35
Uniform Price Auctions: Equilibria and Efficiency Vangelis Markakis Athens University of Economics & Business (AUEB) 1 Orestis Telelis University of Liverpool

Uniform Price Auctions: Equilibria and Efficiency Vangelis Markakis Athens University of Economics & Business (AUEB) 1 Orestis Telelis University of Liverpool

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Uniform Price Auctions: Equilibria and Efficiency

Vangelis Markakis

Athens University of

Economics & Business

(AUEB)

1

Orestis Telelis University of Liverpool

Outline

• Intro to Multi-unit Auctions

• Uniform Price Auctions• Pure Nash Equilibria: Existence, Computation

and Efficiency• Bayes-Nash Equilibria

2

Multi-unit Auctions

Auctions for selling multiple identical units of a single good

In practice:

• US Treasury notes, bonds

• UK electricity auctions (output of generators)

• Radio spectrum licences

• Various online sales

3

Multi-unit Auctions

Online sites offering multi-unit auctions

• UK− uk.ebid.net

• Greece− www.ricardo.gr

• Australia− www.quicksales.com.au

• …

4

Some Notation• n bidders

• k available units of an indivisible good

• Bidder i has valuation function vi : [k] R−vi(j) = value of bidder i for obtaining j units

• Alternative description with marginal valuations:−mi(j) = vi(j) – vi(j-1) = additional value for obtaining the

j-th unit, if already given j-1 units

− (mi(1), mi(2),…, mi(k)): vector of marginal values

5

(Symmetric) Submodular Valuations

6

• In the multi-unit setting, a valuation vi is submodular iff

x ≤ y, vi(x+1) - vi(x) ≥ vi(y+1) – vi(y)

• Hence: mi(1) ≥ mi(2) ≥ … ≥ mi(k)

Discrete analog of concavity

Value

# bottles

A Bidding Format for Multi-unit Auctions

• Used in various multi-unit auctions

[Krishna ’02, Milgrom ’04]

1. The auctioneer asks each bidder to submit a vector of decreasing marginal bids

• bi = (bi(1), bi(2),…, bi(k))

• bi(1) ≥ bi(2) ≥ … ≥ bi(k)

• The bids are ranked in decreasing order and the k highest win the units

7

Example

8

b1 = (45, 42, 31, 22, 15)

b2 = (35, 27, 20, 12, 7)

b3 = (40, 33, 24, 14, 9)

Example

9

# units

45

bids

42

40

35

33

31

winning bids losing bids

(45, 42, 31, 22, 15)

(35, 27, 20, 12, 7)

(40, 33, 24, 14, 9)

supply

How should we charge the winners?

0

Standard Auction Formats

10

1. Multi-unit Vickrey auction (VCG) [Vickrey ’61]− Each bidder pays the externality he causes to the others

− Generalization of single-item 2nd price auction

− Good theoretical properties, strategyproof, but barely used in practice

2. Discriminatory Price Auctions− Bidders pay their bids for the units won

− Generalization of 1st price auction

− Not strategyproof, but widely used in practice

Standard Auction Formats (cont’d)

11

3. Uniform Price Auctions [Friedman 1960]− Same price for every unit

− Price is set so that Supply = Demand (market clears)

− Interval of prices to pick from:

[highest losing bid, lowest winning bid]

− This talk: price = highest losing bid

− For 1 unit, same as Vickrey auction

− For ≥ 2 units, not strategyproof, but widely used in practice (following the campaign of Miller and Friedman in the 90’s)

Example Revisited

12

# units

45

bids

42

40

35

33

31

winning bids losing bids

(45, 42, 31, 22, 15)

(35, 27, 20, 12, 7)

(40, 33, 24, 14, 9)

supply

Interval of candidate prices = [31, 33]Uniform price = 31

0

Uniform Price Auctions

13

Pros

• Intuitively the right thing to do: identical goods should cost the same!

• No complaints arising from price discrimination

Cons

• Not strategyproof

• Nash equilibria are usually inefficient

Debate still going on for treasury auctions:Uniform Price vs Discriminatory?

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

14

Q1: Existence?

Q2: Computation?

Q3: Social Inefficiency – Price of Anarchy?

We will focus on Nash equilibria in undominated strategies

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

15

Q1: Existence?

Theorem: For bidders with submodular valuations, a pure Nash equilibrium (PNE) always exists

Properties of Nash Equilibria

16

Lemma 1: It is a weakly dominated strategy to declare a bid bi = (bi(1), bi(2),…, bi(k)) s.t.

• bi(1) ≠ vi(1)• bi(j) > mi(j), for some j [k]

For bidders with submodular valuations:

Properties of Nash Equilibria

17

Lemma 2: Let b be a PNE in undominated strategies. There always exists an equilibrium b’ resulting in the same allocation, s.t.

• b’i(x) = mi(x), i and every x ≤ # units won 1. the new price is either 0 or vi(1) for some bidder i

For bidders with submodular valuations:

Lemma 1: It is a weakly dominated strategy to declare a bid bi = (bi(1), bi(2),…, bi(k)) s.t.

• bi(1) ≠ vi(1)• bi(j) > mi(j), for some j [k]

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

18

Q2: Computation?

Theorem: A PNE in undominated strategies satisfying the properties of Lemma 2 can be computed in time poly(n, k)

Idea:• Iterative ascending process starting with bi(1) = vi(1)

• Initial price set to 0 or highest losing vi(1)• At each step: careful adjustment of price and allocation

based on currently least winning bid and current demand

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

19

Q3: Social Inefficiency – Price of Anarchy?

Let b be a pure Nash equilibrium satisfying the properties of Lemma 2

Resulting allocation: x := x(b) = (x1,…, xn)

Social Welfare: SW(b) = vi(xi)

Let the optimal allocation be y = (y1,…, yn)

Optimal Welfare: OPT = vi(yi)

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

20

• Equilibria of uniform price auctions are usually inefficient due to demand reduction

[Ausubel-Cramton ’96]• Bidders may have incentives to lower their demand (to

avoid paying a high price)

PoA = sup OPT/SW(b)

Example of Demand Reduction

21

OPT = 3, SW(b) = 13/6

• Revealing true profile for bidder 1 results in a price that is

too high for him

(1, 1, 1)

(2/3, 0, 0)

(1/2, 0, 0)

Real profile

(1, 0, 0)

(2/3, 0, 0)

(1/2, 0, 0)

Equilibrium profile

Equilibria in Uniform Price Auctions

22

Q3: Social Inefficiency – Price of Anarchy?

Theorem: For submodular valuations,PoA ≤ e/e-1

Can demand reduction create a huge loss of efficiency?

Proof Sketch

23

W := W(x) = set of winners under b

W(y) = winners of optimal allocation

Decomposition of W:

• W0 = {i W(y): xi ≥ yi}

• W1 = {i W(y): xi < yi}

• W2 = W \ W0 W1

Note: All winners of W(y) belong to W (because bi(1) = vi(1))

W = W0 W1 W2

Source of Inefficiency is W1

Proof Sketch

24

Let βj := βj(b) = j-th lowest winning bid of b

• Because of no-overbidding:

• Every unit “lost” by some i W1 is won by a bidder in W0 W2

• Units lost by i: ri = yi – xi • The sum of winning bids for these units should be ≥

β j

j=1

ri

• It suffices to find a lower bound α such that:

Proof Sketch

25

• Consider the deviations of each i W1, for obtaining j additional units, for j = 1, 2,…, ri

• Lemma 1 + 2 new price after each deviation would be βj

• Since b is a Nash equilibrium no such deviation is profitable

Proof Sketch

26

Manipulation of harmonic terms+

Properties of submodular functions

Tight Examples

27

Theorem: For any k ≥ 9, PNE in undominated strategies that recovers at most 1-1/e + 2/k of the optimal welfare• Even for 2 bidders with submodular valuations

For k=2: PoA = 4/3

Real profile: v1 = (1, 1), v2 = (1/2, 0), OPT = 2

Equilibrium: b1 = (1, 0), b2 = (1/2, 0), SW(b) = 3/2

For k=3: PoA = 18/13

Bayes-Nash Equilibria

28

Incomplete information game• Every bidder knows his own valuation and the distribution of valuations for the other bidders

• Vi: domain of bidder i

• Valuation vi drawn from known probability distributionπi: Vi [0,1]

• Independent of other bidders’ distributions• π = i πi = product distribution

• Bidding strategy for i: bi(vi)A profile b is a Bayes-Nash equilibrium (BNE) if vi

Ev− i ~π − iui b( )[ ] ≥ Ev− i ~π − i

ui c i,b−i( )[ ]

Bayes-Nash Equilibria

29

• Let xv = optimal allocation for profile v = (v1,…,vn), where v ~ π

E[OPT] = Ev~π [SW(xv)]PoA for BNE:

supb E[OPT] / E[SW(b)]

• supremum over all BNE b, and all distributions π.

Bayes-Nash Equilibria

30

Proof inspired by the PoA analysis for item-bidding[Christodoulou, Kovacs, Schapira ’08][Bhawalkar, Roughgarden ’11]

Theorem: For the domain of submodular valuations and for any product distribution, the Bayesian PoA is O(logk)

Beyond Submodular Valuations

31

• Very little known for non-submodular bidders

Theorem: For subadditive valuations and1. Pure Nash equilibria,

2 PoA 4 2. Bayes-Nash equilibria,

PoA = O(logk)

• Subadditive valuations: v(x+y) v(x) + v(y)• Valuation compression is needed for such bidders

Open Questions - Future Work

• Tighten the gap in the Bayesian case

• Better understanding for non-submodular bidders– Valuation compression (analogous compression happens in

the item-bidding format) [Christodoulou, Kovacs, Schapira ’08]

[Bhawalkar, Roughgarden ’11]– Other bidding formats?

• Analysis of Discriminatory price auctions

32

Open Questions - Future Work

• Do you like living in Athens?• We are hiring phd students!• More info: [email protected]

33

Open Questions - Future Work

• Do you like living in Athens?• We are hiring phd students!

34

Thank You!

35