53
Two-Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances A Neoclassical Approach Pengfei Wang, a Yi Wen, b;c Zhiwei Xu a (May 7, 2012; Preliminary) Abstract Financial capital and xed capital tend to ow in the opposite directions between poor and rich countries. Why? What are the implications of such two-way capital ows for global trade imbalances and welfare in the long run? This paper uses a tractable, incomplete-market neoclassical model to explain the pattern of two-way capital ows between emerging economies (such as China) and the developed world (such as the U.S.). We show how underdeveloped credit markets in China can lead to abnormally high rate of returns to xed capital but excessively low rate of returns to nancial capital, hence driving out household savings (nancial capital) on the one hand while simultaneously attracting foreign direct investment (xed capital) on the other hand. When calibrated to match Chinas high marginal product of capital and low real interest rate, the model is able to account for the observed rising trends of Chinas nancial capital outows and FDI inows as well as its massive trade imbalances. We also evaluate the welfare consequences of nancial and xed capital ows and show that the welfare e/ects of capital ows obey a general principlecapital ows (especially FDI) are benecial for the sourcing country while may be harmful to the recipient country, in sharp contrast to predictions of the existing literature. Our quantitative results also cast doubts on the conventional wisdom that the "saving glut" of emerging economies is responsible for the low world interest rate. Keywords: China-US Trade Relations, FDI, Global Imbalances, Two-Way Capital Flows, Welfare. JEL Classication: E21, E22, E44, F21, F32, F34, F41. We thank Yili Chien, Bill Gavin, Jiandong Ju, Qing Liu, B Ravikumar and seminar participants at Tsinghua University and St. Louis Fed for comments and suggestions. a: Hong Kong University of Science & Technology. b: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. c: Tsinghua University. 1

Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Two-Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances�A Neoclassical Approach�

Pengfei Wang,a Yi Wen,b;c Zhiwei Xua

(May 7, 2012; Preliminary)

Abstract

Financial capital and �xed capital tend to �ow in the opposite directions between poor

and rich countries. Why? What are the implications of such two-way capital �ows for global

trade imbalances and welfare in the long run? This paper uses a tractable, incomplete-market

neoclassical model to explain the pattern of two-way capital �ows between emerging economies

(such as China) and the developed world (such as the U.S.). We show how underdeveloped credit

markets in China can lead to abnormally high rate of returns to �xed capital but excessively

low rate of returns to �nancial capital, hence driving out household savings (�nancial capital)

on the one hand while simultaneously attracting foreign direct investment (�xed capital) on the

other hand. When calibrated to match China�s high marginal product of capital and low real

interest rate, the model is able to account for the observed rising trends of China�s �nancial

capital out�ows and FDI in�ows as well as its massive trade imbalances. We also evaluate

the welfare consequences of �nancial and �xed capital �ows and show that the welfare e¤ects

of capital �ows obey a general principle� capital �ows (especially FDI) are bene�cial for the

sourcing country while may be harmful to the recipient country, in sharp contrast to predictions

of the existing literature. Our quantitative results also cast doubts on the conventional wisdom

that the "saving glut" of emerging economies is responsible for the low world interest rate.

Keywords: China-US Trade Relations, FDI, Global Imbalances, Two-Way Capital Flows,

Welfare.

JEL Classi�cation: E21, E22, E44, F21, F32, F34, F41.

�We thank Yili Chien, Bill Gavin, Jiandong Ju, Qing Liu, B Ravikumar and seminar participants at TsinghuaUniversity and St. Louis Fed for comments and suggestions. a: Hong Kong University of Science & Technology. b:Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. c: Tsinghua University.

1

Page 2: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

1 Introduction

The pattern of international capital �ows is a long standing puzzle. Lucas (1990) pondered on why

capital does not �ow from North (developed countries) to South (developing countries) despite it

is scarcer and commends a higher rate of return (or marginal product) in South. The standard

neoclassical growth theory attributes the high marginal product of capital (MPK) in South to a

low capital-to-labor ratio or low household saving, thus predicting savings to �ow from rich to

poor countries. But the truth is exactly the opposite� savings appear abundant in many emerging

economies and they have been �owing massively into rich countries over the past decades.

To explain the "reversed capital �ow" puzzle, the mainstream literature on global imbalances ar-

gues that the rate of return to capital is actually lower (rather than higher) in developing economies

because of savings glut (Bernanke, 2005). Hence, capital moves in the reversed direction� from

South to North.

However, the "reversed capital �ow" puzzle is partially a fallacy of aggregation. In reality, �xed

capital does and mainly �ow from North to South� in the form of foreign direct investment (FDI).

It is �nancial capital (portfolio investment) that has been �owing in the opposite direction. Since

historically the "uphill" �ows of �nancial capital dominate the "downhill" �ows of �xed capital,

net aggregate capital �ow (�nancial plus �xed) shows the reversed pattern.

For example, during the 1995-2003 period, the industrial countries as a whole had net �nancial

capital in�ows (including foreign reserve de-cumulations) averaged -$266 billion, and net FDI out-

�ows averaged $115 billion per year. In contrast, the less developed countries (LDCs) as a block

had net FDI in�ows averaged -$154 billion per year and net �nancial capital out�ows (including for-

eign reserve accumulations) averaged $171 billion. These opposite movements (or diverging trends)

in �nancial and �xed capital �ows have been growing over time.1 In the meantime, industrial

countries have been running large and persistent trade de�cits with South. The major countries

contributing to such global imbalances are the U.S. (representing developed countries) and China

(representing LDCs in recent years). In particular, China is now both the largest holder of foreign

reserves ($3.2 trillion in the end of 2011, mostly U.S. government bonds) and the largest recipient

of FDI ($185 billion in the year of 2010 with a total in�ow of more than $1 trillion in 1978-2009)

among developing countries, as well as the major contributor to global current account imbalances

(with a surplus of over 400 billion in 2008). In contrast, the U.S. is the largest importer of �nancial

capital from developing countries and the largest exporter of FDI to South. Meanwhile, the U.S.

1The statistics are based on data provided by Ott (2008).

2

Page 3: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

is also the largest trade-de�cit country (e.g., with a current account de�cit of 800 billion in 2008).

Persistent net capital in�ows to a country would imply current account de�cits in the short

run but trade surplus in the long run� because of positive interest payments in the steady state.2

Since by textbook theory unidirectional one-way capital �ow is not sustainable (i.e., a country�s

net foreign asset position should be zero at steady state), trade should always be balanced in the

long run. However, if �nancial capital (e.g., bonds) and �xed capital (FDI) earn di¤erent rates of

returns and they �ow in the opposite directions, a country can sustain long-run trade de�cits (or

surplus) even if its net capital (�nancial and �xed) in�ows are balanced at zero. For example, if

the U.S. gleans a substantially larger rate of return from foreign capital than foreigners do from

owning U.S. capital (as it is in the data), it could run substantial trade de�cits forever. Conversely,

if China holds most of the world�s low-yield foreign reserves and pays the highest rate of return to

FDI in�ows from rich countries, it will experience trade surplus even in the long run.

Two-way capital �ows have the opposite e¤ect on domestic interest rate. Therefore, it is not

clear a priori that �nancial capital in�ows from the South would necessarily reduce the interest

rate of the North because FDI out�ows will raise the marginal product of capital in the North.

In addition, these two forms of capital �ows reinforce with each other through general equilibrium

e¤ects on the interest rate. For example, FDI in�ows may crowd out domestic �xed capital in-

vestment in the recipient country and push down the real interest rate, which in turn can trigger

�nancial capital out�ows. This in turn may restore the interest rate back to its original level. On

the other hand, �nancial capital in�ows reduce the real interest rate and the MPK in the recipient

country, thus causing FDI out�ows, which in turn raises the interest rate.

Despite the importance of FDI in the North-South trade and its growing signi�cance in rebal-

ancing international capital �ows and national current accounts, the bulk of the existing literature

on global imbalances does not distinguish �nancial capital from �xed capital �ows. Failing to

distinguish these two forms of capital �ows not only obscures our description of the reality but

may also impede correct theoretical analysis and empirical testing of di¤erent models aiming at

explaining the global imbalances.

Why do �xed capital and �nancial capital move in the opposite directions between South and

North? Why do developing countries (such as China) lend massively to rich countries at low (or

possibly negative) real interest rate while willing to pay dearly (high returns) to attract foreign

investment? In other words, why does the South lend cheaply and borrow expensively at the same

2A nation�s current account balance (CAt) is de�ned as the net changes in foreign asset positions (NFAt):

CAt = NFAt �NFAt�1;

which is zero in the steady state. Since the current account equals net exports (NXt) plus net factor payments(rtNFAt), where r denotes the interest rate, we have in the steady state NX = �rNFA. Thus, if the country hasa negative foreign asset position because of capital in�ows (NFA < 0), it runs current account surplus in the steadystate.

3

Page 4: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

time? Are such seemingly irrational behaviors caused by distorted exchange rates and are they

sustainable? Finally, what are the welfare implications of such two-way capital �ows?

Standard neoclassical growth model and its open-economy analogue cannot answer these ques-

tions. These models assume that �nancial assets and �xed capital are either the same thing or have

the same (or similar) rate of returns under arbitrage. Hence, if capitals move across boarders at all,

they ought to �ow in the same direction� consequently, the global imbalances are not sustainable.

But such a synchronized (unidirectional) one-way capital �ow is not what is observed in reality.

Intuitively, because capital �ows are driven by rates of returns, the observed two-way capital

�ows may suggest that the South has a higher rate of return to �xed capital but a lower rate of

return (interest rate) for �nancial capital, so �nancial assets are relatively more attractive in the

North while �xed investment more pro�table in the South. But what economic forces (frictions)

might generate such a gap between the interest rate and the return to �xed capital that can explain

the magnitudes of the imbalanced two-way capital �ows? Why have not arbitrage activities closed

the gap? In particular, why cannot Chinese �rms bring down their MPKs by borrowing cheaply at

low domestic interest rate?

This paper provides an explanation for the two-way capital �ow puzzle by augmenting the neo-

classical growth model with �nancial frictions. Speci�cally, following the approach of Gourinchas

and Jeanne (2011), we augment the neoclassical growth model with two wedges: one wedge that

distorts �rms�investment decisions, and one wedge that distorts households�saving decisions. How-

ever, unlike Gourinchas and Jeanne�s (2011) approach where the wedges are ad hoc black boxes,

we derive these wedges explicitly through �nancial frictions, thus providing micro foundations for

these theoretical constructs.

Our story goes as follows. Due to underdeveloped banking-credit-�nancial system, both house-

holds and �rms in the South are severely borrowing constrained. As a result, households save

excessively to self-insure against unpredictable shocks and �rms rely heavily on internal cash �ows

to �nance �xed investment. Since domestic savings by households cannot be e¤ectively channeled

to �rms where �xed capital formation takes place, �xed capital is scarce in the production sector

while savings are abundant in the household sector. In such a world, the rate of return to �nancial

assets can be signi�cantly lower than that of �xed capital. In China, for example, the real rate of

return to �xed capital has been over 20% in the past decades while the real rate of return to �nan-

cial capital (such as bank deposits and short-term bonds) has been negative (Bai, Hsieh and Qian,

2006). Despite such an enormous gap, households in China save excessively and the bulk of their

savings is in the form of bank deposits (Wen, 2010, 2011). This enormous arbitrage opportunity

implies that �nancial liberalization between the South and the North will trigger two-way capital

�ows. Because it is relatively easier for �nancial capital to �ow internationally than shipping �xed

capital abroad (e.g., transportation costs), the former will dominate the latter in global capital

4

Page 5: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

�ows, resulting in short-run current account imbalances. In addition, because the rates of return to

�xed and �nancial capital di¤er, the net income (interest) payments to the opposite capital �ows

do not cancel out, further contributing to global trade imbalances in the long run.

Therefore, in contrast to the standard neoclassical theory that attributes high MPK in the

South to low household savings, we show how the lack of e¢ cient �nancial system in the South can

lead to insu¢ cient investment on the �rm side but savings glut on the household side, resulting

in a high MPK and a low interest rate at the same time. This wedge in rates of return drives

the observed two-way capital �ows between developing and developed countries and the current

account imbalances. More importantly, such two-way capital �ows can sustain permanent trade

imbalances even if the current account is perfectly balanced at zero.3

Our model can be calibrated to match (i) the observed gap between �nancial interest rate and

the rate of return to �xed capital in China and those in the developed countries, (ii) the high Chinese

saving rate, and (iii) the massive and growing trends in two-way capital �ows between China and

its trading partners. The model also generates predictions that cast doubt on conventional wisdom

in several fronts. First, Obstfeld and Rogo¤ (2000, 2007) have argued that a permanent trade

imbalance is unsustainable, thus predicting that a reversal of the U.S. current account de�cit is

inevitable and that the future U.S. trade surplus requires substantial depreciation of the dollar real

exchange rate. Our model predicts instead that the U.S. is able to sustain a trade de�cit of at least

3% of GDP permanently with China unless �nancial markets in China develop to the same degree

as in the U.S.

Second, the popular view holds that the "saving glut" in emerging markets is responsible for the

declining and sustained low interest rate in the U.S. (Bernanke, 2005). Our quantitative analysis

shows that �nancial capital out�ows from the South has negligible impact on the interest rate in the

North. At the peak of the impact after �nancial liberalization, the world interest rate in our model

is reduced by less than 0.2 percentage points (or 20 basis points), and this e¤ect dies out quickly

in 2 years despite persistent increase in capital �ows (reaching over 30% of world GDP in terms

of accumulated net foreign asset positions and 4% of world GDP in terms of trade imbalances,

consistent with what is observed in the data).

Third, two-way capital �ows have distinct welfare implications. The accepted wisdom (e.g.,

Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas, 2008; MQR, 2009; Ju and Wei, 2010) is that developed countries

gain unambiguously while developing countries lose after �nancial liberalization. We show instead

that the opposite may be true: In general, capital exporting countries gain unambiguously from

�nancial liberalization while capital importing countries may gain or lose depending on the speci�c

form of capital in�ows. In addition, the welfare gains from the consumption margin and the leisure

3That is, imbalanced trade exists even if �nancial capital �ows and �xed capital �ows exactly cancel (balance)each other� because the cross-country net factor payments do not cancel each other due to the investment wedge.

5

Page 6: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

margin are quite di¤erent and often with the opposite sign.

Our analysis is related to a large and growing literature on global imbalances. Caballero et al.

(2008) attribute the global imbalances to the inability of the South to generate saving instruments,

thus causing the reversed capital �ow after �nancial liberalization. MQR (2009) attributes the

global imbalances to the heterogeneous degrees of �nancial development between developed and

developing countries. Such a heterogeneity implies that households in the North prefer more risky

equity in their portfolio than in the South, inducing the South to maintain a positive net asset

position in risk-free bonds. Similar to MQR (2009), Angeletos and Panousi (AP, 2011) attribute

global imbalances to heterogeneous degree of idiosyncratic risks between the North and the South.

Out�ows of �nancial capital from the South is driven by its low interest rate under the precautionary

saving motives. Similar to our paper, AP allow �rms to accumulate �xed capital and their model

can also generate a wedge between the MPK and the real interest rate. Di¤erent from our study,

however, AP do not study FDI and two-way capital �ows. Related works also include Ohanian and

Wright (2007), Sandri (2008), Carroll and Jeanne (2009), Durdu, Mendoza, and Terrones (2009),

Buera and Shin (2010), Ju and Wei (2010), Chien and Naknoi (2011), Song, Storesletten, and

Zilibotti (2011), Gourinchas and Jeanne (2011), and Wen (2011), among many others.4

However, the bulk of this literature does not distinguish (unbundle) �nancial capital and �xed

capital �ows. As such, many of the models proposed to explain the global imbalances would be

inconsistent with the empirical pattern of the two-way capital �ows and trade imbalances. Typically,

because no distinction is made between household savings and �rms��xed capital stocks, such a

model would imply excess domestic savings in the form of tangible capital goods and these capital

goods are then rented to foreign �rms as a way of capital out�ows (e.g., Carroll and Jeanne,

2009). This particular form of capital out�ows from the South to the North is inconsistent with

the empirical facts.5 In addition, persistent capital �ows from the South to the North would imply

that the North runs trade surplus (instead of de�cits) with the South in the long run because of

positive interest payment to the South. This prediction is not yet observed in the data.

To the best of our knowledge, little previous work has addressed the issue of two-way capital

�ows and their distinct welfare implications in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE)

framework. The work closest to ours includes MQR (2009) and Chien and Naknoi (CN, 2011).6

Our approach complements that of MQR in several aspects. In contrast to our full-�edged DSGE

4This paper does not address the main issues raised by Wen (2011), especially the positive relationship betweenChina�s high saving rate and rapid income growth rate and the connection between capital controls and trade.

5Such a model that can generate low interest rate through precautionary savings would also imply low MPK (i.e.,Aiyagari, 1994); but the saving glut countries have high MPKs.

6Also see Hageny and Zhang (2011), Wen (2011), and Ju and Wei (2006, 2010). However, the model of Hagenyand Zhang (2011) is a deterministic 2-period model with a fundamentally di¤erent setup from ours; the model ofWen (2011) is a small open economy model with a focus on household savings; and the model of Ju and Wei (2010)is a static non-neoclassical model with a focus on corporate governance and property rights as the main frictions.

6

Page 7: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

model, MQR assume that the stock of aggregate capital is �xed in each country and there is

no labor market. Consequently, there are no cross-country �xed capital �ows in their model by

assumption.7 Most importantly, FDI in the model of MQR is modeled as purchasing foreign �rms�

equities. While foreign equity holding is a special form of FDI, it is no longer the major form

of FDI in reality. Data show that the currently dominate form of FDI is setting up new �rms or

establishing new a¢ liations in foreign countries by exporting technology-embodied �xed capital and

receiving factor payments as capital owners. For example, based on BEA�s de�nition, out of the

total non-�nancial capital out�ows from the United States to the rest of the world, the particular

form of FDI assumed in the model of MQR (2009) accounts for less than 38% of total FDI, leaving

more than 62% of American�s FDI unexplained. In contrast, the speci�c form of FDI studied in our

paper accounts for more than 76% of U.S. FDI out�ows to China. Also, out of China�s total FDI

in�ows from developed countries, the new establishment of a¢ liations (or �rms) with ownership

fully belong to foreigners account for 80% of China�s total inward FDI in the years of 2009 and

2010 and this number is still growing over time.8 Therefore, our approach represents a step forward

toward understanding the mechanisms of FDI and its role in global imbalances.

Moreover, the model of MQR generates trade surplus for the U.S. in the longer term. In their

model the interest payment on the in�ow of �nancial capital from developing countries outweigh

the returns from outward FDI, so the U.S. net foreign income payment is positive in the steady

state. Hence, their model does not lend support for the notion that the persistent U.S. trade de�cits

with China and the rest of the world may be sustainable in the long run.

In addition, the model of MQR is not analytically tractable. Because of computational burdens,

MQR need to rule out any aggregate risks in their model. Without aggregate uncertainty, their

model generates only a small risk premium for the rate of return to FDI (i.e., equity holdings

of foreign capital stocks), and this small risk premium leads to a positive net factor payment

(interest payment - FDI earnings) in their model. To overcome the computational challenge under

aggregate risk, CN (2011) simpli�es the MQRmodel to a pure endowment economy and use a special

algorithm to numerically solve the model. CN show that with aggregate uncertainty (stochastic

output growth), the model can generate a large risk premium between equity and risk-free bonds,

thus able to generate long-term trade de�cits for the U.S. However, the CN model is not suited for

studying the two-way capital �ows discussed in this paper because it is an endowment economy

without capital. In addition, CN do not study the welfare consequences of �nancial liberalization.

In contrast, the wedge between the risk-free rate and the rate of return to FDI in our model

does not hinge on the equity premium, but rather on Tobin�s q because we allow �rms to undertake

�xed investment (Tobin�s q is precisely the wedge between the MPK and the �nancial interest

7However, they allow non-reproducible managerial capital or human capital to be reallocated across boarders.8See the Data Appendix (B.8) for details of the classi�cations and compositions of FDI in the U.S. and China.

7

Page 8: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

rate). As long as �rms�borrowing constraints are tighter in developing countries, the South will

have a higher MPK and experience long-run trade surplus with the North regardless of aggregate

uncertainty. In addition, since decision rules can be solved in closed forms at the individual level,

introducing aggregate risk into our model does not create computational burdens at all.9 Therefore,

our model permits transparent analysis of the welfare of �nancial liberalization as well as business

cycle e¤ects of �nancial shocks on the current account and trade balance.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents stylized facts about the two-

way capital �ows between China (representing the South) and the U.S. (representing the North).

Section 3 and 4 present our model. Section 5 studies the conditions for generating two-way capital

�ows. Section 6 provides quantitative predictions and welfare analyses. Section 7 concludes thepaper.

2 Stylized Facts

We decompose global capital �ows into �nancial capital �ows and non-�nancial capital (FDI) �ows.

We use data from China to represent developing countries and those from the U.S. to represent the

developed world.10 We have the following three observations.

1 China is a net exporter of �nancial capital and a net importer of FDI, whereas the U.S. holds

the opposite asset positions against developing countries (such as China).

Fig. 1a. U.S.-China Foreign Asset Positions Fig 1b. China�s Foreign Asset Positions

Figure 1a shows the net foreign asset positions of the U.S. with respect to China. In particular,

the upward trended line (dashed) is the accumulated net FDI out�ows from the U.S. to China as a

share of U.S. GDP (right axis), and the negative downward trended line (solid) is the accumulated

9Aggregate uncertainty does not a¤ect how individuals obtain closed-form solutions for their decision rules ifaggregate shocks are orthogonal to idiosyncratic shocks.10Appendix B provides details about these data series.

8

Page 9: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

net �nancial capital in�ows from China to the U.S. as a share of U.S. GDP (left axis). Figure 1b

plots the net foreign asset positions of China against the rest of the world. The positive and upward

trended line (solid) is China�s total accumulated net foreign asset positions for �nancial capital,

which accounts for about 60% of China�s GDP in 2010. The negative and downward trended line

(dashed) is China�s total accumulated net FDI in�ows, which accounts for about 30% of China�s

GDP in 2010.11

2 China has a signi�cantly higher rate of return to �xed capital and a signi�cantly lower rate

of return to �nancial capital than the U.S.

Figure 2. Rate of Return to Capital and Real Interest Rate in China andU.S.

The top panel in Figure 2 compares the before-tax rates of return to �xed capital in China and

the U.S. As shown, China�s capital return (the red line) stays at a very high level in the entire

sample period, with a mean of 23%. In contrast, the rate of return to �xed capital in the U.S. (the

blue line) lies signi�cantly below that of China for the entire sample period, with a mean around

10%. The spread remains large though the entire sample period with only a slight decline beginning

in the middle 1990s.12

11Because China has been growing much faster than the U.S., the FDI in�ows to China appear to have sloweddown in recent years relative to China�s GDP (Figure 1b). However, the U.S. FDI to China did not show such apattern as a share of U.S. GDP (Figure 1a).12The after-tax rate of return in China is about 13% while the that in the U.S. is about 7%. Therefore, even taking

tax adjustment into account, the rates of return to �xed capital in the two countries are still signi�cantly di¤erent

9

Page 10: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Table 1. Real Interest Rates (Annual, 1990-2011)

Period 1 Month 3 Month 6 Month 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 5 Year

China (In�ation Rate = 4:78)Deposit Rate �3: 6 �1: 79 �0:93 �0:13 0:44 1: 01 1: 62Gov. Bond �2: 67 �2: 58 �1: 88 �1: 77 �1: 35

U.S. (In�ation Rate = 2:75)CD 1: 07 1: 15 1: 26T-Bill 0:69 0:8 1: 18 2: 06

In contrast, the lower panel in Figure 2 show that there also exists a systematic di¤erence in the

rates of return to �nancial capital between the two countries, except that the spread is reversed.

For example, the real interest rate (de�ned as the risk adjusted annual lending rate) in the U.S. is

about 6 percentage points (per unit of risk) on average while that in China is about 1 percent on

average. Table 1 also reveals that a systematic cross-country gap of about 3 percentage points in

the real interest rate exists when bank deposit rates and government bond rates are compared.13

3 China has a less developed �nancial market than the U.S.

Figure 3. Financial Development in China and U.S.

from each other. We also calculate U.S. rate of return to �xed capital through Poterba (1998) method,the result changes little.13The real rates in Table 1 are computed using CPI in�ation rate in each country. U.S. data are from FRED.

Chinese data are from People�s Bank of China.

10

Page 11: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Figure 3 shows that private credit-to-GDP ratios in both China and the U.S. have been rising

gradually over time, which may indicate �nancial improvement in both countries over time. How-

ever, the disparity between two countries is large and does not show any tendency of diminishing

in time. Similar results obtain when we use other measures of �nancial development, such as the

�nancial-development index in the World Competitiveness Report.14

Intuitively, the within- and cross-country disparities in asset returns in �xed and �nancial capital

(observation 2) are the main driving force of international two-way capital �ows (observation 1).

But the question is: What economic frictions might generate these disparities in asset returns

within and across countries? In our two-country theoretical model, we will make observation 3 as

a key assumption to generate observation 2, and hence explaining observation 1 both qualitatively

and quantitatively, among other things.

3 The Model

We consider an in�nite-horizon economy with two countries, labelled by "h" (home) and "f"

(foreign), respectively. There is no aggregate uncertainty.15 Each country is made up of two types

of heterogeneous agents: consumers and �rms with equal mass normalized to 1. We use i 2 [0; 1] toindex heterogeneous households and j 2 [0; 1] to index heterogeneous �rms. Both households and�rms are subject to idiosyncratic risks and borrowing constraints (to be speci�ed below). Firms

accumulate capital and combine labor and capital to produce consumption goods. Households

supply labor to �rms and can hold bonds and �rms�stocks (or equities) as means of savings. There

are two types of bonds, issued by h-country and f -country, respectively. Each country issues its

own country-speci�c bonds and no country can issue foreign bonds. To simplify the analysis, we

assume that bonds are the only tradable �nancial assets across countries.16 However, �rms can

invest in foreign country through FDI. We use the tightness of borrowing constraints to indicate

the degree of �nancial development in each country, as is standard in the literature (e.g., MQR,

2009). Because �rms are heterogeneous, each consumer hold a portfolio of �rms�equities, taken as

given the market prices of the portfolios.

We focus our analysis on the home country in what follows. The foreign country�s problem is

14We follow the existing literature (e.g., King and Levine, 1993) by using total private credit-to-GDP ratio as ameasure of �nancial development because this variable captures the ability of �nancial intermediaries to allocatecredit. A persistently higher value in this ratio thus indicates a better �nancial system. The World CompetitivenessReport (WCR) is released by the world development forum annually, and one part of the indices is relevant to�nancial development. Suppose we employ "Financial Market Sophistication" index as an indicator for the �nancialdevelopment, the index of China is signi�cantly lower than the U.S. Moreover, the gap remains highly stable over thetime.15 It is straightforward to introduce aggregate uncertainty in our model and this will not a¤ect our results.16Allowing households to hold foreign �rms� equities does not change our results because bonds and equity are

perfect substitutes for households. This simplifying assumption is made so we can focus on FDI in the form ofshipping �xed capital across boarders and not to mix it with acquiring the ownership of foreign �rms through equityholdings.

11

Page 12: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

similar and analogous results can be obtained by simply switching the superscript from "h" to "f".

Whenever convenient, we use ` = fh; fg as the country index and use `c to denote the counterpartof country `.

3.1 Households

Households are subject to uninsurable idiosyncratic preference shocks (to the marginal utility of

consumption). Such shocks capture the idiosyncratic uncertainty in consumption expenditures.

Wen (2011) argues that such uncertainty in spending needs is extremely large in China due to the

high probability of injuries, health hazards, and the stochastically rising costs of living. In each time

period t, Household i derives utility from consumption chit and leisure 1 � nhit. The instantaneous

utility function is quasi-linear, �hit log chit � hnhit, where the preference shock �

hit is drawn from a

common distribution F (�) = Pr [�i � �] with support [�min; �max].

Each time period is divided into two sub-periods. The idiosyncratic preference shocks are

realized in the second sub-period. Each household i chooses labor supply nhit in the �rst sub-period

without observing �hit. This implies that households cannot use labor supply to insure themselves

against the idiosyncratic shocks. Consumption and saving decisions are made in the second sub-

period after preference shocks are realized. Speci�cally, after choosing nhit and upon observing �hit,

household i chooses consumption chit, savings in domestic bonds shit+1, savings in foreign bonds

~shit+1, and savings in �rms�equities ahit+1. As shown by Wen (2009, 2011), such an information

and market structure permits closed-form solutions for household decision rules with imcomplete

markets and borrowing constraints.

Denoting Qht as the price index of a portfolio of �rms�equities (stocks) and Dht as the aggregate

dividend paid to the portfolio (capturing the rate of return to stocks), the borrowing constraint

facing each household is speci�ed as

shit+1 + ~shit+1 + a

hit+1Q

ht � �Bht ; (1)

where ahit+1 is the share of the portfolio newly purchased by the household in period t, and Bht � 0

is an exogenously speci�ed borrowing limit (as in Aiyagari, 1994), which captures the degree of

�nancial development on the household side in country h at time t.

Since countries cannot issue foreign bonds (although households can hold foreign bonds), we

have

~shit+1 � 0 (2)

for all i 2 [0; 1]. This implies that if a country opts to borrow abroad, it must sell its home bonds

12

Page 13: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

to foreigners.17

Taking as given the real wage W ht and the real interest rates at home and abroad, household i

solves

maxfnhit;chit;shit+1;~shit+1;ahit+1g

E0

" 1Xt=0

�t��hit log c

hit � hnhit

�#; (3)

subject to constraints (1) and (2), as well as the budget constraint

chit + shit+1 + ~s

hit+1 + a

hit+1Q

ht � Rhbt�1s

hit +R

fbt�1~s

hit � s

�~shit�1+�

1 + �+W h

t nhit +

�Qht +D

ht

�ahit; (4)

wherenRhbt; R

fbt

odenote domestic and foreign interest rate, respectively, and s

(~shit)1+�

1+� denote the

convex cross-border trading costs for purchasing foreign bonds (with s � 0 and � > 0).18

3.2 Firms

Each �rm j with capital stock Khjt can choose to produce both at home and abroad. A �rm

combines labor and capital to produce output through the Cobb-Douglas technology with capital

share � and labor share 1 � �. Each �rm accumulates productive capital according to the law of

motion,

Khjt+1 = (1� �)Kh

jt + "hjtI

hjt; (5)

where Ijt denotes investment expenditures and "hjt 2 R+ is an idiosyncratic shock to the marginal

e¢ ciency of investment, which is i.i.d across �rms and over time (as in Wang and Wen, 2012). We

denote the probability density function of "hjt by � (") and the cumulative density function by � (").

With heterogenous households, the �rm�s dynamic programing problem becomes slightly more

complicated. The �rst step is to �nd the right discounting factor. We follow Hansen and Richard

(1987), Cochrane (1991), and Wang, Xu and Xu (2011) to assume that there exists a sequence of

prices�P ht1t=0

such that a �rm�s expected value is determined by

V hjt = Et

" 1X�=0

P ht+�P ht

Dhjt+�

#; (6)

17The constraint in equation (2) is not essential. Our general results hold if we simply allow an international bondwith a world interest rate. However, to capture the di¤erent interest rates in China and the U.S. both before andafter �nancial liberalization, we need to have domestic and foreign bonds and asymmetric trading costs.18We assume that there exist cross-boarder trading costs in purchasing foreign bonds and the costs are increasing

in the trading volume. This assumption is not necessary for our general results but is needed only for capturingthe transitional dynamics of international �nancial capital �ows after �nancial liberalization. China opens up itscapital markets only gradually; even today it�s capital markets are not completely open. So the rationale for suchtrading costs include capital controls in developing countries besides other transaction costs discussed in the literature.However, our qualitative results do not hinge on the assumption of trading costs and our model nests the standardmodels with zero trading costs as a special case.

13

Page 14: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

where fDhjt+�g1�=0 is the dividend �ows generated by �rm j and the expectation operator E is taken

on the idiosyncratic shock "hjt. Denote �ht � P ht =

��h�t, where �h < 1, we can rewrite the �rm�s

expected value as V hjt = Et

hP1�=0

��h�� �ht+�

�htDhjt+�

i, which can be rewritten recursively as19

V hjt =

Z Dhjt + �

hEt�ht+1�ht

V hjt+1

!d�: (7)

Notice that because of heterogeneity on the household side, �h does not necessarily equal the

household�s discounting factor �: With the �rm value given by equation (7), the �rm�s problem is

then to maximize its expected value V hjt by choosing labor demand, capital allocation (the share of

FDI), and the level of �xed investment.

In the beginning of each period, �rm j decides to allocate 1 � uhjt fraction of its �xed capital

stock (Khjt) at home and the remaining u

hjt fraction of the capital stock abroad.

20 We assume that

there are costs in reallocating �xed capital across borders and a �rm needs to pay the amount

k(uhjt)

1+�

1+� Khjt to move u

hjt fraction of its capital stock abroad. The parameter k (> 0) and � (> 0)

control capital mobility and the extent of openness for the �xed capital market. For example, when

k = 1, cross-border �xed capital �ows are completely shut down. When k = 0, FDI �ows canbe adjusted instantaneously without any costs. This parameter also captures institutional costs for

setting up foreign business and policies designed to attract FDI through reducing such frictions.21

The optimal choices of uhjt as well as labor inputs are static. Given the capital stock Khjt; the

�rm j�s operating pro�ts �hjt can be derived through the following maximization problem:

maxfuhjt;Nh

jtg

8><>:(1� uhjt)��Khjt

�� �Nhjt

�1���W h

t Nhjt +

�uhjt

�� �Khjt

�� �Xhjt

�1���W f

t Xhjt � k

�uhjt

�1+�1 + �

Khjt

9>=>;(8)

where W ht and W

ft are the real wage in home country and foreign country, respectively, N

hjt is the

demand for domestic labor, and Xhjt is the demand for foreign labor.

19Notice that by our de�nition of �rm�s value, the value function Vjt is independent of the �rm�s idiosyncraticshock "jt in period t. This approach simpli�es our notation but is not essential for our results. Alternatively, we

could de�ne a �rm�s value as V hjt = Dh

jt + �hEt�ht+1

�htV hjt+1, so that it depends on period-t�s shock "jt.

20The outward FDI of the home country in our model is thus uhtKht . According to the BEA data source, this form

of FDI dominates other forms of FDI �ows.21Even though �nancial and �xed capital move in the opposite directions, net aggregate capital (�nancial plus

�xed) still shows the reversed pattern noticed by Lucas (1990). The net foreign asset positions of a country (sum ofnet �ows in �nancial and �xed capitals) is determined by the liquidity (mobility) of the two forms of capital. Thusthe adjustment costs enable our model to quantitatively match the imbalanced two-way capital �ows between Chinaand the U.S.

14

Page 15: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

We now discuss the �rm�s dynamic optimization problem in choosing investment Ihjt. Denote

V ht

�Khjt

�as the expected value of the �rm with capital stockKh

jt at the beginning of period t before

observing "hjt. This value function can now be de�ned recursively using the proper discounting factor

�h�ht+1�ht

as

V ht

�Khjt

�=

ZmaxIhjt

"�hjt � Ihjt + �hEt

�ht+1�ht

V ht+1

�(1� �)Kh

jt + "hjtI

hjt

�#d�: (9)

We assume that �rm j can use both internal funds, �hjt(Khjt), and outside funds (from borrowing),

Lhjt, to �nance investment. Hence, the maximum investment is subject to the constraint:

Ihjt � Lhjt +�hjt: (10)

For simplicity, we assume that the external funds are raised through intra-period loans: �rms

can borrow from �nancial intermediaries at the beginning of period t and pay back at the end of

period t with zero interest rate. Since in each period some �rms will opt not to invest (Ihjt = 0),

�nancial intermediaries can collect these inactive �rms�savings and lend to investing �rms after

paying dividends to equity holders (households).

Loans are subject to collateral constraints, as in Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). That is, �rm

j is allowed to pledge a fraction �h 2 (0; 1] of its �xed capital stock Khjt at the beginning of

period t as the collateral. In general, the parameter �h represents the extent of �nancial market

imperfections� the higher the value of �h; the more a �rm can borrow and thus more advanced

the �nancial market is (as shown in Figure 3). In the end of period t, the market value of the

pledged collateral is equal to �h�ht+1�ht

V ht+1

��hKh

jt

�, which is the present value of the collateral of

�rm j at the beginning of period t+1, or equivalently the value of a �rm who owns collateralizable

capital stock �hKhjt. The amount of loans L

hjt cannot exceed this collateral value because of limited

contract enforcement. Thus, we impose the following collateral constraint:

Lhjt � �h�ht+1�ht

V ht+1

��hKh

jt

�: (11)

We also assume that investment is irreversible as in Wang and Wen (2012),

Ihjt � 0: (12)

To sum up, each �rm j solves the static problem (60) by choosing FDI uhjt and the dynamic

programming problem (9) by choosing investment Ihjt subject to constraints (10), (11), and (12).

15

Page 16: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

3.3 Financial intermediation

The �nancial intermediation in our model is stylized. A representative �nancial intermediary holds

a portfolio consisting of all �rms�stocks and collects the aggregate dividends Dht from all �rms:

Dht =

Z �RhktK

hjt � Ihjt

�dj: (13)

Although the �nancial intermediary makes intra-period loans to �rms using the dividends, the loans

are all paid back within the period, so they do not a¤ect the end-of-period aggregate dividends.

The price of such portfolio, Qht ; is hence

Qht = �h�ht+1�ht

hQht+1 +D

ht+1

i: (14)

Alternatively, one can also assume that households directly hold a market portfolio of equities that

consists of stocks of all �rms, and the equilibrium results will be the same.

3.4 General Equilibrium

We denote the aggregate capital stock, aggregate investment, aggregate labor demand, aggre-

gate output, aggregate labor supply, aggregate bonds holdings, aggregate household savings, and

aggregate consumption in country ` by K`t =

R 10 K

`jtdj; I

`t =

R 10 I

`jtdj; N

`t =

R 10 N

`jtdj; X

`t =R 1

0 X`jtdj; Y

`t =

R 10 Y

`jtdj; n

`t =

R 10 n

`itdi; S

`t =

Rs`itdi;

~S`t =R~s`itdi; and C`t =

R 10 c

`itdi, respec-

tively. The general equilibrium of the model is de�ned as the sequences of aggregate variables,

{K`t ; I

`t ; N

`t ; X

`t ; Y

`t ; n

`t; S

`t ; ~S

`t ; C

`t }, individual �rms�decisions, {K

`jt; I

`jt; N

`jt; L

`jt; Y

`jt}, individual house-

holds�choices,�n`it; s

`it; ~s

`it; c

`it

; and aggregate prices,

�Q`t;W

`t ; R

`kt; R

`bt

, for ` 2 fh; fg, such that

each �rm and each household solve their optimization problems and all markets (labor, equity, and

bonds markets) clear:

N `t +X

`ct �

Z 1

0N `jtdj +

Z 1

0X`cjt dj = n`t; for ` 2 fh; fg (15)

Za`itdi = 1; for ` 2 fh; fg : (16)

Notice that in a �nancial autarky regime, the bonds market-clearing conditions are

Sht = Sft =~Sht =

~Sft = 0; (17)

16

Page 17: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

whereas in a �nancial liberalization regime, the bonds market-clearing conditions are

Sht + ~Sft = Sft +~Sht = 0; (18)

where ~S`t denotes country `�s holdings of the other country�s (foreign) bonds. The aggregate capital

stock evolves according to

K`t+1 = (1� �)K`

t +

Z"`jtI

`jtdj; for ` 2 fh; fg : (19)

4 Solving the General Equilibrium

Since our model permits closed-form solutions for individual decision rules that are independent

of each individual�s history, the distributions of individual variables can be obtained analytically

by the law of large numbers. The result is a system of non-linear dynamic equations for aggregate

variables. This means that solving the general equilibrium path of the aggregate model is then the

same as solving a representative-agent DSGE model. In what follows, we �rst derive the optimal

decision rules of a single �rm and a single household in turn. We then aggregate their individual

choices by the law of large numbers and solve the market competitive equilibrium by perturbation

methods as in the standard RBC literature.

4.1 A single �rm�s decision rules

Denoting rt as the marginal product of capital and Rkt as the marginal pro�t@�jt@Kjt

(gross rate

of return to �xed capital) of a �rm. The following proposition shows that frt; Rktg are bothindependent of �rms�idiosyncratic shocks and are closely related to each other. For convenience of

analysis, we will call Rkt (instead of rt) the marginal product of capital (MPK) in the rest of the

paper unless confusion arises.

Proposition 1 Givennrht ; r

ft

o, the optimal FDI decision (uhjt) is given by

uhjt =

8><>:0 if rft � rht�

rft �rht k

� 1�

if rft > rht; (20)

and the gross MPK (gross rate of return to �xed capital) is determined by

MPK � Rhkt = rht + 1rft >rht

��

1 + � � 1�

k

�rft � rht

� 1+��

�; (21)

17

Page 18: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

where 1rft >r

htis an index function that takes a value of 1 whenever rft > rht and a value of 0

otherwise.

Proof. See Appendix A.1.

So a �rm�s FDI decision depends completely on the spread of marginal product of capital

between the two countries.22 It can be shown easily that the function MPK is strictly increasing

in rht and weakly increasing (non-decreasing) in rft . Because of constant returns to scale (CRS)

production function and i.i.d. investment-e¢ ciency shocks, both Rkt and rt are independent of

�rms�idiosyncratic shocks. Based on this important property, we conjecture that the value of a

�rm is given by the following functional form suggested by Hayashi (1982):

V ht

�Khjt

�= vhtK

hjt; (22)

where vht is the average (and marginal) value of a �rm and it depends only on the aggregate states.

Hence, it is free of the �rm index j. We de�ne qht = �hEt�ht+1�ht

vht+1, which is the conventional measure

of Tobin�s q (to be shown later). With the conjectured value function, the �rm�s investment problem

becomes

vhtKhjt =

Z"jt

maxIhjt

nRhktK

hjt � Ihjt + qht

h(1� �)Kh

jt + "hjtI

hjt

iod�; (23)

subject to the constraints (10), (12), and

Lhjt � qht �hKh

jt: (24)

Proposition 2 There exists a cut-o¤ �"ht =1qht, such that the �rm�s optimal investment decisions

follow a trigger strategy:

Ihjt =

8<:qht �

hKhjt +R

hktK

hjt if "hjt > �"

ht

0 otherwise: (25)

In addition, the marginal value of the �rm is given by

vht = Rhkt + (1� �) qht +�qht �

h +Rhkt

��qht

�; (26)

where �qht��R"hjt>1=q

ht

�qht "

hjt � 1

�d� with 0

�qht�> 0; and Tobin�s q (qht ) evolves according to

qht = �hEt�ht+1�ht

hRhkt+1 + (1� �)qht+1 + (qht+1�h +Rhkt+1)

�qht+1

�i: (27)

22We assume that the value of k is big enough to ensure uhjt < 1.

18

Page 19: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Proof. See Appendix A.2.

Brie�y speaking, vht is the value of one unit of existing capital and qht is the value of one unit of

newly installed capital. The marginal bene�t of new investment is thus qht "hjt. Since the real cost

of investment is one, investment is pro�table if qht "hjt > 1 or "hjt > �"ht � 1=qht , which de�nes the

cuto¤. In such a case, the �rm is willing to borrow as much as possible to invest, so its borrowing

constraint binds. This explains the investment decision rule in equation (25).

By de�nition, qht equals the discounted future value of one unit of capital in the next period

�hEt�ht+1�ht

vht+1, which is equation (27) after substitution using equation (26). The average (marginal)

value of the �rm (vht ) consists of three parts on the right hand side of equation (26). First,

one unit of capital can generate Rhkt units of operating pro�t in period t. Second, one unit of

capital can carry 1� � remaining units to the next period with value (1� �) qht after depreciation.

Finally, the capital can also be used as collateral. With probability 1 � ��1qht

�, the �rm has a

pro�table investment opportunity and one unit of capital is able to obtain qht �h units of loans,

which can expand investment by (qht �h +Rhkt) units by equation (25). After paying back the loans

at zero interest rate, the net value of the loan is�qht "

hjt � 1

�; hence, the value of the collateral is�

qht �h +Rhkt

� R"hjt>1=q

ht

�qht "

hjt � 1

�d�. This explains equation (27).

4.2 A single household�s decision rules

Proposition 3 The optimal demand for foreign bonds ~shit+1 is given by

~shit+1 =

8><>:0 if Rhbt � Rfbt�

Rfbt�Rhbt

s

� 1�

if Rhbt < Rfbt: (28)

Further, arbitrage among �nancial assets implies that the portfolio�s price satis�es

Qht =Qht+1 +D

ht+1

Rhbt: (29)

Namely, the risk free rate is the proper discounting factor for the �rms.

Proof. See Appendix A.3.

The demand for foreign bonds is an increasing function of the cross-country interest spread, Rfbt�

Rhbt, provided that the spread is positive. The parameter s determines the cost of holding foreign

19

Page 20: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

bonds; it thus represents the extent of capital controls or transaction costs in the international

bonds market. Financial autarky for bond trading obtains if s = 1. In the limit as s ! 0, the

two interest rates, Rfbt and Rhbt, must be equalized in general equilibrium, so the model reduces to

the standard setting with a single international bond.

Note that even for households with high realizations of preference shocks (or with a high urge

to consume), they may still hold positive amount of foreign bonds ~shit+1 provided that Rfbt > Rhbt,

because they can borrow from the domestic bond market, i.e., shit+1 < 0. More importantly,

equation (28) implies that the country with lower interest rate will have a positive net out�ows in

�nancial capital. Thus, to show the direction of �nancial capital �ows, we only need to compare

the interest rates in the two countries.Denoting

Hhit =

�Qht +D

ht

�ahit +W

ht n

hit +R

hbt�1s

hit +R

fbt�1~s

hit � s

�~shit

�1+�=(1 + �) (30)

as the gross wealth of household i in period t, the following proposition shows that the house-

hold�s consumption-saving decisions follow simple rules and that the distribution of gross wealth is

degenerate across households (i.e., Hhit = Hh

t for all i).

Proposition 4 Given the real wage W ht and the real interest rate R

hbt, the optimal consumption

and saving of household i are given, respectively, by

chit = min

(�hit��ht

; 1

)�Hht +B

ht

�; (31)

shit+1 + ~shit+1 + a

hit+1Q

ht = max

(��ht � �hit��ht

; 0

)�Hht +B

ht

��Bht ; (32)

where the target wealth Hht and the cuto¤ ��

ht are independent of i and are jointly determined by the

following two equations:

��ht = �Rhbt

�Hht +B

ht

�Et

h

W ht+1

!; (33)

and

W ht

Zmax(�; ��

ht )

Hht +B

ht

d� = h: (34)

Proof. See Appendix A.4.

20

Page 21: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

To facilitate analysis, we assume that the borrowing limit of the households is proportional to

some aggregate variables, say, B`t = b`q`tK`t , where the parameter b

` � 0 measures the tightness ofborrowing constraints on the household side. A speci�c borrowing limit like this permits balanced

growth and facilitates steady-state calibrations.

4.3 System of Aggregate Dynamic Equations

Financial frictions introduce two wedges in our model compared to standard representative-agent

neoclassical growth models. The saving wedge is introduced by borrowing constraints on the

household side, and the investment wedge is introduced by borrowing constraints on the �rm side.

These wedges lead to low returns to household savings (�nancial capital) and high returns to �rm

investment (�xed capital), thus creating the driving forces of international two-way capital �ows.

The CRS production technology implies that the equilibrium factor prices are W `t =

(1��)Y `tn`t

and r`t =�Y `t�K`t, where the aggregate output Y `t =

��K`t

�� �n`t�1��

and the aggregate capital stock

�K`t = u`cK`c

t +�1� u`t

�K`t . After aggregating households�decisions in equations (31) and (32) as

well as the budget constraint,23 and combining with equations (33) and (34), we obtain

���`t

���`t

C`t= �R`bt

���`t+1

���`t+1

C`t+1G���`t+1

�; (35)

���`t

���`t

C`tW `tG���`t

�= `; (36)

where

G���`t

�=

Zmax(

��`t

; 1)dF (�) > 1 (37)

captures the liquidity premium of cash �ows and ���`t

�=

Zmin

����`t

; 1

�dF (�) captures the mar-

ginal propensity to consume. The �rst equation corresponds to the intertemporal Euler equations

for consumption and saving and the second to aggregate labor supply. If one treats���`t

���`t

C`tas the

aggregate marginal utility of consumption, then the savings wedge introduced by the �nancial fric-

tion on the household side is captured by the function G(��). Because G(��) > 1, the �rst equation

shows that the interest rate is lower than the rate of time preference (�Rb < 1), suggesting that

�nancial friction induces higher saving (Aiyagari, 1994). The labor supply equation shows that

23The individual budget constraint is chit + shit+1 + ~shit+1 + ahit+1Q

ht = Hit; where Hit is de�ned in equation (30).

21

Page 22: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

�nancial friction induces a higher labor supply. The intuition is that the positive probability of a

binding borrowing constraints makes the agent e¤ectively poorer, which induces the agent to work

harder. In other words, the liquidity premium G����raises the value of the real wage.

On the �rm side, the Euler equation for capital investment is

q`t =1

R`bt

hR`kt+1 + (1� �)q`t+1 + (q`t+1�` +R`kt+1)

�q`t+1

�i: (38)

Notice that if �q`t�= 0 and qt = 1, the above equation is just the standard neoclassical �rst-order

condition with respect to capital investment. So �qht�> 0 together with qt > 1 capture the

investment wedge. It will be shown that Tobin�s q (qt) measures the gap between the MPK and

the �nancial interest rate.

The equilibrium dynamics of the model are characterized by a system of dynamic rational

expectations equations with aggregate variables. Besides the above wedge equations representing

�nancial frictions, the rest of the aggregate equations are derived as follows. The aggregate resource

constraint is given by

C`t +S`t+1+

~S`t+1+ I`t = Y `t +R

`bt�1S

`t +R

`cbt�1

~S`t � r`tu`ct K`ct �

s

�~S`t�1

�1+�1 + �

� k

�u`t�1+�

1 + �Kht (39)

where the LHS is the total expenditure and the left hand is total income. The total household

income comes from several sources: total domestic output, returns from domestic bonds, and

returns from foreign bonds.

The aggregate production function is given by

Y `t =hu`cK`c

t +�1� u`t

�K`t

i� �n`t

�1��: (40)

Aggregate capital accumulation is given by

K`t+1 =

��q`t�

��q`t�I`t + (1� �)K`

t ; (41)

where ��q`t�= 1 � �

�1=q`t

�and �

�q`t�=R">1=q`t

"d� ("). Aggregate consumption is a fraction of

total saving,

C`t =���`t

�1�

���`t

�(q`tK`t+1 + S

`t+1 + ~S`t+1 +B

`t ): (42)

22

Page 23: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

where B`t = b`q`tK`t : Aggregate investment is obtained through aggregating equation (25),

I`t = ��q`t

��R`kt + q

`t�`�K`t ; (43)

where R`kt = r`t + 1r`ct >r`t

��1+�

� 1�

k

�r`ct � r`t

� 1+��

�: For the �nancial autarky regime, we also add

S`t+1 =~S`t+1 = u`t = 0: (44)

For the �nancial liberalization regime, we also add

S`t+1 + ~S`ct+1 = 0; (45)

~S`t+1 = 1R`cbt>R`bt

R`cbt �R`bt

s

! 1�

; (46)

u`t = 1r`ct >r`t

r`ct � r`t k

! 1�

: (47)

The system of equations (35)-(47) consists of 22 equations that determine the dynamic equi-

librium path of 22 endogenous aggregate variables, {K`t ; n

`t; I

`t ; Y

`t ; q

`t ; C

`t , ��

`t; S

`t ;~S`t ; R

`bt; u

`t}, for

` = fh; fg. The transitional equilibrium path from autarky to �nancial liberalization and impulse

responses to aggregate shocks can all be computed straightforwardly by standard perturbation

methods popular in the representative-agent RBC literature, such as the log-linearization method.24

The local uniqueness of the equilibrium (saddle path) can be easily con�rmed by checking the eigen-

values of the dynamic system near the steady state.

5 International Capital Flows

Everything else equal, the directions of international capital �ows depend on the di¤erential rates

of return to �nancial and �xed capital across countries, which in turn depend on the demand and

supply of capital and the degree of �nancial development in each country. This section characterizes

the relationships among the borrowing constraint parameters�b`; �`

, the interest rates

�R`b, and

the MPKs�R`kfor ` 2 fh; fg through the lens of demand and supply of capital in each country

and how they interact to determine the equilibrium interest rate and MPK.

24More speci�cally, we can compute the transition dynamics from autarky to �nancial liberalization according tothe method in Juillard (1996). All calculations can be done with Dynare 4.0.

23

Page 24: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

In the model, both households and �rms can save. Households save through bonds and equities

(�nancial assets) while �rms save through a domestic intra-period loan market (i.e., a corporate

union) participated only by domestic �rms. Firms will invest if and only if they receive good

investment opportunities and will save (remain inactive) otherwise. Because it is costless for �rms

to borrow from the corporate union (i.e., they pay zero interest rate for loans), only household

savings depend directly on the interest rate in the �nancial market. In particular, the aggregate

household savings depend positively on the interest rate.

Firms�investment are �nanced by two sources: internal cash �ows and outside credit from the

corporate union. Borrowing from the corporate union is free but subject to borrowing constraints.

Hence, the aggregate demand for capital depends indirectly on the �nancial interest rate through

the rate of return to equities. When the interest rate is high, the rate of return to equities must

also be high to attract equity buyers. This means that either the equity price has to be low or

the dividend payment has to be high. In either case, �rms�present value of internal cash �ows

are reduced, which will decrease �rms� investment demand. Besides this intensive margin, the

reduction of equity price also raises the threshold (cuto¤) of investing, thus lowering the aggregate

investment through the extensive margin. Therefore, the aggregate demand for capital depends

negatively on the interest rate, among other things.

So in the model household savings are channeled to �rms through the equity market, and they

a¤ect �rms�investment demand through equity prices and dividends. When the household saving

rate is high, the demand for equities will increase. In equilibrium, either the equity price level will

increase or the average dividends will decrease; in either case the rate of return to equities must

decline. By arbitrage, the interest rate on bonds must also decline. This has positive e¤ects on

�rm�s investment demand because (i) a lower interest rate increases �rms�present value of future

cash �ows due to a lower discounting rate; and (ii) a lower dividend payment improves �rms�cash

positions. A higher investment rate by �rms will then reduce the marginal product of capital. This

suggests that �nancial capital in�ows from other countries can lower domestic interest rate and the

MPK of the home country. On the other hand, �xed capital in�ows from foreign countries will (i)

reduce the MPK in the home country and (ii) lower the domestic interest rate because it reduces

the equity return at home.

For the U.S., the in�ows of �nancial capital will decrease the domestic interest rate and MPK,

but meanwhile the out�ows of FDI will increase its interest rate and MPK. So two-way capital

�ows have the opposite e¤ects on domestic interest rate and MPK. This suggests that �nancial

liberalization may not necessarily decrease the U.S. interest rate unless �nancial capital in�ows

dominate FDI out�ows.

On the other hand, the e¤ects of �nancial development on the interest rate and MPK are

somewhat di¤erent from those of capital �ows and more complicated, because changes in the

24

Page 25: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

borrowing constraints (e.g., �) have ambiguous e¤ects on the interest rate (since they simultaneously

shift the demand and supply curves of capital). To study these e¤ects, we now turn.

5.1 Aggregate Capital Demand

We �rst derive the steady-state demand function for aggregate capital in the home country based on

�rms�investment behaviors. From the evolution equations of Tobin�s q (Eqn. 38) and capital stock

(Eqn. 41) as well as the aggregate investment (Eqn. 43), we obtain following two equations that

implicitly describe the gross rate of return to �xed capital Rhk (MPK) and Tobin�s q as functions

of the real interest rate Rhb

� =�Rhk + q

h�h���qh�; (48)

Rhk = qh�Rhb � 1

�+ �

1

� (qh) =� (qh): (49)

where ��qh�= 1��

�1=qh

�, and �

�qh�=R">1=qh "d� (") : The term �

�qh�=��qh�on the RHS of

last equation is the average investment e¢ ciency for active �rms, thus it is increasing in the cut-

o¤ 1=qh or decreasing in qh. This equation suggests that the Tobin�s q (qh) measures the spread

between the return of �xed capital and the return of �nancial capital (the interest rate). Indeed,

if we assume that the e¢ ciency shock "hj follows binomial distribution with only two realizations:

0 and 1, then the above equation degenerates to Rhk � � = qh�Rhb � 1

�: In this case, qh is exactly

the wedge between the return of �xed capital (MPK) and the real interest rate.

Combining (49) and (48), we can solve Rhk and qh as function of the interest rate Rhb and the

�nancial development parameter �h: Rhk � R�Rhb ; �

h�; qh � Q

�Rhb ; �

h�: The following proposition

shows that given the interest rate, the country with lower �nancial development (�h) on the �rm

side tends to have both a higher Tobin�s q (qh) and a higher MPK (Rhk).

Proposition 5 The MPK Rhk is strictly increasing in the interest rate Rhb and strictly decreasing

in the �nancial development �h; i.e.@R(Rhb ;�

h)@Rhb

> 0 and@R(Rhb ;�

h)@�h

< 0: The Tobin�s q (qh) is strictly

decreasing in both the interest rate Rhb and the �nancial development �h; i.e.

@Q(Rhb ;�h)

@Rhb< 0 and

@Q(Rhb ;�h)

@�h< 0.

25

Page 26: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Proof. By the fact that both ��qh�and 1

�(qh)=�(qh)are strictly increasing in qh, the results can

be obtained easily through the implicit function theorem.

Our model predicts that the MPK and �nancial interest rate are positively correlated but the

correlation is not perfect� there is a wedge between the two and the magnitude of this wedge

(Tobin�s q) depends crucially on the degree of �nancial development. The wedge is smaller and the

correlation is stronger for �nancially more developed countries. These predictions are consistent

with the empirical �ndings of Ohanian and Wright (2007).

To obtain the aggregate capital demand function, we need to link MPK to the capital-to-

output ratio. According to the discussions in section 4.2, the LHS of (48) is increasing in rht and

thus decreasing in capital-to-output ratio�Kh

Y h. On the other hand, Proposition 1 implies that the

RHS of (48) is increasing in the interest rate Rhb . Therefore, equation (48) implicitly describes the

aggregate capital demand (or the capital-to-output ratio) as a downward sloping function of the

interest rate.

5.2 Aggregate Capital Supply

We now derive the aggregate capital supply from the household side. From (36), the cut-o¤ ��h is

implicitly determined by

�RhbG(�h) = 1: (50)

Since Gh is a decreasing function of �h, (50) implies the cut-o¤ is increasing in Rhb . Since G

h > 1,

the �nancial frictions on the household side make the steady-state interest rate Rhb lower than 1=�.

The intuition is simple. The presence of borrowing constraint limits the households� ability to

diversify the uninsurable risk �; thus inducing households to over-save to self-insure themselves.

The over-saving behavior consequently reduces the interest rate in equilibrium.

Now, combining equations (39), (42) and (49), and with some algebra, we have

(1� �)h�1� uh

�+ �uf

i Y h�Kh

=

�1

1�h �Rhb

�qh +

h

1�h qhbh (51)

+

�1

1�h �Rhb

�Sh

Kh+

�1

1�h ��

1 + �Rfb +

1

1 + �Rhb

�� ~ShKh

;

where �Kh = ufKf +�1� uh

�Kh, and � � Kf

Kh is the relative ratio of �xed capital stocks in the

two countries.

Equation (51) describes the aggregate supply of capital (capital-to-output ratio) for the home

country as a positive function of the interest rate. Given uf and �; the LHS of the equation is

26

Page 27: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

decreasing in�Kh

Y hsince both 1� uh and Y h

�Kh are decreasing in�Kh

Y h; whereas given Rfb (and ignoring

the terms Sh and ~Sh for simplicity), the RHS of (51) is decreasing in Rhb since both h and qh are

decreasing functions of Rhb .25

5.3 General Equilibrium in the Capital Market

To close the 2-country model, we need a market clearing condition for international bonds to

determine the foreign reserves ~Sh at home and ~Sf abroad. From equations (18), we have

~Sh = �Sf ; Sh = � ~Sf : (52)

The general equilibrium of the 2-country model with �nancial integration can be characterized by

the equilibrium capital-to-output ratiosn�Kh

Y h;�Kf

Y f

oand the real interest rates

nRhb ; R

fb

o, which are

determined jointly by the demand and supply of capital in the two countries.

However, to understand the factors determining capitals�rates of return and the directions of

capital �ows, it helps to study a world without capital �ows� the �nancial autarky regime. A

�nancial autarky is de�ned as the situation without international capital �ows, regardless of �nan-

cial or �xed capital. To obtain a �nancial autarky regime, we can simply set the cost parameters

k and s to in�nity, so that there are no cross-border �ows in �nancial and �xed capitals (i.e.,

u` = S` = ~S` = 0). In a �nancial autarky equilibrium, the demand function (??) and supply

function (51) of capital in the two countries collapse to

�Y `

K`= R

�R`b; �

`�; (53)

(1� �) Y`

K`=

�`

1�` �R`b + 1

�q` +

`

1�` q`b`; (54)

for ` = fh; fg. Note that due to the immobility of both �xed and �nancial capital, there is nointeraction between the two countries, and the equilibrium capital-to-output ratio and interest rate

in each country are then fully pinned down by its domestic capital demand curve and capital supply

curve in equations (53) and (54).

25Here we implicitly assume the term 11�h � Rhb is strictly positive. Indeed, this assumption holds under fairly

weak conditions. To see this, since 11�h �R

hb > 0 implies 1�h < 1=Rhb ; from (50), we only need to show 1�h <

�Gh: According to the de�nitions of h and Gh; last inequality is equivalent to (1� �)F���h�<R�<��h

���hdF +

�R�>��h

���hdF: Therefore, we only need to show F

���h�< �

1��

�R�<��h

���hdF +

R�>��h

���hdF�: This inequality always

holds if we have E(�)��h

� 1���; which is easily satis�ed under the conditions that � ! 1 and bh is not too large (to

ensure ��h � �max).

27

Page 28: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Proposition 6 In the �nancial autarky regime, the country with tighter borrowing constraints on

the �rm side (i.e., smaller �) has a higher MPK but either a higher or a lower domestic interest

rate; and the country with tighter borrowing constraints on the household side (i.e., smaller b) has

both a lower MPK and a lower real interest rate.

The proof is straightforward and can be illustrated graphically. The left panel in Figure 4 is the

autarky equilibrium in which the two countries di¤er only in the degree of borrowing constraints on

the �rm side, but have the same degree of borrowing constraints on the household side. Speci�cally,

suppose �rms in country-f can borrow more than �rms in country-h: �f > �h: The "S-S" curve in

Figure 4 represents capital supply and the "D-D" curve capital demand, and point H represents

autarky equilibrium in country-h and point F autarky equilibrium in country-f . According to

equations (53) and (54), a larger � will shift both the demand and the supply curves towards the

right. As a result, point H lies on the left side of point F and the home country has a lower capital-

to-output ratio (or a higher MPK). The rank of interest rates in the two countries, however, is

ambiguous since point F can be either above or below point H, depending on the magnitudes of the

right-ward shifts of the two curves. The intuition is that looser borrowing constraints on �rms in

the foreign country lead to a higher demand for capital, which shifts out the "D-D" demand curve

directly and results in a lower Tobin�s q due to the lowered MPK. A lower Tobin�s q in turn leads

to a lower equity price (Q). Thus, households are willing to buy more equities or, equivalently, save

more. As a result, the "S-S" supply curve will also shifts out to the right. Consequently, whether

the equilibrium interest rate is lower or higher than that in country-h is ambiguous.

Figure 4. The Steady-State Equilibrium in the Financial Autarky

The right panel in Figure 4 illustrates the case in which the degree of borrowing constraints is

identical on the �rm side between the two countries while that on the household side is di¤erent.

28

Page 29: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Assume households in country-f are less borrowing constrained, bf < bh. From equation (54),

capital demand in the two countries is thus identical since �h = �f ; but the capital supply curve in

the foreign country lies on the left-hand side of the home country�s. This is so because households

in the foreign country tend to borrow more and save less due to a looser borrowing limit. In

equilibrium, the foreign country (labelled by point F) ends up with both a higher interest rate and

a higher MPK (lower capital-to-output ratio) than the home country (point H).

This result shows that less developed countries could have both a lower interest rate and a

lower MPK than developed countries. Consequently, both �nancial capital and �xed capital should

�ow from the South to the North. Although such a one-way unidirectional capital �ow is observed

in the real world for some developing countries (such as the oil-exporting countries in the Middle

East), it is not the dominate pattern of international capital �ows. The above discussions conclude

that to explain the two-way capital �ow puzzle, borrowing constraints on both the household side

and the �rm side are important.

5.4 Two-Way Capital Flows

Proposition 7 Moving from �nancial autarky to �nancial liberalization (i.e., k < 1 and s <

1), �nancial capital will �ow from country-h to country-f and �xed capital (FDI) will �ow in the

opposite direction simultaneously if one of the following sets of conditions are satis�ed: (i) �h < �f

and b��f ; �h; bf

�< bh < �b

��f ; �h; bf

�; or (ii) bh < bf and �h < �(�f ; bh; bf ), provided that "jt is

Pareto distributed.

Proof. See Appendix A.5.

As shown in the previous discussions (Figure 4), the assumption of �h < �f alone guarantees

that the home country has a higher MPK in autarky and thus country-h would attract FDI from

abroad. However, the direction of �nancial capital �ow is ambiguous in this case because the

autarky interest rate at home can be either lower or higher than the foreign interest rate. Therefore,

to ensure a lower interest rate at home, we also need the household side to face a tight enough

borrowing constraint (bh < �b). However, since a tighter borrowing constraint on the household side

also brings down the MPK at home, the value of bh cannot be too low (i.e., bh > b). This explains

the �rst set of conditions in the proposition.

On the other hand, the assumption of bh < bf alone ensures that the home country has both

a lower interest rate and a lower MPK, so we also need a tight enough borrowing constraint on

the �rm side at home (or a loose enough borrowing constraint abroad) to induce a higher MPK at

home than abroad. However, although a lower �h at home induces a higher MPK, its e¤ect on the

interest rate Rhb is ambiguous. So we do not know if the home country will necessarily have a lower

29

Page 30: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

interest rate if �h is reduced. One special case is that if " follows the Pareto distribution, then the

interest rate depends only on b`, so the value of �` does not a¤ect the interest rate. This explains

the second set of conditions in the proposition.

Since capital �ow itself can change the equilibrium interest rate and MPK, it is worth em-

phasizing that in our model FDI and �nancial capital �ows tend to reinforce each other in the

opposite directions by their general-equilibrium e¤ects on the interest rate and MPK. Speci�cally,

FDI in�ows from f to h tend to drive out h�s �nancial capital because inward FDI brings down

the domestic interest rate; and bonds in�ows from h to f tend to drive out �xed capital in f

toward h because inward �nancial capital �ows brings down f�s MPK. Therefore, the parameter

requirements on the values of��`; b`

for triggering two-way capital �ows are much easier to be

satis�ed than appeared in the above Proposition.

5.5 Balance of Payment

The balance of payment is straightforward to compute in our model. For bonds �ows we have

Sht = � ~Sft and ~Sht = �Sht . Moreover, either Sht > 0 or ~Sht > 0, but not both. For �xed capital

�ows, only one of the following conditions is true: either uht > 0 or uft > 0, but not both. Suppose

~Sht > 0 and uft > 0 (as in the data). The current account balance of the home country (CAht ) in

period t is then given by

CAht =�~Sht+1 � ~Sht

���uftK

ft � u

ft�1K

ft�1

�; (55)

where the terms inside the �rst bracket on the RHS are the changes of �nancial asset positions and

those in the second bracket are the changes of non-�nancial asset (FDI) positions. The net factor

payments (NFPht ) from abroad to the home country are given by

NFPht =�Rfbt�1

~Sht � ~Sht

�� rht u

ftK

ft ; (56)

where terms inside the �rst bracket on the RHS are the interest rate payment from abroad and

the second term on the RHS is the home country�s net income payment (rents) to foreign �rms�

FDI. The trade balance of the home country (TBht ) can be obtained from the following accounting

identity:26

TBht = CAht �NFPht : (57)

26To be precise, aggregating the individual budget constraint in the home country gives�~Sht+1 � ~Sht

���uftK

ft � uft�1K

ft�1

�= Y h

t ��Cht + Iht

�+�Rfbt�1

~Sht � ~Sht

�� rht u

ftK

ft

where Iht is the total domestic investment including investments from both domestic �rms and foreign �rms and the

cross-border adjustment costs. The trade balance is thus Y ht �

�Cht + Iht

�= CAht �NFPh

t .

30

Page 31: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Plugging equations (55) and (56) into equation (57) gives the relationship between trade balance

and capital account balance (KAt):

TBht =h�1 + rht

�uft�1K

ft�1 �R

fbt�1

~Sht

i| {z }

Gross Interest Payments

��uftK

ft � ~Sht+1

�| {z }

KAht

: (58)

where rht = rht (1 + gFDI;t) and gFDI;t is the growth rate of FDI position: Equation (58) implies

that capital-account surplus (KAht > 0) may not necessarily imply trade de�cit (TBht < 0), because

it also depends on the magnitude of the gross interest payments on �nancial and �xed capital �ows.

For instance, if the gross interest payment is positive because of higher rate of return to FDI than

the interest on foreign reserves, then it is possible that the home country experiences trade surplus

in the steady state despite that it has zero (or positive) balances on its capital account (KAht � 0).This suggests that China�s trade surplus with the U.S. may be sustainable in the long run even

if net capital (�nancial plus �xed capital) �ows between the two countries are balanced at zero

(KAht = 0).

6 Quantitative Analysis

6.1 Calibration

We now calibrate the deep parameters in the model by taking country-h as China and country-

f as the rest of the world (ROW). Let the time period be one quarter, the discounting factor

� = 0:99, the capital share � = 0:4, and the leisure coe¢ cient in the utility function = 2:5.27

Both the idiosyncratic investment shock " and the idiosyncratic preference shock � follow Pareto

distributions, with CDF 1��

""min

���and 1�

��

�min

���, respectively; and the means of both shocks

are set to one.28

Next, we calibrate the �ve country-speci�c parameters f�; �; �; �; bg. These parameters controlsmany moments in our model, including the distribution of �rms (such as the lumpiness of �rm-

level investment), the distribution of households (such as consumption inequality), the aggregate

investment-to-capital ration, and national saving rate, the MPK, and real interest rate, and so

on. In general, we choose parameter values to match the key moments in the data. Due to data

limitations, some of the data moments in ROW are based on data from the OECD countries or the

U.S. Our priority is to match the Chinese economy.

27This parameter value of together with other country-speci�c parameter values imply that the steady-statehours worked per week is 30% of time endowment in U.S. and 32% in China.28This implies the lower bounds "min = ��1

�and �min = ��1

�:

31

Page 32: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Our calibrations will try to target the following moments for ROW: (i) an average annualized

investment rate (I/K ratio) of 12%, (ii) an annual investment spike rate of 18%, (iii) a consumption

Gini coe¢ cient of 0.3, (iv) a national saving rate of 20%, and (v) an annual rate of pre-tax capital

return (MPK) of 10%.

For China, the shape parameter � in the Pareto distribution function takes the same value

as that in ROW. The remaining four parameters f�; �; �; bg are calibrated to target the followingfour moments of Chinese data: (i) an annual rate of return to �xed capital (MPK) of 20%; (ii) a

household saving rate of 35%; (iii) a consumption Gini coe¢ cient of 0.5; and (iv) the cross-country

ratio ROW�s private credit-output ratioChina�s private credit-output ratio = 1.6.

29

Table 2: Parameter Values

China ROW� : discounting factor 0:99 0:99� : capital share in production 0:4 0:4� : capital depreciation rate 0:0626 0:0341 : coe¢ cient of leisure in utility function 2:5 2:5� : borrowing constraint on �rm side 0:0080 0:0289b : borrowing constraint on household side 0:0003 0:1035� : shape parameter for investment e¢ ciency shock 1:5203 1:5203� : shape parameter for preference shock 1:3735 2:1827

Parameters Controlling for Financial Liberalization� k : FDI adjustment cost 0:8385� : curvature of FDI adjustment cost 1� k: AR(1) coe¢ cient 0:9122

� s : bond-�ow adjustment cost 0:0016� : curvature in bond-�ow adjustment cost 1� s: AR(1) coe¢ cient 0:9703

The remaining parameters are related to the cross-border adjustment costs for international

capital �ows. For the curvature parameters f�; �g ; we set them to 1, so that the cost functions are

quadratic. The parameters f k; sg control the magnitudes of capital �ows, therefore representingthe extent of �nancial liberalization. To capture the gradualness of market integration, we assume

f kt; stg follow deterministic AR(1) processes:

kt � � k = � k� kt�1 � � k

�;

st � � s = � s� st�1 � � s

�:

29Wen (2011) argues that the reported Gini coe¢ cients for China are underestimated. He conjectures that incomeGini in China is about 0.8 and the consumption Gini is about 0.5.

32

Page 33: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

We then calibrate the values ofn� k; � s; � k ; � s

oso that the dynamic path of capital �ows in the

model closely match the Chinese data. In particular, the targeted series are Chinese net inward

FDI (accumulated) and total foreign reserves, starting from 1992 to 2010. We assume the process

of kt and st start with some initial values in 1992, and gradually achieve their long-run values � k

and � s. Table 2 summarizes all of the calibrated parameters.

6.2 Steady-State Predictions

Table 3 reports the predictions of the model in �nancial autarky and �nancial liberalization regimes.

Columns 1 and 2 pertain to China and the ROW in the autarky regime. Columns 3 to 8 pertain

to the two countries in the �nancial liberalization regime where �nancial and �xed capital are

internationally mobile.

In the autarky regime, China has a higher Tobin�s q than ROW (2.1995 v.s. 1.1148), a higher

annual return of �xed capital (21.9895% v.s. 9.6325%), but a lower real interest rate (1.4357% v.s.

4.0323%). All these predictions are due mainly to a relatively less developed �nancial system in

China than ROW.

Because of the cross-country spread in the rates of return to �nancial and �xed capital, �nancial

liberalization between countries will induce China to hold negative foreign productive asset positions

(FDI in�ow) but positive �nancial asset positions (bonds out�ow), with the former equal to -30%

and the latter equal to 84% (as shares of GDP) in the long-run steady state. These values are

about 25% and 33% larger than their counterparts in the real data,30 indicating that the actual

Chinese economy is not at its steady state yet in the �nancial liberalization regime.

Table 3. Steady States in Financial Autarky and Financial Liberalization

Autarky Only Financial Only Fixed BothCapital Flows Capital Flows Capital Flows

Country China ROW China ROW China ROW China ROW

Return of Capital (%) 21.9895 9.6325 22.3555 9.6248 21.6071 9.6375 22.0581 9.6304Interest Rate (%) 1.4357 4.0323 1.7754 4.0223 1.0903 4.0387 1.4986 4.0295Tobin�s q 2.1995 1.1148 2.1634 1.1151 2.2378 1.1145 2.1927 1.1149

Net Foreign Asset Positions (%) � � � � � � 76.6031 -42.3428 -26.0278 16.0877 54.2133 -30.7928Direct Investment Abroad (%) � � � � � � 0 0 -26.0278 16.0877 -29.5504 16.7844Bonds (%) � � � � � � 76.6031 -42.3428 0 0 83.7638 -47.5772

Trade Balances (%) � � � � � � -3.0358 1.6781 5.6239 -3.4761 3.1928 -1.8135Interest Rate Payments (%) � � � � � � 3.0358 -1.6781 0 0 3.3255 -1.8888

To better understand the di¤erent impacts of �nancial and �xed capital �ows on each country�s

MPK and interest rate, we consider �rst partial liberalization scenarios by allowing only one type

of capital (bonds or �xed capital) to move across borders. Columns 3 and 4 report the steady state

30By 2010, the accumulative net inward FDI of China is about 24% of GDP, and the net outward debt position isabout 59% of GDP.

33

Page 34: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

in which only �nancial assets (bonds) are internationally mobile. The opening of bonds market

induces �nancial capital out�ow from China into ROW, which makes the interest rates converge

across countries� the convergence is not 100% because of across boarder trading costs (home bias).

As a result, the equilibrium interest rate in China increases from 1.4% in autarky to 1.8%, which

further raises domestic return of �xed capital from 21.99% to 22.36%. The situation in ROW is the

opposite: the interest rate decreases from 4.03% in autarky to 4.02%, and the rate of return of �xed

capital declines slightly from 9.63% in autarky to 9.62%. The above results con�rm the statement

in Proposition 7 that international bonds �ow narrows the gap of country-speci�c interest rates but

enlarges the gap in the rate of return to �xed capital.

Column 5 and 6 report the situation when only �xed capital can move internationally. Fixed

capital will �ow from ROW to China because China has a higher MPK in autarky. In particular,

FDI in�ows increase the capital supply in China, therefore reducing China�s domestic interest rate

from 1.4% to 1.1%. The inward FDI also reduces the equilibrium return of �xed capital in China

from 21.99% to 21.61%. In contrast, FDI out�ows raise the interest rate in ROW from 4.03% in

autarky to 4.04%, and pushes up ROW�s MPK from 9.6325% to 9.6375%.

To summarize, �nancial capital out�ow tends to increase domestic interest rate and �xed capital

return, whereas FDI in�ow has the opposite e¤ects. As a result, under the fully �nancial liberaliza-

tion regime, both MPK and the interest rate do not change signi�cantly from their autarky values,

as shown in columns 7 and 8.

Since international capital �ows are fully determined by the cross-country discrepancies in

interest rate and MPK, the two types of capital �ows reinforce each other. Namely, FDI in�ows

may cause �nancial capital out�ows, and �nancial capital out�ows in turn may cause FDI in�ows.

The line in Table 3 labeled "Net Investment Position" quantitatively shows this point. When only

bonds can be traded across countries, the �nancial capital out�ow from China is about 77% of its

GDP. When only �xed capital is allowed to move across countries, FDI in�ows in China is 26%

of its GDP. The corresponding ratios increase signi�cantly when the two capital markets are both

liberalized. The �nancial capital out�ows in China become 84% of China�s GDP, about 10% larger

than that in partial liberalization. Meanwhile, the FDI in�ows rise to 30% of China�s GDP, which

is also 10% more than that in partial liberalization.

Next we discuss the impact of capital �ows on long-run trade balances (the lower panel in Table

3). When only �nancial assets are mobile across countries, China will run trade de�cits (-3% of

GDP) in the long run despite that China has net �nancial capital out�ows. In contrast, the U.S.

(ROW) will run trade surplus (1.7% of GDP). These trade balances come entirely from interest

payments on international bonds. However, when only �xed capital is mobile across countries,

China will run trade surplus (5.6% of GDP) in the steady state while ROW will run trade de�cits

34

Page 35: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

(-3.5% of GDP). These balances derive entirely from capital gains from FDI positions: FDI out�ows

from ROW to China. Because the rate of return to FDI dominates the rate of return to �nancial

assets, in the long run China maintains a trade surplus of 3.2% of its GDP while ROW (e.g.,

the U.S.) maintains a trade de�cit of -1.8% of its GDP. Therefore, despite that FDI �ows are

smaller than �nancial asset �ows in GDP shares, developed countries (such as the U.S.) can have

permanent trade de�cits with developing countries (such as China) because FDI payments from

China are much larger than U.S. interest payments on its bonds.

6.3 Transitional Dynamics

Figure 5. Transition Dynamics after Financial Liberalization.

Figure 5 graphs the transitional dynamics of major aggregate variables when the model economy

opens up to �nancial liberalization (with both �nancial and �xed capital �ows). The top panel on

35

Page 36: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

the right column and the second panel on the left column show a typical pattern of two-way capital

�ows: �nancial assets leave China and �ow into ROW (second panel on the left) while FDI leaves

ROW and �ow into China (top panel on the right). Because the volume of �nancial asset �ows

dominates that of FDI, the net foreign asset position is positive in China and negative in ROW

(top left panel), suggesting global imbalances in capital �ows.

Because of positive net capital out�ows (�nancial plus �xed), China runs trade surplus in the

short run (second and third panels on the right column). In particular, the current account in

China experiences sharply increases on impact and then decreases in the following years before

rising again. However, since FDI earns a much higher rate of return than bonds, China always

receives negative income payments (third panel on the left). As a result, China runs persistent

and permanent trade surplus while ROW runs persistent and permanent trade de�cits. Hence,

our model suggests that the imbalanced world trade is sustainable as a long-run equilibrium. In

addition, the bottom panels on both the right and the left show that the interest and the rate of

return to �xed capital (MPK) are almost una¤ected under two-way capital �ows. This is so because

FDI in�ows and �nancial asset out�ows have the opposite e¤ects on the interest rate and MPK,

con�rming the previous theoretical analysis.

Figure 6. Net Foreign Asset Positions in China� Model Simulations v.s. RealData

36

Page 37: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Finally, Figure 6 compares the model simulated paths of capital �ows in the home country

(dashed lines) and their counterparts in Chinese data (solid lines). The top panel is net FDI in�ows

to the home country, the middle panel is net �nancial asset out�ows from the home country, and

the bottom panel is net exports of the home country. The simulated series closely track the long-

run trends of the Chinese data, indicating that the model explains the dynamics of China�s capital

�ows and trade imbalances quite well. Although our calibrations do not target the net exports,

the simulated path tracks the trend in the data quite well. Moreover, the simulated series predict

that in 2020 China�s FDI in�ow and foreign reserves (�nancial asset out�ow) will reach the level of

80% and 75% of GDP in the long run, respectively. This will take another 10 years to accomplish

from now on. The model also predicts that China�s net exports peaked in 2007 and will gradually

approach a steady-state level of 3.2% of GDP.

6.4 Welfare Implications

In this section, we examine the welfare implications of two-way capital �ows. We measure the

welfare e¤ect of �nancial liberalization by the percentage change of consumption that is required

to make households indi¤erent between liberalizing capital markets and staying in autarky. In

computing this measure, we take into account the welfare e¤ects of the transition dynamics from

autarky to liberalization. Speci�cally, we start with steady state in autarky and measure the

percentage changes in consumption (�) such that all households in a country are ex anti indi¤erent

between two types of economies in expected life-time utilities:

1

1� �

Z �� log

�(1 + �) cA

�� nA

�dF (�) = E

1Xt=0

�Z�t (i) log ct(i)� nt(i)di

�; (59)

where the LHS denotes life-time expected utility of staying in autarky and the RHS that of moving

to �nancial liberalization, with cA and nA on the LHS denoting the consumption and labor supply

in autarky, and ct and nt on the RHS denoting the dynamic paths of consumption and labor supply

after �nancial liberalization.

In general, the welfare e¤ects of �nancial liberalization seem to obey the Dynamic Ine¢ ciency

Principle� taxing over-accumulated capital is optimal. That is, when the economy is dynamically

ine¢ cient because of over-accumulation of capital, capital out�ows improve welfare for the sourcing

country because they raise the domestic interest rate and MPK.31 In contrast, capital in�ows may

or may not induce welfare loses for the recipient countries, depending on wether the extensive

margin or the intensive margin of consumption dominates. On the one hand, capital in�ows relax

borrowing constraints and enable more consumers to increase consumption� the extensive margin.

31FDI out�ow indirectly releases the over-accumulated household savings through the interest rate channel.

37

Page 38: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

On the other hand, capital in�ows lower domestic interest rate and reduce consumer wealth (the rate

of return to savings)� the intensive margin. Under �nancial capital in�ows, the extensive margin

dominates the intensive margin, leading to welfare gains for the recipient country; whereas under

�xed capita �ows, the opposite is true, leading to welfare loses for the recipient country. These

�ndings are in sharp contrast to the standard welfare results obtained by the existing literature

(e.g., Mendoza et al., 2009; Ju and Wei, 2010) where capital �ows unambiguously bene�t the

recipient country and hurt the sourcing country.

Table 4. Welfare Gains (%)

Only Financial Only Fixed 2-Way FlowCountry China ROW China ROW China ROW

Benchmark

Consumption 0.23 0.20 -0.08 0.75 0.06 1.05Add Leisure 0.92 0.03 -1.09 1.40 -0.17 1.53

Large Openness of Bonds Market

Consumption 0.38 0.29 -0.08 0.75 0.17 1.19Add Leisure 1.34 0.05 -1.09 1.40 0.25 1.59

Also, �nancial liberalization will a¤ect welfare along two dimensions: consumption and leisure.

We report our welfare results with and without taking into account of leisure. It turns out that the

leisure margin plays an important role in welfare analysis, which is often ignored by the existing

literature.

Table 4 reports the welfare e¤ects of �nancial liberalization. Consider the case with only

�nancial capital �ows across countries in our benchmark model (the top panel, columns 2 and 3).

Financial capital �ows bene�t both countries, with the sourcing country (China) gains more than

the recipient country (ROW). If we ignore the leisure margin, China gains slightly more than ROW

(the increase in life-time consumption is 0.23% for China and 0.20% for ROW). However, since an

out�ow of �nancial capital from China will decrease domestic labor supply and increase foreign

labor supply, leisure also rises in China and declines in ROW. As a result, if the leisure margin is

taken into account, China�s welfare gain is signi�cant (0.92%) while that of ROW is insigni�cant

(it reduces to 0.03%).

Next, consider the case with only �xed capital �ows across countries (columns 4 and 5). The

welfare implication in this case is signi�cantly di¤erent from the former case. In particular, although

the sousing country of FDI gains unambiguously (0.75% of consumption), the recipient country loses

(-0.08% of consumption). If the leisure margin is taken into account, both the gains and the loses

are further signi�cantly magni�ed (with a gain of 1.4% and a lose of -1.1%, respectively). As we

38

Page 39: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

discussed before, inward FDI into China increases the aggregate capital supply and thus decreases

China�s MPK and the interest rate. This hurts Chinese savers by lowering the rate of return on

bonds and domestic equity holdings in addition to workers�wage rate. The opposite is true for

ROW. In addition, since FDI in�ows increase aggregate labor demand in China, leisure in China

drops while that in ROW increases, explaining the big welfare e¤ect along the leisure margin.

Finally, consider the case with both �nancial and �xed capital �ows across countries (the last

columns in Table 4). As the welfare e¤ects of FDI �ows dominate those of �nancial capital �ows,

the overall welfare gain for ROW is signi�cant (1.05% of consumption without leisure and 1.53%

with leisure) while China has a mild gain of 0.06% without considering leisure and a loss of -0.17%

after taking leisure into account.

One implication from the welfare analysis is that a country can bene�t unambiguously from

capital out�ows but may su¤er from capital in�ows (especially with respect to FDI in�ows). There-

fore, if �nancial capital �ows signi�cantly dominate FDI �ows, it is possible that both China and

ROW gain from �nancial liberalization. To con�rm this conjecture, we reduce the cross-border ad-

justment cost for bond trading by setting s to 0:001, implying that the steady-state bond position

in China is about 120% of GDP. The lower panel in Table 4 (labeled "Large Openness in Bond

Market") shows that China can have welfare gains under two-way capital �ows regardless of the

leisure margin.

7 Conclusions

International capital �ows between the North and South are two-way instead of one-way �ows,

with �xed capital �owing from rich to poor countries and �nancial capital �owing in the opposite

direction. We augment the standard neoclassical growth model with two wedges (a saving wedge

and an investment wedge) to quantitatively explain the magnitude of the two-way capital �ows.

We show that �nancial frictions� the lack of an e¢ cient credit system in particular� can lead

to insu¢ cient investment on the �rm side (the investment wedge) and excessive saving on the

household side (the saving wedge). Consequently, �xed capital is scarcer while �nancial capital is

relatively abundant in the South, creating a gap between the MPK and the real interest rate both

within and cross countries. This gap in rates of capital returns drive the observed two-way capital

�ows between the North and the South.

The main advantages of our model are therefore fourfold: (i) able to make a clear distinction

between �nancial capital �ows and �xed capital �ows in a full-�edged neoclassical growth model

with double-heterogeneous agents; (ii) able to disentangle the �nancial interest rate and the MPK

through Tobin�s q theory and show that the market rate of return to �xed capital can be over 20%

a year despite that �rms can borrow (with limits) at low interest rate to �nance investment (as in

39

Page 40: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

China); (iii) able to explain China�s excessively high saving rate and its massive trade imbalances

with the ROW; and (iv) able to provide a tractable tool for evaluating the welfare consequences of

the two fundamentally di¤erent forms of capital �ows.32

In contrast to the existing approaches of studying FDI (e.g., MQR 2009; CN, 2011), which

model FDI as households�portfolio choices through �nancial equity investment, we model FDI as

�rms�production decisions through international factor allocation. Therefore, instead of creating

the di¤erential rates of return between bonds and FDI through equity premium, we achieve this

through Tobin�s q theory� a standard approach in line with the neoclassical investment theory.

Our main �ndings challenge the conventional wisdom in the global imbalance literature on

several grounds: (i) Our model predicts that permanent global trade imbalances are sustainable

(with the North running de�cits and the South running surplus). (ii) Our quantitative analysis

shows that the impact of massive �nancial capital �ows from emerging economies to the developed

world is quantitatively small and negligible on the world interest rate, in sharp contrast to the

conjecture of Bernanke (2005). (iii) We also show that capital �ows driven by �nancial frictions

bene�t the sourcing country unambiguously and may hurt the recipient country.33

Another implication of our analysis is that the thrust of reducing global imbalances (for better

or worse) does not hinge on adjusting the exchange rates nor on capital account liberalization.34

Rather, it hinges on improving emerging economies�banking system (i.e., reducing borrowing con-

straints facing both households and �rms) so that household savings can be channeled more e¤ec-

tively to domestic production sector.

However, our model does not fully resolve the "allocation puzzle" of Gourinchas and Jeanne

(2011) because we did not show why countries with faster growth attract less international capital.

To resolve the "allocation puzzle", we need to introduce TFP growth and show that the wedge

between �nancial interest rate and the rate of return to �xed capital is an increasing (rather than

decreasing) function of the growth rate. This is left for future work (see Wen, 2011, for some

important progress in this direction).

32Our in�nite-horizon model is tractable despite heterogeneous households and heterogeneous �rms. This doubleheterogeneity would have made most dynamic models (even the two-period OLG models) intractable. However, ourmodel permits closed-form solutions for households� and �rms� decision rules despite in�nitely lived agents and alarge state space involving distinct distributions of households and �rms across countries. Welfare gains can then becomputed analytically. In particular, we are able to decompose the welfare gains into a consumption and a leisuremargin under either �nancial or �xed capital �ows.33MQR (2009) and Ju and Wei (2010) argue that capital out�ows reduce the welfare of the South. We disagree

with their results.34Capital account liberalization e¤ectively means the reduction in the costs of international capital �ows. Our

model predicts that this would only generate more global imbalances by enhancing the two-way capital �ows.

40

Page 41: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

References

[1] Aiyagari, S Rao, 1994, "Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving," The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol. 109(3), pp. 659-84.

[2] Angeletos, G.M. and V. Panousi, 2011, "Financial integration, entrepreneurial risk and global

imbalances", NBER Working Paper 16761.

[3] Bernanke, Ben S., 2005, "The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account De�cit", The

Federal Reserve Board Speech.

[4] Buera, F. and Y. Shin, 2010, "Productivity growth and capital �ows: The dynamics of reform,"

Working Paper, Washington University in St. Louis.

[5] Bai Chong-En, Chang-Tai Hsieh and Yingyi Qian, 2006, "The Return to Capital in China,"

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 37(2), pp. 61-102.

[6] Caballero, Ricardo, Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2008, "An equilibrium

model of global imbalances and low interest rates," American Economic Review vol. 98(1), pp.

358-393.

[7] Carroll, C. and O. Jeanne, 2009, "A tractable model of precautionary reserves, net foreign

assets, or sovereign wealth funds," Peterson Institute for International Economics Working

Paper Series WP 09-10.

[8] Chamley, Christophe, 1986, "Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with

In�nite Lives," Econometrica, vol. 54(3), pp. 607-22.

[9] Chien, YiLi and Kanda Naknoi, 2011, The risk premium and long-run global imbalances,

Purdue University Working Paper.

[10] Cochrane, John H, 1991, "Production-Based Asset Pricing and the Link between Stock Returns

and Economic Fluctuations," Journal of Finance, vol. 46(1), pp. 209-37.

[11] Cooper R. and J. Haltiwanger, 2006, "On the nature of capital adjustment costs," Review of

Economic Studies vol. 73, pp. 611-633.

[12] Durdu, Ceyhun B., Mendoza, Enrique G. and Terrones, Marco E., 2009, "Precautionary de-

mand for foreign assets in Sudden Stop economies: An assessment of the New Mercantilism,"

Journal of Development Economics, vol. 89(2), pp. 194-209.

41

Page 42: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

[13] Gourinchas, P-O. and O. Jeanne, 2011, Capital Flows to Developing Countries: The Allocation

Puzzle, Working Paper.

[14] Hageny, Jurgen von and Haiping Zhang, 2011, Financial Development and the Patterns of

International Capital Flows, Working Paper.

[15] Hansen, Lars Peter and Richard, Scott F, 1987. "The Role of Conditioning Information in

Deducing Testable," Econometrica, vol. 55(3), pp. 587-613.

[16] Hayashi, F., 1982, Tobin�s marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation, Economet-

rica 50(1), 213-224.

[17] Ju Jiandong and Shang-Jin Wei, 2006. "A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital

Flows," NBER Working Papers 12668, National Bureau of Economic Research.

[18] Ju Jiandong and Shang-Jin Wei, 2010, "Domestic Institutions and the Bypass E¤ect of Inter-

national Capital Flow," American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 173-204.

[19] Juillard, Michel, 1996. "Dynare : a program for the resolution and simulation of dynamic mod-

els with forward variables through the use of a relaxation algorithm," CEPREMAP Working

Papers (Couverture Orange) 9602, CEPREMAP.

[20] King, Robert G. and Levine, Ross, 1993. "Finance, entrepreneurship and growth: Theory and

evidence," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 32(3), pp. 513-542.

[21] Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and Moore, John, 1997. "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political Economy,

vol. 105(2), pp. 211-48.

[22] Liu Zheng, Pengfei Wang and Tao Zha, 2011. "Land-price dynamics and macroeconomic �uc-

tuations," NBER Working Papers 17045, National Bureau of Economic Research.

[23] Lucas, Robert E, Jr, 1990. "Why Doesn�t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?," Amer-

ican Economic Review, vol. 80(2), pp. 92-96.

[24] Mendoza, Enrique G., Vincenzo Quadrini and Jose-Victor Rois-Rull, 2009, "Financial Inte-

gration, Financial Development, and Global Imbalances," Journal of Political Economy, vol.

117(3), pp. 371-416.

[25] Ohanian L. and M. Wright, 2007, Where Did Capital Flow? Fifty Years of International Rate

of Return Di¤erentials and Capital Flows. Working Paper.

[26] Ott, Mack, 2008, "International Capital Flow", in The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.

42

Page 43: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

[27] Poterba, James M., 1998. "The rate of return to corporate capital and factor shares: new

estimates using revised national income accounts and capital stock data," Carnegie-Rochester

Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 48(1), pp. 211-246.

[28] Sandri, Damiano, 2010, "Growth and capital �ows with risky entrepreneurship," IMF Working

Paper WP/10/36.

[29] Song, Z., K. Storesletten, and F. Zilibotti, 2011, "Growing like China," American Economic

Review vol. 101, pp. 202-241.

[30] Wang, Pengfei and Yi Wen, 2011, Hayashi meets Kiyotaki and Moore: A theory of capital

adjustment costs, Review of Economic Dynamics (forthcoming).

[31] Wang, Pengfei, Xu, Lifang and Xu, Zhiwei, 2011, �Financial Development and Aggregate

Saving Rates: A Hump-Shaped Relationship,�mimeo., Hong Kong University of Science and

Technology.

[32] Wen, Yi, 2009, "Saving and growth under borrowing constraints: Explaining the high saving

rate puzzle," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2009-045C.

[33] Wen, Yi, 2010, "Liquidity demand and welfare in a heterogeneous-agent economy," Federal

Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2010-009A.

[34] Wen, Yi, 2011, "Explaining China�s Trade Imbalance Puzzle," Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis Working Paper 2011-018A.

43

Page 44: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

A Appendix A

A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Since the optimal labor demand in the domestic and foreign markets is given, respectively, by Nhjt =�

1��Wht

�1=�(1�uhjt)Kh

jt and Xhjt =

�1��W ft

�1=�uhjtK

hjt, the CRS production technology implies that the

marginal product of capital for domestic and foreign business can be expressed as rht = ��1��Wht

� 1���

and rft = �

�1��W ft

� 1���

, respectively. After substitution, the pro�t-maximization problem of the

�rm can then be simpli�ed to

�hjt = maxuhjt

264rht (1� uhjt) + rft uhjt � k�uhjt

�1+�1 + �

375Khjt (60)

� RhktKhjt:

The optimal FDI decision variable uhjt can be solved as

uhjt =

8><>:0 if rft � rht�

rft �rht k

� 1�

if rft > rht: (61)

Substituting the optimal FDI decision rules into the pro�t function gives equation (21). Q.E.D.

A.2 Proof of Proposition 2

For each period t, after the realization of "hjt; �rm j chooses optimal investment level to solve

following problem

maxIjt

RhktKhjt � Ihjt + qht

h(1� �)Kh

jt + "hjtI

hjt

isubject to (11), (12) and (24). The objective function can be simply rewritten as

�Rhkt + q

ht (1� �)

�Khjt��

1� qht "hjt�Ihjt: De�ne the cut-o¤ �"

ht � 1=qht : For the "

hjt > �"ht ; �rm j will invest the maximum

amount that it can achieve, therefore (11) and (24) are binding, i.e. Ihjt = qht �hKh

jt + RhktKhjt. For

the "hjt � �"ht ; �rm j will choose the minimum investment, i.e. zero level due to the irreversibil-

ity constraint. Put the optimal investment into (23), we can easily obtain the marginal value of

44

Page 45: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

the �rm vht = Rhkt + (1� �) qht +�qht �

h +Rhkt��qht�; where

�qht��R"hjt>�"

ht

�qht "

hjt � 1

�d� with

0�qht�> 0: Furthermore, from the de�nition qht � �hEt

�ht+1�ht

vht+1; the evolution of qht is thus

qht = �hEt�ht+1�ht

hRhkt+1 + (1� �) qht+1 +

�qht+1�

h +Rhkt+1

��qht+1

�i:

Q.E.D.

A.3 Proof of Proposition 3

Denote��hit; �

hit; �

hit

as the Lagrangian multipliers for constraints (1), (2), and (4), respectively.

The �rst-order condition for labor is

W ht

Z�hitdF (�) = h: (62)

Since labor is determined in the �rst sub-period of t before observing �it, the household knows

only the expected value of �hit when making labor supply decisions. The �rst-order conditions for�chit; s

hit+1; ~s

hit+1; a

hit+1

are given, respectively, by

�hitchit= �hit; (63)

�hit � �hit = �Et

��hit+1R

hbt

�; (64)

�hit � �hit � �hit = �Et

h�hit+1

�Rfbt � s

�~shit+1

���i; (65)

�hit � �hit = �Et

�hit+1

Dht+1 +Q

ht+1

Qht

!: (66)

Note that by arbitrage, bonds and equities must yield the same expected rate of return. Hence,

equations (64) and (66) imply Rhbt =Dht+1+Q

ht+1

Qhtin the absence of aggregate uncertainty.35 Rewriting

this relationship, we obtain equation (29). From equations (64) and (65), we can obtain equation

(28). Q.E.D.

35With aggregate uncertainty, the result holds to a �rst-order approximation.

45

Page 46: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

A.4 Proof of Proposition 4

For simplicity, here we drop the superscript h: We now �rst prove that the total wealth Hit =

(Qt +Dt) ait +Wtnit + sit + ~sit � s (~sit)� =(1 + �) is degenerated. In the second sub-period, the

households�consumption, saving, stock holding, can be written as a function of her own wealth

Hit, liquidity shock �it, and aggregate variables. We hence have

�it =�itcit=

�itct(Hit; �it)

(67)

Equation (64) can then be written as

�itct(Hit; �it)

= �RbtEi [�it+1] + �it (68)

= �Rbt

Wt+1+ �it;

where the second line has used equation (62). De�ne ��it, such that

��itHit +Bt

= �Rbt

Wt+1; (69)

Since cit � Hit + Bt, so we must have �itct(Hit;�it)

� ��itHit+Bt

for �it � ��it. By (68) and (69), we

must have �it > 0. Or the borrowing constraint (1) binds. And the household�s consumption is

cit = Hit +Bt. On the other hand, �it = 0, we must have

�itct(Hit; �it)

=��it

Hit +Bt(70)

or cit = (Hit +Bt)�it��it:Since cit < Hit +Bt, we must have �it < ��it. Finally using the consumption

rule derived above we rewrite equation (62) as

Wt

�Z�<��it

��itHit +Bt

f(�)d� +

Z�>��it

Hit +Btf(�)d�

�= 1: (71)

Equation (69) and (71) jointly determine ��it and Hit. It is evident that Hit and ��it only depend on

aggregate variables in the economy. Hence we have Hit = Ht, and ��it = ��t. Drop the subscription

i from equation (69), we obtain equation (33). Write equation (71) more compactly and drop the

subscription i, we obtain equation (34). The rest equations (31) and (32) are straightforward to

obtain. Q.E.D.

46

Page 47: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

A.5 Proof of Proposition 7

We proceed our proof in two steps. First, we show that there exist parameter values of �nancial

development such that home country in autarky has higher MPK and lower interest rate. Then

we show under these parameter values, the home country, in �nancial liberalization, holds positive

position in �nancial capital and negative position in �xed capital.

Lemma 1 Suppose the home country has tighter borrowing constraints on the �rm side, i.e.

�h < �f ; then for any bf ; there exist b and �b such that if bh 2�b;�b�;36 in the �nancial autarky

regime, the home country has higher MPK and lower real interest rate.

Proof of Lemma 1. In the �nancial autarky regime, the equilibrium return of capital r`

(MPK) (or the inverse KY ratio) and the real interest rate R`b are determined by (53) and (54).

In the autarky equilibrium r` and R`b are the functions of �nancial developments��`; b`

; we

denote them as rAut��`; b`

�and R�Aut

��`; b`

�respectively. As the Proposition 6 shows, we have

@rAut(�`;b`)@b`

> 0;@rAut(�`;b`)

@�`< 0 and

@R�Aut(�`;b`)

@b`> 0: Therefore, there exists �b satisfying

R�Aut

��f ; bf

�= R�Aut

��h;�b

�; (72)

such that for any bh < �b; we must have R�Aut��f ; bf

�> R�Aut

��h; bh

�:37 There also exists b satisfying

rAut

��f ; bf

�= rAut

��h; b

�; (73)

such that for any bh > b; 38 we must have rAut��h; bh

�> rAut

��f ; bf

�: Note that �b > b because of

@R(R`b;�`)

@Rb> 0 and

@R(R`b;�`)

@� < 0: Q.E.D.

Lemma 2 Suppose the home country has tighter borrowing constraints on the household side,

i.e. bh < bf ; and idiosyncratic investment e¢ ciency " follows Pareto distribution, then for any

�f ; there exists �� such that if �h < �� < �f ; in the �nancial autarky regime, the home country has

higher MPK and lower real interest rate.

Proof of Lemma 2. From (48), the Pareto distribution of " implies the MPK (or Y=K) in

autarky regime is a linear function of q: Furthermore, (54) implies R�Aut only depends on b and does

not depend on �: Thus, according to Proposition 6, bh < bf implies R�Aut�bh�< R�Aut

�bf�: On the

36Of course, �b and b are the functions of �h; �b and bf : Without risk of confusion, here we do not express themexplicitly as �b

��h; �f ; bf

�and b

��h; �f ; bf

�:

37 If we assume the investment e¢ ciency shock follows Pareto distribution, it can be shown that the R�Aut does notdepend on �; therefore �b is simply bf : That is, the higher level of �nancial development of foreign country on thehousehold side induces a higher interest rate.38Note that since �h < �f ;

@rAut(�`;b`)@�`

< 0 implies b < bf :

47

Page 48: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

other hand, analog to the proof of Lemma 1, there exists ����f ; bf ; bh

�satisfying

rAut

��f ; bf

�= rAut

���; bh

�> rAut

��f ; bh

�(74)

such that for any �h < �� < �f ; we must have rAut��h; bh

�> rAut

��f ; bf

�: Q.E.D.

We now turn to prove Proposition 7 with one of the following conditions: (i) �h < �f , and

bh 2�b;�b�; as stated in Lemma 1; or (ii) bh < bf ; �h < �� < �f and " follows Pareto distribution,

as stated in Lemma 2. The pattern of two-way capital �ows requires us to show that in the

liberalization regime interest rates satisfy Rfb > Rhb and MPKs satisfy rh > rf : We proceed the

proof by ruling out all the complement relationships.

First, we show Rfb = Rhb is impossible. In this case, there is no �nancial capital �ow across

countries. Since R (Rb; �) is decreasing in � and �h < �f ; we must have Rhk > Rfk and rh > rf .39

The higher MPK in home country attracts FDI from foreign country, i.e. uf > 0: And FDI

in�ow will shift the capital supply downwardly.40 Consequently, FDI in�ow reduces interest rate

in home country and raises interest rate in foreign country. This means, comparing to the autarky

equilibrium, we have Rfb > R�Aut��f ; bf

�> R�Aut

��h; bh

�> Rhb which contradicts R

fb = Rhb :

Second, we show rh = rf is impossible. In this case, there is no FDI �ow across countries, and

Rhk = rh = Rfk = rf . Under the parameter values satisfying Lemma 1 or 2, we must have Rhb < Rfb

since R (Rb; �) is decreasing in � and increasing in Rb:41 The higher interest rate in foreign country

attracts bonds in�ow, which shifts capital supply curve in foreign country downwardly. In contrast,

the bonds out�ow moves capital supply curve in home country upwardly.42 As a result, comparing

to the autarky regime, MPK in home country goes up and MPK in foreign country falls down.

Therefore we have rh > rAut��h; bh

�> rAut

��f ; bf

�> rf which is a contradiction with rh = rf :

Third, we show Rfb < Rhb and rh > rf is impossible. Since in this case, home country experiences

both FDI and bonds in�ows, both of which shift capital supply curve downwardly and thus reduces

interest rate, i.e. Rhb < R�Aut��h; bh

�. In contrast, the FDI and bonds out�ows in foreign country

39Then we already rule out two combinations: Rfb = Rhb and rh < rf or Rfb = Rhb and r

h = rf :40More speci�cally, in this case, the capital supply curve in home country (Eqn. 51) takes the form

(1� �)�1 + �uf

�Y h

�Kh =�

11�h �Rhb

�qh + h

1�h qhbh: Since �uf > 0; comparing to the autarky regime, the supply

curve shifts downwardly.41Thus we rule out the combination: rh = rf with Rhb � Rfb :

42More speci�cally, in this case, the capital supply curve in home country (Eqn. 51) takes the form (1� �) Yh

�Kh =�1

1�h �Rhb

�qh + h

1�h qhbh +

h1

1�h ��

�1+�

Rfb +1

1+�Rhb

�i~Sh

Kh : Since the last term in R.H.S is greater than zero;

comparing to the autarky regime, the supply curve shifts upwardly.

48

Page 49: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

shift both capital demand and supply curve upwardly43. As a result, the interest rate in foreign

country increases, i.e., Rfb > R�Aut��f ; bf

�. Since with the parameter values satisfying Lemma 1 or

2, we have R�Aut��h; bh

�< R�Aut

��f ; bf

�, and thus we must have Rhb < Rfb which contradicts with

Rfb < Rhb : With the same logic, we can show Rfb > Rhb and rh < rf is impossible as well.

Hence, home country, in the fully liberalization regime, has higher MPK and lower interest

rate. Consequently, home country will hold positive position in �xed capital and negative position

in �nancial capital. Q.E.D.

Appendix B: Data

B1. U.S. net positions of direct investment abroad relative to China (dashed line in Figure 1a).

The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) produces comprehensive statistics on U.S. direct invest-

ment abroad through the mandatory surveys. U.S. direct investment abroad is de�ned as ownership

by a U.S. investor of at least 10 percent of a foreign business. Direct investment position statistics

are stocks and are cumulative; they measure the total outstanding level of U.S. direct investment

abroad at year end. The series used in our paper is the item "Position of direct investment abroad

on a historical-cost basis" from the BEA website44.

B2. U.S. net positions in debt instruments relative to China (solid line in Figure 1a). The

United States collects data on cross-border portfolio investment through the Treasury International

Capital (TIC) reporting system. The cross-border portfolio investment includes foreign holdings

of U.S. long-term and short-term securities, and U.S. holdings of foreign long-term and short term

securities. In our paper, we de�ne the U.S. net positions in debt relative to China as the U.S.�s

holdings of China�s long-term and short-term debt net of China�s holdings of U.S. long-term and

short-term debt. Therefore, the negative value indicates net in�ows of �nancial capital toward the

U.S.

B3. China�s GDP is measured in U.S. dollar. More speci�cally, we transform China�s nominal

GDP by multiplying it with the annual exchange rate. Since RMB experienced sharp devaluation

starting from 2006, to aviod the valuation e¤ect, we replace the exchange rates in 2006 to 2010 by

the value at 2005. China�s net position of �nancial capital investment (solid line in Figure 1b). The

series consists of the total net international reserve (excluding gold reserve) and the net security

investments (equity+debt) which represents portfolio investments. Data source: CEIC.

B4. China�s net position of direct investment abroad (dashed line in Figure 1b). The series is

the accumulative outward direct investment �ows minus the accumulative inward direct investment

�ows. Data source: CEIC.43 In particular, the FDI out�ow simultaneously shifts capital demand and supply upwardly. The bonds out�ow

only shifts the capital supply upwardly.44Comparing to the U.S. direct investment to China, the amount of foreign investment from China to U.S. is

negligible, we use the former series to represent U.S. net position of direct investment abroad relative to China.

49

Page 50: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

B5. Rate of return to �xed capital (�rst panel in Figure 2). Here we brie�y illustrate the

method and data used in our calculations. Bai et al (2006) use the following formula to calculate

the real rate of return to capital r (t)

r (t) =� (t)

PK (t)K (t) = [PY (t)Y (t)]+hPK (t)� PY (t)

i� � (t) ; (A1)

where � (t) is the share of payments to capital; PK (t)K (t) and PY (t)Y (t) are capital stock and

GDP in current price, respectively; PK (t) and PY (t) are the growth rate of investment price de�ator

and GDP de�ator, respectively; � (t) is the depreciation rate. For China�s capital return r (t) ; we

just use the updated data to extend Bai�s series to more recent year 2010. And the counterpart of

the United States, we use the same method. In particular, we compute the capital return for the

non-�nancial corporate business in private sector. We also exclude the residential sectors. � (t) is

capital share in US non-�nancial corporate business . It is 1� Compensation of employeesValue added . Both series

are from "Table 1.14. Gross Value Added of Domestic Corporate Business in Current Dollars and

Gross Value Added of Non�nancial Domestic Corporate Business in Current and Chained Dollars",

BEA. PK (t)K (t) is the nonresidential capital stock (equipments&softwares plus structures) in

current cost in non-�nancial corporate business, billions of dollars. Data are from "Table 4.1.

Current-Cost Net Stock of Private Nonresidential Fixed Assets by Industry Group and Legal Form

of Organization". � (t) is the depreciation rate in U.S. private non-�nancial corporate business. It

is consumption of capitalCapital Stock , data source is the same as � (t) : PY (t) is the growth rate of GDP de�ator,

PK (t) is the growth rate of Gorden price index for investment goods. The Gorden price index

measures prices of bunch of investment goods by quality adjustment, for details, see Liu, Wang and

Zha (2011). For the alternative calculation of the return of capital, we follow the simple de�nition

in Poterba (1998) as (Pro�ts Before Tax with IVA&CCAdj + Net Interest Payments)/Capital

Stock, the data source are the same as � (t) : Note that our calculated series is slightly higher than

Poterba�s results (only up to those data before 1996), this is probably because we do not include

inventory and land into our capital stock de�nition.

B6. Real interest rate (second panel in Figure 2). Annual lending rate in real term, downloaded

from World Development Indicator (WDI).

B7. Private credit to GDP ratio (Figure 3). Downloaded from the World Development Indicator

(WDI), it is de�ned as the ratio of domestic credit to private sector to GDP. It is a traditional

indicator of the asset side capture one of the most important functions of �nancial intermediaries�

credit allocation.

B8. Components of the U.S. direct investment abroad and Chinese inward FDI.

According to the de�nition of BEA, foreign direct investment �ows consists of four parts:

50

Page 51: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

(1) Equity investment, which is the di¤erence between equity increases and equity decreases.

Equity increases arise from

(a) parents�establishments of new a¢ liates,

(b) payments by parents to una¢ liated parties for the purchase of capital stock or other

equity interests when they acquire an existing business,

(c) payments made to acquire additional ownership interests in their a¢ liates,

(d) capital contributions to their a¢ liates. Equity decreases are the funds parents receive

when they reduce their equity interest in their a¢ liates.

(2) Intercompany debt investment, which results from changes in net outstanding loans

between parents (or for inward investment, other foreign parent group members) and their

a¢ liates, including loans by parents to a¢ liates and loans by a¢ liates to parents.

(3) Reinvested earnings (without current-cost adjustment), which are the parents� share of

the current-period operating earnings of their a¢ liates, less distributions of earnings that

a¢ liates make to their parents. A related measure of reinvested earnings is featured in the

international transactions accounts; this measure includes a current-cost adjustment that

re�ects current-period prices. This adjustment converts depreciation charges to a current-

cost, or replacement-cost, basis; it adds charges for depletion of natural resources back to

income and reinvested earnings because these charges are not treated as production costs in

the national income and product accounts; and it reallocates expenses for mineral exploration

and development across periods, so that they are written o¤ over their economic lives rather

than all at once.

(4) Various valuation adjustments to the historical-cost position, which are made to account

for the di¤erences between changes in the historical-cost positions, which are measured at

book value, and direct investment �nancial �ows, which are measured at transaction value.

(Unlike the positions on current-cost and market-value bases, the historical-cost position is

not usually adjusted to account for changes in the replacement cost of the tangible asset of

a¢ liates or in the market value of parent companies equity in a¢ liates.)

If we only look at the �rst three components, only item (b) and (c) in Equity investment

correspond to the FDI in Mendosa et al. (2011). Item (a) and (d) in Equity investment, as well

as Intercompany debt investment + Reinvested earnings, in our view, correspond to the

de�nition of FDI in our model. In particular, the change of FDI (or U.S. FDI out�ow) can be

expressed as

�FDIt = uftKft � u

ft�1K

ft�1

51

Page 52: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

where the total earnings from FDI is rht uftK

ft ; which consists of reinvested earnings (REt) and

earnings distributed to parents (EDt). Therefore, �FDIt can be further expressed as

�FDIt = REt +hEDt � rht u

ftK

ft +

�uftK

ft � u

ft�1K

ft�1

�i:

The �rst term is reinvested earnings, the second term can be treated as (a)+(d)+(2)+(3).

Therefore, (a)+(d)+(2)+(3)(1)+(2)+(3) measures the fraction of FDI captured by our model. However, BEA

only has the series of equity investment, so we can only calculate the ratio (2)+(3)(1)+(2)+(3) , which tends

to understate the role of the form of FDI de�ned in our model. Collecting the relevant data and

calculating the ratio (2)+(3)(1)+(2)+(3) for U.S-China FDI �ows gives 0.76.

45 As a robustness check, we also

calculate the ratio (2)+(3)(1)+(2)+(3) for the total FDI out�ow from U.S. to all countries and the number

is about 0.62.46

According to the ownership of foreign invested projects in China, the FDI in�ows can be divided

into four main categories: equity joint ventures (EJVs), cooperative operation enterprises or con-

tractual joint ventures (CJVs), wholly foreign-owned enterprises (WFOs), and others.47 EJVs and

CJVs both involve joint investment by Chinese and foreign partners, the main di¤erence between

these two type of FDI is the arrangement for sharing pro�t and losses. WFOs are the enterprises

whose ownerships fully belong to foreigners. According to the above de�nitions, WFOs largely

represent new businesses established and owned by foreign �rms. The following �gure reports the

shares of WFOs and EJVs+CJVs in total FDI in�ows to China. As can be seen, after China�s

accession to WTO in 2001, WFOs exceed EJVs+CJVs and become the dominant form of FDI

in�ows. Therefore, we can safely infer that new businesses set up by foreign �rms play a dominant

role in FDI in�ows.45The series used are from U.S. Direct Investment Abroad, i.e. FDI out�ow from U.S. to China. Since FDI out�ow

from China to U.S. is negligible and has very limited observations, we use the former series to represent net FDI �owsbetween two countries. Next, we calculate the sum of each item. For instance, we sum (3), the reinvested earnings,from 1982 to 2010 to get the stock of FDI. We can then obtain the ratio through the formula (2)+(3)

(1)+(2)+(3):

46 In particular, the sum of intercompany debt (item (2)) from 1982 to 2010 is about 148,128 millions of dollars,the reinvested earnings (item (3)) is about 1,979,725 millions of dollars, and the equity investment (item (1)) is1,264,370 millions of dollars. If we look at the net FDI out�ow from U.S. to all countries, item (2) is -323,179 m$,item (3) is 1,753,657 m$, and item (1) is -1,205,846. Therefore, in terms of absolute level, (2)+(3) still dominate (1).47Catagory "Others" contains foreign sharing-holding enterprises (SH) and joint exploration (JE).

52

Page 53: Two$Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances v A Neoclassical

Figure A1. Percentage Shares of FDI In�ows by Type (data source: CEIC).

53