13
Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 The performance of different models of primary care provision in Southern Africa Anne Mills a, *, Natasha Palmer a , Lucy Gilson b , Di McIntyre c , Helen Schneider b , Edina Sinanovic c , Haroon Wadee b a Health Economics and Financing Programme, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine (LSHTM), Keppel Street, WC1E 7HT London, UK b Centre for Health Policy, School of Public Health, University of Witwatersrand, P.O. Box 1038, Johannesburg 2000, South Africa c Health Economics Unit, School of Public Health, University of Cape Town, Anzio Road, Observatory, Cape Town 7925, South Africa Abstract Despite the emphasis placed during the last two decades on public delivery of comprehensive and equitable primary care (PC) to developing country populations, coverage remains far from universal and the quality often poor. Users frequently patronise private providers, ranging from informal drug sellers to trained professionals. Interest is increasing internationally in the potential for making better use of private providers, including contractual approaches. The research aim was to examine the performance of different models of PC provision, in order to identify their strengths and weaknesses from the perspective of a government wishing to develop an overall strategy for improving PC provision. Models evaluated were: (a) South African general practitioners (district surgeons) providing services under public contracts; (b) clinics provided in Lesotho under a sub-contract between a construction company and a South African health care company; (c) GP services provided through an Independent Practitioner Association to low income insured workers and families; (d) a private clinic chain serving low income insured and uninsured workers and their families; and (e) for comparative purposes, South African public clinics. Performance was analysed in terms of provider cost and quality (of infrastructure, treatment practices, acceptability to patients and communities), allowing for differences in services and case-mix. The diversity of the arrangements made direct comparisons difficult, however, clear differences were identified between the models and conclusions drawn on their relative performance and the influences upon performance. The study findings demonstrate that contextual features strongly influence provider performance, and that a crude public/private comparison is not helpful. Key issues in contract design likely to influence performance are highlighted. Finally, the study argues that there is a need before contracting out service provision to consider how the performance of private providers might change when the context within which they are working changes with the introduction of a contract. r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: Primary care; Contracting out; Public sector; Private sector; Southern Africa; Health systems research Introduction Ensuring that service organisation matches health needs and resource availability is the key challenge in designing equitable primary care (PC) systems (Starfield, 1998). In low and middle income country (LMIC) populations, PC coverage remains incomplete and technical and user-perceived quality often poor. Where users have a choice, they frequently patronise private providers ranging from informal drug sellers to trained professionals (Bennett, McPake, & Mills, 1997). Recent reviews argue that greater attention needs to be paid to ARTICLE IN PRESS *Corresponding author. Tel.: +44-20-7927-2354; fax: +44- 20-7637-5391. E-mail address: [email protected] (A. Mills). 0277-9536/$ - see front matter r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.socscimed.2003.12.015

The performance of different models of primary care provision in Southern Africa

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943

ARTICLE IN PRESS

*Correspond

20-7637-5391.

E-mail addr

0277-9536/$ - se

doi:10.1016/j.so

The performance of different models of primary care provisionin Southern Africa

Anne Millsa,*, Natasha Palmera, Lucy Gilsonb, Di McIntyrec, Helen Schneiderb,Edina Sinanovicc, Haroon Wadeeb

aHealth Economics and Financing Programme, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine (LSHTM), Keppel Street,

WC1E 7HT London, UKbCentre for Health Policy, School of Public Health, University of Witwatersrand, P.O. Box 1038, Johannesburg 2000, South Africa

cHealth Economics Unit, School of Public Health, University of Cape Town, Anzio Road, Observatory, Cape Town 7925, South Africa

Abstract

Despite the emphasis placed during the last two decades on public delivery of comprehensive and equitable primary

care (PC) to developing country populations, coverage remains far from universal and the quality often poor. Users

frequently patronise private providers, ranging from informal drug sellers to trained professionals. Interest is increasing

internationally in the potential for making better use of private providers, including contractual approaches. The

research aim was to examine the performance of different models of PC provision, in order to identify their strengths

and weaknesses from the perspective of a government wishing to develop an overall strategy for improving PC

provision. Models evaluated were: (a) South African general practitioners (district surgeons) providing services under

public contracts; (b) clinics provided in Lesotho under a sub-contract between a construction company and a South

African health care company; (c) GP services provided through an Independent Practitioner Association to low income

insured workers and families; (d) a private clinic chain serving low income insured and uninsured workers and their

families; and (e) for comparative purposes, South African public clinics. Performance was analysed in terms of provider

cost and quality (of infrastructure, treatment practices, acceptability to patients and communities), allowing for

differences in services and case-mix. The diversity of the arrangements made direct comparisons difficult, however, clear

differences were identified between the models and conclusions drawn on their relative performance and the influences

upon performance. The study findings demonstrate that contextual features strongly influence provider performance,

and that a crude public/private comparison is not helpful. Key issues in contract design likely to influence performance

are highlighted. Finally, the study argues that there is a need before contracting out service provision to consider how

the performance of private providers might change when the context within which they are working changes with the

introduction of a contract.

r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Primary care; Contracting out; Public sector; Private sector; Southern Africa; Health systems research

Introduction

Ensuring that service organisation matches health

needs and resource availability is the key challenge in

ing author. Tel.: +44-20-7927-2354; fax: +44-

ess: [email protected] (A. Mills).

e front matter r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserve

cscimed.2003.12.015

designing equitable primary care (PC) systems (Starfield,

1998). In low and middle income country (LMIC)

populations, PC coverage remains incomplete and

technical and user-perceived quality often poor. Where

users have a choice, they frequently patronise private

providers ranging from informal drug sellers to trained

professionals (Bennett, McPake, & Mills, 1997). Recent

reviews argue that greater attention needs to be paid to

d.

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943932

improving private services and establishing or improv-

ing relationships between the public sector and private

providers, in particular through contracting out

service provision (eg Giustu, Criel, & De Bethune,

1997; Mills, Brugha, Hanson, & McPake, 2002),

reflecting the debate over the appropriate structure

and management of the public sector as a whole

(Jackson & Price 1994; World Bank, 2003). The

extent to which government hierarchies, business

models or the non-profit sector provide appropriate

models is unclear (Mintzberg, 1996; Salamon, 1993).

Williamson (1975) argued that the appropriate

design of service production should be influenced

by the identity, ownership and motivation of the

actors as well as the nature of the transaction being

governed. Within this overall literature, a key ques-

tion for the health sector has been appropriate

payment mechanisms for doctors (Gosden et al.,

2001).

Very limited information is available for LMICs

regarding the performance of alternative approaches to

PC provision. Bennett (1997) identified only three

studies of efficiency and quality, all comparing

public and not-for-profit providers. With respect to

contracts, there is some country-specific evidence

for hospital and non-clinical services (Mills, 1998),

district health services (Souters & Griffiths, 2003),

and preventive services (Abramson, 1999), but vir-

tually no evidence specifically on contracting out

PC.

In South Africa, contracts between the state and

private firms have been used for many years to provide

long-stay hospital care, and, on a limited scale, for

district hospital care. In 1995, a Committee of Inquiry

(South Africa (Republic), 1995) recommended contract-

ing with accredited private GP practices to provide

comprehensive PC for a defined population, but this has

yet to be implemented.

The aim of the study reported here was to explore

whether the government should continue with the public

hierarchical model of PC provision, or should also

consider contracting-out service provision and if so, to

what type of provider. Performance of a cross-section of

public clinics was compared with a range of privately

owned PC services (some operating under contract,

others being potential contractors) in order to identify

the models’ strengths and weaknesses. The study also

considered influences upon the performance of the

different models (including contract design) and

differences between models which should be taken

into account when writing contracts. While the study

focus was South Africa, the questions asked, and

analytical findings, are of relevance to other coun-

tries which have public provision of poor perceived

quality, and rapidly growing and widely used private

services.

Conceptual framework and methods

A series of case studies were conducted of the different

models, using quantitative and qualitative methods of

data collection within an overall qualitative case study

design. Comparisons are not made statistically but paint

a picture of key features of service delivery, enabling

useful consideration of similarities and differences.

Performance was defined as technical quality (in terms

largely of structure and process aspects), acceptability to

users and cost of service delivery. Fig. 1 outlines the

framework developed to assist in understanding the

influence of the context in which a provider was

operating, as well as differences in the nature of

providers. As the figure shows, performance is affected

by a combination of influences upon both the demand

for services and the supply of services.

Factors influencing demand are the socio-economic

and demographic characteristics of the population, and

their preferences for different provider characteristics.

Whether clients are insured, have to pay fees or can

access state-financed services, and the degree of choice of

alternative providers, are also likely to be important

influences on demand. Supply side factors encompass

the size and location of providers, and capacity issues

such as provider resources and expertise, and the

financial and non-financial incentive structure which

determines how resources are used.

A distinction is drawn in Fig. 1 between incentives

within hierarchical organisations (salaried employees in

the public or private sector) and within private ‘owner

managed’ providers (GPs in solo or group practice).

Private ‘owner managed’ providers benefit directly from

the incentives created by each payment method, as well

as being subject to non-financial incentives which may

be personal or professional (Palmer & Mills, 2003).

Within hierarchical organisations, the incentives faced

by employees are different, and potentially more

influenced by salary level and management style and

competency than the manner in which the provider

organisation is remunerated. Demand and supply

factors affect the performance of providers both

directly, and via their influence on the nature and size

of their workload.

Models of PC available for study, and especially of

contracted out PC, were quite limited. Two public/

private contracts were studied, together with two models

of PC delivery existing within the private sector which

were judged to offer potential for contracts with

government in the future. Public provision of PC was

also studied, as the current dominant policy choice.

Community-based NGO approaches were excluded

since they served very specific populations with a limited

range of services. Table 1 summarises the five models

chosen and the purposive selection of the sample within

each model. The models demonstrate a range of

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Fig. 1. Demand and supply factors affecting the performance of PC providers.

A. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 933

providers (private GPs, commercial companies, public

providers); offering various mixes of PC services (doctor

or nurse-led; large and small clinics); over a cross-section

of settings (rural and urban in different parts of South

Africa); and to a range of clients (uninsured and low

income insured).

Using a range of data collection tools, a picture was

built up of the nature of service delivery in each model.

Methods were standardised across the research sites,

including costing methods. Table 2 summarises data

collection tools, data sources, and the aspects of

performance addressed (for more detail see Palmer,

Sinanovic & McIntyre, 1998). Capital items were valued

at replacement cost and annualised using an 8%

discount rate and appropriate life-spans. The different

service mixes of the models was allowed for by

estimating service-specific costs: drug costs were allo-

cated to each service (e.g. sexually transmitted infections

(STIs), chronic care), and staff time was apportioned in

relation to the relative lengths of different types of

consultation. Sensitivity analysis was performed to allow

for different valuations of the time of self-employed

GPs. The very variable quality of patient records posed

the greatest problem with respect to data quality, and

was addressed by using multiple sources of quality data.

Analyses were done for each model and compared

across models on a number of dimensions. Where there

were two sites for a model, results are presented for

individual sites. Where the number of sites was greater

than two, results report an average across sites.

Description of models

Table 3 summarises key features of each model and its

patient population. The public model, which encom-

passed large urban polyclinics and small rural clinics,

was grouped into large and small clinics.

Providers under contract to the public sector

Individual GP contract

The part-time district surgeon arrangement has been

in existence for many years in rural towns, and

originated in the need to provide forensic medicine,

medical cover for the hospital, and curative PC for

‘state’ patients (those below a certain income) in areas

where full time public doctors were either not needed or

could not be recruited. Provinces contracted private GPs

part-time. For PC services, they were remunerated at

sessional rates, based on an assumed time per type of

service (eg 10min for a PC consultation), plus a flat fee

per prescription. GPs usually provided facilities for

public patients in separate areas within their private

practice. Separate, nurse-based, public clinics provided

preventive care. Since the removal of user fees for public

PC in 1996, contracted GPs have been delivering services

free to users and demand for services has therefore been

high, with some practices seeing daily over 100 public

patients. Others were turning patients away as their

province had imposed a daily cap on the number of

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Table 1

Models and characteristics of sites studied

Model Individual GP

contract

Company contract IPA Clinic chain Public integrated

model

Services provided PC physician in

individual or group

practice providing

PC services and

drugs

Commercial

company running

PC clinics for

construction sites

and local

communities,

providing PC

services, drugs, lab,

X-ray

PC physician in

individual or group

practice providing

PC services and

drugs

Commercial

company running a

chain of clinics

providing PC

services; drugs; lab

tests; X-ray

PC clinics

providing PC

services, drugs, lab

tests (some clinics),

X-ray (some

clinics)

Funding/payment

mechanism

Contracted by

provincial

authority to

provide free

services to the

general public (also

receive income

from private

practice)

Contracted by

construction

company funded

by parastatal

company

Capitated patients

enrolled in IPA-

managed insurance

scheme (clinics also

see fee-paying

patients)

Fee-paying patients

both insured and

uninsured;

capitated patients

enrolled in their

employer’s

insurance scheme

Global budget

from either

provincial or local

authority

Sites studied 2 provinces; 4 sites

in Western Cape

and 5 in Eastern

Cape

2 sites in Lesotho 2 sites in Eastern

Cape

1 site in Gauteng; 1

in North West

province

7 sites: Western

Cape (3), Eastern

Cape (2), Gauteng

(2)

Reasons for model

and site selection

Provinces:

contracted GPs

important service

providers in

selected provinces;

these provinces

historically used

the same contract

The most recent

and the longest

established clinics

One site in low

income area with

few capitated

patients and one

site in centre of

town with higher

proportion of

capitated patients

Typical examples

of the most up to

date service

provision

Chosen to

represent the range

of circumstances in

the public sector

including location,

size, range of

services, and

availability of

doctor

Sites: cross-section

of: areas, types of

town, number of

GPs per town, and

contractual history

A. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943934

patients reimbursed. Patients were predominately poor,

with little education.

Company contract

Large scale mining or industrial enterprises frequently

provide medical care services to their workers (often

through contracts with medical care firms), and some-

times also to local communities. In the model evaluated

here, a Lesotho parastatal company was funding major

construction works, and included in the service specifi-

cation the running of PC clinics for workers and the

local community. The Ministry of Health reimbursed

the cost of drugs, and other costs were covered by the

contract. Community members paid a user fee of 15

Rand, which was 1.5–3 times higher than that charged in

Lesotho government or church clinics; relatively few

patients attended per day.

Pure private sector models

Independent practice association (IPA)

Urban areas in South Africa have large numbers of

GPs practising privately, their income coming both from

fee-paying walk-in patients and from insured patients

whose medical scheme pays either fee-for-service or

capitation, depending on the scheme. This IPA offered

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Table 2

Data collection tools and sources

Tool (sources) Aiming to measure To shed light ony Target sample size per site

Semi-structured interviews

(facility and company

managers, public sector

purchasers, key informants at

national level)

All aspects of managerial and,

where relevant, contractual

relationships

Organisational structures and

management systems

Contract design

All relevant personnel

Operational details of clinics

e.g. services, opening hours

Manager and provider

motivations and capacity

Nature of service delivery

Cost analysis (facility and

office records; clinic

observations)

Total cost and cost per visit Efficiency of resource use Not relevant

Exit Interviews (patients

leaving clinics)

Experience and perception of

users

Process quality 50

Socio-demographic profile of

users

Structural qualitya

Observation checklist and

Interview (observation at

clinics; clinic managers)

Resources and services

available

Structural qualitya Not relevant

Waiting and consultation

times (timing patients in

clinics)

Adequacy of resources

Duration of consultation

Structural qualitya 50

Process quality

Reviews of STI, diabetes and

hypertension patients (patient

records)

Medical practice Process quality 30 per tracer condition

Adherence to standard

treatment guidelines

Quality of records

Proxy for outcomes

Structural qualitya

Focus Group discussions

(groups of women aged over

20 living adjacent to study

sites)

Experience and perception of

users and non-users of service

Range of treatment options

available

Acceptability to users (adult

women chosen as most

frequent users of PC)

23 purposively sampled to

cover all models

aThese were combined in a structural quality index, with scores attached, in order to summarise the adequacy of resources for service

delivery.

A. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 935

an insurance plan to local employers which provided

comprehensive cover at low cost, using IPA member

surgeries as gatekeepers. Practices were generally busy

with a mix of insured and fee-paying patients. The IPA

reinsured for hospital care and specialist services and

paid GPs monthly according to the number of people

registered with their practice; deductions were made for

specialist referrals, visits to other GPs and auxiliary

services. Although most patients of these practices were

employed, their incomes were relatively low.

Clinic chain

The profits to be made from the urban PC market

have begun to attract commercial companies providing

standardised services in chains of branded clinics,

usually concentrated where there are many low

income employed workers (e.g. near townships). The

example studied was a chain providing PC services, X-

ray and laboratory testing. Its functioning is described

more fully in Palmer, Mills, Wadee, Gilson, and

Schneider (2003). Patients were filtered through a

series of health care providers, starting with a PC

worker, then a nurse clinician, and finally a doctor if

necessary.

Public integrated model

Public sector PC in South Africa is provided and

financed by the state and is currently free at the point of

use to all uninsured patients. Historically, provincial

ARTIC

LEIN

PRES

S

Table 3

Service and user characteristics

Model Individual GP contract Company contracta IPA Clinic chain Public integrated model

Setting and clients Rural towns; low

income groups

Remote rural area;

local communities

Urban; low income

insured workers and

their families

Urban; low income

workers and families,

some insured

Large urban and peri-urban

areas; rural towns and

districts; non-insured

people

Services provided Doctor-based service; curative

only (preventive care done

by adjacent public

clinics)

Doctor based service;

limited preventive

activities

Doctor-based service;

immunisation,

MCH, ANC

Nurse screening; full time

doctor available; limited

preventive services

Comprehensive PC; doctor

based service (1); nurse

based service (1); sessional

doctor (4); full time

doctor available (1)

W Cape E Cape Site 1 Site 2 Site 1 Site 2 Site 1 Site 2 Large Small

Mean patient

workload per FTE

health worker per day

127 98 13 40 96 33 164 127 370 89

% completed

primary education

17 20 33 94 59 80 41 44

% with household

income oR500/mth

65 78 66 17 10 14 7 55 51

Utilisation (%):

Curative care 46 60 83 62 59 75 73 49 50

Chronic care 30 35 14 12 10 13 12 27 25

ANC/MCH/FP 2 2 2 9 11 12 14 6 12

ANC: antenatal care; MCH: maternal and child health; FP: family planning.aDue to the small volumes of patients at one clinic, data from both clinics were analysed together.

A.

Mills

eta

l./

So

cial

Scien

ce&

Med

icine

59

(2

00

4)

93

1–

94

3936

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 937

clinics were tasked with providing curative services while

local government clinics undertook the provision of

‘preventive’ PC (including treatment of STIs and TB);

services have yet to be fully integrated. Users were

generally poor, with the majority not having completed

primary education.

Performance of the alternative models

Prior to considering performance across the models, it

is important to re-emphasise key differences between

them, as summarised in Table 3. They include differ-

ences in provider mix, with some services doctor-based

and others involving nurse screening; very different sized

clinics in terms of staff quota and daily workload; a

greater share of chronic patients in the individual GP

contract clinics and the public clinics; and, not surpris-

ingly, a more educated and relatively less poor popula-

tion using the pure private models.

Cost of care

Table 4 summarises the cost per visit for the different

models, showing the breakdown by input. Small public

clinics had much lower costs than large public clinics.

The IPA and the company contract costs were not

competitive with any of the public clinics. However, the

contracted GPs and the clinic chain had costs that were

highly comparable to public costs. Valuing GP time in

terms of potential income lost from private consulta-

Table 4

Costs to provider (Rand 1998/1999)a

Individual GP

contract

Company

contract

W. Cape E. Cape

n ¼ 4 n ¼ 5 n ¼ 2

Input shares (%)

Clinical staff 42 48 27 33

Medical and surgical

supplies

38 24 21 19

Recurrent costs 89 85 81 87

Capital costs 11 15 19 13

Unit costs (Rand)

Clinical staff/visit 17.28 20.44 42.53 53.07

Medical and surgical

supplies/visit

15.58 10.14 32.69 29.51

Recurrent cost/visit 36.94 35.96 128.58 139.14

Capital cost/visit 4.25 6.05 29.49 20.18

Total cost/visit 41.19 42.01 158.08 159.32

aR1=$12.74.

tions reduced the GP contract cost to close to that of

small public clinics (data not shown). Service-specific

costs reflected a similar pattern of differences between

the models (data not shown).

The IPA model cost was considerably higher than the

contracted GPs’ cost, with spending on drugs and

supplies twice as high. The company contract model had

extremely high costs relative to the other providers in all

categories. Contract specifications required clinics to

have 24 h operation, full doctor cover and an array of

emergency equipment in order to meet health and safety

standards for the construction workforce (though

facilities exclusively for construction workers were

excluded from the costing). Clinical staff costs per visit

and capital cost per visit were at least double those of

other providers. The ‘cost plus’ contract design appeared

instrumental in encouraging high expenditure, as re-

flected in the average cost of drugs prescribed.

Despite the similarity in overall cost per visit between

public clinics, contracted GPs and the clinic chain, the

input mix differed considerably especially for drug costs,

staff costs and capital expenditure. Expenditures on

drugs and medical supplies were roughly comparable

between these models, although large public sector

clinics and some contracted GPs were spending rela-

tively high amounts (data not shown). Expenditure on

clinical staff in small public clinics and the clinic chain

was much below the other models, reflecting their

greater reliance on PC nurses. Lastly, capital expendi-

ture both in absolute terms and as a proportion of total

expenditure was greatest for the clinic company and the

IPA Clinic chain Public integrated model

Large Small

n ¼ 2 n ¼ 2 n ¼ 4 n ¼ 3

23 32 23 29 40 29

41 29 23 15 23 31

95 90 79 79 81 88

5 10 21 21 19 12

19.58 29.62 9.17 12.92 21.32 9.44

34.76 26.95 9.06 6.76 12.44 10.80

81.18 84.43 31.41 35.84 44.48 29.37

4.60 9.11 8.27 9.48 10.44 3.85

85.78 93.53 39.68 45.31 54.92 33.21

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943938

large public clinics. Management costs were also higher

for the clinic chain (data not shown; see Palmer et al.,

2003).

Technical quality of care

Table 5 presents indicators of technical quality.

Consultation times were short overall, with contracted

GPs the shortest and the IPA model, clinic chain and

small public clinics the longest. Structural quality scores

revealed considerable differences. Amongst private

providers there was a considerable range, with both

the best and the worst structural scores (company

contract and contracted GPs respectively). In terms of

physical environment, contracted GPs’ low scores

reflected a lack of investment in terms of space, building

maintenance, and availability of toilets and equipment.

Practices were often cramped, in a poor state of repair

and lacking disabled access. The company contract

clinics in contrast were well equipped, furnished and

maintained, and their staff were operating under less

pressure. Public clinics tended to score well on physical

infrastructure and environment but suffered from long

waiting times and excessive workload. Smaller public

clinics scored higher because their resources were not so

over-stretched, and their workload was more appro-

priate to their size.

The structural quality index sought to capture

elements of service standardisation such as whether all

parts of South Africa’s proposed essential package of

PC services were offered, and whether the facility had a

copy of the government Essential Drug List (EDL). No

private sector provider was offering more than 75% of

what the government considered essential services and

none could show a copy of the EDL. Services typically

not offered were antenatal care and immunisation, as

well as more specialised services such as physiotherapy

and social work. In the case of contracted GPs, this was

because such service provision was done by adjacent

public clinics. In the case of the Lesotho clinics, the

purchasers considered these services were included in the

contract but providers were not keen to deliver them,

arguing this would duplicate the work of public clinics,

and create problems when contracts ended. Many public

clinics also did not provide the full package of services

expected, due to the historical divide between curative

and preventive care. Emergency cover was not provided

by the IPA GPs, the clinic chain or the smaller public

clinics.

The indicators of quality of care for the three tracer

conditions (STIs, diabetes and hypertension) showed

that knowledge of correct STI treatment was poor

amongst private providers, with the exception of the

company contract, and some public providers. Record

reviews noting what proportion of STI patients were

diagnosed syndromically and treated correctly (in line

with government guidelines) reflected poorly on all

models except small public clinics and the clinic chain,

which were the only two models to score over 80%. In

the two IPA clinics, very few STI patients had been

diagnosed syndromically or treated correctly. Such data

were not available for contracted GPs due to their poor

record-keeping, but in interviews their correct treatment

knowledge averaged 50%. Large public clinics’ perfor-

mance fell between the best and the worst of the private

providers.

Care of chronic conditions reflected a different

pattern. Here, the clinic chain scored markedly below

the other models, notably on continuity of care. It gave

adequate treatment (or treatment in line with other

models) to those chronic patients that attended, but a

high proportion of patients with hypertension and

diabetes made less than 25% of expected visits. This

pattern probably reflected some combination of finan-

cial access barriers, plus the often relatively good

reputation of public chronic disease services.

Acceptability to users

Acceptability of services to users is a key element of

quality, though one that is particularly difficult to assess

(Schneider & Palmer, 2002). Total time spent at the

clinic was taken as one indicator. The longest was an

average of three hours at the company contract clinics,

due to a ‘tiered’ system where all construction workers

and their families were treated before local residents.

Total time for GP contract and public models, which

had no financial barrier to access and were the most

crowded, was around 2 h. In contrast, service users

could access consultations and drugs at the IPA in

around half an hour, and at the clinic chain in one hour.

Despite their highly situated and relative nature, data

from FGDs are crucial for shedding light on the human

dimensions of service acceptability. FGD participants

spoke about all their experiences of health services,

public and private, and discussed a number of common

issues including accessibility (waiting times, queues,

likelihood of being sent away without being seen); and

attitudes and practices of staff (politeness, perceived

competence, willingness to explain, amount of time

spent examining/discussing problem, confidentiality).

Views on the attitudes and competence of public

service providers ranged across the spectrum from

excellent to unacceptable. Contracted GPs and the

public sector (large clinics) were most criticised with

frequent mention of waking early to get to a facility, and

waiting until afternoon only to be told to go home and

return next day. The longer measured waiting times of

these models support these views. Public nurses in large

urban clinics were criticised for their attitude and

treatment of patients, rudeness, lack of confidentiality

ARTIC

LEIN

PRES

S

Table 5

Technical quality of care indicators

Individual GP contract Company contract IPA Clinic chain Public integrated model

Western

Cape

Eastern

Cape

Large Small

n ¼ 4 n ¼ 5 n ¼ 2 n ¼ 2 n ¼ 2 n ¼ 4 n ¼ 3

Total consultation

time

Mean (min) 3 5.1 7.7 7.9 9.5 9 N/A 6 9

Structural quality

scores

Infrastructure (%)a 68 66 94 97 61 79 100 74 83 71

Access (%)b 54 76 80 93 80 70 88 70 75 82

Patient environment (%)c 68 50 78 78 90 95 90 90 72 80

Drugs (%)d 60 56 55 75 55 55 55 31 75 95

Total (%) 68 64 80 85 69 75 90 83 83 84

STI treatment Correct treatment knowledge of

providers (%)

51 48 91 46 67 52 44 72 80

Syndromic diagnosis (%) N/A N/A 95 8 0 77 93 51 79

% treated correctlye N/A N/A 37 31 14 97 97 59 96

Diabetes

treatment

% of patient actual visits with BGL

recorded X75%

66 76 50 94 47 82 9 61 89

% of patients p25% expected visits 7 0 0 10 8 74 59 2 1

Hypertension

treatment

% of patient actual visits with BP

recorded X75% of times

50 84 92 72 33 94 96 72 93

% of patients p25% expected visits 3 0 0 0 0 48 48 5 0

N/A: not applicable; BGL: blood glucose level; BP: blood pressure.aFor example, adequacy and state of repair of buildings, adequate emergency equipment, adequacy of toilets.bFor example, opening hours, range of services offered, access for disabled people.cFor example, time spent in the clinic, adequacy and comfort of waiting area, patient privacy during the consultation, whether appropriate health education materials were on

display.dFor example, supply at the time of visit of basic checklist of essential drugs and some drugs specific to tracer conditions such as STIs, diabetes and hypertensione In terms of Department of Health guidelines.

A.

Mills

eta

l./

So

cial

Scien

ce&

Med

icine

59

(2

00

4)

93

1–

94

3939

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943940

and blatant favouritism towards those that they knew or

perceived to be better off patients.

They pick and choose people, it depends if you have a

sister or someone that they attend church with, then

you will be helped soon and given a good service

One woman described how a nurse had yelled at and

threatened to smack her son when he struggled as she

was giving an injection; others said:

nurses shouldn’t be allowed to scold patients

nurses at [large urban clinic] like yelling

In other areas, often smaller or rural clinics, the

perception of public nurses was different and they were

praised for their sympathy and involvement with the

community:

the relationship between the sister and the commu-

nity is good. She lives here and she knows what most

people’s circumstances are like

they are always able to handle my problems and

they are not short tempered. They are always there

for you when you need them and they give you good

medication

Some participants explained that in the public sector

it was a matter of luck which nurse you saw and that

some were sympathetic and helpful whilst others ‘had no

care’. In several groups it was suggested that problems

arose not because the nurses were themselves cruel or

uncaring but due to the pressure under which they

worked and a lack of resources:

I think the problem started when the basic medical

services became free of charge. In the past the nurses

used to handle the patients the right way, but now

they become impatienty

Contracted GPs were viewed in a similar fashion as

public sector nurses, with some complaints:

it isn’t about the patients’ well-being, it’s about the

money that he will get at the end of the month

and some praise:

I like the attention that he gives. He doesn’t just ask

me what the problem is. He also examines meygives

me medicineytells me to come back

The attitudes of staff in other private providers,

contracted or not, was barely criticised.

They make you feel important. Their reception is

good.

You don’t have to wait in long queues, you walk in

and they help you

Favourable comments on the clinic chain centred

on their equipment and willingness to do diagnostic

tests:

They provide many services, sonar, better than

private doctors. Optometrists. Dentists

They check you thoroughly, but if you go to a

government clinic, they just give you Panado, they

don’t even check your urine

It is unclear to what extent the favourable views of

private providers may reflect the experience of paying

for care, and the creation of patient expectations that

treatment would, as a result of payment, be better.

Antenatal care was universally highlighted by FGDs

as a gap in the services offered by all private providers.

Private GPs in the IPA were also criticised for not

always being available when their surgery was open (e.g.

when they were doing sessions at the public hospital), or

over the weekend and for emergencies.

Discussion

Findings

Whether private providers can deliver services of

higher quality at a cost comparable to public sector

delivery is the crux of debates around contracting out

services. In this study, two of the private sector models

examined were delivering services at comparable cost to

the public sector—the contracted GP model and the

clinic chain. However, the two other private sector

models were delivering services at much higher cost,

demonstrating the importance of examining the private

sector model by model. The relatively high cost of the

company contract and IPA models reflected dramati-

cally higher drug spending (more than twice the highest

of any other model) as well as high clinical staff costs (a

staff mix favouring physicians over nurses). The design

of the company contract was based on cost plus

reimbursement and specified very high standards of

equipment, thereby creating clear incentives for the high

costs and emphasising the importance of payment

mechanism design (Gosden et al., 2001). In the IPA,

provider interviews suggested that competition for

patients was based on quantity of drugs dispensed, long

consultation and short waiting times. Competing on

these dimensions entailed relatively high clinical staff

and drug costs.

Returning to the models with unit costs comparable

to those of the public sector, underlying these similarities

were a variety of cost structures, revealing differences in

provider behaviour. In the case of the contracted GPs,

their own salary and drug costs dominated the cost per

visit: few GPs employed extra staff, preferring to see

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 941

patients themselves, and capital investment was very

low. In contrast, the clinic chain’s costs showed lower

expenditure per visit on both drugs and staff, but the

company invested in management systems to monitor

staff performance, and capital equipment both to attract

patients and monitor staff. They provided a less highly

trained medical cadre to see the majority of patients,

whilst maintaining the perception amongst service users

that access to a doctor was always possible. In the public

sector, patterns of spending were varied, but usually had

a higher capital share than was the case for contracted

GPs.

These differences in cost structure had clear con-

sequences for quality and acceptability of care. In the

case of contracted GPs, low capital outlay was reflected

in sparsely equipped, cramped premises in poor repair,

in contrast to the high quality facilities of the clinic

chain. Contracted GPs’ high workload resulted in long

waiting times, short consultations and infrequent

performance of standard procedures such as regular

BP measurement of hypertensives. The clinic chain

limited the services it offered, not providing out of hours

or emergency cover.

Amongst all private providers, even those working

under a public contract, standardisation of services in

line with government guidelines was lacking. This limits

comparisons of service quality to those commonly

delivered by all. For STIs, technical quality of care

appeared to be on average better within the public

sector, with private providers offering an extreme range

of practice. GPs (both contracted and in the IPA) scored

particularly poorly on treatment knowledge, probably

reflecting lack of opportunities for continuing medical

education and contact with peers. In contrast the clinic

chain exercised greater control over service standards

and treatment protocols. Results on the continuity and

quality of care for chronic conditions were mixed for all

providers, and it is likely that charges were an important

deterrent to use for the clinic chain. Overall, smaller

public clinics scored better than the large ones.

The principal consistent advantage of pure private

models appeared to be their greater acceptability to

service users, as found elsewhere (Mills et al., 2002). This

resulted from greater politeness of staff, cleaner facilities

and shorter waiting times, all aspects of a service that

appeared to value users as ‘customers’ and was

adequately resourced for the volume of services deliv-

ered. Pure private models reviewed had little else to

consistently recommend them in terms of quality of care.

As emphasised at the beginning of this paper, these

findings must be understood in the light of the context in

which different providers were working (Fig. 1). Starting

with the demand side, and the characteristics of users,

the clinic chain and IPA were seeing fewer, and less

poor, service users than the public sector or contracted

GP models. These service users were also more powerful

in that they could readily switch to another provider.

These models had higher levels of patient acceptability,

and shorter waiting and longer consultation times.

Where services were state financed, waiting times were

higher, consultation times shorter, and the acceptability

of care to users suffered correspondingly. State pur-

chased services had two, closely related, features: the

user did not pay for the service, and there was generally

excess demand. These both had adverse implications for

the care offered.

A further influence on demand, the degree of choice of

alternative providers, was a function of geography

(urban areas had competitive markets for private PC)

and also of whether services were privately or publicly

funded. Publicly funded services faced a clientele that

had little choice, either because of low income or place

of residence, removing the opportunity to exit from

services that were considered poor quality. This trans-

lated into a lack of incentives to attract patients or

ensure the acceptability of services, as the volume of

demand could be expected to be high.

Supply factors to note were the structure of providers

(public hierarchies, commercial companies, solo practi-

tioners), and related incentives. Each structure gave rise

to different incentives, with implications for health

worker behaviour and service delivery. Findings on

treatment knowledge and practice within the public

sector appear an endorsement of hierarchical structures,

which could effectively ensure standardised clinical

procedures, but their ‘down side’, in terms of behaviour

of providers and perception of service users, was equally

demonstrated. In the pure private models, two very

different incentive structures were evident. In the clinic

chain, the management structure and systems were

devised to keep costs down while still attracting

customers—for example, through computer software

which guided prescribers on best practice (and low cost)

diagnosis and prescribing. Within the IPA, GPs saw all

patients themselves, made clinical decisions indepen-

dently, and bore most financial risk, in terms of both

their own treatment practices and referral decisions.

Financial incentives were clearly important. For

instance, the effect of the fee for service design of the

GP contract was to encourage high volumes of patients

but minimal investment in inputs such as other staff or

equipment (as this was not reimbursed). However, other

factors are also important. As explored in depth in

Palmer and Mills (2003), differences between contracted

GPs suggested that individual factors play an important

role in determining the relative performance of provi-

ders; that is, different providers working under the same

structures and organisational incentives can deliver care

of different cost and quality. This effect is likely to be

stronger for individual providers, such as GPs, than for

those within a well controlled hierarchy such as that of

the contracted company or clinic chain.

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943942

Limitations of the study

The study examined a range of real life examples of

PC delivery, enabling it to highlight some of the

practical strengths and weaknesses of models of public

and private provision and the potential for public/

private contracts. However, attempting to compare

across such a varied population of cases also has

disadvantages. Firstly, the study was able to explore

only a limited number of models and sites, though it did

encompass the main models relevant to current policy

options and there is no reason to believe that the sites

were atypical. Moreover, given lack of knowledge, the

aim was to obtain a comprehensive in depth picture of

all aspects of each model, rather than more limited

information on certain aspects of a large number of

sites. Secondly, the study could provide only a snapshot

of performance for each model and each site at one

point in time, and therefore can only speculate on how

this may alter when some of the demand and supply

factors highlighted in Fig. 1 change, including changes

in purchasing arrangements. Moreover, some perfor-

mance data, for example from the company contract,

reflect more the perverse nature of current incentives

than the potential efficiency or quality of services which

a provider could deliver under different circumstances.

Similarly, the high demand faced by some GP contract

and public clinics may have overwhelmed otherwise

adequate performance by these providers.

Finally, the study suffered from the usual challenges

of health systems research, in that performance was hard

to define, tools to measure aspects such as quality of care

hard to design, and data scarce. The range of models

studied exacerbated these problems, but added to the

value of the overall results for policy making by

demonstrating the diversity of settings and performance

in a middle income country health system.

Concluding comments

These points provide a challenge for what can usefully

be said from the research to aid policy makers in their

decisions. The following appear the most relevant.

1. Two models involving private providers, contracted

GPs and the clinic chain, were delivering care at a

cost comparable to that of the public sector.

2. No model involving private providers consistently

demonstrated higher overall technical quality than

public clinics; GP care suffered from a lack of

standardisation; and the clinic chain, while posses-

sing the potential for standardisation, failed to

deliver this for chronic care due to low patient

contacts.

3. Private providers (except contracted GPs) were

perceived by users to offer much higher quality of

service.

4. Both examples of public/private contracts suffered

from weakness of contract design and implementa-

tion, which affected performance adversely.

Given differences in contextual factors, drawing

conclusions across providers must be done very cau-

tiously. In particular, the assumption that either publicly

or privately owned providers can be assumed to have

defining features in common appears questionable.

Other dimensions of difference between providers, such

as location, size, organisational and management

structure, and population served, appear equally im-

portant influences on performance. With this in mind, to

consider the desirability of further involving the private

sector in public service delivery, it is helpful to reflect on

how both supply and demand factors shown in Fig. 1

might change.

On the demand side, it is important to consider how

the responsiveness and acceptability of private providers

might change if public sector levels of demand are faced.

For instance, contracting with the public sector would

increase the volume of patients seen by providers such as

the clinic chain. This could shorten consultation times

and lengthen waiting times, thus changing the attitude of

staff and reducing the general attractiveness of the

facilities, unless the contractor is allowed to expand

capacity to the same degree. Given public budgetary

constraints, there is the risk that public purchasers

would impose budget limits that might inhibit the

adjustment of supply and demand.

On the supply side, any increase in supplying public

sector services through the private sector needs to

address issues of contract design. Findings from this

study have highlighted the importance of acknowledging

the variety of private providers with whom contracts

might be made, and their different structures and

methods of operation. These have implications for

contract design:

1. At a minimum, a payment system is required that

does not create perverse incentives.

2. The power of users needs to be strengthened, where

possible, for example through mechanisms to enable

exit (e.g. vouchers) or strengthen voice (e.g. commu-

nity management).

3. The choice of service provider needs careful con-

sideration, given the difficulties of monitoring provi-

der performance even in the presence of a contract.

The comparison of models in this paper suggests that

clinic chains may have some advantages given their

internal mechanisms of control, though skilled

contract management would be required to counter-

balance their for-profit orientation.

ARTICLE IN PRESSA. Mills et al. / Social Science & Medicine 59 (2004) 931–943 943

The research reported here represents only an initial

start in exploring these very important policy questions

in South Africa. Future research would benefit from a

larger sample size for models studied, and more specific

exploration of hypotheses, building on the initial

differences between models identified in this research.

While the context of PC provision in South Africa

may appear highly specific, there are many other

countries in a similar position of poor or inadequate

public PC, and relatively abundant, but also varied,

resources in the private sector. The study’s findings

demonstrate the importance of understanding variations

in performance within each provider’s context and

structure, and emphasise the importance of a case by

case judgement on the merits of contracting out (Mills,

1998). Each model was influenced by the nature of the

demand it faced; by the nature and organisational

structure of the provider; by any contractual arrange-

ments that existed; and finally by the individual

preferences of service providers, especially where owner

and provider were the same.

Policy questions around the desirability of contracting

out services are rooted in theoretical arguments about

the incentives offered by different organisational struc-

tures (Williamson, 1975; Mintzberg, 1996), and practical

questions about the relative performance of specific

providers in any given setting. This study emphasises the

variety that can be contained within the standard

‘public–private’ dichotomy, and documents both good

and bad clinical practice and resource use across both

public and private providers, and sometimes within the

same type of provider. Policy makers should beware of

exhortations in favour of either public or private sector

provision that do not allow for such diverse experience.

Acknowledgements

The UK Department for International Development

(DFID) supports policies, programmes and projects to

promote international development. DFID provided

funds for this study as part of that objective but the

views and opinions expressed are those of the authors

alone. We acknowledge the contribution of Khethisa

Taola, Bongani Magongo and Vishal Brijlal to data

collection and analysis.

References

Abramson, W. (1999). Partnerships between the public sector

and non-governmental organisations: Contracting for primary

health care services. A state of the practice paper. LAC

Initiative for Health Sector Reform Report no. 25.

Bethesda: Abt Associates.

Bennett, S. (1997). Private health care and public policy

objectives. In C. Colclough (Ed.), Marketizing education

and health in developing countries: Miracle or mirage? (pp.

93–123). Oxford: Clarenden Press.

Bennett, S., McPake, B., & Mills, A. (1997). Private health

providers in developing countries: Serving the public interest?.

London: Zed Books.

Giustu, D., Criel, B., & De Bethune, X. (1997). Viewpoint:

Public versus private health care delivery: Beyond the

slogans. Health Policy and Planning, 12(3), 193–198.

Gosden, T., Forland, F., Kristiansen, I., Sutton, M., Leese, B.,

Giuffrida, A., Sergison, M., & Pedersen, L. (2001). Impact

of payment method on behaviour of primary care physi-

cians: A systematic review. Journal of Health Services

Research and Policy, 6(1), 44–55.

Jackson, P., & Price, C. (1994). Privatisation and regulation—a

review of the issues. Harlow: Longman.

Mills, A. (1998). To contract or not to contract? Issues for low

and middle income countries. Health Policy and Planning,

13(1), 32–40.

Mills, A., Brugha, R., Hanson, K., & McPake, B. (2002). What

can be done about the private sector in low income

countries? WHO Bulletin, 80(4), 325–330.

Mintzberg, H. (1996). Managing government—governing

management. Harvard Business Review, 74(3), 75–84.

Palmer, N., & Mills, A. (2003). Classical versus institutional

approaches to understanding controls on a contract with

individual GPs in South Africa. Health Economics, 12,

1005–1020.

Palmer, N., Mills, A., Wadee, H., Gilson, L., & Schneider, H.

(2003). A new face for private providers in developing

countries: What implications for public health? WHO

Bulletin, 81(4), 292–297.

Palmer, N., Sinanovic, E., & McIntyre, D. (1999). Findings from

an evaluation of the western cape district surgeon system.

Cape Town: Health Economics Unit, University of Cape

Town.

Salamon, L. (1993). The marketization of welfare-changing

non-profit and for-profit roles in the American Welfare

state. Social Service Review, 67(1), 16–39.

Schneider, H., & Palmer, N. (2002). Getting to the truth?

Researching user views of primary health care. Health

Policy and Planning, 17(1), 32–41.

Souters, R., & Griffiths, F. (2003). Improving government

health services through contract management: A case from

Cambodia. Health Policy and Planning, 18(1), 74–83.

South Africa (Republic) (1995). Restructuring the National

Health System for universal primary health care: Report of

the Committee of Inquiry into a national health insurance

system. Pretoria: Department of Health.

Starfield, B. (1998). Primary care—balancing health needs,

services and technology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and

antitrust implications. New York: The Free Press.

World Bank (2003). World development report 2004. Oxford:

Oxford University Press.