73
Supply & Demand

We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Supply & Demand

Page 2: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The Demand Function

Page 3: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market will drop, and thus the quantity q of the good that is purchased will also drop.

The Demand Function

Page 4: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market will drop, and thus the quantity q of the good that is purchased will also drop.

To put it another way, as the price of a good rises, the quantity that is demanded of that good will fall. Conversely, if the price of a good falls, the demand for that good will rise.

The Demand Function

Page 5: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can capture this idea of demand falling as price rises in a graph.

Page 6: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can capture this idea of demand falling as price rises in a graph. We put the price on the horizontal axis and the quantity demanded on the vertical axis:

Page 7: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The graph of the demand function will always have a negative slope, since demand falls as prices rise:

Page 8: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The graph of the demand function will always have a negative slope, since demand falls as prices rise:

Page 9: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The graph of the demand function will always have a negative slope, since demand falls as prices rise:

Page 10: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The slope of the demand equation is the change in q over the change in p.

Page 11: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The slope of the demand equation is the change in q over the change in p.

Page 12: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The slope of the demand equation is the change in q over the change in p.

Page 13: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Often you will be asked to find a demand equation given the demand at two different price levels.

Page 14: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Often you will be asked to find a demand equation given the demand at two different price levels.

For example, suppose a store is able to sell 40 mugs in a week if the price is $3.50 per mug, but is only able to sell 30 per week if the price is $4 per mug.

Page 15: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Often you will be asked to find a demand equation given the demand at two different price levels.

For example, suppose a store is able to sell 40 mugs in a week if the price is $3.50 per mug, but is only able to sell 30 per week if the price is $4 per mug.

This gives us two price/quantity ordered pairs, in the form (p, q ). The pairs are (3.50, 40) and (4, 30)

Page 16: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

Page 17: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

We find m as follows:

Page 18: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

We find m as follows:

Page 19: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

We find m as follows:

Page 20: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

We find m as follows:

Page 21: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We need to find the demand equation, which always has the form q=mp+b. We must find both m and b using our two points.

We find m as follows:

Page 22: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Page 23: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Using (4, 30), we can substitute 4 for p and 30 for q, and then solve for b.

Page 24: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Using (4, 30), we can substitute 4 for p and 30 for q, and then solve for b.

Page 25: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Using (4, 30), we can substitute 4 for p and 30 for q, and then solve for b.

Page 26: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Using (4, 30), we can substitute 4 for p and 30 for q, and then solve for b.

Page 27: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Now that we have m, we can find b using either of the price/quantity points we were given. So far we have .

Using (4, 30), we can substitute 4 for p and 30 for q, and then solve for b.

Thus, our demand function is

Page 28: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can interpret the value of b =110 to mean that if the price drops to zero, the quantity of mugs demanded will be 110.

Page 29: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can interpret the value of b =110 to mean that if the price drops to zero, the quantity of mugs demanded will be 110.

We can write the slope m =-20 as

Page 30: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can interpret the value of b =110 to mean that if the price drops to zero, the quantity of mugs demanded will be 110.

We can write the slope m =-20 as Recall that in this case, the slope is

Page 31: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We can interpret the value of b =110 to mean that if the price drops to zero, the quantity of mugs demanded will be 110.

We can write the slope m =-20 as Recall that in this case, the slope is

Thus, the slope can be interpreted to mean that if the price p increases by $1, then the quantity q of mugs demanded will decrease by 20.

Page 32: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The Supply Function

Page 33: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We now view prices and quantities sold from the point of view of the supplier.

The Supply Function

Page 34: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We now view prices and quantities sold from the point of view of the supplier.

From the supplier’s point of view, higher prices means more money from sales. If the price of an item rises, the supplier is willing to supply more of that item.

The Supply Function

Page 35: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

We now view prices and quantities sold from the point of view of the supplier.

From the supplier’s point of view, higher prices means more money from sales. If the price of an item rises, the supplier is willing to supply more of that item.

Thus, on a supply curve, we expect that higher prices will lead to a higher quantity of items supplied, and so the supply function

has a positive slope.

The Supply Function

Page 36: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Notice that both the supply and the demand functions have the same form,

Page 37: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Notice that both the supply and the demand functions have the same form,

The easiest way to tell a supply function from a demand function is to check the sign of the slope. A supply function always has a positive slope, and a demand function always has a negative slope.

Page 38: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Notice that both the supply and the demand functions have the same form,

The easiest way to tell a supply function from a demand function is to check the sign of the slope. A supply function always has a positive slope, and a demand function always has a negative slope.

We can find a supply function in the same way we found a demand function – we will usually be given two price/quantity pairs, and we use them to find both m and b.

Page 39: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Equilibrium Price and Quantity

Page 40: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

There is a seeming disconnect between buyers and sellers of any particular item.

Equilibrium Price and Quantity

Page 41: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

There is a seeming disconnect between buyers and sellers of any particular item.

The buyers will buy more of an item if the price is lower, but the sellers may not be willing to supply very many of the item if they can’t make money on the sales.

Equilibrium Price and Quantity

Page 42: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

There is a seeming disconnect between buyers and sellers of any particular item.

The buyers will buy more of an item if the price is lower, but the sellers may not be willing to supply very many of the item if they can’t make money on the sales.

If the price is higher, the sellers will be willing to supply more of the item since they can make more money, but if they raise the price, the buyers won’t want to buy as many of the item.

Equilibrium Price and Quantity

Page 43: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Fortunately, there is a particular price/quantity combination that will (theoretically) make both buyers and sellers happy.

Page 44: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Fortunately, there is a particular price/quantity combination that will (theoretically) make both buyers and sellers happy.

By “happy,” we mean that all of an item that is supplied by the suppliers will be purchased by buyers, so that there will be none left over (surplus), and no buyer will be unable to purchase the item because a supplier didn’t supply enough of it (shortage).

Page 45: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This price/quantity combination is called the equilibrium point. The p – coordinate of the this point is the equilibrium price and the q –coordinate is the equilibrium quantity.

Page 46: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This price/quantity combination is called the equilibrium point. The p – coordinate of the this point is the equilibrium price and the q –coordinate is the equilibrium quantity.

Graphically, the equilibrium point is the point where a supply function for a particular item intersects the corresponding demand function for the item.

Page 47: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This price/quantity combination is called the equilibrium point. The p – coordinate of the this point is the equilibrium price and the q –coordinate is the equilibrium quantity.

Graphically, the equilibrium point is the point where a supply function for a particular item intersects the corresponding demand function for the item.

You can find the equilibrium point by setting the supply function equal to the demand function, and solving for p.

Page 48: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 49: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 50: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 51: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 52: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 53: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Graphically, the point of equilibrium looks like this:

Page 54: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

As an example, suppose a college newspaper has a demand function of

Page 55: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

As an example, suppose a college newspaper has a demand function of

Suppose the same newspaper has a supply function of

Page 56: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

As an example, suppose a college newspaper has a demand function of

Suppose the same newspaper has a supply function of

Note that the price p is measured in dollars.

Page 57: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The q-intercept of 8000 on the demand function means that if the newspaper is given away free of charge (if p = 0), then 8000 papers would be demanded.

Page 58: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

The q-intercept of 8000 on the demand function means that if the newspaper is given away free of charge (if p = 0), then 8000 papers would be demanded.

The q-intercept of 800 on the supply function means that if the newspaper is given away free of charge, then the university (the supplier) is willing to supply 800 papers.

Page 59: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium price, we set the supply function equal to the demand function and solve for p.

Page 60: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium price, we set the supply function equal to the demand function and solve for p.

Page 61: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium price, we set the supply function equal to the demand function and solve for p.

Page 62: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium price, we set the supply function equal to the demand function and solve for p.

Page 63: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium price, we set the supply function equal to the demand function and solve for p.

Thus, the equilibrium price for the newspaper is $0.40 (or 40 cents).

Page 64: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium quantity, we can plug the equilibrium price back into either the supply or the demand equation.

Page 65: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium quantity, we can plug the equilibrium price back into either the supply or the demand equation.

Page 66: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium quantity, we can plug the equilibrium price back into either the supply or the demand equation.

Page 67: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

To find the equilibrium quantity, we can plug the equilibrium price back into either the supply or the demand equation.

Either way, we get the equilibrium quantity of 4,000 newspapers.

Page 68: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This means that if the college charges $0.40 per newspaper and supplies 4,000 newspapers, there will be neither a surplus nor a shortage of newspapers.

Page 69: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This means that if the college charges $0.40 per newspaper and supplies 4,000 newspapers, there will be neither a surplus nor a shortage of newspapers.

Notice that if they supply 4,000 newspapers and charge more than $0.40, there will be some newspapers left unsold since not as many people will want to pay a higher price.

Page 70: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

This means that if the college charges $0.40 per newspaper and supplies 4,000 newspapers, there will be neither a surplus nor a shortage of newspapers.

Notice that if they supply 4,000 newspapers and charge more than $0.40, there will be some newspapers left unsold since not as many people will want to pay a higher price.

This would result in a surplus of newspapers since supply is greater than demand.

Page 71: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Conversely, if the college supplied 4,000 newspapers and charged less than $0.40, there would be some people who want to buy a newspaper but would not be able to, since more people would want to buy them at the lower price than would be supplied by the college.

Page 72: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

Conversely, if the college supplied 4,000 newspapers and charged less than $0.40, there would be some people who want to buy a newspaper but would not be able to, since more people would want to buy them at the lower price than would be supplied by the college.

This would result in a shortage of newspapers since demand is greater than supply.

Page 73: We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market

For more information on supply and demand, see the PDF file linked on p. 61 of the e-book. It contains some example problems with detailed solutions.