32
magazine 24 ine ine Tinbergen Magazine is published by the Tinbergen Institute, the research institute and graduate school of Erasmus University Rotterdam, University of Amsterdam and VU University Amsterdam. Fall 2011 Interview with Jerry A. Hausman: Taking heterogeneity seriously Interview with Bengt Holmström: In search of the unexpected inDepth Owen O’Donnell / Eddy van Doorslaer: Lifting the lid on socioeconomic inequalities in health

TI 24 nummer - Tinbergen Institute · Katz and Paul Lazarsfeld1 identifi ed a key feature of social communication: a very small fraction—

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

magazine24magazine24magazine

Tinbergen Magazine is published bythe Tinbergen Institute, the research

institute and graduate schoolof Erasmus University Rotterdam,

University of Amsterdam and VU University Amsterdam.

Fall 2011

Interview with Jerry A. Hausman:Taking heterogeneity seriously

Interview with Bengt Holmström:In search of the unexpected

inDepth

Owen O’Donnell /

Eddy van Doorslaer:

Lifting the lid on

socioeconomic

inequalities

in health

2

Colophon | Fall 2011 | #24

Tinbergen Magazine is published by

Tinbergen Institute, the research

institute and graduate school operated

jointly by the Economics and

Econometrics faculties of three Dutch

universities: Erasmus University

Rotterdam, University of Amsterdam

and VU University Amsterdam.

Tinbergen Magazine highlights

on-going research at the Tinbergen

Institute and is published twice a year.

Photographs

Henk Thomas, Amsterdam

Levien Willemse, Rotterdam

Editorial services

Etc. Editorial, Breda

Design

Crasborn Grafi sch Ontwerpers bno,

Valkenburg a.d. Geul

www.crasborn.nl

Printing

Drukkerij Tonnaer, Kelpen

ISSN 1566-3213

Addresses

Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam

Gustav Mahlerplein 117

1082 MS Amsterdam

The Netherlands

Telephone:

+31 (0)20 525 1600

Tinbergen Institute Rotterdam

Burg. Oudlaan 50

3062 PA Rotterdam

The Netherlands

Telephone:

+31 (0)10 408 8900

e-mail: [email protected]

www.tinbergen.nl

Column 4 The economics of social networks The economics of social networks

Sanjeev Goyal

upClose 5Taking heterogeneity seriouslyTaking heterogeneity seriously

An interview with Jerry A. Hausman An interview with Jerry A. Hausman > By Marloes Lammers> By Marloes Lammers

upClose 8upClose 8In search of the unexpectedIn search of the unexpected

An interview with Bengt HolmströmAn interview with Bengt Holmström > By Falk Bräuning and Karoline Scholtus > By Falk Bräuning and Karoline Scholtus

inDepth 14inDepth 14Lifting the lid on socioenconomic inequalities in healthLifting the lid on socioenconomic inequalities in health

Owen O’Donnell and Eddy van Doorslaer Owen O’Donnell and Eddy van Doorslaer

Letters from Alumni 18 Letters from Alumni 18 Taco C.R. van Someren, YnnovateYnnovate

inShort 19 Papers in journals 19

Discussion papers 20 papers 20Theses 22

References 23References 23About us 31 About us 31

contents

24Colophon | Fall 2011 | #2424Colophon | Fall 2011 | #24

3tinbergen magazine fall 2011

L L LettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlum Alum Alum Alum Alum nininininininininininininininininininininininininininininininininininifromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumlife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defense

inShort

4

1918

contentmagazinemagazinecontentmagazinecontent

ettersettersettersettersettersettersettersetters

5

148

Column

columnThe economics of social networks

TI Magazine’s column highlights a current news topic.

Sanjeev Goyal

• Sanjeev Goyal is Professor of Economics at the University of Cambridge and Fellow of Christ’s College, Cambridge. He has been a research fellow at Tinbergen Institute since 1995. •

4

Workers fi nd jobs via personal acquaintances, fi rms collaborate to introduce new technologies, doctors prescribe new drugs based on conversations with colleagues, farmers learn about crops from neighboring farms, and pupils strive to conform to the work ethic of their peers at school. Our ideas, opportunities and choices are shaped by the connections we have. Our awareness that connections matter leads us to invest in them—and this gives rise to such things as friendship circles, Twitter, the World Wide Web, inter-fi rm alliances and many other networks that we see around us.

In a series of pioneering studies in the 1950s, Elihu Katz and Paul Lazarsfeld1 identifi ed a key feature of social communication: a very small fraction—about 20%—of the population, whom they called ‘opinion leaders’, served as the primary source of information for the rest. In the intervening decades, a number of studies on information and communication have confi rmed that this is a robust feature of social networks. Malcolm Gladwell, author of “The Tipping Point”, calls this the law of the few2.

The network of social communication is comprised of ties between individuals. Creating and maintaining ties is costly in terms of time and effort. A tie with another person gives access not only to the information and ideas that this person has—but also to information that she may have acquired from others through her own connections. It is more attractive to form a tie with someone who is well connected, as this person is more likely to be better informed. So the decision on whether or not to form a tie will be sensitive to the tie formation decisions of others.

An important insight gleaned from the research on network formation is that economic pressures give rise to networks that exhibit the law of the few. These networks have what is called a core-periphery architecture. The core contains a small fraction of the population; a member of the

core typically has a substantial number of ties (with most

members of the core, and with a small fraction of the periphery). The

periphery is comprised of the vast majority of the population; an individual in the

periphery has a few links—most of which are with members of the core. When there is a single core member, this gives rise to a ‘star’ network. Everyone is at most two ties away from everyone else. This is a small world indeed.

There are two economic forces underlying the salience of the core-periphery architecture in social communication. The fi rst is that additional information has diminishing returns; if information of different individuals is substitutable, this implies that individuals’ incentives for forming ties are falling with the number of current connections. The second economic force has to do with decay/delay of information as it fl ows across the network: this creates a pressure to shorten paths to others.

The core-periphery structure is effi cient, as it economizes on the number of links and at the same time has little information decay/delay (due to short distances between the individuals). However, it also exhibits signifi cant inequality: the members of the core are much better connected than members of the periphery—and this is often refl ected in unequal economic outcomes.

A simple way to make advertising and social information campaigns more effective is to exploit the network of social communication. If the network is homogenous, then there is little to be gained from learning more about it. However, if the network is very unequal, then knowing about its structure—who is connected to whom—can greatly enhance the effectiveness of information campaigns. The law of the few tells us that there are good reasons for investing in the collection of network data.

Notes

1) Katz, E. and P. Lazarsfeld (1955), Personal Infl uence: The Part Played by People in the Flow of Mass Communications. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.

2) Gladwell, M. (2000), The Tipping Point: How Little Things Can Make a Big Difference, Boston, MA: Little, Brown and Company.

Further Reading

Bala, V. and S. Goyal (2000), A non-cooperative model of network formation.Econometrica.

Bramoulle, Y. and R. Kranton (2007), Public goods in networks. Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, 135(1), 478-494, July.

Galotti, A. and S. Goyal (2010), The law of the few, American Economic Review, 100(4): 1468–92.

Goyal, S. (2007), Connections: An Introduction to the Economics of Networks. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 5

You have written on numerous topics, both in theoretical econometrics and applied

econometrics. What do you think has been your main contribution to economic research thus far?I’d have to say it is the Hausman1 (1978) test, without a doubt. And, more in general, introducing the idea that when we can estimate an economic model in different ways, we should get approximately the same results if this model is correctly specifi ed.

You must have developed the Hausman test with some specifi c applications in mind. Have you ever encountered a paper using the Hausman test in an area or fi eld that you never expected it would be applied to?It happens all the time, actually. At a conference in China last summer I met George Tauchen (Professor of Economics and Finance at Duke University), who was talking about the use of Laplace transforms in fi nancial economics. I would never have thought that my test would be applied in this type of research.

By Marloes Lammers

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics at MIT in Cambridge, Massachusetts. He has published numerous papers in

econometrics and applied microeconomics. In May, Hausman taught the Tinbergen

Econometrics Lectures 2011 on modeling heterogeneity in econometric models.

upCloseInterview

Taking heterogeneity

seriouslyJerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie

S. MacDonald Professor of Economics at MIT in Cambridge, Massachusetts. He has published numerous papers in

econometrics and applied microeconomics. In May, Hausman taught the Tinbergen

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics at MIT in Cambridge, Massachusetts. He has published numerous papers in

econometrics and applied microeconomics.

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics at MIT in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

econometrics and applied microeconomics.

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie S. MacDonald Professor of Economics

econometrics and applied microeconomics.

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie

heterogeneity

Jerry A. Hausman is the John and Jennie

heterogeneityheterogeneityheterogeneityheterogeneityheterogeneity

6

You have written some papers on duration models. To date, these models are mainly used in mortality studies and in labor economics. Do you think there is scope for using these methods outside of these fi elds? What are the advantages of using these methods? And what are their limitations?An example of the use of duration models outside of labor economics concerns the studying of defaults—for example, on home mortgages. Suppose you give out a loan and someone pays you back each month. Then you want to know what the probability of a default is. The problem with a loan is that the probability to default on the loan is very high in the beginning of the period. When individuals do not default in the beginning, the probability of default becomes much lower. The fact that we see this behavior in the data has much to do with unobserved heterogeneity: some individuals are ‘movers’, whereas others are ‘stayers’. Another example therefore can be seen in the moving behavior of households. What researchers sometimes do is to fi t a logit model for each period and estimate the probability of a default or a move. But that really does not take into account unobserved heterogeneity. Then you do not get a correct estimate on the effect of your covariates. Instead, the estimate tells you something about your stochastic disturbances. Duration models are able to take this unobserved heterogeneity into account, and can therefore be applied in these fi elds as well. The main defect of duration models is that they cannot take into account simultaneity problems. Their other main weakness is that the econometric modeling should be more closely connected to economics. Currently, we just think of some variables that can plausibly affect our dependent variable and put them in our duration framework. It would be better to derive the

framework from a more structural model of, for example, a demand equation or search models.

Talking about structural models: there has been a long ongoing debate in economics concerning the use of structural versus reduced-form modeling. What is your stand in this debate?I am leaning more toward the structural side—although I do think that reduced-form modeling is useful in the following sense: I share the view of Richard Blundell (UCL), who was involved in a tax reform in the UK. His view was that when you need to convince policymakers of the fact that when taxes change, people’s behavior changes, you often cannot explain that to policymakers who are not economists using a structural model. Structural models are far too complicated for policymakers to understand. But if you present a reduced-form model, and you explain that taxes changed last year, and at the same time people’s labor force participation and hours worked changed as well, then that is very easy to comprehend. This gives policymakers more faith in reduced-form results. The problem with that, however, is that reduced-form modeling often reveals very little about the parameters that you need to know. That is where you really need a structural model. It is good if you can convince a policymaker that when taxes go up, people will buy fewer goods, but what you really want to know is what the elasticity is, such that you can advise on optimal taxation.

Then how do you feel about all the quasi- experimental methods, natural experiments and fi eld experiments being used?I did a lot of work myself on actual experiments a long time ago. The problems with these experimental methods (and these are well-known drawbacks) are that when an effect is measured in, say, a village

in India, you do not know what the effect will be in the next village— let alone the effect in a village in Pakistan. The second defect, as I mentioned earlier, is that experimental methods do not allow us to estimate relevant policy parameters. The last issue is that you should take selective attrition into account. For example, in medicine, where researchers use double blind experiments for drug testing, results are often biased as follows: when a medicine is fi rst developed and goes on trial, it usually comes with a host of side-effects. Later on, doctors fi gure out how to deal with these. So if there is heterogeneity, the people that the drug started to work on stay in the sample, whereas the ones that the drug did not start to work on drop out in an attempt to escape the side-effects. This is selective attrition. The only thing that a researcher can do is to assume that for the people that dropped out the drug had no effect, which will give a lower bound on the estimate of the effectiveness of the drug. More generally, individuals can behave in a way that the researcher did not intend. Say that you are distributing mosquito nets. Who is to say that these things are actually used in the right way? And: who is monitoring whether these people use the nets? And I could think of numerous other examples… Non-random attrition is a huge problem when doing experiments—and researchers should worry more about it. Unfortunately, there is not a whole lot you can do about it, and people tend to forget the things they cannot do anything about.

Another example is the estimation of Local Average Treatment Effects using quasi-experimental methods. I am not a fan of that at all, because why do we do statistics? With statistics, we can have a random sample and draw inferences for the population. With a Local Average

You have written some papers on duration models. To date, these models are mainly used in mortality studies and in labor economics. Do you think there is scope for using these methods outside of these fi elds? What are the advantages of using these methods? And what are their limitations?An example of the use of duration models outside of labor economics concerns the studying of defaults—for example, on home mortgages. Suppose you give out a loan and someone pays you back each month. Then you want to know what the probability of a default is. The problem with a loan is that the probability to

framework from a more structural model of, for example, a demand equation or search models.

Talking about structural models: there has been a long ongoing debate in economics concerning the use of structural versus reduced-form modeling. What is your stand in this debate?I am leaning more toward the structural side—although I do think that reduced-

“Especially in these kinds of models with nonlinear prices (which are a consequence of nonlinear

taxation) it is very important to take heterogeneity into account.”

7

Treatment Effect you are studying a group of people, for whom the results cannot be extrapolated to a population of interest.

You mentioned a few times that it is important to take heterogeneity into account when doing economic modeling. Could you give an example in which not modeling heterogeneity—or modeling it “the wrong way”—could lead to detrimental (policy) conclusions?Back in the ’80s I did some work on the effect of taxes on labor supply. I modeled heterogeneity in a labor supply model, and it turned out that especially in these kinds of models with nonlinear prices (which are a consequence of nonlinear taxation) it is very important to take heterogeneity into account. I found that the effect of taxes on labor supply is much larger than what was found without incorporating heterogeneity. It used to be thought that for men, there was no effect of nonlinear taxes on labor supply at all. Now we understand that the effect is sizable. And policy reacts to those results: we used to have fourteen tax brackets, now we have three. Blomquist and Newey2 (2002) modeled this for Sweden, and found similar results.

Can you give another example in which you could directly infl uence governmental or business policy using insights from your work as a researcher? An early paper of mine written in the ’70s explored the issues involved when individuals consider buying more effi cient appliances, which use less electricity. There is the trade-off that effi cient appliances cost more, but then are less expensive in usage. I discovered that there is quite some heterogeneity—in that especially among poorer people, individuals tend to pay too much attention to the initial cost and not to the cost of the electricity usage. Because they are fi nancially constrained, they acted as if they had very high

discount rates. I later used these insights when I worked with a mobile telephone company in the ’80s and advised them to offer a contract with a low initial price of the mobile phone that makes it possible to pay off the phone over a period of two years. And the insight this research provided is not only used in the mobile phone industry: if you buy an alarm system in the US, it is free when you sign a two-year contract. The same applies with a satellite dish in England. These examples show both the effect of econometrics on real life and how important heterogeneity is.

The Netherlands is unique in that it has a bachelors/masters program in econometrics separate from the economics bachelors/masters. However, this distinction between economics and econometrics currently disappears in the PhD phase. Do you think that it would be a good idea (for the quality of econometric research in the Netherlands) to have specialized courses for econometricians in the PhD phase as well?I’d have to say ‘no’, since most econometricians will end up doing a mixture of applied economics and econometrics, and the methodology is much more useful when it has applications. If we train econometricians just to do statistics and math, it is easy to lose sight of the usefulness of new methods in

applied work. So at MIT, in the fi rst two years of their studies students take courses in both economics and econometrics—and I think they are good because of that.In the Netherlands, I think there is something that should be reinstated in the graduate economics programs. I once taught some lectures in NAKE courses, which students from all over the Netherlands attended. Such specialized courses with lecturers from all over the world are truly valuable. However, the Netherlands is obviously doing really well, since it beats many of the larger European countries in terms of the number of excellent econometricians.

Notes

1) Hausman, J.A. (1978), Specifi cation tests in econometrics, Econometrica, 46, 1251-1271.

2) Blomquist, S. and W. Newey (2002), Nonparametric estimation with nonlinear budget sets. Econometrica, 70, 2455–2480.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011

“The Netherlands is obviously doing really well, since it beats

many of the larger European countries in terms of the number

of excellent econometricians.”

upClose

8

In search of the unexpected

Interview

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 9

Now that the TI Finance Lectures 2011 have taken place, could you please share your impressions

about the atmosphere and the students at Tinbergen Institute?One of the reasons I had for coming here had to do with wanting to know what the students are like at Tinbergen Institute, and what their interests are. This visit also allowed me to meet some of the faculty, including Enrico Perotti, whom I know very

well. It’s been nice to see—for the fi rst time—where his intellectual home is, and it’s been a pleasure to communicate with the students, who seem happy and enthusiastic about what they are doing. Overall, a great experience.

Could you summarize in a few main messages what you wanted to communicate during the lectures?I spoke about approaches to analyzing

liquidity provision. Although I had initially planned to go through a canon of models, I eventually decided to focus on my own work, because I thought it would be of interest for the students not just to learn how the models work, but also to hear why we approached the questions the way we did.

In my work with Jean Tirole2, the main messages relate to the demand for and supply of insurance. More specifi cally, how do fi rms meet their need to arrange future funding in advance through credit lines, bonds and related instruments, and what are the constraints placed on the suppliers of such insurance? To be credible, all insurance contracts must be backed up by income from productive assets. In a world in which all income cannot be pledged, as we assume, there may be a shortage of collateral. Collateral shortages have been one of the hallmarks of the current fi nancial crisis. Our analysis of collateral shortages suggests that the government has a key role to play in helping markets to stay suffi ciently liquid and avoid crises. Private markets will not be able to do an adequate job, because they lack the ability to tax current and future generations. Central bank interventions of the kind we have seen, where the taxpayer foots part of the bill, can theoretically be justifi ed along these lines—although our analysis does not include the costs of moral hazard.

Bengt Holmström is the Paul A. Samuelson professor of Economics at MIT in Cambridge, Massachusetts and holds a joint appointment with MIT’s Sloan School of Management. In September 2011, he gave the Tinbergen Institute Finance Lectures on liquidity and fi nancial crises. He is currently president of the Econometric Society. Besides his academic activities, Holmström is also on the board of Nokia1.

by Falk Bräuning and Karolina Scholtus

10

During the lectures I also discussed the work I am currently doing with Gary Gorton and Tri Vi Dang3. This work emphasizes the role of trust in money markets. These markets are designed in a way that minimizes the amount of information that participants need to acquire. This is why debt contracts are used. The virtue of debt is that— properly collateralized— it requires less information than other securities, including equity. Contrary to the prevailing wisdom, lack of transparency is not an anomaly in money markets — rather the opposite. I know that this is a radical thought, but our argument is more plausible than the common claims that only a handful of outsiders saw what really was taking place on Wall Street and in the economy. There must be a reason why so little information was acquired, and the reason we are suggesting is that instruments in money markets are designed exactly with that purpose in mind. Of course, someone has to make sure the instruments are credible; issuers, raters and the government all have to share that responsibility.

What would you consider to be your most infl uential work? How do you perceive your contribution after so many years of research?I am best known for my work on moral hazard, and I am pleased with the scientifi c fl ow of this work. My early papers focused on uncovering the logic of the basic moral hazard models: how those models “think”. I found that they are fundamentally about the optimal use of performance information, as if performance is a signal of what the agent does. This view is surprising, because the model assumes that the principal knows what the agent does, once a contract has been signed. The information perspective led to precise prescriptions for the type of information that is of value in a contract, including the value of relative performance evaluation. The characterization of the optimal contract is highly intuitive, but also reveals that the early models over-emphasized the role of detailed information. This led to me to wonder, with Paul Milgrom, why linear contracts are so frequently used. They fi t poorly with the basic agency model, because linear contracts aggregate information. Our analysis of linear contracts led us to discover the importance of multi-tasking and the role of alternative instruments. This completely changed our perspective on agency models. It made us see, for instance, the virtue of low-powered incentives and bureaucracy, which are so prevalent in fi rms. The thought that these features are anything else than liabilities

“Contrary to the prevailing wisdom, lack of

transparency is not an anomaly in money markets — rather the

opposite.”

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 11

within fi rms is a fairly radical (but I think fundamentally correct) idea that can be supported by casual observation. Incentive provision within fi rms is much more about indirect instruments such as job design than about direct instruments.

What often intrigues me most are insights that run against the prevailing wisdom. This is true of my current work on ignorance and liquidity, but it has been present in most of what I’ve done. My work with Milton Harris on downward wage rigidity showed that the widely held belief that worker commitment is required for wage insurance is false. Even if workers can walk away whenever their productivity proves to be high, downside protection can be offered by having the worker pay for the insurance in advance by taking a lower pay early in their career.4 In the fi eld of dynamic agency, it was thought that the agent’s concern for reputation will alleviate incentive problems. Actually, “career concerns” are often the source of incentive problems rather than the solution. For instance, ‘short-termism’ by fi rms is probably driven by the attempt to infl uence perceptions about value in capital markets. Political pandering has similar roots. Transparency in these models may worsen these problems.

Turning things upside down —in a revealing and constructive way—gives me quite a bit of pleasure. The best lectures are those where the listener walks in with the

conviction that A is true, and after the lecture is convinced not only that A is not true, but that it is obviously so.

There are plenty of different explanations for the global fi nancial crisis, including greed, wrong actions or inaction by the US and other governments. What is your view of the global crisis? Greed alone cannot be the explanation. People have been greedy for as long as we have studied human behavior. The question is which additional ingredient made 70 years of relative fi nancial calm turn into calamity. A popular view seems to be that the crisis was caused by opaque and complex instruments. My work with Tri Vi Dang and Gary Gorton questions this view. Collective trust and ignorance are at the heart of liquidity provision in money markets.

The problem is that liquidity may be oversupplied, making the system susceptible to a loss of confi dence and panic. Globalization created trade imbalances that led to unprecedented demands for safe investment instruments that would allow excess savings to be parked at low or no risk. The shadow banking system in the US was ideally positioned to satisfy the demand. Securitization could deliver AAA-rated securities out of relatively low-grade collateral—and the system was highly scalable, thanks to the large housing market and the reuse of home equity.

The general idea of securitization was prevalent, as most of Wall Street was following this course. The problem was not qualitative. It was quantitative. The scale got too big and the underlying collateral proved insuffi cient and susceptible to correlated risks. There is a deep underlying paradox with regard to liquidity. Making the system safer increases the risk of large collapses, as investors become less wary of risks. Europe is facing the same problem right now. Excess trust in the euro led to excess issuance of debt. Regulation is needed, but it’s not obvious to me what structure it should have. I like stress testing, and prudence suggests that bank capital should be increased. But what is enough? Transparency is not the obvious answer people seem to think it is, either.

As a Finnish citizen you must be concerned about the future of the euro. The current crisis has raised a lot of questions and debates, but somehow the whole situation seems to be a longer term, structural problem. Where do you see the Euro zone, say, within 20 years? Will we have a European government deciding on fi scal policy? Certainly there is a signifi cant probability that things will end up badly for the euro: for the fi rst time in its brief history the Euro zone might become fragmented. Like the rapid expansion of shadow banking in the US, the euro is a historical experiment. There are many problems with the euro. I

“The ECB is responsible for something that it cannot really

control. Detaching responsibility from authority is certainly

a bad principle.”

12

don’t think that fi scal coordination is necessarily the biggest one. I would focus initially on redesigning the banking system. European banks fall under separate jurisdictions, but ‘life support’ for the banking system is provided by a central agency, the ECB. The ECB is responsible for something that it cannot really control. Detaching responsibility from authority is certainly a bad principle. I would consider giving the ECB jurisdiction over all the banks in the Euro zone. Europe could adopt something similar to the US system. If a Californian bank goes bankrupt or comes close to fi ling for bankruptcy, it is handled by the FDIC (the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation), not by the state of California. Another key element of the US system is that the FED never buys state bonds the way the ECB is buying Greek, Spanish and Italian bonds. There is no bailout. As a result, California and other states have adopted balanced budget amendments to be able to raise funds more cheaply. They have done so voluntarily, without any federally imposed requirements. This may be the long-term structure 20 years from now.

Do you think that all of the knowledge and insights we have gotten from fi nancial crises can help to prevent future crises?There will always be the potential for crises. Calls for “never again” probably raise the likelihood and size of the next crisis. People will be more trusting, which sows the seeds for another bout of excess liquidity. Not perhaps soon, but eventually. It may well be good for the system if people were slightly wary of crises. Awareness of the possibility of a crisis will naturally reduce liquidity. But we have miles to go in trying to understand how to regulate the amount of liquidity so that there’s not too much or too little of it. And investors may seize on odd assets, as they did during the ‘tulipmania’ that took place here in the Netherlands in the 1600s. Bubbles like these are a response to the demand for liquidity. There’s disagreement on what the government should do about bubbles. In the end, liquidity is ephemeral, because it’s a belief structure, partly detached from fundamentals.

Theoretical models usually rely on quite restrictive assumptions. However, empirical work tends to prove the reality to be different. Perhaps you could identify some of the critical assumptions in contract theory that you fi nd of most concern? How relevant do you think unrealistic assumptions are for the practical applicability of the models? All models are unrealistic. The art of

“An intelligent model is a very interesting conversation partner.”

modeling is about fi guring out what can be left out without losing relevance, not what can be fi t in and still be solvable. This is a lesson each of us has to learn as we progress from being students to skilled modelers. None of the models I discussed in the lectures are realistic by any stretch of the imagination. The right question is whether the models can deliver some important insights—and to do that effectively, the models have to drop everything that isn’t relevant. So how relevant is contract theory, then? Throughout my career I’ve been involved with business practice in some way or another—most of the time as a board member. One of the premises underlying contract theory is that parties strive to maximize the total pie before dividing it up in some type of bargaining process. My experience with negotiations suggests that this logic is foreign to most businessmen. They’re looking at things from their own angle much more than our theoretical constructs suggest. This is one issue that has given me some pause. It is also evident that people are motivated in much richer ways than our theories currently allow. Digging deeper into the multitude of motivations behind human behavior and what this implies for the design of incentives should be a high research priority.

Do you perhaps have some advice for the graduate students here at Tinbergen Institute?The best advice I can give has to do with the way one teaches about theories and models. It is important to provide context for theories. Why did we study this kind of model at that particular time? How does a particular model fi t into the long journey of discovery? For me, it is very diffi cult to make sense of models in isolation. I think this is something that science shares with art and culture. Another bit of advice I can offer is that it’s important to have your heart in your research. Economics is serious business that matters for the world and the welfare of humanity. Finally, I might add that models are conversation partners—and an intelligent model is a very interesting conversation partner. Learn to listen to what the model says and wants. Don’t silence it with assumptions when it doesn’t go where you want it to go. This is similar to the empiricist’s advice not to torture the data. Empirical research and theoretical work are more similar than we think.

Notes

1) This interview refl ects his personal views, and not necessarily those of his employers.

2) Holmström, B. and J. Tirole (2011), Inside and Outside Liquidity, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

3) Holmström, B., T.V. Dang and G. Gorton (2010), Financial crises and the optimality of debt for liquidity provision, mimeo, April.

4) Harris, M. and B. Holmström (1982), A theory of wage dynamics, Review of Economic Studies, 49 (3): 315-333.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 13

14

inDepth

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 15

Owen O’Donnell is professor of applied economics and Eddy van Doorslaer is professor of health economics at Erasmus University. Since 1997 they have worked together on a large number of articles on health economics.

Health differs by socioeconomic status. The socially and economically advantaged enjoy

better health—irrespective of whether it is measured by morbidity, disability or mortality. In the Netherlands, for example, men and women with a university degree can expect to live six to seven years longer than those with a primary education only (see Figure 1). The difference in the expected number of life years in good health is even greater: between sixteen and nineteen years.

Understanding the causes and consequences of such strong socioeconomic disparities in health is the core of the research agenda of the health economics group at the Erasmus School of Economics (ESE). In the past, much of our work has been concerned with the measurement of health inequalities. We have proposed summary indices2 and identifi ed their normative implications.3 Our colleague Tom van Ourti is testing whether there is popular support for these norms and, with Guido Erreygers of Antwerp University, is re-considering the suitability of these measures for application to health data that are typically not ratio-scaled.4 Good measurement of health inequality requires good measurement of health. Toward this end, we have designed and tested methodologies for correcting biases in health data reported in surveys.5,6

From measurement to explanationWith evidence on the existence and persistence of socioeconomic inequalities in health fi rmly established, the focus of the health economics group at ESE is turning towards achieving a better understanding of causality and the mechanisms underlying health disparities. Despite the accumulation of evidence across a range of disciplines that clearly documents this phenomenon, remarkably little is known about its causes. The public health fi eld tends to emphasize causality running from socioeconomic status to health, through material deprivation and psychosocial stress, while economists place greater weight on ill-health interfering with the acquisition of human capital and the generation of income. Our research agenda is based on three premises. First, a life-cycle perspective is crucial to understanding the socioeconomic gradient in health. Second, it is likely that the relationship is bidirectional, and careful design is essential in identifying causality. Third, the mechanisms will only be understood through the construction and testing of theories.

The gradient varies across the life cycleA striking observation is that socioeconomic differences in health tend to widen from early adulthood until late middle age

Lifting the lid on socioeconomic inequalities in health

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Male Female Male FemaleLife expectancy Healthy life expectancy

Higher educationHigher secondary educationLower secondary educationPrimary education

0

10

20

30

Quartile 1

Quartile 3

Quartile 4

20 30 40 50 60 70 80Age

Percent

Quartile 2

Figure 1: Life Expectancy and Healthy Life

Expectancy by education and sex, the

Netherlands 2008. Source: CBS (2008)1

By Owen O’Donnell and Eddy van Doorslaer

16

“It seems unlikely that socioeconomic differences in health are wholly, perhaps even mainly, attributable to the impact of health on income through labor market outcomes.”

before narrowing in old age.7 This is apparent for the Netherlands in Figure 2, where health profi les are distinguished by income quartile. This pattern is remarkably similar to that observed for the US.8,9 Despite their starkly different health and welfare systems, in both countries mean self-reported health declines much more rapidly until middle age for low-income individuals. But this age pattern in health disparities by income disappears, for the most part, after controlling for employment status. Health differences between high- and low-income individuals who are in work are limited and increase only slightly with age, while mean health declines rapidly with age for non-working individuals, irrespective of their income.10 The health-work nexus appears central to understanding both the level and the age profi le of health disparities by income.

In contrast to the US, income-related health inequality is not greater among the younger cohorts of the Dutch and other European population than among the older cohorts.11 The reasons for this continental difference, which have not yet been explored, may help pinpoint the structural characteristics of society, the economy and health systems that are responsible for sustaining health inequalities.

Uncovering causalityIn recent research together with Pilar Garcia Gomez and Hans Van Kippersluis, we estimated the magnitude of causal effects of ill-health on employment and income in the Netherlands using acute, unscheduled hospitalizations as a source of exogenous variation in health.11 On average, an acute hospital admission lowers the employment probability by seven percentage points and results in a 5% loss of personal income (30% for those entering disability insurance) two years after the shock. A more interesting fi nding is that there is no subsequent recovery of either employment or income. Further, there are sizeable negative spillover effects on the earnings of the spouse, with household income falling by 50% more than that of the disabled person. The results also have implications for the magnitudes of both income- and health inequality. Lower income individuals are more likely both to suffer a health shock and subsequently to leave employment as a result. They also experience a larger relative loss of income and so income inequality is raised. In the Netherlands, where disability benefi ts are strongly related to previous earnings, the income loss arising from ill-health is constrained. In the UK, for example, where disability benefi ts are paid at a fl at rate, the fall in income following the onset of disability is far greater. This policy difference presumably helps explain why the Netherlands has one of the weakest correlations between health and income in Europe, while the UK has one of the strongest.12 Nevertheless, it seems unlikely that socioeconomic differences in health are wholly, perhaps even mainly, attributable to the impact of health on income through labor market outcomes. For example, it is more diffi cult to explain health inequalities among children in this way. Correlated

unobservable characteristics, such as time preference, risk attitudes and genetics, make it diffi cult to identify the causal effect of socioeconomic status on health. Together with Hans van Kippersluis, we used the 1928 Dutch schooling reform, which raised compulsory schooling from six to seven years and led to many male pupils (but not females) entering high school, to estimate the impact of education on mortality in old age.14 At the beginning of the period of analysis, the fi rst cohort that was subjected to the 1928 reform was already 81 years old. Conditional on survival to this age, an extra year of schooling is estimated to reduce the probability that a man will die before reaching 89 by almost three percentage points relative to a baseline probability of 50 percent. Of course, not everyone survives to 81. This analysis does not capture any impact of education on mortality at younger ages. It is nonetheless striking that socioeconomic determinants of health maintain their potency even in old age.

Towards an economic theory of health inequalitiesWhile representing a step forward from the measurement of associations, causal effect analysis can only take us so far in understanding health inequalities. The mechanisms generating the effects largely remain hidden inside a ‘black box’. Conceptual understanding of the reasons why health varies along specifi c dimensions of socioeconomic status requires the elaboration and testing of theories of health behavior. In economics, the relevant workhorse remains the health capital model developed by Michael Grossman some forty years ago.15 Titus Galama of RAND and our colleague Hans van Kippersluis recently extended this model with the aim of providing a richer understanding of how education, wages

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Male Female Male FemaleLife expectancy Healthy life expectancy

Higher educationHigher secondary educationLower secondary educationPrimary education

0

10

20

30

Quartile 1

Quartile 3

Quartile 4

20 30 40 50 60 70 80Age

Percent

Quartile 2

Figure 2: Percent reporting fair or

poor health by household income quartiles,

the Netherlands 1983-2000.

Source: CBS Health Interview Surveys,

1983-2000, (Van Kippersluis et al., 2010)

and wealth impact on health behavior through occupational choices and lifestyles.16 The ESE health economics group is currently working with RAND on a US National Institute of Aging project that, among other objectives, aims to test the predictions of this model.

Looking forwardA recent initiative sponsored by Harvard University identifi ed the most pressing research question in the social sciences as follows: ‘How can we induce people to look after their health?’17 This prioritization is persuasive in the context of growing obesity, ageing populations and ever-greater shares of GDP absorbed by health care. But the continued existence of substantial socioeconomic disparities in health alongside increasingly effective medical treatments suggests a more refi ned question. How can we induce individuals of low socioeconomic status to better look after their health? We suspect that answers to this question will require a departure from the utility-maximization-under-certainty model of human capital that Galama and Van Kippersluis have proposed. In any case, it is likely that the search for answers to these and related questions will keep our group busy for some time to come.

Notes

1) Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (2008). Hoogopge leiden leven lang en gezond. In: Gezondheid en zorg in cijfers, ed. Van Hilten, O., and A.M.H.M. Mares. CBS, The Hague.

2) Wagstaff, A., P. Paci and E. van Doorslaer (1991). On the measurement of inequalities in health. Social Science & Medicine 33(5): 545-557.

3) Bleichrodt, H. and E. van Doorslaer (2006). A welfare economics foundation for health inequality measurement. Journal of Health Economics 25(5): 945-57.

4) Erreygers, G. and T. Van Ourti (2011) Measuring socioeconomic inequality in health, health care and health fi nancing by means of rank-dependent indices: A recipe for good practice. Journal of Health Economics 30(4): 685-694.

5) Bago d’Uva, T., M. Lindeboom, O. O’Donnell and E. van Doorslaer (2011). Slipping Anchor? Testing the Vignettes Approach to Identifi cation and Correction of Reporting Heterogeneity. Journal of Human Resources 46(4): 872-903.

6) Lindeboom, M. and E. van Doorslaer (2004). Cut-point shift and index shift in self-reported health. Journal of Health Economics 23(6): 1083-1099.

7) Van Kippersluis, H., T. van Ourti, O. O’Donnell and E. van Doorslaer (2009). Health and income across the life cycle and generations in Europe. Journal of Health Economics 28(4): 813-830

8) Smith, J.P. (2004), Unraveling the SES-health connection, in Aging, Health, and Public Policy: Demographic and Economic Perspectives, a supplement to Population and Development Review 30: pp. 108-132.

9) Case, A. and A. Deaton (2005). Broken down by work and sex: How our health declines”, in: David A. Wise (ed.) (2005), Analyses in the Economics of Aging, Chicago IL: University of Chicago Press, pp. 185-212.

10) Van Kippersluis, H., O. O’Donnell, E. van Doorslaer and T. Van Ourti (2010). Socioeconomic differences in health over the life cycle in an egalitarian country, Social Science & Medicine 70(3), 428-38.

11) See note 7.

12) Garcia Gomez, P., H. Van Kippersluis, O. O’Donnell and E. Van Doorslaer (2011). Effects of health on own and spousal employment and income using acute hospital admissions. TI discussion paper 11-143/2.

13) Van Doorslaer, E. and X. Koolman (2004). Explaining the differences in income-related health inequalities across European countries. Health Economics 13(7): 609-628.

14) Van Kippersluis, H., O. O’Donnell and E. van Doorslaer (2011). Long run returns to education: Does schooling lead to an extended old age? Journal of Human Resources, 46(4), 695-721.

15) Grossman, M. (1972). On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 82, 223-255.

16) Galama T. and H. van Kipper sluis (2010). A theory of socioeconomic disparities in health. RAND working paper WR-773.

17) Giles, J. (2011). Social sciences lines up its biggest challenges. Nature 470: 18-19.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 17

Taco C.R. van Someren,Managing Partner of YnnovateWest Lafayette, Indiana

Taco C.R. van Someren graduated summa cum laude in 1991 with a thesis on non-technical innovations and their consequences for economic theory.

L L L L L L L L L L L LettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersettersAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlumAlum Alum Alum Alum Alum ninininininininininininininininininininininininininininininifromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromfromAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumAlumfromAlumlife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defenselife after the PhD thesis defense

18

When I was young I had four dreams with regard to work: writing a PhD, becoming a professor, being a business consultant and having my own company. During my study of business economics at Erasmus University, before TI existed, I developed the idea to write a PhD thesis, but universities had no budget. No problem; I decided to get a job in the private sector and to experience what it meant to earn money—not a bad decision for a freshly born business economist. For several years I worked in various management positions for a consumer goods multinational. These experiences taught me about the importance of non-technical innovations (such as new organizational forms and international alliance management). These non-technical innovations intrigued me, and I prepared a one-page PhD proposal and applied for an appointment as a PhD student. My ideas appealed to an internationally renowned professor at the University of Amsterdam, H.W. de Jong, who had his own hands-on business experience. We agreed very quickly on my appointment. Colleagues at my company called me crazy to give up excellent career perspectives to study dull papers in an ivory tower—and they were probably right! But I could not resist the hunger for knowledge, and had seemingly unstoppable curiosity to explore new fi elds and to create my own economic theory. I became one of the fi rst PhD students at the newly established Tinbergen Institute. After four years, the bottom line result was a summa cum laude PhD graduation in the fi eld of strategic innovations and new business models. My plan to establish my own research institute to work out the results was blocked, however, due to failing budgets. But my new insights gave me the confi dence to apply for a job as a consultant. One of the Big Four multinationals in accounting and consulting offered me a job. I worked for this company for 12 years and built a career as a director in Germany and a partner in

The Netherlands. During this period, I was more of an entrepreneur than a consultant. In Germany and the Netherlands I have on three occasions set up new businesses in the fi eld of sustainable development and business innovation. Every time, the central ideas developed during my PhD research provided the foundation for these new ventures. In the mid-1990s, when working in Germany, even the Chinese central government discovered my innovative approach to sustainable development applied at companies like BMW. As a result, the Chinese government invited me to give a lecture, and I met a girl who worked in this fi eld as a personal advisor to the Ministers. And …we got married. But I did not like the short-sightedness of many bosses and the strange corporate strategic decisions at the accounting fi rm, which led me to make plans to do something else. In conformity with both Chinese and my own European family’s tradition, we started our own consultant company, Ynnovate. Meanwhile, the European Commission asked me to become a Seconded Innovation Expert for programs aimed at establishing new industries, eco-innovation and international cooperation. For marketing purposes, we write a lot of articles and books —in which we still use the theory developed during my PhD research, and increasingly combine it with business experiences in all kinds of industries and countries. About fi ve years ago, a Chinese university invited me to become a Visiting Professor in Beijing, and two years after that I also accepted a Chair at a private Dutch university (but I gave up the latter position due to the bureaucracy). Are there any dreams left? Sure. We are expanding our business into trading and M&A, and are aiming to share our experiences with the academic world. My experiences until now have taught me that as far as trading is concerned, no study or PhD is necessary—only guts and just getting to work. But all of the other activities in my life have been strongly and positively infl uenced by the great time I had during my PhD research at TI.It was there that my journey of realizing my dreams started.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 19

inShort papersin journalsErrors in judicial decisions: Experimental resultsPopular television series such as CSI illustrate the progress of modern forensic science. Forensic evidence is essentially probabilistic, and in the more complicated criminal cases the judge (or the jury) has the diffi cult task of combining incriminating and exonerating evidence of different strength in a Bayesian way. However, little or no attention is given to instruction in probability theory and statistics in the typical law school curriculum, and many judges have great diffi culty in understanding the basic notions of the normative model of decision making under uncertainty and its building blocks (such as likelihood ratios and types of error (false positive and false negative)). This leads to a certain level of frustration among judges and forensic experts—and opens the door, more importantly, to judicial errors.

The current paper is the fi rst in a series of studies that attempts to establish how and when the interpretation of statistical evidence by judges leads to inadequate judicial decision-making in criminal cases. This provides a sound basis for constructing both effective methods for reporting forensic evidence to judges, and effective support tools for judges. An extensive literature shows that people deviate from rationality when dealing with probability. It seems therefore unavoidable that in diffi cult criminal cases, miscarriages of justice occur—but this is hard to study in the fi eld. The project

therefore uses a laboratory experiment to examine the relationship between evidence of which the diagnostic value is known, subjective probability of guilt and errors in verdicts for abstract criminal cases. There are two situations under examination: (1) all evidence is given and (2) evidence can be acquired. In both situations, verdicts are inaccurate. For given evidence, errors are biased toward the most serious type, unfounded conviction. In the situation where evidence can be acquired, participants do not acquire enough evidence, which results in many mistakes, evenly divided over unfounded convictions and unfounded acquittals.

AuthorsJoep Sonnemans (UvA) and Frans van Dijk (Council for the Judiciary, The Hague): Errors in Judicial Decisions: Experimental Results, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.

Why do convertible issuers simultaneously repurchase stock?Over the last few years, a substantial percentage of US convertible debt issuers have announced a stock repurchase simultaneously with their convertible offering. These combinations are intriguing. Why would a fi rm issue an equity-linked security, on the one hand, and then use part of the proceeds to repurchase equity, on the other? This paper argues that hedge funds provide an explanation for this phenomenon. Convertible arbitrage hedge funds purchase around three-quarters of recent convertible offerings. These hedge funds combine their long position in convertibles with short positions in the

underlying common stock of the issuer—and this short selling could create downward pressure on the stock price of the issuer. Convertible debt issuers routinely repurchase their stock in order to facilitate arbitrage-related short selling. In a fi rst step, the issuer sells the convertible to an arbitrageur via an underwriter. Subsequently, the arbitrageur borrows issuer shares and sells them to the underwriter at a pre-agreed price. The underwriter then sells the shares back to the issuing fi rm, thereby completing the stock repurchase. The arbitrageur benefi ts from this transaction because he does not have to short stock at an uncertain price. The issuer benefi ts from the combination because, in return for acting as counterparty in the short-selling transaction of the arbitrageur, he can charge a higher price for the convertible offering. Moreover, by privately crossing the arbitrageur’s trades, the issuer avoids concentrated open-market short sales and their negative stock price effect. For this reason, investment bankers typically refer to the combination of a convertible issue and a stock repurchase as a “Happy Meal.” The results of this study indicate that fi rms, instead of remaining passive or trying to impede short selling, are able to adjust their corporate fi nance actions to cater to the specifi c needs of arbitrageurs.

AuthorsAbe de Jong (EUR), Marie Dutordoir (University of Manchester), Patrick Verwijmeren (VU): Why do convertible issuers simultaneously repurchase stock? An arbitrage-based explanation, Journal of Financial Economics.

Joep Sonnemans (UvA) and Frans van Dijk (Council for the Judiciary, The Hague): Errors in Judicial Decisions: Experimental Results, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.

Marie Dutordoir (University of Manchester), Patrick Verwijmeren (VU): Why do convertible issuers simultaneously repurchase stock? An arbitrage-based explanation, Journal of

20

discussionpapersManagement practices: Are not ‘for-profi ts’ different?How do management practices affect an organization’s performance? A growing body of evidence suggests that there are good and bad management practices, and that studying differences in their use helps in understanding differences in organizational performance. In the literature thus far, research has focused on for-profi t organizations. Less attention has been paid to management practices in the not-for-profi t sector and to how they compare with those in the for-profi t sector—both in terms of their quality and their importance in terms of driving performance. This is the focus of the present paper.

Using unique survey data of around 160 fi rms in the nursing home and fostering/adoption agency industries in the UK, the paper compares the use of management practices in for-profi t and not-for-profi t organizations, and how this correlates with organizational performance as measured by independent public regulators of these industries.

The results confi rm previous fi ndings for for-profi t fi rms: better management practices (i.e. higher management practice scores) are associated with better outcomes. Interesting differences were also found, however, between ‘for-profi ts’ and ‘not-for-profi ts’. Consistent with the paper’s theoretical predictions, ‘not-for-profi ts’ score lower than ‘for-profi ts’ on the overall

management practices score. Examination of the relationship between managerial practices and the quality of output reveals that these poorer managerial practices do not map directly onto lower quality of output in the not-for-profi t sector, in contrast with the fi ndings for the for-profi t sector. In fact, for some indicators, a negative relationship was found between performance and ‘good’ management practices. Hence, management practices that work for ‘for-profi ts’ may be less effective or even counterproductive in driving performance in ‘not-for-profi ts’.

By Josse Delfgaauw (EUR); Robert Dur (EUR); Carol Propper (University of Bristol and Imperial College, London); Sarah Smith (University of Bristol) TI11-094/1

From fi rst-release to ex-post fi scal data: Exploring the sources of revision errors in the EUAre the real-time fi scal fi gures produced by the Ministry of Finance reliable information about the fi nal fi scal position of a country? Are there institutional arrangements that could improve the degree to which governments stick to their fi scal targets? These questions are of fundamental importance for the credibility of the fi scal consolidation process that European countries are currently undergoing. However, in order to address these issues, we fi rst need to understand the nature of the fi scal budget process.

The fi scal budget process consists of three stages. The fi rst is the planning stage; the

second is the implementation stage, which leads to the real-time “fi rst-release” outcomes published by the Ministry of Finance. Finally, the ex-post control stage produces the fi nal outcomes. These outcomes are published by the national statistics offi ce after having been scrutinized by Eurostat, and measure the budgetary situation of a given year most accurately.

This paper analyzes the credibility of the entire budget process from planning to implementation and ex-post control, and underscores the relevance of improving fi scal institutions and ownership of the EU fi scal rules at the national level for the improvement of real-time fi scal fi gures.

The paper’s fi ndings indicate that, while fi scal plans are on average too optimistic relative to the fi rst-release outcomes, fi rst-release fi gures are overly optimistic relative to the ex-post fi gures. Ministries of Finance control the production of fi rst-release fi gures and may have an incentive to be over-optimistic at this stage.

An improvement in the quality of institutions, whether measured by the tightness of national fi scal rules, the medium-term budgetary framework, or the degree of budgetary transparency, is found to reduce the degree of optimism at the fi rst-release stage, which makes fi rst-release fi gures more informative about the eventual outcomes. For example, an improvement in the fi scal rules index from its minimum to its maximum in-sample value reduces the average degree of optimism in the fi rst-release

inShort

By Josse Delfgaauw (EUR); Robert Dur (EUR); Carol Propper (University of Bristol and Imperial College, London); Sarah Smith (University of Bristol) TI11-094/1

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 21

relative to the ex-post outcome for the balance by more than one percent of GDP. These results thus support last year’s proposal by the European Commission to specify minimum requirements for national budgetary frameworks.

By Roel Beetsma (UvA); Benjamin Bluhm (Goethe University Frankfurt); Massimo Giuliodori (UvA); Peter Wierts (De Nederlandsche Bank) TI11-080/2

On the effects of private information on volatilityPrices and volatility of fi nancial assets are driven by the arrival of new information. Information can be classifi ed as ‘public’ or ‘private’. Public information has to do with news that becomes available to all market participants at the same point in time—for example, in the form of announcements of important macroeconomic variables. Private information refers to news that is distributed asymmetrically amongst market participants, and could be related to advance knowledge of fi rm-related news such as earnings announcements. Previous literature has provided extensive evidence that various asset prices (including stocks, bonds, and currencies) respond to both public and private information. Similarly, the effects of public information on volatility have been well documented. The impact of private information on volatility in fi nancial markets has not been studied before, however. This paper attempts to fi ll this gap. The paper develops a

comprehensive framework based on the Spline GARCH model of Engel and Rangel (2008) to investigate this link, while controlling for the effects of public and private information on prices and the effects of public information on volatility.

Using a high-frequency dataset of transaction prices for the 30-year US Treasury bond futures, the study fi nds that proxies for private information, such as order fl ow (defi ned as the difference between the volume in buyer-initiated transactions and the volume in seller-initiated transactions) and bid-ask spread, are statistically and economically signifi cant explanatory variables for volatility. Specifi cally, a larger degree of information asymmetry increases the uncertainty surrounding Treasury futures prices.Moreover, an interaction between public and private information effects on volatility is documented, with the impact of order fl ow on volatility depending positively on the dispersion of analysts’ expectations about macro-economic announcements. Finally, the study fi nds that the effect of private information on volatility is larger during contractions than during expansions.

ReferencesRobert F. Engle & Jose Gonzalo Rangel, 2008. The Spline-GARCH Model for Low-Frequency Volatility and Its Global Macroeconomic Causes, Review of Financial Studies, Oxford University Press for Society for Financial Studies, 21(3), 1187-1222, May.

By Anne Opschoor, (EUR); Michel van der Wel, (EUR); Dick van Dijk, (EUR); Nick Taylor, (Cardiff University), On the effects of private information on volatility, TI11-077/4

Intention-based reciprocity and the hidden costs of controlThere is a widespread belief in human resource management and the popular business press that more tightly controlling workers can damage the latter’s performance by eroding motivation. This view is consistent with numerous empirical studies from psychology and organizational economics. In contrast to the existing theoretical wisdom, the present paper shows that intention-based reciprocity can explain why exerting more control can cause motivational crowding-out.

The key assumption of the paper is that individuals differ in their propensity for reciprocity while preferences are private information. Some individuals are selfi sh and thus only care for their own payoffs, whereas others are reciprocal in the sense that they want to be kind to those who they perceive to be kind to them.

In this setting, exerting less control is regarded as being kind to selfi sh workers, as it allows them to exert little effort. For reciprocal workers this is more complicated. Suppose that these workers reciprocate not being controlled by exerting high effort. In this case, exerting less control is unkind to reciprocal workers, because reciprocal workers then exert high effort and thus receive

low payoffs. Workers’ preferences are private information, however. Since bosses cannot know whether workers reciprocate not being controlled, not controlling workers can still be kind, on average, if many workers are selfi sh. Reciprocal workers know that bosses do not know whether a particular worker is reciprocal. In consequence, reciprocal workers might perceive not being controlled as kind, and thus reciprocate with high effort.

Intention-based reciprocity as an explanation for motivational crowding-out complements standard theoretical arguments that are entirely based on signalling. In particular, only the present analysis can explain hidden costs of control in situations in which workers are well informed about the job environment. This demonstrates that intention-based reciprocity can be fruitfully applied to recent topics in organizational economics that are diffi cult to understand with standard economic theory.

By Ferdinand von Siemens (UvA) TI11-115/1

GARCH Model for Low-Frequency Volatility and Its Global Macroeconomic Causes, Review of Financial StudiesOxford University Press for Society for Financial Studies, 21(3), 1187-1222, May.

By Roel Beetsma (UvA); Benjamin Bluhm (Goethe University Frankfurt); Massimo Giuliodori (UvA); Peter Wierts (De Nederlandsche Bank) TI11-080/2

economic theory.

By Ferdinand von Siemens (UvA) TI11-115/1

By Anne Opschoor, (EUR); Michel van der Wel, (EUR); Dick van Dijk, (EUR); Nick Taylor, (Cardiff University), On the effects of private information on volatility, TI11-077/4

22

inShort

thesesThe moral herd: Groups and the evolution of altruism and cooperationOur species is born and bred to be helpful, as attested by our very apparent capacity for collective action. But we are also prepared to be selfi sh and even harm others under specifi c circumstances. This thesis examines the origins of the human taste for helping behavior, by looking precisely at these complexities.The fi rst part of the thesis studies the co-evolution of group formation and the tendency to cooperate within those groups. This co-evolutionary process gives rise to cooperative equilibria in large groups, which makes it possible to explain the provision of public goods between unrelated individuals.The thesis then proceeds to explain why cooperation often discriminates against out-groups by studying discriminatory strategies in a prisoner’s dilemma game. The results reveal that helping behavior (inside the group) always comes with hostility towards outsiders. In other words, from an evolutionary perspective, the advantages of helping often come with the disadvantages of discrimination.Finally, the thesis turns to examine the evolution of strategies in repeated games. Reciprocity has often been considered crucial for human cooperation, but it is usually

studied using restricted strategy sets. Studying the full set, the thesis fi nds that every equilibrium can be upset by a succession of mutants. Levels of cooperation that arise from repetition are thus meager. However, this can be repaired with small changes to the population structure: a marginal change in the probability that alike strategies interact goes a long way in promoting reciprocal cooperation. A common ground to all of the models proposed in this thesis is that they consider strategies that are not too simple. All of the specifi c features studied in this thesis have previously been observed in the lab. A satisfactory theory of human cooperation should explain the source of all these features of social preferences. It is likely that no single approach will be able to deliver the whole picture. It would, therefore, be good to devote more attention to explaining how existing evolutionary explanations relate to each other.

Note from the author: I had a real stroke of luck with the timing of my defense. Being the author of ‘thesis 500’ came with the privilege of having a nice round number on my book, a surprise visit to my defense from TI director Bauke Visser, and a huge cake courtesy of the institute. Rumors are that the next cake will go to number 1000.

Thesis: ‘The Moral Herd: Groups and the Evolution of Altruism and Cooperation’, by Julian Garcia Gallego. Published in the Tinbergen Institute Research Series #500

Essays on teams and the social side of consumptionWhen making consumption decisions, people are often motivated at least in part by social concerns. Having the right brand-name clothes or the latest gadget can be about far more than just the product itself; it can also affect people’s views and beliefs about each other. These views also play a role in the workplace, with many fi rms now placing employees together into teams. The challenge in this case is to promote high effort and cooperation when people are rewarded based on team performance rather than individual performance. The fi rst part of this thesis looks at how social concerns can affect consumer behavior; the second part examines social concerns in team production.The fi rst chapter considers a fi rm’s choice of advertising when consumers value social status. Here, advertising informs consumers about the existence of products, but also allows them to recognize products that others buy. The analysis shows that a fi rm may use broad, non-targeted advertising to encourage conspicuous consumption, by allowing wealthy consumers to signal through their purchases. The results may shed light on why fi rms sometimes advertise expensive goods to a broad public, even though most consumers cannot afford to buy them. The second chapter looks at a fi rm’s choice of capacity when consumers care about the popularity of the goods they buy. It explores how a fi rm may try to build a positive buzz around its products by selling out, in a setting where some consumers

are naive in the way that they update their beliefs. It shows that a fi rm may want to strategically limit its capacity to manipulate beliefs about aggregate demand, even when the fraction of naive consumers is small.The third chapter turns to team incentives, and looks at issues of credibility in relational contracting. It considers a setting in which output is observable but non-verifi able—so a principal can promise agents a bonus but then renege on his promise. The results show that team incentives can then make the principal’s promise more credible by smoothing payments over time. Finally, the fourth chapter looks at sustaining cooperation in teams in the shadow of future lay-offs, where some team members are selfi sh, others are conditional cooperators, and where type is private information. The analysis suggests that the best way to sustain cooperation is often in a sorting equilibrium, where cooperative types are able to identify and then work with one another.

Thesis: ‘Essays on Teams and the Social Side of Consumption’, by Nick Vikander. Published in the Tinbergen Institute Research Series #494

tinbergen magazine fall 2011

ReferencesReferences

23

Papers in TI-ranked journals by TI fellowsA-ranked journals

Areosa, W.D., M. McAleer, M.C. Medeiros, 2011, Moment-based estimation of smooth transition regression models with endogenous variables, Journal of Econometrics, 165(1), 100-11.

Bago d’Uva, T., M. Lindeboom, O.A. O’Donnell, 2011, Slipping Anchor?, Journal of Human Resources, 46(4), 875-906.

Camacho, N., A.C.D. Donkers, S. Stremersch, 2011, Predictably non-Bayesian: Quantifying salience effects in physician learning about drug quality, Marketing Science, 30(2), 305-20.

De Haan, M., 2011, The effect of parents’ schooling on child’s schooling: A nonparametric, Journal of Labor Economics, 29(4), 859-92.

De Haan, T., T.J.S. Offerman, R. Sloof, 2011, Noisy signaling: Theory and experiment, Games and Economic Behavior, 73(2), 402-28.

De Jong, A., M. Dutordoir, P. Verwijmeren, 2011, Why do convertible issuers simultaneously repurchase stock? An arbitrage-based explanation, Journal of Financial Economics, 100(1), 113-29.

De Meijer, C., M. Koopmanschap, T. Bago d’Uva, E.K.A. van Doorslaer, 2011, Determinants of long-term care spending: Age, time to death or disability? Journal of Health Economics, 30(2), 425-38.

Den Haan, W.J., V. Sterk, 2011, The myth of fi nancial innovation and the great moderation, The Economic Journal, 121(553), 707-39.

Diecidue, E., J. van de Ven, 2011, Aspiration level, probability of success and failure, and expected utility, International Economic Review, 49(2), 683-700.

Diks, C.G.H., V. Panchenko, D.J.C. van Dijk, 2011, Likelihood-based scoring rules for comparing density forecasts in tails, Journal of Econometrics, 163(2), 215-30.

Erreygers G, T.G.M. van Ourti, 2011, Measuring socioeconomic inequality in health, health care and health fi nancing by means of rank-dependent indices: A recipe for good practice, Journal of Health Economics, 30(4), 685-94.

Facchini, G., A.M. Mayda, 2011, Do interest groups affect US immigration policy?, Journal of International Economics, 85(1), 114-28.

Facchini, G., M.F. Steinhardt, 2011, What drives U.S. immigration policy? Evidence from congressional roll call votes, Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8), 734-43.

Garcia-Gomez, P., 2011, Institutions, health shocks and labour outcomes across Europe’, Journal of Health Economics, 30(1), 200-13.

Houba, H., Q. Wen, 2011, Extreme equilibria in the negotiation model with different time preferences, Games and Economic Behavior, 73(2), 507-16.

Koopman, S.J., A. Lucas, B. Schwaab, 2011, Modeling frailty-correlated defaults using many macroeconomic covariates, Journal of Econometrics, 162(2), 312-25.

Kosfeld, M., F.A. von Siemens, 2011, Competition, cooperation, and corporate culture, The Rand Journal of Economics, 42(1), 23-43.

Kothiyal, A., V. Spinu, P.P. Wakker, 2011, Prospect theory for continuous distributions: A preference foundation, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 42(3), 195-210.

Oosterbeek, H., R. Sloof, J.H. Sonnemans, 2011, Rent-seeking versus productive activities in a multi-task experiment, European Economic Review, 55(5) 630-43.

Pesaran, M.P., A. Pick, 2011, Forecast combination across estimation windows, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 29(2), 307-18.

Pesaran, M.P., A. Pick, A. Timmermann, 2011, Variable selection, estimation and inference for multi-period forecasting problems, Journal of Econometrics, 164(1), 173-87.

Polasky, S., A. de Zeeuw, F.O.O. Wagener, 2011, Optimal management with potential regime shifts, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 62(2), 229-40.

Schram, A.J.H.C., J.H. Sonnemans, 2011, How individuals choose health insurance: An experimental analysis, European Economic Review, 55(6), 799-819.

Sloof, R., J.H. Sonnemans, 2011, The interaction between explicit and relational incentives: An experiment, Games and Economic Behavior, 73(2), 573-94.

24

ReferencesReferences

Van de Kuilen, G., P.P. Wakker, 2011, The midweight method to measure attitudes toward risk and ambiguity, Management Science, 57(3) 582-98.

Van den Berg, V., E.T. Verhoef, 2011, Winning or losing from dynamic bottleneck congestion pricing?: The distributional effects of road pricing with heterogeneity in values of time and schedule delay, Journal of Public Economics, 95(7-8) 983-92.

Van der Ploeg, F., C.A.A.M. Withagen, 2012, Too much coal, too little oil, Journal of Public Economics, 96(1-2), 62-77.

Van Kippersluis, J.L.W., O.A. O’Donnell, E.K.A. van Doorslaer, 2011, Long-run returns to education: Does education lead to an extended old age? Journal of Human Resources, 46(4), 695-721.

Van Ommeren, J.N., D. Wentink, J. Dekkers, 2011, The real price of parking policy, Journal of Urban Economics, 70(1), 25-31.

B-ranked journals

Banal-Estañol, A., J.W. Seldeslachts, 2011, Merger failures, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 20(2), 589-624.

Benchekroun, H., C.A.A.M. Withagen, 2011, The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources: A complete characterization, Resource and Energy Economics, 33(3), 612-36.

Bernoth, K., A. Pick, 2011, Forecasting the fragility of the banking and insurance sectors, Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(4), 807-18.

Bowen, H.P., H. Munandar, J.-M. Viaene, 2011, Are EU countries less integrated than US states? Theory and evidence, Journal of Regional Science, 51(4), 653-77.

Bun, M.J.G., F. Windmeijer, 2011, A comparison of bias approximations for the 2SLS estimator, Economics Letters, 113(1), 76-79.

Chang, C.L., P.H. Franses, M. McAleer, 2011, How accurate are government forecasts of economic fundamentals? The case of Taiwan, International Journal of Forecasting, 27(4), 1066-75.

Chang, C.L., M. McAleer, R. Tansuchat, 2011, Crude oil hedging strategies using dynamic multivariate GARCH, Energy Economics, 33(5), 912-23.

Dari-Mattiacci, G., B. Deffains, B. Loffat, 2011, The dynamics of the legal system, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 79(1-2), 95-107.

De Vor, F., H.L.F. de Groot, 2011, The impact of industrial sites on residential property values: A hedonic pricing analysis from the Netherlands, Regional Studies, 45(5), 609-23.

Dietz, C., D.A. van der Laan, A. Ridder, 2011, Approximate results for a generalized secretary problem, Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 25(2), 157-69.

Franses, P.H., 2011, Averaging model forecasts and expert forecasts: Why does it work?, Interfaces, 41(2), 177-81.

Franses, P.H., 2011, Model selection for forecast combination, Applied Economics, 43(14), 1721-27.

Jungbacker, B., S.J. Koopman, M. van der Wel, 2011, Maximum likelihood estimation for dynamic factor models with missing data, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 35(8), 1358-68.

Karamychev, V.A., P.A. van Reeven, 2011, Park-and-ride: Good for the city, good for the region? Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41(5), 455-64.

Keyzer, M, 2011, Optimal coalition formation and surplus distribution: Two sides of one coin, European Journal of Operational Research, 215(3), 604-15.

Neffke, F.M.H., M. Henning, 2011, How do regions diversify over time? Industry relatedness and the development of new growth paths in regions, Economic Geography, 87(3), 237-65.

Pennings, H.P.G., L. Sereno, 2011, Evaluating pharmaceutical R&D under technical and economic uncertainty, European Journal of Operational Research, 212(2), 374-85.

Pince, C., R. Dekker, 2011, An inventory model for slow moving items subject to obsolescence, European Journal of Operational Research, 213(1), 83-95.

Rouwendal, J., E.T. Verhoef, J. Knockaert. 2012, Give or take? Rewards versus charges for a congested bottleneck, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 42(1-2), 166-76.

Van den Brink, R., I. Katsev, G. van der Laan, 2011, Axiomatizations of two types of Shapley values for games on union closed systems, Economic Theory, 47(1), 175-88.

Van der Klaauw, B., L. Wang, 2011, Child mortality in rural India, Journal of Population Economics, 24(2), 601-28.

Van der Laan, D., 2011, Optimal mixing of Markov decision rules for MDP control, Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 25(3), 307-42.

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 25

Van der Laan, G., D. Talman, Z. Yang, 2011, Solving discrete systems of nonlinear equations, European Journal of Operational Research, 214(3), 493-500.

Van der Ploeg, F., 2011, Rapacious resource depletion, excessive investment and insecure property rights: A puzzle, Environmental and Resource Economics, 48(1), 105-28.

Van Elk, R., M. van der Steeg, D. Webbink, 2011, Does the timing of tracking affect higher education completion?, Economics of Education Review, 30(5), 1009-21.

Van Jaarsveld, W., R. Dekker, 2011, Spare parts stock control for redundant systems using reliability centered maintenance data, Reliability Engineering & System Safety, 96(11), 1576-86.

Van Ommeren, J.N., M. Koopman, 2011, Public housing and the value of apartment quality to households, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41(3), 207-13.

Van Reeven. P., 2011, On the effectiveness of pricing urban car usage, Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 45(3), 367-81.

Von Siemens, F.A., 2011, Heterogeneous social preferences, screening, and employment contracts, Oxford Economic Papers, 63(3), 499-522.

Volosovych, V., 2011, Financial market integration over the long run: Is there a U-shape?, Journal of International Money and Finance, 30(7), 1535-61.

Von Gaudecker, H.M., P. Garcia-Gomez, M. Lindeboom, 2011, Health, disability and work: patterns for the working-age population, International Tax and Public Finance, 18(2), 146-65.

Wall, R.S., M.J. Burger; G.A. van der Knaap, 2011, The geography of global corporate networks: The poor, the rich and the happy few, Environment and Planning A, 43(4), 904-27.

Webbink, D., N.G. Martin, P.M. Visscher, 2011, Does teenage childbearing reduce investment in human capital? Journal of Population Economics, 24(2) 701-30.

(Chapter(s) in)TI-ranked booksAudretsch, D.B., I. Grilo, A.R. Thurik, 2011, Globalization, entrepreneurship, and the region, ch. 2 in: (M. Fritsch (ed.)) Handbook of Research on Entrepreneurship and Regional Development: National and Regional Perspectives, Edward Elgar Publishing, 360 p.

Brons, M., P. Rietveld, 2011, Beyond punctuality: Appropriate measures for unreliability in rail passenger transport, ch. 10 in: (J.A.E.E. van Nunen, P. Huijbregts, P. Rietveld (eds.)) Transitions towards Sustainable Mobility – New Solutions and Approaches for Sustainable Transport Systems, Springer.

Debrezion, G., T. de Graaff, P. Rietveld, 2011, The impact of accessibility on the value of offi ces, ch. 3 in: (J.A.E.E. van Nunen, P. Huijbregts, P. Rietveld (eds.)) Transitions towards Sustainable Mobility – New Solutions and Approaches for Sustainable Transport Systems, Springer.

Den Butter, F.A.G., 2011, The industrial organisation of economic policy preparation in The Netherlands, ch. 10 in: (J. Lentsch, P. Weingart (eds.)) The Politics of Scientific Advice: Institutional Design for Quality Assurance, Cambridge University Press, 416 p.

Capello, R., P. Nijkamp, 2011, Regional growth and development theories revisited, ch. 15 in: (R. Stimson, R.R. Stough, P. Nijkamp (eds.)) Endogenous Regional Development: Perspectives, Measurement and Empirical Investigation, Edward Elgar Publishing, 336 p. De Noronha Vaz, E., T. de Noronha Vaz, P. Nijkamp, 2011, Spatial analyses for policy evaluation of the rural world: Portuguese agriculture in the last decade, ch. 6 in: (A. Torre, J.-B. Traversac (eds.)) Territorial Governance – Local Development, Rural Areas and Agrofood Systems, Springer, 227 p.

Gheasi, M., P. Nijkamp, P. Rietveld, 2011, Migration and tourist fl ows, ch. 8 in: Tourism Economics: Impact Analysis, Springer, 300 p.

Givoni, M., P. Rietveld, Access to rail in urban areas: Examination of the number of stations, 2011, ch. 5 in: (K. Button, A. Reggiani (eds.)) Transportation and Economic Development Challenges, Edward Elgar Publishing, 205 p.

Goos, P.P., B. Jones, 2011, Optimal Design of Experiments: A Case Study Approach, John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, UK, 304 p.

26

ReferencesReferences

Hartog, J., 2011, Ethnic minorities in the Netherlands, ch. 9 in: (M. Kahanec, K.F. Zimmermann (eds.)) Ethnic Diversity in European Labor Markets: Challenges and Solutions, Edward Elgar Publishing, 336 p.

Hulsink, W., S.J.A. Hessels, K. Suddle, 2011, Building entrepreneurial platforms and innovative hotspots: Science and technology based regional development in the Netherlands, ch. 10 in: (S.A. Mian (ed.)) Science and Technology based Regional Entrepreneurship: Global Experience in Policy and Program Development, Edward Elgar Publishing, 544 p.

Knockaert, J., J. Bakens, D. Ettema, E.T. Verhoef, 2011, Rewarding peak avoidance: The Dutch ‘Spitsmijden’ projects, ch.6 in: (J.A.E.E. van Nunen, P. Huijbregts, P. Rietveld (eds.)) Transitions towards Sustainable Mobility – New Solutions and Approaches for Sustainable Transport Systems, Springer.

Kourtit, K., P. Nijkamp, 2011, Creativity and diversity: Strategic performance management of high-tech SMEs in Dutch urban areas, 143-76, in: (P. Nijkamp, K. Kourtit, R.R. Stough (eds.)) Drivers of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Regional Dynamics, Advances in Spatial Science Part 2, Springer, 416 p.

Matias, A., P. Nijkamp, M. Sarmento, 2011, Impact of tourism, in: (A.I. Matias, P. Nijkamp, M. Sarmento (eds.) Tourism Economics: Impact Analysis, Springer, 300 p.

Stough, R.R., S. Desai, P. Nijkamp, 2011, New directions in regional economic development: An introduction, ch. 1 in: (S. Desai, P. Nijkamp, R.R. Stough (eds.)) New Directions in Regional Economic Development: The Role of Entrepreneurship Theory and Methods, Practice and Policy, Edward Elgar Publishing.

Stough, R.R., R.J. Stimson, P. Nijkamp, 2011, An endogenous perspective on regional development and growth - The evolution of regional economic development theory, in: (P. Nijkamp, K. Kourtit, R.R. Stough (eds.)), 3-20, Drivers of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Regional Dynamics, Advances in Spatial Science, Part 1, Springer, 416 p.

Van Praag, C.M., 2011, Who values the status of an entrepreneur?, ch. 4 in: (D. Audretsch, O. Falck, S. Heblich, A. Lederer (eds.)), Handbook of Research on Innovation and Entrepreneurship, Edward Elgar Publishing, 510 p.

Yu, J., P. Nijkamp, J. Yuan, 2011, The spatial dynamics of China’s high-tech industry: An exploratory policy analysis, in: (P. Nijkamp, K. Kourtit, R.R. Stough (eds.)), 223-43, Drivers of Innovation, Entrepreneurship and Regional Dynamics, Advances in Spatial Science, Part 3, Springer, 416 p.

Discussion papersInstitutions and Decision Processes

11-069/1Thomas de Haan, Theo Offerman, Randolph Sloof, UvA, Money talks? An Experimental Investigation of Cheap Talk and Burned Money

11-070/1Sander Onderstal, Arthur J.C. Schram, Adriaan R. Soetevent, UvA, Bidding to Give in the Field: Door-to-Door Fundraisers Had it Right from the Start

11-072/1Jaromir Kovarik, University of the Basque Country, Marco J. van der Leij, UvA, Risk Aversion and Social Networks

11-083/1Jeroen Hinloopen, UvA, On the Exact Finite Sample Distribution of the L1 -FCvM Test Statistic

11-086/1Arantza Estévez-Fernandez, VU, New Characterizations for Largeness of the Core

11-089/1René van den Brink, VU, Anna Khmelnitskaya, Saint-Petersburg State University, Gerard van der Laan, VU, An Owen-Type Value for Games with Two-Level Communication Structures

11-094/1Josse Delfgaauw, Robert Dur, EUR, Carol Propper, University of Bristol and Imperial College, London, Sarah Smith, University of Bristol, Management Practices: Are Not For Profi ts Different?

11-095/1Joseph A. Clougherty, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and CEPR-London, Jo Seldeslachts, UvA, The Deterrence Effects of U.S. Merger Policy Instruments

11-099/1José Luis Moraga-Gonzalez, Groningen University, ICREA, IESE, Vaiva Petrikaite, Groningen University, Consumer Search Costs and the Incentives to Merge under Bertrand Competition

11-115/1Ferdinand von Siemens, UvA, Intention-Based Reciprocity and the Hidden Costs of Control

11-120/1Josse Delfgaauw, Robert Dur, EUR, CESifo, IZA, Arjan Non, Willem Verbeke, EUR, ERIM, The Effects of Prize Spread and Noise in Elimination Tournaments: A Natural Field Experiment

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 27

Financial and International Markets

11-064/2/DSF20Andreas Schabert, TU Dortmund University, UvA, Sweder J.G. van Wijnbergen, UvA, Sovereign Default and the Stability of Infl ation Targeting Regimes

11-068/2Sweder J.G. van Wijnbergen, UvA, Nina Budina, IMF, Fiscal Sustainability, Volatility and Oil Wealth: A Stochastic Analysis of Fiscal Spending Rules

11-073/2Julia Swart, EUR, Charles van Marrewijk, Utrecht University and Tjalling C. Koopmans Institute, The Pollution Effects of Mergers and Acquisitions: Asymmetry, Disaggregation, and Multilateralism

11-076/2/DSF21Albert J. Menkveld, VU, High Frequency Trading and the New-Market Makers

11-078/2/DSF22Xin Zhang, Drew Creal, Siem Jan Koopman, Andre Lucas, VU, Modeling Dynamic Volatilities and Correlations under Skewness and Fat Tails

11-080/2Roel Beetsma, UvA, Benjamin Bluhm, Goethe University Frankfurt, Massimo Giuliodori, UvA, Peter Wierts, De Nederlandsche Bank, From First-Release to Ex-Post Fiscal Data: Exploring the Sources of Revision Errors in the EU

11-084/2/DSF23Antonio Di Cesare, Bank of Italy, Philip A. Stork, VU, Casper G. de Vries, EUR, Risk Measures for Autocorrelated Hedge Fund Returns

11-091/2/DSF24Murillo Campello, University of Illinois, and NBER, Erasmo Giambona, UvA, and Duisenberg school of fi nance, Capital Structure and the Redeployability of Tangible Assets

11-101/2/DSF25Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley, and NBER, Enrico Moretti, UC Berkeley, and NBER, Florian Peters, Duisenberg school of fi nance, and UvA, Winning by Losing: Evidence on Overbidding in Mergers

11-124/2Sander Muns, EUR, and CPB, A Note on the Shapley Value for Characteristic Functions on Bipartitions

11-126/2Laura Alfaro, Harvard Business School, and NBER, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, Koc University, University of Houston, CEPR, and NBER,

Vadym Volosovych, EUR, and ERIM, Sovereigns, Upstream Capital Flows and Global Imbalances

11-143/2Pilar Garcia-Gomez, Hans van Kippersluis, Owen O'Donnell, Eddy van Doorslaer, EUR, Effects of Health on Own and Spousal Employment and Income Using Acute Hospital Admissions

11-144/2Lorenzo Pozzi, EUR, The Time-Varying Volatility of Earnings and Aggregate Precautionary Savings

11-145/2Alessandro Gobbi, Politecnico di Milano, Tim Willems, UvA, Identifying US Monetary Policy Shocks through Sign Restrictions in Dollarized Countries

Labor, Region and Environment

11-065/3Chris van Klaveren, TIER, Maastricht University, Henriette Maassen van den Brink, TIER, Maastricht University, and UvA, Bernard van Praag, UvA, Intra-Household Work Timing: The Effect on Joint Activities and the Demand for Child Care

11-066/3Jose Maria Millan, Emilio Congregado, Concepcion Roman, University of Huelva, Spain, Mirjam van Praag, ACE, UvA, Andre van Stel, EIM Business and Policy Research, Zoetermeer, The Value of an Educated Population for an Individual’s Entrepreneurship Success

11-067/3Mirjam van Praag, UvA, André van Stel, EIM Business and Policy Research, Zoetermeer, The More Business Owners the Merrier? The Role of Tertiary Education

11-071/3Stefan P.T. Groot, Jan L. Mohlmann, VU, Harry Garretsen, Groningen University, Henri L.F. de Groot, VU, The Crisis Sensitivity of European Countries and Regions: Stylized Facts and Spatial Heterogeneity

11-074/3Sander Hoogendoorn, Hessel Oosterbeek, Mirjam van Praag, UvA, The Impact of Gender Diversity on the Performance of Business Teams: Evidence from a Field Experiment

11-075/3Joop Hartog, UvA, Xiaohao Ding, Juan Liao, Peking University, Is Earnings Uncertainty Relevant for Educational Choice? An Empirical Analysis for China

28

ReferencesReferences

11-079/3Vincent A.C. van den Berg, Erik T. Verhoef, VU, Is the Service Quality of Private Roads Too Low, Too High, or Just Right when Firms Compete Stackelberg in Capacity?

11-081/3Masagus M. Ridhwan, VU, and Bank Indonesia, Henri L.F. de Groot, Piet Rietveld, Peter Nijkamp, VU, The Regional Impact of Monetary Policy in Indonesia

11-085/3Hans Koster, Jos N. van Ommeren, Piet Rietveld, VU, Geographic Concentration of Business Services Firms: A Poisson Sorting Model

11-087/3Pieter A. Gautier, VU, CEPR, IZA, Aico van Vuuren, VU, A Flexible Test for Present Bias and Time Preferences Using Land-Lease Contracts

11-092/3Pieter A. Gautier, VU, CEPR, IZA, Christian L. Holzner, University of Munich, Ifo Institute for Economic Research, CESifo, Simultaneous Search and Network Effi ciency

11-096/3Sergejs Gubins, Erik T. Verhoef, VU, Teleworking and Congestion:A Dynamic Bottleneck Analysis

11-100/3Jos N. van Ommeren, Eva Gutierrez-i-Puigarnau, VU, Distortionary Company Car Taxation: Deadweight Losses through Increased Car Ownership

11-102/3Jose Rosero, Hessel Oosterbeek, UvA, Trade-offs between Different Early Childhood Interventions: Evidence from Ecuador

11-103/3Simonetta Longhi, Institute for Social and Economic Research, University of Essex, Colchester, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Jacques Poot, Population Studies Centre, University of Waikato, Hamilton, The Economic Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market of Host Countries - Meta-Analytic Evidence

11-104/3Aura Reggiani, University of Bologna, Pietro Bucci, Signifi cance, The Hague, Giovanni Russo, VU, Anette Haas, Institute for Employment Research, Nuernberg, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Regional Labour Markets and Job Accessibility in City Network Systems in Germany

11-105/3Peter Nijkamp, VU, Behaviour of Humans and Behaviour of Models in Dynamic Space

11-106/3Purifi cacion Vicente Galindo, University of Salamanca, and CIEO, University of the Algarve, Faro, Teresa de Noronha Vaz, CIEO, University of the Algarve, Faro, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Eric de Noronha Vaz, Institute of Statistics and Information Management, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, and CIEO, University of the Algarve, Faro, Analysis of Regional Innovation Performance in Portugal - Results from an External Logistic Biplot Method

11-107/3Purifi cacion Vicente Galindo, University of Salamanca, and Centro de Investigacao sobre o Espaco e as Organizacoes, Teresa de Noronha Vaz, Centro de Investigacao sobre o Espaco e as Organizacoes, and University of the Algarve, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Institutional Capacity to Dynamically Innovate: An Application to the Portuguese Case

11-108/3Jaume Puig-Junoy, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, and Research Centre for Economics and Health (CRES), Barcelona, Pilar Garcia-Gomez, EUR, David Casado-Marin, Institut d’Avaluacio de Polítiques Publiques (IVALUA), Barcelona, Free Medicines Thanks to Retirement: Moral Hazard and Hospitalization Offsets in an NHS

11-109/3Eveline van Leeuwen, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Importance of E-services for Cultural Tourism

11-110/3Soushi Suzuki, Sapporo University, Peter Nijkamp, Piet Rietveld, VU, Regional Effi ciency Improvement by Means of Data Envelopment Analysis through Euclidean Distance Minimization including Fixed Input Factors - An Application to Tourist Regions in Italy

11-111/3Aura Reggiani, University of Bologna, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Alessandro Cento, KLM Royal Dutch Airlines, Milan, Connectivity and Competition in Airline Networks: A Complexity Analysis of Lufthansa’s Network

11-112/3Ceren Ozgen, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Jacques Poot, National Institute of Demographic and Economic Analysis (NIDEA), University of Waikato, Hamilton, Immigration and Innovation in European Regions

11-113/3Soushi Suzuki, Hokkai-Gakuen University, Sapporo, Peter Nijkamp, VU, A Stepwise Projection Data Envelopment Analysis for Public Transport Operations in Japan

11-114/3Giovanni Russo, VU, Federico Tedeschi, Aura Reggiani, University of Bologna, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Commuter Effects on Local Labour Markets: A German Modelling Study

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 29

11-116/3Andrea Caragliu, Politecnico di Milano, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Cognitive Capital and Islands of Innovation: The Lucas Growth Model from a Regional Perspective

11-117/3Johan H.L. Oud, Radboud University Nijmegen, Henk Folmer, Groningen University, Roberto Patuelli, University of Lugano, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Continuous-Time Modelling with Spatial Dependence

11-118/3Marco Alderighi, Universita della Valle d’Aosta, Universita Bocconi, Alessandro Cento, KLM Royal Dutch Airlines, Milan, Peter Nijkamp, Piet Rietveld, VU, Second-degree Price Discrimination and Inter-group Effects in Airline Routes between European Cities

11-119/3Marina van Geenhuizen, TU Delft, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Knowledge Virtualization and Local Connectedness among Smart High-tech Companies

11-121/3Jan-Maarten van Sonsbeek, Raymond Gradus, VU, Estimating the Effects of Recent Disability Reforms in The Netherlands

11-129/3Thomas de Graaff, VU, Frank G. van Oort, Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, The Hague, and Utrecht University, Raymond J.G.M. Florax, VU, Purdue University, Regional Population-Employment Dynamics across Different Sectors of the Economy

11-133/3Alexandros Dimitropoulos, Piet Rietveld, Jos N. van Ommeren, VU, Consumer Valuation of Driving Range: A Meta-Analysis

11-134/3Olaf Jonkeren, European Commission, JRC, Jos N. van Ommeren, Piet Rietveld, VU, Directional Imbalance in Transport Prices: An Application to Inland Shipping in North-West Europe

11-136/3Masood Gheasi, Peter Nijkamp, Piet Rietveld, VU, Migration and Foreign Direct Investment: Education Matters

11-140/3Bart Neuts, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Crowding Perception in a Tourist City: A Question of Preference

11-142/3Eric de Noronha Vaz, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, Peter Nijkamp, VU, Marco Painho, Mario Gaetano, Universidade NOVA de Lisboa, A Multi-Scenario Forecast of Urban Change: A Study on Urban Growth in the Algarve

11-147/3Masood Gheasi, Peter Nijkamp, Piet Rietveld, VU, Migrants and International Economic Linkages: A Meta-Overview

11-155/3Ellen van de Poel, Health Policy & Management, Eddy van Doorslaer, Owen O’Donnell, EUR, Measurement of Inequity in Health Care with Heterogeneous Response of Use to Need

11-156/3Elbert Dijkgraaf, Rotterdam School of Economics, EUR, Raymond Gradus, VU, Effi ciency Effects of Privatising Refuse Collection: Be Careful and Alternatives Present

11-157/3Regis Barnichon, CREi, Michael Elsby, University of Edinburgh, Bart Hobijn, FRB San Francisco, and VU, Aysegul Sahin, FRB New York, Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve?

11-158/3Mary C. Daly, FRB San Francisco, Bart Hobijn, FRB San Francisco, and VU, Theodore S. Wiles, The Analysis Group, Aggregate Real Wages: Macro Fluctuations and Micro Drivers

11-159/3Michael W.L. Elsby, University of Edinburgh, and NBER, Bart Hobijn, FRB San Francisco, and VU, Aysegul Sahin, FRB New York, Unemployment Dynamics in the OECD

11-160/3Mary Daly, FRB San Francisco, Bart Hobijn, FRB San Francisco, and VU, Aysegul Sahin, FRB New York, Robert Valletta, FRB, A Rising Natural Rate of Unemployment: Transitory or Permanent?

11-161/3Frank A.G. den Butter, VU, Harro B.J.B. Maas, Utrecht University, From Expert Judgment to Model based Monetary Analysis: The Case of the Dutch Central Bank in the Postwar Period

Econometrics

11-077/4Anne Opschoor, Michel van der Wel, Dick van Dijk, EUR, Nick Taylor, Cardiff University, On the Effects of Private Information on Volatility

11-082/4Monica Billio, Roberto Casarin, University of Venice, GRETA Assoc. and School for Advanced Studies in Venice, Francesco Ravazzolo, Norges Bank, Herman K. van Dijk, EUR, Bayesian Combinations of Stock Price Predictions with an Application to the Amsterdam Exchange Index

30

ReferencesReferencesReferences

11-088/4Maurice J.G. Bun, UvA, Frank Windmeijer, University of Bristol, A Comparison of Bias Approximations for the 2SLS Estimator

11-090/4Geert Mesters, Netherlands Institute for the Study of Crime and Law Enforcement, Siem Jan Koopman, Marius Ooms, VU, Monte Carlo Maximum Likelihood Estimation for Generalized Long-Memory Time Series Models

11-093/4Sjoerd van den Hauwe, Dick van Dijk, Richard Paap, EUR, Bayesian Forecasting of Federal Funds Target Rate Decisions

11-097/4Jan.S. Cramer, UvA, Childhood Intelligence and Adult Mortality in the Brabant Data Set: First Report

11-098/4Jan.S. Cramer, UvA, Childhood Intelligence and Adult Mortality in the Brabant Data Set: Technical Report

11-122/4Christophe Croux, K.U. Leuven, Belgium, Peter Exterkate, EUR, Sparse and Robust Factor Modelling

11-123/4Monica Billio, University of Venice, Gretta Assoc. and School for Advanced Studies in Venice, Roberto Casarin, University of Venice, Gretta Assoc. and School for Advanced Studies In Venice, Ravazzolo, Norges Bank, Herman K. van Dijk, EUR, VU, Combination Schemes for Turning Point Predictions

11-125/4Oleg Sokolinskiy, Dick van Dijk, EUR, Forecasting Volatility with Copula-Based Time Series Models

11-130/4Ao Yuan, Howard University, Washington DC, Jan G. de Gooijer, UvA, Asymptotically Informative Prior for Bayesian Analysis

11-131/4Lennart F. Hoogerheide, VU, Francesco Ravazzolo, Norges Bank, Herman K. van Dijk, EUR, VU, Backtesting Value-at-Risk Using Forecasts for Multiple Horizons, a Comment on the Forecast Rationality Tests of A.J. Patton and A. Timmermann

11-132/4Siem Jan Koopman, Marcel Scharth, VU, The Analysis of Stochastic Volatility in the Presence of Daily Realised Measures

11-135/4Rianne Legerstee, Philip Hans Franses, EUR, Do Experts’ SKU Forecasts Improve after Feedback?

11-137/4Arnold Zellner (posthumous), Booth School of Business, University of Chicago, Tomohiro Ando, Graduate School of Business Administration, Keio University, Nalan Basturk, Econometric Institute, EUR, The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis, Rimini, Lennart Hoogerheide, VU, Herman K. van Dijk, Econometric Institute, EUR, and VU, Instrumental Variables, Errors in Variables, and Simultaneous Equations Models: Applicability and Limitations of Direct Monte Carlo

11-138/4Peter Exterkate, EUR, Modelling Issues in Kernel Ridge Regression

11-141/4Rianne Legerstee, Philip Hans Franses, Richard Paap, EUR, Do Experts Incorporate Statistical Model Forecasts and Should They?

11-149/4Heleen Mees, Tilburg University, Philip Hans Franses, EUR, Are Chinese Individuals Prone to Money Illusion?

11-154/4Sanne Lise Blauw, Philip Hans Franses, EUR, The Impact of Mobile Telephone Use on Economic Development of Households in Uganda

Theses496 VINCENT VAN DEN BERG (08-06-2011) Congestion Pricing with Heterogeneous Travellers

497 ERIK DE WIT (08-09-2011) Liquidity and Price Discovery in Real Estate Assets

498 CARMEN LEE (10-06-2011) Psychological Aspects of the Disposition Effect: An Experimental Investigation

499 MASAGUS RIDHWAN (08-06-2011) Regional Dimensions of Monetary Policy in Indonesia

500 JULIAN GARCIA GALLEGO (29-06-2011) The Moral Herd: Groups and the Evolution of Altruism and Cooperation

501 FELIX LAMP (10-06-2011) Essays in Corporate Finance and Accounting

502 JOERI SOL (01-07-2011) Incentives and Social Relations in the Workplace

Tinbergen Research Institute Four themes distinguish Tinbergen Institute’s research program: I. Institutions and Decision AnalysisII. Financial and International MarketsIII. Labour, Region and the EnvironmentIV. Econometrics and Operations Research

Each theme covers the whole spectrum of economic analysis, from theoretical to empirical research. Stimulating discussions on theories, methodologies and empirical results arise from the interaction of the Institute¹s faculty, which is comprised of approximately 130 research fellows. These fellows are faculty members with excellent track records in economic research, active in organising research activities, teaching graduate courses and supervising PhD students.

Discussion PapersResearch is pre-published in the institute’s own Discussion Paper Series.Download discussion papers at www.tinbergen.nl/ti-publications/discussion-papers.php. E-mail address for correspondence: [email protected].

Tinbergen Graduate SchoolTinbergen Institute offers three research master tracks (MPhil): one in Economics, one in Econometrics and one in Finance. Due to the demanding nature of the programs, the MPhil programs are open only to a rigorously selected group of students. An excellent preparation for PhD thesis research, the MPhil programs are connected to three-year PhD positions in the economics departments of Erasmus University Rotterdam, University of Amsterdam, and VU University Amsterdam.

The research master program has been accredited by the Dutch and Flemish Accreditation Organization for higher education (NVAO), and eligible students can claim two years of fi nancial aid (“studiefi nanciering”). In addition, Tinbergen Institute allocates scholarships each year based on academic merit.

Detailed information on the institute’s graduate program and the application procedure can be found in the Graduate School section of www.tinbergen.nl.Please send any questions to [email protected].

BoardC.N. Teulings (Chair), H.P. Boswijk, E.T. Verhoef, C.G. de Vries

General DirectorB. Visser

Directors of Graduate StudiesA.R. Soetevent, A.C.F. Vorst

Research Program Co-ordinatorsInstitutions and Decision Analysis:J.H. Sonnemans, O.H. SwankFinancial Economics andInternational Markets:A.J. Menkveld, J.-M. ViaeneLabour, Region and the Environment:E.J.S. Plug, C.A.A.M. WithagenEconometrics:A. Wagelmans, S.J. Koopman

Alumni Board Tinbergen InstituteI. Ossokina (Chair), Y. Chung Cheung, E. Mendys, M. van der Wel

Editorial Board Tinbergen InstituteK. Scholtus-Navickaite, B. Visser, R. van Veldhuizen, F. Brauning, P. Robalo

How to subscribe?Address for correspondence/ subscriptions:

Tinbergen Institute RotterdamBurg. Oudlaan 503062 PA Rotterdamthe Netherlands

E-mail: [email protected] changes may be sent to the above e-mail address.

About us

tinbergen magazine fall 2011 31

503 IRMA HINDRAYANTO (07-09-2011) Periodic Seasonal Time Series Models with Applications to U.S. Macroeconomic Data

504 KOBUS DE HOOP (22-09-2011) Keeping Kids in School: Cash Transfers and Selective Education in Malawi

505 OLEG SOKOLINSKIY (23-09-2011) Essays on Financial Risk: Forecasts and Investor Perceptions

506 TATIANA KISELEVA (05-10-2011) Structural Analysis of Complex Ecological Economic Optimal Management Problems

507 UMUT KILINC (08-09-2011) Essays on Firm Dynamics, Competition and Productivity

508 MARCEL DE HEIDE (04-11-2011) R&D, Innovation and the Policy Mix

509 FRISO (F.) DE VOR (12-10-2011) The Impact and Performance of Industrial Sites: Evidence from the Netherlands

510 ARJAN NON (06-10-2011) Do ut Des: Incentives, Reciprocity, and Organizational Performance

511 SANDER KONIJN (02-11-2011) Empirical Studies on Credit Risk

512 HENDRIK VRIJBURG (29-09-2011) Enhanced Cooperation in Corporate Taxation

514 PAUL STEFFENS (10-11-2011) It's Communication, Stupid! Essays on Communication, Reputation and (Committee) Decision-Making

www.tinbergen.nl