Tail Risk Mom

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    1/34

    Jan 13, 2012 Comments Welcome

    Tail Risk in Momentum Strategy Returns

    Kent Daniel, Ravi Jagannathan and Soohun Kim

    Abstract

    Price momentum strategies have historically generated high positive returns with little

    systematic risk. However, momentum strategies incur periodic but infrequent largelosses. During 13 of the 1002 months in our 1927:07-2010:12 sample, losses to a US-equity momentum strategy exceeded 20 percent per month. We characterize theserisk-spikes with a two state hidden Markov model, with turbulent and calm states.These states are persistent, and forecastable using ex-ante instruments. Each of the 13months with losses exceeding 20 percent per month occurs during a turbulent month,meaning a month when the predicted probability of the hidden state being turbu-lent exceeds 0.5. During turbulent months, momentum returns are more volatilite,and average -0.65 %/month. A dynamic momentum strategy that avoids turbulentmonths has a Sharpe Ratio 0.32 double that of the static momentum strategy. Thepredictability of momemtum tail-risk renders momentum an even stronger anomaly.

    Columbia University, Graduate School of Business (Daniel) and Northwestern University, Kellogg School

    (Jagannathan and Kim). This paper originally appeared under the title Risky Cycles in Momentum Re-

    turns We thank Raul Chhabbra, Francis Diebold, Robert Engel, Robert Korajczyk, Jonathan Parker,

    Prasanna Tantri, the participants at the Fourth Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Economet-

    rics and the participants of seminars at Northwestern University, the Indian School of Business, the Securities

    and Exchange Board of India, and the Shanghai Advance Institute for Finance, Shanghai Jiao Tong Univer-

    sity for helpful comments on the earlier version of the paper. We alone are responsible for any errors and

    omissions.

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    2/34

    1 Introduction

    Relative strength strategies, also known as price momentum strategies, have been and con-

    tinue to be popular among traders. Quantitative strategies used by active money managersgenerally employ at least some form of momentum,1 and even non-quantiative mutual fund

    managers appear to utilize momentum in their trading decisions.2

    Price momentum in stocks can be described as the tendency of stocks with the highest

    (lowest) past return to outperform (underperform) the broader market. Price momentum

    strategies exploit this pattern by taking a long position in past winners and an equal short

    position in past losers. While such strategies produce high abnormal returns, they also

    generate infrequent, but large losses.

    Over the 1002 month sample period we examine in this paper July 1927 through

    December 2010 the particular momentum strategy we examine generated monthly returns

    in excess of the return on the risk free asset with a mean of 1.18%, a standard deviation of

    8%, and with little systematic risk as measured by a standard CAPM or a Fama and French

    (1993) three factor model. However, the strategy returns have an empirical distribution

    that is both strongly leptokurtic and highly left skewed. There are thirteen months with

    losses exceeding 20%. In its worst month the strategy experiences a loss of 79%. Were

    momentum returns generated from an i.i.d. normal distribution with mean and variance

    equal to their sample counterparts, the probability of realizing a loss of more than 20% in

    thirteen or more months in a sample of 1002 months would be 0.03%, and the probability of

    incurring a single loss of 79% or worse would be 3 1024.The skewed and leptokurtic distribution of momentum strategy returns suggests that

    momentum returns may be drawn from a mixture of normal distributions. To capture this,

    we develop a variation of the two state hidden Markov regime switching model (HMM) of

    Hamilton (1989), where the market is calm in one state and turbulent in the other.

    However, our switching model captures not only changes in the volatility of the underlying

    return generating processes, but also other features of the joint distribution of momentum

    1Swaminathan (2010) estimates that about one-sixth of the assets under management by active portfoliomanagers in the U.S. large cap space is managed using quantitative strategies.

    2Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) note that . . . a majority of the mututal funds examined by Grinblatt andTitman (1989; 1993) show a tendency to buy stocks that have increased in price over the previous quarter.

    2

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    3/34

    strategy returns and market returns, many of which are documented in the literature and

    some of which are new.3 In particular, momentum returns have the features of a written call

    on the stock index, and the nature of this option-like feature changes with the underlying

    state.

    Based on this model, we infer the state of the economy by observing changes in joint dis-

    tribution of momentum returns with past and contemporaneous stock index returns. Con-

    sistent with results in the literature, we find that momentum returns have the features of

    a written call on the stock index. The hidden states are persistent, and can be estimated

    ex-ante using the switching model.

    Our estimation reveals that distribution from which returns are drawn is more volatile

    when the market is in the unobserved turbulent state. We find that all the thirteen months

    with losses exceeding 20% occur when the predicted probability of the market being in

    the turbulent state exceeds 50%. The probability of observing a loss of 20% or more in

    thirteen or more months during the 200 months in the sample when we classify the market

    as turbulent increases to 91%, and the large momentum strategy losses become less black

    swan-like. Linear regression models of momentum returns and GARCH models of time

    varying volatility are not as successful as the HMM in identifying time periods when large

    losses are more likely to occur. Our findings are consistent with Ang and Timmerman

    (2011) who argue in favor of using regime switching models to capture abrupt changes in

    the statistical properties of financial market variables.

    Use of the ex ante probability of the turbulent state that we extract from the switching

    model allows us to construct a dynamic momentum strategy that outperforms the standard,

    static strategy. We find that the monthly Sharpe Ratio of momentum returns in months

    with a predicted probability of being in the turbulent state exceeding 0.5 is -0.05; and the

    monthly Sharpe Ratio for the other months is 0.32. The corresponding numbers for the

    excess returns on the stock index portfolio are 0.09 and 0.13. This high Sharpe-ratio in the

    calm state makes the momentum a still stronger anomaly.

    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We provide a brief review of related

    literature in Section 2. We describe the data and develop the econometric specifications of

    the hidden Markov model for characterizing momentum returns in Section 3. We discuss the

    3Section 2 provides a review of this literature

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    4/34

    empirical findings in Section 4 and conclude in Section 5.

    2 Related Literature

    Levy (1967) is one of the early academic articles to document the profitability of stock price

    momentum strategies. However, Jensen (1967) raised several issues with the methodology

    employed by Levy (1967). Perhaps as a consequence, momentum received little attention

    in the academic literature until Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), who developed with a clever

    method for constructing portfolios based on relative price momentum in stocks that was

    rigorous and replicable. A number of studies have subsequently confirmed the Jegadeesh

    and Titman (1993) findings using data from markets in a number of countries (Rouwen-

    horst, 1998), and in a number of asset classes (Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen, 2008). As

    Fama and French (2008) observe, the abnormal returns associated with momentum are

    pervasive.

    Korajczyk and Sadka (2004) show that momentum profits cannot be explained away by

    transactions costs and so remain an anomaly. Chabot, Ghysels, and Jagannathan (2009)

    find that momentum strategies earned anomalous returns even during the Victorian era

    with very similar statistical properties, except for the January reversal, presumably because

    capital gains were not taxed in that period. Interestingly, they also find that momentum

    returns exhibited negative episodes once every 1.4 years with an average duration of 3.8

    months per episode.

    The additional literature on momentum strategies is vast, and can be grouped into

    three categories: (a) documentation of the momentum phenomenon across countries and

    asset classes (b) characterization of the statistical properties of momentum returns, both in

    the time-series and cross-section and (c) theoretical explanations for the momentum phe-

    nomenon. We make a contribution to (b). In what follows we provide review of only a few

    relevant articles that characterize the statistical properties of momentum returns, and refer

    the interested reader to the comprehensive survey of the momentum literature by Jegadeesh

    and Titman (2005).

    Our work is directly related to several other papers in the literature. First, a number of

    authors, going back to Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), have noted that momentum strategies

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    5/34

    can experenience severe losses over extended periods. In particular, Griffin, Ji, and Martin

    (2003) document that there are often periods of several months when momentum returns

    are negative.

    In addition, a large number of papers have explored the time-varying nature of the risk of

    momentum strategies. Kothari and Shanken (1992) note that, for portfolios formed on the

    basis of past returns, the betas will be a function of past market returns. Using this intuition,

    Grundy and Martin (2001) show that beta of momentum returns become negative when

    the stock market has performed poorly in the past. Rouwenhorst (1998) documents that

    momentum returns are nonlinearly related to contemporaneous market returns i.e., that

    their up market beta is less than their down market beta.4 Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) find

    that this non-linearity is present only following market losses. Building on Cooper, Gutierrez,

    and Hameed (2004), who show that the expected returns associated with momentum profits

    depend on the state of the stock market, Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) also show even after

    controlling for the dynamic risk of momentum strategies, average momentum returns are

    lower following market losses, and when market volatility is high. They find evidence of

    these features not only in US equities, but also internationally, and in momentum strategies

    applied to commodity, currency, and country equity markets. Finally, they show that the

    factors combine to result in large momentum strategy losses in periods when the market

    recovers sharply following steep losses.5

    4To our knowledge, Chan (1988) and DeBondt and Thaler (1987) first document that the market beta ofa long-short winner-minus-loser portfolio is non-linearly to the market return, though DeBondt and Thaler(1987) do their analysis on the returns of longer-term winners and losers as opposed to the shorter-termwinners and losers we examine here. Rouwenhorst (1998) demonstrates the same non-linearity is present forlong-short momentum portfolios in non-US markets. Finally Boguth, Carlson, Fisher, and Simutin (2010),building on the results of Jagannathan and Korajczyk (1986), note that the interpretation of the measures ofabnormal performance in Chan (1988), Grundy and Martin (2001) and Rouwenhorst (1998) is problematic.

    5Ambasta and Ben Dor (2010) observe a similar pattern for Barclays Alternative Replicator return thatmimics the return on a broad hedge fund index. They find that when the hedge fund index recoverssharply from severe losses the replicator substantially underperforms the index. Also, Elavia and Kim(2011) emphasize the need for modeling changing risk for understanding the recent weak performance of

    quantitative equity investment managers who had over two decades of good performance.

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    6/34

    3 Data and Econometric Specifications

    3.1 Data

    Price momentum strategies using stocks can be constructed in a variety of different ways.

    For this study we utilize a momentum strategy based on the momentum decile portfolio

    returns available in Ken Frenchs Data Library.6 These portfolios are formed by first ranking

    stocks based on past 11 months of returns and grouping them into ten decile portfolios. The

    returns on each of the ten decile portfolios are measured in the second month after the return

    measurement period.7 Most of our analysis will concentrate on the zero-investment portfolio

    which, at the end of each month, invests $1 in the top decile portfolio of past winners and,

    and takes a short position of $1 in the bottom decile portfolio of past losers. The return tothis strategy is the difference between the top and bottom decile returns.

    Data for the CRSP value-weighted market return, the risk-free rate, and the Fama and

    French (1993) size and value portfolios SMB and HML are also taken from Ken Frenchs

    Data Library.

    3.2 Data Summary Statistics

    Table 1 presents estimators of the moments of the monthly momentum strategy returns,and of the CRSP value-weighted portfolio return, net of the risk-free rate. The monthly

    momentum strategy returns averages 1.18% over this 1002 month period, with a monthly

    Sharpe Ratio of 0.15. In contrast, the realized Sharpe ratio of the market is only 0.11. The

    alpha of momentum strategy is 1.75%/month with respect to the Fama and French (1993)

    three factor model, and when the three Fama and French factors are combined with the

    momentum portfolio the Sharpe Ratio almost doubles to 0.30.

    While the momentum strategy has a higher in sample Sharpe Ratio than the stock index

    portfolio, Table 1 shows that it exhibits strong excessive kurtosis and negative skewness. The

    excess kurtosis is also evident from the infrequent but very large losses to the momentum

    6The library is available at http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data library.htmlThe specific momentum decile portfolios we use are those designated by 10 Portfolios Prior 12 2.

    7Skipping the month after the return measurement period is done both so as to be consistent with themomentum literature, and is done so as to minimize market microstructure effects and to avoid the short-horizon reversal effects documented in Jegadeesh (1990) and Lehmann (1990).

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    7/34

    Table 1: Estimates of First Four Moments of Momentum and Market ReturnsThis table presents estimates of the first four moments of the distribution of monthly returnsfor MOM the zero-investment momentum portfolio used in the study and for the CRSPvalue weighted (market) portfolio net of the risk-free rate. The sample period is 1927:07-2010:12.

    Mean Std.Dev Skewness Kurtosis

    MOM 1.18% 8.00% -2.45 21.02MktRf 0.62% 5.46% 0.16 10.44

    strategy during the 1002 months in the sample period. Given the low unconditional volatility

    of the momentum strategy, if returns were normal the probability of observing a month with

    a loss exceeding 42% in a sample of 1002 months would be one in 29,000, and the probability

    of seeing five or more months with losses exceeding 42% would be almost zero. Yet the

    lowest five monthly returns in the sample are: -79%, -60%, -46%, -44%, and -42%, a rare

    black swan like occurrence from the perspective of someone who believes that the time series

    of monthly momentum returns are generated from an i.i.d. normal distribution.

    In Section 3.7 we describe a hidden Markov model, based on the framework of Hamilton

    (1989), which we use to capture the behavior of momentum returns. Specifically, we model

    momentum returns with a mixture of normal distributions where the parameters of the

    normal distributions depend on past and contemporaneous history in possibly nonlinear ways

    to accommodate the negative skewness of momentum strategy returns. Even though the

    distribution of returns conditional on the hidden state and the current market is normal,

    this model is able to capture the unconditional skewness and kurtosis of the momentum

    returns as documented above.

    In what follows we first describe our rationale for modeling the joint distribution of

    momentum strategy returns and current and past market returns the way we do.

    3.3 Dependence of Beta on Past Market Return

    Grundy and Martin (2001), using a result which to our knowledge was first pointed by out

    by Kothari and Shanken (1992), argue that the momentum portfolio beta will be a function

    7

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    8/34

    of the market return over the return measurement period.8

    The intuition for the Kothari and Shankens result is as follows: If the market return

    is negative over the return measurement period then, from a Bayesian perspective, a firm

    which earned a negative return i.e. which moved down with the market is likely to have

    a higher beta than a positive return firm. Conversely, when the market return was strongly

    postive over the return measurement period, the past winners will tend to be high beta

    stocks, and the past losers low beta stocks.

    Because the momentum portfolio is long past winners and short past losers, the intuition

    of Kothari and Shanken (1992) and Grundy and Martin (2001) suggests that the momentum

    portfolio beta should be negative in bear markets when the market return was negative

    over the return measurement period and positive in bull markets.

    If we define the IBt as a indicator that the market-state is Bearish, meaning that the

    return on the market over the return measurement period from t 12 through t 2 monthsis negative, i.e.:

    IBt 1 if R

    M(t12, t2) > 00 otherwise

    (1)

    this suggests the following specification for the joint distribution of momentum and stock

    market returns

    Rmomt = + 0 + BIBt RMt + t.Estimation of this specification over our full sample yields:

    0 B

    estimate 0.01 0.16 1.29t-stat 5.66 2.93 17.16

    Consistent with the findings in the literature noted above, B is economically and statistically

    negative, but the abnormal return, controlling for the dynamic market risk, is still strong.

    8See pp. 195-198 of Kothari and Shanken (1992).

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    9/34

    3.4 Dependence of Beta on Current Market Return

    As noted in Section 2, a number of authors have noted that the contemporaneous return

    of past-return sorted portfolios are nonlinearly to contemporaneous market return.9 In the

    language of Henriksson and Merton (1981), the up-beta of momentum portfolios is lower

    than their down-beta. This option-like feature of portfolios is captured with the following

    specification:

    Rmomt = +

    0 + U IUt

    RMt + t

    Where our up-market indicator, IUt , is an indicator variable which is one when the market

    return is above zero in month t. Estimation of this specification over our full sample yields:

    0 U

    estimate 0.03 0.07 0.89t-stat 9.96 0.95 7.53

    Notice that up-beta estimate our momentum portfolio is lower than the down-beta estimate

    by 0.89, and is again strongly statistically significant, consistent with the literature noted

    above. Also, here it is important to note that the estimated is no longer a valid mea-

    sure of abnormal performance, since the contemporaneous up-market indicator uses ex-post

    information.10

    3.5 Beta and Market Recoveries

    Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) find that momentum portfolios incur large losses when the

    market recovers sharply following large losses. For example, the worst five months with the

    largest losses on the momentum portfolio we discussed have the pattern in Table 2, consistent

    with the observations in Daniel and Moskowitz (2011).

    In order to capture this effect, we follow Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) and define the

    recovery indicator function that takes the value of 1 whenever both the bear-market indicator

    is 1 and the contemporaneous market return is postive (i.e., when IBt IUt = 1), where IU,t isand indicator variable which is 1 when the contemporaneous market return is positive, and

    9See, in particular, footnote 4.10See Jagannathan and Korajczyk (1986) and, more recently, Boguth, Carlson, Fisher, and Simutin (2010).

    9

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    10/34

    Table 2: Patterns of Historical Momentum Crashes

    Month Rmomt (%) RMt (%)

    24n=1 R

    Mtn(%)

    1932/8 -78.96 37.60 -68.35

    1932/7 -60.11 33.72 -75.452009/4 -45.89 11.05 -44.111939/9 -43.94 15.96 -21.501933/4 -42.33 38.37 -59.46

    is zero otherwise:

    IUt

    1 if RMt > 0

    0 otherwise(2)

    This motivates the following specification for the momentum return generating process.

    Rmomt = +

    0

    +B IBt+R IBt IUt > 0

    RMt + t (3)

    Estimation of this specification yields:

    0

    B

    R

    estimate 0.02 0.14 0.91 0.66t-stat 7.65 2.61 9.33 5.94

    The results can be summarized as follows:

    0 > 0 : 0 is the average beta in bull (i.e., non-bear). The point estimate is positiveand statistically significant, though small.

    B < 0 : The momentum beta is strongly negative when the measurement periodmarket return is negative that is in a bear-market.

    R < 0 : The momentum beta is even more negative when the contemporaneous marketreturn is positive, in a bear market-state.

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    11/34

    3.6 Final Specification

    The specification of (3) by Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) emphasizes the role of past market

    return on the option-like feature of momentum return. They show that the option-like feature

    of momentum return depends on the past market return being negative by examining the

    specification of the form given in equation (3). Since our objective is to infer the hidden

    state by examining the joint behavior of momentum returns and stock index returns, we

    consider the following slightly more general specification for the stochastic process governing

    the evolution of the stock index and momentum returns that nests (3) as a special case.

    Rit = +

    L ILt

    + LU

    IL

    t IU

    t

    + B IBt

    + BU IBt IUt

    RMt + t (4)

    where i denotes the Winner, the Loser or the Momentum (i.e., Winner - Loser) portfolios.

    Here, we have added one final indicator: a BulL market indicator which is one when the

    measurement-period market return is greater than zero, so that

    ILt

    (1

    IBt

    ) (5)

    In the regression equation of (4), L/B represent the beta when the market return during

    the measurement period is positive/negative. When momentum returns have written call

    option like feature the sign of LU and BU will be negative, and BU will be more negative

    indicating the accentuated option-like feature following declining markets. The dependence

    of momentum return beta on past and contemporaneous stock index return is summarized

    below.Market State

    BulL Bear

    RMtUp L + LU B + BU

    Down L B

    (6)

    Table 3 present the results of estimating equation (4). As before, L > B. Also, as in

    Daniel and Moskowitz (2011), BU is negative. However, notice that LU is also negative

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    12/34

    Table 3: Momentum components in Bull and Bear Markets

    Portfolio

    winner loser mom

    0.01 -0.01 0.02(8.97) (-5.47) (8.27)

    L 1.45 1.10 0.38(33.47) (16.52) (4.28)

    LU -0.27 0.26 -0.53(-3.84) (2.51) (-3.66)

    B 0.89 1.59 -0.70(22.10) (26.47) (-8.37)

    BU -0.28 0.53 -0.81(-4.93) (6.22) (-6.85)

    though less negative than BU. Noting that LU is similar to BU for the Winner return, we

    can observe that the stronger option like feature of momentum returns following past down

    market is mainly due to the behavior of the loser component of momentum returns.11

    We therefore use equation (4) in developing our Hidden Markov Model specification.

    3.7 A Hidden Markov Model of Momentum Strategy Returns

    We now define a Hidden Markov Model (HMM) of momentum strategy returns based on the

    specification given in equation (4). We use St to denote the unobserved random underlying

    state of the economy, and st the realized state of the economy. We assume that there are

    two possible states, one is Calm (C) and the other Turbulent (T).

    Our specification for the momentum portfolio return generating process is based on equa-

    tion (4), but we allow the coefficients to vary by state:

    Rmomt = (St) +

    L(St) I

    L

    t

    + LU(St) ILt I

    Ut

    + B(St) IBt

    + BU(St) IBt I

    Ut

    RMt + (St)

    momt . (7)

    11The difference in statistical significance between our results and those of Daniel and Moskowitz (2011)is because of the lower residual variance that is achieved with this specification.

    12

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    13/34

    Here momt is i.i.d. N(0, 1), so (St) denotes the residual volatility, which is a function ofthe state. As before, the ex-ante bulL and Bear market indicators ILt and I

    Bt , and the ex-post

    Up market indicator IUt are as defined in equations (1), (2), and (5), respectively.

    In addition we define the return generating process for the market as

    RMt = (St) + M (St) Mt , (8)

    3.8 Maximum Likelihood Estimation

    We estimate the parameters of the hidden Markov model using the maximum likelihood

    method described in Hamilton (1989).

    We begin by defining the vector of observable variables of interest as of time t Yt, as:

    Yt =

    ILt , ILt I

    Ut , I

    Bt , I

    Bt I

    Ut , R

    momt , R

    Mt , 1

    ,

    We let yt denote the realized value of Yt.

    We let St denote the random state at time t (which, in our setting, is either calm or

    turbulent, and st denote the particular realized value of the state at date t.

    We let Pr (St = st|St1 = st1) denote the probability of moving from state st1 at timet 1 to state st at time t.12 Also, Ft1 denotes the information set at time t 1, i.e.,{yt1, , y1}.

    Note that the unconditional probabilities of the two states are determined by the transi-

    tion probabilities. In our esimation, we set Pr (S0 = s0) to the unconditional probabilities,

    based on the two parameters governing the transition probabilities.

    Suppose we know the value of Pr (St1 = st1|Ft1). Then, Pr (St = st|Ft1) is given by:

    Pr (St = st

    |Ft1) = st1

    Pr (St = st, St1 = st1

    |Ft1)

    =st1

    Pr (St = st|St1 = st1) P r (St1 = st1|Ft1) , (9)

    which can be computed since we know the elements of the transition probability matrix,

    12Here, we use Pr(x) to denote the probability of the event x when x is discrete, and the probabilitydensity ofx when x is continuous.

    13

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    14/34

    Pr (St = st|St1 = st1).Next, we can compute the joint conditional distribution of the hidden state at time t, st

    and observable variables at time t, yt as follows.

    Pr (yt, St = st|Ft1) (10)= Pr (yt|St = st,Ft1) P r (St = st|Ft1)

    The second term on the RHS is given by (9) and the first term is the state dependent

    likelihood ofyt, which under the distributional assumption from (7) is given by

    Pr (yt

    |St = st,

    Ft1) =

    1

    mom (st)2exp

    1

    2mom (st)

    2(mom (St)

    momt )

    2

    (11)

    1mom (st)

    2

    exp 1

    2M (st)2

    M (St)

    Mt

    2(12)

    where

    mom (St) momt = R

    momt (St)

    St, I

    Lt , I

    LUt , I

    Bt , I

    BUt

    RMt

    M (St) Mt = R

    Mt (St) .

    Given Pr (yt, St = st|Ft1) from (10), we can integrate out St for St = {turbulent, calm}and compute Pr (yt|Ft1) the conditional likelihood of yt as:

    Pr (yt|Ft1)=st+1

    Pr (yt, St = st|Ft1) .

    Now consider the log likelihood function of the sample given by:

    L =Tt=1

    log(Pr(yt|Ft1)) , (13)

    14

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    15/34

    which may be maximized numerically to form estimates of the parameter set

    =

    (C) , L (C) , LU (C) , B (C) , BU (C) , mom (C)

    (T) , L

    (T) , LU

    (T) , B

    (T) , BU

    (T) , mom (T) (C) , M (C) , (T) , M (T)

    Pr (St = C|St = C) , Pr (St = T|St = T)

    .

    We showed how to compute Pr (yt|Ft1) given Pr (St1 = st1|Ft1) . To compute Pr (yt+1|Ft)we need to know Pr (St = st|Ft) . This is accomplished by Bayesian updating procedure asfollows.

    Pr (St = st|Ft) = Pr (St = st|yt,Ft1)=

    Pr (yt, St = st|Ft1)Pr (yt|Ft1) (14)

    where the last equality of (14) is due to Bayes rule. Using (14) to compute Pr (St = st|Ft)and the algorithm described above, we can compute Pr (yt+1|Ft). This way we can generatethe likelihood Pr (yt+1|Ft) for t = {0, 1, , T1} and compute L =

    Tt=1 log(Pr(yt|Ft1))

    given specific values for the unknown parameters that we need to estimate.

    We estimate the values of the models of the hidden Markov model parameters by maxi-

    mizing the log likelihood given by (13), i.e.,

    ML = arg max

    L () (15)

    A consistent estimator of the asymptotic covariance matrix of the estimated parameters,

    () , is given by: () = H (ML)1 ,where H () is the Hessian ofL ().

    13

    13We estimate H (ML) numerically using the Matlabs function fminunc .

    15

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    16/34

    4 Empirical Results

    Table 4 summarizes the maximum likelihood estimates of the model parameters. The param-

    eter estimates are consistent with the observations in Grundy and Martin (2001). In bothhidden states, we can see that L > B, 14 i.e., the beta of momentum returns is smaller

    when the average return on the market index during the portfolio formation period is neg-

    ative. Also, both of LU and BU, are negative consistent with the written call option-like

    features of momentum returns discussed in section 3.6. While both the calm and turbulent

    states are persistent, the probability of remaining in the calm state starting from the calm

    state is higher.

    Table 4: Maximum Likelihood Estimates of HMM ParametersThis table presents the parameters of the HMM model, estimated using the momentumstrategy return and the market return over the full sample. As indicated below, the MLestimates ofmom and M are each multiplied by 100. The Log-Likelihood for this estimationis 3.14 103. The AIC is 6.23 103, and the BIC is 6.15 103.

    STATE

    Calm Turbulent

    Parameter MLE t-stat MLE t-stat 1.96 7.11 2.91 2.77L 0.51 4.43 0.26 1.39

    LU 0.45 2.55 0.63 1.85B 0.33 2.05 0.73 4.56BU 0.34 1.58 1.02 4.28mom (102) 4.10 23.16 10.22 19.44 0.99 6.85 0.50 0.84M (102) 3.64 31.54 8.91 18.68Pr (St= st|St1= st) 0.97 83.15 0.91 26.68

    Table 5 provides the maximum likelihood estimates of the differences in parameter values

    in the calm and the turbulent states and the corresponding t-values. BU

    the parameterthat captures the effect of market recovery following sharp losses on the sensitivity of mo-

    mentum returns to market returns is significantly different across the two states. B is

    marginally different across hidden states, indicating that it is easier to differentiate hidden

    states following past-down market than past-up market. The variance of the market return

    14t-stat on the null that L = B is 3.85 for calm state and 3.58 for turbulent state.

    16

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    17/34

    as well as the residual variance of the momentum return in the two hidden states are sig-

    nificantly different. The returns are about twice as volatile in the turbulent states when

    compared to the calm states. This difference in parameters helps us to infer the hidden

    state.

    Table 5: A Test of Equality of the Parameters in the Two Hidden States

    MLE t-statC T 0.94 0.85LC LT 0.25 1.10LUC LUT 0.18 0.44BC BT 0.40 1.73BUC BUT 0.68 2.08C

    mom T

    mom 0.06 11.39C T 1.48 2.40CM TM 0.53 11.15

    Table 6 shows that how many of large positive and negative returns occur when the

    predicted probability of the turbulent state is p or more, where p takes any of the values from

    10% to 50% in steps of 10%. When we estimate the model using all the sample observations,

    all the 13 months with losses of more than 20% occur in months with Pr (St = T

    |Ft1) > 0.5.

    There are 11 months of when momentum return exceed 20%. and 8 of those 11 months occur

    during months with Pr (St = T|Ft1) > 50%. Each entry represents the number of detectedlarge gains(loses)/the number of total large gains (losses) in the sample.

    We also examine the ability of the hidden Markov specification to predict the state of

    the economy in real time, following the suggestion of Amisano and Geweke (2011). For that

    purpose we use an expanding window to estimate the model parameters and that gives us

    real time predicted probability of the next month being in the turbulent state for 400 months.

    In particular, for each month t = T 399, , T, we estimate the model parameters usingmaximum likelihood using data for the months {1, , t 1}. The first period of our out ofsample test is September 1977 and the last is December 2010.

    From table 7 we can see that there were 5 months with losses exceeding 20% and all

    of them occur during months with predicted probability of being in the turbulent state in

    excess of 50%. In contrast, there were 4 months with gains exceeding 20% but 3 of them

    17

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    18/34

    Table 6: Ability of the HMM to Capture Extreme Gains and Losses

    Pr (St= T

    |Ft1) # Gains captured/Total #Gains #

    is more than 10% 12.5% 15% 17.5% 20% of Months50% 37/69 25/42 17/27 10/14 8/11 20640% 43/69 28/42 18/27 11/14 9/11 24130% 46/69 30/42 20/27 11/14 9/11 27120% 47/69 30/42 20/27 11/14 9/11 30910% 55/69 34/42 23/27 14/14 11/11 381

    Pr (St= T|Ft1) # Losses captured/Total #Losses #is more than 10% 12.5% 15% 17.5% 20% of Months

    50% 32/53 27/35 24/31 19/21 13/13 206

    40% 34/53 27/35 24/31 19/21 13/13 24130% 37/53 29/35 26/31 19/21 13/13 27120% 41/53 33/35 30/31 21/21 13/13 30910% 42/53 33/35 30/31 21/21 13/13 381

    occur during months with predicted probability of being in the turbulent state exceeding

    50%. The asymmetry is probably due to the fact that in the momentum return generating

    process we use, steep stock market losses, being more likely in turbulent markets, will result

    in assigning a higher probability to the underlying state being turbulent. Steep losses willalso result in the loser stocks will be highly levered, and accentuated option-like features.

    Consequently, when the market recovers sharply the momentum strategy which has a short

    position in the losers will also lose sharply. However, because of the accentuated option

    like features, when the market falls further, the loser stocks in the portfolio will not gain

    as much, leading to the asymmetric pattern we observe, i.e., the prevalence of steep losses

    during predicted turbulent markets relative to gains. We find that this pattern is observed

    primarily when the economy is in the turbulent state.

    The association between large losses and the predicted probability of being in the turbu-

    lent state is illustrated in Figure 1 using the entire sample and in Figure 2 using an expanding

    window in real time.

    The vertical axis is the realized return in a month and the horizontal axis is the predicted

    probability of the month being in a turbulent state. As can be seen,the scatter plot fans out

    18

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    19/34

    Table 7: Out of Sample Ability of the HMM to Capture Extreme Moves

    Pr (St= T

    |Ft1) # Gains captured/Total #Gains #

    is more than 10% 12.5% 15% 17.5% 20% of Months50% 12/29 10/18 7/12 4/5 3/4 7440% 13/29 11/18 7/12 4/5 3/4 7930% 16/29 12/18 7/12 4/5 3/4 9020% 19/29 14/18 9/12 4/5 3/4 10610% 21/29 14/18 9/12 4/5 3/4 130

    Pr (St= T|Ft1) # Losses captured/Total #Losses #is more than 10% 12.5% 15% 17.5% 20% of Months

    50% 14/26 11/16 8/12 6/7 5/5 7440% 14/26 11/16 8/12 6/7 5/5 7930% 15/26 12/16 9/12 6/7 5/5 9020% 15/26 12/16 9/12 6/7 5/5 10610% 15/26 12/16 9/12 6/7 5/5 130

    with lot more dispersion when we move from the left to the right, providing a visual measure

    of the ability of the hidden Markov model to predict turbulent months.

    The behavior of momentum and stock market returns during months with predicted

    probability of being in the turbulent state in excess of 50% are summarized in the table 8.

    Table 8: Summary Statistics of Returns in Turbulent and Calm Months

    Fcst. # of MOM Returns MKT-Rf ReturnsState months Mean (%) SD (%) SR Mean (%) SD (%) SRCalm 796 1.66 5.19 0.32 0.57 4.37 0.13

    Turbulent 206 -0.65 14.27 -0.05 0.80 8.55 0.09All 1002 1.18 8.00 0.15 0.62 5.49 0.11

    Of the 1002 months, 206 months are turbulent and 796 months are calm. Momentum

    returns are on average negative though not statistically significantly so during turbulent

    months, and almost three times as volatile as calm months. In contrast momentum returns

    average 1.66% during calm months with an associated Sharpe Ratio of 0.32, twice the Sharpe

    Ratio for all months for the stock market portfolio. To the extent that turbulent months are

    19

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    20/34

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.90.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    Predicted Probability of Turbulent State

    RealizedMomentumR

    eturn

    Figure 1: Realized Momentum versus Predicted Probability (in sample)

    Table 9: Summary Statistics of Returns in Turbulent and Calm Months (Out ofSample)

    Fcst. # of MOM Returns MKT-Rf ReturnsState months Mean (%) SD (%) SR Mean (%) SD (%) SRCalm 326 1.71 5.48 0.31 0.58 4.31 0.14

    Turbulent 74 -0.94 13.42 -0.07 0.49 5.83 0.08All 400 1.22 7.64 0.16 0.57 4.62 0.12

    predictable and can be avoided the momentum phenomenon becomes more of a puzzle.

    Interestingly, the average return on the stock market portfolio is the same during turbu-

    lent as well calm months even though the market is almost twice as volatile during turbulent

    months, which is consistent with the evidence presented in Breen, Glosten, and Jagannathan

    (1989). We also report the result with out of sample estimation with Table 9.

    When we classify months with predicted probability of the unobserved state being in

    the turbulent state exceeding 50% as being turbulent and the other months as calm, as we

    noted earlier, all large losses (exceeding 20%) occur during turbulent months. While both

    calm and turbulent months exhibit persistence, the former is less so. Calm months have an

    average duration of 16 months and turbulent months have an average duration of 4 months.

    As can be seen from figure 3 turbulent months occur when the economy is in a recession as

    well as when the economy is in an expansion.

    20

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    21/34

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10.5

    0.4

    0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    Predicted Probability of Turbulent State

    RealizedMomentumR

    eturn

    Figure 2: Realized Momentum versus Predicted Probability (out of sample)

    As can be seen from Table 10 and 11, during the 1002 months in our sample, the mo-

    mentum portfolio formation period stock index returns were negative only for 303 months,

    i.e., 30% of the months. However, in the 206 months classfied as belonging to the turbu-

    lent class (i.e., months with probability of the hidden state being turbulent exceeding 0.50),

    formation period stock returns were negative for 124 months, i.e., 60% of the months. This

    is consistent with the view that declining markets are more likely when the hidden state is

    turbulent.

    Table 10: Past market return and the likelihood of hidden state being turbulent in sample

    Pr (St = T|Ft1)Formation Period Return 50% 50%

    Positive 82 617Negative 124 179

    Past 2 year Return

    50%

    50%Positive 91 666Negative 114 119

    21

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    22/34

    1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 20200

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    Pr(S

    t=T|F

    t

    1)

    NBER Recession

    Turbulent Periods

    Figure 3: Turbulent Months and NBER Recessions

    Table 11: Past market return and the likelihood of the hidden state being turbu-lent out of sample

    Pr (St = T|Ft1)Formation Period Return 50% 50%

    Positive 26 260Negative 48 66

    Past 2 year Return 50% 50%Positive 37 280Negative 37 46

    4.1 Alternative Specifications

    4.1.1 Linear Model of Expected Momentum Strategy Return

    In this section we examine whether we can model the expected momentum strategy return

    as a linear function of observed variables that describe the state of the market. To answer

    this question we consider the linear model considered by Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) given

    below:

    Rmomt = 0 + 1

    I12n=2

    RMtn

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    23/34

    Table 12: Linear Model for Predicting Momentum Strategy Return

    0 1 R2adj

    Estimate 0.02 -105.95 4.23t-stat 6.83 -6.64

    As can be seen, the estimated value of 1, the effect of past daily volatility on the future

    mean momentum return, is highly significant with a t-statistic of6.64. However, this linearmodel is not as effective as the HMM when it comes to predicting months in which large

    losses are likely to occur. This is not surprising, as the objective of this linear model is not

    to forecast volatility as we do here, but rather to forecast mean return.

    0.14 0.12 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 0.020.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    RealizedMomentumR

    eturn

    Fitted Momentum Return

    Figure 4: Realized and Fitted Momentum Returns: Linear Model

    Figure 4 gives a plot of the realized momentum strategy returns against their predicted

    counterpart of the analogue of the linear model in (16) that we estimate. As can be seen,

    the HMM may add some ability to forecast large losses relative to the linear model.

    4.1.2 GARCH Model of Momentum Strategy Return Volatility

    In this section, we compare the results of Markov regime-switching model with those of

    GARCH15 model for the joint movement of momentum returns and market returns. We

    15See Bollerslev (1986)

    23

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    24/34

    assume that momentum returns are related to the average stock market return during the

    portfolio formation period as well as the contemporaneous stock market return in nonlinear

    ways in equation (7) of the hidden Markov model specification. Also, we let the volatility

    of market returns has an effect on the variance of momentum returns in a GARCH(1,1)

    manner. We estimate the following specification:

    Rmomt = +

    LILt

    +LUILUt

    +BIBt

    +BUIBUt

    R

    Mt + mom,t (17)

    RMt = + M,t (18)

    where mom,t

    M,t

    N

    0

    0

    , t 0

    0 t

    and t and t are specified as follows in a Bivariate GARCH:

    2t = 0 + p12t1 + q1

    2mom,t1 + p2

    2t1 + q2

    2M,t1 (19)

    2

    t = 0 + p32

    t1 + q32

    M,t1 (20)

    With the variance specification of (19) and (20), we try to capture the spillover of the

    variance of market to the variance of momentum. p2 and q2 are parameters to measure

    the effect of the past variance of market on the current variance of momentum return in a

    GARCH manner. We estimate the model specified from (17) to (20) through ML method

    using Matlab.

    Table 13 gives the parameters in the variance equation of GARCH(1,1). The estimated

    values of L is similar in magnitude to what we obtained using OLS. However, unlike for

    OLS, the estimated value of B or BU is smaller than the regression results. This is to

    be expected, since the nonlinear recovery response occurs mostly during volatile market

    conditions, past-down market is correlated with turbulent hidden states, and those periods

    are down weighted when estimating the model parameters with GARCH effects through ML

    24

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    25/34

    Table 13: Bivariate Model Parameter Estimates

    Mean-ReturnParams MLE t-stat

    1.70 5.84L 0.38 3.90

    LU -0.33 -1.98B -0.57 -6.22

    BU -0.43 -3.10 0.75 5.72

    GARCH of MOMParams MLE t-stat

    0 3.70 2.48p1 0.27 2.81q1 0.35 5.18

    p2 0.26 2.22q2 0.22 3.34

    GARCH of MKTParams MLE t-statal

    0 0.61 2.91p3 0.86 45.93q3 0.12 6.09

    procedure.

    Given the return specification of (17), it is not trivial to calculate the conditional vari-ance of momentum return. However, with the assumption that the market return is normally

    distributed and independent of the residual terms of the momentum return, we can calcu-

    late the conditional variance of momentum return using the property of truncated normal

    distribution for the changing beta conditional on the current market return in the equation

    of (17).

    0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 4080

    60

    40

    20

    0

    20

    40

    Inferred Standard Deviation of Momentum Return

    RealizedMomentumR

    eturn

    Figure 5: Realized Momentum vs GARCH forecast of Volatility

    Figure 5 shows the plot of realized momentum returns against the predicted standard

    deviations of the returns. Figure 5 is similar to figures 1 and 2 except that the predicted

    standard deviation of momentum return replaces the predicted probability of being in the

    25

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    26/34

    Table 14: HMM-GARCH Comparison

    HMM GARCHThreshold # of Sharpe Ratio # of Sharpe Ratio

    Loss Months Calm Turbulent Months Calm Turbulent-10% 990 0.27 0.15 881 0.40 0.14

    -12.50% 517 0.35 0.09 634 0.39 0.10-15% 396 0.36 0.05 374 0.37 0.03

    -17.50% 287 0.36 -0.01 354 0.35 0.04-20% 148 0.31 -0.08 229 0.33 -0.02

    turbulent state.

    In order to evaluate the performance of the hidden Markov model, we classified a month

    as being turbulent when the predicted probability for the turbulent state exceeded a giventhreshold, say 50%. In a similar fashion, for the GARCH model, we classify a month as being

    turbulent when the predicted standard deviation of momentum return during the month is

    higher than a given threshold standard deviation level.

    Table 14 compares the minimum number of months that will be classified as being tur-

    bulent so as to include all months with losses exceeding a given loss level under hidden

    Markov and GARCH models. As can be seen, the hidden Markov model is better in identi-

    fying months that are likely to have large losses in the following sense. The hidden Markov

    model will classify 145 of the 1002 months as being turbulent if the turbulent months were

    to contain all the months with losses exceeding 20% In contrast, the GARCH specification

    will classify 229 of the 1002 months as being turbulent for capturing all months with losses

    exceeding 20%. The comparison with the realized Sharpe Ratios is also interesting. With

    20% threshold, the Sharpe Ratios of turbulent month returns are -0.08 and -0.02 for the

    hidden Markov model and GARCH model. The Sharpe Ratios for the corresponding calm

    month returns are 0.31 and 0.33. Even though the GARCH model classifies much more

    months as turbulent, in terms of Sharpe Ratio separation, GARCH is about as efficient as

    the hidden Markov model. The advantage of the hidden Markov model is in its ability to

    predict months with higher probability of large losses.

    26

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    27/34

    4.1.3 Alternative Hidden Markov Model Specifications

    this section has been revised substantially to take into account the new specifi-

    cation

    Recall the hidden Markov model for the joint movement of momentum and market return

    given in equations (7) and (8). We examine four different versions of the mean equation by

    imposing alternative sets of restrictions:

    Model 1: L = B and LU = BU = 0

    Model 2: LU = BU = 0

    Model 3: L = B

    Model 4: LU = 0

    That is, Model 1 is a standard one factor market model. Model 2 takes allows the beta to

    depends on the past market return. Model 3 is designed to capture the option-like features of

    momentum returns, and Model 4 allows for differential up- and down-market betas following

    down markets.

    Table 15 shows the estimated parameter values for the four restricted versions of the

    hidden Markov model. Interestingly, the volatility of the market return and the momentum

    strategy residual returns in the two states are about the same in all four models, and the

    turbulent state is much less persistent.For all the four models, as before, we classify a month as being turbulent when the

    predicted probability of the unobserved underlying state being turbulent exceeds 50%. Table

    16 compares the fraction of large gains and losses exceeding a given threshold level that

    occur during turbulent months in the four restricted models and the unrestricted model we

    considered earlier. Note that during turbulent months the sensitivity of momentum strategy

    returns to the stock market return rises sharply in magnitude. Therefore it should come as no

    surprise that model 1 which is the standard market model for momentum return generating

    process but with state dependent parameters performs almost as well as the full model.

    Model 4 that corresponds to the specification of Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) about the

    same as the full unrestricted model, suggesting that the increased turbulent state sensitivity

    of momentum return to stock index return when the market recovers following a decline

    helps most in learning about the hidden state from the data.

    27

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    28/34

    Tab

    le15:

    Max

    imum

    Likel

    ihoo

    dEst

    ima

    teso

    fAlterna

    tive

    HMM

    Spec

    ifica

    tions

    Mo

    del

    1

    Mo

    del

    2

    M

    ode

    l3

    Mo

    del

    4

    Ca

    lm

    Turbu

    lent

    Ca

    lm

    Turbu

    len

    t

    Ca

    lm

    Turbu

    len

    t

    Ca

    lm

    Turbu

    len

    t

    1.4

    7

    -0.9

    2

    1.4

    9

    -0.6

    0

    2.0

    1

    4.0

    1

    1.4

    6

    0.14

    (8.1

    3)

    (-0

    .96)

    (8.5

    1)

    (-0

    .68)

    (6.9

    3)

    (3.4

    5)

    (7.7

    0)

    (1.62)

    L

    0.0

    9

    -0.9

    3

    0.2

    6

    -0.0

    5

    0.3

    9

    -0.2

    6

    0.2

    5

    -0.

    00

    (1.5

    7)

    (-9

    .66)

    (4.5

    3)

    (-0

    .32)

    (3.3

    3)

    (-1

    .74)

    (-4

    .29)

    (-0.

    02)

    LU

    -0.46

    -1.2

    7

    (-2

    .66)

    (-5

    .16)

    B

    0.0

    9

    -0.9

    3

    -0.5

    6

    -1.3

    1

    0.3

    9

    -0.2

    6

    -0.4

    5

    -0.

    85

    (1.5

    7)

    (-9

    .66)

    (-6

    .35)

    (-12

    .23)

    (3.3

    3)

    (-1

    .74)

    (-2

    .91)

    (-5.

    59)

    BU

    -0.46

    -1.2

    7

    -0.1

    3

    -0.

    80

    (-2

    .66)

    (-5

    .16)

    (-0

    .63)

    (-3.

    57)

    mom

    4.4

    5

    12

    .23

    4.1

    7

    11

    .00

    4.4

    0

    11

    .14

    4.1

    2

    10.4

    0

    (27

    .11)

    (17

    .26)

    (24

    .41)

    (17

    .08)

    (26

    .58

    )

    (18

    .04)

    (24

    .35)

    (18

    .54)

    0.9

    8

    -0.7

    4

    0.9

    6

    -0.6

    1

    1.0

    1

    -0.0

    1

    0.9

    8

    -0.

    01

    (6.9

    3)

    (-1

    .09)

    (6.7

    2)

    (-0

    .92)

    (7.1

    5)

    (-1

    .10)

    (6.8

    4)

    (-0.

    85)

    M

    3.7

    0

    9.4

    9

    3.6

    8

    9.3

    2

    3.6

    6

    9.1

    0

    3.6

    5

    8.99

    (33

    .11)

    (17

    .09)

    (32

    .38)

    (15

    .91)

    (32

    .80

    )

    (18

    .42)

    (32

    .77)

    (17

    .91)

    Pr

    (St=

    st|St1=

    st

    )

    0.9

    7

    0.8

    8

    0.9

    6

    0.8

    6

    0.9

    7

    0.9

    1

    0.9

    7

    0.90

    (81

    .44)

    (18

    .78)

    (80

    .85)

    (18

    .76)

    (96

    .51

    )

    (27

    .26)

    0.9

    0

    (24

    .64)

    Log-L

    ike

    lihoo

    d(103)

    3.0

    6

    3.1

    2

    3.0

    8

    3.1

    3

    AIC

    (103)

    -6.1

    0

    -6.2

    2

    -6.13

    -6.2

    3

    BIC

    (10

    3)

    -6.0

    5

    -6.1

    5

    -6.06

    -6.1

    5

    SharpeR

    atio

    0.3

    0

    -0.0

    6

    0.2

    8

    -0.0

    3

    0.3

    0

    -0.0

    2

    0.3

    2

    -0.

    05

    28

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    29/34

    Table 16: Fraction of Large Gains(Losses) that Occur in Turbulent Months

    Gains greater than or equal to: # ofModel

    10%

    12.5%

    15%

    17.5%

    20% Months

    1 32/69 22/42 16/27 10/14 8/11 1732 34/69 24/42 17/27 10/14 8/11 1733 40/69 28/42 18/27 10/14 8/11 1974 35/69 25/42 17/27 10/14 8/11 202

    Full 40/69 25/42 18/27 10/14 8/11 206

    Losses worse than or equal to: # ofModel 10% 12.5% 15% 17.5% 20% Months

    1 29/53 26/35 23/31 18/21 13/13 1732 28/53 24/35 21/31 16/21 12/13 1733 31/53 27/35 24/31 19/21 13/13 1974 32/53 27/35 24/31 19/21 13/13 202

    Full 33/53 27/35 25/31 20/21 13/13 206

    The scatter plots of the momentum strategy return against the predicted probability of

    the unobserved state being turbulent for the four restricted models are given in Figure 6.

    The patterns are similar across all four models, which is consistent with the results in Table

    16.

    29

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    30/34

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

    1

    0.5

    0

    0.5

    Predicted Probability

    RealizedMomentum

    Model 1

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.91

    0.5

    0

    0.5

    Predicted Probability

    RealizedMomentum

    Model 2

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.91

    0.5

    0

    0.5

    Predicted Probability

    RealizedMom

    entum

    Model 3

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

    1

    0.5

    0

    0.5

    Predicted Probability

    RealizedMomentum

    Model 4

    Figure 6: Alternative HMM specifications

    5 Conclusion

    Relative strength strategies, also known as momentum strategies are widely used by active

    quantitative portfolio managers and individual investors. These strategies generate large

    positive returns on average with little systematic risk as measured using standard asset

    pricing models and remain an anomaly.

    In this paper we studied the returns on one such momentum strategy. During the period

    covering July 1927 - December 2010 the returns on that widely studied strategy using U.S.

    stocks generated an average monthly return in excess of 1.18% and an alpha of 1.75%/month

    with respect to the three Fama and French (1993) factor model. Momentum strategy returns,

    30

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    31/34

    when combined with the Fama and French three economy wide pervasive factor returns, gives

    rise to a portfolio with a Sharpe Ratio of almost 0.30 per month.

    However momentum strategies also incur infrequent but rather large losses. There were

    five months with losses exceeding 42%/month in the sample of 1002 months. The probability

    of such an event occurring if momentum strategy returns were independently and normally

    distributed would be close to zero. We show that such periodic tail risk in momentum

    returns can be captured by a two state hidden Markov model, where one state is turbulent

    and the other is calm. We find that it is possible to predict which of the two hidden state

    the economy is in with some degree of confidence All the 13 months with losses exceeding

    20%/month occur during turbulent months, i.e., months when the predicted probability of

    the hidden state being turbulent exceeds 0.5. Momentum returns averaged -0.65%/month

    during turbulent months, with a Sharpe Ratio of -0.05. When such turbulent states are

    avoided, the monthly Sharpe Ratio of momentum strategy returns increases to 0.32 and

    price momentum poses still more of a challenge to standard asset pricing models.

    31

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    32/34

    References

    Ambasta, M., and A. Ben Dor, 2010, Barclays Capital Alternative Replicators: A syntheticapproach to replicating hedge fund performance, Barclays Capital Report.

    Amisano, G., and J. Geweke, 2011, Optimal Prediction Pools, Journal of Econometrics,164, 130141.

    Ang, A., and A. Timmerman, 2011, Regime Changes and Financial Markets, WorkingPaper.

    Asness, C. S., T. Moskowitz, and L. Pedersen, 2008, Value and Momentum Everywhere,University of Chicago working paper.

    Boguth, O., M. Carlson, A. Fisher, and M. Simutin, 2010, Conditional risk and performanceevaluation: Volatility timing, overconditioning, and new estimates of momentum alphas,

    Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

    Bollerslev, T., 1986, Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity, Journalof Econometrics, 31, 307327.

    Breen, W., L. R. Glosten, and R. Jagannathan, 1989, Economic Significance of PredictableVariations in Stock Index Returns, Journal of Finance, 44, 117789.

    Chabot, B., E. Ghysels, and R. Jagannathan, 2009, Momentum Cycles and Limits toArbitrage - Evidence from Victorian England and Post-Depression US Stock Markets,Working Paper.

    Chan, K., 1988, On the Contrarian Investment Strategy, Journal of Business, 61, 147163.

    Cooper, M. J., R. C. Gutierrez, and A. Hameed, 2004, Market States and Momentum,Journal of Finance, 59, 13451365.

    Daniel, K. D., and T. J. Moskowitz, 2011, Momentum Crashes, Columbia Business Schoolworking paper.

    DeBondt, W. F. M., and R. H. Thaler, 1987, Further Evidence on Investor Overreactionand Stock Market Seasonality, Journal of Finance, 42, 557581.

    Elavia, T., and M. Kim, 2011, Managing the volatility of alpha models, Journal of Invest-ment Management, 9, 116.

    Fama, E. F., and K. R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks andbonds, Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 356.

    Fama, E. F. F., and K. R. French, 2008, Dissecting Anomalies, Journal of Finance, 63,16531678.

    32

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    33/34

    Griffin, J. M., X. Ji, and J. S. Martin, 2003, Momentum Investing and Business Cycle Risk:Evidence from Pole to Pole, Journal of Finance, 58, 25152547.

    Grinblatt, M., and S. Titman, 1989, Mutual fund performance: an analysis of quarterly

    portfolio holdings, Journal of Business, 62, 393416.

    Grinblatt, M., and S. Titman, 1993, Performance Measurement without Benchmarks: AnExamination of Mutual Fund Returns, Journal of Business, 66, 4768.

    Grundy, B., and J. S. Martin, 2001, Understanding the Nature of the Risks and the Sourceof the Rewards to Momentum Investing, Review of Financial Studies, 14, 2978.

    Hamilton, J. D., 1989, A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary TimeSeries and the Business Cycle, Econometrica, 57, 35784.

    Henriksson, R. D., and R. C. Merton, 1981, On market timing and investment performance.

    II. Statistical procedures for evaluating forecasting skills, Journal of Business, 54, 513533.

    Jagannathan, R., and R. A. Korajczyk, 1986, Assessing the Market Timing Performanceof Managed Portfolios, Journal of Business, 59, 21735.

    Jegadeesh, N., 1990, Evidence of Predictable Behavior of Security Returns, Journal ofFinance, 45, 881898.

    Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Impli-cations for stock market efficiency, Journal of Finance, 48, 6591.

    Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 2005, Momentum, in Richard Thaler, ed.: Advances in Be-havioral Finance II, Princeton Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Jensen, M. C., 1967, Random Walks: Reality or Myth: Comment, Financial AnalystsJournal, 23, 7785.

    Korajczyk, R. A., and R. Sadka, 2004, Are Momentum Profits Robust to Trading Costs?,Journal of Finance, 59, 10391082.

    Kothari, S., and J. Shanken, 1992, Stock Return Variation and Expected Dividends, Jour-nal of Financial Economics, 31, 177210.

    Lehmann, B. N., 1990, Fads, Martingales, and Market Efficiency, Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 105, 128.

    Levy, R. A., 1967, Relative Strength as a Criterion for Investment Selection, The Journalof Finance, 22, 595610.

    Rouwenhorst, K. G., 1998, International Momentum Strategies, Journal of Finance, 53,267284.

    33

  • 8/2/2019 Tail Risk Mom

    34/34

    Swaminathan, B., 2010, Qunatitative Money Management: A practical application of be-havioral finance, Working Paper.