39
The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility – Appendix * For online publication Oleksiy Kryvtsov and Nicolas Vincent October 2019 * The views expressed here are ours, and they do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of Canada. We thank the editor, Veronica Guerrieri, and three referees, for their valuable comments and suggestions that helped to improve the paper. We would like to thank Susanto Basu, Nicoletta Berardi, Marty Eichenbaum, Gee Hee Hong, Kim Huynh, David Jacho-Ch´ avez, Nir Jaimovich, Alejandro Justiniano, Jim MacGee, Sergio Rebelo, Leonard Sabetti, Gregor Smith, Joe Vavra and participants at the 2015 Canadian Macroeconomic Study Group, the 2015 Banque de France Price Setting and Inflation Conference, the NBER Price Dynamics 2014 Workshop, the 2014 Shanghai Macroeconomic Policies and Business Cycles Conference, the Bank of Canada 2014 Fellowship Learning Exchange, the 2014 Meetings of the European Economics Association, the 2014 Dynare Conference, and the Universit´ e de Montr´ eal, University of Toronto, Queen’s University, Duke University, Mannheim University, Riksbank, Uppsala University, and Banque de France seminar series for helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Ainslie Restieaux and colleagues in the Prices Division at the Office for National Statistics (ONS) for valuable feedback regarding the U.K. CPI data, and Brendan Williams at the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics for providing us the series based on the U.S. CPI data. All estimates and analysis in this paper, based on data provided by ONS, are by the authors and not by the U.K. Office for National Statistics. Claudiu Motoc, Tony Chernis, Anderson Nzabandorra and Minnie Cui provided superlative research assistance. We are grateful to Glen Keenleyside for extremely helpful editorial assistance. Vincent acknowledges financial support from the Fondation HEC Montr´ eal. Bank of Canada, 234 Wellington Av., Ottawa, Ontario K1A 0G9, Canada. [email protected]. HEC Montr´ eal, Department of Applied Economics, 3000 Cˆ ote-Sainte-Catherine, Montr´ eal, Quebec H3T 2A7, Canada. Email: [email protected]

The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility

– Appendix∗–

For online publication

Oleksiy Kryvtsov†and Nicolas Vincent‡

October 2019

∗The views expressed here are ours, and they do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of Canada.We thank the editor, Veronica Guerrieri, and three referees, for their valuable comments and suggestions thathelped to improve the paper. We would like to thank Susanto Basu, Nicoletta Berardi, Marty Eichenbaum,Gee Hee Hong, Kim Huynh, David Jacho-Chavez, Nir Jaimovich, Alejandro Justiniano, Jim MacGee, SergioRebelo, Leonard Sabetti, Gregor Smith, Joe Vavra and participants at the 2015 Canadian MacroeconomicStudy Group, the 2015 Banque de France Price Setting and Inflation Conference, the NBER Price Dynamics2014 Workshop, the 2014 Shanghai Macroeconomic Policies and Business Cycles Conference, the Bank ofCanada 2014 Fellowship Learning Exchange, the 2014 Meetings of the European Economics Association, the2014 Dynare Conference, and the Universite de Montreal, University of Toronto, Queen’s University, DukeUniversity, Mannheim University, Riksbank, Uppsala University, and Banque de France seminar series forhelpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Ainslie Restieaux and colleagues in the Prices Divisionat the Office for National Statistics (ONS) for valuable feedback regarding the U.K. CPI data, and BrendanWilliams at the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics for providing us the series based on the U.S. CPI data. Allestimates and analysis in this paper, based on data provided by ONS, are by the authors and not by the U.K.Office for National Statistics. Claudiu Motoc, Tony Chernis, Anderson Nzabandorra and Minnie Cui providedsuperlative research assistance. We are grateful to Glen Keenleyside for extremely helpful editorial assistance.Vincent acknowledges financial support from the Fondation HEC Montreal.†Bank of Canada, 234 Wellington Av., Ottawa, Ontario K1A 0G9, Canada. [email protected].‡HEC Montreal, Department of Applied Economics, 3000 Cote-Sainte-Catherine, Montreal, Quebec H3T

2A7, Canada. Email: [email protected]

Page 2: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Contents

A Data Appendix 3

A.1 U.K. ONS Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

A.2 Sales and food products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

A.3 Sales and business cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

A.4 Boostrapped standard errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

A.5 Sales frequency for selected categories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

A.6 Cyclicality of sales at the category level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

A.7 Regional regressions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

A.8 Clearance sales . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

A.9 Probit regressions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

A.10 Retailer type . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

B Model Appendix 19

B.1 Household’s dynamic optimization problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

B.2 Intermediate input producers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

B.3 Retailers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

B.4 Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

B.5 Full system of equilibrium equations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

B.6 Price dispersion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

B.7 Steady-state properties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

B.8 Elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

B.9 Model Robustness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

B.9.1 Convex adjustment cost for discounts and shopping time . . . . . . . . . 31

B.9.2 Price of shopping time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

B.9.3 Model with materials as intermediate input in retail production . . . . . 32

C Measuring the impact of discounts on the aggregate price level 35

2

Page 3: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A Data Appendix

A.1 U.K. ONS Data

Here we provide a more detailed description of the consumer price index (CPI) micro dataset

from the United Kingdom’s Office for National Statistics (ONS), which is publicly available.

We also describe some adjustments we made to the raw data to ensure their suitability for

our exercises.

To construct the consumer price index (CPI), the Office for National Statistics (ONS)

surveys the prices for goods and services that are included in the household final monetary

consumption expenditure component of the U.K. National Accounts.1 The survey includes

prices for more than 1,100 individual goods or services a month, collected locally from more

than 14,000 retail stores across the United Kingdom. The survey excludes the housing portion

of consumer prices, such as mortgage interest payments, house depreciation, insurance and

other house purchase fees.2 Also, expenditures for purposes other than final consumption are

excluded, e.g., those for capital and financial transactions, direct taxes, and cash gifts.3

Goods and services in the CPI are classified into 71 classes, according to the international

(European) classification of household expenditure, Classification of Individual Consumption

by Purpose (COICOP). A CPI class represents a basic group category, such as “Meat,” “Liq-

uid Fuels” or “New Cars”; and each CPI class is divided into finer categories, “items.” For

each item and stratum (given by region and shop type pairing in the U.K. data), ONS dataset

provides sampling weights that reflect products’ relative importance in households’ consump-

tion expenditures. These weights exhibit small variation over time due to annual revisions

to capture permanent changes in the expenditure composition of households’ consumption

baskets.4

Prices are collected across 13 geographical regions (e.g., London, Wales, East Midlands).

There are four levels of sampling for local price collection: locations, outlets within location,

items within section and product varieties. For each geographical region, locations and outlets

are based on a probability-proportional-to-size systematic sampling with a size measure based

on the number of employees in the retail sector (locations) and the net retail floor space

(outlets). The data set contains around 150 locations with an average of more than 90 outlets

per location.

Representative items are selected based on a number of factors, including expenditure size

1Detailed descriptions of the data underlying the CPI, the statistical methodology used, collection andvalidation of prices, and calculation of weights, can be found in ONS (2014). The price quote data areavailable via the ONS website: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/datasets-and-tables/index.html.

2These prices are used to construct the retail prices index (RPI).3CPI inflation was used by the government for its inflation target starting in December 2003. Before then,

the index was published in the United Kingdom as the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP).4Weights are calculated based on the Household Final Monetary Consumption Expenditure (HFMCE) and

ONS Living Cost and Food Survey (LCF).

3

Page 4: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

and product diversity, variability of price movements, and availability for purchase throughout

the year (except for certain goods that are seasonal). There are currently over 510 items in

the basket. Examples of representative items include: onions, men’s suit, single bed. Finally,

for each item-outlet-location, individual products and varieties are chosen by price collectors

based on their shelf size and regular stock replenishment.

Most prices are collected monthly, except for some services in household and leisure groups,

and seasonal items. For the purpose of this paper, the sample period includes 212 months,

from February 1996 till September 2013. The total raw number of observations is over 24.4

million, or about 115,000 per month, though we make some adjustments that are described

later in order to make the database amenable to analysis.

In addition to posted prices, the data set also contains information about some charac-

teristics of goods during price collection. Prices for goods that are on special offer (available

to all consumers) or on temporary sale comprise 6.4% of observations in the data set (4.4%

weighted). It is important to note that these “sales” have to be available to everyone (i.e.,

coupons and discounts that require a loyalty card are not taken into account) and on a sin-

gle purchase (e.g., discounts implied by “buy-two-get-one-free” promotions are not recorded).

Forced substitutions happen 8.0% (5.5% weighted) of the time, with about a quarter (three-

quarters) of them corresponding to substitutions for items that are non-comparable (compa-

rable) to previously priced items. An item can be temporarily out of stock (2.2% or 1.5%

weighted) or permanently missing (0.5% or 0.3% weighted). Finally, a small subset of goods

has distinct seasonal patterns and is treated separately: they include some items of clothing,

gardening products, holiday products and air fares. For those seasonal goods for which prices

are not available, such as clothing, gardening and food, prices are imputed based on prices

observed at the end of the previous season or based on prices observed for in-season goods in

the same item category; in addition, weights are adjusted in accordance with the availability

of such goods throughout the year.

We make some adjustments to the ONS database to make it suitable for our analysis.

First, we delete observations that are not coded as valid by the ONS. Second, we deal with

product substitutions by splitting the price time series of a given item every time we encounter

a substitution flag. The resulting benchmark data set contains a total of 20.7 million observa-

tions across about 2.3 million unique items. It should be noted that for our empirical analysis,

we will mostly focus on items that have at least ten price quotes (17.1 million observations).

Value-added taxes (VAT) are included in the price quotes. The implication is that any

change in the VAT rate will automatically lead to a price change. VAT changes, however,

were very few over our sample period. The only exceptions are three major changes to the

standard VAT rate in the later part of the sample. First, in response to the Great Recession,

the Conservative government announced a widespread reduction in the VAT rate from 17.5%

to 15% effective 1 December 2008. Then, the rate was brought back to 17.5% starting 1

4

Page 5: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

January 2010. Finally, the standard VAT rate was raised from 17.5% to 20% on 4 January

2011. We control for these events in our analysis.5

A.2 Sales and food products

We show that controlling for a linear time trend in the regression of sales frequency on

unemployment, as it is done in Coibion, Gorodnichenko, and Hong (2015), yields only a

weak relationship for food products, but does not alter the strong positive correlation at the

aggregate level (Tables A.1, A.2).

Table A.1: Regressions at the aggregate level, United Kingdom

Aggregate Food

W W UW UW W W UW UW

ut 0.179*** 0.233*** 0.286*** 0.328*** 0.341*** 0.110** 0.574*** 0.207***

Linear time trend N Y N Y N Y N Y

R2 0.42 0.45 0.26 0.26 0.40 0.55 0.55 0.72

Notes: OLS regressions. CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics, sample period is fromFebruary 1996 to September 2013. The dependent variable is the fraction of sales flag in a given month. ’W’indicates that the series is weighted using CPI weights, ’UW’ is unweighted. *** and ** indicate statisticalsignificance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.

5Moreover, VAT changes are more akin to regular price changes, while our focus is on temporary sales. Forthis reason, they have little incidence on our results.

5

Page 6: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Tab

leA

.2:

Con

trib

uti

onof

sale

sto

the

pri

ceof

food

inth

eU

nit

edK

ingd

om

Contribution

ofsa

les,

all

food

Contribution

ofsa

les,

by

basicclass

Contribution

ofsa

les,

by

region

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

Fra

ctio

nof

sale

sγt

γt

γt

γit

(cla

ss)

γit

(cla

ss)

γit

(cla

ss)

γit

(reg

ion)

γit

(reg

ion)

γit

(reg

ion)

–1.15

–1.20

–1.04

–1.03

–0.97

–1.09

–1.05

–0.95

–1.54

Fix

edeff

ects

Y(c

lass

)Y

(cla

ss)

NY

(reg

ion)

Y(r

egio

n)

N

Month

dum

mie

sN

YY

Y(c

lass

)Y

(cla

ss)

NY

(reg

ion)

Y(r

egio

n)

N

Lin

ear

tim

etr

end

NN

YN

Y(c

lass

)N

NY

(reg

ion)

N

Month

fixed

effec

tsN

NN

NN

Y(c

lass

)N

NY

(reg

ion)

R2

0.7

10.7

40.8

20.5

80.6

20.9

20.6

20.6

60.5

7

#obs

216

216

216

2373

2373

11

2592

2592

12

Note

s:Sale

sare

defi

ned

as

V-s

hap

eddis

counts

of

10%

or

more

.R

egre

ssio

nty

pes

are

indic

ate

din

colu

mns.

Aggre

gate

regre

ssio

n(c

olu

mns

1-3

)is

pt

=c

+βγt+X′ tΦ

+e t

,w

her

ept

isth

em

ean

sale

-pri

cete

rmfo

rall

food,

andγt

isth

efr

act

ion

of

sale

sin

montht,

andXt

are

month

dum

mie

sand

linea

rtr

end.

Panel

regre

ssio

ns

arepit

=αi+βγit

+X′ itΦi+e it,

wher

epit

are

the

mea

npri

cegap

for

food

basi

ccl

assi

(colu

mns

4-6

)or

for

regio

ni

(colu

mns

7-9

)in

per

iodt

andγit

isth

efr

act

ion

of

sale

sfo

rth

at

class

or

regio

nin

montht,

andXit

are

month

dum

mie

s,ca

tegory

-sp

ecifi

clinea

rtr

end,

and

fixed

effec

ts.

Panel

regre

ssio

ns

are

wei

ghte

dby

CP

Isa

mple

wei

ghts

.A

llco

effici

ents

are

stati

stic

ally

signifi

cant

at

1%

level

.

6

Page 7: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.3 Sales and business cycles

Table A.3 provides standard deviations and correlations for the fraction of sales, real con-

sumption and hours worked in the U.S. We use the following U.S. business cycle variables (all

monthly):

• lt : (Log) Hours worked per capita, total adult population (16+). Total hours

worked, all private [series CES0500000056], BLS. Total civilian uninstitutionalized pop-

ulation, 16 and over [series LNS10000000]. BLS.

• ct : (Log) Real consumption (non-durables and services) per capita, adult

equivalent. U.S.: Real consumption, non-durables [from FRED, series PCESC96].

BEA. Real consumption, services [from FRED, series PCENDC96]. BEA. Adult-equivalent

population = (Population ≥ 16) + 0.5 * (Population ≤ 15). Total population, all ages

[from FRED, series POPTHM]. BEA. Total civilian uninstitutionalized population, 16

and over [series LNS10000000]. BLS.

Table A.3: Standard deviations and correlations

Business cycle United States

variable BLS sample

Standard deviations

γt, ppt 0.44

ut, ppt 2.84

lt, % 3.05

ct, % 1.64

Correlations

corr(γt, ct) –0.635

corr(γt, lt) –0.444

Notes: Table provides standard deviations and correlations. The fraction of sales γt and unemployment rateut are expressed in percentage points, the remaining variables are in log %. The fraction of sales is based onv-shapes. Business cycle variables include ut : unemployment rate; lt : (Log) Hours worked per capita, totaladult population (16+); ct : (Log) Real consumption (non-durables and services) per capita, adult equivalent.The sample period is January 2000 to December 2011.

A.4 Boostrapped standard errors

In the main text we provide a number of alternative standard errors to account for possible

serial correlation and/or heteroskedasticity in the residuals. However, because the small

7

Page 8: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

sample properties of these methods are known to be problematic under some cases, we also

compute bootstrapped standard errors according to the following methodology:

1. Run the base regression described in Table 3 on the actual data to obtain parameter

estimates as well as the residuals εγt .

γt = α+ βut +X′t γ + εγt

where γt is the fraction of products on sale in period t, ut is the unemployment rate,

and Xt is a vector of controls such as calendar month dummies and a time trend.

2. Run an AR(1) regression for the unemployment rate using actual data, and save the

residuals εut :

ut = δ + ρut−1 + uut

3. From the empirical distributions of εγt and εut , draw N = 5, 000 samples of residuals

with replacement. For every sample n, the two time series of randomly drawn residuals,εγn,t

andεun,t

, are of length T ′ = B+T , where T is the number of observations used

in the base regression of Step 1 and B is a burn-in parameter set to 500.

4. Take a given sample n. For each t from 1 to T ′:

(a) Using the randomly drawn residual εun,t, generate:

un,t = δ + ρun,t−1 + εun,t

(b) Using the value of the unemployment rate un,t generated in the previous step as

well as the randomly drawn residual εγn,t, generate

˜γn,t = α+ βun,t + εγn,t

5. For each bootstrap sample n, run the base regression using the last T observations:

γn,t = α∗n + β∗nun,t + εγt

and save the standard error for coefficient of interest, β∗n, which we denote as σβn .

6. Report the average standard error across the 5,000 bootstrap samples,∑5,000

n=1 σβn .6

Table A.4 reports the alternative standard errors alongside the point estimates and OLS

standard errors that were provided in the main text.

6Another approach is to find the x2% and 1− x

2% quantiles of the distribution of 5,000 β∗n in order to compute

the x% confidence interval. The conclusions are similar using either method. Also, we find the estimated biasof the estimated coefficientβ is negligible.

8

Page 9: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Table A.4: Alternative standard errors

OLSestimate

Standard Errors

OLS Robust C-O N-W Bootstrap

UK

mean, V-shaped, no trend 0.544 0.024∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ 0.057∗∗∗ 0.047∗∗∗ 0.068∗∗∗

mean, V-shaped, linear trend 0.464 0.023∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗ 0.040∗∗∗ 0.033∗∗∗ 0.059∗∗∗

mean, flag, no trend 0.393 0.024∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ 0.053∗∗∗ 0.040∗∗∗ 0.063∗∗∗

mean, flag, linear trend 0.358 0.026∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ 0.052∗∗∗ 0.041∗∗∗ 0.061∗∗∗

US - BLS

mean, no trend 0.177 0.017∗∗∗ 0.016∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.021∗∗∗ 0.045∗∗∗

mean, linear trend 0.233 0.025∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗ 0.030∗∗∗ 0.043∗∗∗

US - Vavra (2014)

mean, no trend 0.338 0.032∗∗∗ 0.030∗∗∗ 0.044∗∗∗ 0.043∗∗∗ 0.048∗∗∗

mean, linear trend 0.320 0.033∗∗∗ 0.033∗∗∗ 0.048∗∗∗ 0.046∗∗∗ 0.048∗∗∗

US - Anderson et al. (2017)

fixed weights, no trend 0.151 0.021∗∗∗ 0.013∗∗∗ 0.053∗∗∗ 0.026∗∗∗ 0.038∗∗∗

fixed weights, linear trend 0.035 0.013∗∗∗ 0.009∗∗∗ 0.032∗ 0.017∗∗ 0.023∗

BLS weights, no trend 0.067 0.013∗∗∗ 0.010∗∗∗ 0.030∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗

BLS weights, linear trend 0.073 0.014∗∗∗ 0.011∗∗∗ 0.032∗∗∗ 0.018∗∗∗ 0.024∗∗∗

BLS weights, sales flag, no trend 0.219 0.016∗∗∗ 0.011∗∗∗ 0.030∗∗∗ 0.019∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗

BLS weights, sales flag, linear trend 0.152 0.014∗∗∗ 0.014∗∗∗ 0.022∗∗∗ 0.021∗∗∗ 0.023∗∗∗

Notes: Linear regressions of the fraction of products on sale on the unemployment rate (ut). “OLS estimate”:regression estimates from Table 3 above, with cases specified in rows. Alternative standard errors are reportedin separate columns: “OLS”: OLS standard errors from Table 3; “Robust”: Huber/White/sandwich estimator;“C-O” (Cochrane-Orcutt) standard errors assume that the errors follow an AR(1) process; “N-W”: Newey-West standard errors assume that the errors are heteroskedastic and follow an AR(4) process; “Bootstrap”:OLS-HAC standard errors across bootstrap samples. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 denote significance levelscorresponding to alternative standard errors.

9

Page 10: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.5 Sales frequency for selected categories

The volatility and cyclicality of sales are not driven by just a few large categories. The top-

left plot of Figure A.1 shows the evolution of the fraction of price quotes with a sales flag

aggregated using equal weights across categories, as opposed to the weighted statistic reported

so far. Another concern could be that some changes in the collection of data or the definition

of sales coincided with the onset of the recession and therefore are leading to spuriously

identify a high degree of cyclicality. While the fact that the results hold across multiple sales

filters should allow us to dismiss this concern, we further note that the cyclicality of sales is

not a feature that is common to all categories, and therefore it is unlikely to be generated

mechanically. Figure A.1 shows a significant rise in the incidence of sales (here defined as the

fraction of items with a sales flag) for categories such as “Clothing and footwear,” “Furnishings

and other household equipment,” and “Personal care.” Yet, for other categories such as

“Books” or “Housing rents and maintenance,” there is no significant rise in sales around

2007–09.

It should also be noted that the rise in the sale frequency is broad-based: the number

of products that experienced a rise in their sale frequency between the periods 2005–06 and

2009–10 is almost three times as high as those that saw a drop.

Figure A.1: Frequency of sales (sales flag), selected categories

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

.02

.03

.04

.05

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

All products − unweighted

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

.02

.03

.04

.05

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Clothing and footwear

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Furnishings and hhld eqpt

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

.01

.02

.03

.04

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Personal care

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

0.0

05.0

1.0

15S

ales

freq

uenc

y (s

olid

)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Housing rents & maintenance

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

0.0

5.1

.15

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Alcoholic bevs.

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

0.0

5.1

.15

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Books

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

0.0

02.0

04.0

06S

ales

freq

uenc

y (s

olid

)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Restaurants and cafes

.05

.06

.07

.08

.09

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

ashe

d)

0.0

5.1

.15

.2S

ales

freq

uenc

y (s

olid

)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

Audio & Video

Notes: Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data.

10

Page 11: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.6 Cyclicality of sales at the category level

We explore more on composition and differences by sector. Table A.5 reports coefficients

from two regressions at basic class level. Column (1): Sales frequency on monthly aggregate

unemployment rate and a time trend (t-statistics in Column 2); Column (3): Sales frequency

on the log of quarterly category-level real consumption and a time trend (t-statistics in Column

4). Sales are identified using the ONS sales flag and must be at least 10% in size.

We merge the results from these regressions with three types of sector-specific information.

First, we add the data on life expectancy for durable goods, obtained from Bils and Klenow

(1998) for the United States (Column 6 in the Table). Second, we add 5-firm concentration

ratios for the United Kingdom in 2004 from Mahajan (2006), see Column (7). Finally, we

compute class-specific moments for price-adjustment variables: inflation, frequency of price

changes, and absolute size of price changes, their means and standard deviations over time,

using posted and regular prices (Columns 8 through 17).

We find that more durable goods and goods with more concentrated businesses tend

to have more countercyclical sales. These correlations are relatively weak with p-values in

regression on unemployment rate of 0.027 and 0.016, respectively; and in regression on real

consumption 0.162 and 0.224 respectively, owing to the small number of observations for which

we matched the data for durability (12) and concentration ratios (29).

In regressions on price-adjustment moments, only two of them result in significant corre-

lations across basic classes. Goods with smaller mean absolute size of price changes or those

with more volatile frequency of price changes (for either poster or regular prices) tend to

be more countercyclical, with coefficients significant at 1% level or better for regressions on

unemployment rate and 5% or better for regressions on real consumption. The number of

matched goods in these regressions is 35.

11

Page 12: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Tab

leA

.5:

Cycl

ical

ity

ofsa

les

by

bas

iccl

ass,

Un

ited

Kin

gdom

coicop

_id

Basic

class

Class

weight

Freq

uency

of sa

les

Durabil

ity

5‐firm

concen

trati

on ra

tiomean( t)

mean(frt)

mean

(|DP

t|)

mean( t)

mean(frt)

mean

(|DP

t|)

std( t)

std( t)

std(frt)

std(frt)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

(13)

(14)

(15)

(16)

(17)

coeff

t‐stat

coeff

tstat

posted

regular

posted

regular

1010

1BR

EAD & CER

EALS

4.98

1.05

11.20

‐1.10

‐6.92

0.03

131

0.23

0.20

17.1

0.27

0.16

12.3

0.74

0.57

0.08

0.07

1010

4MILK, CHE

ESE & EGGS

4.12

0.75

10.07

‐0.45

‐2.82

0.02

232

0.23

0.17

15.7

0.26

0.14

11.3

0.92

0.81

0.09

0.08

1010

9FO

OD PR

ODU

CTS

1.00

0.98

7.87

‐0.06

‐0.40

0.03

239

0.19

0.18

18.5

0.23

0.14

13.1

0.97

0.71

0.09

0.07

1010

7VE

GETAB

LES INCLUDING

POTA

TOES AND OTH

ER TUBE

RS

4.50

0.84

7.51

‐0.47

‐3.03

0.03

00.06

0.34

19.6

0.08

0.30

17.9

2.57

2.37

0.06

0.06

1020

2MINER

AL W

ATER

S, SOFT

DRINKS

AND JUICES

2.74

1.41

7.03

‐1.47

‐7.58

0.03

475

0.18

0.20

17.1

0.21

0.16

11.7

0.93

0.66

0.11

0.10

5060

1NON‐DURA

BLE HO

USEHO

LD

GOODS

1.69

1.57

6.94

‐1.93

‐6.86

0.04

30.13

0.21

17.7

0.19

0.16

12.7

1.23

0.75

0.12

0.10

2010

2WINE (IN

C PERR

Y)2.90

1.16

6.31

‐1.41

‐4.78

0.06

750

0.19

0.26

17.6

0.30

0.17

12.8

1.27

0.75

0.13

0.10

1203

01JEWELLERY

CLO

CKS AN

D WAT

CHES

1.78

0.89

6.18

‐0.71

‐2.76

0.03

17.8

160.32

0.12

24.6

0.41

0.09

22.1

0.88

0.60

0.07

0.06

1010

5OILS & FAT

S0.62

1.60

5.74

‐0.76

‐1.63

0.03

888

0.28

0.21

16.0

0.33

0.16

10.8

1.89

1.39

0.12

0.11

1201

02AP

PLIANCE

S, ART

ICLES &

PRODU

CTS FO

R PERSONAL

CA

RE

5.79

0.68

5.47

‐0.59

‐3.71

0.03

740

0.13

0.17

21.3

0.23

0.13

16.6

0.74

0.58

0.08

0.06

5040

0GLASSWAR

E, TAB

LEWAR

E AN

D HO

USEHO

LD UTENSILS

1.94

0.85

4.42

‐0.69

‐3.42

0.05

017

.726

0.01

0.16

28.7

0.16

0.11

27.8

1.54

0.89

0.08

0.07

1010

8SU

GAR

, JAM

, HONEY, SYR

UPS,

CHOCO

LATE AND

CONFECT

IONER

Y

3.42

0.46

4.16

‐0.20

‐2.13

0.01

881

0.30

0.14

14.4

0.34

0.12

10.6

0.76

0.47

0.08

0.07

1203

02OTH

ER PER

SONAL

EFFEC

TS0.97

1.19

3.71

‐0.07

‐0.17

0.05

717

.526

0.14

0.19

24.4

0.31

0.13

23.2

1.66

1.06

0.08

0.06

2010

1SPIRITS

1.68

1.39

3.64

‐0.97

‐1.74

0.09

250

0.15

0.34

11.3

0.23

0.20

8.1

2.35

1.03

0.17

0.13

4030

1PR

ODU

CTS FO

R TH

E RE

GULAR

MAINTENAN

CE AND RE

PAIR OF

DWELLING

2.80

0.44

3.41

‐0.39

‐2.79

0.02

00.24

0.11

18.8

0.27

0.10

17.0

0.89

0.79

0.08

0.08

1010

2MEA

T6.73

0.67

3.39

‐0.83

‐4.39

0.05

017

0.28

0.25

18.3

0.34

0.19

14.2

0.93

0.77

0.06

0.06

9050

3MISC. PRINTED MAT

TER AN

D STAT

IONER

Y AN

D DR

AWING

MAT

ERIALS

1.77

0.35

3.35

‐0.14

‐1.30

0.01

112

0.16

0.09

23.5

0.20

0.09

22.3

0.70

0.65

0.06

0.06

9030

4PETS AND RE

LATED PR

ODU

CTS

INCLUDING VETER

INAR

Y AN

D OTH

ER SER

VICE

S FO

R PETS

2.41

0.26

3.31

‐0.29

‐3.74

0.01

136

0.23

0.13

13.1

0.25

0.12

10.5

0.65

0.48

0.07

0.07

1020

1CO

FFEE, TEA

, COCO

A0.97

0.56

3.08

‐0.46

‐2.17

0.03

80.20

0.24

15.1

0.22

0.19

10.3

1.46

0.94

0.13

0.12

9010

1EQ

UIPMEN

T FO

R TH

E RE

CEPTION & REPRO

DUCT

ION

OF SO

UND & PICTU

RE

1.76

1.55

2.89

‐1.23

‐1.81

0.10

311

.927

‐0.70

0.31

15.9

‐0.46

0.22

16.9

1.96

1.92

0.11

0.08

7020

1SPAR

E PA

RTS & ACC

ESSO

RIES

1.83

0.26

2.81

‐0.14

‐1.43

0.01

23.0

340.17

0.11

13.3

0.19

0.10

12.4

0.63

0.57

0.08

0.08

2010

3BE

ER1.60

0.87

2.69

‐1.48

‐3.10

0.06

550

0.11

0.30

14.5

0.18

0.22

11.6

1.55

1.15

0.13

0.12

6010

2OTH

ER M

EDICAL

PRO

DUCT

S TH

ERAP

EUTIC AP

PLIANCE

S AN

D EQ

UIPMEN

T

1.36

0.17

2.53

0.11

1.39

0.00

92.9

14

0.08

0.06

21.6

0.08

0.05

19.5

0.67

0.56

0.04

0.04

1010

3FISH

1.30

0.94

2.35

‐0.09

‐0.15

0.05

436

0.42

0.26

18.7

0.53

0.19

13.3

1.33

0.78

0.07

0.06

Une

mploymen

t rate

Real

consum

ption

posted

prices

regular p

rices

12

Page 13: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

5050

0TO

OLS AND EQ

UIPMEN

T FO

R HO

USE AND GAR

DEN

1.79

0.26

2.03

‐0.54

‐2.06

0.02

07.5

110.18

0.11

21.7

0.23

0.09

20.7

1.29

1.22

0.07

0.07

3010

2GAR

MEN

TS14

.16

0.37

2.03

‐0.46

‐2.40

0.06

93.1

14‐0.25

0.24

32.7

0.19

0.16

28.0

2.95

0.95

0.07

0.06

9030

1GAM

ES TOYS AND HO

BBIES

4.77

0.35

1.89

‐0.43

‐1.91

0.04

05.0

23‐0.05

0.16

27.1

0.11

0.12

25.5

1.30

1.01

0.09

0.08

3010

3OTH

ER ART

ICLES OF CLOTH

ING

& CLO

THING ACC

ESSO

RIES

0.88

0.26

1.83

‐0.40

‐3.06

0.02

90.04

0.14

34.5

0.17

0.10

30.4

2.04

1.03

0.07

0.06

5010

1FU

RNITURE

, FURN

ISHINGS

6.49

0.31

1.29

‐0.53

‐1.40

0.15

29.6

50.17

0.27

23.5

0.38

0.13

22.0

3.51

1.06

0.08

0.05

6010

1PH

ARMAC

EUTICA

L PR

ODU

CTS

1.41

0.05

0.56

0.04

0.46

0.01

957

0.11

0.13

19.6

0.14

0.10

17.2

0.99

0.68

0.08

0.07

9030

2EQ

UIPMEN

T FO

R SPORT

CA

MPING AND OPEN‐AIR

RECR

EATION

1.06

0.06

0.27

‐0.15

‐0.57

0.05

423

‐0.06

0.14

27.4

0.14

0.09

25.4

1.38

0.76

0.08

0.05

5020

0HO

USEHO

LD TEXTILES

2.13

0.06

0.22

‐0.12

‐0.37

0.10

36.2

15‐0.01

0.21

25.3

0.20

0.10

23.6

2.22

0.58

0.07

0.05

1010

6FRUIT

2.51

0.04

0.17

0.08

0.33

0.03

136

0.02

0.37

23.8

0.08

0.33

22.8

3.14

2.61

0.09

0.08

3020

0FO

OTW

EAR INCLUDING

REPA

IRS

2.62

‐0.03

‐0.17

‐0.16

‐0.70

0.06

02.6

25‐0.14

0.18

28.2

0.20

0.12

22.9

1.84

0.67

0.07

0.05

9030

3GAR

DEN PLANTS AND

FLOWER

S1.53

‐0.09

‐0.35

0.16

0.61

0.02

30.07

0.15

29.0

0.12

0.13

28.1

1.75

1.60

0.07

0.06

weighted mean

0.60

‐0.56

0.05

2.6

260.08

0.21

22.0

0.22

0.15

18.8

1.67

0.95

0.08

0.07

med

ian

0.56

‐0.45

0.04

6.8

310.15

0.18

19.6

0.21

0.13

17.0

1.30

0.78

0.08

0.07

(A) regression coeff o

n (1)

‐0.546

0.05

10.00

90.35

41.48

8‐0.034

‐0.188

1.96

6‐0.036

‐0.123

‐0.006

10.497

12.489

p

‐value

0.79

20.02

70.01

60.31

00.15

00.00

20.73

60.12

30.00

00.09

90.96

50.00

10.00

1

(B) regression coeff o

n (3)

‐1.866

‐0.025

‐0.005

‐0.175

‐1.672

0.02

30.00

3‐1.412

0.02

80.07

60.11

0‐11.14

4‐11.96

6 p‐value

0.38

70.16

20.22

40.63

20.12

10.04

90.99

60.29

40.01

50.33

80.47

40.00

10.00

2

(1)

coeff

coefficient in

regressio

n of sa

les frequ

ency on un

employmen

t rate

(2)

t‐stat

correspo

nding t‐statistic

(3)

coeff

coefficient in

regressio

n of freq

S on

real con

sumption (quarterly)

(4)

tstat

correspo

nding t‐statistic

(5)

Freq

uency of sa

les

freq

uency of sa

les (V‐shaped

disc

ounts o

ver 1

0%)

(6)

Durability

expe

cted

life (in years), U

nited States, Tables 1

‐3 from

"Usin

g Co

nsum

er The

ory to Test C

ompe

ting Bu

siness C

ycle M

odels" (B

ils and

Kleno

w, JPE

199

8)(7)

5‐firm con

centratio

n ratio

top 5 bu

sinesses a

s a percentage of to

tal outpu

t, United Kingdo

m, 200

4(8)

mean( t)

average mon

thly weighted mean price change, posted prices

(9)

mean(frt)

average mon

thly weighted mean fractio

n of price changes, posted prices

(10)

mean(|D

P t|)

average mon

thly weighted mean absolute size of p

rice change (con

d. on change), po

sted

prices

(11)

mean( t)

average mon

thly weighted mean price change, regular prices

(12)

mean(frt)

average mon

thly weighted mean fractio

n of price changes, re

gular p

rices

(13)

mean(|D

P t|)

average mon

thly weighted mean absolute size of p

rice change (con

d. on change), regular p

rices

(14)

std( t)

posted

standard deviatio

n of th

e weighted mean price change, posted prices

(15)

std( t)

regular

standard deviatio

n of th

e weighted mean fractio

n of price changes, posted prices

(16)

std(frt)

posted

standard deviatio

n of th

e weighted mean price change, regular prices

(17)

std(frt)

regular

standard deviatio

n of th

e weighted mean fractio

n of price changes, re

gular p

rices

posted

prices

regular

prices

Une

mploymen

t rate

Real con

sumption

Notes: C

olum

ns (1

) and

(3) rep

ort coe

fficien

ts from

two regressio

ns at the

category level. (1): Sales frequ

ency on mon

thly aggregate une

mploymen

t rate and a tim

e tren

d. (3

): Sales frequ

ency on the log of quarterly category‐level real

consum

ption and a tim

e tren

d. Sales are iden

tified using the ONS sales flag and must b

e at least 1

0% in

size. U

.K. O

ffice fo

r National Statistics d

ata. Row

s (A) and

(B) rep

ort coe

fficien

ts of regressing cyclicality

coe

fficien

ts in

colum

ns (1

) and (3) o

n column‐varia

ble values across b

asic classes.

13

Page 14: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.7 Regional regressions

Table A.6 shows the results of panel regressions with region fixed effects, in which the depen-

dent variable is the fraction of sales flag for a given region and month. The first regression

yields results very much in line with the benchmark regressions from the main text. The

conclusions are little changed once we include a time trend. However, when we include

time fixed effects, the unemployment rate becomes non-significant, in line with the Coibion,

Gorodnichenko, and Hong (2015) who find little evidence of a relationship between sales and

unemployment in the cross-section.

Table A.6: Panel regressions with regional unemployment rate, United Kingdom

(1) (2) (3)

urt - Regional 0.300*** 0.258*** 0.017

Calendar month dummies Y N N

Linear time trend N Y N

Time fixed effects N N Y

R2 0.34 0.47 0.77

Notes: Panel regressions with region fixed effects. CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics,sample period is from February 1996 to September 2013. Each observation is a region/month. Thedependent variable is the fraction of sales flag in a given region/month. urt is the unemployment rate inregion r at time t. *** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level based on robust standard errors.

Finally, Table A.7 reports the coefficients from region-specific regressions of the frequency

of sales on the monthly regional unemployment rate and a time trend. The largest semi-

elasticities are recorded for Scotland and East Anglia, and the lowest for London, North and

Yorks & Humber. One can also notice that there is very little variation in the unconditional

frequency of sales across regions, at around 2.5%. The only exception is London, where the

frequency is somewhat lower at 1.9%.

14

Page 15: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Table A.7: Region-specific regressions, United Kingdom

ScotlandEast East South

WalesWest

Anglia Midlands West Midlands

urt 0.415(0.042)

0.415(0.074)

0.397(0.059)

0.369(0.050)

0.366(0.047)

0.316(0.055)

R2 0.56 0.35 0.56 0.44 0.56 0.45

Sales2.4% 2.4% 2.3% 2.5% 2.6% 2.4%

freq.

South NorthLondon North

Yorks &

East West Humber

urt 0.307(0.060)

0.306(0.045)

0.219(0.024)

0.211(0.032)

0.193(0.031)

R2 0.46 0.55 0.45 0.46 0.62

Sales2.4% 2.4% 1.9% 2.5% 2.4%

freq.

Notes: Linear regressions of the frequency of sales on the regional unemployment rate (urt) and a time trend,ran separately for each region. CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics, sample period is fromFebruary 1996 to September 2013. Newey-West standard errors allowing for a maximum autocorrelation of 4lags are indicated in parentheses.

A.8 Clearance sales

As evidenced from Figure A.2, temporary sales tend to be more prevalent toward the end of the

price quote line, an indication that clearance sales are an important part of retailers’ pricing

strategies in the U.K. To construct these plots, we computed the probability of observing a sale

N months before the end of a quote line.7 Aggregating across all products, this probability

is almost 8% in the last month of a typical quote line, compared to 3.5% three years earlier.

There are wide differences in this pattern across product categories, however. For Clothing

and Footwear, 22% of the observations in the last month are flagged as sales by the ONS,

compared to a frequency of around 8% one year earlier, while the same numbers are 26% and

14% respectively for Audio and Video. Food products, on the other hand, display a very flat

hazard function with no evidence of clearance sales. We also find that the average size of

discounts tends to increase as the end of a quote line approaches.

7A price line can end because the product is replaced by another comparable item at a specific store, becausethe ONS stops collecting its price, or if the store permanently shuts down.

15

Page 16: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Figure A.2: Lifecycle frequency of sales

.03

.04

.05

.06

.07

Pro

babi

lity

0102030Months until end of quote line

All products

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8P

roba

bilit

y

0102030Months until end of quote line

Food products

.08

.1.1

2.1

4.1

6P

roba

bilit

y

0102030Months until end of quote line

Clothing & Footwear

.1.1

5.2

.25

Pro

babi

lity

0102030Months until end of quote line

Audio & Video

Notes: Notes: Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Probability ofobserving a sale flag N months before the end of a quote line. CPI quote weights are used.

16

Page 17: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.9 Probit regressions

In addition to the results from the linear probability model of the main text, here we provide

robustness checks using probit regressions instead. Estimation results are summarized in the

top panel of Table A.8, while the bottom panel shows the predicted sales frequencies at various

unemployment rate levels.

Table A.8: Probit regressions at the product level, United Kingdom

(1) (2) (3)

ut 5.89*** 6.839*** 5.922***

Calendar month dummies Y Y N

Categories dummies N Y Y

Region dummies N Y Y

Linear time trend N N Y

Predicted sales frequencies

ut = 0.04 0.025 0.025 0.026

ut = 0.06 0.033 0.033 0.033

ut = 0.08 0.043 0.043 0.042

ut = 0.10 0.054 0.055 0.052

Notes: Probit regressions. CPI data are from the U.K. Office for National Statistics, sample period is fromFebruary 1996 to September 2013. *** indicate statistical significance at the 1% level.

17

Page 18: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

A.10 Retailer type

First, we plot in Figure A.3 the incidence of sales for independent stores and chains, against

the unemployment rate. The UK ONS calls “Independent retailers” those have less than 10

outlets, while “Chains” (or “Multiples”) must have at least 10 outlets. It is clear that sales

are much more prevalent at chains. There is also evidence that they may be more cyclical,

though this depends on the filter used.

Figure A.3: Lifecycle frequency of sales

.03

.04

.05

.06

.07

.08

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

otte

d)

.005

.015

.025

.035

.045

.055

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id a

nd d

ashe

d)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

2013

V−shaped

.03

.04

.05

.06

.07

.08

Une

mp.

rat

e (d

otte

d)

.005

.015

.025

.035

.045

.055

Sal

es fr

eque

ncy

(sol

id a

nd d

ashe

d)

19971999

20012003

20052007

20092011

2013

Sales flag

Multiples Independents Unemp. rate

Notes: Sample period is 1996:02–2013:09. U.K. Office for National Statistics data. Probability of observing asale flag N months before the end of a quote line. CPI quote weights are used.

18

Page 19: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

B Model Appendix

To understand the dynamics of temporary sales and their importance for aggregate fluctua-

tions, we build a general equilibrium business cycle model in which discounts arise endoge-

nously. In order to simplify the exposition, in the main text we lay out a static shopping-time

problem and other key non-standard features of the model. This appendix provides the other

elements of our framework: the complete description of the household’s dynamics optimization

problem, organization of production, the market clearing conditions, a sufficient condition for

the existence of two-price locally unique equilibrium, the full system of equilibrium conditions,

steady state properties, derivations of the key elasticities, and the results of model robustness

exercises.

B.1 Household’s dynamic optimization problem

In each period, the household consumes, works, shops, and trades money, state-contingent

securities, and nominal bonds. Household utility is separable in consumption and leisure.

The aggregate consumption bundle in period t, ct, consists of differentiated varieties of

perishable consumption goods, indexed by j, combined according to a CES aggregator,

ct =

∑j c

1− 1θ

jt

θθ−1

, where θ is the elasticity of substitution across good varieties. House-

holds have access to a shopping technology that converts time into additional consumption.

The total cost of using this technology in period t is Ξt units of time. Let At+1 denote a vec-

tor of Arrow-Debreu securities paying one dollar in t+1, Qt+1|t is the vector of corresponding

prices, Bt denote holdings of nominal bonds paying the household a gross return Rt in period

t+ 1, and let Mt denote money holdings at the beginning of period t.

Households supply working hours, lut, in a monopolistically competitive labor market,

comprised of unions supplying differentiated labor services indexed by u. These varieties

aggregate into a final labor service lt, according to lt =

∑u l

1− 1ϑ

ut

ϑϑ−1

, where ϑ is the

elasticity of substitution across labor varieties. Each union sets wages Wut for its services,

and accordingly faces the following demand: lut =(WutWt

)−ϑlt, where Wt is aggregate wage,

Wt =∑

uW1−ϑut

11−ϑ

.

We assume unions set wages according to Taylor contracts, with wages fixed for Nw

periods. Contracts are perfectly staggered across unions, i.e., in every period, a fraction 1/Nw

of unions reset their wages. Initial bond holdings of unions are such that each union has the

same present discounted value of income. Although unions set different wages and supply

different amounts of labor services, the availability of a complete set of securities and the

separability between consumption and leisure imply that unions make identical consumption,

savings and shopping decisions in equilibrium. We therefore drop the union-specific index

19

Page 20: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

hereafter. A similar setup is implemented in Kryvtsov and Midrigan (2013).

At the end of the period, households combine unspent money holdings from the previous

period with labor income, payments on securities, return on bonds, dividends, and transfers,

and split them into cash and bond holdings to be carried over to the next period.

For their household members, unions choose the sequences of total consumption ct, hours

worked lt, cash holdings, Mt, security holdings At+1, and bond holdings Bt to maximize

lifetime expected utility:

E0

∑t

βt [u (ct)− v (lt)] ,

subject to the budget constraint

Mt +Bt +∑

t+1|tQt+1|tAt+1 ≤ Mt−1 − Ptct +Wt [lt − Ξt] +Rt−1Bt−1 +At + Πt + Tt ,

and a cash-in-advance constraint

Ptct ≤Mt , (1)

where Pt is the price of consumption bundle ct, Wt is a wage, Πt are dividends paid, Tt are

lump-sum government transfers.

The optimality conditions are standard: the first-order condition for hours worked implies

v′ (lt)

u′ (ct)=Wt

Pt, (2)

while the first-order conditions for Arrow-Debreu securities and nominal bonds yield

1 = βRtEt

(u′ (ct+1)

u′ (ct)

PtPt+1

),

where Et(·) denotes the expected value with respect to information available through period

t.

We assume that the supply of money M st follows a random-walk process of the form

lnM st = lnM s

t−1 + µt ,

where µt is log money growth, a normally distributed i.i.d. random variable with mean 0 and

standard deviation σµ.

20

Page 21: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

B.2 Intermediate input producers

A continuum of competitive intermediate good firms own and invest in capital kt, hire labor

nt and produce a homogeneous good Yt using a Cobb-Douglas technology

Yt = atn1−χt kχt , (3)

where at denotes total factor productivity in period t. The homogeneous good is sold at the

competitive price Ωt to other intermediate good firms to augment their capital stock, and to

retail firms to produce consumption varieties. The intermediate good producer solves

maxYt,xt,nt

E0

∞∑t=0

βtu′ (ct)

Pt· [ΩtYt − Ωt (xt + φt)−Wtnt]

,

subject to the law of motion of the capital stock

kt+1 = (1− δ) kt + xt ,

and the technology constraint (3). Parameter δ denotes the depreciation rate of the capital

stock, and φt is the convex cost of adjusting capital:

φt =φ

2

(kt+1

kt− 1

)2

kt .

The first-order conditions yield the expression for the price of the intermediate input:

Ωt = (1− χ)−(1−χ)χ−χa−1t W 1−χ

t

(Rkt

)χ,

where Rkt denotes the return on capital, Rkt = χΩtYtkt

.

B.3 Retailers

Each retail firm selling brands of variety j is endowed with a linear production technology

that converts the homogeneous intermediate input Yjt into output of brands of variety j, yjt:

yjt = Yjt . (4)

This technology implies that the retailer’s marginal cost of production is equal to the price of

the intermediate input, Ωt.

Denote by Πkjt =

(P kjt − Ωt

)ckjt the period-t retailer’s profit function from selling con-

sumption goods at price P kjt, k = L,H, and Nkjt be the measure of transactions at price P kjt:

NLjt = γjt

(αRjt + αjtf

), NH

jt = (1− γjt)αRjt + αjt (1− fγjt). The problem of the retail store

21

Page 22: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

selling variety j is to choose the sequences of its two consumption price points PHjt and PLjt;

the fraction of price discounts γjt; the fraction of bargain hunters visiting its location, αBjt;

intermediate inputs Yjt; and output levels yjt to maximize the present discounted value of its

profits until it can reset prices again:

maxyjt,Pkjτ ,γjτ ,α

Bjτ

Et

t+NP−1∑τ=t

βt−τ

u′ (ct)

Pτ·[NLjτΠL

jτ +NHjτΠH

jτ − κWτγjτ]

, (5)

subject to the supply constraint

yjt ≤ NLjtc

Ljt +NH

jt cHjt ,

and the demand constraints for ckjt (6, main text), the technology constraint (19), the equation

for the probability of bargain hunting (7, main text), the constraint for the number of bargain

hunters in the retailer’s location (8, main text), and Taylor price adjustment constraints, with

NP denoting the duration of regular price contracts.

B.4 Equilibrium

In each period the timing of events is as follows (see model diagram in Figure 10, main text).

First, the aggregate money and TFP shocks are realized, the household head deposits all of

its cash in the checking account, retail firms post their prices and send their price menus to

households. Next, the household head observes for each variety the overall distribution of

prices across locations and the specific prices for only one random retailer; she then chooses

the shopping types, consumption plans, and pays search costs. She also provides debit cards

to shoppers and sends them off to shop. All shoppers are matched with locations, retail firms,

and consumption brands; they bring the purchased consumption goods back to the household.

At some point during the period the household also earns labour income, which cannot be used

for consumption spending in the same period.8 At the end of the period, households combine

unspent money holdings with labor income, return on bonds, dividends, and transfers, and

split them into cash and bond holdings to be carried over to the next period.

The market clearing condition for labor implies that total hours supplied by unions in the

labor market are equal to the total hours demanded by firms:∑u

lut = nt + κ∑j

γjt .

8It is not material how exactly household earns labour income. For example, we could assume that shopperswork during the day, and after the workday they shop using debit cards to pay for consumption. Standardcash-in-advance models typically assume a dedicated type of household members distinct from shoppers whoare responsible for working and earning income.

22

Page 23: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

The equilibrium search flow condition states that the total number of shoppers for each

variety j is equal to 1 in each location:

αBjt + αRjt = 1 .

In the symmetric equilibrium, each location receives the same measure of bargain hunters

for each variety, i.e.,

αBjt = αjt ,

where αjt is the probability of bargain hunting that each household assigns to a shopper j.

The market clearing condition for each good variety j states that the total consumption

is equal to the total amount produced:

NLjtc

Ljt +NH

jt cHjt = yjt .

The market clearing for intermediate goods:

xt +∑j

Yjt = Yt .

Finally, capital, money, bond and security markets also clear. A symmetric equilibrium

for this economy is a collection of allocations and prices that satisfy household and firm

maximization, as well as market clearing conditions. Below we provide the full system of

equilibrium conditions in the model with sticky prices, and derive a sufficient condition for

the existence of two-price locally unique equilibrium.

B.5 Full system of equilibrium equations

This section contains the full system of equilibrium conditions in the model with sticky prices.

The model is solved by applying the Blanchard and Kahn (1980) local solution method to

the log-linearized system of stochastic equilibrium equations around the deterministic steady

state. The code and other replication materials are available upon request. Period utility is

u(c)− v(l) = c1−σ

1−σ − ψl1+1/η

1+1/η .

Denote the following auxiliary variables:

ΠLjt =

(PLjt − Ωt

)(PLjtPt

)−θct, ΠH

jt =(PHjt − Ωt

)(PHjtPt

)−θct ,

ΠRjt = γjtΠ

Ljt + (1− γjt)ΠH

jt , ΠBjt = fγjtΠ

Ljt + (1− fγjt) ΠH

jt ,

NHjt = (1− γjt)αRjt + αjt (1− fγjt) , NL

jt = γjt(αRjt + αjtf

).

The equilibrium consists of 8NP +NW + 12 equations for 8NP +NW + 12 variables PLjt,

23

Page 24: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

PHjt , cLjt, cHjt , γjt, α

Rjt, αjt, z

∗jt, n,t,k,t,x,t, Yt,Pt, ct, lt, Ωt,Wt, Wjt,W

dt , Rkt , Rt including:

- equation for Ωt

Ωt = (1− χ)−(1−χ)χ−χa−1t W 1−χ

t

(Rkt

)χ,

- 2NP equations for ckt,0, ..., ckt,N−1, k = L,H,

ckjt ,=

(P kjtPt

)−θct ,

- cost-minimization condition for nt

1− χχ

ktnt

=Wt

Rkt,

- equation for aggregate wage Wt

Wt =

∑u

(Wu,t)1−ϑ

11−ϑ

,

- equation for “dual” aggregate wage W dt

W dt =

∑u

(Wu,t)−ϑ

1−ϑ

,

- equation for PHt,0

PHt,0 =θ

θ − 1

Et∑t+NP−1

τ=t βτ c1−στ P θ−1

τ ·NHτ,τ−tΩτ

Et∑t+NP−1

τ=t βτ c1−στ P θ−1

τ ·NHτ,τ−t

(1 + ∆H

τ,τ−t) ,

- NP − 1 equations for PHt,1, ..., PHt,N−1

PHt,0 = PHt+1,1 = ... = PHt+NP−1,NP−1 ,

- NP equations for PLt,0, ..., PLt,N−1

PLjt =θ

θ − 1

1

1 + ∆Ljt

Ωt , (6)

where

∆Hjt = − ∂αjt

∂ lnPHjt

ΠBjt

(θ − 1)NHjt P

Hjt c

Hjt

=1− fγjtWtΞ′′ (αjt)

·ΠBjt

(θ − 1)NHjt

, (7)

24

Page 25: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

∆Ljt = − ∂αjt

∂ lnPLjt

ΠBjt

(θ − 1)NLjtP

Ljtc

Ljt

=fγjt

WtΞ′′ (αjt)

ΠBjt

(θ − 1)NLjt

, (8)

- NP equations for the shopping time of the marginal shopper z∗jt

Wtz∗jt =

(f − 1) γjtθ − 1

(PLjtc

Ljt − PHjt cHjt

), (9)

- NP equations for the fraction of bargain hunters αjt

z∗jt = Ξ′ (αjt) ,

- NP equations for the fraction of low prices γjt

(αRjt + fαjt

) [ΠHjt −ΠL

jt

]+ κWt =

∂αjt∂ γ∗jt

·ΠBjt , (10)

where

∂αjt∂ γ∗jt

=f

WtΞ′′ (αjt)

(PLjtc

Ljt − PHjt cHjt

)(11)

- NP equations for the fraction of random shoppers of variety j

αRjt = 1− αjt ,

- equation for the price of aggregate consumption Pt

Pt =

1NP

∑NP−1j=0

[NLjt

(PLjt

)1−θ+NH

jt

(PHjt

)1−θ] 1

1−θ,

- cash-in-advance constraint

Mt = Ptct ,

- equation for Wt,0

W1+ϑ/ηt,0 = ψ

ϑ

ϑ− 1

Et∑t+NW−1

τ=t βτ(W ϑτ lτ)1+1/η

Et∑t+NW−1

τ=t βτ (W ϑτ lτ ) c−στ P−1

τ

,

- NW − 1 equations for Wt,1, ..., Wt,NW−1

Wt,0 = Wt+1,1 = ... = Wt+NW−1,NW−1 ,

25

Page 26: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

- aggregate resource constraint

xt +φ

2

(kt+1

kt− 1

)2

kt +∑j

(NLjtc

Ljt +NH

jt cHjt

)= Yt ,

- labor market clearing,

nt + κ∑j

γjt =

(W dt

Wt

)−ϑlt ,

- law of motion for capital stock kt+1

kt+1 = (1− δ) kt + xt ,

- optimality condition for capital stock kt+1

1+φ

(kt+1

kt− 1

)= βEt

(ct+1

ct

)−σ PtPt+1

Ωt+1

Ωt

(Rkt+1

Ωt+1+ 1− δ + φ

(kt+2

kt+1− 1

)+φ

2

(kt+2

kt+1− 1

)2)

- return on capital, Rkt

Rkt = χΩtYtkt,

- equation for the risk-free rate

R−1t = βEt

(c−σt+1Pt

c−σt Pt+1

),

- and an exogenous AR(1) process (in logs) for money growth µt = MtMt−1

:

lnµt+1 = (1− ρµ) lnµ+ ρµ lnµt + εµt ,

where i.i.d. innovations εµt drawn from N(0, σ2

µ

).

TFP process at follows a zero-mean exogenous AR(1) process (in logs) :

ln at+1 = ρµ ln at + εat ,

where i.i.d. innovations εat drawn from N(0, σ2

a

).

Approximation of the cost function.

We approximate the cost function z∗jt = Ξ′ (αjt) around the steady state up to second

order:

ξ ln

(z∗jtz∗j

)= αjt − αj , (12)

26

Page 27: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

where ξ =z∗j

Ξ′′(αj).

B.6 Price dispersion

There exists a locally unique equilibrium with price dispersion in this model. In this section,

we derive a sufficient condition for the existence of two-price equilibria, expressed in terms of

the expected fixed cost Ξ (α), the probability parameter f , the cost of posting sales κ, and the

demand elasticity θ. A retailer prefers to post two different prices, instead of a single price for

all its brands when the expected returns to retailer from posting an extra fraction of brands

on sale outweighs the opportunity cost of maintaining high average profit margin. That is

the case when the return on searching is high, the cost of posting sales is low, and demand

is sufficiently inelastic. When the sufficient condition is satisfied, there are always varieties

for which the search cost realizations are low-enough so that households choose the shoppers

responsible for that variety to be bargain hunters. In turn, the presence of bargain hunters

validates the retailers’ incentives to post sales. We also show that there is no single-price

equilibrium when the sufficient condition is satisfied.

Consider the case with fully flexible prices; omit indexes for variety and time. Denote

by Π (p) = (p− Ω)(pPt

)−θct the retailer’s current-period profit function at price p, and by

Rt (p) = p( pP

)−θc the current-period revenue function at p. The retailer’s expected profit

and revenue from selling to regular shoppers in period t are

ΠR = γΠ(PL)

+ (1− γ)Π(PH),

RR = γR(PL)

+ (1− γ)R(PH).

Similarly, the retailer’s expected profit and revenue from selling brands to bargain hunters,

ΠB and RB, are the same as above with γ replaced by fγ.

To gain intuition for why it is optimal for retailers to post different prices, consider the

effect of the search constraint (7, main text) on the retailer’s pricing behavior. If this con-

straint were not binding, the retailer would optimally choose—due to concavity of the profit

function—to charge the monopoly price for all its brands, PL = PH = P ∗ ≡ θθ−1Ω, and

collect monopoly profits Π∗ = Π (P ∗).

In contrast, when the retailer can attract bargain hunters, it chooses the number of bargain

hunters, facing constraints (7) and (8) in the main text. In this case, posting a single price

for all of its brands is no longer optimal. Consider a small price perturbation for a retailer

that, instead of posting a single monopoly price P ∗ for all its brands, posts an arbitrarily

lower price PL < P ∗ for a small fraction of brands dγ, attracting a small number of bargain

hunters, dα, and taking the number of random shoppers as given, αR / 1. The variation of

the retail firm’s profit relative to monopolistic profit δΠ∗ ≡ Π−Π∗ is, up to the first order of

27

Page 28: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

magnitude, given by

δΠ∗ ≈ Π∗dα+ dγ[Π(PL)−Π (P ∗)− κW

]. (13)

The first term on the right-hand side is the gain in profits due to sales to the extra fraction

dα of bargain hunters. The second term is the loss in profits due to sales of the fraction dγ

of brands at a lower price PL and the total fixed cost of posting sale prices. From the search

constraint (7, main text), we can express dα, up to the first order of magnitude, as

dα ≈ (f − 1) dγ ·1θ−1

(R(PL)−R (P ∗)

)WΞ′′ (0)

. (14)

For a household, the increase in the probability of becoming a bargain hunter, dα, is pro-

portional to the increase in the probability of finding a low price (in known location versus

random location), (f − 1) dγ, and the ratio of the marginal utility of switching consumption

from high to low price, 1θ−1

(R(PL)−R (P ∗)

), to the marginal cost of becoming a bargain

hunter, WΞ′′ (0).

Plugging (14) into the expression (13) for profit variation, we obtain

δΠ∗ ≈ dγ ·Π∗[−Π (P ∗)−Π

(PL)

+ κW

Π∗+

(f − 1)

θ − 1

R(PL)−R (P ∗)

WΞ′′ (0)

].

If the expression in brackets is positive, i.e., if

(f − 1) ·1θ−1

(R(PL)−R (P ∗)

)WΞ′′ (0)

>Π (P ∗)−Π

(PL)

+ κW

Π∗,

then the benefits stemming from the increase in the market share of the retailer from selling

to bargain hunters outweighs the cost of a smaller profit margin from selling at lower prices,

and so the retailer can improve upon single-price monopolistic profit by posting two prices.

Also note that as γ → 0, PH → P ∗ and PL → 1

1+ fθ−1

Π∗WΞ′′(0)

P ∗ < P ∗; i.e., price dispersion

does not disappear as the fraction of sale prices goes to zero. This means that there is no

equilibrium with a single price. The reason why firms find it optimal to deviate from having

a single price for all brands is that for any small but positive measure of brands on sale, the

return for the household becoming a bargain hunter is strictly positive. So if the marginal

expected fixed cost of becoming a bargain hunter is not growing too quickly with the fraction

of bargain hunters (e.g., if Ξ′′ (0) is low enough), then there will always be households with

low-enough fixed cost realizations who choose to become bargain hunters, justifying price

dispersion by retailers.

28

Page 29: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

B.7 Steady-state properties

Fraction of discounts. The desirable number of discount prices for a retailer is determined

by the retailer’s first-order condition with respect to the fraction of brands on sale, γ∗jt :

∂NLjt

∂γ∗jt

(ΠHjt −ΠL

jt

)+ κWt =

∂(NHjt +NL

jt

)∂γ∗jt

ΠHjt . (15)

Condition (15) equates the cost of increasing the fraction of sales (left-hand side) with the

return from extra sales (right-hand side). The cost stems from an increased share of trans-

actions at discounted prices and the additional cost of posting price discounts. The return

comes from the gain in market share,∂(NH

jt+NLjt)

∂γ∗jt, which is proportional to γ∗−1

jt and the rate

of increase in shopping cost, ξ. Panel A in Figure B.1 visualizes the trade-off between the

cost and the return from extra discounts as functions of their fraction in all prices. The cost

is increasing as the fraction of discounts raises the share of transactions at discounted prices.

The return decreases as extra sales bring a diminishing number of additional bargain hunters.

Price decisions. In the flexible-price case, the first order condition for P kjt, k = L, His

∂Πkjt

∂P kjt= −

∂(NHjt +NL

jt

)Nkjt∂P

kjt

(fγ∗jtΠ

Ljt + (1− fγ∗jt)ΠH

jt

). (16)

The left-hand side is the marginal profit as a function of P kjt, keeping market share constant.

If bargain hunters are insensitive to discounts, the firm sets this term to zero by setting both

prices at the optimal monopoly price. If bargain hunters are sensitive to prices, the firm can

boost the demand for its product by setting two different prices, both below the monopoly

price. The term on the right-hand side of (16) captures profits from additional market share.

The optimal pricing decisions for the flexible-price case are visualized in Panel B, Figure B.1.

Shopping time. Bargain hunting entails additional shopping time between zero and z∗.

In equilibrium, the maximal shopping time is equated to the ratio of returns on shopping

∆x and the cost of time W/P to determine the fraction of bargain hunters αB, see Panel

C in Figure B.1. Higher returns or lower opportunity cost of time will push the cut-off for

shopping, leading to an increase in bargain hunters.

29

Page 30: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Figure B.1: Household and firm decisions, steady state

B.8 Elasticities

In the model, the household’s additional shopping time is equal to∫z<z∗t

zdG(z) units of time,

where z is drawn from distribution with c.d.f. G(z). z∗t denotes the maximal shopping time

30

Page 31: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

by a bargain hunter. Small variations of total shopping time St around its steady state S are:

Sd lnSt ≈ z∗ (G(z∗t )−G(z∗))

i.e., the additional shopping time stems from changes in the mass of bargain hunters around

the steady state. Given our definitions, G(z∗t ) = αt ≈ α+ ξd ln (z∗t ), we obtain

Sd lnSt ≈ z∗ξ · d ln z∗t (17)

The log-linearized first-order condition (7, main text) for the household’s shopping time im-

plies:

d ln z∗t ≈ d (ln ∆xt)− d ln (Wt/Pt) (18)

Together, (17)–(18) imply that the elasticity of shopping time to the price of time is −ξ z∗S .

Our baseline parameterization implies that the average shopping time S corresponds to 4

hours per week and the average working time L is 37.1 hours per week, yielding z∗ to be 3.1

hours per week. This gives an elasticity of log shopping time with respect to log wages of

–0.14. Aguiar and Hurst (2007) estimate this elasticity in the ATUS sample to be roughly

–0.12.

Aguiar and Hurst (2007) also find that doubling the frequency of shopping trips lowers

the price of consumption by 7 to 10%. In the model, the household’s variation in total price

savings around the steady state is αd (∆xt). Noting that d (∆xt) = ∆x · d (ln ∆xt), (17)–(18)

imply that the elasticity of price to household’s shopping time is −αP∆x

ξ z∗

S

. For the baseline

model, this yields an elasticity of –11.9%.

B.9 Model Robustness

Table B.1 provides the results for alternative versions of the model.

B.9.1 Convex adjustment cost for discounts and shopping time

In the main text, we use counterfactual exercises in which we shut down adjustments of

discounts or shopping time by imposing prohibitively large convex adjustment costs. These

costs are introduced as follows.

Convex cost of adjusting the number of discounts. In the problem of the retailer,

the cost of posting discounts is replaced with: κWt

(γjt +

εγ2 (γjt − γ)2

). Equilibrium condi-

tion (10) is replaced with

(αRjt + fαjt

) [ΠHjt −ΠL

jt

]+ κWt(1 + εγ (γjt − γj)) =

∂αjt∂ γ∗jt

·ΠBjt .

31

Page 32: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Convex cost of adjusting the size of discounts. Add adjustment cost term in the

decision of adjusting the discount price: εδ2

(PLjt/P

Hjt − PL/PH

)2. Equilibrium condition (6)

is replaced with

PLjt =θ

θ − 1

Ωt

1 + ∆Ljt

· exp(εδ(PLjt/P

Hjt − PL/PH

)).

Convex cost of adjusting shopping time. In specification (12), we add quadratic

term:

ξ ln

(z∗jtz∗j

)= (αjt − αj) +

1

2εα (αjt − αj)2 ,

where ξ =z∗j

Ξ′′(αj)and εα =

Ξ′′′(αj)Ξ′′(αj)

.

B.9.2 Price of shopping time

In the main text, the price of shopping time is given by the market wage Wt in front of the

shopping cost∑

j Ξ(αjt) in the household’s expenditure minimization problem (5, main text).

In Section 6, we conduct simulations in models with alternative measures of the price of time.

We consider a plausible alternative, whereby the household head bases her decision of shopper

type on the cost of supplying time, measured by the marginal rate of substitution between

consumption and hours worked, σct + η−1lt. For this version of the model, we replace Wt

with σct + η−1lt, in equilibrium conditions (7)–(9), (11).

We also considered an alternative version of the model where we replace Wt with the

non-sticky real wages of new hires, Wt,0. The results were quantitatively in-between what we

obtained with the two other specifications.

B.9.3 Model with materials as intermediate input in retail production

To asses the effect of strategic pricing complementarities on the retailer’s pricing decisions, we

introduce materials as another intermediate input of production in the retail firm’s technology:

yjt = Y 1−χmjt mχm

jt , (19)

where mjt denotes the quantity of composite material input demanded by firm j.

The brands of variety j are sold to shoppers for consumption or to other retailers as

materials in production. Retail firm j buys brands from other retailers j′ at price PMj′t , and

combines them into a composite material input via CES technology:

mjt =

∑j

[(mj,j′,t

)1− 1θ

]θθ−1

,

32

Page 33: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

where mj,j′,t denote intermediate inputs that the firm j acquires from other retailers, j′.

Cost minimization by retailers implies:

- the demand by firm j of materials from firm j′, mj,j′,t is

mj,j′,t =

(PMj′,t

PMt

)−θmjt ,

- the price of intermediate input composite is PMt =∑

j

(PMjt

)1−θ 1

1−θ,

- the demand for composite input according to

1− χmχm

mjt

Yjt=

Ωt

PMt,

- and the modified expression for retailer’s marginal cost

ΩRt = (1− χm)−(1−χm)χ−χmm Ω1−χm

t

(PMt

)χm.

We assume that prices of material inputs are also subject to Taylor-type adjustment con-

straints, and assume that they are reset at the same time as regular prices for consumption

brands. The roundabout production structure and pricing constraints for the price of mate-

rials create strategic pricing complementarities in the retailer’s pricing decisions (Basu, 1995,

Nakamura and Steinsson, 2010).

Denoting total demand for materials by Mt =∑

jmjt, we obtain the following optimal

pricing conditions

- equation for PMt,0

PMt,0 =θ

θ − 1

Et∑t+NP−1

τ=t βτ(P−1τ c−στ

) (PMτ

)θMτ · Ωτ

Et∑t+NP−1

τ=t βτ(P−1τ c−στ

)(PMτ )θMτ

,

- NP − 1 equations for PMt,1 , ..., PMt,NP−1

PMt,0 = PMt+1,1 = ... = PMt+NP−1,NP−1 .

Finally, the modified resource constraint for variety j is

NLjtc

Ljt +NH

jt cHjt +

∑j′

mj′,j,t = Y 1−χmjt mχm

jt .

33

Page 34: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

Tab

leB

.1:

Rob

ust

nes

sof

mod

elp

red

icti

ons

Shop

ping

cos

t: O

ppor

tuni

ty

cost

of t

ime

Shop

ping

co

st: W

ages

of

new

hir

es

Stic

ky s

ales

pr

ices

, N

P=12

Pers

iste

nt

mon

etar

y sh

ock,

=0

.6

Low

er re

venu

e sh

are

from

sa

les,

2.0

Low

er a

vg

retu

rn o

n sh

oppi

ng, 2

%

Hig

her a

vg

retu

rn o

n sh

oppi

ng, 8

%

Mat

eria

ls in

pr

oduc

tion,

m

=0.7

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

std( t

)/st

d(C

t)0.

27

0.24

0.38

0.33

0.32

0.43

0.32

0.34

0.24

0.10

std( t

)/st

d(L t

)0.

140.

200.

350.

280.

260.

240.

260.

290.

200.

09

corr

(t ,

Ct)

–0.6

4–0

.53

–0.5

5–0

.55

–0.5

5–0

.63

-0.5

5–0

.60

-0.5

1–0

.39

corr

(t ,

Lt)

–0.4

4 –0

.35

–0.5

2–0

.42

–0.3

7–0

.73

-0.3

7–0

.31

-0.3

7–0

.30

No

disc

ount

s–0

.48

–0.4

8–0

.48

–0.4

8–0

.89

–0.4

8–0

.48

–0.4

8–0

.60

Con

stan

t di

scou

nts

–0.4

8–0

.41

–0.4

7–0

.48

–0.8

9–0

.48

–0.4

9–0

.49

–0.6

4

Cyc

lical

dis

coun

ts–0

.29

–0.2

3–0

.30

–0.3

1–0

.60

–0.3

1–0

.28

-0.3

0–0

.55

% d

iffer

ence

39.7

44.4

35.6

34.9

32.4

34.0

42.3

39.8

14.1

U.S

. Dat

a

B. A

vera

ge re

spon

se to

a –

1% im

puls

e to

mon

ey s

uppl

y

A. T

ime-

seri

es s

tati

stic

s

Base

line

Mod

el ro

bust

ness

Note

s:T

he

table

pro

vid

esre

sult

sof

sim

ula

tions

of

alt

ernati

ve

ver

sions

of

the

model

inth

em

ain

text.

Alt

ernati

ve

ver

sions

dis

cuss

edin

Sec

tions

6.3

–6.4

of

the

main

text,

and

Sec

tion

B.9

inA

pp

endix

.P

anel

Apro

vid

esti

me-

seri

esst

ati

stic

sfo

rth

eU

.S.

data

and

the

model

.P

anel

Bpro

vid

esav

erage

consu

mpti

on

resp

onse

sto

a–1%

impuls

eto

money

supply

over

the

firs

t12

month

saft

erth

esh

ock

.C

olu

mn

(1):

U.S

.data

,(2

):B

ase

line

model

,(3

),(4

):th

epri

ceof

tim

eis

giv

enby

the

opp

ort

unit

yco

stof

tim

eor

by

wages

of

new

hir

es(S

ecti

on

B.9

.2),

(5):

dis

count

pri

cePL t

issu

bje

ctto

the

sam

epri

ceco

nst

rain

tsas

regula

rpri

cePH t

,(6

):se

rially

corr

elate

dm

oney

gro

wth

,(7

):L

ower

calibra

tion

targ

etfo

rth

ere

ven

ue

share

from

sale

sto

2.0

,kee

pin

goth

erta

rget

sth

esa

me,

(8),

(9):

change

calibra

tion

targ

etfo

rpri

cesa

vin

gs

by

barg

ain

hunte

rsto

2%

or

8%

,kee

pin

goth

erta

rget

sth

esa

me,

(10):

intr

oduce

mate

rial

inputs

inre

tail

pro

duct

ion

(Sec

tion

B.9

.3).

34

Page 35: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

C Measuring the impact of discounts on the aggregate price

level

In our model, the flexibility of the aggregate price response is due to the increase in the fraction

of sale prices and a shift of consumption weights toward discounted items. Because the shift

in consumption weights is generally not observed by statistical agencies, fluctuations in sale

prices may have important implications for aggregate price measurement. In this section, we

explore empirical importance of this margin.

The advantage of using a model-based approach to measure the importance of sales lies

in the explicit specification of the mechanisms that can account for their cyclicality. We

argued in the main text that these mechanisms are realistic and can be corroborated by the

evidence on retailers’ discounting and households’ search behaviour. Nonetheless, some of

the simplifying assumptions in the model may be material for the quantitative importance of

sales. For example, our analysis assumes symmetry across consumption sectors; homogeneity

of price discounts in the data, both in terms of frequency and size, and that nominal demand

shocks are the main drivers of business cycles. While the model can be extended along these

dimensions, we undertake a complementary approach based on available micro price data.

Specifically, we quantify empirically the wedge between the standard (CPI) aggregate price

index and the effective price index, assuming that the shift in consumption expenditures

toward discounted items is based on the constant-elasticity-of-substitution demand system.

Unlike the model-based approach, this empirical exercise takes the observed dynamics of price

discounts as given and measures the impact of shutting down those dynamics, keeping all else

equal. We focus on the main idea and results here, leaving the details available upon request.

First, express any posted (log) price of an item i in month t, pi,t , as the sum of the regular

(log) price, pRi,t, and a (log) discount in the event of a sale, ∆i,t:

pi,t = pRi,t + ∆i,t , (20)

By definition, ∆i,t < 0 if there is a sale in month t, and ∆i,t ≡ 0 if there is no sale. This

decomposition allows us to express the aggregate price index as the sum of the regular price

index, pRt , and an aggregate discount term, ∆t:

pt =∑i

ωi,tpRi,t +

∑i

ωi,th∆i,t∆i,t

= pRt + ∆t , (21)

where ωi,t are the usual CPI item weights while h∆i,t are additional weights for items on sale.

To construct the official CPI, statistical agencies implicitly assume that h∆i,t = 1 for all i and

35

Page 36: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

t: the weight on each quote is the same, irrespective of whether the item is discounted or

regularly-priced. In light of the cyclicality of sales in the data, we study the implications of

relaxing this assumption and allowing h∆i,t to be above 1 and vary over time.

Ideally, one would estimate the h∆i,t factors using data on both prices and quantities. Such

data, however, are not available for a broad spectrum of products. Therefore, we opt for a

simple alternative: we use the weights implied by a constant-elasticity-of-substitution demand

system, similar to the one in our model. With an elasticity of substitution θ, the additional

weight h∆i,t is given by:

h∆i,t =

(exp pi,t

exp pRi,t

)−θ= (exp ∆i,t)

−θ . (22)

For instance, a value of θ = 5 implies that the weight on a 25% discount should be about 4.2

times higher than the weight on a regular price. We also explored a large scanner dataset for

food to show that CES demand with θ = 5 is a good approximation of the average elasticity

of quantities to discount prices across products within a category.9 This estimate is also

in line with other studies. For example, Glandon (2018) reports that for groceries in the

United States, sales account for 17% of price quotes but 40% of revenue, i.e., one percentage

point of price discounts accounts for 2.7 percentage points of revenue share. Assuming a 20%

discount, Glandon’s results imply a discount weight of 4.1. Using IRI data, Chevalier and

Kashyap (2019) found the elasticities for peanut butter to be above 4.5 across metropolitan

markets, and between 2 and 10 for coffee. In sum, the amount of extra consumption generated

by sales is substantial.

The final step is to use weights ωi,t and h∆i,t to construct a measure of the aggregate discount

term ∆t for the United Kingdom. An implicit assumption in this exercise is that the price

elasticity of quantities estimated across products with regular and sales prices is useful for

inferring the elasticity of aggregate price in response to time variation in the number of sales.10

For example, if Coke goes on sale without Pepsi going on sale, then, under this assumption,

the increase in demand for Coke rises by approximately the same amount as in the case when

both Coke and Pepsi go on sale simultaneously. This assumption is reasonable since in the

data the fraction of discounts is not correlated with regular prices or other discounts within

the same category, and the size of discounts is relatively stable. Both of these features are

accounted for in our model, which explicitly expresses the elasticity of the aggregate price with

respect to the fraction of discounts as a function of additional expenditure weights δ−θ(the

counterpart of h∆i,t in equation 21).

In Figure C.1, we compare our constructed series for three values of θ: 0 (equivalent to

9We also explored an alternative approach where, instead of assuming CES demand, we measure weightfactors h∆

i,t directly from the scanner dataset. This approach yields quantitatively similar results.10We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out to us.

36

Page 37: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

the CPI case, with ω∆i,t = 1), 3 and 5. By construction, each series represents a deviation

from the regular price index (pRt ). Time series are provided for the aggregate as well as three

broad categories.

Figure C.1: Contributions of sales to the effective price level in the United Kingdom.

-.06

-.04

-.02

0%

20022004

20062008

20102012

q = 5 q = 3q = 0

All products

-.1

-.08

-.06

-.04

-.02

0%

20022004

20062008

20102012

Food and beverages

-.2

-.15

-.1

-.05

0%

20022004

20062008

20102012

Household furniture and equipment-.

15-.

1-.

050

%

20022004

20062008

20102012

Personal care services

Notes: The time series are the 12-month centered moving averages of the aggregated discount term defined in(22) in Section (C), for various values of the elasticity of substitution θ. All series represent percentagedeviations of the effective price index from its regular-price counterpart. Discount terms are based onV-shaped discounts and aggregated across products using official quote and stratum weights. “ θ = 0 ”corresponds to the official CPI mesure in that it uses equal weights for regular-priced and discounted pricequotes. The sample period is 1996:02–2012:12, U.K. Office of National Statistics data.

First, there are significant differences in the average levels of the discount term across

values of θ and categories. In the aggregate, the effective price level is 0.9% below the regular

price index for θ = 0 (the official CPI case), but 7% lower when θ = 5. With an elasticity

of subsitution of θ = 3, the average contribution of sales ranges from -3% for Food and

Beverages to –6.2% for Household Furniture and Equipment, reflecting mostly differences in

the prevalence of sales across categories.

Without any fluctuations in the frequency or the size of discounts, these contributions

37

Page 38: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

would be stable over time. Figure C.1 makes it clear that they are not. In the aggregate, for

θ = 5, sales contributed to a 3-percentage-point drop in the effective price level in less than

three years, relative to the regular-price index. For Personal care services, the contribution

falls from –5% in 2005 to –17% by 2010. In other words, ignoring sales altogether leads us to

overestimate the effective price inflation of this category by about 2.4 percentage points per

year over this period.11

Comparing those fluctuations to the ones for θ = 0 (i.e. sale and regular quotes get equal

weights) indicates that the official CPI can in some instances significantly underestimate the

role of sales: in this scenario, the range of the discount term ∆t over the sample period is

only about one percentage point for Food and Beverages and Clothing and footwear and 1.8

percentage point for Personal care services. These findings are consistent with Anderson et al.

(2017) who document a small contribution of sales to U.S. inflation measured using BLS micro

price dataset but imposing constant expenditure weights.

An important observation from the empirical analysis (Figure C.1) is that the importance

of discounts is close to what the model predicts. For example, in the empirical analysis, a

1-percentage-point increase in the fraction of sales is associated with a 1.56-percentage-point

decrease in the aggregate price level for θ = 5 , whereas in the model that decrease would

be 0.92 percentage points. This difference can be reconciled by Jensen’s inequality: since

the weights in (22) are convex and increasing in the absolute size of the log discount, larger

sales have a disproportionately larger contribution to the discount term, ∆t. For instance,

recomputing ∆t using only discounts smaller than 30% reduces the elasticity by a six-fold,

from 1.56 to 0.26. Because in our model all sales have the same size, the effect of the spread

in the size of discounts is not captured.

In summary, our findings in this section demonstrate that properly accounting for sales

can have important ramifications for the assessment of the cyclical behavior of aggregate

price and consumption. First, even small fluctuations in the frequency of sales can have

economically-relevant effects on the effective price level, in line with what we found in our

model. Second, the size of these effects depends heavily on the expenditure-switching behavior

of consumers between discounted and regular-price items; this channel is mostly absent from

official consumer price indices. Third, larger discounts provide a disproportionately large

impact on consumption and price levels.

11Freeman et al. (2008) reports the findings from The Rapport Attali in France that introduction of theban on below-cost price discounting led to a decrease in competition between the grocery retail chains andbetween suppliers, resulting in significant increases in price levels. For example, between 1996 and 2004, theprice of food in France (excluding meat and fresh produce) increased by 16%, 3 percentage points more thanthe general price index in France, and faster than food (excluding meat and fresh produce) in the rest of theEuro zone.

38

Page 39: The Cyclicality of Sales and Aggregate Price Flexibility { Appendix - HEC …neumann.hec.ca/pages/nicolas.vincent/Kryvtsov_Vincent... · 2019. 10. 16. · The Cyclicality of Sales

References

Anderson, Eric, Benjamin A. Malin, Emi Nakamura, Duncan Simester, and Jon Steinsson.

2017. “Informational rigidities and the stickiness of temporary Sales.” Journal of Monetary

Economics 90 (C):64–83.

Basu, Susanto. 1995. “Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity

and Welfare.” American Economic Review 85 (3):512–531.

Bils, Mark and Peter J. Klenow. 1998. “Using Consumer Theory to Test Competing Business

Cycle Models.” Journal of Political Economy 106 (2):233–261.

Blanchard, Olivier J. and Charles. M. Kahn. 1980. “The solution of the linear difference

models under rational expectations.” Econometrica 48:1305–1313.

Chevalier, Judith A. and Anil K. Kashyap. 2019. “Best Prices: Price Discrimination and

Consumer Substitution.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 11 (1):126–159.

Coibion, Olivier, Yuriy Gorodnichenko, and Gee Hee Hong. 2015. “The Cyclicality of Sales,

Regular and Effective Prices: Business Cycle and Policy Implications.” American Economic

Review 105 (3):993–1029.

Freeman, Peter, Jayne Almond, Barbara Donoghue, Alan Gregory, Alan Hamlin, and Bruce

Lyons. 2008. “The Supply of Groceries in the UK.” Market investigation, Competition

Commission. The Stationery Office, London.

Glandon, P.J. 2018. “Sales and the (Mis)measurement of price level fluctuations.” Journal of

Macroeconomics 58 (C):60–77.

Kryvtsov, Oleksiy and Virgiliu Midrigan. 2013. “Inventories, Markups, and Real Rigidities in

Menu Cost Models.” Review of Economic Studies 80 (1):249–276.

Mahajan, S. 2006. “Concentration ratios for businesses by industry in 2004.” Economic

Trends 635, Office for National Statistics.

Nakamura, Emi and Jon Steinsson. 2010. “Monetary Non-neutrality in a Multi-Sector Menu

Cost Model.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (3):961–1013.

39