RSO = 0.734

CONSTANT

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD FRPOR

T-STATISTIC

E~STIMATE VALUF

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

25.83

7.68

3.36

RLTOT-0.551

0.050

10.99

SP

-0.441E-96

0. 108E-06

4.08

TOLPCT0. 222

0.124

1.79

.JIEA.-0.561

0.041

13.55

QEELCY

0.017

0.001

12.17

2EFK&T

15.012

1.784

8.97

DEFTGo .044

0.035

1.27

0.427

0.172

2.48

BPTCX0.331

0.076

4.38

____-__- ~ ~ _ _ _dwSio " _ __OL -0 . L

0

fEUlLAUI.tL-&SULlS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

mDDEL.5a. t1113

(&NERAJLIEDLE A .LSQUAR&E

F-STAT: F i q*s i = 1, 9S76 SEF = .S7-- a a _ -a6 __. .6w A .

CONSTANT

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANPAPD FPROR

T-STATISTIC

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANPARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

24.98

7.98

3.13

RLTOT-0.657

o.048

13.57

spnp

-0.622E-06

0. 102E-06

6.12

1TOLPCT0.496

0. 103

4.81

RSC = n.777

IFAr

-0.529

0.042

12.49

* P.EERC.

0.019

0.001

13.19

DFFKSTK

15.419

1.712

9.00

DEFTG0.004

0.032

0.13

0.447

0.176

2.54

GPOP-n .659

0.243

2.72

4 :Ib

- - - - - - - - - - -

_-_ _-- - i ----- -.

om

EU1leA112N-EULUS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

GENELALILQEDEASL.SQUAES

F-STAlv El t61I -= FF3.22 -SEE = 7f3 -RSU-= O4

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDAR ERROR

T-STAT1STIC

LDtSIAUI

45.66

A.71

5.24

-0.45 3F-06

0. 106E-06

4.27

11.789

1.437

8.20

FSTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD EPROR

T-STATISTIC

UEAQ.

-0.655

0.043

15.13

0.015

0.002

10.61

0.791

0.173

4.58

-L L-0.489

0.052

9.44

TJOL PC T0.212

0.124

1.71

DEFTG0.067

0.032

2.08

81 PTCX0.315

0.074

4.24

GPOP-0. 736

0.236

3.12

N3b

Aso. A.d

.W.mo__..Go0-

ft

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODl.

MODEL N Z.D21

F S IETEtALlEDUIL.SQ2U A R.2

F - a I L 1B1 -12 l_. .. 3 E.2-.- 2.

-------------------------- ---------------------

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

CCNiiAI

Q4.63

13.92

6.80

0.224E-05

0. t4E-05

1.58

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDAPD ERROR

T-ST&TISTIC

DfFFKSTK

2.180

0.671

3.25

iFAC-

-1.09 7

0.250

4.40

DEEPCY

0.003

0.002

1.07

-0.619

0.271

2.28

RLTOT-0.?86

0.116

2.45

TOL PCT1.322

0.129

10.25

DEFTG0.563

o .094

6.00

4-)z

E.IlaI.ON-REULI5

- _-. __ _ __J-.__ _ ---jL o

ESily.All -REULIS

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

BUDELNO_.-XI22

fiENE ALLE ASflUARU

F-cZTAT! Ft Q. RAI = 16A CFF = A. 92 RSO = nA?9a~.~-a ~ Mad-a aa n~a~

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD ERROR

T-STAT!STIC

QaI AIs2 an EEKU uE cD e x---1-h~

107.32 0.109E-05 0.372 -1.870 0.009 -0.381

11.0C 0.117E-05 0.140 0.275 0.002 0.278

9.10 0.93 2.66 6.81 3.50 1.37

RLTOT-0.368

0.110

3.36

TOLPCT3.578

0.657

5.45

DEF3G0.580

0.086

6.76

BIPTC0.057

0.127

0.45

W-mm...kw

s ATIhl-NA_.EULI

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

2DfEL_.JTD31

fGLNERALI.E LFAS L ._ QUARES

E-AIA.L 1...23DQ. FF = 6AR

DEF KSTK-

RQS = (1.772Am - --- _ .- .r --- - = - _

UFAC- OE EPCY

FSTIMATF VALuE

STANDAPO ERROR

T-STATISTIC

ESTIMATE VALUE

STANDARD EPROP

T-STATISTIC

34.84

7.15

4.87

SL T nT-O.8 34

0.058

16.40

-0.498E-06

0.948E-07

5.25

.10LC-T

0.479

0.095

5.05

DEFTG0.001

o.029

0.04

4'-:1

10.351

1.217

8.51

GINI

-0.643

0.043

15.00

0.019

0.001

14.41

0.574

0.160

3.59

.. J6 _ M _ _ _..._ . _ _ _ __~JA 16 oaw o__

EI5!IALLHLRtiULT

TOTAL EXPENDITURE MODEL

. D E LN.a2

G EBE~lZ LE A SI QMA

CFE =

C fmcT AN T oP nE cK rTK UFAC nFFPrY rl NT-a& ~~ ~ a~ a.- - - ..

FSTTMATE VALUE

STANTARD ERROR

T-STATISTIC

ESTIMATE VALUF

STANDAI) ERRPOR

T-STATISTIC

32.15

7.14

4.50

OR LTO T-0.OA1

0.056

14.21

-0.455F-06

0.101E-06

4.50

T...L PC T%.382

0.115

3.31

F-TAT:AT Ft Q.AA4I = 2t 2 RQ = 0 77S

-0.641

0.043

15.00

0.019

0.001

13.93

11.340

1.290

8.79

DEFTG0.002

0.032

0.05

0.612

0.159

3.86

0.082

0.073

[.12

4N)

L- A *= I-10--I-L- -ZX2 %Jxa :-- - _ _ _.. .. aj__ L._ .- _ 0 ]" jLdj~d- - .I j L

.-- - -..&Xaj

427

Appendix B

Derivation of Derivatives and Elasticities

from the Expenditure Mndels

428

This appendix sets forth the derivation of derivatives and

elasticities from the long run revenue policy model, and the short

run allocation model. Moreover, it will be shown how the results

from these two models can be combined to indicate the total change-

on both revenue and allocation- resulting from changes in the level

of the explanatory variables.

The short run allocation model takes the form

If(1) .=E. = f

where S. = share of expenditure devoted to category j

E = expenditures on category j

R = E = total expenditures (State and FederalI funds)

f. = f(X) = n XJk or iejk Xkkej k

We wish to derive the form of both the derivative of E. with

respect to Xk ,DE. , and the elasticity of E. with respect to

k kE

3 XkX ks'n E /X k

From (1) we get

(2) = R j = R(X) jL.

i f (X)

429

But R(X) is related to the estimated form of the long run

revenue policy model.

The long run revenue policy model takes the form:

(3) Rown, -pc a + I RMXmm

where Rown,.pc = total per capita expenditures from statesown sources (i.e. exclusive of Federalpayments to the States, F).

a= estimated coefilcients

Thus, R own, pcin (3) is related to R in (2) by:

(4) R = SPOP *(Rown,p + FPC)

where SPOP state population

Fpc = Federal highway payments per capita

Assuming a long run static solution1 whereby

F = GPCwhere Gpc = per capita highway grants,

1. Assuming that the states ultimately expend all Federal grantsmade available, differences between GPC and FPC can be

attributed to short run, transient responses. In the longrun, it can be assumed that Federal payments will eventually"settle down" to the rate of Federal grant availability.

(5)

430

the long run revenue policy model can be rewritten as:

(6) R += (s+mXm+ (1 + ) Gpc )*SPOP

Returning to equation (2) we can now define the derivative of

E with respect to Xk as:

(7) @E .

Xk= Si

j kX+ R s.

ak

The corresponding elasticity is simply:

(8) Ej/Xk

XkE.

3

SaE

ax k

R Xk

x =E.

ax

ak

xk

3TR

) = XkR

a RaX k

Xk

3

as.

aXk

- R/Xk + Sj/Xk

431

The Product Form Model

In this case, the specification of each share takes the form:

T1 Xkjk Ej n

(9) s. = = ~dj

where: n = share numerator

d = share denominator

k = estimated share modeljk coefficients

Assume variable Xp appears in the share numerator and one or more

of the fi in the share denominator. The derivative of the numera-

tor with respect to Xp takes the form:

aa- &1jkj n

(10) = Jpp Xk jk Xp kjp

kfp

By the same reasoning, the derivative of the share denominator

with respect to XP is:

432

(11) - I.p i p

Using these results, we can now derive:

2 as. and(12) = d - n - p

=(Y Gd-n - n f

= s~ (1 - s) p

p

a.- sI Y s

i/jI

Returning to equation (7), the derivative of expenditures on

category i with respect to variable Xp is:

(13) aE = s n + {sR (1 - sQ )pp - s4 i }

But from (6),

If the variable in question X = SPOP, then apop= 0+

2 S SPOP

(14) 3E

Thus, we can

with respect

(15) KE.axP

= SPOP

now state the final

to variable X :

= SPOP +

The corresponding elasticity for

simply:

(16) /X p X SPOP

R

form of the derivative of E

{ s~ (I - s.) S.

-s Ot 8 Ps }

i hj

the product form model is

+ (1-s.) S. - a s3 Jp iPi

Ivi

Special Cases: The Product Form Model

In the derivation of the derivatives and elasticities of the

expenditure models, on the preceding pages, it was assumed that

the explanatory variables X enter into the allocation model as

given in equation (9). In the actual estimated form of the

models, there were two exceptions to this specification.

The first concerns the highway grant variables, which enter

several of the expenditure shares as either specific grant types

(e.g. Interstate, Primary, Secondary) or as aggregates across

433

434

grant categories (e.g. total non-Interstate grants, total grants).

We are interested in deriving the derivatives and elasticities of

expenditures with respect to each of the categorical grant types.

Since the derivation in this instance follows the same reasoning

as in the preceding section, the results are presented without

a detailed derivation.

Let G I

G,

G s

GNI

GT

- Interstate grants

- Primary grants

- Secondary grants

- Gp + GS = non-Interstate grants

- Total Grants

From equation (6), it is clear that:

-A

(17) -G = (1 + ) SPOP, for g = I, P, S

Using this result in equation (7), the derivatives of expenditures

with respect to grant terms take the form:

(18)aE.

-tag = s.'(l + 6 )-SPOP + R { s -() -s

g + yAjNI+ G -

G ) s }

A

(OXj &* GNIczNI

435

for g = I, P, S

and = 0 if g=I{l ifg= P or S

The corresponding derivatives follow directly from equation (18):

(19) (E /G (1 + 0g ) G SPOP + (1 -s

R

+ G + taT -

NI T

GG(ig + 6i aiNI + aiT)sii j NI

The second exception to the general derivation of elasti-

cities and derivatives concerns the population variable, SPOP.

This variable appears in several of the expenditure shares in

both direct form, and as the denominator of the variable measuring

capital per capita (KSTK). In this case, we can rewrite

equation (9) as:

S jSPOP- CAPTL jKSTK X jk XAk(20) S(Xk

SPOP i (SPOP A iKSTK X i-- XkI k

where: CAPTL = highway capital stocks

436

The derivative and elasticity of share s with respect to SPOP

can be written respectively as:

as. = LIISPOPI~2KSTK) s (l -si) -SPOP

&iSPOP - &iKSTK

3 13 SPOP

(22) 3Is /SPOP

As noted in

of total expenditures,

(1i s) (&jSPOP ~ &IjKSTK)

. s i(iSPOP - &iKSTK)

itj

the footnote on page , the derivative

R with respect to population is:

- +2U SPOP(23)

Thus we can now state the form of the 'derivative and elasticity

of E with respect to SPOP:

(24) = Si( + 2 SPOP SPOP) +

14is.{(jSPOP 7 SjKSTK) (1 - s ) -

.. i SPOP ~ -iKSTK)5i}

(21)

437

SOP A A(25) TE./SPOP = - o ( + 2$Spop) +

(&jSPOP - JKSTK) (1 - -

j (&iSPOP - CiKSTK)*Si

The Exponential Form Model

The derivatives and elasticities from the exponential

form allocation model differ from the previously presented results

of the product form model. In this case, each share is specified

as:

(26) s. = k a

IIe

'i hei

Following the same reasoning as expressed in equations (10)

through (12), the derivative of expenditure share j with respect

to a particular variable Xp is given by:

(27) as. = A s (1 - s) - saxJip 3 3j S.

The corresponding elasticity is simply:

(28) rsx = j X ( - s ) - Xp{j .S

438

Substitutin these results in equations (7) and (8), we get the

derivative and elasticity of E with respect to X for the exponen-

tial form allocation model:

(29) = OP + R{& s (1 - si) - s a s}

pp JjL

(30) X SPOP + 0.X (1 - sj) - aX s

R

Special Cases: The Exponential Form Model

As in the product type allocation model, the general form

of the derivatives and elasticities for the exponential form allo-

cation model do not apply in the case of the population variable

and the highway grant terms. The derivatives and elasticities

from the exponential model, for these special cases are presented

below.

(31) = (1 + ) SPOP + R{ s (1 - s ) (a. +

gg

6 i JfNI + aJT) - si(ig + YiNI + iT

1The notation used here is identical to the definitions given inthe section "Special Cases: The Product Form Model."

439

= -) SPOP + G {(1 - s.) (. +

S ajNI + &jT ig5

for g = I, P, S

and 6, 0 if g1Iand 6~ ={ 1 i gII1 if g0I

= s O +C 2SPOP SPOP) +

ReKSTK-s6.{(1-s.) (&jSPOP-

+ 5SiNI jI+ &iT) s }

LjKSTK) -SPOP

iSPOP _ i S K )

SPOP + P= T(0 + 20po SPOP) +

KSTK { 3(1 - s ) (jSPOP SPOP -

aSPOP S -aiKSTK) si

5jIKSTK) -

(32)T'E /G

(33) aE.i

(34)TE /SPOP

440

Appendix C

Derivatives and Elasticities from the

Two Expenditure Models

441

This appendix contains the derived elasticities and derivatives

from the expenditure models described in Chapters IV and V. On the

pages that follow, the tables are titled "Short Run" or "Long Run"

Elasticities (or Derivatives). The short run measures pertain to the

short run expenditure model (SRAM), where by definition the States'

budgets are fixed. The long run elasticities and derivatives reflect

the empirical analysis integrating the results of the SRAM and TEM,

and thus describe States' long run expenditure responses to Federal

grants (inter alia) where budget levels can change.

The derivatives and elasticites are presented for both the

product form and exponential form of the SRAM (see Chapter V.).

442

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICiTIES

SHAR E

VARI ABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

G I N I

KS TK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCM F

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AV PG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

-0.682

0.402

-0.201

-0.033

-0.169

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

-0.059

0.029

0.873

-0.070

-0.002

PRI MARY

0.069

0.192

-0. 201

-0.033

0. 112

-0.031

-0. 011

-0.001

0.023

0. 029

-0.416

0. 534

-0.045

SECONDARY

0.105

-0.280

-0.201

0.298

0.026

0.277

0.026

-0.001

0.023

0.029

-0.433

-0.176

0.261

443

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

NONFASYST

0.650

-0.884

-0.201

-0.033

0.026

-0.031

0. 183

-0.001

0.023

-0.488

-0.161

-0.130

-0.026

MAI NT

-0.515

-0.036

-0.201

-0.033

0.285

-0.031

-0.011

0.007

0.023

-0.041

0. 082

-0.062

0. 001

OTHER

0.975

-0.036

0.616

-0.033

-0.068

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

0.023

0.028

-0.505

-0.226

-0.066

VARI ABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GiNI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

444PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

SEVEN STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHAR E

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GI NI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCM F

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

-0.573

-0.128

-0.049

0.022

-0.077

-0.150

-0.014

-0.021

0.015

0.189

0.774

-0.016

0.084

PRIMARY

0.126

0.366

-0.049

0. 022

-0.021

-0.150

-0. 014

-0.021

-0.006

0.189

-0.217

0. 379

0.035

SECONDARY

0.085

0.726

-0.049

-0.168

-0.211

1.150

-0.038

-0.021

-0.006

0. 189

-0.759

-0.105

-0.282

445

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMSEVEN STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTI C ITI ES

SHARE

VARIABLE NONFASYST MAINT OTHER

spop 1-122 0.114 0.347

UFAC -0.867 -0.245 -0.245

PCY -0.049 -0.049 0.232

GINI 0.022 0.022 0.022

KSTK -0.211 0.110 0.238

TS PMR -0.150 -0.150 -0.150

PCCRMT 0.348 -0.014 -0.014

PCMF -0.021 0.103 -0.021

TOLPCT -0.006 -0.006 -0.006

RLTOT -0.161 0.131 -0.750

AVIG -0.962 -0.076 -0.186

AVPG - -0.375 -0.117 -0.149

AVSG -0.115 0.028 0.010

446PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

INTERSTATE

-0.406

0.314

-0.162

-0.037

-0.174

-0.032

-0.010

0.005

-0.104

0. 024

0.781

-0.124

0.112

PRIMARY

-0. 117

-0.254

-0.162

-0.037

0.070

-0.032

-0.010

0.005

0.041

0.024

-0.397

0.617

-0.157

SECONDARY

-0.102

-0.339

-0.162

0. 343

0. 075

0. 292

0. 030

0. 005

0. 041

0. 024

-0.401

-0. 193

0. 140

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

447

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTiCITIES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

NONFASYST

0.406

-0.663

-0. 162

-0.037

0.075

-0.032

0.155

0.005

0.041

-0.472

-0.006

-0.096

0.221

MAINT

-0.361

0.050

-0.162

-0.037

0.200

-0.032

-0.010

-0.035

0.041

0.003

0. 102

-0.066

0.338

OTHER

0.690

0.050

0.465

-0.037

-0.003

-0.032

-0. 010

0. 005

0.041

0. 012

-0.441

-0. 217

-0. 253

448

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

INTERSTATE

-.105E 02

0.402E08

-0.474E 04

-0.524E 07

-0.172E 08

-0.221E 03

-0.172E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.661E 07

0.111E 01

-0.317E 00

-0.170E-01

PRIMPRY

-.753E 00

-0.136E08

-0.335E 04

-0.371E 07

0.808E 07

-0.157E 03

-0.122E 08

-0.281E 06

0.287E 08

0.468E 07

-0.374E 00

O.172E 01

-0.354E 00

SECONDARY

0.578E 00

-0.100E 08

-0.170E 04

0.167E 08

0.940E 06

0.707E 03

0.147E 08

-0.142E 06

0.145E 08

0.237E 07

-0.197E 00

-0.286E 00

0.104E 01

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

449

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VAR I ABLE

SPOP

-J FA C

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

P CM F

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

NON FASYST

0.134E 01

-0.118E 08

-0.f633 E 03

-C.701E 06

0.351E 06

-0.296E 02

0.379E 08

-0.531E 05

0.-41E 07

-0.146E 08

-0. 273E-01

-0. 71E-01

-0.390E-01

MAINT

-0.378E 01

-0.169E 07

-0.226E lL4

-0.250E 07

0.138E 08

-0.106E 03

-0.821E 07

0.122E 07

0.193E 08

-0.445E 07

0. 495E- 01

-0.135E 00

0.774 E -02

OT H E R

0. 131E

-0. E10E

0.127E

-0. 4558E

-0. 601E

-0. 193E

-0. 150E

-0.347E

0.35 4E

0.5143E

-0.561E

-0. 3 99 E

-0. 637E

02

07

05

07

07

03

08

06

08

07

00

00

00

450PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

SEVEN STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE INTERSTATE PRIMARY SECONDARY

SPOP -0.930E 01 0.150E 01 -.553E 00

U5AC -0.114E 08 0.238E 08 0.259E 08

PCY -0,888E 03 -0.649E 03 -0.356E 03

GIN! 0.231E 07 0,..69E 07 -0.710E 07

KSTK -0.481E 07 -0.957E 06 -0.52E 07

TSPMR -0.870E 03 -0.636E 03 O.268E 04

PCCRMT -0.412E 08 -0.301E 08 -0.448E 08

PcMP -0.102E 08 -0.746E 07 -0.409E 07

TOLPCT 0.525E 08 -0.155E 08 -0.851E 07

RLTOT 0.365E 08 0.267E 08 0.146E 08

AVIG 0.9572 00 -0.196E 00 -0.376E 00

AVPG -0.679E-01 0.118E 01 -0.179E 00

AVSG p.645E '0 0.194E 00 -O.66E 00

451

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMSEVEN STATE SAMPLE

Si-ORT RUN ICDEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

G1 N

KS TK

TS PMR

PCCAIT

P CM F

TULPCT

R L T

AVIG

AV PG

AVSG

ON FAS Y.ST

0.29 E

-0. 124E

-0. 143E

O.371E

-0. 213E

-0.140E

0.165E

-3.164E

~-O.500E

-O.191E

-0.257E

-0 .142 E

MAINT

01

08

03

06

07

03

09

07

07

07

00

00

00

0.109E 01

-0.129E 08

-0.524E 03

0.136E 07

0.407E 07

-0.5i14E 03

-0.243E 08

0.295E 08

-0.123E 08

0.149E 08

-0.53 2E-01

-C.295E 00

0.126E 00

C THE R

0.340E 01

-0.132E 08

0.255E 04

0.139E 07

0.899E 07

-0.526E 03

-0.249E 08

-0.517E 07

-0.128E 08

-0.874E 08

-0.139E 00

-0.384E 00

0. 465E-01

452

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

INTERSTATE.

0.799E 00

-0.865E 07

-0.509E 03

-0.799E 06

0.106E 07

-0.300E 02

0.293E 08

0.243E 06

0.864E 07

-0.139E 08

-0.908E-03

-0.566E-01

-0.644E-02

PRIMARY

-0.252E 01

0.232E 07

-0.181E 04

-0.284E 07

0.997E 07

-0.106E 03

-0.666E 07

-0.586E 07

0.307E 08

0.266E 06

0.594E-01

-0.133E 00

0.398E-01

SECONDARY

0.972E 01

0.468E 07

0.104E 05

-0.571E 07

-0.306E 06

-0.214E 03

-0.134E 08

0.174E 07

0.618E 08

0.254E 07

-0.517E 00

-0.915E 00

-0.556E 00

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

453

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

ShORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

FCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

NONFASYST

0.799E 00

-0.865E 07

-0.509E 03

-0.799E 06

0.106E 07

-0.300E 02

0.293E 08

O.243E 06

O.864E 07

-O.139E 08

-0 .908E-03

-C.566E-01

-0.6L- 4E-02

MAINT

-J.252E 01

0.232E 07

-0.181E 04

-0.284E 07

O.997E 07

-0.106E 03

-0.66FE 07

-C .586E 07

O.307E 08

0.266E 06

0.59 4E-01

-0.138E 00

0.398E-01

OTHER

0.972E

0.468E

0.IO4E

-0.571E

-0. 306E

-0. 214E

-3.134 E

0.174 E

O.618E

0. 254E

-0.517E

-0.915E

-. 5S6E

01

07

05

07

06

03

08

07

08

07

00

00

00

454PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVS G

INTERSTATE

0.330

0.396

0.623

-0.029

-0.067

-0. 031

-0. 011

-0.001

-0. 059

0.028

1.232

-0. 070

-0.002

PRIMARY

0.943

-0.198

0.623

-0.029

0. 214

-0. 031

-0.011

-0. 001

0.023

0.028

-0.057

0.534

-0.045

SECONDARY

1.117

-0.287

0.623

0.302

0.127

0.277

0.026

-0.001

0.023

0.028

-0.074

-0.176

0.261

455

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

NONFASYST

1.662

-0.890

0.623

-0.029

0.127

-0.031

0.183

-0.001

0.023

-0.489

0.198

-0.130

-0.026

OTHERMAINT

0,497

-0.042

0.623

-0.029

0.387

-0.031

-0.011

0.007

0.023

-0.043

0.440

-0.062

0.001

1.987

-0.042

1. 440

-0.029

0.034

-0.031

-0.011

-0.001

0. 023

0.026

-0. 146

-0.226

-0.066

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PC C RMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVS G

456PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

SEVEN STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

1. 326

-0.139

0.188

0.018

-0.075

-0.150

-0.014

-0. 021

0.016

0.189

1.159

0.031

0.110

PRIMARY

2.026

0.355

0.188

0.018

-0.019

-0.150

-0. 014

-0.021

-0.006

0.189

0.168

0.425

0.061

SECONDARY

1.985

0.715

0.188

-0.172

-0.209

1.150

-0.038

-0.021

-0.006

0.189

-0.374

-0.058

-0.256

457

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMSEVEN STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

NONFASYST

3.021

-0.878

0.188

0.018

-0.209

-0.150

0.348

-0. 021

-0.006

-0.162

-0.576

-0.328

-0.089

MAINT

2. 014

-0.256

0.188

0. 018

0.113

-0.150

-0.014

0.103

-0.006

0.131

0.310

-0.071

0. 054

OTlER

2.247

-0.256

0.468

0.018

0. 240

-0.150

-0.014

-0.021

-0.006

-0.750

0. 200

-0.103

0. 036

VARIABLE

S POP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

458PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

INTERSTATE

0. 754

0.307

0.690

-0. 033

-0.086

-0. 032

-0. 010

0.005

-0.104

0.021

1.098

-0. 115

0.115

PRIM ARY

1. 042

-0. 261

0.690

-0. 033

0.157

-0.032

-0. 010

0. 005

0.041

0. 021

-0. 080

0.626

-0.154

SECONDARY

1.057

-0.346

0. 690

0. 348

0.162

0.292

0.030

0.005

0.041

0.021

-0. 084

-0.184

0.144

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

A V I G

AVPG

AVSG

459

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VAR I A BLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

G I N I

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCM F

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

NONFASYST

1.565

-0.670

0.690

-0.033

0.162

-0. 032

0.155

0.005

0. 041

-0.475

0.312

-0.087

0.224

MA I NT

0.799

0. 043

0.690

-0.033

0.287

-0.032

-0.010

-0.035

0. 041

-0.0Oo

0.419

-0.057

0. 341

0 TH ER

1.850

0.043

1.318

-0.033

0.084

-0. 032

-0. 010

0.005

0.041

0.009

-0.124

-0.208

-0.249

460PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GiNI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AV I G

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

0.507E 01

0.395E 08

0.147E 05

-0.460E 07

-0.686E 07

-0.221E 03

-0.172E 08

-0.398E 06

-0.103E 09

0.627E 07

0.157E 01

-0.317E 00

-0. 170E-01

PRIMARY

0.103E 02

-0.140E 08

0.104E 05

-0.325E 07

0.154E 08

-0.157E 03

-0.122E 08

-0.281E 06

0.290E 08

0.444E 07

-0.5 16E-01

O.172E 01

-0.354E 00

SECONDARY

O.615E 01

-0.103E 08

0.526E 04

0.170E 08

0.464E 07

O.707E 03

0.147E 08

-0.142E 06

0.147E 08

0.225E 07

-0.336E-01

-0.286E 00

0.1O4E 01

461

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCC.RMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AV I G

AV PG

AVSG

NONFASYST

O.342E 01

-0.119E 08

0.196E 04

-0.614 E 06

0.173E 07

-0.296E 02

0.379E 08

-0.531E 05

0.543E 07

-0.147E 08

0. 33 6E-01

-0. 791E-01

-0.390E-01

MAINT

0.365E 01

-0.201E 07

0.701E 04

-0.219E 07

0.188E 08

-0.106E 03

-0.821E 07

0.122F 07

0.196E 08

-0. 461E 07

0.267E 00

-0.135E 00

0. 774E-02

OTHER

0.267E 02

-0.368E 07

0.297E 05

-0.402E 07

0.302E 07

--0.193E 03

-0.J50E 08

-0.347E 06

0.358E 08

0.513E 07

-0.162E 00

-0.899E 00

-0.5&7F 00

462PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

SEVEN STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE INTERSTATE PRIMARY SECONDARY

SPOP 0.215E 02 0.240E 02 .129E 02

UFAC -0.L24E 08 0.231E 08 O.255E 08

PCY 0.342E 04 0.250E 04 0.137E 04

GIN, 0.191E 07 0.140E 07 -0.726E 07

KSTK -0.466E 07 -0.8h6E 06 -0.523E 07

TSPIR -0.870E 03 -0.636E 03 O.268E 04

PCCRMT -0.412E 08 -0.301E 08 -0.448E 08

PCMF -0.102E 08 -0.746E 07 -0.409E 07

TOLPCT 0.546E 08 -0.140E 08 -0.770E 07

RLTOT 0.36 4E 08 0.266E 08 0.146E 08

AVIG 0.143E 01 0.152E 00 -0.185E 00

AVPG 0.130E 00 0.132E 01 -0.996E-01

AVSG 0.843E 00 0.339E 00 -0.787E 00

463

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMSEVEN STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE NONFASYST MAINT OTHER

SPOP 0.789E 01 0.193E 02 0.220E 02

UFAC -0.126E 08 -0.135E 08 -0.138E 08

PCY 0.531E 03 0.202E 04 0.516E 04

GINI 0.308E 06 0.113E 07 0.116E 07

KSTK -0.210E 07 0.416E 07 0.908E 07

TSPMR -0.140E 03 -0.5l14E 03 -0.526E 03

PCCRMT 0.165E 09 -0.2L43E 08 -0.249E 08

PCMF -0.164E 07 0.295E 08 -0.617E 07

TOLPCT -0.309E 07 -0.113E 08 -0.116E 08

RLTOT -0.5C2E- 07 0.14 9E 08 -0.875E 08

AVIG -0.115E 00 0.226E 00 0.149E 00

AVPG --0.225E 00 -0.178E 00 -0.264E 00

AVSG -0.110E 00 0.243E 00 0.166E 00

464PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCv=

TOLPCT

ALTOT

AV I G

AV PG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

0.115E

0.311 F

0. 168E

-0. 540E

-0.944E

-0. 233E

-0. 145E

0. 189E

-0.1.72E

0. 479E

1.140E

-0. 526E

-0. 137E

02

08

05

07

C7

03

03

07

09

07

01

00

00

PRIMARY

0.112E 02

-0.186E 08

0.118E 05

-0.380E 07

0.121E 08

-0.164E 03

-0.102E 08

0.133E 07

0,475E 08

0.337E 07

-0. 719E-01

0.202E 01

-0.318E 00

SECONDARY

0.566E 01

-0.123E 08

0.589E 04

0.202E 08

0.622E 07

O.748E 03

0.156E 08

0.661E 06

0.237E 08

0168E 07

-0.3 74E-01

-0.295E 00

0.106E 01

465

PRODUCT FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY ONE STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

G I N I

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AV PG

AVSG

NOIFASYST

0.308E 01

-0.874E 07

0.216E 04

-0.696E 06

0.229E 07

-0.300E 02

0.293E 08

0. 243E 06

0.870E 07

-0.140E 08

0. 511E-01

-0. 514E-01

-0. 123E-02

MA NT

0.558E 01

0.199E 07

0.768E 0 (

-0.2 47E 07

0.14 3E 08

-0.106E 03

-0.666E 07

-0.586E 07

0.309E 08

-0.993E 04

0.?L44E 00

-C.120E 00

0.5 83E-01

OTHER

0. 260E

0.400E

0.295E

-0. 498E

0.8 48E

-0.214E

-0.134E

0.174E

0. 622E

0. 198E

-0. 145E

-0. 878E

-0. 519E

02

07

05

07

07

03

08

07

08

07

00

00

00

466EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINi

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

-0. 469

0.554

-0. 242

-0. 015

0.314

-0.014

0.007

0.008

-0.164

0.065

0.554

-0.057

0.012

PRIMARY

-0.018

-0.415

-0.242

-0.015

-09.026

-0. 014

0.007

06008

0. 064

06065

-0.108

0.379

-0.058

SECONDARY

0.087

-0.579

-0. 242

0.138

-0.051

0.121

-0.082

0.008

0. 064

0.065

-0.435

-0.229

0.031

467EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHAR E

NONFASYST

0.308

-0.569

-0.242

-0.015

-0.051

-0. 014

0.063

0. 008

0.064

-1.345

0.404

0.086

0.071

MAl NT

-0.157

0.017

-0.242

-0.015

0.077

-0.014

0.007

-0.0 54

0.064

-0.248

0.230

0.038

0.051

OTHER

0.554

0.017

0.740

-0.015

-0.351

-0. 014

0.007

0. 008

0.064

0.188

-0. 555

-0.182

-0.039

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KS TK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

468EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHAR

VARIABLE

SPOP

UPAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCM F

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AV PG

AVSG

INTERSTATE

-0. 721E

O .553E

-0. 570E

-0. 243E

0. 319E

-0.968E

0.106E

0.315E

-0. 236E

0.145E

O.704E

-0. 258E

3.136E

01

08

04

07

08

02

08

37

09

0?

00

00

00

PRIMARY

-0.191E 00

-0. 293E 08

-0.403E 04

-0.172E 07

-0.187E 07

-0.685E 02

0,747E 07

0.223E 07

0.79Y 08

0.103E 08

-0.9 71E-01

0.122E 01

-0.456E 00

SECONDARY

0.477E

-0.207E

-0. 204E

0. 776E

-0. 188E

0.309E

-0. 453E

0.113E

0. 401E

0.522E

-0.198E

-0. 372E

0.322E

00

08

04

07

07

03

08

07

08

07

00

00

00

469

EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

SHORT RUN MODEL DERI VATI VES

SHARE

VARIABLE

S POP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI

AVPG

AVS G

NONFASYST

0. 633E 00

-0.760E 07

-0. 761E 03

-0.325E 06

-0.700E 06

-0.129E 02

0.130E 08

0.421E 06

0.150E 08

-0. 404E 08

0.6 86E-01

0. 524E-01

0.105E 00

MAINT

-0.115E 01

0.825E 06

-0.272E 04

-0.116E 07

0.373E 07

-0.462E 02

0.504E 07

-0.968E 07

0.535E 08

-0.266E 08

0.139E 00

0. 817E-01

0.270E 00

OTHER

0. 744E

0. 151E

0.152E

-0. 212E

-0. 312E

-0. 846E

0.922E

0.275E

0.0 979E

0. 369E

-0. 617E

-0. 72 3E

-0. 377E

01

07

05

07

08

02

07

07

08

08

00

00

00

470EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAM

FORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VARI ABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVIG

AVPG

AVSG

I NTh.RSTATE

0.543

0.547

0.583

-0.011

0.415

-0. 014

0.007

0.008

-0.263

J. 063

0.913

-0. 057

0.012

PR IMARY

0.994

-0. 421

0. 583

-0.011

0. 076

-0.014

0.007

0.008

0. 064

0. 063

0. 251

0. 379

-0.058

SECONDARY

1.098

-0.586

0.583

0.142

0.050

0.121

-0.082

0.008

0.064

0.063

-0.076

-0. 229

0.081

471

EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL ELASTICITIES

SHARE

VARIABLE

SPOP

UFAC

PCY

GINI

KSTK

TS PMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

R LTCT

AVI G

A V PG

AVSG

NONFASYST

1.320

-0.57T

0.533

-0.011

0. 050

-0. 014 i

0.063

0.008

0.064

-1. 346

0.762

0.086

0.071

MAI NT

0.855

0. 011

0. 583

-0. 011

0.179

-0. 014

0.007

-0.054

0. 064

-0. 250

0.589

0.038

0.051

OTHER

1.565

0.011

1.564

-0.011

-0.250

-0. 014

0.007

0.008

0.064

0.18 7

-0.196

-0. 182

-0.039

472

EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARIABLE INTERSTATE PR IMARY SECONDARY

SPOP 0.836E 01 0.108E 02 0.605E 01

UFAC 0.547E 08 -0.298E 08 -0. 210E 08

PCY O.137E 05 O.972E 04 0.492E 04

GINI -0.178E 07 -0.126E 07 0.799E 07

KSTK 0.423E 08 0.545E 07 0.183E 07

TSPMR -0.968E 02 -0.685E 02 0.309E 03

PCCRMT 0.106E 08 0. 747E 07 -0. 453E 08

PCMF 0.315E 07 0.223E 07 0.113E 07

TOLPCT -0.285E 09 0.797E 08 0.403E 08

RLTOT 0.142E 08 0o.101E 08 0.510E 07

AVIG 0.116E 01 0.226E 00 -0. 347E-01

AVPG -0. 258E 00 0.122E 01 -0.372E 00

AVSG 0.136E 00 -0.456E 00 0.322E 00

473

EXPONENTIAL FORM SPECIFICATION OF THE SRAMFORTY EIGHT STATE SAMPLE

LONG RUN MODEL DERIVATIVES

SHARE

VARI ABLE

S PO F

UFAC

PCY

GI NI

KSTK

TSPMR

PCCRMT

PCMF

TOLPCT

RLTOT

AVI G

AVPG

AVSG

NONFASYST

0. 271E

-0.769E

01

07

0.184E 04

-0.238E 06

0.681E 06

-0.129E 02

O.130E 08

0.421E 06

0.150E 08

-0.404E 08

0.129E 00

0. 524E-01

0.105E 00

MA INT

0. 628E 01

0.512E 06

0.656E 04

-0.851E 06

0.867E 07

-0.462E 02

0.50L4E 07

-0.968E 07

0.537E 08

-0.268E 08

0.357E 00

0. 817E-01

0.270E 00

OTHER

0. 211E

0.9 38E

0.322E

-0. 156E

-0. 222E

-0.846E

0.922E

0. 275E

0.9 84E

0. 366E

-0. 218E

-0. 723E

-0. 377E

02

06

05

07

08

02

07

07

08

08

00

00

00