43
Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER Shuang Zhang University of Colorado Boulder This version: March 8, 2016 Preliminary draft – PLEASE DO NOT CITE OR CIRCULATE Abstract This paper provides among the first revealed preference estimate of willingness to pay (WTP) for clean air in developing countries. We use product-by-store level transaction data on air purifier sales in Chinese cities and city-level air pollution data. Our empirical strategy leverages the Huai River heating policy, which created discontinuous quasi-experimental variation in air pollution between the north and south of the river. Using a spatial regression discontinuity design, we estimate the marginal willingness to pay for removing 1 ug/m 3 PM 10 . Our findings provide important policy implications for optimal environmental regulation. Ito: Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago, and NBER (e-mail: [email protected]). Zhang: De- partment of Economics, University of Colorado Boulder (e-mail: [email protected]). For helpful comments, we thank Douglas Almond, Richard Freeman, Rema Hanna, Shanjun Li, Matt Neidell, and seminar participants at Harvard, MIT, Cornell and Colorado Boulder.

Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Willingness to Pay for Clean Air:

Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China

Koichiro Ito

University of Chicago and NBER

Shuang Zhang

University of Colorado Boulder

This version: March 8, 2016

Preliminary draft – PLEASE DO NOT CITE OR CIRCULATE

Abstract

This paper provides among the first revealed preference estimate of willingness to pay (WTP)

for clean air in developing countries. We use product-by-store level transaction data on air

purifier sales in Chinese cities and city-level air pollution data. Our empirical strategy leverages

the Huai River heating policy, which created discontinuous quasi-experimental variation in air

pollution between the north and south of the river. Using a spatial regression discontinuity

design, we estimate the marginal willingness to pay for removing 1 ug/m3 PM10. Our findings

provide important policy implications for optimal environmental regulation.

⇤Ito: Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago, and NBER (e-mail: [email protected]). Zhang: De-partment of Economics, University of Colorado Boulder (e-mail: [email protected]). For helpful comments,we thank Douglas Almond, Richard Freeman, Rema Hanna, Shanjun Li, Matt Neidell, and seminar participants atHarvard, MIT, Cornell and Colorado Boulder.

Page 2: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

1 Introduction

Air quality is remarkably worse in developing countries, and severe air pollution causes substantial

health and economic burdens for billions of people. For example, the annual average exposure to

fine particle pollution (PM2.5) in China is six times higher than that in the United States in 2010.1

Such high levels of air pollution cause large negative impacts on a variety of economic outcomes,

including infant mortality (Jayachandran, 2009; Arceo et al., 2012; Greenstone and Hanna, 2014),

life expectancy (Chen et al., 2013) and labor supply (Hanna and Oliva, 2015). Therefore, air

pollution is one of the first-order problems for economic development for many countries.

However, high health and economic burdens of air pollution do not necessarily imply that

existing environmental regulations are not optimal. The optimal environmental regulation depends

on the extent to which individuals value air quality improvements—that is, willingness to pay

(WTP) for clean air (Greenstone and Jack, 2013). If WTP for clean air is low, the current level

of air pollution can be optimal because the social planner would prioritize economic growth over

environmental regulation. On the other hand, if WTP is high, the current stringency of regulation

can be away from the optimum. Therefore, WTP for clean air is a key parameter for economists and

policymakers when considering tradeo↵s between economics growth and environmental regulation.

Despite the importance of this question, the economics literature provides limited empirical evidence

because obtaining a revealed preference estimate of WTP for clean air is particularly hard in

developing countries due to the limited availability of comprehensive data.

In this paper, we provide among the first revealed preference estimates of WTP for clean air in

developing countries. Our idea is that demand for home-use air purifiers, a main defensive invest-

ment for reducing indoor air pollution, provides valuable information for estimating a lower bound

of WTP for air quality improvements. We begin by developing a random utility model in which

consumers purchase air purifiers to reduce indoor air pollution. A key advantage of analyzing air

purifier markets is that one of the product attributes informs consumers and econometricians about

the purifier’s ability to reduce air pollution. We apply this framework to unique transaction data in

air purifier markets in 81 Chinese cities. For each retail store in the 81 cities, we observe product-

level information on monthly sales, monthly average price, and detailed product characteristics.

1http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/EN.ATM.PM25.MC.M3/countries?display=default

1

Page 3: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Our data cover January 2006 through December 2012.

Our empirical strategy is a spatial regression discontinuity (RD) design, which exploits discon-

tinuous valuation in air pollution created by a policy experiment at the Huai River boundary. The

so-called Huai River policy provided city-wide coal-based heating for cities north to the river, which

generated higher pollution levels in the north (Almond et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2013). The attrac-

tiveness of this spatial RD approach is twofolds. First, it allows us to exploit plausibly exogenous

variation in air pollution created by the policy. Second, the discontinuous di↵erence in air pollution

created by the policy has existed for a long time since the 1950s, which is particularly useful for

studying the demand for durable goods like air purifiers.

Furthermore, we use a measure of transportation costs as a supply shifter as an instrument for

price. For each product, we measure the distance from the city it sells to its manufacturing plant

if it is domestically produced, or to the port if it is imported.

We present visual and statistical evidence that, in winter months, 1) the PM10 level is signifi-

cantly higher in the north of the Huai River, and 2) there is a discontinuous and substantial increase

in the market share of air purifiers that remove particular matters just north to the river. Using

estimates from the RD design, we find that the local average of MWTP for removing 1 ug/m3 of

PM10 is 2 dollars. Our RD estimates are robust to using di↵erent functional forms of latitude and

di↵erent bandwidths from the river line.

Our study provides two primary contributions to the literature. The first contribution is that

we develop a framework to estimate WTP for improvements in environmental quality by estimating

demand for defensive investment. Earlier studies on avoidance behavior against pollution examine

whether individuals take avoidance behavior in response to pollution exposure.2 A key question

in recent studies is whether researchers can estimate WTP for improvements in environmental

quality from observing defensive investment in markets. To our knowledge, two recent papers ask

this question. Kremer et al. (2011) uses a randomized control trial (RCT) for water pollution in

Kenya. Our approach, a quasi-experimental experiment with non-experimental data, is closer to

the approach by Deschenes et al. (2012), in which they use medical expenditure data in the United

Sates at the individual level. There is no doubt that RCT would be the ideal empirical strategy

2For evidence in the United States, see Neidell (2009); Zivin and Neidell (2009); Zivin et al. (2011). For evidencein China, see Mu and Zhang (2014); Zheng et al. (2015). For evidence in other developing countries, see Madajewiczet al. (2007); Jalan and Somanathan (2008).

2

Page 4: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

to answer the question. However, a large-scale RCT on pollution is not always feasible in many

countries. Therefore, quasi-experimental approaches are also important complements to address

this question. We believe that our quasi-experimental framework can be useful for other contexts

because our method relies on market-level sales and price data, which are more likely to exist in

most countries because manufacturers and retail stores usually collect scanner data on product

sales and price.3

The second contribution is that our analysis provides empirical evidence for an important“miss-

ing piece” in the literature on air pollution in developing countries, which o↵ers important policy

implications. Many recent studies show that severe air pollution in developing counties cause large

negative impacts on a variety of economic outcomes, including infant mortality (Jayachandran,

2009; Arceo et al., 2012; Greenstone and Hanna, 2014), life expectancy (Chen et al., 2013) and

labor supply (Hanna and Oliva, 2015). However, as emphasized by Greenstone and Jack (2013),

there is little evidence on revealed preference estimates of WTP for clean air. Our estimates provide

a lower bound of MWTP for improvements in air quality, which is a key parameter for policymakers

when considering tradeo↵s between economic growth and environmental regulation. Specifically, in

theory, more stringent environmental regulations can be justified if the marginal cost of regulation

is below our MWTP estimate.

2 Air pollution, Air Purifiers and the Huai River Policy in China

2.1 The main pollutant in Chinese cities

Northern and eastern China has perhaps the most polluted cities in the world according to NASA’s

global map on PM2.5 (particulate matter with diameter of 2.5 micrometers or less).4 Among

ambient pollution measures, PM2.5 has shown most consistently an adverse e↵ect on human health

(Dockery et al. (1993), Pope et al. (2009) and Correia et al. (2013)).

The main pollutant in Chinese cities is particulate matter. The Chinese Ministry of Environ-

3There are a few more related studies. Berry et al. (2012); Miller and Mobarak (2013) use randomized controlledtrials to estimate WTP for water filters and cook stoves per se instead of WTP for improvements in environmentalquality. Consumer behavior in housing markets is usually not considered to be “avoidance behavior”, but Chay andGreenstone (2005) is related to our study in the sense that they provide a quasi-experimental approach to estimateWTP for clean air.

4http://www.nasa.gov/topics/earth/features/health-sapping.html

3

Page 5: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

mental Protection (MEP) releases an daily air pollution index (API) in 120 cities since 2000. In

each city, a number of monitors take hourly concentration measures of three air pollutants: PM10

(particulate matter with diameter of 10 micrometers or less), SO2 and NO2. Daily API is converted

from one of these pollutants that has the highest daily average value. During 2006-2012, among

the 78% of days when the MEP reported the specific type of pollutant from which API was taken

from, 91.2% were from PM10, 8.7% from SO2 and 0.1% from NO2.

The o�cial API, mostly based on ambient PM10, is the only accessible pollution information for

Chinese citizens during the time period of this study.5 Both daily API level and the main pollutant

type are reported to local residents by city weather channel, radio and newspapers.

2.2 Air purifiers

Among already known air purification technologies, the High E�ciency Particulate Arrestance

(HEPA) filter is most e↵ective against particulate matter. According to the US Department of

Energy, a HEPA filter must remove (from the air that passes through) at least 99.97% of particles

in 0.3 micrometer in diameter (DOE (2005)). It is more e↵ective for particles which are larger, for

example, PM10 and PM2.5. Recent clinical studies find that the uses of HEPA purifiers in various

settings are associated with improvements in health, including reduced asthma visits and asthma

symptoms among children, lower levels of markers for inflammation and heart disease and reduced

incidences of invasive aspergillosis among adults (Abdul Salam et al. (2010); Allen et al. (2011);

Lanphear et al. (2011)).

On the Chinese market, other Non-HEPA purification technologies are designed for removing

other target pollutants, not particulate matter. Activated carbon absorbs volatile organic com-

pounds (VOCs), but it does not remove particles. A catalytic converter is e↵ective in removing

VOCs and formaldehyde. An air ionizer generates electrically charged air or gas ions, which attach

to airborne particles that are then attracted to a charged collector plate. However, there are no

specific standards for air ionizers, and they also produce ozone and other oxidants as by-products.

A study by Health Canada finds that residential ionizer only removes 4% of indoor PM2.5 (Wallace,

2008).

5The Chinese government started to report PM2.5 in 2014. We focus on 2006-2012 because of the availability andrepresentativeness of our air purifier data in this time period.

4

Page 6: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

An air purifier can use multiple air purification technologies, which must pass quality testing

by a certified testing center before entering the market. Air purifier companies are required to

make their product testing results available. We compiled testing certificates for most products

in our sample from company websites. Air purifiers with a HEPA filter report testing results on

the percentage of indoor PM2.5 it removes, and Non-HEPA air purifiers that use activated carbon

report testing results on the e↵ectiveness in removing VOCs. Testings on PM2.5 are not conducted

if a product does not have a HEPA filter. Air purifiers that combine a HEPA filter with activated

carbon to remove both particulate matter and VOC report testing results on both.

Market advertisements of air purifiers with a HEPA filter typically state that they can remove

more than 99% of PM2.5.

2.3 The Huai River policy and its recent reform

China has adopted the Soviet-era centralized heating system since 1958. Due to budget constraint,

the Chinese government decided to provide city-wide centralized heating to cities in North China

only (Almond et al. (2009)). North and South China are divided by the line formed by the Huai

River and Qinling Mountains. This line was used to divide the country for heating policy because

the average January temperature is roughly 0° Celsius along the line, and it is not a border used

for administrative purposes (Chen et al. (2013)). Cities north to the line have received unlimited

heating in winter every year. In contrast, cities south to the line have been denied centralized

heating supply from the government. The heating policy is therefore called the Huai River policy.

The heating supply to the north has been considered a public welfare entitlement, and it remains

the same today.

The centralized heating supply in the north relies on coal-fired heating systems. Two-thirds

of heat is generated by heat-only hot water boilers for one or several buildings in an apartment

complex, and the other one-thid combined heat and power generators for larger areas of a city. This

system is inflexible and energy ine�cient. Consumers have no means to control their heat supply,

and there is no measurement of heat consumption in apartments or even at the building level. The

incomplete combustion of coal in the heat generation process leads to the release of air pollutants,

especially particulate matter. Because most of heat is generated by boilers within an apartment

complex, the pollution from coal-based heating largely remains local. Almond et al. (2009) finds

5

Page 7: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

that the Huai River policy led to higher total suspended particulates (TSP) levels in the north.

Chen et al. (2013) further finds that the higher pollution levels created by the policy led to a loss

of 5.5 years of life expectancies in the north.

The heating supply to the north has been consistent since the 1950s, while the payment system

under the policy had an important change in 2003. Prior to 2003, free heating was provided for

residents in the north, and employers or local governments were responsible to pay for household

heat bills (WorldBank (2005)). It was designed under the centrally planned economy, in which

public sector employment dominated the labor market. However, during China’s transition to a

market economy, heat billing became a practical problem. The size of private sector has increased

dramatically since the 1990s, and employers in private sector were not regulated to pay heat bills

for their employees. Further, many public sector employees have moved out of public housing and

purchased home in the private market, which made it di�cult for employers to pay their heat bills

in private homes.

In July 2003, the Chinese government issued a heat reform in northern cities.6 The reform

changed the payment system from free provision to consumer-based billing (WorldBank (2005)).

Individual households became responsible for paying their own heat bills each season, which is a

flat rate per square meter of floor area (without changes in the metering method).7 Whether heat

subsidy is provided by employers depends on the sector. In public sector, former in-kind transfer

were changed to a transparent payment for heat added to the wage. In contrast, private sector

employers were not explicitly required to provide heat subsidy to their employees. In the 2005 mini

census, 21% of labor force was in urban public sector in the 81 cities in our sample, suggesting

that only a small percentage of employees get heat subsidy after the reform. Anecdotally, from an

online survey on heat bills among more than 800 individuals in Qingdao (a northern city) in 2012,

78% do not receive any heat subsidy, 12% think that the amount of heat subsidy is very small, and

only 10% think that they get a reasonable subsidy for heat.8

6http://news.xinhuanet.com/zhengfu/2003-07/29/content_998737.htm

7The Chinese government has also been interested in introducing heat metering and consumption-based billingto improve the e�ciency of heat utilization. To learn more about the progress of the reform, we recently had aconversation with the energy team of the World Bank about their collaboration with the Chinese government onthe reform. According to their experiences in China, it has been di�cult to switch to energy-saving constructiontechnologies on a large scale. Little substantial progress along this dimension has been made so far. Thus, theconsumer-based billing at a flat rate is not equivalent to consumption-based billing.

8http://news.bandao.cn/news_html/201212/20121224/news_20121224_2048038.shtml

6

Page 8: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Our analysis focuses on 2006-2012, after the 2003 reform. We summarize our comparison on

winter heating between the north and the south since the reform. First, the way winter heating has

been provided remains the same after the reform. The centralized city-wide heating supply in the

north remains the same, where households have little option other than the coal-based heating that

generates higher pollution levels. In the south, households choose their own ways to stay warm in

winter, including using air conditioners, space heaters, heated blankets, and etc. Second, heating

cost in the north has changed since the 2003 reform. Northern households no longer enjoy free

heating and instead have to pay a substantial proportion of their heat bills from the centralized

heating, while households in the south remain to pay for heating methods of their choice. According

to our comprehensive search of heating costs in 20 cities within 3 degrees of latitude relative to the

Huai River boundary, household heating costs in the north are comparable to, or could even be

higher than, those in the south.9

3 Data and Descriptive Statistics

We compile comprehensive data from several sources. Our dataset is unique because it integrates air

pollution data with detailed market transaction data at the product-city-year-month level, which

are usually hard to obtain in developing countries.

Air purifier data

We obtain monthly market transaction data of air purifiers in 81 cities in 2006-2012 from a top

marketing consulting firm in China. In each city, the transaction data are collected every month

from a network of major department stores and electrical appliance stores, which take up on average

more than 80% of all in-store sales in a city. During 2006-2012, in-store sales consist of on average

over 95% of overall sales including in-store and online sales.10 The original sales and price data are

9For example, in Xi’an, a city within 1 degree of latitude north to the Huai River, the price of heating per squaremeter per winter is 3.9USD. For an apartment of 100 square meters, the household pays 390USD. The average subsidyin public sector is 177USD per employee, and the number of public employee per household is 0.32 in the 2005 minicensus. The average amount of subsidy per household is 57USD. Therefore, an average household’s out-of-pocketpayment is 333USD. In southern cities, space heater and heated blankets are the most common choices that couldcost 150-200USD including purchasing these devices and the electricity bill in winter for a similar size of home. If ahousehold choose a more expensive option, air conditioning, the electricity bill for three months in winter could bearound 240-280USD, and their entire cost depends on the price of the air conditioners that varies to a large extent.

10The marketing consulting firm provides detailed product-level data on in-store sales only. The share of onlinesales has increased dramatically since 2013, while the share of in-store sales has decreased. Data from the firm suggest

7

Page 9: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

at the product-city-store-year-month level. Because our empirical strategy using the Huai River

policy relies on cross-sectional variation, we aggregate the transaction data to the product-city level,

for example, the total number of sales of a product during 2006-2012 by city, the average price in

2006-2012 by product-city, etc. There are 395 di↵erent products of 30 brands in our sample.

A unique feature of the data is that the type of filtration system that a product uses is included.

Importantly, we observe whether a product uses a High E�ciency Particulate Arrestance (HEPA)

filter, which enables us to quantify the amount of pollution reduction that a product brings. As

discussed in Section 2.2, the HEPA filter is most e↵ective against particulate matter. Based on the

US standard for HEPA filters, air purifier advertisements in Chinese cities highlight that the HEPA

filter can remove more than 99% of PM2.5. Combining the binary measure of having a HEPA filter

with pollution levels, we measure the amount of pollution reduction as follows. Assuming that

consumers are fully informed, the amount of pollution reduction that consumers think they will get

from a HEPA purifier is equal to the PM10 level, and 0 if they get a Non-HEPA purifier.

We also observe other useful product attributes, for example, the maximum coverage area for

two-thirds of all products in our sample, which is used to estimate the MWTP per square meter.

Pollution data

The o�cial air pollution index (API) is the only accessible pollution information for Chinese citizens

during the time period of this study. We obtain daily API data for 81 cities in our sample in 2006-

2012 from Chinese Ministry of Environmental Protection (MEP). In addition to the API level, the

specific type of pollutant from which API was taken from is also disclosed to the public. During

2006-2012, among the 78% of days when the MEP reported the type of pollutant on which API was

based, 91.2% were from PM10. The conversion from the concentration of each pollutant to API

is non-linear. For days that PM10 is reported as the main pollutant, we use the o�cial formula

used by Chinese MEP to convert daily API to daily PM10. To match with the product-city level

market transaction data, we aggregate the average PM10 in winter months and non-winter months

respectively, at the city level.

We are cautious in using the API data because recent studies find evidence on underreporting

that online sales increased to 36% in 2013 and to 47% in 2014. Therefore, to use the data most representative of allsales, we focus our analysis on 2006-2012.

8

Page 10: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

of API at the margin of 100 (Chen et al. (2012), Ghanem and Zhang (2014)). The manipulation is

motivated by the blue-sky award, which defines a day with API below 100 as a blue sky day and link

the number of blue sky days in a year to the annual performance evaluation of city governments.

For our analysis using the city-level pollution measure, we are concerned about the extent to which

the manipulation a↵ects the average level of API.

To investigate potential manipulation in our sample, we perform McCrary density tests (Mc-

Crary (2008)) on daily API data for each of these 81 cities in 2006-2012. We find no statistically

significant discontinuity in the density of daily API at 100 in 75% of city-years in Figure A.2a,

while there is statistically significant discontinuity at 100 in 25% of city-years in Figure A.2b. To

examine to what extent the manipulation changes the average API in the 25% of city-years, we

use the distribution of API in the 75% non-manipulation city-years to plot a counterfactual dis-

tribution in the manipulation subsample. Figure A.2c shows the original distribution of API in

the 25% subsample, where the mean of API is 147.90. Figure A.2d shows the the counterfactual

distributions of API, where the mean of API is 147.95. The similarity of these two mean values of

API reduces the concern about the manipulation for our analysis.

Measure of transportation costs

We are concerned that the price of air purifiers is likely correlated with unobserved demand shocks,

particularly product-city level unobserved factors that generated cross-city variation within product.

We use a measure of transportation costs as a supply shifter as an instrument for price. For each

product, we geo-coded the location of its manufacturing plant if it is domestically produced, or the

location of the port if it is imported. Around 16% of products are imported. We then calculate

the distance from the city a product sells to its manufacturing plant for domestically produced

products, or to the port for imported products. We use this product-city level distance measure to

capture transportation costs and use it as the instrument for price.

Descriptive statistics

Table 1 reports summary statistics for key variables in our sample. In the air purifier data, 52%

of products have a HEPA filter. We report summary statistics for all products in column (1),

and for HEPA purifiers in column (2) and Non-HEPA purifiers in column (3). On average there

9

Page 11: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

are 463 sales per product during 2006-2012, and HEPA purifiers have more sales than Non-HEPA

purifiers. HEPA purifiers are also more expensive than Non-HEPA purifiers. On average a HEPA

purifier costs $461 USD, while a Non-HEPA purifier costs $347. Becuase a purifier could have

multiple filters, we also report the other three main filteration systems: activated carbon, ionizer

and catalytic converter. These Non-HEPA filters are mostly used by Non-HEPA purifiers. On

the additional function as a humidifier, HEPA purifiers and Non-HEPA purifiers are very similar.

HEPA purifiers have slightly larger room coverage (44 square meters) than Non-HEPA purifiers (39

square meters). Finally, HEPA and Non-HEPA purifiers have similar transportation costs in terms

of the distance to factory or port.

Turning to city-level pollution measures, the average PM10 in winter months is 119 ug/m3,

while it is 95ug/m3 in non-winter months.

Figure 1 shows the location of the 81 cities on the China map in our analysis. The line of Huai

River/Qinling Mountains divides China into its North and South. Each dot represents a city in our

sample. All cities in our sample are located east to 100 degree of longitude. The river line east to

100 degree of longitude ranges between 32.6 and 34.2 degree of latitude. In our spatial RD approach

using the Huai River policy, we define a city’s relative latitude north to the river line. Because

the river line has several di↵erent curved segments, we divide the river line to five segments. In

each segment, we measure a city’s relative latitude to the middle point of the river latitude range.

For example, Beijing locates at 39.9 degree of latitude and 116.3 degree of longitude, and the

corresponding middle point of the river latitude range is 33.4 degree. Beijing’s relative latitude

north to the river line is 6.5 (39.9-33.4) degree. Cities in our sample locate between -12.9 and 14.8

degree north to the river line.

Figure A.1 adds locations of manufacturing plants of domestically produced products and ports

of imported products on the map. Most manufacturing plants and ports are located on the east

coast.

4 A Random Utility Model for Air Purifier Demand

Our goal is to obtain a revealed preference estimate of WTP for indoor air quality improvements

by analyzing demand for air purifiers. In a standard demand model for di↵erentiated products,

10

Page 12: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

a consumer purchases an air purifier by considering utility from its product characteristics and

disutility from its price. An advantage of analyzing air purifier markets is that one of the product

characteristics called high-e�ciency particulate arrestance (HEPA) indicates the purifier’s ability

to reduce indoor particulate matter. The extent to which consumers value this characteristic, along

with the price elasticity of demand, provides useful information for their WTP for indoor air quality

improvements.

We begin with a standard random utility model similar to Berry (1994), Nevo (2001), and

Kremer et al. (2011) to model demand for air purifiers. Consider that consumer i in city c has

average ambient air pollution zc (particular matters). The consumer can purchase air purifier j at

price pcj to reduce indoor air pollution by �zcj = zc · aj . We describe purifier j’s ability to reduce

indoor particulate matters by aj 2 [0, 1]. We observe markets for c = 1, ..., C cities with i = 1, ..., Ic

consumers. In our estimation below, a market is defined as a city. The conditional indirect utility

of consumer i from purchasing air purifier j at market c is:

uijc = ��zjc + ↵pjc + ✓j + ⇠jc + ✏ijc, (1)

where �zcj is the pollution reduction, pjc is the price of product j in market c, ✓j is a utility gain

from unobserved and observed product characteristics for product j, ⇠jc is a product-city specific

demand shock, and ✏ijc is a mean-zero stochastic term. Assuming the error term ✏ijc has an extreme

value density function, the market share for product j in city c is:

sjc =exp(��zjc + ↵pjc + ✓j + ⇠jc)PJ

j0=0 exp(��zj0c + ↵pj0c + ✓j0 + ⇠j0c). (2)

For j = 1, ..., J , we observe product-level sales data in city c, from which we construct the

market share (sjc). The outside option (j = 0) is not to buy any purifier. We make a few assump-

tions to construct the market share for outside options (s0c). We define s0c following Berry (1994);

Nevo (2001). Assuming that the number of households in city c are potential buyers and that each

household purchases one or zero air purifier, s0c can be calculated by the di↵erence of the number

of households in city c and the total number of sales in city c . Then, we assume that �zc0 = 0 and

pc0 = 0. That is, the outside option is free and does not reduce indoor air pollution.11 We then con-

11This assumption could be violated if consumers can reduce indoor air pollution by purchasing some goods other

11

Page 13: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

struct the market share for outside options by ln s0c = 0� ln�P

exp(��zj0c + ↵pj0c + ✓j0 + ⇠j0c)�.

The di↵erence between log market share for product j and log market share for outside options can

be described by,

lnsjc � lns0c = ��zjc + ↵pjc + ✓j + ⇠jc, (3)

where � is the marginal utility from having one unit of pollution reductions and ↵ is the marginal

disutility from paying one more dollar for the purchase. Therefore, marginal willingness to pay

(MWTP) for one unit of indoor air pollution reductions can be obtained by ��/↵.

Notably, when we include city fixed e↵ects in our prefered estimation below, the outside option

does not matter to the estimation because the term (lns0c) will be absorbed by city fixed e↵ects.

The estimation is, therefore, una↵ected by the assumption on outside options.

We interpret that our estimate of ��/↵ provides a lower bound of MWTP for one unit of

indoor pollution reductions. Our approach assumes that indoor air pollution levels equal to ambient

pollution levels (zc). A recent engineering study shows that indoor pollution levels are lower than

outdoor pollution levels in Beijing.12 If people understand that indoor air pollution level is lower

than outdoor pollution level, our approach underestimates �. An alternative approach would be to

rely on an engineering estimate of indoor-outdoor air pollution ratio, which would produce slightly

larger values for the MWTP. However, we want to be conservative about our estimate as much as

possible, and therefore, our estimation mostly focuses on estimating the lower bound of MWTP.

An advantage of studying air purifier markets is that aj (purifier j’s ability to reduce indoor

particulate matters) is straightforward, and consumers are well informed about it. As we explained

in Section 2.2, mechanically, if a purifier has a High E�ciency Particulate Arrestance (HEPA)

filter, it reduces 99% of indoor particular matters. On the other hand, if a purifier does not have a

HEPA filter, it is not e↵ective in reducing indoor particular matters. In advertisements and product

descriptions for both types of products on the Chinese market, consumers are well informed about

the di↵erence between HEPA purifiers and non-HEPA purifiers. Therefore, we define the pollution

than air purifiers. To our knowledge, we are not aware of other major indoor devices for indoor pollution reducationin China.

12A study from Tsinghua University finds that, in Beijing, the indoor concentration of PM2.5 is 67% of the outdoorconcentration of PM2.5. See http://news.tsinghua.edu.cn/publish/news/4204/2015/20150423100046963966000/20150423100046963966000_.html

12

Page 14: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

reduction by:

�zcj = zc ·HEPAj =

8>><

>>:

zc if HEPAj = 1

0 if HEPAj = 0.

(4)

However, it could be possible that some consumers do not fully understand the di↵erence and

think that Non-HEPA purifiers could also reduce particular matters to some extent. We test this

possibility empirically by including zc in our baseline estimation below (without including city fixed

e↵ect). If consumers do not respond to the level of particular matters in purchasing Non-HEPA

purifiers, we would expect that the estimate of zc is 0. Again, in our preferred specification, zc is

absorbed by city fixed e↵ects.

Our measure of zc is PM10, which is converted from API using the o�cial formula. The estimate

��/↵ indicates the MWTP for one unit of reduction in PM10.

Furthermore, for two-thirds of air purifiers in our sample, we also observe each purifier’s max-

imum coverage of square meters. It is possible that customers value an air purifier that cov-

ers larger square meter. To test this possibility, our second approach defines �zcj by �zcj =

zct ·HEPAj ·Roomsizej . Using this definition, we estimate the MWTP for one unit of reduction

in PM10 per square meter.

5 Empirical Strategy and Results

The goal of our empirical analysis is to obtain consistent estimates of ��/↵ in equation (3), which

is MWTP for indoor air quality improvements. Our main empirical tasks include identifying both

� and ↵, both of which should not be correlated with omitted variables.

To address the first challenge, identifying �, we take advantage of a natural experiment at the

spatial border of the Huai river, which is described in section 2.3. This approach is appealing for

the following reasons. First, it allows us to exploit plausibly exogenous variation in air pollution

created by the natural experiment to estimate local average estimates of � in cities close to the

Huai River boundary. If people value air quality, our demand model in section 4 predicts that the

market shares for HEPA purifiers are higher in the north. Our RD design tests this hypothesis.

Second, the discontinuous di↵erence in air pollution created by the Huai River policy exists for

a long period of time (since the 1950s), which is particularly useful for studying the demand for

13

Page 15: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

durable goods like air purifiers.

The second concern is on identifying ↵, where the price of air purifiers is likely correlated

with unobserved demand shocks. Our first step is including product fixed e↵ects, which absorbed

product-level omitted factors. However, we are still concernd about product-city level unobserved

factors that generated cross-city variation within product. We take a further step to use a measure

of transportation costs as a supply shifter as an instrument for price. For each product, we measure

the distance from the city it sells to its manufacturing plant if it is domestically produced, or to

the port if it is imported.

Baseline specification

We start with the baseline specification, where city fixed e↵ects are not included.

Baseline reduced form:

The reduced form regression estimates a discontinuous change in the market share of air purifiers

at the border of the Huai river. The baseline reduced-form regression is,

lnsjc�lns0c = �Northc⇤HEPAj+�Northc+f(Latc)+f(Latc)⇤HEPAj+↵pjc+Xc�+Longc+✓j+✏jc

(5)

where for city c, we define a latitude north to the Huai River boundary by Latc and a dummy

variable for cities north to the Huai River by Northc = 1 {Latc � 0} . The amount of pollution

reduction using HEPA air purifiers is measured by the interaction term Northc ⇤HEPAj . f(.) is

a smooth control function for latitude. We allow the function of latitude to di↵er between HEPA

purifiers and Non-HEPA purifiers by including f(Latc) ⇤ HEPAj . The price of air purifiers is

denoted by pjc. Our coe�cients of interests are � and ↵. The identify ↵, we instrument price pjc

with the distance from a product’s selling city to its manufacturing plant or port. The WTP to

remove the amount of pollution generated by the Huai River policy is measured by ��/↵. We

are also interested in �, which captures whether household response to higher pollution levels in

purchasing Non-HEPA purifiers.

14

Page 16: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

We include product FE, ✓j , to absorb product characteristics. Furthermore, Lee and Lemieux

(2010) note that geographical discontinuity designs should be used with careful investigation of

omitted variables at the border. In our case, we are particularly concerned that the Huai river

border is long distanced, and therefore, observable and unobservable characteristics can be di↵erent

between cities in di↵erent parts of the Huai river. To address this concern, we compare observed

demographic characteristics of cities on either side of the Huai River and find little discrete changes

at the river boundary. We include these city demographics as covariates Xc. Finally, considering

that cities around the Huai river span from the west to the east, we narrow the scope of unobserved

di↵erences on either side of the river by including fixed e↵ects of longitude decile, Longc, where

Longc = 1, ..., 10.

Baseline second stage (2SLS)

For the second stage regression, we estimate two-stage least squares for,

lnsjc�lns0c = �PM10c⇤HEPAj+�PM10c+f(Latc)+f(Latc)⇤HEPAj+↵pjc+Xc�+Longc+✓j+✏jc

(6)

by using Northc as the instrument for PM10c, Northc⇤HEPAj as the instrument for PM10c⇤

HEPAj , and distance as the instrument for pjc. Therefore, � is identified by the discontinuous

cross-sectional variation in pollution between the north and the south of the Huai river. The

identification assumption is that the instrumentNorthc is uncorrelated with the error term given the

smooth control function f(Latc) and covariates. The MWTP to remove 1 unit of PM10 generated

by the Huai River policy is measured by ��/↵.

Final specification

We prefer a more restrictive specification by including city fixed e↵ects and use it in most of our

estimations below. Advantages of including city fixed e↵ects are twofolds. First, any unobserved

di↵erences in city characteristics along the Huai river are obsorbed by city fixed e↵ects. Second,

the estimation does not depend on assumptions on outside options because the term (lns0c) is also

absorbed by city fixed e↵ects. The two-stage least square is:

15

Page 17: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Second stage (2SLS) with city fixed e↵ects

lnsjc � lns0c = �PM10c ⇤HEPAj + f(Latc) ⇤HEPAj + ↵pjc + ✓j + �c + ✏jc (7)

where �c denotes city fixed e↵ects. Note that PM10c is no longer identifiable because it is

absorbed by �c. We are able to identify our coe�cients of interest, � and ↵.

Visual presentation

Because the Huai River policy provides heat in winter only, we begin by plotting the average PM10

in winter months (December-March) during 2006-2012 by a city’s latitude relative to the Huai River

boundary. Because very few cities locate in the farthest north and the farthest south, we focus on

cities located within 10 degrees of latitude to the river line.13 There are 70 cities in this range (out

of 81 cities in our sample). Figure 2a plots the average PM10 by 1.5 degree of latitude north to the

river boundary. The vertical line at 0 indicates the location of the river. Consistent with findings

on pollution in earlier studies (Almond et al. (2009), Chen et al. (2013)), in winter months, there

is a discontinuous increase in PM10 just north to the Huai River, suggesting that the coal-based

heating policy generates higher pollution levels in the north. In contrast, in Figure A.3, during

non-winter months (April-November), there is no discrete change in PM10 levels just north to the

Huai River. Therefore, we focus our analysis on winter months.

Turning to Figure 2b, it shows the market share of HEPA purifiers by 1.5 degree of latitude

north to the river line. In the south, the market share of HEPA purifiers are below 60%. A sharp

jump to over 70% appears just north to the river, and the higher market share persists in the north.

Moreover, the south and north trends are fairly smooth, suggesting that the choice of functional

form would have little impact on the estimated di↵erence of HEPA purifiers’ market share at the

river line.

These sharp increases of both PM10 and the market share of HEPA purifiers right north to the

river suggest that higher PM10 levels generated by the heating policy trigger higher demand for

HEPA purifiers.

The visual presentation also provides useful guidance in choosing the functional form of latitude

13All cities in our sample locate between -12.9 and 14.8 degree north to the river line.

16

Page 18: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

in our estimation below. We use quadratic trend in the main specification. For comparison, we also

report results using linear trend and linear trend interacted with North, as well as cubic trend.

Estimation results

First stage:

Table 2 presents results of two first stage estimations: the first stage on PM10 in Table 2a and

the first stage on price in Table 2b.

In Table 2a, column (1) includes quadratic trend of latitude and interactions of quadratic

latitude and the HEPA dummy, and product FE, and column (2) adds demographic controls, and

column (3) further controls for longitude decile FE. Note that the preferred specification controlling

for city FE is not used because North is defined at the city-level. Column (1) and (2) show similar

estimates of a 15 units increase of PM10 just north to the Huai river, which is similar to the visual

size of the change in Figure 2a. When longitude FE are included in column (3), the magnitude

becomes smaller.

Turning to the first stage on price in Table 2b, in addition to the same specifications in Table

2a, we are also able to include city FE in column (4). We find similar estimates from all four

specifications that a 1 km increase in the distance to the manufacturing plant or the port increases

price by around $0.02 dollars. All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

Reduced form and 2SLS:

In Table 3, Panel A presents the reduced form results. Consistent with Figure 2b, there is an

economically and statistically significant increase in HEPA purifiers’ market share in the north of

the river across all specifications. Interestingly, the North dummy is not statistically significant in

column (1)-(3), suggesting that households do not respond to higher pollution level in purchasing

Non-HEPA purifiers. Using estimates from our preferred specification (city FE controlled for) in

column (4), the reduced form estimate is 0.690/0.023=$30. The WTP to reduce the amount of air

pollution generated by the Huai river policy is 30 dollars.

Panel B reports 2SLS results. Estimates are robust to using di↵erent specifications. Again, we

find no evidence that households purchase Non-HEPA purifiers as response to higher PM10 levels.

17

Page 19: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Using our preferred specification in column (4), we find that the MWTP to reduce 1 unit of PM10

generated by the Huai river policy is 0.050/0.025=2 dollars.

Robustness tests

A possible concern on the preferred specification is that, high income or highly educated individuals

might prefer HEPA purifiers over Non-HEPA purifiers for non-pollution reasons, and therefore

interaction terms of income and HEPA or education and HEPA could be omitted variables. To

directly test these possibilities, in Table A.1, we include interactions of city-level GDP and the

HEPA dummy and interactions of average schooling and the HEPA dummy in all three columns.

Reduced form and 2SLS estimates are similar to our main estimates in Table 3, which reduces the

concern on di↵erential preferences on purifier types by income and education.

We also test whether our estimates in Table 3 are robust to using di↵erent functional forms of

latitude and di↵erent bandwidths from the river line. In Table 4, we use linear trend and linear

trend interacted with North in Panel A, quadratic trend in Panel B, and cubic trend in Panel

C. For Panel A and B, column (1) uses 81 cities in the full sample, column (2) 70 cities within

10 degrees to the river, column (3) 54 cities within 7 degrees, and column (4) 45 cities within 5

degrees. In narrower windows (within 7 degrees and within 5 degrees), Figure 2a and 2b do not

suggest cubic trend as appropriate. Therefore, using cubic trend in Panel C, we report estimates in

the full sample in column (1) and cities within 10 degrees in column (2). Estimates in Panel A and

B are robust to our main estimates in Table 3 that the MWTP is around 2 dollars in all windows.

In Panel C, the magnitude of the interaction of PM10 and HEPA becomes smaller. This is because

the first stage estimate on PM10 is much larger using cubic trend. In Table A.2, we report the first

stage estimates on PM10 using various functional forms and window lengths. Using cubic trend in

panel C, we find larger first stage estimates than those in Panel A and B.

Comparison of covariates and migration

A natural concern on the RD design is that if cities in the north are systematically di↵erent from

cities in the south, higher demand for HEPA purifiers could be explained by north-south di↵erences

other than the Huai River policy. Particularly, if households have higher income or education level

in cities just north to the river, these di↵erences could contribute to the observed jump in HEPA

18

Page 20: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

purifiers’ market share. Therefore, we compare observed demographics of cities on either side of

the Huai River.

In Figure A.4, we report the mean of city-level demographic measures by 1.5 degree of latitude

relative to the Huai River (in the 10-degree latitude window). Little discrete change is observed

at the Huai River boundary on GDP per capita, population, share of industrial GDP and average

years of schooling. Some decrease of GDP per capita appear just north to the river, which are

in the opposite direction to the increase in air pollution and unlikely explain the increase in the

demand for HEPA purifiers. There is an increase in the share of GDP from manufacturing in the

first dot north to the river, but the increase does not persist in the north.

In Table A.3, we formally test whether these city-level demographics are di↵erent in the north

of the river compared to the south. For each of these covariates, we report an estimate of North

controlling for quadratic trend of latitude and an estimate also adding longitude decile FE as

controls. These di↵erences are not statistically significant, only except for GDP per capita when

longitude decile FE are not controlled for. In column (3), GDP per capita is lower in the north,

consistent with the observation from Figure A.4. However, in column (4) where longitude decile FE

are included, the estimate is statistically insignificant and the magnitude becomes much smaller.

None of these estimates controlling for longitude decile FE are statistically significant, supporting

the use of longitude decile FE as controls in one of our baseline specifications. Note that in our

preferred specification, city FE absorb any city-level di↵erences.

Another possible concern is about migration for cleaner air. If some households migrated from

the north to the south for cleaner air, our estimates on WTP from demand for air purifiers do

not take into account of these households. Although we can not completely rule out migration for

air quality, we do not find it very likely in China for the following reasons. First of all, internal

migration in China is strictly constrained by the Hukou system. The hukou, obtained at one’s

city of birth, is crucial for getting local social benefits and education opportunities, which makes

migration a more costly decision than that in countries without mobility restriction. Second, we

look into migration to the south using the 2005 census micro-data. Figure A.5 presents the number

of migrants currently residing south of the river by one’s city of origin. Migrants residing in the

south are mostly from the south, and very few of them are from the north. Particularly, residents

just north to the river are not more likely to move to the south than residents just south to the

19

Page 21: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

river. Third, we find that northern migrants residing in the south are not among the richest in the

income distribution of their city of origin, and therefore the cost of migration for clean air is very

high relative to their income.

Interpretation

To interpret the higher demand for HEPA purifiers in the north as the consequence of the higher

pollution levels generated by the heating policy, one should exclude other potential confounders. We

find that observed demographics are not significantly di↵erent between the south and the north of

the Huai River. Another possible concern is that the Huai River boundary might a↵ect air quality

and the demand for HEPA purifiers in the north through other policies other than the heating

policy. For example, if the Huai River boundary is used for making economic policies, for example,

allocating heavy industries to the north which might also generate higher pollution level, we cannot

attribute higher pollution and higher market share of HEPA purifiers solely to the heating policy.

To incorporate such confounding policies, we have conducted a comprehensive search for policies

that are made di↵erently on either side of the Huai River. We fail to find other policies using the

Huai River to divide the country. This is consistent with the fact this line was used to divide the

country for heating policy because the average January temperature is roughly 0° Celsius along the

line, and it is not a border used for administrative purposes (Chen et al. (2013)).

Conceptually, one might still be concerned that the heating policy could lead to higher demand

for HEPA purifiers in the north through channels other than higher pollution levels. Particularly,

if the heating supply to the north has been a public welfare entitlement and subsidized heating

cost of northern households, while households in cities just south to the river (with similar winter

temperature) are responsible for paying their heating choice, northern households might have higher

disposable income because of the heating subsidy. If this is the case, the heating policy might

generate higher demand for HEPA purifiers through the subsidy channel instead of the pollution

channel. However, as we discussed in Section 2.3, the heat reform in 2003 changed the payment

system from free provision to consumer-based billing. Of critical importance is the change that

northern households have to pay a substantial proportion of their heat bills from the centralized

heating after 2003. From our comparison of heating costs in the north versus in the south in Section

2.3, household heating cost in the north could even be higher than that in the south. Therefore, in

20

Page 22: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

our analysis during 2006-2012, heating subsidy has minimal e↵ect on household disposable income

in the north.

A final note is on the availability of HEPA purifier products between the north and south of

the river. If HEPA purifiers are more available in the north because appliance stores supply more

of them relative to Non-HEPA purifiers, what we observe in Figure 2b might reflect the di↵erence

in supply. To test this concern, in Figure A.6, we plot the fraction of HEPA purifier products (out

of all purifier products available) by 1.5 degree of latitude relative to the Huai River. We do not

observe a discontinuous jump on the supply side just north to the river.

MWTP for 1 unit pollution reduction per square meter

We propose an alternative way to define MWTP, which is the marginal willingness-to-pay for 1

unit of indoor pollution reduction per square meter, as discussed in Section 4. Table 5 reports

the 2SLS results, where the regressors of interests are Pollution*HEPA*Room size and Price. We

focus on column (4) using our preferred specification. The MWTP for 1 unit reduction in PM10

per square meter is 0.0011/0.0271=$0.04. The average maximum coverage area in our data is 41

square meters. Therefore, the MWTP for 1 unit reduction in PM10 in an average room of 41 square

meters is $1.64, close to our main findings in Table 3.

6 Policy implications

Our estimates provide a lower bound of MWTP for improvements in air quality in China. There

are two approaches to compare our estimate to estimates in the literature. One could combine

our estimate and a pollution-health estimate to infer health valuation, under assumptions that

households are aware of the relationship between PM10 and health outcomes and more precisely

the exact functional form, and compare a value of statistical life (VSL) estimate with those in

the literature. However, we prefer not to make unverifiable assumptions. We use an alternative

approach to directly compare our WTP estimate with WTP estimates in the literature. Readers

should keep the caveat in mind that, this is not an apple-to-apple comparison because existing

studies discuss WTP for di↵erent measures of improvements in environmental quality.

Among limited design-based evidence on revealed preference in developing countries, the WTP

21

Page 23: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

for spring protection (improved water quality) is $2.96 per household in Kenya in Kremer et al.

(2011), which accounts for roughly 0.6% of annual household income.

In studies in developed countries, the magnitude of WTP for improvements in environmental

quality also varies depending on the measure of behavioral changes. On defensive expenditures,

Deschenes et al. (2012) finds that the reductions in NOx emissions decreased mean ozone con-

centrations by 6% and drug expenditures decreased by 1.9% annually. These estimates combined

with average levels of ozone and drug expenditure per capita suggest that the MWTP for one unit

reduction of ozone is $2.1 per capita per year. Using the hedonic approach, Chay and Greenstone

(2005) find that the Clean Air Act led to a decrease of TSPs by 10 ug/m3 and a rise in housing

prices by 2.5%. These estimates, combined with mean values of housing prices and TSPs, suggest

that the MWTP for one unit reduction in TSPs is $101.

We find that the lower bound of MWTP for one unit reduction in PM10 is $2 in China, suggesting

a considerable level of MWTP compared to findings above.

The estimate we provide is a key parameter for policymakers when considering tradeo↵s be-

tween economic growth and environmental regulation. China has recently declared “War Against

Pollution”,14 followed by a series of new policies. For example, $1.65 billion a year is o↵ered to

reward cities and regions that make “significant progress” in air pollution control,15 tougher fines

are enforced for polluters,16 and coal-fired power plants will be upgraded to cut pollution from

power plants by 60 percent by 2020.17 More prominently, China is going to start a national cap-

and-trade program in 2017 that will limit and put a price on greenhouse gas emissions.18 For each

environmental policy, policy-makers could compare the marginal cost to our MWTP estimate to

assess the policy. Specifically, more stringent regulations can be justified if the marginal cost of

regulation is below our MWTP estimate.

14http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/special/2014-03/05/c_133163557.htm

15http://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/14/world/asia/china-to-reward-localities-for-improving-air-quality.

html

16http://www.theguardian.com/environment/chinas-choice/2014/apr/25/china-environment-law-fines-for-pollution

17http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/03/world/asia/china-plans-to-upgrade-coal-plants.html?_r=0

18http://www.nytimes.com/2015/09/25/world/asia/xi-jinping-china-president-obama-summit.html

22

Page 24: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

7 Conclusion

Despite higher pollution levels and mortality rates from pollution, limited design-based evidence

shows very lowWTP for environmental quality in developing countries. For example, the VSL based

on WTP for environmental quality in Kenya is 10,000 times lower than that in US (Kremer et al.

(2011)). Does the low WTP for environmental quality imply that the current level of environmental

quality in developing countries is optimal? Or is WTP high, yet policy makers fail to express

the preference of citizens in policy making and implementation? These questions remain poorly

understood among economists and policy makers.

This paper provides new evidence on WTP for air quality from one of the most polluted coun-

tries in the world. Our estimates on the lower bound of WTP for improvements in air quality and

health valuation in China are substantially higher than previously understood for developing coun-

tries, which suggests that the current environmental regulations are not optimal and strengthening

environmental regulations will largely improve human welfare.

23

Page 25: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

References

Abdul Salam, Z.-H., R. B. Karlin, M. L. Ling, and K. S. Yang (2010). The impact of portablehigh-e�ciency particulate air filters on the incidence of invasive aspergillosis in a large acutetertiary-care hospital. American Journal of Infection Control 38 (4), e1–e7.

Allen, R., C. Carlsten, B. Karlen, S. Leckie, S. van Eeden, S. Vedal, I. Wong, and M. Brauer (2011).An air filter intervention study of endothelial function among healthy adults in a woodsmoke-impacted community. American Journal of Respiratory and Critical Care Medicine 183, 1222–1230.

Almond, D., Y. Chen, M. Greenstone, and H. Li (2009). Winter heating or clean air? unintendedimpacts of china’s huai river policy. The American Economic Review: Papers and Proceed-ings 99 (2), 184–190.

Arceo, E., R. Hanna, and P. Oliva (2012). Does the e↵ect of pollution on infant mortality di↵erbetween developing and developed countries? evidence from mexico city. NBER Working PaperNo. 18349.

Berry, J., G. Fischer, and R. Guiteras (2012). Eliciting and utilizing willingness to pay: evidencefrom field trials in northern ghana. Unpublished manuscript .

Berry, S. T. (1994, July). Estimating discrete-choice models of product di↵erentiation. The RANDJournal of Economics 25 (2), 242–262.

Chay, K. Y. and M. Greenstone (2005, April). Does air quality matter? evidence from the housingmarket. Journal of Political Economy 113 (2), 376–424.

Chen, Y., A. Ebenstein, M. Greenstone, and H. Li (2013). Evidence on the impact of sustainedexposure to air pollution on life expectancy from china’s huai river policy. Proceedings of theNational Academy of Sciences 110 (32), 12936–12941.

Chen, Y., G. Z. Jin, N. Kumar, and G. Shi (2012). Gaming in air pollution data? lessons fromchina. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 13 (3).

Correia, A., C. A. P. III, D. Dockery, Y. Wang, M. Ezzati, and F. Dominici (2013). The e↵ect ofair pollution control on life expectancy in the united states: An analysis of 545 us counties forthe period 2000 to 2007. Epidemiology 24 (1), 23–31.

Deschenes, O., M. Greenstone, and J. S. Shapiro (2012, July). Defensive investments and thedemand for air quality: Evidence from the NOx budget program and ozone reductions. NBERWorking Paper (ID 2109861).

Dockery, D., A. P. third, X. Xu, J. Spengler, J. Ware, M. Fay, B. Ferris, and F. Speizer (1993).An association between air pollution and mortality in six u.s. cities. New England Journal ofMedicine 329, 1753–1759.

DOE (2005). Specification for hepa filters used by doe contractors. DOE TECHNICAL STANDARDDOE-STD-3020-2005, U.S. Department of Energy, Washington, D.C.

Ghanem, D. and J. Zhang (2014). E↵ortless perfection: Do chinese cities manipulate air pollutiondata? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 68, 203–225.

24

Page 26: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Greenstone, M. and R. Hanna (2014). Environmental regulations, air and water pollution, andinfant mortality in india. American Economic Review 104 (10), 3038–3072.

Greenstone, M. and B. K. Jack (2013, September). Envirodevonomics: A research agenda for ayoung field. NBER Working Paper (19426).

Hanna, R. and P. Oliva (2015). The e↵ect of pollution on labor supply: Evidence from a naturalexperiment in mexico city. 122, 68–79.

Jalan, J. and E. Somanathan (2008). The importance of being informed: Experimental evidenceon demand for environmental quality. Journal of Development Economics 87, 14–28.

Jayachandran, S. (2009). Air quality and early-life mortality: Evidence from indonesia’s wildfires.Journal of Human Resources 44 (4), 916–954.

Kremer, M., J. Leino, E. Miguel, and A. P. Zwane (2011). Spring cleaning: Rural water impacts,valuation, and property rights institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1), 145–205.

Lanphear, B., R. Hornung, J. Khoury, K. Yolton, M. Lierl, , and A. Kalkbrenner (2011). E↵ectsof hepa air cleaners on unscheduled asthma visits and asthma symptoms for children exposed tosecondhand tobacco smoke. Pediatrics 127 (1), 93–101.

Lee, D. S. and T. Lemieux (2010). Regression discontinuity designs in economics. Journal ofEconomic Literature 48 (2), 281–355.

Madajewicz, M., A. Pfa↵, A. van Geen, J. Graziano, I. Hussein, H. Momotaj, R. Sylvi, and H. Ahsan(2007). Can information alone change behavior? response to arsenic contamination of ground-water in bangladesh. Journal of Development Economics 84, 731–754.

McCrary, J. (2008). Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: Adensity test. Journal of Econometrics 142 (2), 698–714.

Miller, G. and M. Mobarak (2013). Gender di↵erences in preferences, intra-household externalities,and low demand for improved cookstoves. NBER Working Paper No.18964.

Mu, Q. and J. Zhang (2014). Air pollution and defensive expenditures: Evidence from particulate-filtering facemasks. E3 WP-078.

Neidell, M. (2009). Information, avoidance behavior, and health. Journal of Human Re-sources 44 (2), 450–478.

Nevo, A. (2001). Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry. Econometrica 69 (2),307–342.

Pope, C. A. I., M. Ezzati, and D. Dockery (2009). Fine-particulate air pollution and life expectancyin the united states. New England Journal of Medicine 360, 376–386.

Wallace, L. (2008). E↵ectiveness of home air cleaners in reducing indoor levels of particles. Technicalreport, Health Canada.

WorldBank (2005). China - heat reform and building energy e�ciency project. Technical report,World Bank, Washington, DC.

25

Page 27: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Zheng, S., C. Sun, and M. Kahn (2015). Self-protection investment exacerbates air pollutionexposure inequality in urban china. NBER Working Paper No.21301.

Zivin, J. G. and M. Neidell (2009). Days of haze: Environmental information disclosure andintertemporal avoidance behavior. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 58,119–128.

Zivin, J. G., M. Neidell, and W. Schlenker (2011). Water quality violations and avoidance be-havior: Evidence from bottled water consumption. American Economic Review: Papers andProceedings 101 (3), 448–453.

26

Page 28: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure 1: Huai River Boundary and City Locations

Notes: The line in the middle of the map is the Huai River-Qinling boundary. Each dot represents 1 city.There are 81 cities in our sample.

27

Page 29: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure 2: Regression Discontinuity Design at the Huai River Boundary

(a) PM10 in Winter

8010

012

014

016

0PM

10

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

(b) Market Share of HEPA Purifiers in Winter

.3.4

.5.6

.7.8

.9M

arke

t sha

re o

f HEP

A pu

rifier

s

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Notes: The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. Figure 2a plotsthe average PM10 during winter (December-March) in 2006-2012 by 1.5 degree of latitude north to the HuaiRiver boundary. The vertical line at 0 indicates the location of the river. Each dot represents cities in 1.5degree of latitude and corresponds to the middle point of the range on the x-axis. For example, the dot at0.75 on the x-axis represents cities between 0 and 1.5 degree of latitude north to the river line. The y-axisindicates the average PM10 level of cities within 1.5 degree of latitude. Figure 2b shows the market share ofHEPA purifiers in winter by 1.5 degree of latitude north to the Huai River line.

28

Page 30: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table 1: Summary Statistics

Whole sample HEPA purifiers Non-HEPA purifiers

(1) (2) (3)Panel A: Air purifier data (product level)

Percentage of HEPA purifiers 0.52(0.50)

Number of sales 463.07 535.52 383.18(1214.97) (1452.07) (879.83)

Price (USD) 407.21 461.47 347.38(343.94) (356.14) (320.40)

Humidifing 0.135 0.137 0.135(0.343) (0.345) (0.343)

Room coverage (square meter) 41.84 44.11 38.67(22.87) (24.25) (20.49)

Distance to factory or port (km) 885.58 884.54 886.73(344.26) (314.26) (375.44)

Panel B: Pollution data (city level)

PM10 in Winter (ug/m3) 118.53(22.97)

PM10 in Non-winter (ug/m3) 95.41(13.56)

Panel C: City demographics data (city level)

Population (1,000) 2498.69(419.11)

GDP per capita (USD) 8353.36(3371.61)

Share of inustrial GDP 0.50(0.11)

Years of schooling 8.29(0.04)

29

Page 31: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table 2: First stage estimates on PM10 and Price

(a) First stage on PM10

PM10

(1) (2) (3)

North 14.36⇤⇤⇤ 15.40⇤⇤⇤ 7.85⇤⇤⇤

(0.76) (0.67) (0.83)Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686R2 0.43 0.55 0.75Quadratic latitude Y Y YQuadratic latitude*HEPA Y Y YModel FE Y Y YDemographic controls Y YLongitude decile FE Y

(b) First stage on Price of air purifiers

Price of Air Purifiers

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Distance to factory or port 0.020⇤⇤⇤ 0.018⇤⇤⇤ 0.020⇤⇤⇤ 0.018⇤⇤⇤

(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686 4,686R2 0.95 0.95 0.95 0.96Quadratic latitude Y Y Y YQuadratic latitude*HEPA Y Y Y YModel FE Y Y Y YDemographic controls Y YLongitude decile FE YCity FE Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. City demographic controls include population, GDP percapita, share of industrial GDP and average years of schooling from City Statistical Yearbook (2006-2012)and the 2005 Census. Standard errors in brackets are clustered at the model level. * significant at 10% level;** significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level.

30

Page 32: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table 3: Reduced form and 2SLS

Ln(market share)-Ln(outside option)

(1) (2) (3) (4)Panel A: Reduced form

North*HEPA 0.577⇤⇤ 0.573⇤⇤⇤ 0.584⇤⇤ 0.690⇤⇤⇤

(0.243) (0.206) (0.238) (0.244)

North 0.161 -0.197 -0.199(0.170) (0.149) (0.184)

Price -0.022⇤⇤⇤ -0.018⇤⇤⇤ -0.022⇤⇤⇤ -0.023⇤⇤⇤

(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686 4,686Panel B: 2SLS

PM10*HEPA 0.045⇤ 0.041⇤⇤ 0.041⇤⇤ 0.050⇤⇤⇤

(0.023) (0.017) (0.018) (0.019)

PM10 0.021 -0.013 -0.008(0.016) (0.012) (0.022)

Price -0.031⇤⇤⇤ -0.021⇤⇤⇤ -0.024⇤⇤⇤ -0.025⇤⇤⇤

(0.006) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005)Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686 4,686First-Stage F-Stat 10.27 10.51 12.59 16.35Quadratic latitude Y Y Y YQuadratic latitude*HEPA Y Y Y YModel FE Y Y Y YDemographic controls Y YLongitude decile FE YCity FE Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. Panel A presents reduced-form estimates, where priceis instrumented by distance to factory/port. Panel B presents 2SLS results, where PM10*HEPA is instru-mented with North*HEPA, PM10 is instrumented with North, and price is instrumented with distance tofactory/port. City demographic controls include population, GDP per capita, share of industrial GDP andaverage years of schooling from City Statistical Yearbook (2006-2012) and the 2005 Census. Standard er-rors in brackets are clustered at the model level. * significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level; ***significant at 1% level. Stock-Yogo weak identification test critical value for two endogenous variables (10%maximal IV size): 7.03.

31

Page 33: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table 4: Robustness

Ln(market share)-Ln(outside option)

(1) full sample (2) 10-degree (3) 7-degree (4) 5-degreePanel A: Linear and Linear*North

PM10*HEPA 0.045⇤⇤⇤ 0.050⇤⇤⇤ 0.051⇤⇤ 0.025⇤⇤⇤

(0.014) (0.019) (0.022) (0.009)

Price -0.028⇤⇤⇤ -0.025⇤⇤⇤ -0.029⇤⇤⇤ -0.014⇤⇤⇤

(0.005) (0.005) (0.008) (0.004)Observations 5,368 4,686 3,865 3,046First-Stage F-Stat 18.40 15.90 7.09 11.62Panel B: Quadratic

PM10*HEPA 0.054⇤⇤⇤ 0.050⇤⇤⇤ 0.049⇤⇤ 0.023⇤⇤⇤

(0.018) (0.019) (0.021) (0.009)

Price -0.028⇤⇤⇤ -0.025⇤⇤⇤ -0.029⇤⇤⇤ -0.014⇤⇤⇤

(0.005) (0.005) (0.008) (0.004)Observations 5,368 4,686 3,865 3,046First-Stage F-Stat 17.85 16.35 7.20 11.68Panel C: Cubic

PM10*HEPA 0.036⇤⇤ 0.025⇤⇤

(0.016) (0.013)

Price -0.027⇤⇤⇤ -0.024⇤⇤⇤

(0.005) (0.004)Observations 5,368 4,686First-Stage F-Stat 19.43 19.36Model FE Y Y Y YCity FE Y Y Y Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. All results are from 2SLS regressions. Panel A controls forlinear latitude and linear latitude*north, and their interaction terms with HEPA. Panel B controls quadraticlatitude and their interaction terms with HEPA. Panel C controls for cubic latitude and their interactionterms with HEPA. Column 1 uses the full sample. Column 2 uses cities within 10 degrees relative to theHuai river. Column 3 uses cities within 7 degrees relative to the Huai river. Column 4 uses cities within 5degrees relative to the Huai river. In all regressions, PM10*HEPA is instrumented with North*HEPA, andprice is instrumented with distance to factory/port. Standard errors in brackets are clustered at the modellevel. * significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level. Stock-Yogo weakidentification test critical value for two endogenous variables (10% maximal IV size): 7.03.

32

Page 34: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table 5: MWTP per Square Meter

Ln(market share)-Ln(outside option)

(1) (2) (3) (4)PM10*HEPA*Room size 0.0012*** 0.0009*** 0.0009*** 0.0011***

(0.0004) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0003)

PM10 0.0278 -0.0172* -0.0143(0.0213) (0.0100) (0.0208)

Price -0.0322*** -0.0182*** -0.0237*** -0.0271***(0.0099) (0.0065) (0.0067) (0.0087)

Observations 3,191 3,191 3,191 3,191Quadratic latitude Y Y Y YQuadratic latitude*HEPA Y Y Y YModel FE Y Y Y YDemographic controls Y YLongitude decile FE YCity FE Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. This table presents 2SLS results, wherePM10*HEPA*Room size is instrumented with North*HEPA*Room size, PM10 is instrumented with North,and price is instrumented with distance to factory/port. City demographic controls include population,GDP per capita, share of industrial GDP and average years of schooling from City Statistical Yearbook(2006-2012) and the 2005 Census. Standard errors in brackets are clustered at the model level. * significantat 10% level; ** significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level.

33

Page 35: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Online Appendices Not For Publication

A Additional Figures

Figure A.1: Huai River Boundary and City Locations

Notes: The line in the middle of the map is the Huai River-Qinling boundary. Each dot represents 1 city.Each triangle represents a factory location or a port location.

34

Page 36: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure A.2: API distribution

(a) McCrary density test (75% of sample)

0.05

.1.15

0 200 400 600

(b) McCrary density test (25% of sample)

0.02

.04

.06

0 200 400 600

(c) Original distributions of the 25% sample

020

040

060

080

010

00nu

mbe

r of d

ays

in 7

yea

rs

0 100 200 300 400 500API

Original

(d) Counterfactual distribution of the 25% sample

020

040

060

080

010

00nu

mbe

r of d

ays

in 7

yea

rs

0 100 200 300 400 500API

Counterfactual

35

Page 37: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure A.3: Huai River: PM10 in non-winter months (April-November)

8010

012

014

016

0PM

10

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Notes: The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. This figure plotsthe average PM10 during non-winter months (April-November) in 2006-2012 by 1.5 degree of latitude northto the Huai River boundary. The vertical line at 0 indicates the location of the river. Each dot representscities in 1.5 degree of latitude and corresponds to the middle point of the range on the x-axis. For example,the dot at 0.75 on the x-axis represents cities between 0 and 1.5 degree of latitude north to the river line.The y-axis indicates the average PM10 level of cities within 1.5 degree of latitude.

36

Page 38: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure A.4: Huai River and Demographics

040

0080

0012

000

1600

0G

DP

per c

apita

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

GDP per capita

010

0020

0030

0040

0050

00Po

pula

tion(

1000

)

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Population

.3.4

.5.6

.7Sh

are

of in

dust

rial G

DP

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Share of industrial GDP4

68

1012

1416

Year

s of

sch

oolin

g

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Years of schooling

Notes: The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. These figuresplot the mean of each demographic variable by 1.5 degree of latitude north to the Huai River boundary.The vertical line at 0 indicates the location of the river. Each dot represents cities in 1.5 degree of latitudeand corresponds to the middle point of the range on the x-axis. For example, the dot at 0.75 on the x-axisrepresents cities between 0 and 1.5 degree of latitude north to the river line. The y-axis indicates the meanlevel of each variable in cities within 1.5 degree of latitude.

37

Page 39: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure A.5: Number of migrants to South of the river by city of origin

020

0040

0060

00N

umbe

r of m

igra

nts

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Number of migrants to South by city of origin

Notes: The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. This figure plotthe number of migrations currently residing South of the Huai River by their city of origin. The verticalline at 0 indicates the location of the Huai river. Each dot represents cities in 1.5 degree of latitude andcorresponds to the middle point of the range on the x-axis. For example, the dot at 0.75 on the x-axisrepresents cities between 0 and 1.5 degree of latitude north to the river line. The y-axis indicates the meanlevel of each variable in cities within 1.5 degree of latitude.

38

Page 40: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Figure A.6: Fraction of available HEPA purifier products

.5.5

5.6

.65

Frac

tion

of a

vaila

ble

HEP

A pu

rifier

pro

duct

s

-10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Degree North to the Huai River

Notes: The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. This figure plotsthe fraction of available HEPA purifier products out of all purifier products by 1.5 degree of latitude northto the Huai River boundary. The vertical line at 0 indicates the location of the river. Each dot representscities in 1.5 degree of latitude and corresponds to the middle point of the range on the x-axis. For example,the dot at 0.75 on the x-axis represents cities between 0 and 1.5 degree of latitude north to the river line.The y-axis indicates the mean level of each variable in cities within 1.5 degree of latitude.

39

Page 41: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

B Additional Tables

Table A.1: Controlling for GDP*HEPA and Schooling*HEPA

Ln(market share)-Ln(outside option)

(1) (2) (3)Panel A: Reduced form

North*HEPA 0.527** 0.562** 0.646***(0.208) (0.239) (0.250)

North -0.169 -0.185(0.151) (0.190)

Price -0.018*** -0.022*** -0.023***(0.004) (0.004) (0.004)

Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686Panel B: 2SLS

PM10*HEPA 0.044** 0.045** 0.053**(0.019) (0.021) (0.022)

PM10 -0.016 -0.012(0.013) (0.023)

Price -0.021*** -0.024*** -0.025***(0.005) (0.004) (0.005)

Observations 4,686 4,686 4,686First-Stage F-Stat 9.99 12.32 16.01Quadratic latitude Y Y YQuadratic latitude*HEPA Y Y YModel FE Y Y YDemographic controls Y YLongitude decile FE YCity FE YGDP*HEPA and Schooling*HEPA Y Y Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. Panel A presents reduced-form estimates, where priceis instrumented by distance to factory/port. Panel B presents 2SLS results, where PM10*HEPA is instru-mented with North*HEPA, PM10 is instrumented with North, and price is instrumented with distance tofactory/port. GDP per capita*HEPA and schooling*HEPA are included in all regressions. Standard errors inbrackets are clustered at the model level. * significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level; *** significantat 1% level. Stock-Yogo weak identification test critical value for two endogenous variables (10% maximalIV size): 7.03.

40

Page 42: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table A.2: First stage (robustness)

PM10

full sample 10-degree 7-degree 5-degreePanel A: Linear and Linear*North

North 19.44*** 16.28*** 21.63*** 18.23***(0.58) (0.68) (1.02) (1.54)

Observations 5,368 4,686 3,865 3,046R2 0.63 0.55 0.48 0.47Panel B: Quadratic

North 14.30*** 15.46*** 20.45*** 18.49***(0.54) (0.66) (0.95) (1.43)

Observations 5,368 4,686 3,865 3,046R2 0.64 0.55 0.49 0.47Panel C: Cubic

North 23.09*** 33.08***(0.70) (0.93)

Observations 5,368 4,686R2 0.65 0.57Model FE Y Y Y YDemographic controls Y Y Y Y

Notes: Each observation represents a product-city. Panel A controls for linear latitude and linear lati-tude*north, and their interaction terms with HEPA. Panel B controls quadratic latitude and their interactionterms with HEPA. Panel C controls for cubic latitude and their interaction terms with HEPA. Column 1uses the full sample. Column 2 uses cities within 10 degrees relative to the Huai river. Column 3 uses citieswithin 7 degrees relative to the Huai river. Column 4 uses cities within 5 degrees relative to the Huai river.Standard errors in brackets are clustered at the model level. * significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5%level; *** significant at 1% level.

41

Page 43: Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air ... · Willingness to Pay for Clean Air: Evidence from Air Purifier Markets in China Koichiro Ito University of Chicago and NBER

Table A.3: Huai river and Demographics

Population GDP per capita Industrial GDP share Schooling(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

North -1725.701 -1837.974 -2800.805⇤⇤ 20.214 0.026 0.055 -0.089 -0.087(1170.940) (1152.711) (1396.275) (1572.412) (0.048) (0.050) (0.369) (0.401)

Observations 71 71 71 71 71 71 71 71R2 0.03 0.15 0.07 0.41 0.01 0.17 0.19 0.39Mean of Dependent Variable 2498.69 2498.69 8353.36 8353.36 0.50 0.50 8.29 8.29Quadratic latitude Y Y Y Y Y Y Y YLongitude decile FE Y Y Y Y

Notes: Each observation represents a city. The sample includes 70 cities within 10-degree latitude relative to the Huai River. Quadratic latitude isincluded in all regressions. Robust standard errors are in brackets.

42