53
The cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A novel approach for the Euro area Giovanni Carnazza (*) (*) Paolo Liberati (§) (§) Agnese Sacchi (**) Abstract This paper presents novel estimates for the cyclically- adjusted primary balance for 18 countries of the Euro area over years 1999-2017. We improve the methodology adopted by the European Commission by using quarterly rather than annual frequency data and providing accurate identification of the budgetary items whose response can be considered automatic to the economic cycle. This disaggregated outcome combined with high frequency data marks a significant improvement with respect to previous studies. The empirical analysis is implemented on two sub- periods to examine the impact of governments’ discretionary fiscal policy before and after the Great Recession. The most striking policy implication is that even though the budgetary policy of most European countries can be qualified in principle as anticyclical, this outcome has been weakened by the impact of (*)(*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: [email protected] (§) (§) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics, E-mail: [email protected] ((**) Corresponding author - Sapienza University of Rome, Department of Economics and Law, Via del Castro Laurenziano 9, 00161, Rome (Italy). E-mail: [email protected] 1

  · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

The cyclically-adjusted primary balance:

A novel approach for the Euro area

Giovanni Carnazza (*)(*)

Paolo Liberati (§) (§)

Agnese Sacchi (**)

Abstract

This paper presents novel estimates for the cyclically-adjusted primary balance for 18 countries of the Euro area over years 1999-2017. We improve the methodology adopted by the European Commission by using quarterly rather than annual frequency data and providing accurate identification of the budgetary items whose response can be considered automatic to the economic cycle. This disaggregated outcome combined with high frequency data marks a significant improvement with respect to previous studies. The empirical analysis is implemented on two sub-periods to examine the impact of governments’ discretionary fiscal policy before and after the Great Recession. The most striking policy implication is that even though the budgetary policy of most European countries can be qualified in principle as anticyclical, this outcome has been weakened by the impact of discretionary policies of many governments especially after the crisis. The results are robust to the use of different de-trending methods.

Keywords: fiscal policy, cyclically-adjusted primary balance, automatic stabilizers, economic cycle, Great Recession, de-trending methods.

JEL Classification: H30; H61; H62; E62

(*)(*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: [email protected] (§) (§) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics, E-mail: [email protected] ((**) Corresponding author - Sapienza University of Rome, Department of Economics and Law, Via del Castro Laurenziano 9, 00161, Rome (Italy). E-mail: [email protected]

1

Page 2:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

1. Introduction

The adoption of a balanced budget rule in almost all member states of the European

Union (EU) was aimed at affecting the budgetary policies with, at least, two objectives:

strengthening fiscal discipline (Hauptmeier et al., 2011); alleviating tensions in the

financial markets (Spilimbergo et al., 2009) in a context where national fiscal policies

coexist with a monetary policy moved at the supranational level.1

From a theoretical viewpoint, the new rule allows some flexibility for the policy-

makers as it defines the balanced budget in structural terms. This requires to split the

overall actual balance (OB) in two components: the cyclical balance (CB), which

isolates the action of the automatic stabilizers (Debrun and Kapoor, 2010) and whose

variations are due to factors that are mainly outside the direct control of governments;

and the cyclically-adjusted balance (CAB), which measures the impact of discretionary

fiscal policies implemented by governments. Since the CAB has to be equal to zero in

the medium term, the overall actual budget balance (OB) should only temporarily

deviate from the cyclical balance (CB).2

This new institutional setting has important consequences for the fiscal policy of the

countries of the Euro area. By limiting the use of discretionary policies to a zero-budget

balance, it implicitly confines the anticyclical function to the automatic response of the

public budget. This means that discretionary policies implemented by governments

might possibly fail to strengthen the anticyclical impact of automatic stabilizers or even

1 According to the ‘balanced budget rule’ introduced by the Fiscal Stability Treaty (FST), national budget has to be in balance (or surplus). More precisely, the structural budget balance should not exceed a country-specific Medium-Term budgetary Objective (MTO), which at most can be set at 0.5% of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) for member states with a debt-to-GDP ratio exceeding 60%, or at most 1.0% of GDP for states with debt levels below the 60% threshold. With regard to the moral hazard problem implicit in this framework, see Frankel (2015). It is worth noting that the recent fiscal tightening is part of a broader path started with the Maastricht Treaty, before the Monetary Union.2 By definition, the CAB is obtained by subtracting the CB from the OB.

2

Page 3:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

go in the opposite direction. Thus, in both cases, they might compromise the

anticyclical impulse, an information that is, in fact, crucial for policy-makers and that

has extremely important consequences on their decisions on how to spend and tax

(Blanchard, 1990; Larch and Turrini, 2010, Claeys et al., 2016).

It is worth noting, however, that the way in which policy-makers implement

discretionary fiscal policies is endogenous to the method in which the CAB is

calculated. To this regard, the empirical methodology adopted by the European

Commission (EC) has debatable characteristics, as it could lead a country to implement

a restrictive budgetary policy while experiencing a recessionary phase of the economic

cycle (Afonso and Clayes, 2008; D’Auria et al., 2010; Mourre et al., 2013; Mourre et

al., 2014;).

A crucial point of this vicious circle consists in the estimation of the non-observable

potential GDP by using a production function where the potential contribution of

labour depends on the unemployment rate consistent with the NAWRU (Non-

Accelerating Wage Rate of Unemployment). The latter, however, is estimated through

a methodology that can imply a strong variability over time and that makes the

estimated unemployment excessively dependent on the current level of unemployment

and on the wage rigidity in the short term (Gordon, 1997; Holden and Nymoen, 2002;

Schreiber and Wolters, 2007; FitzGerald, 2014). Faced with these problems, the

European Commission has recently revised the method for calculating the CAB (Havik

et al., 2014); however, this adjustment applies only to some countries of the Eurozone,

while it does not in others for which the detected critical issues remain.

Our paper tries to fill this gap by providing new estimates of the CAB that enrich the

information set and the data available for the policy-maker in order to properly assess

3

Page 4:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

the impact of discretionary fiscal policies as well as to identify the sign of the automatic

response of the public budget. In particular, this information is provided for 18

countries of the Euro area using quarterly budgetary data from 1999 to 2017. By

considering country-specific responses combined with high frequency, the paper marks

a significant improvement with respect to previous contributions aimed at analysing the

cyclical properties of the fiscal aggregates in the Euro area as a whole (see, for

example, Paredes et al., 2014). More importantly, it is in line with the good practice of

relying on infra-annual budgetary data with the aim of fiscal forecasting (Onorante et

al., 2010) and simulating fiscal policies targets in the monetary union (Brück and

Zwiener, 2006).

To this purpose, the focus of our paper is on the evolution of the cyclically-adjusted

primary balance (CAPB), i.e. excluding interest payments, over time.3 In detail, we

provide new series using an alternative empirical methodology based on Burnside and

Meshcheryakova (2005a; 2005b), which is not affected by the dependence among the

actual unemployment rate, the NAWRU and the potential GDP. The CAPB is

estimated for two non-overlapping sub-periods (1999-2007 and 2008-2017)4 in order to

capture the different fiscal attitudes of the countries of the Euro area before and after

the recent Great Recession started in 2008. Note that 2008 represents a structural break

in our analysis, as it is thought to give rise to a period of ‘secular stagnation’

(Summers, 2014) experienced by many Euro area countries (Craft, 2016). This might

involve relevant changes in the conduct of national fiscal policies, and, to this respect,

3 Interest expenditures are excluded from the analysis as they are not under the direct control of the policy-makers, and to avoid discrepancies in measuring interest payments. In doing that, we also follow the recent approach of the European Fiscal Board (2019) that uses the primary balance to evaluate the combined impact of discretionary fiscal policies and automatic stabilizers. 4 Due to lack of data, it has not been possible to estimate the CAPB for Estonia. The availability of data in some countries is reduced in relation to the first sub-period: Austria (2001-2007); Germany (2002–2007); Ireland (2002–2007); Luxembourg (2002–2007); Malta (2000–2007).

4

Page 5:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

the estimation of the CAPB will provide important information about the degree in

which discretionary policies may be affected by the institutional setting.

The most striking policy implication deriving from our estimates is that, even

though the automatic stabilizers have widely acted in an anticyclical way in almost all

countries of the Euro area, this impact has often been severely weakened by

discretionary policies by governments, especially after the Great Recession. This

outcome suggests that discretionary policies, rather than being the result of an

intentional pro-cyclical behaviour of policy-makers, can be severely constrained by the

institutional setting. Furthermore, the fact that this occurs in a great number of

countries of the Euro area also suggests that the pro-cyclical impact of discretionary

policies may be uncorrelated with the specific way in which national governments

decide to tax and spend.

It is worth noting that this outcome differs from the results obtained by previous

studies, according to which the impact of the automatic stabilizers in cushioning the

cycle is often stronger than that of the discretionary changes (Lane, 2003; Fatás and

Mihov, 2009; Egert, 2010). One possible reason of this difference is that those studies

analyze the fiscal policy stance using annual data and confine the analysis to years

immediately after the recent economic crisis, thus only partially capturing its impact.

At the same time, our results are more in line with the recent empirical evidence, based

on annual data, provided by the European Fiscal Board (2019) and Paredes et al.

(2014), concluding for a high frequency of pro-cyclical behavior of important fiscal

aggregates in EU countries.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the empirical

methodology to estimate the CAPB for countries of our sample. Section 3 discusses the

5

Page 6:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

main results and the policy implications linked thereto, while some sensitivity checks

are included in Section 4. Section 5 concludes.

2. The empirical methodology

2.1 Selecting budgetary items

The first step of the methodology consists in seasonally adjusting the budgetary data of

the 18 EU member states through the TRAMO/SEATS approach (Bee Dagum and

Bianconcini, 2016). We use a model-based approach, which conceives the series as the

finite part of the realization of a stochastic process, whose probabilistic structure is

described by an Auto Regressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA) model.5 The

second step consists in converting budgetary data in real terms by using the GDP

deflator. Finally, fiscal series have been decomposed into the trend and the cycle

components by using the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997).

This choice is aware of the criticisms that have been raised on the use of the HP

filter (e.g., Harvey and Jaeger, 1993; Cogley and Nason, 1995; Guay and St-Amant,

2005; Hamilton, 2018), but also of the fact that the main critique rests on an inadequate

definition of the distortion it may create (Pedersen, 2001).6 More recently, Sakarya and

De Jong (2019) provide an additional formal justification of the use of the HP filter

5 In detail, this seasonal adjustment procedure is a model-based approach which consists of two parts: the first part (TRAMO, Time Series Regression with Arima Noise) preliminarily eliminates the deterministic effects from the time series; it interpolates any missing observations and identifies and estimates the ARIMA model that best fits the data. The second part (SEATS, Signal Extraction in ARIMA Time Series), based on the ARIMA model and the deterministic effects previously identified, carries out the real seasonal adjustment of the historical series. In this context, the identification of the so-called deterministic calendar effects carried out in TRAMO plays an important role, as the identification of the ARIMA model requires the historical series to be purely stochastic. Subsequently, these effects are attributed by SEATS to the seasonal component.6 While showing that the optimal value of the smoothing parameter of the HP filter, λ, lies in the range 1,000-1,050 for quarterly data, the difference in the distortionary effect when using λ =1,600, for which Hodrick and Prescott (1997) provide a theoretical background, is weak and the difference in computed business cycle stylized facts is small. For details about the procedure for adjusting the smoothing parameter for the data frequency, see Ravn and Uhlig (2002) and De Jong and Sakarya (2016).

6

Page 7:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

when the time series have not an exponential path, as in our case, and Drehmann and

Yetman (2018) underline that any filter lacks a clear theoretical foundation, thus

holding the HP filtered trend as preferred.7

With available quarterly data, the HP decomposition consists in choosing the values

y t¿ of a given variable at time t that minimize the following quadratic loss objective

function:

∑t=1

T

( y t− y t¿)2+λ∑

t=2

T −1

[ ( y t+1¿ − y t

¿ )−( y t¿− y t−1

¿ ) ]2 (1)

This minimization problem leaves a degree of freedom in relation to the choice of the

parameter λ. To this regard, the HP filter establishes a trade-off between the adherence

of the trend to the historical series and the regularity of the trend itself. In particular, by

setting λ=0, the trend that minimizes the previous function collapses to the original

series (y t= y t¿); if λ →+∞, the trend tends to a linear form.8 In our case, the HP filter

has been applied with a smoothing parameter λ equal to 1,600.

The methodology used in this paper to estimate the CAPB includes at least two

potential advantages for the policy-makers. The former concerns the use of quarterly

budgetary data. In detail, the availability of intra-annual fiscal information allows, for

instance, to acknowledge fiscal slippages early enough, and implement corrective

measures (Onorante et al., 2010). Moreover, providing high frequency budgetary data

to the policy-makers allow them to rely on information actually available at the time

7 In any case, we provide further discussion on alternative filters, also providing some robustness checks, in Section 4.8 Hodrick and Prescott (1997) show how their results do not significantly depend on the value of the smoothing parameter, λ, unless this value tends to infinity. Robustness checks with different values of the smoothing parameter are provided in Section 4.

7

Page 8:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

budgetary decisions were taken and not on the basis of the latest available (ex post) data

(Golinelli and Momigliano, 2006). Finally, employing those short-term fiscal indicators

could be relevant not only at a national level but also at the European level for fiscal

surveillance and forecasting issues.

The second advantage refers to the accurate identification of the budgetary items

whose response can be considered automatic with respect to the fluctuations of the

economic cycle is needed (Burnside and Meshcheryakova, 2005a; 2005b).9 This

identification could be affected by the shortcoming that even though it is known that

there are items in the public budget that are mostly affected by automatic responses, the

possibility that their movements are at least partially determined by discretionary

changes cannot be excluded. Thus, the choice to label a budgetary item as ‘automatic’

has been made when it can be safely assumed that the discretionary component may

represent only a small part of the overall trend. To this purpose, two different types of

information have been considered: the first is based on a qualitative examination of the

economic nature of such series; the second concerns the quantitative characteristics of

the historical budgetary series.

From a qualitative perspective, some budgetary items have not been classified as

automatic when it is known that they have been targeted by discretionary policies, even

though their cyclical component may have shown a significant correlation with the

economic cycle. This is the usual case, for instance, of capital taxes, capital transfers

and investments, whose trend is mainly due to discretionary policies of the policy-

makers.10

9 For example, on the expenditure side, some welfare programs, such as the unemployment benefits, automatically activate in response to negative fluctuations of the economic cycle showing a natural anticyclical response.10 It is worth noting that when one uses the CAB as an index of discretionary changes in fiscal policy, there is no adjustment for the one-off measures, as those measures are not related with the business cycle

8

Page 9:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

From a quantitative point of view, instead, equation (1) has been applied to all items

of the public budget and to GDP in order to separate trend and cycle.11 This is done by

applying the HP filter to a generic item Y t, where the subscript t indicates quarterly

frequency, to obtain Y t=Y tc+Y t

¿, where Y tc is the cyclical component and Y t

¿ is the trend

component. Then, the cyclical component Y tc of each budgetary item has been

correlated with the cyclical component of GDP (i.e. the economic cycle). The aim is to

select only those budgetary items showing statistically significant correlations under

the assumption that, if the correlation is statistically significant, the cyclical movements

of each item are mostly due to the automatic response.12 Overall, this thorough

approach is not valuable per se but, as explained later, to the extent to which it provides

to the policy-makers specific information on which budgetary items are de facto, and

not only de jure, more reactive to GDP fluctuations and over different periods.

The outcome of this selection process is reported in Table 1, providing information

for each country in both sub-periods (1999-2007 and 2008-2017).

[Table 1 about here]

It is worth noting that for the cyclical component of direct and indirect taxes the

statistically significant correlation with the economic cycle occurs more frequently,

followed by social benefits on the expenditure side. Furthermore, as expected, current

budgetary variables are more correlated with the cycle than non-recurrent budgetary

but they depend on a discretionary intervention (Burnside and Meshcheryakova, 2005a; 2005b). The rationale of this choice relies on the seminal paper by Blanchard (1990), which describes the right uses and the potential abuses of the CAB.11 Results are not reported but they are available upon request.12 In order to be taken into consideration for the calculation of the CAPB, the elasticities of each selected budgetary item have also to be statistically significant.

9

Page 10:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

items, since both capital taxes and expenditures are usually not induced by the

economic cycle.

From a policy point of view, this preliminary analysis offers an interesting

perspective, highlighting the different reactions of the national public budget

components to the business cycle over time, distinguishing two different sub-periods.

Indeed, Table 1 reveals that the statistical significance of automatic responses is more

pronounced in the second sub-period, which includes the Great Recession. This aspect,

to some extent expected, is particularly evident on the revenue side, with regard to

indirect taxes and net social contributions, and, on the expenditure side, with regard to

intermediate consumption and social benefits. Considering the effect of the automatic

stabilizers, national fiscal policies seem to have worked in an anticyclical way. On the

contrary, capital expenditures, which are part of the discretionary item of the budget,

have showed a more frequent correlation with the business cycle in the first sub-period,

while discretionary capital expenditures policies have been characterized by an almost

total lack of connection with the economic cycle in the second sub-period.

2.2 Calculating the CAPB

Since Table 1 shows some heterogeneity of the correlation between single budgetary

items and the economic cycle in our sample, a country-specific approach is adopted to

calculate the CAPB in order to take into account those different reactions.

To this purpose, for each selected budgetary item and for each country – as resulting

from Table 1 – we have first calculated the elasticity of their cyclical components with

respect to the cyclical component of GDP by using the OLS technique (after

transforming the selected series in logarithms) as follows:

10

Page 11:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

ykjtc =θkj gkt

c +ε kjt (2)

where ykjtc represents (the logarithm of) the cyclical component of the budgetary item j

of country k; gktc is (the logarithm of) the cyclical component of GDP for country k; θkj

is the country-specific elasticity of the budgetary item j, to which we are interested in,

and ε kjt is the error term.

Then, the estimated elasticities (θ̂kj) from equation (2) are used to calculate the

CAPB by clearing the actual public revenues and expenditures of the corresponding

cyclical components. In symbols:

CAPBkt= {Rkt−X kt }⏟Actual primary balance

−¿¿ (3)

where Rkt represents actual total revenues in country k , X kt stands for actual total

expenditures (excluding interest on public debt), Rkjt and X kjt are, respectively, single

revenue and expenditure items for which elasticities have been estimated according to

equation (2). It is worth recalling that these items are, by definition, those whose

reaction is mostly automatic, and for which the elasticities should capture the size of

these automatic responses that are removed from the actual figures to calculate the

CAPB.

The interpretation of equation (3) is straightforward: if the cyclical component of

GDP would be zero, then gktc =0, and ykjt

c =0, which implies exp (−θ̂kj gkjtc )=1, and no

11

Page 12:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

cyclical adjustment would be needed. When gktc >0 and θ̂kj>0 , the adjustment would be

negative. The intuition is that during a positive stage of the economic cycle, some items

of the public budget rise automatically (e.g., income taxes and VAT) because the

economy is growing. This means that, without the positive cycle, that specific item

would have not risen in the same way; thus, to neutralise the impact of the cycle, the

adjustment has to be negative. The opposite holds in the case of a negative phase of the

economic cycle. Furthermore, a specular reasoning can be made for those items for

which θ̂kj<0when gktc >0 such as, for example, the unemployment benefits and other

social transfers.

3. Main results and policy implications

3.1 Correlations between the cyclical components of the primary balance and the

economic cycle

Figures 1 and 2 provide a visual impact of the correlation between the cyclical

component of the primary balance (the continuous line), i.e. the automatic stabilizers,

and the cyclical component of GDP (the dotted line), i.e. the economic cycle, before

and after the crisis respectively, both expressed as a percentage of the HP trend of the

real GDP. In each figure, the comparison between the two lines identifies the impact of

the automatic stabilizers. If the automatic stabilizers work, it is expected that when the

cyclical component of GDP lies in the negative quadrant, the cyclical component of the

primary balance lies in the positive one.13

13 In order to visualize the countercyclical action of the automatic stabilizers, the continuous line, which represents the cyclical component of the primary balance, is expressed by the difference between the CAPB and the actual primary balance. In this case, a positive value of the cyclical component implies a net expenditure, while a negative value a net revenue. Put differently, the continuous line can also be interpreted as the correction that has to be applied to the actual primary balance to get the CAPB. For example, in Figure 2 for Austria 2008_Q1 the value is about –2 percent, which means that the actual primary balance is higher than the CAPB due to the impact of automatic stabilizers amounting to about 2

12

Page 13:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

With regard to the period after the crisis, i.e. 2008-2017 (Figure 2), this effect is

more evident in 11 of 18 countries of our sample: Austria, Belgium, Finland, France,

Germany, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Slovakia and Slovenia. In the

remaining countries, the impact of the automatic stabilizers is either weaker or absent

(as in Cyprus, Ireland, Luxembourg, Portugal, and Spain). The comparison with the

pre-crisis period in Figure 1 confirms these characteristics with some interesting

exceptions: Austria and Italia exhibit a weaker impact of the automatic stabilizers,

while Cyprus, Portugal, and Spain reveal a more anticyclical path.

Thus, even though at a different degree, there is the general impression that

automatic stabilizers work in almost all countries in the period considered. From a

policy point of view, the interesting question now arises about whether and in which

country this anticyclical impact is either reinforced or mitigated by discretionary fiscal

policies.

[Figures 1 & 2 about here]

3.2 The fiscal policy stance

In order to investigate the relationship between the impact of the automatic stabilizers

and that of discretionary fiscal policies, Table 2 reports the correlations of both the

actual primary balance and the CAPB with the economic cycle by each country and for

each sub-period. In general, a positive correlation means that the primary balance

percentage points of the HP trend of the real GDP. The opposite holds when the continuous line lies in the positive quadrant. In this case, the automatic stabilizers have worsened the actual primary balance, which is thus lower than the CAPB.

13

Page 14:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

improves during the expansionary phase of the cycle and worsens during recessions.

This features the traditional function of an anticyclical budgetary policy, with an

important caveat: the actual primary balance contains both automatic and discretionary

fiscal policies, whereas the CAPB isolates the impact of discretionary policies only.

[Table 2 about here]

Table 2 reports two important policy outcomes of the analysis. The first is that the

actual primary balance shows some anticyclical power in most countries. In particular,

there are countries in which the anticyclical impact holds in both sub-periods (Austria,

Finland, France, Germany, Luxembourg, the Netherlands); and countries in which this

impact is less stable (Belgium, Cyprus, Italy, Lithuania, Slovakia, and Spain), together

with countries for which the impact is neutral (Ireland, Malta, Portugal, and Slovenia).14

However, the second even more important result from a policy perspective is that

most of the countries, where an anticyclical impact of the actual primary balance has

been found, fail to implement anticyclical discretionary policies. This is evident not

only in the first sub-period, where discretionary fiscal policies have an anticyclical

impact only in Austria, Finland, and Luxembourg, but also – and more surprisingly –

during and after the Great Recession, where a robust statistically significant anticyclical

impact is found only in Greece. If one combines this outcome with the fact that in the

second sub-period the anticyclical impact of the actual primary balance is more

widespread across countries, it can be concluded that discretionary budgetary policies

14 It is worth noting that Greece and Latvia, in the first sub-period, shows a pro-cyclical impact of the actual primary budget balance.

14

Page 15:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

in many countries have worked in the opposite direction to the automatic stabilizers,

thus weakening their impact.

In a nutshell, the sign of discretionary fiscal policies in those countries suggests that

the bulk of the economic stabilization is now provided by the automatic stabilizers,

leaving the discretionary side of the policies to obey the institutional rule of balancing

the structural budget, regardless of the stage of the economic cycle. The great number

of countries for which this occurs also marks a fundamental outcome according to

which the impact of discretionary fiscal policies seems rather independent of the

specific tax and spending provisions implemented in different countries. This policy

conclusion is reinforced by the observations that our result also holds for countries with

very different fiscal positions in terms of debt-to-GDP ratios.15 Thus, if the aim would

be to reinforce the action of the automatic stabilizers, the policy conclusion one can

draw from the previous outcome is that tax and spending policies should not be used as

they have been used during and after the crisis.

Our findings – even though with different methodologies – are in line with and

extend the conclusions proposed by Debrun and Kapoor (2010). Since their analysis

includes a period before the recent economic crisis, our results not only confirm their

conclusion that before 2008 the power of the discretionary policy is weaker than that of

automatic stabilizers, but also provide evidence that after the crisis the power of the

discretionary policy to counteract adverse economic cycles has even weakened.

In our study, pro-cyclicality or a-cyclicality is, indeed, a frequent outcome of the

estimates. From the point of view of national policy-makers, this would suggest that the

15 In detail, it happens for: ‘very high-debt’ countries (i.e. with debt ratios above 90% of GDP) such as Italy and Belgium; ‘high-debt’ countries (i.e. between 60% and 90% of GDP) such as Austria, Germany, France and the Netherlands; ‘low-debt’ countries (i.e. below 60% of GDP) such as Finland, Luxembourg, Slovakia, Latvia and Lithuania. We adopt the thresholds proposed by the European Fiscal Board (2019) for defining very high-, high-, and low-debt countries.

15

Page 16:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

European reforms that have moved the attention from nominal to structural variables,

with the aim of reducing pro-cyclicality, do not appear to have encouraged anticyclical

discretionary policies. As a policy suggestion, an improvement of the overall

anticyclical impact of the public budgets should be possible by changing at least two

elements. The first should consists in removing those rules based on unobservable

variables whose estimates are often a source of uncertainty, and the second in enlarging

the time horizon within which targets have to be achieved.16

4. Sensitivity analysis

In order to check the robustness of the results obtained with the standard application of

the HP filter, we replicate the previous estimates by using different methods of de-

trending.17 First, we used the HP filter with five new values of the parameter based on

the contribution provided by Pedersen (2001).18 Second, we apply new band-pass filters

have been developed over time, such as the Baxter-King filter (Baxter and King, 1999)

and the Christiano-Fitzgerald filter (Christiano and Fitzgerald, 2003).19 However, it is

worth noting that the Baxter-King filter truncates observations from both the beginning

and the end of the original sample, which implies the loss of important information

16 For a discussion about the uncertainty about countries’ compliance with the Stability and Growth Pact, see Ferré (2012). The perspective of the new member states is dealt with in Orban and Szapáry (2004).17 We decide to not take into consideration the Beveridge-Nelson approach (Beveridge and Nelson, 1981) as an alternative method of de-trending. Indeed, as highlighted in Bouthevillain et al. (2001), the main problem of that approach is the theoretical assumption according to which the cyclical component is highly correlated with the first differences of the original series especially in the typical case of a positively auto-correlated original series. 18 In detail, Pedersen (2001) identifies five optimal values for the smoothing parameter when using the HP filter: =1,007; =1,038; =1,041; =1,103; =1,269.19 The band-pass filter by Baxter and King (1999) and that by Christiano and Fitzgerald (2003) are very similar in their design; they only differ in the approximation of the ideal band-pass filter to a filter that can be applied in reality. An approximation of the ideal filter is necessary as the ideal filter requires an infinite-order moving average which implies a data series of infinite length. The most important difference is the amount of output data, resulting from the different assumptions with respect to the symmetry of the weights: Baxter and King assume symmetric weights while Christiano and Fitzgerald omit this assumption.

16

Page 17:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

about the response of discretionary fiscal policy in the period before and after 2008.

The same would happen in the case of the Hamilton filter (Hamilton, 2018), with the

loss of relevant data whose extension depends on the value of the back-shifting

parameter at the beginning of the sample. Additionally, such assumption is not neutral

and it significantly influences the properties of the estimated cyclical component,

implying a filter that eliminates two-year cycles and overweight frequencies that are

longer than the typical business cycle frequencies. This tends also to create

inconsistencies with the NBER business cycle definition (Schüler, 2018).20

For all these reasons, to the purpose of providing robustness checks, we decide to

use only the Christiano-Fitzgerald filter, which does not cause any loss of data. Finally,

we apply a polynomial filter of three different orders (linear, quadratic and cubic time

trend).21 Results are reported in the Appendix (Table A1 and Table A2 for the two sub-

periods, respectively).

When using the HP filter with different value of the smoothing parameter , we get

the same results as those previously observed, regardless of the five selected values of

.22 In relation to the other methods of de-trending, the soundness of our findings is

confirmed. In relation to the period 1999-2007, most of the countries show stable

results as reported in Table A1 in the Appendix. In particular, no significant differences

emerge in the relationships between the primary budget balances and the economic

20 In detail, Hamilton (2018) proposes to use simple forecasts of a series to remove their cyclical nature by fitting values from a regression of a variable y on four lagged values of the same variables back-shifted by a number of observations that depends on both the data frequency and the nature of the series. Following this approach, we would lose the first eleven observations for each country, using quarterly data, with a significant loss of meaning especially in relation to the response of discretionary fiscal policy to GDP changes in the second sub-period.21 Historically, the removal of linear (or log-linear) trends has been a standard method for separating trends and cycles. In any case, it should be kept in mind that recent evidence suggests that many macroeconomic series contain unit root (stochastic trend) components that would not be removed by this procedure (Baxter and King, 1999). For this reason, the results deriving from the use of this kind of filter have to be interpreted in a careful way.22 Results are not reported but they are available upon request.

17

Page 18:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

cycle. In any case, a small group of countries show some differences in the estimated

correlations of the primary budget balances with the economic cycle.

This represents an interesting aspect, especially when we compare the results from

the sensitivity analysis between the two sub-periods. Estimates for the period 2008-

2017 are reported in Table A2 in the Appendix. With the exception of the Netherlands,

the sensitivity analysis confirms the direction of the discretionary government’s

intervention aimed at counteracting the anticyclical effects of the automatic stabilizers

in the post-crisis period.

5. Conclusions

This paper has estimated the CAPB for 18 countries of the Euro area using quarterly

budgetary data for the period 1999-2017. The methodology here used differs from that

based on the EC approach and gives the opportunity to better characterize the

discretionary fiscal policy in two different sub-periods marked off by the recent

economic crisis.

We find that, especially in relation to the period after the crisis (i.e. 2008-2017), the

fiscal policy could be defined as anticyclical in most countries of our sample. However,

once the automatic impact of the economic cycle is removed from the budget balance,

the CAPB loses its positive correlation with the business cycle. This means that

discretionary fiscal policies have weakened the automatic anticyclical nature of the

budgetary policy. Concerning the effectiveness of the fiscal policy, this result

highlights to what extent the discretionary action of national policy-makers has failed

to provide an expansionary contribution in the most severe phases of the economic

crisis.

18

Page 19:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

These findings challenge the core of recent reforms of the European fiscal rules

aimed at reducing the pro-cyclicality of the public budgets since, in most cases, they

have neither reduced pro-cyclicality nor encouraged anti-cyclicality. From a policy

viewpoint, we can argue that this unsatisfactory outcome may be partially due to two

main elements. The first is the excessive difficulty in managing the European fiscal

rules, which are mainly based on variables that are not observable and that need to be

estimated under debatable assumptions. The second is that the time horizon in the

application of the rules is too short (i.e. the annual basis), a characteristic that may

particularly affect the incentives to activate those public investments that are

anticyclical in the medium term. In this perspective, the possibility of reforming at least

these two settings of the European fiscal rules should be seriously considered.

Acknowledgements

We thank the participants at the: XXXI Conference of the Italian Society of Public Economics; XXX Conference of the Italian Economic Society; INFER Workshop on New Challenges for Fiscal Policy for their comments. Special thanks are due to Massimo Bordignon, Daniela Monacelli, Alberto Petrucci and Luìs Pinheiro de Matos for insightful suggestions on a previous version of the paper. We are also indebted to anonymous referees and to the Editor for valuable comments on the paper.

References

Afonso, A., & Claeys, P. (2008). The dynamic behaviour of budget components and output. Economic Modelling, 25(1), 93-117.

Baxter, M., & King. R. G. (1999). Measuring business cycles: approximate band-pass filters for economic time series. The Review of Economic and Statistics 81, 575-593.

Bee Dagum E., & Bianconcini S. (2016). Seasonal Adjustment Based on ARIMA Model Decomposition: TRAMO-SEATS. In: Seasonal Adjustment Methods and Real Time Trend-Cycle Estimation. Springer, Cham, 115-145.

Beveridge, S., & Nelson, C. (1981). A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the business cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics 7, 151-174.

Blanchard. O. J. (1990). Suggestions for a New Set of Fiscal Indicators. OECD Economics Department Working Papers. No. 79. OECD Publishing. OECD.

19

Page 20:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Bouthevillain, C., Cour-Thimann, P., van den Dool, G., Hernández de Cos, P., Langenus, G., Mohr, M., Momigliano, S., & Tujula, M. (2001). Cyclically Adjusted Budget Balances: An Alternative Approach. ECB Working Paper No. 77.

Brück, T., & Zwiener, R. (2006). Fiscal policy rules for stabilisation and growth: A simulation analysis of deficit and expenditure targets in a monetary union. Journal of Policy Modeling 28(4), 357-369.

Burnside. C., & Meshcheryakova. Y. (2005a). Cyclical Adjustment of the Budget Surplus: Concepts and Measurement Issues. In: Burnside. C. (eds.). Fiscal Sustainability in Theory and Practice. A Handbook. The World Bank, 113–131.

Burnside. C., & Meshcheryakova. Y. (2005b). Mexico: A Case Study of Procyclical Fiscal Policy. In: Burnside. C. (eds.). Fiscal Sustainability in Theory and Practice. A Handbook. The World Bank, 133-174.

Christiano, L. J., & Fitzgerald, T. J. (2003). The band pass filter. International Economic Review 44, 435-465.

Claeys, G., Darvas, Z., & Leandro, A. (2016). A proposal to revive the European Fiscal Framework. Bruegel Policy Contribution. Issue 2016/07.

Cogley, T., & Nason, J. M. (1995). Effects of the Hodrick-Prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series. Implications for business cycle research. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 253-278.

Crafts, N. (2016). Is Secular Stagnation the Future for Europe? In: Askanazy, P., Bellman, L., Bryson, A. & Galbis, E. M. (editors), Productivity Puzzles Across Europe. Oxford University Press, 49-67.

D’Auria, F., Denis, C., Havik, K. M. C., Morrow, K., Planas, C., Raciborski, C., Roeger, W., & Rossi, A. (2010). The production function methodology for calculating potential growth rates and output gaps. European Commission Economic Papers. n. 420.

De Jong, R. M., & Sakarya, N. (2016). The econometrics of the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Review of Economics and Statistics 98(2), 310-317.

Debrun X., & Kapoor, R. (2010). Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Stability: Automatic Stabilizers Work. Always and Everywhere. IMF Working Paper WP/10/111.

Drehmann, M. and Yetman, J. (2018). Why you should use the Hodrick-Prescott filter – at least to generate credit gaps. BIS Working Papers n. 744.

Egert, B. (2010). Fiscal Policy Reaction to the Cycle in the OECD: Pro-or Counter-Cyclical?. OECD Economic Department Working Papers n. 763, OECD Publishing.

European Fiscal Board (2019). Assessment of EU Fiscal Rulesc with a Focus on the Six and Two-Pack Legislation. European Commission. Brussels.

Fatás, A., & Mihov, I. (2009). Why Fiscal Stimulus is Likely to Work. International Finance 12(1), 57–93.Ferré, M. (2012). The effects of uncertainty about countries’ compliance with the

Stability and Growth Pact. Journal of Policy Modeling 34(5), 660-674.FitzGerald, J. (2014). The new EU governance arrangements. Revue de l'OFCE 1, 93-

99.Frankel, J. (2015). The euro crisis: Where to from here?. Journal of Policy Modeling

37, 428-444.Golinelli, R., & Momigliano, S. (2006). Real-time determinants of fiscal policies in the

euro area. Journal of Policy Modeling 28(9), 943-964.

20

Page 21:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Gordon, R. J. (1997). The time-varying NAIRU and its implications for economic policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(1), 11-32.

Guay, A., & St-Amant, P. (2005). Do the Hodrick-Prescott and Baxter-King filters provide a good approximation of business cycles?. Annals of Economics and Statistics 77, 133-135.

Hamilton, J. (2018). Why you should never use the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Review of Economics and Statistics 100(5), 831-843.

Harvey, A. C., & Jaeger, A. (1993). Detrending, stylized facts, and the business cycle. Journal of Applied Econometrics 8, 231-247.

Hauptmeier, S., Sanchez-Fuentes, A. J., & Schuknecht, L. (2011). Towards expenditure rules and fiscal sanity in the euro area. Journal of Policy Modeling 33(4), 597-617.

Havik, K., Mc Morrow, K., Orlandi, F., Planas, C., Raciborski, R., Roger, W., Rossi, A., Thum-Thysen, A., & Vandermeulen, V. (2014). The Production Function Methodology for Calculating Potential Growth Rates & Output Gap. European Commission Economic Papers. n. 535.

Heimberger, P., Kapeller, J., & Schütz, B. (2017). The NAIRU determinants: What’s structural about unemployment in Europe?. Journal of Policy Modeling 39(5), 883-908.

Hodrick, R., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 29, 1-16.

Holden, S., & Nymoen, R. (2002). Measuring structural unemployment: NAWRU estimates in the Nordic countries. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 104(1), 87-104.

Lane, P. R. (2003). The Cyclical Behaviour of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the OECD. Journal of Public Economics 87(12), 2661–2675.

Larch, M., & Turrini, A. (2010). The cyclically adjusted budget balance in EU fiscal policymaking. Intereconomics. 45(1), 48-60.

Mourre, G., Isbasiou, G. M., Paternoster, D., & Salto, M. (2013). The cyclically-adjusted budget balance used in the EU fiscal framework: an update. European Economy - Economic Papers n. 478. Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs. European Commission.

Mourre, G., Astarita, C., & Princen, S. (2014). Adjusting the budget balance for the business cycle: the EU methodology. European Economy - Economic Papers n. 536. Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs. European Commission.

Onorante, L., Pedregal, D.J., Pérez, J.J., Signorini S. (2010). The usefulness of infra-annual government cash budgetary data for fiscal forecasting in the euro area. Journal of Policy Modeling, 32, 98-119.

Orban, G., & Szapáry, G. (2004). The stability and growth pact from the perspective of the new member states. Journal of Policy Modeling 26(7), 839-864.

Paredes, J., Pedregal, D.J., Pérez, J.J. (2014). Fiscal policy analysis in the euro area: Expanding the toolkit. Journal of Policy Modeling 36, 800-823.

Pedersen, T. M. (2001). The Hodrick-Prescott filter, the Slutzky effect, and the distortionary effect of filters. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25, 1081-1101.

Ravn, M. O., & Uhlig, H. (2002). On adjusting the Hodrick-Prescott filter for the frequency of observations. Review of Economics and Statistics 84(2), 371-376.

Sakarya, N., & de Jong, R. M. (2019). A property of the Hodrick-Prescott filter and its application. Econometric Theory, forthcoming.

21

Page 22:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Schüler, Y. S. (2018). On the cyclical propoerties of Hmilton’s regression filter, Bundesbank Discussion Paper n. 3.

Schreiber, S., & Wolters, J. (2007). The long-run Phillips curve revisited: Is the NAIRU framework data-consistent?. Journal of Macroeconomics 29(2), 355-367.

Spilimbergo, A., Symansky, S., Blanchard, O., & Cottarelli, C. (2009). Fiscal Policy for The Crisis. CESifo Forum 10(2), 26-32.

Summers, L. (2014). U. S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound, Business Economics 49 (2), 65-73.

Figures

Figure 1 – The economic cycle and the cyclical component of the primary balance,

by country (1999-2007)

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

Austria

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

Belgium

22

Page 23:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Cyprus

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

Finland19

99_Q

119

99_Q

219

99_Q

319

99_Q

420

00_Q

120

00_Q

220

00_Q

320

00_Q

420

01_Q

120

01_Q

220

01_Q

320

01_Q

420

02_Q

120

02_Q

220

02_Q

320

02_Q

420

03_Q

120

03_Q

220

03_Q

320

03_Q

420

04_Q

120

04_Q

220

04_Q

320

04_Q

420

05_Q

120

05_Q

220

05_Q

320

05_Q

420

06_Q

120

06_Q

220

06_Q

320

06_Q

420

07_Q

120

07_Q

220

07_Q

320

07_Q

4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

France

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

Germany

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Greece

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

Ireland

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Italy

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-4%

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

Latvia

23

Page 24:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

Lithuania

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

Luxembourg

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-4%

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Malta

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Netherlands

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Portugal

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

Slovakia

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Slovenia

1999

_Q1

1999

_Q2

1999

_Q3

1999

_Q4

2000

_Q1

2000

_Q2

2000

_Q3

2000

_Q4

2001

_Q1

2001

_Q2

2001

_Q3

2001

_Q4

2002

_Q1

2002

_Q2

2002

_Q3

2002

_Q4

2003

_Q1

2003

_Q2

2003

_Q3

2003

_Q4

2004

_Q1

2004

_Q2

2004

_Q3

2004

_Q4

2005

_Q1

2005

_Q2

2005

_Q3

2005

_Q4

2006

_Q1

2006

_Q2

2006

_Q3

2006

_Q4

2007

_Q1

2007

_Q2

2007

_Q3

2007

_Q4

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

Spain

Notes: in order to visualize the countercyclical action of the automatic stabilizers, the continuous line, which represents the cyclical component of the primary balance, is expressed by the difference between the CAPB and the actual primary balance. The dotted line represents the cyclical component of GDP

24

Page 25:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

(i.e. the economic cycle). Each series is presented as a percentage of the HP trend of the real GDP. The availability of data in some countries is reduced in relation to the first sub-period: Austria (2001-2007); Germany (2002–2007); Ireland (2002–2007); Luxembourg (2002–2007); Malta (2000–2007).Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

25

Page 26:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Figure 2 – The economic clycle and the cyclical component of the primary balance,

by country (2008-2017)20

08_Q

120

08_Q

220

08_Q

320

08_Q

420

09_Q

120

09_Q

220

09_Q

320

09_Q

420

10_Q

120

10_Q

220

10_Q

320

10_Q

420

11_Q

120

11_Q

220

11_Q

320

11_Q

420

12_Q

120

12_Q

220

12_Q

320

12_Q

420

13_Q

120

13_Q

220

13_Q

320

13_Q

420

14_Q

120

14_Q

220

14_Q

320

14_Q

420

15_Q

120

15_Q

220

15_Q

320

15_Q

420

16_Q

120

16_Q

220

16_Q

320

16_Q

420

17_Q

120

17_Q

220

17_Q

320

17_Q

4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Austria

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

Belgium

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-4%

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

Cyprus

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Finland

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

France

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Germany

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Greece

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-10%

-8%

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

Ireland

26

Page 27:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

Italy

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

15%

Latvia

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-15%

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

15%

Lithuania

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

Luxembourg

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-5%

-4%

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

Malta

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Netherlands

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

Portugal

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-6%

-4%

-2%

0%

2%

4%

6%Slovakia

27

Page 28:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-5%

-4%

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

Slovenia

2008

_Q1

2008

_Q2

2008

_Q3

2008

_Q4

2009

_Q1

2009

_Q2

2009

_Q3

2009

_Q4

2010

_Q1

2010

_Q2

2010

_Q3

2010

_Q4

2011

_Q1

2011

_Q2

2011

_Q3

2011

_Q4

2012

_Q1

2012

_Q2

2012

_Q3

2012

_Q4

2013

_Q1

2013

_Q2

2013

_Q3

2013

_Q4

2014

_Q1

2014

_Q2

2014

_Q3

2014

_Q4

2015

_Q1

2015

_Q2

2015

_Q3

2015

_Q4

2016

_Q1

2016

_Q2

2016

_Q3

2016

_Q4

2017

_Q1

2017

_Q2

2017

_Q3

2017

_Q4

-3%

-2%

-1%

0%

1%

2%

Spain

Notes: in order to visualize the countercyclical action of the automatic stabilizers, the continuous line, which represents the cyclical component of the primary balance, is expressed by the difference between the CAPB and the actual primary balance. The dotted line represents the cyclical component of GDP (i.e. the economic cycle). Each series is presented as a percentage of the HP trend of the real GDP.Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

28

Page 29:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

TablesTable 1 – Budgetary items and the economic cycle

1999 - 2007

Direct

taxes

Indirect taxes

Net social contributio

ns

Other curren

t taxes

Capital taxes

Compensation of

employees

Intermediate

consumption

Social benefit

s

Other current

expenditures

Capital expenditur

es

Austria x

Belgium x x x ° °

Cyprus * x ° °

Finland x x x * x ° x ° x

France x x x °

Germany x x x x ° x

Greece x x x

Ireland ° °

Italy x °

Latvia x x x ° ° x

Lithuania x x x ° xLuxembourg x ° °

Malta x * x xNetherlands x ° ° ° X x

Portugal x * x x *

Slovakia ° x °

Slovenia * * ° x x

Spain * x x °

                     

2008 - 2017

Direct

taxes

Indirect taxes

Net social contributio

ns

Other curren

t taxes

Capital taxes

Compensation of

employees

Intermediate

consumption

Social benefit

s

Other current

expenditures

Capital expenditur

es

Austria x x x x x x

Belgium x x x x x

Cyprus ° ° x x °

Finland x x x x x

France x x x x x x x x

Germany x x x * * x x

Greece x x ° °

Ireland * x °

Italy ° x x x * °

Latvia x x x * x * x

Lithuania x x x x *Luxembourg x x x

Malta ° x °Netherlands ° x x x

Portugal x x x x °

Slovakia x x * ° °

Slovenia x x x x x

Spain ° x x x ° x

29

Page 30:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Note: the symbol ‘x’ means that the correlation between the cyclical component of each budgetary item and the economic cycle is statistically significant at 1%, ‘°’ at 5% and ‘*’ at 10%. In any case, the elasticities of each budgetary item have also to be significant to be taken into consideration for the calculation of the CAPB.Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

30

Page 31:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Table 2 – Correlations between the primary balances and the economic cycle

    1999 - 2007   2008 – 2017

   Actual primary

balance CAPB   Actual primary balance CAPB

             

Austria   0.51*** 0.41**   0.57*** 0.13   

Belgium   0.24 0.06   0.63*** 0.14   

Cyprus   0.59*** 0.25   0.1 0.16   

Finland   0.82*** 0.36**   0.66*** 0.14   

France   0.50*** 0.1   0.73*** 0.12   

Germany   0.43** 0.11   0.51*** 0.05   

Greece   -0.35** -0.25   0.26 0.36**   

Ireland   -0.01 -0.2   -0.06 -0.08   

Italy   0.12 0.03   0.38** -0.04   

Latvia   -0.35** -0.42**   0.38** 0.01   

Lithuania   -0.2 -0.07   0.45*** 0.05   

Luxembourg   0.65*** 0.50**   0.41*** 0.29*   

Malta   0.29 0.01   0.15 -0.07   

Netherlands   0.40** 0.15   0.48*** 0.30*   

Portugal   0.12 -0.1   -0.15 -0.17   

Slovakia   -0.05 -0.09   0.41*** 0.13   

Slovenia   0.09 0.01   0.25 0.12   

Spain   0.33** -0.06   0.14 0.11   

Notes: the actual primary balance and the CAPB are expressed as a percentage of the HP trend of the real GDP; the economic cycle is expressed in the same way. The correlation coefficients are statistically significant at three different levels: 0.01 (***); 0.05 (**); 0.1 (*). The availability of data in some countries is reduced in relation to the first sub-period: Austria (2001-2007); Germany (2002–2007); Ireland (2002–2007); Luxembourg (2002–2007); Malta (2000–2007). Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

Appendix A

31

Page 32:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

Table A.1 – Sensitivity analysis (1999–2007)

    CF filter Order 1 polynomial trend

Order 2 polynomial trend

Order 3 polynomial trend

AustriaActual primary balance 0.49 0.57 -0.01 -0.03

(0.0077***) (0.0016***) (0.9454) (0.8873)

CAPB 0.40 0.30 0.00 -0.01(0.0355) (0.1236) (0.9849) (0.9515)

BelgiumActual primary balance

0.24 0.30 0.20 0.06

(0.1615) (0.0735*) (0.2329) (0.7232)

CAPB0.08 0.04 0.01 -0.10

(0.6518) (0.8241) (0.9429) (0.573)

CyprusActual primary balance 0.54 0.69 0.45 0.36

(0.0007***) (0.0***) (0.0057***) (0.0314**)

CAPB 0.38 0.19 -0.01 0.31(0.0208) (0.2623) (0.9491) (0.0619*)

FinlandActual primary balance 0.81 0.78 0.81 0.45

(0.0***) (0.0***) (0.0***) (0.0057***)

CAPB 0.44 0.09 0.13 0.11(0.0075***) (0.5899) -0.4571 -0.5127

FranceActual primary balance 0.68 0.56 0.48 0.43

(0.0***) (0.0004***) (0.0031***) (0.0087***)

CAPB 0.34 0.09 0.11 -0.03(0.0446**) (0.5995) (0.5199) (0.8547)

GermanyActual primary balance 0.50 0.44 0.08 0.08

(0.0136**) (0.0316**) (0.7019) (0.706)

CAPB 0.20 -0.08 -0.05 -0.06(0.3374) (0.7034) (0.8255) (0.7984)

GreeceActual primary balance -0.37 -0.37 -0.38 -0.35

(0.0282**) (0.0258**) (0.0238**) (0.0351**)

CAPB -0.30 -0.27 -0.26 -0.29(0.0728*) (0.1048) (0.1216) (0.0808*)

IrelandActual primary balance 0.12 -0.10 0.29 0.16

(0.5841) (0.6356) (0.1637) (0.4466)

CAPB -0.24 -0.26 0.06 0.16(0.249) (0.2288) (0.7752) (0.4466)

ItalyActual primary balance 0.30 0.11 0.17 0.05

(0.0759*) (0.5376) (0.3189) (0.78)

CAPB 0.16 0.02 -0.11 -0.03(0.3497) (0.8894) (0.541) (0.8542)

LatviaActual primary balance -0.23 -0.37 -0.14 -0.15

(0.1747) (0.0244**) (0.412) (0.3935)

CAPB -0.21 -0.46 -0.16 -0.20(0.2115) (0.0044***) (0.3444) (0.2415)

Lithuania Actual primary balance -0.10 -0.08 -0.03 -0.02

32

Page 33:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

(0.5774) (0.6505) (0.8565) (0.9005)

CAPB -0.22 -0.22 -0.16 -0.14(0.197) (0.2026) (0.3564) (0.4147)

LuxembourgActual primary balance 0.63 0.70 -0.10 -0.02

(0.001***) (0.0001***) (0.6339) (0.9209)

CAPB 0.53 0.11 -0.19 -0.12(0.0082***) (0.6182) (0.3737) (0.5667)

MaltaActual primary balance 0.02 0.34 0.21 0.24

(0.9139) (0.0548**) (0.2447) (0.1842)

CAPB -0.05 0.05 0.01 -0.03(0.7728) (0.7844) (0.9447) (0.8669)

NetherlandsActual primary balance 0.53 0.56 0.26 0.47

(0.001***) (0.0004***) -0.12 (0.0042***)

CAPB 0.34 0.06 -0.03 0.05(0.0422**) (0.7229) (0.8666) (0.7804)

PortugalActual primary balance 0.07 0.13 0.16 -0.04

(0.6687) (0.4627) (0.3454) (0.8154)

CAPB 0.00 -0.09 -0.05 -0.08(0.9991) (0.6008) (0.7732) (0.6244)

SlovakiaActual primary balance 0.34 -0.22 0.20 0.38

(0.0436**) -0.2026 -0.2487 (0.0242**)

CAPB 0.31 -0.37 0.15 0.35(0.0665*) (0.0250**) (0.3699) (0.0372**)

SloveniaActual primary balance 0.07 0.16 -0.11 0.05

(0.6753) (0.3501) (0.5277) (0.7558)

CAPB -0.02 -0.23 -0.15 0.02(0.9104) (0.1857) (0.3787) (0.9203)

SpainActual primary balance 0.36 0.41 0.23 0.58

(0.029**) (0.0127**) -0.1704 (0.0002***)

CAPB 0.01 0.05 -0.15 0.07(0.972) (0.7555) (0.384) (0.6908)

Notes: The correlation with the economic cycle is calculated taking into account the actual primary balance and the CAPB as a percentage of the four different trends of the real GDP; the economic cycle is expressed in the same way. The correlation coefficients are statistically significant at three different levels: 0.01 (***); 0.05 (**); 0.1 (*). The availability of data in some countries is reduced in relation to the first sub-period: Austria (2001-2007); Germany (2002–2007); Ireland (2002–2007); Luxembourg (2002–2007); Malta (2000–2007). Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

Table A.2 – Sensitivity analysis (2008–2017)

    CF filter Order 1 polynomial

Order 2 polynomial

Order 3 polynomial

33

Page 34:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

trend trend trend

AustriaActual primary balance 0.49 0.58 0.54 0.51

(0.0013***) (0.0001***) (0.0004***) (0.0009***)

CAPB 0.08 0.16 0.06 0.08(0.6164) (0.331) (0.7179) (0.6154)

BelgiumActual primary balance

0.34 0.74 0.53 0.52

(0.0336**) (0.0***) (0.0005***) (0.0006***)

CAPB-0.26 0.15 0.02 0.13

(0.109) (0.3439) (0.9192) (0.4083)

CyprusActual primary balance 0.09 0.24 -0.02 0.15

(0.5798) (0.1427) (0.9033) (0.3501)

CAPB 0.15 0.16 0.15 0.13(0.3706) (0.3244) (0.3718) (0.4219)

FinlandActual primary balance 0.49 0.80 0.54 0.54

(0.0012***) (0.0***) (0.0003***) (0.0004***)

CAPB -0.13 0.06 -0.01 -0.02(0.4333) (0.7331) (0.9369) (0.9193)

FranceActual primary balance 0.56 0.77 0.69 0.60

(0.0002***) (0.0***) (0.0***) (0.0001***)

CAPB -0.11 0.05 0.01 -0.01(0.5021) (0.7483) (0.9715) (0.9334)

GermanyActual primary balance 0.44 0.52 0.52 0.41

(0.0042***) (0.0006***) (0.0006***) (0.008***)

CAPB -0.01 0.02 0.01 -0.03(0.9704) (0.914) (0.9312) (0.8529)

GreeceActual primary balance 0.18 0.30 0.26 0.26

(0.2727) (0.0644*) (0.1039) (0.1039)

CAPB 0.27 0.28 0.39 0.34(0.0942*) (0.0818*) (0.0135**) (0.0333**)

IrelandActual primary balance -0.08 0.00 -0.17 -0.21

(0.6265) (0.9958) (0.299) (0.2011)

CAPB -0.10 -0.09 -0.19 -0.22(0.5338) (0.5632) (0.2515) (0.1803)

ItalyActual primary balance 0.39 0.25 0.34 0.39

(0.0119**) (0.1203) (0.0313**) (0.0122**)

CAPB -0.04 -0.16 0.05 -0.04(0.8007) (0.3167) (0.7468) (0.7922)

LatviaActual primary balance 0.48 0.14 0.45 0.43

(0.0019***) (0.3909) (0.0038**) (0.006***)

CAPB 0.10 -0.03 0.02 0.00(0.5482) (0.8614) (0.9096) (0.9967)

LithuaniaActual primary balance 0.35 0.42 0.45 0.23

(0.0264**) (0.0068***) (0.0038***) (0.145)

CAPB 0.00 -0.17 -0.05 -0.04(0.986) (0.2904) (0.7494) (0.8275)

Luxembourg Actual primary balance 0.15 0.56 0.35 0.11

34

Page 35:   · Web viewThe cyclically-adjusted primary balance: A. novel approach for . the . Euro area. Giovanni Carnazza (*) University of Roma Tre, Department of Economics. E-mail: giovanni.carnazza@

(0.3486) (0.0002***) (0.0286**) (0.484)

CAPB 0.06 0.13 0.20 0.08(0.7346) (0.4077) (0.2151) (0.6424)

MaltaActual primary balance 0.27 0.21 0.0 0.16

(0.0901**) (0.1929) (0.9889) (0.3285)

CAPB 0.18 -0.03 -0.04 0.09(0.275) (0.8579) (0.829) (0.5954)

NetherlandsActual primary balance 0.37 0.60 0.25 0.29

(0.0188**) (0.0***) (0.1181) (0.0664*)

CAPB 0.09 0.06 0.10 0.09(0.5878) (0.707) (0.5208) (0.5721)

PortugalActual primary balance -0.08 -0.01 -0.28 -0.14

(0.6064) (0.9462) (0.0763*) (0.3779)

CAPB -0.11 -0.15 -0.24 -0.17(0.5042) (0.3522) (0.1303) (0.3025)

SlovakiaActual primary balance 0.43 0.38 0.39 0.32

(0.0058***) (0.0171**) (0.0128**) (0.0472**)

CAPB 0.09 -0.07 0.13 0.17(0.5652) (0.6876) (0.4152) (0.2901)

SloveniaActual primary balance 0.11 0.40 0.09 0.09

(0.4959) (0.0115**) (0.5837) (0.5688)

CAPB 0.00 0.16 0.02 0.02(0.9974) (0.3161) (0.9022) (0.9217)

SpainActual primary balance 0.13 0.25 -0.20 0.04

(0.4209) (0.1262) (0.2218) (0.8061)

CAPB 0.01 -0.07 -0.05 -0.05(0.9561) (0.6841) (0.7576) (0.7596)

Notes: The correlation with the economic cycle is calculated taking into account the actual primary balance and the CAPB as a percentage of the four different trends of the real GDP; the economic cycle is expressed in the same way. The correlation coefficients are statistically significant at three different levels: 0.01 (***); 0.05 (**); 0.1 (*).Source: authors’ elaborations on Eurostat data

35