28
THE EMERGENCE OF NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS ECON 434 | Spring 2011

The emergence of neoclassical economics

  • Upload
    akasma

  • View
    53

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

The emergence of neoclassical economics. ECON 434 | Spring 2011. Finishing up from last time. Alternatives to capitalism . Alternatives to capitalism . Socialism Utopian Fabian Christian Revolutionary (Marxism) Anarchism Syndicalism . Perspectives on libertarianism. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: The emergence of neoclassical economics

THE EMERGENCE OF NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICSECON 434 | Spring 2011

Page 2: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Alternatives to capitalism

Finishing up from last time

Page 3: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Alternatives to capitalism Socialism

Utopian Fabian Christian Revolutionary (Marxism)

Anarchism Syndicalism

Page 5: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Tenants of libertarianism The modern champions of laissez-faire

capitalism, libertarians prize freedom as the most important social value, and advocate replacing government with the market system wherever possible. Forbid govt. provision of many goods (i.e. education,

highways, postal service) Abolish any laws governing

Drugs, consensual sex, pornography Parental rights over teens Wages and prices (including utility rates) Military drafts

Page 6: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Scandinavian welfare states In modern welfare states, resources are

largely privately owned, but high taxes and a massive welfare system mean that income is distributed across the society much more equally than, for example, in the United States.

“Welfare capitalism”

Page 7: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Buddhist economics The idea that "small is

beautiful" stresses curbing material want as the key to dealing with scarcity, and emphasizes local self-sufficiency, and small-scale, labor-intensive technology.

Drawn from Buddhist and Hindu religious thought

Intellectual foundations from Gandhi and E.F. Schumacher (Small is Beautiful: Economics as if People Mattered)

Page 8: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Neoclassical economics

Page 9: The emergence of neoclassical economics

The marginalist revolution Application of mathematical analysis to

economics begins in the mid 19th century This new methodological approach

distinguishes classical economics from neoclassical economics.

The use of formal mathematics was absent from Adam Smith’s works, for example

What is a marginal unit? What does it mean for a decision to be made “at the margin”?

Page 10: The emergence of neoclassical economics

The marginalist revolution cont. Marginal decisions are an incremental process Microeconomic analysis is based on

optimization, which entails weighing marginal benefits and marginal costs. Individuals maximize utility; firms, profits

A marginal unit is the extra (or last) unit. In a class of 20 students, all students, technically,

are the marginal student (if any student were to drop the course, 19 students would be enrolled).

Marginal changes are typically denoted with the Greek symbol delta (ΔP reads “change in price”)

Page 11: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Marginal analysis

(Q*, P*) optimizes individual utility (MC = MB) To the left of Q* = Individual hasn’t consumed enough To the right of Q* = Individual has consumed too much

MC

MB

P*

Q*

Page 12: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Marginal analysis cont. The law of equal marginal advantage requires

equivalent goods or similar resources to be allocated in equally advantageous ways at the margin. Mathematically, we can write MUx/Px = MUy/Py = …

Suppose that you and your identical twin are equally strong, experienced, and intelligent. If your twin works an 8-hour day and produces $64 worth of mowed lawns while you generate $48 worth of cleaned windows with similar effort, something is wrong. You will (and should) shift into mowing lawns so that your labor resources are allocated equally advantageously, at $8 per hour instead of the $6 per hour you have been earning.

Page 13: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Marginal analysis cont. Would you eat less from a menu where

prices are a la carte or where fixed price is charged for a buffet?

You probably eat less from a menu where prices are a la carte than if a restaurant charges a fixed price for a buffet; “all-you-can-eat” pricing causes you to view the cost of extra food as zero.

Page 14: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Marginal analysis cont. Other examples of marginal analysis in economics:

People's time must be divided between work and leisure so that the gain in income from the last hour an individual works (the individual's wage) just equals the subjective value of the last hour of leisure enjoyed.

The last dollar a firm pays for labor must generate the same amount of extra production (and profit) as the last dollar spent on capital or land.

The dollar value to a consumer of the right to consume a particular good must equal the value of other production that society sacrifices in making that marginal unit of the good available to that consumer.

Page 15: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Calculus and marginal analysis Isaac Newton and Gottfried Wilhelm von

Leibniz independently discover calculus around 1675.

Takes over 170 years before calculus is applied to economics.

Page 16: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Examples of calculus and marginal analysis (per Cournot) Firms want to maximize profits. Profit = Total revenue – total cost Profit = P•Q – wL – rK Profit = pF(K, L) – wL – rK To maximize: Take the derivate and set equal to 0. 0 = p dF(K, L)/dK – r p dF(K, L)/dk = r r/p = dF(K, L)/dk The firm hires capital until the price of capital (r/p)

equals the marginal product.

Page 17: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Early foundations of marginalism

W. S. Jevons (1835-1882) “Bygones are forever

bygones” Sunk costs are irrelevant

for future decisions. Example: Waiting in line

Diamond-water paradox and marginal pricing

Page 18: The emergence of neoclassical economics

W.S. Jevons cont. Theory of Political Economy (1871)

Diminishing marginal utility Equimarginal principle

Sunspot theory and the beginnings of econometrics

Prices are determined by supply and demand Contrast with classical assumption that

demand is always adequate Say’s law: Supply creates its own demand

Page 19: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Forerunners of marginal analysis

Jules Dupuit Price discrimination: Occurs when virtually

identical units of a good are sold at different prices, and price differentials do not reflect different production costs. Popular examples include movie tickets (i.e., different

prices for teens, senior citizens) and coupons Requirements for price discrimination

The firm must have some amount of market power The firm must know the demand schedule (the

consumers’ willingness to pay) The firm must be able to prevent resale (arbitrage)

Page 20: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Types of price discrimination 1st degree price discrimination

Charge each consumer their willingness to pay.

This eliminates all consumer surplus; it also eliminates all deadweight loss.

Creates conditions of perfect competition Because price discrimination can eliminate

the deadweight loss associated with monopolies, it can make monopolistic behavior efficient

Page 21: The emergence of neoclassical economics

The effects of 1st degree price discrimination

MC

DMR

P*

Q*Producer surplus

Profit

Consumer surplus Deadweigh

t loss

1st degree price discrimination eliminates all consumer surplus and all deadweight loss. The elimination of deadweight loss makes the monopoly efficient (as if in a state of perfect competition).

Page 22: The emergence of neoclassical economics

A monopoly with 1st degree price discrimination

Price discrimination on a person-by-person basis where each is charged the most they are willing to pay (the firm knows each person’s demand curve)

Marginal revenue = demand No consumer surplus; all producer surplus

MC

D

Page 23: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Price discrimination cont. 2nd degree price discrimination: Charge

different per unit prices for different amounts of a good for strategic reasons Bulk discounts Block pricing: first bunch of goods you buy is

expensive; the next bunch is less expensive 3rd degree price discrimination: Charge each

group of consumers a different price based on their willingness to pay Classify individuals into groups and charge all

they will bear

Page 24: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Forerunners of marginal analysis

A.A. Cournot First to clearly define a demand curve

mathematically Profit maximizing rule: MR = MC Employs calculus for optimization problems

(see the “Examples of Calculus in Marginal Analysis” slide)

Distinguishes changes in demand from changes in quantity demanded

Page 25: The emergence of neoclassical economics

A.A. Cournot Distinguishes changes in demand from

changes in quantity demanded

P

Q

D1D0

S0

P

Q

S0

D0

S1

Change in demand Change in quantity demanded

Page 26: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Cournot duopoly model Sets the foundation for modern game

theory Two firms strategically choose their

output (quantity-adjusting model) P = a – bq Marginal cost = c(q) Profit firm x(q1, q2) = p*qx – c(qx) Profit firm 1(q1, q2) = q1[a – b(q1 + q2)] –

c(q1) Profit firm 2(q1, q2) = q2[a – b(q1 + q2)] –

c(q2)

Page 27: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Cournot duopoly model Profit firm 1(q1, q2) = q1[a – b(q1 + q2)] –

c(q1) Re-write the equation: q1[a – bq1 – bq2] –

c(q1) Re-write the equation: q1a – bq12 – bq1q2 – c(q1) 0 = aq1 – bq12 – bq1q2 – c(q1) 0 = a – 2bq1 – bq2 – c 2bq1 = a – bq2 – c Q1 = (a – bq2 – c)/(2b)

This is firm one’s best response function.

Page 28: The emergence of neoclassical economics

Cournot duopoly model The point: The quantity at which a firm

decides to produce is dependent upon the quantity (and subsequent quantity adjustments) of another firm

Assumes continuous strategic interaction between firms

Compare to Bertrand, who said that firms would adjust prices This anticipates a larger debate between

Keynesians and traditional macroeconomists