35
Does Inflation Targeting matter? T. Dergiades 1 , C. Milas 2 , T. Panagioditis 3 1 IHU, Greece, 2 University of Liverpool, UK , 3 University of Macedonia, Greece, LSE, UK and RCEA, Italy. November 2015

Does Inflation Targeting matter?

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

Does Inflation Targeting matter?

T. Dergiades1, C. Milas2, T. Panagioditis3

1IHU, Greece, 2University of Liverpool, UK ,

3University of Macedonia, Greece, LSE, UK and RCEA, Italy.

November 2015

Page 2: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

2

1. Background

• Inflation Targeting (IT) became a popular framework forthe conduct of monetary policy replacing other targetingregimes (monetary or exchange rate targeting).

• It features an explicit target for inflation and greateremphasis on central banks’ transparency, credibility,and accountability in conducting monetary policies.

• Main benefit the alleviation of the dynamicinconsistency problem and leads to lower(expectations) of inflation and inflation variability.

• From the 1990s inflation rates became lower, lesspersistent and less variable. These were regarded asindications that IT was successful.

2

Page 3: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

• Bernake (2011): flexible inflation targeting “increasedthe effective scope of monetary policy” and “the basicprinciples of flexible inflation targeting – thecommitment to a medium-term inflationobjective…seem destined to survive”.

• Mervyn King (2012) reflecting on twenty years of IT :“…the results in terms of low and stable inflation havebeen impressive. There have been pronouncedreductions in the mean , variance and persistence ofinflation in Britain and elsewhere.”

3

Page 4: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

•But Carney (2014): “That fight (againstinflation) culminated in the adoption of aninflation target, which helped secured 15years of price stability and sustainedeconomic growth. However, with time, ahealthy focus became a dangerousdistraction”.

4

Page 5: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

5

Background

• Svesson (1997) argues that IT implies base drift of theprice level, suggesting that the price level has a unitroot and inflation is stationary.

• Previous studies have tested for stationarity of the level ofinflation by employing either linear or nonlinear unit roottests.

• Culver and Papell (1997) employ sequential break andpanel unit root tests and Hassler and Wolters (1995)fractional unit root tests for international inflation data.

5

Page 6: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

• Advantages: an official announcement of the targetincreases the credibility of the policy of the CB,alleviates the dynamic incontinency problem, anchorsexpectations and secures price stability. Empiricalevidence further strengthens the efficiency of the policy.

• Opponents of IT argue that it is merely a conservativewindow dressing (Romer 2006 p532), it reflects a moregeneral process of reforms (Gertler 2005) such ascentral bank independence (Kohn 2005) and/or theCB’s communication policy (Mankiw 2005).

6

Page 7: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

• Batini and Lexton (2007): Other disadvantages (1)decreased discretion by the central bank that leads todeclines in output growth; (2) too much discretion thatresults in the inability to influence inflation expectations;(3) higher exchange rate volatility as inflation targetingignores exchange rate levels; and (4) inability ofinflation targeting to be successful in countries that donot meet strict preconditions

7

Page 8: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

8

2. Existing Literature

• Ball and Sheridan (2005) focusing on twenty majordeveloped OECD countries (7 of which adopted ITregime) and through the implementation of the standard“differences in differences” approach they concludedthat the IT regime seems to have no significant impactupon the improvement of inflation, output and interestrates.

8

Page 9: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

Literature

• Gregoriou and Kontonikas (2006) looked at 5 OECDcountries (UK, Canada, Sweden, Australia and NZ) andtwo high inflation non-OECD countries (Chile andIsrael). Sample starts from the establishment of IT ineach country until 2004. ADF fail to reject the non-stationarity null. ESTAR unit root test points towardsstationarity (nonlinear mean reverting).

9

Page 10: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

10

Existing Literature continued

• Gonçalves and Salles (2008) argue that thesample selection bias problem contaminatesthe results reported by Ball and Sheridan(2005). In their effort to overcome the biasselection problem, they examined a sample of36 emerging economies (13 of which adoptedIT regime). Gonçalves and Salles (2008) foundthat the IT regime delivers irrefutable gains,with respect to inflation and growth volatility.

10

Page 11: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

•Lin and Ye (2007) by implementing a variety ofpropensity score matching methods for 22 majorindustrial countries (7 inflation targeters)managed to take in consideration the self-selection problem. The authors showed that sucha policy adoption is non-effective in industrialcountries with respect to inflation, inflationvariability, long-term interest rates and incomevelocity of money.

11

Page 12: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

12

Existing Literature continued

• Lin and Ye (2009) using for once more the propensityscore matching methodological framework and focusingon 52 developing countries for the years 1985 to 2005,they offered evidence for the effectiveness of the ITregime. Specifically, Lin and Ye (2009) showed that theIT regime for the developing countries constituted asignificant parameter for lowering both inflation andinflation variability.

• These results come to confirm the Gonçalves andSalles (2008) empirical findings.

Page 13: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

13

3. Econometric MethodologyTo examine a change in persistence we implement themodified Busetti and Taylor (2004) tests (BT), assuggested by Harvey et al (2006). BT to test a change inpersistence from I(0) to I(1) proposed the followingstatistics (the null is a constant I(0) process) :

13

1[ , ]

max ( )l u

M MH

K K

3 [ , ]log exp ( )K K

l uM MH d

22

1,[ ] 1 [ ] 1

2[ ]20,1 1

ˆ[(1 ) ]( )

ˆ[ ]

T t

it T i T

MT t

it i

T

T

K

(1)

(2)

with

(3)

2 [ , ]( )

l uM MH d

K K

Page 14: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

14

Methodology continued

where, τ(0,1), [τl ,τu] is a sub-interval of (0,1), T is thesample size and finally, ε0,i and ε1,i are the OLS residualsfrom the regression of the examined series on aconstant for the samples t = 1,…,[τΤ] and t = [τΤ],…,T,respectively.

BT to test for a change from I(1) to I(0) proposed the use of the reciprocal of , that is , with J=1,2,3

However, the above statistics are severely oversized when the true generating process is constantly I(1).

M K 1 /j MH K

Page 15: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

15

Methodology continued

min,minexpj M j Mj

H bJ H K K

9

1, 1, ,[ ]i

t t i ti ky t u t T

x

Harvey et al (2006) to test the null of a constant I(0) or I(1)generating process against a change from I(0) to I(1),proposed the following modification:

where, b is a constant provided by Harvey et al (2006) and ,with equals to 1/T times the Wald statistic that corresponds to the test of the joint hypothesis , in the regression below:

min [ , ] 1,[ ]m inl u Tj j 1,[ ]Tj

1 9... 0k

(4)

(5)

Page 16: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

16

Methodology continued

When the alternative examined hypothesis is of an opposite direction (that is, I(1) to I(0)), the statistic used in equation (4) is substituted by its reciprocal analogue and the factor is replaced with , where is defined as , with the exception that specification (5) is now estimated for t=[τT],…,T.

The modified statistic is denoted as :

1 ,[ ]Tj min [ , ] [ ],min

l u

RT Tj j

[ ],T Tj 1 ,[ ]Tj

,min

1/j M jH K

Page 17: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

17

Methodology continued

The location of the breakpoint for a change that might be either from I(0) to I(1) or from I(1) to I(0), BT propose the use of (5) and (6), respectively.

[ , ]

ˆ arg m axl u

[ , ]

arg minl u

221,[ ] 1 2 2

0, 1,[ ] 220,1

ˆˆ ˆ

ˆwhere and defined as previously ,  are

T

tt T

t tT

tt

T T

T

(6)

(7)

Page 18: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

18

4. Data

• Our study implements tests for change in persistence for 45 countries individually as well as for three groups of countries (G7, OECD and OECD Europe).

• The frequency of the data used is monthly over the period 1980:1 to 2010:6.

• For each country (or croup of countries) the annualized inflation is used which is estimated by the logarithmic difference of the respective consumer price index.

• Exception consist the countries of Australia and New Zealand given that there is no availability of monthly observations. For the two abovementioned countries the annualized inflation series is used in quarterly frequency for the period 1980:q1 to 2010:q2.

18

Page 19: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

19

Data continued

• Primary source of the data used is the InternationalFinancial Statistics (IFS) database of the InternationalMonetary Fund (IMF), while the secondary source ofdata is the Main Economic Indicators (MEI) databaseprovided by OECD.

• The MEI database has been used as source of dataonly for the following countries (or group of countries):OECD total, OECD Europe, G7 countries, China,Germany and Ireland.

Page 20: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

20

5. ResultsTable 1. Change in Persistence Testing

Statistics for testing I(0)→I(1) Statistics for testing I(1)→I(0) Country Sample

Break date

H1(K Μ (.))min H2(K Μ (.))min H3(K Μ (.))min Break date

H1(1/K Μ (.))min H2(1/K Μ (.))min H3(1/K Μ (.))min Euro-zone countries

Austria 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.134 0.038 0.014 1987m05 87.073*** 30.455*** 39.343***

Belgium 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.028 0.006 0.002 1987m10 144.839*** 75.477*** 67.742*** Cyprus 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.058 0.027 0.010 1987m03 79.357*** 35.680*** 35.732*** Finland 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.095 0.015 0.004 1994m05 83.397*** 45.496*** 36.660*** France 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.009 0.001 0.000 1992m05 478.584*** 232.202*** 229.055*** Germany 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.057 0.025 0.008 1994m03 40.1148*** 17.167*** 16.927*** Greece 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 11.102 2.923 3.914 1999m10 247.639*** 48.409*** 108.655*** Ireland 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.013 0.008 0.002 1987m06 18.452** 13.561*** 7.513** Italy 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 0.002 0.000 0.000 1996m09 664.274*** 235.192*** 328.272*** Luxembourg 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.018 0.004 0.001 1988m04 147.160*** 62.256*** 67.814*** Malta 1980m01-2010m05 2004m06 e 0.002 0.001 0.000 1986m05 181.266*** 90.587*** 85.549*** Netherlands 1980m01-2010m06 2000m12 0.012 0.008 0.001 1988m06 60.488*** 13.874*** 26.200*** Portugal 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 2.871 0.287 0.334 1995m10 76.208*** 30.398*** 32.446*** Slovakia 1994m12-2010m06 1999m06 9.634 2.294 2.862 2004m12 2.191 0.560 0.407 Slovenia 1994m12-2010m06 2007m06 e 0.439 0.173 0.063 1998m01 e 2.454 1.438 0.786 Spain 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.317 0.039 0.014 1995m07 78.909*** 37.857*** 35.696***

Inflation-targeting countries

Australia 1980 q01-2010 q02 1986 q03 0.918 0.142 0.074 2001 q02 799.178*** 140.774*** 392.197*** Brazil † 1996m01-2010m06 2002m11 0.359 0.141 0.050 2007m07 e 22.772** 3.471 8.597** Canada 1980m01-2010m05 2004m06 e 0.003 0.001 0.000 1995m01 163.941*** 77.138*** 77.101*** Chile 1980m01-2010m01 1989m11 13.390 3.123 4.755 1997m04 67.754*** 29.205*** 29.743*** Columbia 1980m01-2010m01 1988m03 43.726*** 13.075*** 18.853*** 2003m09 113.813*** 11.254*** 49.018*** Czech Reb. 1994m12-2010m06 1998m01 e 7.077 0.257 1.155 1999m12 16.628* 7.914*** 6.387** Ghana 1980m01-2010m06 1995m03 0.265 0.104 0.051 2004m01 307.032*** 35.878*** 145.705*** Hungary 1980m01-2010m06 1987m07 768.189*** 65.894*** 367.710*** 2001m09 295.583*** 42.756*** 136.369*** Iceland 1984m01-2010m06 2005m03 e 0.377 0.089 0.039 1993m01 14.401* 7.581*** 5.069* Indonesia 1980m01-2010m05 1997m12 24.433** 4.255* 8.278** 2000m06 45.793*** 5.721** 18.221***

Notes: see next page

Page 21: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

21

Results continued

Table 1 (continued). Change in Persistence Testing Statistics for testing I(0)→I(1) Statistics for testing I(1)→I(0)

Country Sample

Break date H1(K Μ (.))min H2(K Μ (.))min H3(K Μ (.))min

Break date H1(1/K Μ (.))min H2(1/K Μ (.))min H3(1/K Μ (.))min

Inflation-targeting countries (continued)

Israel 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 0.016 0.003 0.001 1999m08 926.556*** 586.374*** 676.896*** Korea† 1980m01-2010m05 2005m11 e 0.024 0.002 0.004 1984m09 581.440*** 142.162*** 281.137*** Mexico 1980m01-2010m05 1986m05 3.838 0.339 0.429 2001m10 724.031*** 337.753*** 373.500*** New Zeal. 1980m01-2010m06 1986 q03 1.486 0.115 0.073 1999 q04 958.553*** 256.141*** 564.051*** Norway 1980m01-2010m06 2003m12 0.033 0.005 0.001 1992m09 258.789*** 139.025*** 125.209*** Peru 1992m01-2010m06 2006m11 e 0.000 0.000 0.000 1998m12 641.159*** 208.118*** 227.242*** Philippines 1980m01-2010m05 2004m06 e 0.434 0.132 0.066 1987m04 162.917*** 41.325*** 76.607*** Poland 1989m01-2010m06 1993m05 e 0.004 0.005 0.000 2001m08 261.734*** 306.316*** 192.123*** Romania 1991m10-2010m06 1995m07 e 0.197 0.033 0.012 2006m03 102.608*** 154.718*** 37.065*** South Africa† 1980m01-2010m05 1985m01 67.162*** 5.794** 28.631*** 2000m03 10.548 3.726* 3.568* Sweden 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 0.528 0.089 0.036 1990m02 192.208*** 62.820*** 88.167*** Switzerland 1980m01-2010m06 1986m02 e 1.461 0.294 0.155 1994m10 131.723*** 45.908*** 61.252*** Thailand† 1980m01-2010m06 2005m11 e 0.012 0.013 0.003 1985m01 17.372* 7.760*** 6.030** Turkey 1980m01-2010m06 1994m03 10.746 4.555* 3.029 2004m03 263.594*** 97.625*** 123.579***

UK 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.016 0.006 0.001 1991m07 100.182*** 60.403*** 46.175***

Other countries and Groups

China 1994m01-2010m02 2006m12 e 0.000 0.000 0.000 1999m06 10.250 7.069** 3.678 Denmark 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.009 0.001 0.000 1990m03 545.549*** 302.392*** 263.543*** Japan 1980m01-2010m05 2004m06 e 0.081 0.035 0.010 1992m09 52.361*** 16.131*** 22.663*** US 1980m01-2010m06 2004m06 e 0.002 0.001 0.000 1987m01 71.582*** 38.464*** 32.731***

G7 1980m01-2010m04 2004m04 e 0.000 0.000 0.000 1992m04 175.663*** 84.571*** 82.724*** OECD Europe

1980m01-2010m04

1994m07 0.025 0.025 0.004 2002m12 116.406*** 12.696*** 52.345***

OECD 1980m01-2010m04 1986m02 e 0.184 0.064 0.018 1998m07 136.591*** 27.647*** 62.882***

Notes: (a) ***, ** and * a change in persistence at the 0.01, 0.05 and 0.10 significance level, respectively. (b) The subscript e signifies that the identified breakpoint is located on an extreme of the initial search interval (0.20-0.80). (c) The superscript † implies that an extreme breakpoint is also combined with a significant change in the persistence. In these cases we amend the search interval to (0.15-0.85) and the tests for a change in persistence are implemented from the beginning. (d) On those cases where there is no evidence of a significant change in the persistence, given the identification of an extreme breakpoint, then the extreme breakpoint is disregarded and the testing procedure is not repeated for the extended search interval.

Page 22: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

22

Results continued

• From the 45 countries included in the sample, 35countries (13 from the euro-zone group, 19 from the ITgroup and 3 from the rest countries) appear toexperience change in persistence from I(1) to I(0) in theannualized inflation (criterion used: 1% significancelevel for all the implemented statistics).

- Exception are the following 10 countries:

For the Euro zone group: Ireland, Slovakia, Slovenia

For the IT group: Brazil, Czech Republic, Iceland,

Indonesia, South Africa, Thailand

For the rest countries: China

Page 23: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

23

Results continued

• The 3 examined groups of countries (G7, OECDEurope and OECD) appear also to experience changein persistence from I(1) to I(0) in the annualized inflation(criterion used: 1% significance level for all theimplemented statistics).

• From the 45 countries included in the sample, only 2countries (both from the IT group) appear to experiencechange in persistence from I(0) to I(1) in the annualizedinflation (criterion used: 1% significance level for all theimplemented statistics).

These two countries are the following:

Columbia and Hungary

Page 24: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

24

Results continued

Figure 2. Difference between the formal adoption date and the estimated break date.

-200 -160 -120 -80 -40 0 40 80 120 160 200

A us tra lia ***Canada ***

Ch ile ***Co lum bia ***

Cz ec h Rebub lic*** G hana

Hungary ** *Ic eland

Indones iaIs rael ***

*** K oreaM ex ic o ***

New Zea land ****** Norway

*** P eru*** P hilipp ines

P oland ***Rom ania ***

S outh A fric a*** S weden*** S w itz erland

Thailand*** Turk ey

*** UK

(94)(48)

(79)(48)

(23)(-40)

(3)(-98)

(-61)(91)

(-163)(33)

(109)(-102)

(-37)(-177)

(34)(7)

(1)(-35)

(-63)(-184)

(-22)(-15)

adopt ion datem onths be fore m onths a fte r

Notes: (a) Figures within the parentheses denote the time difference in months between the formal adoption date and the estimated break date for all the inflation targeting counties, (b) *** denotes a 0.01 significant change in persistence provided that there is an agreement among the three alternative implemented tests, (c) Finally, Brazil is excluded since the estimated break date has been found to be an extreme breakpoint.

Page 25: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

25

Results continuedTable 2. Descriptive statistics for the inflation targeting countries.

Before the FAD After the FAD Before the EBD After the EBD Country FAD EBD

Mean Median St. dev. Mean Median St. dev. Mean Median St. dev. Mean Median St. dev. Inflation-targeting countries (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

Australia 1993m04 2001 q02 7.25 7.79 3.15 2.69 2.55 1.42 5.36 5.45 3.57 2.94 2.80 0.94 Brazil 1999m06 2007m07 e 7.98 5.49 6.01 6.79 6.27 3.08 - - - - - - Canada 1991m01 1995m01 6.36 4.71 3.09 2.01 1.87 1.26 5.27 4.36 3.38 1.94 1.99 0.91 Chile 1990m09 1997m04 21.67 21.05 8.22 7.04 4.69 6.16 18.55 17.83 8.51 3.73 3.61 2.25 Columbia 1999m09 2003m09 23.06 23.44 4.74 6.17 6.10 1.92 20.50 21.88 7.16 5.16 5.26 1.49 Czech Reb. 1998m01 1999m12 8.94 8.89 1.23 3.31 2.65 2.92 8.05 8.70 3.30 2.72 2.56 1.99 Ghana 2007m05 2004m01 33.48 23.80 30.83 15.53 16.43 3.75 36.36 26.39 31.84 14.07 13.09 3.55 Hungary 2001m06 2001m09 15.23 13.55 8.73 5.51 5.59 1.85 15.16 13.03 8.70 5.40 5.40 1.74 Iceland 2001m03 1993m01 11.74 5.75 12.28 6.47 5.39 4.02 19.94 19.27 12.00 4.71 3.72 3.63 Indonesia 2005m07 2000m06 11.34 9.03 12.16 8.65 6.72 4.67 12.01 9.11 13.43 8.65 7.41 3.86 Israel 1992m01 1999m08 113.17 103.58 121.78 5.31 4.25 4.63 73.18 17.93 107.74 2.12 2.10 2.28 Korea 1998m04 1984m09 7.44 5.25 6.85 3.16 2.98 1.53 13.36 9.34 11.10 4.34 3.94 2.25 Mexico 1999m01 2001m10 46.69 28.58 39.62 6.19 4.83 3.70 42.23 26.52 38.88 4.55 4.44 0.82 New Zealand 1990m03 1999 q04 11.89 13.14 5.13 2.38 2.19 1.42 7.09 4.70 6.22 2.58 2.64 0.88 Norway 2001m03 1992m09 5.27 4.00 3.59 1.99 1.96 1.31 7.31 6.56 3.29 2.11 2.16 1.05 Peru 2002m01 1998m12 19.91 10.09 24.55 2.44 1.99 1.86 27.38 11.81 26.28 2.63 2.51 1.74 Philippines 2002m01 1987m04 11.43 8.87 10.91 5.17 4.33 2.68 17.52 11.96 16.51 7.25 7.13 4.01 Poland 1998m10 2001m08 133.01 35.74 270.33 3.97 3.67 2.87 104.92 31.06 243.41 2.60 2.44 1.44 Romania 2005m08 2006m03 83.46 43.87 84.72 6.25 6.30 1.71 80.42 41.33 84.29 5.93 5.99 1.57 South Africa 2000m02 2000m03 12.22 13.08 3.87 6.13 5.96 3.20 12.18 13.06 3.91 6.17 5.98 3.19 Sweden 1993m01 1990m02 7.81 7.92 3.25 1.50 1.44 1.41 7.95 7.69 3.05 2.34 1.66 2.82 Switzerland 2000m01 1994m10 2.81 2.64 2.01 0.96 0.96 0.82 3.53 3.40 1.82 0.90 0.83 0.77 Thailand 2000m05 1985m01 5.33 4.49 4.41 2.55 2.20 2.23 8.49 5.09 7.17 3.61 3.47 2.38 Turkey 2006m01 2004m03 57.46 60.36 27.57 9.03 9.61 1.99 61.07 62.75 25.16 9.30 9.72 1.78 UK 1992m10 1991m07 7.28 5.68 4.14 2.65 2.76 1.25 7.62 6.34 4.22 2.75 2.89 1.27

Notes: (a) FAD denotes the formal adoption date. (b) EBD denotes the estimated break date. (c) Columns (1), (2), (3) and (4), (5), (6), present the mean, the media and the standard deviation before and after the formal adoption date of the inflation targeting policy. (d) Columns (7), (8), (9) and (10), (11), (12), present the mean, the media and the standard deviation before and after the estimated break date. (e) The descriptive statistics in columns (7), (8), (9) and (10), (11), (12) are not reported for Brazil, since the EBD is located on an extreme of the search interval.

Page 26: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

26

Results continuedT able 3. D escrip tive statistics for the non-inflation targeting countries or groups.

B efore the E B D A fter the E B D C ountry E B D

M ean M ed ian St. dev. M ean M ed ian St. dev . E uro-zone countries

A ustria 1987m 05 4 .45 4 .97 2 .00 2 .19 2 .05 1 .00 B elgium 1987m 10 5 .73 6 .52 2 .66 2 .11 2 .09 1 .08 C yprus 1987m 03 6 .74 6 .03 4 .07 3 .32 3 .23 1 .63 F inland 1994m 05 6 .16 5 .83 3 .24 1 .50 1 .32 1 .19 F rance 1992m 05 6 .60 3 .78 4 .22 1 .62 1 .69 0 .73 G erm any 1994m 03 3 .23 2 .95 1 .99 1 .54 1 .50 0 .72 G reece 1999m 10 15.48 16 .42 6 .54 3 .19 3 .24 0 .93 Ire land 1987m 06 11.53 10 .20 6 .52 2 .66 2 .78 2 .19 Italy 1996m 09 8 .91 6 .27 5 .56 2 .17 2 .19 0 .68 L uxem bourg 1988m 04 5 .15 6 .26 3 .57 2 .32 2 .27 1 .01 M alta 1986m 05 5 .05 1 .51 6 .51 2 .45 2 .58 1 .54 N etherlands 1988m 06 3 .22 2 .80 2 .73 2 .16 2 .13 0 .87 P ortugal 1995m 10 14.30 12 .29 7 .50 2 .55 2 .71 1 .26 Slovakia 2004m 12 7 .85 7 .24 3 .07 3 .06 3 .04 1 .21 Slovenia 1998m 01 e - - - - - - Spain 1995m 07 8 .58 6 .90 3 .85 2 .81 2 .94 1 .25

O ther countries and G roups

C hina 1999m 06 9 .39 7 .40 9 .76 1 .68 1 .28 0 .96 D enm ark 1990m 03 6 .87 5 .51 3 .25 2 .10 2 .11 0 .78 Japan 1992m 09 2 .61 2 .31 2 .05 0 .08 -0 .10 0 .97 U S 1987m 01 6 .15 4 .20 4 .04 2 .95 2 .90 1 .33

G 7 1992m 04 5 .35 4 .30 2 .99 2 .03 2 .13 0 .85 O E C D E urope 2002m 12 8 .11 7 .67 2 .79 2 .59 2 .52 0 .83 O E C D 1998m 07 7 .60 6 .77 2 .73 2 .83 2 .79 1 .04

N otes: (a) E B D denotes the estim ated break date . (b) C olum ns (1), (2), (3 ) and (4), (5 ), (6 ), present the m ean, the m ed ia and the standard dev iation before and after the estim ated break date . (c ) T he descriptive statistics are not reported for S lovenia, since the E B D is located on an extrem e of the search interval.

Page 27: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

27

6. Does Inflation Targeting matter?• On the basis of the above implemented tests for a change in the annualized inflation persistence from I(1) to I(0), theme of interest is whether a significant change in persistence is significantly associated with those countries that implement an inflation targeting policy.

• This is a binary choice problem, which may be handled through a simple probit regression model:

0 1ln1

ii i

i

b b D

where, πi is the probability that the country i experiences a significant change in persistence from I(1) to I(0). Di is a dichotomous dummy variable which indicates whether the country i is an IT country or not. b0 and b1 are coefficients to be estimated and is as usual the error term.

Page 28: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

28

Does Inflation Targeting matter? continued

• Provided that each country’s πi is non-observable, we introduce the binary yi variable, which receives the value of 1 if a significant change in persistence is signified simultaneously by the three implemented Statistics at the 0.01 significance level, and 0 otherwise.

• A positive and significant value for the b1 coefficient, it would be an indication for the validity of the proposition that IT countries face a significant higher probability, over the rest countries, for a change in the inflation persistence from I(1) to I(0).

Page 29: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

29

Does Inflation Targeting matter? continued

• The parameter estimates of the simple probit regression model are analytically illustrated in Table 2.

Table 2. The binary Probit estimation results and diagnostic Statistics. Variable Coefficient Std. error z-Statistic p-value Marginal effect (Std. error) Constant 0.8416 0.3194 2.6343 0.0084 - Di -0.1353 0.4213 -0.3211 0.7481 -0.0400 (0.1376)

Diagnostic statistics McFadden R-squared 0.0021 LR Statistic 0.1034 Log-likelihood -23.7850 LR Statistic p-value 0.7477

• Based on a sample of 45 observations (countries) the estimated b1 coefficient is negative and non-significant. Therefore, it can be said that countries which are inflation targeters face similar probability for a significant 1% change in the inflation persistence from I(1) to I(0), compared with other countries.

Page 30: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

30

Does Inflation Targeting matter? continued

• Another subject of interest is whether the inflation targeting countries present higher values for the three estimated statistics used to test the change in persistence

• For this purpose, we regress the binary Di variable (defined as previously) over the three modified Busetti and Taylor (2004) Statistics. The three subsequent specifications are illustrated below:

0 1 ,mini j M ij iD b b H

K 1,2j with and 3

• Positive and significant b1 coefficient for each specification, it would be an indication that IT countries face indeed higher probability to receive greater values for the implemented persistence change Statistics.

Page 31: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

31

Does Inflation Targeting matter? continued

• The estimation results for the three similar probit regressions are provided in Tables 6, 7 and 8, below:

Table 3. The binary Probit estimation results and diagnostic Statistics. Variable Coefficient Std. error z-Statistic p-value Marginal effect (Std. error)

Constant -0.1627 0.2621 -0.6207 0.5347 - H1j(1/K Μ (.))min 0.0014 0.0009 1.5626 0.1181 0.0005 (0.0003)

Diagnostic statistics McFadden R-squared 0.0519 LR Statistic 3.2121 Log-likelihood -29.3072 LR Statistic p-value 0.0731 Table 4. The binary Probit estimation results and diagnostic Statistics.

Variable Coefficient Std. error z-Statistic p-value Marginal effect (Std. error) Constant -0.0685 0.2510 -0.2729 0.7849 - H2j(1/K Μ (.))min 0.0024 0.0020 1.1862 0.2355 0.0009 (0.0007)

Diagnostic statistics McFadden R-squared 0.0299 LR Statistic 1.8501 Log-likelihood -29.9882 LR Statistic p-value 0.1738

Page 32: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

32

Does Inflation Targeting matter? continued

• What is revealed from the estimation results (Tables 3,4 and 5) no matter which Statistic is used as regressor, is that IT countries do not receive significantly higher values for the Statistics used to test the change in persistence.

• The above conclusion is justified upon the fact that all the coefficients remain statistically insignificant even at the 0.1 significance level.

Table 5. The binary Probit estimation results and diagnostic Statistics. Variable Coefficient Std. error z-Statistic p-value Marginal effect (Std. error)

Constant -0.14902 0.2580 -0.5774 0.5636 - H3j(1/K Μ (.))min 0.0027 0.0018 1.4795 0.1390 0.0011 (0.0006)

Diagnostic statistics McFadden R-squared 0.0566 LR Statistic 3.5020 Log-likelihood -29.1622 LR Statistic p-value 0.0613

Page 33: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

• Other Considerations:

1.CBI

2.Institutions

3.Endogeneity

33

Page 34: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

34

Conclusions

• We provide econometric evidence that the IT regime has no significant effect upon the change in persistence of the annualized inflation series from I(1) to I(0).

• The reported results should be interpreted with caution

• Many non-targeting countries in our sample, implement policies close to those of the IT countries.

• Our results imply that central banks deeds matter more than their publicly announced intentions.

Page 35: Does Inflation Targeting matter?

Conclusions

• Forder (1998) point out that : “ The test might appear toshow a statistical regularity, say between the content of the statutes of a central bank and the rate of inflation, but in the absence of a theoretical connection thatwould be of no interest. We might note that the European German-speaking countries (Germany, Switzerland, and Austria) have low inflation. This doesnot mean that if we all started speaking German, inflation would fall ”.

35