75
Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial Style in Syndicated Bank Loans * Yu Shan Jan 13th, 2018 Abstract In this study, I investigate the relationship between systemic risks and bankscredit risk-taking in syndicated bank loan market, and analyze how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects help explain the variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity on bank-level systemic risk. I find that systemically riskier banks originate riskier loans even after controlling for self-selection of lenders by borrowers, and this relationship is weaker during periods of economic turmoil (recessions or high CATFIN periods). Using within-loan regressions to remove the demand-side factors, I find that the result is at least partially driven by supply-side factors. Lead-lag analyses and dynamic panel GMM estimations help address the reverse causality concerns. Using factor analyses to identify executive and bank styles, I find that some idiosyncratic bank executive-specific innovation preferences can explain the variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk, indicating that unobservable executive personal traits play an important role in affecting banks reactions to potential systemic risk crisis. Also, executive-specific styles are much more important than bank-specific styles in explaining credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk. JEL Classifications: G20, G21, G24, G28. Keywords: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, Public Guarantee, Syndicated Bank Loans, Manager Style, Risk-taking, Bank Governance. * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng, Michael LaCour-Little, Nahata Rajarishi, Nancy Wallace, Sonali Hazarika, Yildiray Yildirim, and seminar/conference participants at the Baruch College Brownbag Seminar and Financial Management Association 2017 Annual Meeting for their insightful suggestions and comments. All errors are my own. Ph.D. candidate in finance, Bert W. Wasserman Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College, New York, NY 10010, E-mail: [email protected].

Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial Style in

Syndicated Bank Loans*

Yu Shan†

Jan 13th, 2018

Abstract

In this study, I investigate the relationship between systemic risks and banks’ credit risk-taking in

syndicated bank loan market, and analyze how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects help explain

the variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity on bank-level systemic risk. I find that systemically

riskier banks originate riskier loans even after controlling for self-selection of lenders by borrowers,

and this relationship is weaker during periods of economic turmoil (recessions or high CATFIN

periods). Using within-loan regressions to remove the demand-side factors, I find that the result is at

least partially driven by supply-side factors. Lead-lag analyses and dynamic panel GMM estimations

help address the reverse causality concerns. Using factor analyses to identify executive and bank

styles, I find that some idiosyncratic bank executive-specific innovation preferences can explain the

variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk, indicating that unobservable executive

personal traits play an important role in affecting banks’ reactions to potential systemic risk crisis.

Also, executive-specific styles are much more important than bank-specific styles in explaining credit

risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk.

JEL Classifications: G20, G21, G24, G28.

Keywords: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, Public Guarantee, Syndicated Bank Loans, Manager Style,

Risk-taking, Bank Governance.

* I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

Michael LaCour-Little, Nahata Rajarishi, Nancy Wallace, Sonali Hazarika, Yildiray Yildirim, and seminar/conference

participants at the Baruch College Brownbag Seminar and Financial Management Association 2017 Annual Meeting

for their insightful suggestions and comments. All errors are my own. † Ph.D. candidate in finance, Bert W. Wasserman Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business,

Baruch College, New York, NY 10010, E-mail: [email protected].

Page 2: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

1

1. Introduction

An important lesson that policymakers and academicians have taken away from the global financial

crisis of 2007-2009 is the importance of distinguishing between individual financial institutions’ risks

in isolation and their systemic risk exposure. Bank regulations that focus exclusively on the individual

institution fail to recognize systemic interrelationships that should form an important component of

macro-prudential regulation. Basel I and Basel II are designed to regulate banks’ risk in isolation, but

ignored the systemic impact of those institutions on the financial system and the real sector of

economy. Basel III capital requirements incorporate this recognition through the imposition of

countercyclical capital buffers and total loss absorbing capacity (TLAC) requirements related to

aggregate market conditions. However, systemic bank regulations are viewed as add-ons and do not

integrate established individual bank regulations to newer systemic risk regulations. If there exists a

direct connection between systemic risk and disaggregated credit risk exposure on an individual bank

basis, and if this connection is ignored, then bank regulations at one dimension could lead to

suboptimal outcomes at the other dimension. For instance, if banks regularly reduce its individual

bank risk exposure when their systemic risk rises, then systemic bank regulations can be less drastic

due to this automatic stabilizer. Alternatively, if banks regularly exacerbate their own bank risk

exposure by exploiting potential moral hazard advantages, systemic risk regulation will be

insufficient to address system-wide crises. In this paper, I build the connection between systemic risk

and individual bank’s risk-taking in the context of syndicated bank loan market.

Credit risk is a major source of risk in bank portfolios. In this study, I examine whether systemically

risky banks endogenously adjust the credit risk they take in syndicated bank loans as either the

individual micro-level or the aggregate macro-level measure of systemic risk changes. Specifically,

I test three alternative responses to systemic risk in the credit risk-taking of syndicated bank loans.

That is, banks may either reduce or increase their credit risk in their loans as their systemic risk

increases, or alternatively, there may be no connection between credit risk and systemic risk.

First, banks may reduce their own risk exposures when a systemic crisis looms in order to pull back

from the brink of insolvency. This automatic stabilizer may reduce systemic risk, thereby mitigating

some of the negative impact. This could be driven by higher charter values (Cordella and Levy-Yeyati,

2003), reducing undiversifiable contagion risk across banks (Freixas, Parigi, and Rochet, 2000; Allen

and Gale, 2001; Diamond and Rajan, 2005; Dell’Ariccia and Ratnovski, 2013; Choi, 2014),

managerial incentives (Schwarcz, 2017), and clawbacks (Allen and Li, 2011). Charter values may

induce banks to control the credit risk in their loan portfolios when systemic crises are more likely to

Page 3: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

2

occur. Either implicit or explicit government bail-out guarantees may result in higher charter values

for protected banks due to lower refinancing costs (Keeley, 1990; Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel,

2011). Thus, my first hypothesis is:

Hypothesis I: Banks’ credit risk-taking in syndicated bank loans decreases with bank’s systemic risk,

ceteris paribus.

Alternatively, systemically risky banks may exacerbate their credit risk exposure. This behavior could

be incentivized by limitations in market discipline and imperfections in regulatory pricing. A growing

literature has shown that explicit (deposit insurance) and implicit (potential bail-outs) public

guarantees may increase systemically important banks’ risk-taking by reducing market discipline

(Flannery, 1998; Sironi, 2003; Gropp, Vesala, and Vulps, 2006; Acharya, Anginer, and Warburton,

2016) and increasing moral hazard (Kane, 1989; Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache, 2002; Diamond

and Rajan, 2009; Farhi and Tirole, 2012). First, the deposit insurance premiums in US are not priced to

include actuarially fair risk premiums (Acharya, Santos, Yorulmazer, 2010) and exhibit a procyclicality

feature, which reduce the cost of high risk-taking especially for systemically risk banks (Angier, Demirguc-

Kunt, and Zhu, 2013). Second, the system of capital surcharges for GSIBs is insensitive to banks’ actual

risk-taking (Passmore and Hafften, 2017) and is completely free for non-G-SIBs, which can also be highly

systemically risky. Since the cost is not sufficiently internalized by current regulation, systemically risky

banks will rationally take advantage of it to pursue abnormal returns. Third, due to explicit and implicit

public guarantees, depositors’ and other insured stakeholders are less incentivized to monitor bank,

thereby limiting the risk premium embedded in market rates on the bank’s obligations. Acharya,

Anginer, and Warburton (2016) find that market discipline is less effective in curbing the risk-taking

behavior of systemically important financial institutions. Thus, the above arguments lead me to the

following hypothesis:

Hypothesis II: Banks’ credit risk-taking in syndicated bank loans increases with bank’s systemic risk,

ceteris paribus.

Lastly, some literature also provides evidence showing that the connection between credit risk and

systemic risk could be very weak. Credit risk relates to the idiosyncratic risk a bank is confronting,

which is an internal risk, while systemic risk is the importance of bank to the financial system and

the broader economy, which is a form of externality. Adrian and Brunnermeier (2016) suggest that

there is only a very loose cross-sectional link between institution’s risk/tail risk and its systemic risk

(Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2016). Focusing on bank charter values (rather than credit risk in the loan

Page 4: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

3

portfolio), Cordella and Yeyati (2003) and Hakenes and Schnabel (2010) argue that the net effect of

systemic risk and public guarantees on bank risk-taking is ambiguous. Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel

(2011) shows that there is no evidence that public guarantees increase the protected banks’ risk-taking,

except for banks that have outright public ownership.

This topic is particularly relevant in light of recent regulatory interventions during the 2007-2009

crisis. The explicit and implicit cost of funds from government support may actually be quite high.

First, the injected preferred equity has priority over common equity, which may amplify the losses of

common equity holders in the event of failure, resulting in a reduction in the value of common equity,

and increasing the difficulty of raising equity (Berger, Roman and Sedunov, 2016). If banks’

shareholders are concerned about the negative implications of bailouts, they may require the bank

managers to adjust the credit risk of their loans in order to pull back from the brink of delinquency

and bailout. Second, the supported banks may have to undertake certain social welfare responsibilities

through lending expansion, which may not be an equilibrium choice during economic downturns.

Recent experience with government intervention in the financial system may induce banks to reduce

their credit risk exposure in order to mitigate the bank’s own risk of insolvency, thereby reducing the

likelihood that bailouts will be needed.‡ This paper empirically examines the relationship between

systemic risk and credit risk exposure in bank loan portfolios to address these important public policy

issues.

Using data on syndicated bank loans, this paper investigates whether financial institutions adjust the

credit risk in their loan portfolios risks in response to levels of systemic risks. I measure the credit

risk using borrower distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination, while controlling for an

array of loan characteristics. I use two complementary measures of systemic risk in this paper. To

measure the macro-level aggregate systemic risk, I utilize CATFIN (Allen, Bali and Tang, 2012),

which is a cross-sectional measure that identifies the overall level of systemic risk in the financial

system at each point in time. This allows me to examine whether high levels of aggregate systemic

risk that are likely to lead to government bailouts or other interventions induce banks to adjust the

credit risk in their loan portfolios upward or downward. To measure the micro-level systemic risk, I

‡ In the wake of the 2007-2009 financial crisis, greater regulatory costs, stricter security, and higher disciplinary

pressure has been imposed on systemically important banks. For example, G-SIBs are subject to higher capital

buffer requirements, Total Loss-Absorbing Capacity (TLAC) standards, resolvability requirements, and higher

supervisory expectations. With all these higher regulatory requirements, systemically important banks may be

at a competitive disadvantage relative to other banks, leading them to reduce their lending to high risk borrowers

that may encourage regulatory scrutiny. For example, regulatory warnings regarding leveraged loans in 2014

induced banks to cut back on lending to high risk borrowers. Alternatively, however, systemically risky banks

may choose to lend to riskier borrowers in order to recoup their higher costs of bank capital.

Page 5: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

4

utilize Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 (Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2016) to determine the impact of an individual bank’s

insolvency on systemic risk in the overall financial system. The greater the contribution of an

individual bank’s insolvency to market-wide systemic risk, the greater the individual bank’s

imposition of systemic risk onto the macroeconomy. I utilize this measure to determine whether the

bank’s systemic risk exposure impacts its ability to lend to borrowers of differing risk levels.

I find that during periods of non-recession or low macro-level systemic risk, bank systemic risk is

positively related to its credit risk-taking. This indicates that banks may develop a proclivity that

encourages the pursuit of abnormal returns from risk enhancing activities. The result is robust to

several different specifications, which control for loan, borrower, and bank characteristics, as well as

a series of fixed effects and endogeneity controls. This supports Hypothesis II that bank’s credit risk-

taking in syndicated bank loans increases with bank’s systemic risk.

I also find that, when the economy enters a recession or a heightened risk of systemic crisis, the positive

relationship between systemic risk and credit risk-taking is weaker, and the banks with most systemic risk

reduce the credit risk in their loan portfolios the most. This indicates that, during volatile periods, the

heightened risk of insolvency and the growing importance of bank charter value dominate the incentives to

exploit abnormal returns from risk-taking. Thus, banks pull back from the brink of insolvency by reducing

their credit risk, particularly if they have a high exposure to systemic risk. Indeed, during these volatile

periods, my results show that systemically important banks actually maintain high levels of systemic risk

while also reducing their credit risk exposure in order to improve the likelihood that they would benefit

from government bailouts. Since the federal government does not have any explicit, ex-ante commitment

to support a distressed bank, banks do not know in advance whether they will be rescued once they become

financially distressed. The combination of increased systemic risk and reduced loan portfolio credit risk

may improve the likelihood that the bank receives government support. These results are consistent with

the Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2016) policy uncertainty index, which hit a peak after Lehman Brothers failed,

as well as the subsequent reforms codified in the Dodd-Frank Act and the Consumer Protection Act which

explicitly aim to reduce expectations of government shield. Further, consistent with my results, lower credit

risk in the loan portfolio may reduce regulatory capital requirements, thereby reducing the bank’s risk of

failure.

In the baseline regressions, the borrower self-selection and lender-borrower matching is endogenous.

In other words, the probability of initiating a new loan between firm i and bank j is endogenous. It’s

possible that some unobservable borrower characteristics induce borrowing firms to choose to apply

for loans from certain banks, thereby introducing selection bias into the OLS analysis. Therefore, I

Page 6: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

5

must control for the probability of originating a loan between firm i and bank j that is independent of

the channel of systemically risky banks selecting borrower with certain default risks. That is, the

lending relationship measure used as a control variable in my baseline regressions is itself endogenous.

In order to reduce this endogeneity, I conduct a two-stage-least-square analysis and employ the

geographic distance and number of banks in the state of the borrower as instruments for observed

lending relationships. In the first stage, I regress the lending relationship variable on geographic

distance and number of banks, and other independent variables. In the second stage, I re-run the

baseline regression using fitted value of lending relationship in all specifications. The results are

consistent with those in the baseline regressions.

The baseline results indicate that systemically risky banks are matched with risky borrowers in the

syndicated bank loan market. However, it is unclear whether high systemic risk leads to high credit risk-

taking or vice versa. To address this, I use a set of lead-lag regressions, using contemporaneous borrower’s

distance-to-default or lender’s Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 as the dependent variables, and test whether they are associated

with lagged lender’s Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 or lagged borrower’s distance-to-default. I find that higher lender’s systemic

risk in quarter t-1 is associated with higher borrower’s credit risk in quarter t, while higher borrower credit

risk in quarter t-1 is not necessarily associated with higher lender’s systemic risk in quarter t. This indicates

that the causality very likely extends from systemic risk to credit risk-taking and not vice versa.

Banks control the credit risk in their loan portfolios by adjusting their credit and underwriting

standards. However, borrowers may also respond to bank risk-taking. For example, riskier borrowers

may be more dependent on stable refinancing sources especially during economic downturns.

Therefore, riskier borrowers may tend to request loans from systemically important banks, which

may be protected by public guarantees, and therefore maybe more likely to survive during periods of

economic turmoil. Thus, it is hard to disentangle the supply-side or demand-side effects empirically.

In this study, I empirically control for the demand effects of lending at systemically important banks

using within-loan analysis. Thus, I test my findings of a direct relationship between systemic risk and

credit risk using a within-loan regression analysis that controls for borrower self-selection lenders

(Chu, Zhang and Zhao, 2017). Taking advantage of the unique feature that a syndicated loan often

has multiple lenders, I examine how the systemic risks of banks that fund the same loan affect their

contributions to the loan, i.e., within-loan estimation, which eliminates any fluctuation on the

demand-side. Consistent with my previous findings, I find systemically risky banks contribute a large

(smaller) portion to risky (safe) loans, and the results are more significant for loans whose risk are

more extreme relative to other loans originated in the same year. This result indicates that my previous

findings are at least partially driven by supply-side factors.

Page 7: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

6

Endogeneity can arise from reverse causality, meaning that current values of bank systemic risk can

be affected by credit risk-taking in previous periods. Current values of systemic risk may not be

independent of the credit risk-taking on previous loans, and ignoring the dynamic nature of the

independent and dependent variable relationship may yield biased and inconsistent estimates

(Wintoki, Linck, and Netter, 2012). To alleviate the reverse causality concern, I follow Wintoki,

Linck, and Netter (2012) by utilizing a dynamic panel GMM estimation. There are several advantages

of using dynamic panel GMM method. First, it allows current explanatory variables to be influenced

by previous realizations of dependent variable. Second, it eliminates unobservable heterogeneity by

first differencing all dependent and independent variables. Third, if utilize the combination of

variables from the history as valid instruments to account for simultaneity. The dynamic panel GMM

estimation confirms my pervious findings.

I then analyze how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects help explain the variation in credit risk-

taking sensitivity on bank-level systemic risk. Even though I find a positive relationship between

systemic risk and credit risk-taking, different banks, possibly with different risk-taking cultures, may

react to changes in systemic risks very differently. It is indeed the case. There is a wide variation in

credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk across banks, which raises the question of what factor

is driving this heterogeneous reaction of credit risk-taking to systemic risk changes. Recent literature

has been focusing on the roles of bank executives and their effects on bank risk-taking culture and

extreme risk exposure (Berger, Kick and Schaeck, 2014; Nguyen, Hagendorff and Eshraghi, 2017),

and Hagendorff et. al. (2017) suggest that compensation and various other observable executive

characteristics can only describe a small amount of the variation in banks business model and risk-

taking preference, and they find that much of the variation in bank business policy can be explained

by executive factors (“styles”) that are time-invariant, which helps explain the risk-taking culture in

some banks. Since bank credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk is largely related to banks

business models and how banks are managed (aggressively or conservatively) by the executives, its

variation may also be explained by the unobservable, time-invariant executive fixed effects.

Motivated by the recent work of Hagendorff et. al (2017), I provide evidence that idiosyncratic

executive-specific effects (“styles”) can also help explain a large variation in banks’ credit risk-taking

sensitivity on systemic risk. Focusing on executives including CEOs, CFOs, COOs, and executive

directors and using a connectedness sample method of Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (AKM,

thereafter) (1999), I run a series of three-way fixed effects regressions (bank, executives, and year)

to estimate bank and executive fixed effects, and then conduct factor analysis for the executive and

bank fixed effects to extract factors that dominant in explaining pattern across the styles of individual

Page 8: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

7

executives and banks. The two dominant factors capture two dimensions of innovations that

executives and banks show preferences: asset-side and liability-side. I find executives’ asset- and

liability-side innovation preferences significantly affect a bank’s credit risk-taking and credit risk-

taking sensitivity on systemic risk, while banks’ innovation preferences don’t. Based on the loadings

of individual executives on the two factors, I assign executive into four types: (1) Asset innovator but

liability traditionalist; (2) Asset and liability innovator; (3) Asset and liability traditionalist; (4) Asset

traditionalist and liability innovator. I find that banks managed by different types of executives exhibit

very different credit risk-taking sensitivities on systemic risk.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and sample construction

for the main tests and with-in loan models. Section 3 presents the empirical results, including the

baseline results, a two-stage least squares analysis controlling for borrower self-selection, a lead-lag

analysis, and within-loan estimations. Section 4 provides robustness checks, including a different

version of within-loan regression and a dynamic panel GMM analysis. Section 5 focus on how

idiosyncratic executive-specific effects help explain the variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity on

bank-level systemic risk. Section 6 concludes.

2. Data and Variable Constructions

2.1. Credit Risk: Borrowing Firm Distance-to-default

In this paper, I use the Merton distance-to-default as a measure of borrower default risk. Since credit risk

can also be affected by loan characteristics such as loan amount, maturity, and being secured or not, I

control for an array of loan characteristics. I follow Bharath and Bharath and Shumway (2008) and Crosbie

and Bohn (2003) in calculating Merton’s distance-to-default. The market equity value of a company is

modeled as a call option on the company’s assets:

𝑉𝐸 = 𝑉𝐴𝑒−𝑑𝑇𝑁(𝑑1) − 𝑋𝑒−𝑟𝑇𝑁(𝑑2) + (1 − 𝑒−𝑑𝑇)𝑉𝐴 (1)

𝑑1 =log(

𝑉𝐴𝑋

)+(𝑟+𝑠𝐴

2

2)𝑇

𝑠𝐴; 𝑑2 = 𝑑1 − 𝑠𝐴√𝑇 (2)

where 𝑉𝐸 is the market value of a firm’s equity, which is calculated from the CRSP database as the product

of share price at the end of the quarter and the number of shares outstanding. X is the face value of debt

maturing at time T, which is calculated as debt in current liabilities (COMPUSTAT data item 45) plus one

half of long term debt (COMPUSTAT data item 51). 𝑉𝐴 is the value of the firm’s assets. r is the risk-free

rate, which is defined as the 1-year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate obtained from the Board of Governors

Page 9: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

8

of the Federal Reserve system. 𝑠𝐴 is the volatility of the value of assets. I simultaneously solve the above

two equations to find the values of 𝑉𝐴 and 𝑠𝐴. Quarterly Merton’s distance-to-default is finally computed as:

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 =log (

𝑉𝐴

𝑋) + (𝑚 −

𝑠𝐴2

2)𝑇

𝑠𝐴√𝑇 (3)

As a robustness check, I also calculate quarterly distance-to-default by first calculating the monthly

distance-to-default and then taking quarterly averages. Both measures generate similar results in the

baseline regressions.

2.2. Systemic Risks

To measure the micro-level systemic risk, I follow the methodology used in Adrian and Brunnermeier

(2016) to generate time-varying Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅. First, I run the following quantile regressions in the weekly data

(where j is a financial institution):

𝑋𝑡𝑗

= 𝛼𝑞𝑗

+ 𝛾𝑞𝑗𝑀𝑡−1 + 𝜖𝑞,𝑡

𝑗, (4)

𝑋𝑡𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

= 𝛼𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

𝑀𝑡−1 + 𝛽𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

𝑀𝑡−1 + β𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

𝑋𝑡𝑗

+ 𝜖𝑞,𝑡𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

, (5)

where 𝑋𝑡𝑗 is the weekly return of institution j in week t, 𝑋𝑡

𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗 is the financial sector return in week t,

and 𝑀𝑡−1 is a vector of seven systematic state variables in week t, including three-month yield change,

term spread change, TED spread, credit spread change, market return, real estate excess return, equity

volatility. Then I generate the predicted values from these regressions to obtain

𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

= �̂�𝑞𝑗

+ 𝛾𝑞𝑗𝑀𝑡−1, (6)

𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

= �̂�𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

+ �̂�𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

𝑀𝑡−1 + �̂�𝑞𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗

𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

, (7)

Finally, I compute the 𝛥𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

for each institution:

𝛥𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

= 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

− 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅50,𝑡𝑗

= �̂�𝑠𝑦𝑠𝑡𝑒𝑚|𝑗(𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

− 𝑉𝑎𝑅50,𝑡𝑗

) (8)

From these regressions, I get a panel of weekly 𝛥𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

. I obtain a quarterly time series of 𝛥𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑞,𝑡𝑗

by averaging the weekly risk measures within each quarter. Throughout the paper, I use q equals 99%, but

my results are robust to the 95% level.

Page 10: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

9

To construct the macro-level systemic risk, CATFIN§, I follow Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012) and first

estimate VaR at the 99% confidence level using three different methodologies - the generalized Pareto

distribution (GPD), the skewed generalized error distribution (SGED) and the non-parametric

estimation method based on the left tail of the actual empirical distribution without any assumptions

about the underlying return distribution. CATFIN is defined as the arithmetic average of the GPD,

SGED and non-parametric VaR measures.

Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012) suggest that the risk of macroeconomic downturns increases when

CATFIN is above some early warning level, where early warning level is determined by using Chicago

Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI) as a benchmark. CFNAI is an index of eighty-five existing

monthly economic indicators. The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago denotes the three-month moving

average of CFNAI (CFNAI-MA3) value of -0.7 as a turning point indicating economic contraction, and

Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012) show that when CATFIN is above some early warning level, it can

significantly predict lower economic activity (CFNAI-MA3) one month to eight months in advance of

the downturn. Therefore, CATFIN offers an early warning to alert regulators to the risk of economic

recessions. In this paper, I also test whether the credit risk of the banks’ loan portfolio is affected by

whether CATFIN breaches the early warning level. Following Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012), I

construct an early warning dummy, which is equal to 1 if CATFIN is above the early warning level,

and 0 otherwise. For each quarter t, the early warning level is calculated as the median CATFIN using

all observations up to quarter t in which CFNAI-MA3 falls below -0.7. To address possible reverse

causality, I utilize both contemporaneous and lagged measures of systemic risk to examine the

following quarter’s credit risk in the bank’s loan portfolio. A historical monthly CATFIN, CFNAI-

MA3, Early Warning Level, and Warning dummy are presented in the Online Appendix.

2.3. Control Variables

I use a set of control variables to control for loan characteristics, borrower characteristics and lender

characteristics. To ensure that outliers do not heavily influence statistical results, I set all observations

higher than the 99th percentile of each variable to that value; all values lower than the 1st percentile of

each variable are similarly winsorized. All variables are defined in the appendix.

The first set of control variables include bank characteristics, such as Bank Total Assets, Bank Capital Ratio,

Return on Equity, Liquidity, Loan Charge-offs, Loan Loss Allowance, and Risk-Weighted Assets. Since

§ I thank Linda Allen and Yi Tang for providing the data on their CATFIN systemic risk measure and Tobias Adrian

and Markus Brunnermeier for making their measure of systemic risk (∆CoVaR) available.

Page 11: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

10

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is constructed using market data and most public banks are bank holding companies, I measure

bank financial information at the bank holding company level. ln(Bank Total Assets) is defined as the

natural logarithm of bank total assets (in billions); Bank Capital Ratio is defined as the bank’s total capital

over bank’s total assets; Bank ROE is defined as bank net income over book equity; Bank Liquidity is

defined as the sum of cash and available-for-sale securities divided by bank total assets; Loan Charge-offs

is defined as the total charge-offs on loans and leases divided by bank total assets; Loan Loss Allowance is

defined as the total allowance for loan and lease losses divided by bank total assets; Risk-Weighted Assets

is defined as total risk weighted assets divided by bank total assets. Although I include both lead lenders

and participants in all my regressions, I add a lead bank dummy in the within-loan regressions to

account for possible unobservable differences between lead and non-lead banks. I define a bank as a

lead lender if its lend arranger credit variable is “Yes” in Dealscan.

The second set of control variables consists of borrower characteristics. ln(Borrower Total Assets) is

defined as the natural logarithm of total assets (in billions); Tangibility is defined as total property, plant,

and equipment divided by total assets; Leverage is defined as the total debt divided by total assets. I also

include a lending relationship measure, as in Bharath et al. (2007) since the intensity of past lending

relationships can have an impact on the matching between borrowers and lenders. The lending relationship

between borrower i and bank j is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in the last 5

years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years.

Then I control for an array of loan characteristics. ln(Package Amount) is defined as the natural log of the

package amount, where package amount is measured in millions. ln(Package Maturity) is defined as the

natural log of the maturity of the deal in months. Package maturity is calculated as the value-weighted

average of the facility maturities. ln(No. of Lead Banks) is the natural log of the number of lead lenders in

the deal syndicate.

Finally, I control for macroeconomic conditions. I use quarterly GDP per capita growth rate to measure the

macroeconomic performance. I also generate a recession dummy (Recession) to test the differential effect

of bank systemic risk on credit risk-taking in expansion and recession periods. The recession dummy equals

1 if the month of loan origination is designated by NBER to be a contraction month and 0 if it is designated

to be an expansion month.

2.4. Sample Construction

The sample period of my study spans Q1 1995 to Q4 2013. Banks’ financial data are collected from the

Consolidated Financial Statements for Holding Companies (“FR Y-9C”) available on the Federal Reserve

Page 12: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

11

Bank of Chicago website, and all market data are obtained from CRSP. Borrowing firms’ financial data are

collected from Compustat. Syndicated loan data are obtained from Loan Pricing Corporation’s (LPC)

Dealscan loan database. The Dealscan database contains historical information on the terms and conditions

of deals in the global syndicated bank loan market. Borrower financial data are linked to Dealscan using

the Dealscan-Compustat linking data provided by Chava and Roberts (2008, updated in Aug. 2012). All

observations are quarterly.

To construct the sample, I first start with a sample of 219,023 deal packages newly originated between Jan.

1995 and Dec. 2013 from the LPC Dealscan database. Since in this paper I conduct my analysis at the bank

holding company level, I need to first identify the lenders in my sample and their ultimate parent companies.

I utilize the information provided by the Federal Reserve System via its National Information Center (NIC)

database to identify financial institutions acting as lenders in my sample. I do not use the identity variables

for lender and ultimate owner in Dealscan because Dealscan overwrites the ultimate owner of the lenders

after mergers and acquisitions, i.e., the ultimate owner in Dealscan is the ultimate owner at the end of the

merger chain. In this analysis, I must identify the ultimate bank holding company or lending parent at the

time of the issuance of each loan. The NIC database provides detailed information about financial

institutions, including types of institutions, establishment time, ownership information, address changes,

name changes, merger and acquisition history. NIC also provides each financial institution’s RSSD ID, a

unique identifier assigned to each financial institution by the Federal Reserve System. Based on the lender

information provided by Dealscan, including name, location and lending history, I manually find each

lender’s RSSD ID. Using their RSSD ID, which is item RSSD9001 in the Call Report and Y-9C databases,

the lender’s ultimate owner at the time of loan origination is determined by cross-checking the information

contained in Call Report items RSSD ID of Regulatory High Holder 1 (RSSD9348), Financial Higher

Holder ID (RSSD9364), and Financial High Holder Percent of Equity (RSSD9365). The three items provide

the RSSD ID (RSSD9001) of a lender’s ultimate bank holding company during the time when a lead

arranger has a RSSD ID. For a bank that was acquired by another bank and lost its RSSD ID but kept its

lending activity, the acquirer’s RSSD ID was applied to the acquired bank as its new RSSD ID, and the

new ultimate owner can be found from the Call Report and Y-9C items RSSD9348, RSSD9364, and

RSSD9365. The full bank and bank holding companies merger and acquisition history is obtained from the

Federal Bank of Chicago. Using the RSSD ID, I link Dealscan to the Y-9C to obtain bank financial data. I

also link Dealscan to CRSP to collect market data through the PERMCO-RSSD link table provided by the

Federal Reserve Bank of New York. I collect bank characteristics data at the bank holding company level

using Y-9C reports. Using the PERMCO-RSSD link, I merge bank holding companies with their systemic

risk measure, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅. This process reduces my sample to 80,193 packages (140,609 package-lender pairs).

Page 13: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

12

Next, I merge borrower characteristics from Compustat with the information on corporate loans in

Dealscan using the linking table provided by Chava and Roberts (2008, updated in Aug. 2012). This

table matches loan facilities from Dealscan with the borrower’s GVKEY identifier in Compustat. Due

to differences in capital structures and financing strategies between financial and non-financial firms,

I exclude loans to financial companies (SIC between 6000 and 6999) from the sample. I also exclude

the utility firms (SIC code falls between 4900 and 4999) because they may have different operating and

reporting environments. This leads to a sample of 10,915 packages (22,595 package-lender pairs), which

include 3,603 unique borrowers, and 214 unique banks, which are owned by 66 unique publicly traded bank

holding companies with Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 data. Since systemic risk Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is mostly measured at the bank

holding company level, in my subsequent analysis, I run all regressions at the loan-bank holding company

level.

2.5. Summary Statistics for Baseline Regressions

I present the summary statistics in Table 1. There are in total 22,595 lender-package observations in the

baseline regressions. I only use package level data in my baseline regression. The key dependent variable

is borrower’s quarterly distance-to-default, which has a mean of 6.772, a median of 6.002, and a standard

deviation of 4.903. The key independent variables are Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅, which has a mean of 5.216, a median of

4.351, and a standard deviation of 2.550, and CATFIN, which has a mean of 2.393, a median of 2.286, and

a standard deviation of 0.926. The average deal amount is US$878 million, with average maturity of 49

months. On average, there are 4.141 lead lenders in each package. The Lending Relationship between

borrower i and lender j, which is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in last 5 years

over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years, has a mean of 0.47, indicating that on

average each bank engaged in 47% of the total amount a typical firm borrowed in the 5 years preceding the

loan origination. Borrowers have an average size of $6.752 billion, with a mean tangibility of 0.310 and

leverage of 0.322. Banks have a mean size of $779 billion, with mean capital ratio of 8.5% and return on

equity of 8.3%.

Table 2 presents the spearman correlation matrix for the variables included in the baseline regressions.

As shown in Table 2, borrower distance-to-default is negatively correlated with both Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 (the

bank-specific measure of systemic risk) and CATFIN (the aggregate measure of systemic risk), with

correlation coefficients of -0.220 and -0.289, respectively. This provides preliminary evidence that

banks with higher levels of systemic risk lend to borrowers with higher credit risk during periods of

high aggregate systemic risk.

Page 14: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

13

2.6. Sample Construction for Within-loan Regressions

To investigate whether the relationship between systemic risks and borrower default risk is driven by the

bank size, in Section 3 and Section 4, I apply the within-loan estimations methodology from Chu, Zhang

and Zhao (2017). By adding package (facility) fixed effects, I can remove the impact of the demand-

side factors from the supply-side factors.

The sample of within-loan regressions is constructed differently from the one used in the baseline

regressions. First, since all borrower, loan, and macroeconomic characteristics drop out in a package

or facility fixed effects regression, only lender characteristics are relevant to the within-loan

regressions. Second, to control for an array of lender characteristics, I use a broader set of lender

variables, which includes bank size, capital ratio, return on equity, liquidity, loan charge-offs, loan loss

allowance, and risk-weighted assets, to control for lender characteristics and avoid omitted variable bias.

Bank liquidity is the sum of cash and available-for-sale securities divided by bank total assets. Loan charge-

offs is defined as the total charge-offs on loans and leases divided by bank total assets. Loan loss allowance

is the total allowance for loan and lease losses divided by bank total assets. Risk-weighted assets is the total

risk weighted assets divided by bank total assets. Third, since I employ the bank allocation share variable

in Dealscan to measure bank lending at the individual facility/package level, I put a series of

requirements on this variable to increase its validity. The sample is constructed as follows.

I construct my samples for the within-loan estimation at the package level and facility level,

separately, because the data processing procedures are different between the two levels. I first

construct my sample for within-loan estimations at the facility level. I start with an initial sample of

246,260 loan facilities originated between Jan. 1995 and Dec. 2013. Following Chu, Zhang, and Zhao

(2017), I focus on 182,745 facilities that involve credit lines, term loans, or both in my analysis since

they are the dominant types of bank loans borrowed by non-financial firms. I further require the

facility to have at least two banks as lenders, because the allocation share for a sole-lender loan is

always 100%. This reduces the sample to 152,549 facilities. Based on lenders’ name, city, state, and

dates of their earliest and latest lending activities, I manually search for their RSSD ID through the

National Information Center, and drop all lenders that don’t have an identifiable RSSD ID. Next, I

identify the ultimate holding companies of those banks from the Consolidated Financial Statements

for Holding Companies (FR Y-9C), following the same methodologies introduced in Section 2.4, and

drop lenders that don’t have an identifiable ultimate holding company in quarter t-1, where t is the

quarter of loan origination. This reduces the sample size to 80,041 facilities.

Page 15: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

14

DealScan reports a bank’s allocation share in a facility for about 31.78% of all lender-facility pairs.

For each bank in each facility, Dealscan reports the allocation share in percentages. Since I use a

bank’s allocation share to measure bank lending at the individual facility level, I exclude loans

without bank allocation share information or with allocation share greater than 100%, which is

apparently erroneous. Since Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is estimated at the bank holding company level, for consistency

I also calculate the allocation share at the bank holding company level. For example, if both bank A

and bank B belong to a same bank holding company C, and if bank A and bank B participate in a

same facility with allocation shares of 10% and 20%, respectively, then I will treat this as bank

holding company C contributing 30% to the facility. If the allocation share for A or B is missing or

greater than 100%, then I entirely remove the observations of A, B and C on this loan because they

will give erroneous allocation share at the level of bank holding company C. I also drop all facilities

in which the sum of all lender shares exceeds 110%. I choose 110% to account for rounding and

minor errors). The above treatments lead to a sample of 15,850 facilities.

Then I restrict my sample to loans from banks with non-missing market equity data, systemic risk

data and Y-9C financial data in quarter t and t-1. This leads to a sample of 10,800 facilities, which

involve 148 unique banks. These 148 banks belong to 68 unique bank holding companies. I then

identify the borrowing firms from Compustat using the DealScan-Compustat linking table provided

by Chava and Roberts (2009, updated in Aug. 2012). For loans originated after Aug. 2012, I manually

adjust the changes in the link by comparing borrower companies’ names in the two databases. I

require the borrowing firms to have SIC code and distance-to-default in quarter t-1 and t to be

included in the sample, and I exclude utility firms and financial firms (two-digit SIC code equal to

49 or between 60 and 69). These procedures lead to a sample of 3,797 facilities, which involve 123

unique banks that correspond to 66 unique bank holding companies.

The sample construction at the package level follows similar procedures as that at the facility level

with several differences. First, I only keep the observations of a bank holding company j in a package

k if the bank allocation share data is non-missing for all its subsidiaries in all facilities under this

package. Otherwise, the bank holding company’s observation in package k is entirely removed from

the sample. For example, bank A and bank B belong to a same bank holding company C, and A

contributes 30% only to facility F1, and B precipitates only in facility F2 but its contribution share

data is missing. F1 and F2 are under the same package. In this case, I remove the observation for C

entirely from this package because its total contribution will be biased downward due to the missing

data. Second, the allocation share for bank holding company j in package k is defined as the total

allocation shares of all banks that belong to j and participate in the package k. A bank’s allocation

Page 16: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

15

share in a package is its allocation share multiplied by facility amount and then divided by package

amount. Third, the lead lender dummy for bank holding company j in package k is 1 if at least one of

its subsidiaries acts as a lead lender in at least one facility under the package k. The final package

level sample includes 3,081 packages, which involve 123 unique banks that correspond to 66 bank

holding companies.

For both levels, I include the lending relationship measure (Bharath et al., 2007) to control for the intensity

of past lending relationship. The lending relationship between borrower i and bank j is defined as the dollar

amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in last 5 years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i

in last 5 years. In my within-loan regressions, the observations are by facility-bank holding company pairs,

while lending relationship is a bank-borrower level measure. In many cases, two or more banks that belong

to the same bank holding company may participate in a same loan. In those cases, I add up their bank level

lending relationship measure to create a bank holding company level measure. The rationale behind is that

the proprietary information obtained from past lending activities are shared among banks that belong to a

same bank holding company.

To account for possible unobservable differences between lead and non-lead banks, I add a lead bank

dummy in the regressions, which is equal to 1 if a bank is the lead bank in the package/facility, and 0

otherwise. I define a bank as a lead lender if its lead lender credit variable is “Yes” in Dealscan. The lead

lender credit variable is by facility-bank pairs, and two or more banks that belong to a same bank holding

company may participate in a same facility but some of them may be lead lenders while the others are not.

To create a bank holding company level lead lender dummy, I assign the dummy a value of 1 if at least one

of its bank acted as a lead lender in the facility.

I present the summary statistics for key variables describing borrower characteristics, bank characteristics,

and loan characteristics in Table 3. Panel A of Table 3 presents the descriptive statistics at the package level

and Panel B of Table 3 presents the descriptive statistics at the facility level. At the package (facility) level,

the borrower distance-to-default has a mean value of 8.181 (8.056) and a standard deviation of 5.073 (5.102).

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 has a mean value of 4.705 (4.701) and a standard deviation of 2.684 (2.643). On average, a bank

contributes 10.513% (11.013%) of the total package (facility) amount, and the standard deviation of bank

allocation is 10.307% (10.914%). The mean value of Bank Total Assets is 692.547 (706.372) billion and

Bank Capital Ratio has a mean value of 9.2% (9.3%). The average package (facility) amount is 1027.549

(741.714) million, and on average, each package (facility) has 2.304 (2.224) lead banks.

Page 17: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

16

3. Empirical Results

3.1. Baseline Results

I first present the baseline results. I estimate the following model:

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼2𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 + 𝛼3Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 + 𝛼4Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1

+ 𝛼5𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝛼6𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑘,𝑡 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡

+ 𝛼8𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼9𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼10𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑡 + 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟 𝐹𝐸

+ 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦 𝐹𝐸 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 (9)

where subscript i, j, k and t indicate the firm, the bank, the package, and the time (quarter), respectively.

The regressions are run at the package level. The dependent variable, 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡, is borrower’s

distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination. The explanatory variables of interest are Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅

and CATFIN, as well as their interaction. The vectors of variables Loan Controls, Bank Controls, and

Borrower Controls contain loan, bank, and firm-specific control variables from the quarter of loan

origination.

In all regressions, I include calendar year fixed effects to remove time trends, and industry and bank

fixed effects to remove time-invariant factors that drive matching between borrowers and lenders. I

control for bank size to distinguish the effects of size and systemic risk on borrower-lending choice.

I also control for bank capital ratio and return on equity since undercapitalized or less profitable banks

may refrain from lending to risky borrowers. I include controls for borrower characteristics (asset

tangibility, size, and leverage) to mitigate the impact of demand-side factors that are correlated with

both the firms distance to default and firm’s choice of bank. Loan Controls include the natural

logarithm of deal amount, maturity, and number of lead lenders. To distinguish secured loans from

unsecured loans, I also add a dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the loan is secured, and 0 otherwise.

Since relationship lending affects lender-borrower matching, I include the lending relationship measure

from Bharath et al. (2007). The lending relationship between borrower i and bank j is defined as the dollar

amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in last 5 years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i

in last 5 years. Finally, I add quarterly GDP growth rate to control for macroeconomic conditions.

Table 4 reports the regression results. In Column I and II, I only include the variables of interest and fixed

effects in the regressions. In Column III and IV, I add all other control variables. The results in Column I

to IV show a significant inverse relation between borrower distance-to-default and the bank’s micro-

Page 18: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

17

level measure of systemic risk. The coefficients on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and lagged Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 in all four columns

are negative and significant at the 1% level. The results show that higher bank systemic risk exposure

is associated with lower borrower distance-to-default, i.e., higher borrower credit risk. That is,

systemically important banks tend to lend to borrowers with high default risk. The coefficients on

both lagged and contemporaneous CATFIN are also negative and significant at the 1% level,

indicating that credit risk in bank loan portfolios is high (i.e., borrowers’ distance-to-default is low)

during periods of high aggregate systemic risk. Economically, taking the coefficients of -0.078 and

-0.452 in Column IV, starting from mean value, one standard deviation increase (2.550) in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅

is associated with a decrease in distance-to-default by 0.199, which a 0.041 standard deviation (4.903)

decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default and a 2.937% decrease from the mean value (6.772) of distance-

to-default; One standard deviation increase (0.926) in CATFIN is associated with a decrease in distance-to-

default by 0.419, which is a 0.085 standard deviation (4.903) decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default

and 6.190% decrease from the mean value (6.772) of distance-to-default. Thus, the empirical results in

Table 4 support Hypothesis II.

To perform a quasi-diff-in-diff analysis, I interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN in Column V to investigate

how aggregate systemic risk affects the relation between Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and borrower distance to default.

The signs, magnitude, and significance of the coefficients on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN remain. The

coefficient on the interaction term is positive and significant at 1% level, although its magnitude is

much smaller than the coefficients on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN. Actually, even though the sign of the

interaction term is positive, unless CATFIN is extremely high, the net effect of changes in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅

on borrower distance-to-default is still significantly negative with large economic magnitude. For

example, when CATFIN is at its median level (2.286), one standard deviation increase in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is

associated with 0.073 standard deviation decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default, which is an even

larger effect than shown in Column IV. Only when CATFIN is much higher than median values do

banks with high individual levels of systemic risk reduce the credit risk in their loan portfolios. The

aggregate effect of an increase in both Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN is also strong. For example, a

simultaneous one standard deviation increase in both Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN is associated with a 0.135

standard deviation decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default. These results suggest that banks reduce

their individual credit risk exposure when aggregate systemic risk is high, thereby lending to safer

borrowers when the risk of recession increases. That is, the negative relation between Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and

borrower distance to default is weakened during periods of high CATFIN. As robustness checks, I

perform another two tests. First, in Column VI, I replace CATFIN by a Recession dummy, which is

equal to 1 if the quarter of loan origination is an economic recession quarter, and 0 otherwise. The

Page 19: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

18

result is similar as in Column VI. The relationship between Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and borrower distance to default

is weakened, but still remains. In Column VII, I replace CATFIN by an Early Warn dummy, which

equal to 1 when CATFIN exceeds its early warning level, and 0 otherwise. As shown in Column VII,

the result remains similar as Column VII. Economically, taking the coefficient of -0.195 on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 in

Column VII, one standard deviation increase in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is associated with 0.101 standard deviation

decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default. If the loan is originated during periods when the early warning

level is breached, then one standard deviation increase in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is only associated with 0.047 standard

deviation decrease in the borrower’s distance-to-default.

The results in Column V, VI, and VII indicate that, during periods of very high levels of aggregate

systemic risk, recession or when the early warning has been triggered, banks with high individual

levels of systemic risk reduce the credit risk in their loan portfolios. This result is consistent with

some mitigation of moral hazard by systemically important banks during crisis (or imminent crisis)

periods, as these banks attempt to pull back from the brink by reducing the credit risk in their loan

portfolios. This is consistent with Anginer, Demirguc-Kunt, and Zhu (2014), which finds that moral

hazard seems to be dominating during calm periods. Note that the coefficients on bank total assets

remain insignificant in all columns of Table 4. Large banks do not necessarily take on higher credit

risk in their loan portfolios. This result, together with the coefficient on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅, indicates that moral

hazard incentives impact all systemically important banks rather than only big banks.

3.2. 2SLS: Self-selection and Lender-borrower Matching

In the baseline regressions, the borrower self-selection and lender-borrower matching is endogenous.

In other words, the probability of initiating a new loan between firm i and bank j is endogenous. It

could be that some unobservable borrower characteristics induce borrowing firms to choose to apply

for loans from certain banks, thereby introducing selection bias into the OLS analysis. Therefore, I

must control for the probability of originating a loan between firm i and bank j that is independent of

the channel of systemically risky banks selecting borrower with certain default risks. That is, the

lending relationship measure used as a control variable in my baseline regressions is itself endogenous.

In order to reduce this endogeneity, I employ the geographic distance and number of banks in the

state of the borrower as instruments for observed lending relationships. Geographic distance is

measured as the distance in thousands of kilometers between the location of the firm and the location

of the parent company of the lending bank in the quarter of loan origination. Geographic distance

proxies for information asymmetries and transportation costs (Degryse and Ongena, 2005) which

impede the bank’s ability to monitor a firm’s financial condition. This may reduce the likelihood of

Page 20: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

19

a loan origination. The number of banks in the borrowing firm’s state of incorporation is measured

as the number of financial institutions that filed Call Report during the quarter of loan origination.

Both instruments should affect the probability of originating loans between a certain pair of borrower

and lender, but is unlikely to affect how systemically risky banks are matched with borrowers with

differing default probabilities.

In the first stage, I regress the lending relationship variable on geographic distance and number of

banks, and other independent variables. Table 5 reports the regression diagnostics for all

specifications in Table 6, and Table 6 reports the results for the first stage regression. In Table 5, I

first report the Anderson LM test statistic for tests of identification. The null hypothesis tested is that

the instruments and endogenous variable are not correlated and, in addition, that the overidentifying

restrictions are valid. The p-values is close to 0, which strongly rejects the null hypothesis. Then, I

report the Sargan's chi-square statistic, which tests the joint null hypothesis that the excluded

instruments are valid instruments (i.e., uncorrelated with the error term) and correctly excluded from

the estimated equation. The Sargan’s chi-square test statistics are insignificant in all specifications.

This implies that the excluded instruments are valid instruments and correctly excluded from the

estimated equation.

Table 6 shows that the distance coefficient is significantly negative in the lending relationship first

stage regression. The further the borrower is from the lender, the less likely that they will have a

lending relationship. The coefficient on No. of Banks is negative but insignificant. The negative sign

is very intuitive; the more banks operating in the state of the borrower, the less likely that the borrower

and lender will have a lending relationship.

Table 7 reports the results for the second stage regression using Distance to Default as the dependent

variable. I use the fitted value of lending relationship in all specifications. The coefficient estimates

on both 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 and 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 are negative and statistically significant at the 1% level as in the OLS

results reported in Table 4. Although the lagged systemic risk, 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1, is less significant than in

Table 4, Table 7 shows that the contemporaneous systemic risks, 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 and 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 , remains

significant with similar economic magnitude as found in the baseline regressions. Taking the

coefficients of -0.107 and -0.540 in Column IV as an example, starting from mean value, one standard

deviation increase (2.550) in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 is associated with a decrease in distance-to-default by 0.273, which

a 0.055 standard deviation (4.903) decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default and a 4.030% decrease from

the mean value (6.772) of distance-to-default; one standard deviation increase (0.926) in CATFIN is

associated with a decrease in distance-to-default by 0.500, which is a 0.102 standard deviation (4.903)

Page 21: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

20

decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default and 7.380% decrease from the mean value (6.772) of distance-

to-default. Similarly, a one standard deviation increase (0.926) in CATFIN is associated with a decrease in

distance-to-default by 0.500, which is a 0.102 standard deviation (4.903) decrease in borrower’s distance-

to-default and 7.380% decrease from the mean value (6.772) of distance-to-default.

3.3. Lead-lag Analysis

Previous results indicate that systemically risky banks are matched with risky borrowers in the

syndicated bank loan market. However, it is unclear whether the causality extends from systemic risk

to credit risk or vice versa. That is, borrowers may self-select on the basis of the bank’s systemic risk,

particularly if government bailouts may protect bank customers from the impact of bank insolvency.

To address this, I use a set of lead-lag regressions, using contemporaneous borrower’s distance-to-

default or lender’s Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 as the dependent variables, and test whether they are associated with

lagged lender’s Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 or lagged borrower’s distance-to-default. The intuition is that if higher

lagged systemic risk leads the higher borrower credit risk measured by distance-to-default, it suggests

that banks are very likely making endogenous decision on their loan portfolio credit risk-taking

conditioning on their systemic risk. In contrast, if borrower’s higher credit risk leads the bank’s

systemic risk exposure, it suggests that borrowers are endogenously choosing banks.

Table 8 presents the results of the lead-lag analysis. The dependent variable in Column I, II, III, and

IV is 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡, the borrower’s distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination,

and the dependent variable in Column V, VI, VII, and VII is 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡, bank j’s systemic risk during

the quarter of loan origination. The key variable of interest is 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 and

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 . In Column I, II, V, and VI, I only include variables of interest as

independent variables, while in Column III, IV, VI, and VII, I include all characteristics of loans,

banks, and borrowers as control variables. From Column I to IV, the coefficients on 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 are

all significant at 1% level, indicating that lagged bank systemic risk significantly is related to

contemporaneous borrower distance-to-default. Economically, taking the coefficient on 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1

in Column III, one standard deviation increase in 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 is associated with 0.063 standard

deviation decrease in borrower’s distance-to-default at loan origination. However, in Column V to

VIII, the coefficients on 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 are significant in three out of four specifications.

This suggest that while higher lender’s systemic risk in quarter t-1 is associated with higher

borrower’s credit risk in quarter t, higher borrower credit risk in quarter t-1 is not necessarily

associated with higher lender’s systemic risk in quarter t. In other words, the borrowers that are riskier

Page 22: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

21

in the quarter preceding loan origination do not necessarily borrow from systemically risky banks at

loan origination, and systemically risky banks in the quarter preceding loan origination lend to risky

borrowers at loan origination. Even though this test cannot separate the supply-side effect from the

demand-side, it still provides evidence indicating that systemically risky banks are more likely to

endogenously select risky borrowers, rather than risky borrowers choosing banks with greater

exposure to systemic risk. In the next section, I employ within-loan estimations to remove the impact

of the demand-side factors from the supply-side in order to address these causal effects.

3.4. Within-loan Regressions

Even though previous results show a direct relationship between bank systemic risk and borrower

default risk, the test cannot identify the causal effect. The results can be attributed to supply-side

choice, borrower-side choice, or both. On the supply-side, systemically risky banks may increase

their risk taking by proactively choosing risky borrowers. On the demand-side, due to borrowers’

self-selection, risky borrowers may tend to apply for loans specifically from systemically risky banks

that have a higher likelihood of receiving government support to survive through crisis period. It is

difficult to separate the effect of systemic risk on borrower default risk from demand-side factors. To

resolve this concern, I use the within-loan estimations methodology from Chu, Zhang and Zhao (2017)

to remove the impact of the demand-side factors, so that I can investigate whether the higher credit-

risk taking of systemically risky banks is driven by the supply-side. Taking advantage of the unique

feature that a syndicated loan often has multiple lenders, I examine how the systemic risks of different

banks that fund the same loan impacts their loan allocation share percentages. Because all lenders

lend to the same borrower, this removes demand-side factors from the analysis.

The within-loan estimation methodology takes advantage of the underwriting process of a syndicated

loan. In a syndicated loan, the lead lender (arranger) originates the loan, negotiates the spreads and

terms with the borrower, and attracts other banks to participate. Conditional on the loan demand, a

participant in the syndicated loan can therefore determine its own contribution to funding the total

loan amount. If the previous findings are driven by supply-side choice, then the within-loan regression

should show that, systemically risky banks contribute a larger portion to riskier borrowers, and (or) a

smaller portion to safe borrowers.

I conduct my analysis using multiple methodologies. First, I test banks’ allocation share preference

in risky loan groups versus less risky loan groups, and investigate whether the allocation share

preferences are significantly different between the two groups. In each year for all newly originated

Page 23: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

22

loans, I sort their borrower distance-to-default into ten quantiles, with the 1st quantile including the

lowest distance-to-default (most risky) borrowers, and the 10th quantile indicating highest distance-

to-default (least risky) borrowers. Then I construct three risk dummies: 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 ,

𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 , and 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 . 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 equals 1 if the borrower distance-to-default

falls into the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th quantiles (risky), and 0 if the borrower distance-to-default falls

into the 6th, 7th, 8th, 9th, and 10th quantiles (less risky). 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 equals 1 if the borrower

distance-to-default falls into the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, and 4th quantiles (riskier), and 0 if the borrower distance-

to-default falls into the 7th, 8th, 9th, and 10th quantiles (less risky). I drop all observations that fall

into the 5th and 6th quantile due to the potential ambiguous relationship between Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and bank

share in those groups so that I can focus on borrowers with more extreme credit risk levels, which are

either very high or very low. Similarly, I construct the third risk dummy, 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3, which

focuses on even more extreme credit risk levels. 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 takes a value of 1 if the borrower

distance-to-default falls into the 1st, 2nd, and 3rd quantiles (very risky), and 0 if the borrower distance-

to-default falls into the 8th, 9th, and 10th quantiles (least risky). I will call the group of firms with

risky dummy being 0 the safe group and the group of firms with risky dummy the risky group.

With the three dummy variables defined, I run the following within-loan regression at both package

and facility levels:

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼𝑘 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 + 𝛼2Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦

+ 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 + 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼3𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1

+ 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 , (10)

where subscript i, j, k, and t indicate the borrowing firm, the bank, the packages/facilities, and the

time (quarter) respectively, and 𝛼𝑘 denotes the package/facility fixed effects. 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦 is

𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1, 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2, or 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3. The dependent variable is the bank allocation

share in percentages at either package or facility level. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 denotes bank fixed effects. Since I

use bank fixed effects, I only include banks that have at least five loan observations throughout the

sample period to ensure variation. I also conduct the analysis using either Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 or Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1

to avoid potential simultaneity. I hypothesize that 𝛼1 is negative and 𝛼2 is positive. Note that

𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦 is included in this regression only through the interaction term, but does not show up

independently, because as one of the borrower characteristics, its direct effect on the bank share has

been absorbed by the package/facility fixed effects. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 includes an array of bank

control variables including the natural logarithm of bank total assets (in millions), bank capital ratio,

Page 24: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

23

bank return on equity, bank liquidity, bank loan charge-offs, bank loan loss allowance, and bank risk-

weighted assets. All bank control variables are lagged by one quarter. To account for the possibility

that there might be some funding persistence among frequent bank players and such funding

persistence causes regression error terms to be correlated within banks, I cluster the standard errors

at the bank level.

Table 9 shows the coefficients estimates, with Panel A reporting the results at the package level and

Panel B reporting the results at the facility level. For each panel, Column I, II and III report the

coefficients from the regressions using contemporaneous systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡, and Column IV,

V, and VI report the coefficients from the regressions using one period lagged systemic risk,

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 . I interact bank systemic risk with 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 in Columns I and IV, with

𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 in Columns II and V, and with 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 in Columns III and VI. The results in

Panel A shows a negative 𝛼1 , which are statistically significant at 1% or 5% levels in most

specifications. The negative 𝛼1 indicates that systemically risky banks decrease their allocation share

for loans to less risky borrowers. The coefficient of the interaction term, 𝛼2, is significantly positive

at 1% level in all specifications, implying that the relationship between systemic risk and bank

allocation share is significantly different between the risky group and the safe group. 𝛼1 + 𝛼2

represents the relationship between systemic risk and bank allocation share in the risky group, and

we can see that 𝛼1+𝛼2 is always positive in all specifications, which indicates that systemically risky

banks increase their allocation share on risky borrowers.

Economically, taking the coefficients of -0.096 on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 and 0.204 on the interaction term in

Column I of Panel A as an example, a bank with one standard deviation increase in systemic risk

would decrease contribution to a borrower in the safe group by 0.096 × 2.684 = 0.258% from its mean.

In contrast, for the risky group, a bank with one standard deviation increase in systemic risk would

increase contribution to a borrower in the risky group by (-0.096 + 0.204) × 2.684 = 0.290% from its

mean.

It is also noteworthy that the negative/positive relationship between bank allocation share and

systemic risk is even stronger in borrower groups with even more extreme default risk levels. 𝛼1

decreases from -0.096 in Column I to -0.189 in Column III, with significance levels increase from

10% to 1%. It indicates that on average, systemically risky banks pull back their lending the most on

the most creditworthy borrowers, which provides stronger evidence showing that systemically banks

are less willing to lend to creditworthy borrowers. Meanwhile, 𝛼2 increases from 0.204 in Column I

to 0.387 in Column III, with 1% significance level in all specifications, which indicates that the effects

Page 25: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

24

of systemic risk on bank allocation share are even more different between very risky borrowers and

very safe borrowers. The net effect, 𝛼1+𝛼2, increases from -0.096 + 0.204 = 0.108 in Column I to -

0.189 + 0.387 = 0.198 in Column III, meaning that systemically banks increase their lending even

more on riskier borrowers.

I find similar results in Columns IV, V, and VI, where I use one period lagged systemic risk to reduce

simultaneity. The coefficient on Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 stays negative and is significant at 1% significance

level in all three columns. The coefficient on the interaction term is positive and significant at 1%

significance level, implying that the relationship between bank allocation share and systemic risk is

significantly different between the safe group and the risky group. Economically, taking -0.180 and

0.348 in Column VI as an example, on average, a bank with one standard deviation increase in

systemic risk would decrease contribution to a borrower in the safe group by 0.180 × 2.684 = 0.483%

from its mean, and would increase contribution to a borrower in the risky group by (-0.180 + 0.348)

× 2.684 = 0.451%. Panel B of Table 9 reports the within-loan estimation at the facility level. As

shown in Panel B, the results are very similar with Panel A.

4. Robustness Checks

4.1. Robustness Check of Within-loan Regressions

In Section 3.4, a borrower is defined as a risky or safe borrower based on how its distance-to-default

is ranked among all borrowers in the same calendar year. It is possible that during an economic

expansion some borrowers creditworthy in absolute terms but are categorized into the risky group

just because they are riskier relative other borrowers. If banks are screening borrowers based on their

absolute level of credit risk, instead of their relative rank of credit risk among all borrowers in the

year, then my within-loan regression can create misleading results.

As a robustness check, in this section, I rerun the within-loan regressions using the interaction of

systemic risk and absolute value of borrower distance-to-default. Specifically, I look at the following

regression:

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼𝑘 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 + 𝛼2Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑖,𝑡−1

+ 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 + 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼3𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1

+ 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡, (11)

Page 26: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

25

where subscripts i, j, k, and t index the borrowing firm, the bank, the loan pacage/facility, and time.

The key variables of interest are Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡. 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟 𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

equals 1 if bank j is a lead lender in the package/facility k. 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 controls for the

intensity of past lending relationships between borrower i and bank j. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠 is a vector of bank

characteristics and 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐹𝐸 denotes bank fixed effects.

The aggregate effect of Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 on 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 is 𝛼1 + 𝛼2 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑖,𝑡−1.

Therefore, 𝛼1 measures the relationship between Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛 when borrower

distance-to-default is 0 (or very close to 0). In other words, 𝛼1 measures the relationship between

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and bank contribution for loans whose borrower is at the edge of bankruptcy. A positive 𝛼1

implies that systemically risky banks increase their lending to very risky borrowers, and a negative

𝛼2 would indicate that this relationship is weaker or even reverted for safe borrowers.

The regression results are presented in Table 10. Panel A of Table 10 reports the package-level results

and Panel B of Table 10 reports the facility-level results. To avoid potential simultaneity, I try both

the contemporaneous and one-period lagged values for the two variables of interest, systemic risk

and borrower distance-to-default. For both panels, I use contemporaneous systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑖,𝑡,

in Column I and II, and one-period lagged systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑖,𝑡−1, in Column III and IV. In

Column I and III, I interact systemic risk with contemporaneous borrower distance-to-default, and in

Column II and IV, I interact systemic risk with one-period lagged borrower distance-to-default. In

Panel A of Table 10, 𝛼1 is positive and significant at 5% or 1% significance levels in most

specifications, which suggests that for very risky borrowers, bank allocation share increases with

bank systemic risk. 𝛼2 is negative and significant at 1% significance level in all four columns, which

indicates the positive relationship between bank systemic risk and bank allocation share is weaker as

borrower distance-to-default increases, in other words, as the borrower becomes more creditworthy.

Economically, taking 0.171 and -0.024 in Column II as an example, for a borrower whose distance-

to-default is 0 (or close to 0), a bank with one standard deviation increase in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑖,𝑡 would

increase its contribution by 0.171 × 2.684 = 0.459%, suggesting a higher contribution to risky

borrowers. As borrower distance-to-default increases, in other words, as the borrower becomes more

creditworthy, the positive relationship between systemic risk and bank allocation share is weaker.

When borrower distance-to-default reaches 5.952, 𝛼1 + 𝛼2 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑖,𝑡−1 is

equal to 0 (0.171 – 0.024 × 5.952 = 0) so bank allocation is unrelated with systemic risk on these

loans. At this point, the relationship between systemic and bank allocation is reverted to a negative

Page 27: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

26

relationship. Note that 5.952 is lower than but not far from the sample mean (8.181) or median (7.564)

value of borrower distance-to-default. As borrower distance-to-default further increases to the 75th

percentile, which is about 10.872, a bank with one standard deviation increase in Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑖,𝑡 would

decrease its contribution by (0.171 – 0.024 × 10.872) × 2.684 = 0.241%. Panel B of Table 10 reports

the facility-level results which are similar with those at the package-level.

The results in Table 10 echo my results in Section 3.4 and suggest that the positive (negative)

relationship between bank systemic risk and allocation share for risky (safe) borrowers is robust with

both relative and absolute credit risk levels, and is robust with treatment of discrete credit risk

quantiles and continuous borrower distance-to-default levels.

4.2. Robustness Check of Causality Tests: Dynamic Panel GMM Estimation

Endogeneity can arise from reverse causality. For example, current values of systemic risk could be

a function of the credit risk of previous borrowers. Although the lead lag analysis presented in Table

8 addresses this point, in this section I utilize a dynamic panel GMM analysis to alleviate this concern.

I produce dynamic panel GMM estimators following Wintoki, Linck, and Netter (2012). The

estimation consists of four steps: First, I convert my regression equation to a bank-quarter panel

regression. For each bank j in quarter t, I calculate the average borrower distance-to-default of all

loans originated by this bank in this quarter. For this calculation, I don’t put any restriction on whether

the bank acts as a lead lender or non-lead participant. As long as a bank participates in a loan, this

loan is included to the average borrower distance-to-default calculation in the bank’s loan portfolio.

I name this average distance-to-default Bank Portfolio Distance-to-Default. Following the same

methodology, I generate the average borrower characteristics and loan characteristics for each bank

in each quarter. In this way, the regression is converted to a panel regression using quarterly Bank

Portfolio Distance-to-Default as the dependent variable, quarterly systemic risks as main independent

variables, and quarterly bank, average borrower, and average loan characteristics as control variables.

Second, I rewrite the regression equation as a dynamic model, adding three lags of Bank Portfolio

Distance-to-Default ( 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑗,𝑡−𝑝 , p=1,2,3) as explanatory

variables. Therefore, the regression equation becomes:

Page 28: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

27

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡

= 𝛼0 + 𝛼1 ∑ 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡−𝑝

3

𝑝=1

+ 𝛼2𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1

+ 𝛼3Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼4𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 + 𝛼5𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼6𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡

+ 𝛼7𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼8𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼9𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑡

+ 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟 𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 (12)

Note that 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑗,𝑡−p is different from 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1 .

𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1 controls for the borrower’s lagged credit risk one quarter before their

borrowing activity, while 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝑡𝑜 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡 𝑗,𝑡−1 is the average credit risk the

lender actually took in quarter t-1. Third, I first difference all variables, which allows me to control

for unobserved heterogeneity and eliminate potential omitted variable bias. Fourth, I estimate the

model by dynamic panel GMM and use lagged explanatory variables as instruments. As suggested

by Saunders, Schmid, Walter (2016), using lagged variables as instruments for the present values of

these variables controls for potential simultaneity and reverse causality. In addition, this estimation

procedure allows all the explanatory variables to be treated as endogenous.**

Table 11 reports the results of GMM estimation. For space reasons, only the coefficients on systemic

risks, 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑣𝑔 𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1, and interaction terms are reported. The results across all seven columns

confirm a negative contribution of systemic risks to borrower distance-to-default. Columns V and VI

suggest that this result holds regardless of macrolevel systemic risk as both interaction terms are

statistically insignificantly different from zero. Column VII shows that the magnitude of the effect

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 on dependent variable is reduced to some extent, while the negative contribution still holds.

5. Credit Risk-taking Sensitivity on Systemic Risk – The Effect of

Executive and Bank Innovation Preference and Styles

5.1. Constructing Executive and Bank Innovation Dimensions

**The dynamic GMM test is not without its flaws. All loans used to compute lagged Bank Portfolio Distance-

to-Default are newly originated loans in respective quarters, since it is hard to control for the effect of all existing

loans due to data limitation. Thus, I utilize this as a robustness check of my earlier results

Page 29: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

28

Even though I find a positive relationship between systemic risk and credit risk-taking in the previous

sections, different banks, possibly with different risk-taking cultures, may react to changes in

systemic risks very differently. Table 12 shows the estimates for coefficients 𝛼1 and 𝛼3 in equation

(9) for selected US bank holding companies. 𝛼1 is the coefficient on the micro-level systemic risk,

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 , and 𝛼3 is the coefficient on the interaction of Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and the recession dummy. 𝛼1

measures a bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity during normal periods, and 𝛼1 + 𝛼3 measures the

bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity during recession periods. Table 12 shows that there is a wide

variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity across different US banks in and out of recessions, which

raises the question of what factor is driving this heterogenous reactions of credit risk-taking to

systemic risk changes.

In this section, I provide evidence that some bank executive specific effects, or “styles”, play an

important role in explain banks’ credit risk-taking and credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk.

Recent literature has been focusing on the roles of bank executives and their effects on bank risk-

taking culture and extreme risk exposure, and a growing body of evidence has shown how pay

arrangements and other executive characteristics affect banks’ risk-taking (Berger, Kick and Schaeck,

2014; Nguyen, Hagendorff and Eshraghi, 2017). However, Hagendorff et. al. (2017) suggest that

compensation and various other observable executive characteristics can only describe a small

amount of the variation in banks business model and risk-taking preference, and they find that much

of the variation in bank business policy can be explained by executive factors (“styles”) that are time-

invariant, which helps explain the risk-taking culture in some banks.

Since bank credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk is largely related to banks business models

and how banks are managed (aggressively or conservatively) by the executives, its variation may also

be explained by the unobservable, time-invariant executive fixed effects. In this section, motivated

by the recent work of Hagendorff et. al (2017), I provide evidence that idiosyncratic executive-

specific effects (“styles”) can also help explain a large variation in banks’ credit risk-taking sensitivity

on systemic risk.

I generate executive-specific styles following the method of Hagendorff et. al (2017). Specifically, I

run a series of three-way fixed effects models (with bank, time, and executive fixed effects) using

eight bank business policy variables as dependent variables and a series of bank controls and

macroeconomic controls as independent variables. Executives included are CEOs, CFOs, COOs, and

executive directors, whose position and tenure data are obtained from Execucomp. The executive and

bank fixed effects are disentangled using a sample of banks assembled using the connectedness

Page 30: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

29

sampling method of Abowd, Kramarz and Margolis (1999) (AKM, thereafter) and Abowd, Creecy,

and Kramarz (2002). The AKM method allows me to separate bank and executive fixed effects

through a connectedness sample, which includes not only moving executives but also non-movers

who work in banks that have hired at least one mover during the sample period. The executive fixed

effects proxy for some unobservable executive-specific styles or personality that can potentially affect

banks’ business policy models and risk-taking strategies. Similarly, the bank fixed effects capture

some bank-specific time-invariant (or stable) business or risk-taking culture.

Following Liu, Mao, and Tian (2016), I use graph theory to construct the connectedness sample:

starting with an arbitrary mover executive, I find out all banks for which she had ever worked during

the sample period, then find all executives (movers and non-movers) who had ever worked for these

banks during the sample period, and further track all banks they ever work for. Continue this

procedure until all data are exhausted, and these “connected” executives and banks are assembled

into a single “connected” group. Then, I select another arbitrary mover executive that is not assigned

a group, and follow the above procedure again. Follow the procedures until all mover executives have

been assembled into groups. As suggested by Abowd, Creecy, and Kramarz (2002), the AKM method

makes it computationally feasible to estimate executive and bank fixed effects for each group relative

to a within-in group benchmark. To make executive and bank fixed effects directly comparable across

groups, I follow the normalization procedure by Cornelissen (2008): First, I normalize the mean bank

fixed effects for each group to zero and add the group mean bank fixed effects to executive fixed

effects; Second, I subtract the grand mean of executive fixed effects from each executive fixed effect

and then add this grand mean executive fixed effect to the intercept. Then, the three-way fixed effect

regression can be written as:

𝑃𝑗(𝑚,𝑡+1) = 𝐵𝑗(𝑚,𝑡)𝛾 + 𝐸𝑡𝛽 + Σ𝑗=1𝐽 𝐷𝑚,𝑗,𝑡𝜃𝑗 + 𝜙𝑚 + 𝜇𝑡 + 𝜀𝑗,𝑡 (13)

where 𝐷𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 is a dummy variable that is equal to one if executive m works at bank j at time t, and zero

otherwise. Following Hagendorff et. al. (2017), 𝑃𝑗(𝑚,𝑡+1) are a series of bank business policy variables (non-

interest income, loans over assets, MBS, derivatives, lending diversifications, Gap12, loans over deposits,

non-deposit funding) for bank j and time t. Bank policy variables are based on bank balance sheet

characteristics that parsimoniously reflect key choices that bank executives make with respect to the asset

and liability side of a bank’s balance sheet. The bank policy variables are defined in Appendix II. The

dependent variable is explained by bank characteristics 𝐵𝑗(𝑚,𝑡), macroeconomic conditions 𝐸𝑡, bank fixed

effects 𝜃𝑗, manager fixed effects 𝜙𝑚, and time fixed effects 𝜇𝑡. In the first step, the AKM method sweeps

Page 31: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

30

out the executive fixed effects by averaging over all executive m’s relationship with business model

variables to obtain:

�̅�𝑚 = �̅�𝑚𝛾 + �̅�𝑚𝛽 + Σ𝑗=1𝐽

�̅�𝑚,𝑗𝜃𝑗 + 𝜙𝑚 + �̅�𝑡 + 𝜀�̅� (14)

where �̅�𝑚 is the executive m’s average business policy across the full sample period. Then demean (13)

with (14) to remove executive fixed effects:

𝑃𝑗(𝑚,𝑡+1) − �̅�𝑖 = 𝛾(𝑋𝑗(𝑚,𝑡) − �̅�𝑖) + 𝛽(𝐸𝑡 − �̅�𝑚) + Σ𝑗=1𝐽

(𝐷𝑚,𝑗,𝑡 − �̅�𝑖,𝑗)𝜃𝑗 + (𝜇𝑡 − �̅�𝑡) + (𝜀𝑖,𝑡 − 𝜀�̅�) (15)

Thus, I can use the movers’ information to identify bank fixed effects since 𝐷𝑚,𝑗,𝑡 − �̅�𝑖,𝑗 ≠ 0 for a mover,

which can be estimated by the least-squares dummy variables (LSDV) method (as used by Bertrand and

Schoar, 2003). Finally, using the estimates in the above regression, I can recover the executive fixed effects

equation:

�̂�𝑚 = �̅�𝑚 − �̅�𝑚�̂� − �̅�𝑚�̂� − Σ𝑗=1𝐽 �̅�𝑚,𝑗𝜃𝑗 (16)

where �̅�𝑡 is often treated as the benchmark in estimating time effects and thereby assumed to be zero.

The three-way fixed effects models assign each individual bank and individual executive styles

(estimated fixed effects) in each of the eight policy variables. Since I’m interested in the estimated

fixed effects, the regression results for the three-way fixed effects are omitted. In order to describe

the commonalities in the styles that banks and executives show across different policy choices, I

conduct a factor analysis to identify the main dimensions of variation in executive styles. Factor

analysis allows me to reduce the correlations amongst the eight business policy variables to a lower

number of common factors. Panel A and Panel D of Table 13 presents the results of factor analysis

for executives and banks, respectively. The analysis extracts two dominant factors (Factor 1 and

Factor 2) that summarize a relevant portion of the variance of the correlation matrix of executive

styles.

Panel B of Table 3 reports the factor loadings of each policy style with respect to the Factor 1 and

Factor 2. The results are qualitatively and quantitatively consistent with Hagendorff et. al (2017).

Overall, Factor 1 and Factor 2 exhibit managerial preferences that deviate from the traditional banking

business model of deposit-taking and loan-making. Factor 1 has a high loading on executive

preferences for non-traditional and innovative forms of income generation and asset allocation. For

example, Factor 1 loads positively on non-interest income, indicating a preference for income

generating innovation. It also loads positively on mortgage-backed securities and derivatives, and

Page 32: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

31

loads negatively on loan-to-assets ratio and loan-to-deposit ratio, suggesting a stronger preference for

asset allocation innovation and a lower reliance on traditional loan-making business model. Overall,

an executive that has a higher score on Factor 1 exhibits a stronger preference for asset-side

innovation. Factor 2 loads positively non-deposit funding, which captures a managerial preference

for non-traditional bank liabilities, therefore an executive that has a higher score on Factor 2 exhibits

a stronger preference for liability-side innovation. Thus, I can utilize the scores of each executive on

the two factors to describe an executive’s styles on two dimensions of innovation: asset-side and

liability-side. I define an executive’s score on Factor 1 as the asset-side innovation score, and an

executive’s score on Factor 2 as the liability-side innovation score. Similarly, I can also define bank-

level innovation scores using banks’ score on Factor 1 and Factor 2 in Panel E.

To preliminarily validate that the executive and bank innovation scores on the asset-side and liability-

side are relevant measures for systematic differences in how executives impact banks overall

operations, Table 14 shows a correlation matrix for systemic risk, executive and bank innovation

scores for the period of 1992 to 2013. Table 14 shows that the average executive asset-side innovation

score for all executives working for a bank j in quarter t is highly correlated with bank j’s

contemporaneous and next period bank-level systemic risk. This is consistent with the widely

accepted view that bank non-interest income and innovative assets have a higher contribution to

systemic risk than traditional banking (Brunnermeier et. al., 2012). There is a similar relationship

between systemic risk and executive liability-side innovation, but the relationship is weaker,

indicating that an executive’s asset-side innovation preference is the dominant factor in an executive’s

personal traits that affects her institution’s systemic risk-taking. I also find a similar correlation

pattern between systemic risk and the bank-level innovation scores, but the correlations are lower

than those between systemic risk and executive innovation scores, which is an evidence that in terms

of impact on a bank’s systemic risk-taking, the executive innovation preferences may have a higher

contribution than the institutional innovation culture.

5.2. Credit Risk-taking Sensitivity on Systemic Risk: The Effect of Executive Asset-side and

Liability-side Innovation Dimensions

In this section, I investigate whether executive’s personal traits on asset and liability innovation effect

a bank’s credit risk-taking and credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk. I add the innovation

scores to the credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk model, and interact the scores with bank-

level systemic risk.

Page 33: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

32

Table 15 presents the results. In Column II, I interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with 𝑀𝑎𝑛𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑟 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡 𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 ,

which is the average executive asset-side innovation scores for all executives working in bank j in quarter

t. In Column III, I interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 with 𝑀𝑎𝑛𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑟 𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦 𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡, which is the average liability-

side innovation scores for all executives working in bank j in quarter t. In Column IV, I add both interaction

terms into the regression.

The coefficients on executive asset-side innovation score in both Column II and IV are negative and

significant at 1% or 5% level, and the coefficients on the interaction of Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with asset-side innovation

score are positive and significant at 1% level. There are several implications. First, generally, at normal

state when systemic risk is at its median level (4.351), credit risk-taking increases with executive asset-side

innovation score. A potential explanation is that bank executives that are more innovative on asset

allocation are better at hedging or sourcing credit risk, which enables their bank to take higher credit risk

in the traditional debt instruments (Norden, Buston, and Wagner, 2014). Asset-side innovative executives

are more specialized in utilizing innovative products (in particular structured instruments and credit

derivatives), and the use of the innovative “originate to distribute” products can increase banks’ risk-taking

if the transfer of risks leads to incentive problems at banks. There is evidence that loan sales (Cebenoyan

and Strahan, 2004) and Collateralized Debt Obligations (Franke and Krahnen, 2007) lead to an increase in

lending at banks, potentially to risky borrowers. My result here thus supports the view in that asset-side

innovative executives may participate in riskier syndicated bank loan deals. The second implication from

the results in Table 15 is that, credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk is lower for banks managed by

executives with high asset-side innovation score. This suggests that executives with different asset-side

innovation preferences react to potential systemic risk crisis very differently. Compared with asset-side

traditional executives, asset-side innovating executives are less likely to exploit abnormal returns (induced

by imperfect market discipline) from higher risk-taking in traditional loan-making activities. This is

potentially due to the systemically risky banks’ trade-off between the potential costs from regulatory

scrutiny and requirements such as capital constraints, and the potential benefits that can be obtained from

excessive risk-taking in the traditional syndicated loan market. Note that Factor 1 loads negatively loan-to-

assets ratios and loan-to-deposit ratios, indicating that traditional loans only take a low portion in an asset-

side innovator’s preferred asset portfolio. Thus, compared with the regulatory scrutiny and regulatory risk

pricing, the potential abnormal returns that can be obtained from higher risk-taking in the traditional loan

market is lower, which discourage them from exploiting abnormal returns in the loan market.

Combining the two results above, we can say that banks with asset-side innovators generally take higher

credit risk (this part is independent of systemic risk) but their credit risk sensitivity to systemic risk is low.

This is consistent with the reality that banks with innovators generally focus more on non-interesting

Page 34: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

33

generating activities, so that it's more likely that their moral hazard problems and exploit of excessive return

mainly focus on non-traditional business, which lead to lower credit risk sensitivity on systemic risk.

Traditional activities such as syndicated loans are less of an attractive moral hazard opportunity for them.

Instead, banks with traditionalists generally take lower credit risk but they focus their moral hazard

opportunities on more on traditional businesses than innovators, which leads to a higher credit risk

sensitivity on systemic risk.

The coefficients on the executive liability-side innovation, as shown in Columns III and IV in Table

15, is positive and significant at 1% or 5% level. Columns III and IV also show that the coefficients

on the interactions of systemic risk and liability-side innovation are negative and significant at 1%

level. Combing the two results, for banks managed by executives with high liability-side innovation,

their loan credit risk-taking is generally lower but is more sensitive to potential systemic risk crisis.

This reflects both the bright side and dark side of executives’ liability innovation, and can be

explained from the view of bank competition and trade-off between retail and wholesale funding

costs. Executives with high scores on liability innovation dimension are better at utilizing non-deposit

funding, such as wholesale funding, to supplement retail deposits and finance their investment. The

use of innovative liability such as wholesale funding enables banks to avoid the intense competition

on traditional retail deposits and thus lower the cost of bank funding. Literature has shown that the

incentives of banks to invest in risky projects increase with the cost of its funding, and banks with

cheap sources of funding pursue more conservative risk strategies (Allen and Gale, 2000; Hellmann

et al., 2000). Thus, the liability-side innovation provides a bright side in that executives that are more

innovative on the liability are more able to utilize the cheaper wholesale funding to lower their risk-

taking on loans.

However, the negative coefficient on the interaction term reveals that there is also a dark side.

Compared with traditional retail depositors, innovative fund providers such as wholesale financiers

are relatively more sophisticated and more sensitive to idiosyncratic and systemic risks. They can exit

and withdraw their fund much more quickly than retail depositors. In cases of potential systemic risk

crisis (high Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 periods), innovative liability holders can exit and withdraw their funds much

more quickly than retail depositors, which in the short term may sharply increase a bank’s funding

costs, forcing them to conduct more risky projects. This problem would be severer for banks managed

by executives that deviate from the traditional deposit-taking model and are more innovative in her

liability structure.

Page 35: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

34

5.3. Alternative Explanation: The Effect of Bank Innovation Dimensions

An alternative explanation for the above results could be that, the managerial asset-side and liability-

side innovation preference measures not only capture the managerial styles, but also capture the bank-

level innovation preferences, or bank-level risk-culture, which may be correlated with managerial

innovation preferences, and maybe it’s the bank-level preferences that are affecting a bank’s credit

risk-taking and credit risk-sensitivity on systemic risk. To answer that question, I also estimate the

bank fixed effects in the three-way fixed effect model, and conduct the same factor analysis for bank

fixed effects, and then extracts two dominant factors that summarize a relevant portion of the variance

of the correlation matrix of bank styles, as specified in Panel D of Table 13. In Panel E of Table 13,

I observe a similar pattern of loadings for Factor 1 and Factor 2. Factor 1 loads positively on

innovative business models of income generation and asset allocation. It loads positively on non-

interest income, MBS, and derivatives, and loads negatively on loan-to-assets ratio and loan-to-

deposit ratio. Therefore, a higher score in Factor 1 is associated with a bank’s higher asset-side

innovation preference. In contrast, Factor 2 loads positively on non-deposit funding, which indicates

an innovation on liability structure. Thus, higher scores on Factor 2 indicate that the bank exhibits a

higher liability-side innovation. I then study how executive and bank innovation dimensions affect a

bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk.

The results are presented in Table 16. In all columns, I add bank fixed effects so bank-level innovation

dimension variables are omitted. In Column II and IV, I include the interaction of systemic risk and

bank-level innovation dimensions. The coefficients are insignificant. In Column III and V, I include

the interaction of systemic risk and each of the bank-level innovation dimensions, as well as the

interaction of systemic risk and each of the managerial innovation dimensions. The coefficients on

the interaction of systemic risk and bank-level innovation dimensions remain insignificant, while the

coefficients on the interaction of systemic risk and managerial innovation dimensions remain

significant and consistent with previous results. In Column VI, I include the interactions of systemic

risk with both bank-level asset innovation and liability innovation. The coefficients remain

insignificant. In Column VII, I add all interactions. The signs, magnitude, and significance level for

the interaction of systemic risk and managerial innovation dimensions remain the same as those in

the previous section, and the interactions of systemic risk and bank-level innovation dimensions is

marginally significant, and the magnitudes are much smaller.

The results in Table 16 is important. In terms of affecting credit risk-sensitivity on systemic risk,

managerial innovation preferences are much more important and influential than bank-level

Page 36: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

35

innovation culture or preferences. This result is consistent with Hagendorff et. al. (2017), who argue

that extreme risk-taking and other unsustainable business models in banking could ultimately be a

‘people problem’ that is rooted in the idiosyncratic preferences of individuals and not easily reined

by regulators and investors.

5.4. The Effect of Managerial Styles

Since both managerial asset-side and liability-side innovation dimensions have important but

different effects on a bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk, it is then possible to use

the scores on the two dimensions to assign executives to four different profiles: (1) asset innovating

and liability traditional executives are those with score on Factor1 higher than the mean level (0.012)

and score on Factor 2 lower than the mean level (-0.149); (2) asset and liability innovating executives

are those with scores on Factor 1 and Factor2 higher than the mean levels; (3) asset and liability

traditional executives are those with scores on Factor 1 and Factor 2 lower than the mean levels; (4)

asset traditionalist and liability innovators are those with scores on Factor 1 lower than the mean level

and scores on Factor 2 higher than the mean level. These profiles capture the idiosyncratic effects of

different types of executives on bank credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risks. Figure 1 presents

the graphical clustering of managerial patterns in styles, and Panel C in Table 3 shows the average

values for Factor1 and Factor 2 for each executive style. Since each type of executives represents a

different combination of asset-side and liability-side innovation preferences, and innovation

preferences on the asset-side and liability-side have different effects on bank’s risk-taking choices, it

is interesting to test how these different combinations of innovation preferences affect a bank’s credit

risk reaction to potential systemic risk crisis.

Table 17 presents the results. In order to eliminate the effect of different types of executives, in Table

17, I only include bank-quarters when there are only one type of executives working for the bank. In

Columns II to V, I use the interaction of systemic risk and each of the four type dummies. The type

dummy for bank j in quarter t is equal to 1 if the bank j only hires this type of executives in quarter t.

The results in Column II to V of Table 17 show that, the credit risk-taking sensitivity on systemic risk

is significantly lower for banks managed by asset innovators who are also liability traditionalists, and

significantly higher for asset traditionalists regardless of their liability innovation types. In Column

VI, I add three type dummies while omit the first dummy, and find similar results. The credit risk-

sensitivity on systemic risk is highest for liability innovators who are asset traditionalists, and lower

for pure traditionalists, and even lower for pure innovators, and then lowest for asset innovators who

are liability traditionalists. In other words, the credit risk-sensitivity on systemic risk is lowest for an

Page 37: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

36

executive who prefer innovative assets, which allow then avoid using the traditional loan market to

exploit the excessive returns, and who prefer traditional liability structure, which allows them to avoid

the inefficient and sensitive wholesale financiers in cases of potential systemic risk crisis. Another

important finding from Table 17 is that, an executive’s asset-side innovation preference is more

important in determining a bank’s reaction to systemic risk in the syndicated loan market.

6. Conclusion

This paper investigates whether and how financial institutions adjust their credit risk exposure in their

loan portfolios in response to systemic risks, and study how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects

help explain the variation in this adjustment across banks. First, using a database of syndicated bank

loans, this paper examines whether systemically important banks take higher credit risk in the

syndicated loan market. Using two complementary measures of systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and CATFIN,

and the borrower’s distance-to-default as a measure for borrower credit risk, I find that systemically

risky banks are matched with borrowers with higher credit risk, implying higher credit risk-taking by

systemically risky banks, and this relationship is weaker during recessions and periods of high systemic

risk. The result is robust to a number of different specifications, which control for loan, borrower, and

bank characteristics, as well as a series of fixed effects. The result also persists after controlling for

borrower self-selection of lenders. A lead-lag analysis suggests that the greater the bank’s systemic

risk exposure, the greater the default risk in the loans it chooses for its loan portfolio. By using a

within-loan regression methodology to remove the impact of demand-side factors, I find that banks

with more systemic risk choose to fund larger portions of loans to borrowers with high levels of credit

risk and lower shares of loans to relatively safe borrowers. A dynamic GMM estimation further

supports these results and alleviates the endogeneity concern. I further find that some idiosyncratic

bank executive-specific innovation preferences, or styles, can explain the variation in credit risk-

taking sensitivity on systemic risk, indicating that some unobservable executive personal traits play

an important role in affecting banks’ reactions to potential systemic risk crisis.

Page 38: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

37

References

Abowd, J. M., Kramarz, F., & Margolis, D. N. (1999). High Wage Workers and High Wage Firms.

Econometrica, 67(2), 251-333.

Abowd, J. M., Creecy, R. H., & Kramarz, F. (2002). Computing Person and Firm Effects Using Linked

Longitudinal Employer-employee Data (No. 2002-06). Center for Economic Studies, US Census Bureau.

Acharya, V. V., Anginer, D., & Warburton, A. J. (2016). The End of Market Discipline? Investor

Expectations of Implicit Government Guarantees.

Acharya, V. V., Santos, J., & Yorulmazer, T. (2010). Systemic Risk and Deposit Insurance Premiums.

Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Adrian, T., & Brunnermeier, M. K. (2016). CoVaR. The American Economic Review, 106(7), 1705-1741.

Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2000). Financial Contagion. Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 1-33.

Allen, L., Bali, T. G., & Tang, Y. (2012). Does Systemic Risk in the Financial Sector Predict Future

Economic Downturns? The Review of Financial Studies, 25(10), 3000-3036.

Allen, L., & Li, G. (2011). Clawbacks and Cronyism: Evidence from China. Financial Management, 40(3),

733-756.

Allen, L., & Tang, Y. (2016). What’s the Contingency? A Proposal for Bank Contingent Capital Triggered

by Systemic Risk. Journal of Financial Stability, 26, 1-14.

Anginer, D., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Zhu, M. (2013). How Does Bank Competition Affect Systemic

Stability?

Anginer, D., Demirguc-Kunt, A., & Zhu, M. (2014). How Does Deposit Insurance Affect Bank Risk?

Evidence from the Recent Crisis. Journal of Banking & Finance, 48, 312-321.

Baker, S. R., Bloom, N., & Davis, S. J. (2016). Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 131(4), 1593-1636.

Berger, A. N., Kick, T., & Schaeck, K. (2014). Executive board composition and bank risk taking. Journal

of Corporate Finance, 28, 48-65.

Page 39: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

38

Berger, A. N., Roman, R. A., & Sedunov, J. (2016). Do Bank Bailouts Reduce or Increase Systemic Risk?

the Effects of TARP on Financial System Stability.

Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1169-1208.

Bharath, S., Dahiya, S., Saunders, A., & Srinivasan, A. (2007). So What do I Get? The Bank's View of

Lending Relationships. Journal of Financial Economics, 85(2), 368-419.

Bharath, S. T., & Shumway, T. (2008). Forecasting Default with the Merton Distance to Default Model. The

Review of Financial Studies, 21(3), 1339-1369.

Brunnermeier, M. K., Dong, G. N., & Palia, D. (2012). Banks’ Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk.

Cebenoyan, A. S., & Strahan, P. E. (2004). Risk Management, Capital Structure and Lending at Banks.

Journal of Banking & Finance, 28(1), 19-43.

Chava, S., & Roberts, M. R. (2008). How Does Financing Impact Investment? The Role of Debt Covenants.

The Journal of Finance, 63(5), 2085-2121.

Choi, D. B. (2014). Heterogeneity and Stability: Bolster the Strong, Not the Weak, The Review of Financial

Studies, 27(6), 1830–1867,

Chu, Y., Zhang, D., & Zhao, Y. (2017). Bank Capital and Lending: Evidence from Syndicated Loans.

Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming.

Cornelissen, T. (2008). The Stata Command felsdvreg to Fit a Linear Model with Two High-dimensional

Fixed Effects. Stata Journal, 8(2), 170.

Cordella, T., & Yeyati, E. L. (2003). Bank Bailouts: Moral Hazard vs. Value Effect. Journal of Financial

Intermediation, 12(4), 300-330.

Crosbie, P., & Bohn, J. (2003). Modeling Default Risk. Moody’s KMV.

Degryse, H., & Ongena, S. (2005). Distance, Lending Relationships, and Competition. The Journal of

Finance, 60(1), 231-266.

Dell'Ariccia, G., & Ratnovski, L. (2014). Bailouts and Systemic Insurance. Working Paper.

Page 40: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

39

Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Detragiache, E. (2002). Does deposit insurance increase banking system stability?

An empirical investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(7), 1373-1406.

Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2005). Liquidity Shortages and Banking Crises. The Journal of Finance, 60(2),

615-647.

Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2009). The Credit Crisis: Conjectures about Causes and Remedies. The

American Economic Review, 99(2), 606-610.

Farhi, E., & Tirole, J. (2012). Collective Moral Hazard, Maturity Mismatch, and Systemic Bailouts. The

American Economic Review, 102(1), 60-93.

Flannery, M. (1998). Using Market Information in Prudential Bank Supervision: A Review of the U.S.

Empirical Evidence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30(3), 273-305.

Franke, G., & Krahnen, J. P. (2007). Default Risk Sharing Between Banks and Markets: The Contribution

of Collateralized Debt Obligations. In The risks of financial institutions (pp. 603-634). University of

Chicago Press.

Freixas, X., Parigi, B., & Rochet, J. (2000). Systemic Risk, Interbank Relations, and Liquidity Provision

by the Central Bank. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32(3), 611-638.

Gropp, R., Hakenes, H., & Schnabel, I. (2011). Competition, Risk-shifting, and Public Bail-out

Policies. The Review of Financial Studies, 24(6), 2084-2120.

Gropp, R., Vesala, J., & Vulpes, G. (2006). Equity and Bond Market Signals as Leading Indicators of Bank

Fragility. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38(2), 399-428.

Hagendorff, J., Saunders, A., Steffen, S., & Vallascas, F. (2017). The Wolves of Wall Street: Managerial

Attributes and Bank Business Models.

Hakenes, H., & Schnabel, I. (2010). Banks Without Parachutes: Competitive Effects of Government Bail-

out Policies. Journal of Financial Stability, 6(3), 156-168.

Hellmann, T. F., Murdock, K. C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2000). Liberalization, Moral Hazard in Banking, and

Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough? American Economic Review, 147-165.

Kane, E. J. (1989). The S & L insurance mess: how did it happen? The Urban Institute Press.

Page 41: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

40

Keeley, M. C. (1990). Deposit Insurance, Risk, and Market Power in Banking. The American Economic

Review, 1183-1200.

Liu, T., Mao, Y., & Tian, X. (2016). Do Individuals or Firms Matter More? The Case of Patent Generation.

Nguyen, D. D., Hagendorff, J., & Eshraghi, A. (2017). Does a CEO’s Cultural Heritage Affect Performance

Under Competitive Pressure? The Review of Financial Studies.

Norden, L., Buston, C. S., & Wagner, W. (2014). Financial Innovation and Bank Behavior: Evidence from

Credit Markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 43, 130-145.

Passmore, W., & von Hafften, A. H. (2017). Are Basel's Capital Surcharges for Global Systemically

Important Banks Too Small? Working paper.

Schwarcz, S. L. (2016). Too Big to Fool: Moral Hazard, Bailouts, and Corporate Responsibility. Minnesota

Law Review, 102.

Sironi, A. (2003). Testing for Market Discipline in the European Banking Industry: Evidence from

Subordinated Debt Issues. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 35(3), 443-472.

Wintoki, M. B., Linck, J. S., & Netter, J. M. (2012). Endogeneity and the Dynamics of Internal Corporate

Governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(3), 581-606.

Page 42: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

41

Appendix I

Variable Name Definition

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 Micro-level systemic risk at 1% significance level (Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2016). In all

tables in this paper I’m presenting Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 at 1% significance level but I also used 5%

level as a robustness check and get very similar results.

CATFIN Macro-level systemic risk. (Allen, Bali and Tang, 2012)

ln(Bank Allocation) Natural logarithm of a bank’s allocation share in percentages of a lead or participant bank.

ln(Package Amount) Natural log of the deal size. Amount is in millions. Source: DealScan

ln(Maturity) Natural log of the maturity of the deal in months. Deal maturity is the weighted average of

the facility maturities. Source: DealScan

ln(No. of Lead Banks) Natural log of the number of lead lenders in the deal syndicate. Source: DealScan

ln(Facility Amount) Natural log of the facility size. Amount is in millions. Source: DealScan

ln(Facility Maturity) Natural log of the maturity of the facility in months. Source: DealScan

ln(No. of Participants) Natural log of the number of participating lenders in the facility syndicate. Source: DealScan

Secured Dummy An indicator variable that takes a value of one if the facility is secured. Source: DealScan

ln(Bank Total Assets) Natural log of the total assets of the lender at quarter of loan origination. Source: Y-9c

Bank Capital Ratio Total capital of the lender over total assets of the lender. Source: Y-9c

Bank Return on Equity Lenders return on book equity. Source: Y-9c

Bank Liquidity The sum of cash and available-for-sale securities divided by bank total assets. Source: Y-9C

Bank Loan Charge-offs The total charge-offs on loans and leases divided by bank total assets. Source: Y-9C

Bank Loan Loss Allowance The total allowance for loan and lease losses divided by bank total assets. Source: Y-9C

Bank Risk-Weighted Assets The total risk weighted assets divided by bank total assets.

GDP Growth Quarterly GDP per capita growth rate. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Early Warn An indicator variable that takes a value of one if CATFIN exceeds the early warning threshold

of 35.1855%.

Recession An indicator variable that takes a value of one if the quarter right before loan origination is

a recession period. Source: National Bureau of Economic Research

Distance-to-default The expected distance-to-default of the borrowers following Bharath and Shumway (2004),

Crosbie and Bohn (2003) and Drucker and Puri (2009).

Borrower Asset Volatility The one-year asset volatility calculated using KMV/Merton method.

Borrower Total Assets Borrower book assets. Source: Compustat

Borrower Leverage The ratio of the book value of total long- and short-term debt to the book value of total assets.

Borrower Tangibility The ratio of net plant, property, and equipment (NPPE) to total assets.

Lending Relationship Borrowed from Bharath el al. (2007), this variable measures the lending relationship between

borrower and lender in a specific year. Specifically, the lending relationship between

borrower i and bank j in year t is defined as:

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔 𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 =$ 𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝑙𝑜𝑎𝑛𝑠 𝑡𝑜 𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟 𝑖 𝑏𝑦 𝑏𝑎𝑛𝑘 𝑗 𝑖𝑛 𝑙𝑎𝑠𝑡 5 𝑦𝑒𝑎𝑟𝑠

𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙 $ 𝑎𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡 𝑜𝑓 𝑙𝑜𝑎𝑛𝑠 𝑏𝑦 𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟 𝑖 𝑖𝑛 𝑙𝑎𝑠𝑡 5 𝑦𝑒𝑎𝑟𝑠

Page 43: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

42

Appendix II

Following Hagendorff et. al. (2017), Panel A presents the eight bank business model variables used for the

three-way fixed effect regressions. Panel B lists the bank control variables and macroeconomic variables.

Bank-level data are from form FR Y-9C of the Consolidated Financial Statements published by the Board

of Governors of the Federal Reserve System with references to data mnemonics displayed. State-level

coincident indices are from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Variable Name Definition

Panel A: Bank Business Policy Variable

Non-interest income Non-interest income (bhck4079) over the sum of interest income (bhck4107) and non-interest

income (bhck4079) (%)

Loans Total loans (bhck2122) over total assets (bhck2170) (%)

MBS Before 2009: Private-label mortgage backed securities (bhck1709 + bhck1733 + bhck1713 +

bhck1736 + bhck3536) over total assets (%);

After 2009: Private-label mortgage backed securities (bhckg308 + bhckk146 + bhckg320 +

bhckk154 + bhckg311 + bhckk149 + bhckg323 + bhckk157 + bhckg381 + bhkk198) over total

assets (%)

Derivatives Gross notional amount of derivative contracts held for trading (log of 1 + gross notional amounts

on contracts on interest rate (bhcka126), foreign exchange (bhcka127), equity derivatives

(bhck8723), and others (bhck8724)) over total assets (%)

Lending diversification 1–Herfindahl index of the shares of real estate (bhck1410), commercial and industrial (bhck1763 +

bhck1764), consumer (bhck1975) and other loans out of total loans.

Gap12 Liabilities repricing or maturing within 12 months (bhck3197) minus assets repricing or maturing

within 12 months (bhck3296 + bhck3298) divided by total asset (%)

Loans/Deposits Total loans over total deposits (bhdm6631 + bhdm6636 + bhfn6631 + bhfn6636) (%)

Non-deposit funding 1 – (deposits over total liabilities (bhck2948)) (%)

Panel B: Bank Control Variable and Macroeconomic Variables

Size Log of total assets (in 2000 $)

Equity Total equity (bhck3210) over total assets (%)

Market to book Log of the ratio of the market to book value of equity

Core deposits 1 – (total time deposits of $100,000 or more (bhcb2604) over total deposits (%)

Productivity Total assets over full-time employees (bhck4150) ($ millions)

Economy 12-month average of the monthly coincident index at the state level

Page 44: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

43

Table 1

Summary Statistics

Table 1 reports summary statistics of the sample of 10,915 packages (22,595 package-lender pairs) borrowed by 3,603

firms from 214 banks, which are owned by 66 bank holding companies. All loans are originated between Q1 1995 and

Q4 2013. Syndicated loan data is obtained from Loan Pricing Corporation’s (LPC) Dealscan loan database. Bank

characteristics data are collected from the Consolidated Financial Statements for Holding Companies (“FR Y-9C”)

available on the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago website. Borrower balance sheet data are obtained from Compustat.

The sample presented is used in the baseline regressions presented in Table 3. The number of observations (N) indicates

the sample on which the summary statistics are based. N is by package-lender, where lender is identified at the bank

holding company level. ln(Deal Amount) is the natural logarithm of the package size (in millions). ln(Maturity) is the

natural log of the maturity of the package (in months). Maturity of the package is calculated as the value-weighted

average maturity of all facilities in the package. ln(Number of Leads) is the natural logarithm of the number of lead

lenders in the deal syndicate. A bank is defined as a lead lender if its lend arranger credit variable in Dealscan is “Yes”.

Secured is a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if at least one facility in the package is secured, and 0 otherwise.

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡) is defined as the natural logarithm of borrower’s total assets (in billions);

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑖,𝑡 is defined as total property, plant, and equipment divided by total assets;

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 is defined as borrower’s total debt divided by total assets. ∆CoVaR is the time-varying

microlevel systemic risk calculated following in Adrian and Brunnermeier (2016). 𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡) is

the natural logarithm of the total assets (BHCK2170) of the lender at the quarter of loan origination. Bank Capital

Ratio is lender’s total book equity (BHCK3210) over total assets (BHCK2170). Capital Ratio is in decimal. Bank Return

on Equity is lender’s net income (BHCK4340) over book equity (BHCK3210). Distance-to-default is the expected

distance-to-default calculated using method from Bharath and Shumway (2004), Crosbie and Bohn (2003) and Drucker

and Puri (2009). Lending relationship between borrower i and bank j is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower

i by bank j in last 5 years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years. CATFIN is the macro-level

systemic risk borrowed from Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012). 𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 is quarterly growth rate of US quarterly GDP

per capita.

Page 45: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

44

Variable N Mean Median Std. P25 P75

Loan Characteristics

Deal Amount ($million) 22,595 878.017 400.000 1,555.896 150.000 1,000.000

ln(Deal Amount) 22,595 19.677 19.807 1.504 18.826 20.723

Maturity (in months) 22,595 49.480 59.891 20.530 36.000 60.000

ln(Maturity) 22,595 3.775 4.093 0.566 3.584 4.094

Number of Lead Banks 22,595 4.141 4.000 2.716 2.000 5.000

Secured 22,595 0.576 1.000 0.494 0.000 1.000

Lending Relationship 22,595 0.471 0.482 0.435 0.000 1.000

Borrower Characteristics

Distance-to-default 22,595 6.772 6.002 4.903 3.433 9.184

Tangibility 22,595 0.310 0.243 0.233 0.126 0.446

Borrower Total Assets ($billion) 22,595 6.752 1.828 14.621 0.610 5.777

Leverage 22,595 0.322 0.298 0.194 0.188 0.426

Bank Characteristics

∆CoVaR 22,595 5.216 4.351 2.550 3.432 6.302

Bank Total Assets ($billion) 22,595 778.874 427.849 748.184 167.830 1317.591

Capital Ratio 22,595 0.085 0.083 0.016 0.074 0.094

Return on Equity 22,595 0.083 0.078 0.052 0.041 0.115

Macroeconomic Conditions

CATFIN 22,595 2.393 2.286 0.926 1.644 2.968

GDP Growth (quarterly) 22,595 2.662 2.730 1.565 1.650 4.080

Page 46: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

45

Table 2

Correlation Matrix

Table 2 reports the spearman correlation matrix for the sample of 10,915 packages (22,595 package-lender pairs) originated between Q1 1995 and Q4 2013. The sample is

used in the baseline regressions presented in Table 3. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15)

(1) Borrower Distance to Default 1.000

(2) ∆CoVaR -0.220 1.000

(3) CATFIN -0.289 0.582 1.000

(4) Package Amount 0.204 0.035 -0.074 1.000

(5) Package Maturity 0.145 -0.097 -0.189 0.218 1.000

(6) Number of Lead Banks 0.198 -0.018 -0.100 0.640 0.197 1.000

(7) Secure Dummy -0.357 -0.017 0.008 -0.279 0.157 -0.219 1.000

(8) Bank Total Assets 0.141 0.233 -0.076 0.303 0.132 0.077 -0.075 1.000

(9) Bank Capital Ratio 0.158 -0.154 -0.152 0.068 0.155 0.092 0.044 0.170 1.000

(10) Bank Return on Equity 0.005 -0.059 -0.099 -0.082 -0.014 0.007 -0.020 -0.289 -0.254 1.000

(11) Borrower Tangibility -0.110 0.025 0.021 0.071 0.004 0.032 -0.022 -0.044 -0.086 0.046 1.000

(12) Borrower Total Assets 0.209 0.046 -0.075 0.840 0.047 0.543 -0.410 0.362 0.068 -0.108 0.100 1.000

(13) Borrower Leverage -0.371 0.044 0.012 0.192 0.212 0.106 0.245 -0.029 -0.102 0.044 0.172 0.061 1.000

(14) Lending Relationship 0.079 0.048 -0.080 0.125 0.002 0.008 -0.102 0.274 0.078 -0.122 -0.001 0.163 -0.017 1.000

(15) GDP Growth -0.007 -0.083 -0.032 -0.081 0.031 -0.006 -0.018 -0.362 -0.354 0.299 0.053 -0.145 0.070 -0.110 1.000

Page 47: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

46

Table 3

Summary Statistics: Within-loan Regressions

Table 3 reports the summary statistics for the within-loan regressions in equation (11). Because the regressions are run

at both package and facility level, the summary statistics are reported at both levels, with Panel A reporting at the

package level and Panel B reporting at the facility level. Since all borrower, loan, and macroeconomic characteristics

drop out in a within-loan regression, I only report loan characteristics (at both levels) in this table. A borrower doesn’t

have to have data on characteristics except for their distance-to-default and two-digit SIC code to be included in this

regression.

Page 48: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

47

Panel A: Package Level

Variable N Mean Median Std. P25 P75

Borrower Characteristics

Merton Distance-to-default 13004 8.181 7.564 5.073 4.758 10.872

Bank Characteristics

∆CoVaR 13004 4.705 3.893 2.684 3.067 5.323

Bank Allocation (in percent) 13004 10.513 7.779 10.307 4.300 13.000

Bank Total Assets ($billion) 13004 692.547 307.786 733.975 103.110 1228.625

ln(Bank Total Assets) 13004 19.595 19.522 1.353 18.438 20.917

Bank Capital Ratio 13004 0.092 0.090 0.017 0.081 0.101

Bank Return on Equity 13004 0.068 0.057 0.051 0.033 0.099

Bank Liquidity 13004 0.213 0.197 0.106 0.150 0.239

Bank Loan Charge-off 13004 0.004 0.002 0.004 0.001 0.005

Bank Loan Loss Allowed 13004 0.011 0.010 0.006 0.007 0.014

Bank Risk-weighted Assets 13004 0.760 0.776 0.156 0.658 0.855

Lead Lender Dummy 13004 0.265 0.000 0.441 0.000 1.000

Lending Relationship 13004 0.412 0.063 0.558 0.000 0.791

Loan Characteristics

Package Amount ($million) 13004 1027.549 500.000 1608.502 250.000 1200.000

Package Maturity (in months) 13004 50.970 60.000 13.402 37.846 60.000

Number of Lead Banks 13004 2.304 2.000 2.199 1.000 2.000

Number of Participants 13004 15.194 14.000 9.114 9.000 20.000

Secure Dummy 10949 0.424 0.000 0.494 0.000 1.000

Panel B: Facility Level

Variable N Mean Median Std. P25 P75

Borrower Characteristics

Merton Distance-to-default 16275 8.056 7.363 5.102 4.684 10.684

Bank Characteristics

∆CoVaR 16275 4.701 3.917 2.643 3.076 5.332

Bank Allocation (in percent) 16275 11.013 8.000 10.914 4.665 13.333

Bank Total Assets ($billion) 16275 706.372 308.913 745.355 104.265 1251.046

ln(Bank Total Assets) 16275 19.611 19.534 1.361 18.451 20.927

Bank Capital Ratio 16275 0.093 0.091 0.017 0.081 0.103

Bank Return on Equity 16275 0.068 0.058 0.051 0.032 0.099

Bank Liquidity 16275 0.211 0.195 0.104 0.150 0.236

Bank Loan Charge-off 16275 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.001 0.005

Bank Loan Loss Allowed 16275 0.011 0.010 0.006 0.007 0.014

Bank Risk-weighted Assets 16275 0.759 0.776 0.155 0.650 0.855

Lead Lender Dummy 16275 0.278 0.000 0.448 0.000 1.000

Lending Relationship 16275 0.331 0.000 0.398 0.000 0.692

Loan Characteristics

Facility Amount ($million) 16275 741.714 400.000 1094.778 175.000 850.000

Facility Maturity (in months) 16232 53.370 60.000 12.772 48.000 60.000

Number of Lead Banks 16275 2.389 2.000 2.224 1.000 3.000

Number of Participants 16275 15.602 14.000 9.502 9.000 21.000

Secure Dummy 13657 0.487 0.000 0.500 0.000 1.000

Page 49: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

48

Table 4

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk: Fixed Effects Regressions

Table 4 reports the coefficient estimates from the following fixed effects regression:

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼2𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 + 𝛼3Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 + 𝛼4Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1

+ 𝛼5𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝛼6𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜l𝑠𝑘,𝑡 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼8𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑖,𝑡

+ 𝛼9𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼10𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑡 + 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟𝐹𝐸 + 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦𝐹𝐸 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸

+ 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 ,(9)

where subscript i, j, k, and t indicate the borrowing firm, the bank, the package, and the time (quarter), respectively. The

regressions are run at the package level and observations are by package-lender pairs, where lenders include both lead

lenders and non-lead participants, and are identified at the bank holding company level. The dependent variable,

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡, is borrower’s distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination. Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 and 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡

are contemporaneous systemic risks at the quarter of loan origination. Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 and 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 are

one quarter lagged bank systemic risk and borrower distance-to-default. The vectors of variables Loan Controls, Bank

Controls, and Borrower Controls contain loan, bank, and firm-specific control variables from the quarter of loan

origination. 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 is a dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the loan is originated at an economic recession

quarter defined by National Bureau of Economic Research, and 0 otherwise. 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 is a dummy variable, which

is equal to 1 when CATFIN exceeds its early warning level at the quarter of loan origination, and 0 otherwise. For each

quarter t, the early warning level is calculated as the median CATFIN using all observations up to quarter t in which the

three-month moving average Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI-MA3) falls below -0.7. ln(Deal Amount) is

the natural logarithm of the package size (in millions). ln(Maturity) is the natural log of the maturity of the package (in

months), where deal maturity is the weighted average maturity of all facilities in the package. ln(Number of Leads) is

the natural logarithm of the number of lead lenders in the deal syndicate. Secured is a dummy variable that takes a value

of 1 if at least one facility in the package is secured, and 0 otherwise. 𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡) is the natural logarithm

of the total assets of the lender at the quarter of loan origination. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 is defined as the bank’s total

capital over total assets. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 is defined as bank net income over book equity.

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡) is defined as the natural logarithm of borrower’s total assets (in billions);

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑖,𝑡 is defined as total property, plant, and equipment divided by total assets;

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 is defined as borrower’s total debt divided by total assets. 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 is a

lending relationship measure borrowed from Bharath et al. (2007). The lending relationship between borrower i and

bank j is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in last 5 years over the total dollar amount of

loans by borrower i in last 5 years. 𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 is quarterly growth rate of US quarterly GDP per capita. Standard

errors are in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 50: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

49

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I

II

III

IV

V

VI

VII

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.146∗∗∗ -0.077∗∗∗ -0.144∗∗∗ -0.078∗∗∗ -0.203∗∗∗ -0.200∗∗∗ -0.195∗∗∗

(0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.008) (0.015) (0.008) (0.011)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.029∗∗∗ -0.070∗∗∗ -0.031∗∗∗ -0.071∗∗∗ -0.050∗∗∗ -0.010 -0.020∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.008)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.965∗∗∗ 0.966∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.954∗∗∗ 0.954∗∗∗ 0.954∗∗∗

(0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)

𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 -0.469∗∗∗ -0.452∗∗∗ -0.613∗∗∗

(0.023) (0.030) (0.034)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 0.027∗∗∗

(0.003)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.103∗∗∗

(0.011)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -1.037∗∗∗

(0.125)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 0.105∗∗∗

(0.012)

𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 -1.180∗∗∗

(0.083)

𝑙𝑛(𝐷𝑒𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡)𝑘,𝑡 0.002 0.004 0.003 0.001 0.006

(0.018) (0.017) (0.017) (0.018) (0.017)

𝑙𝑛(𝑀𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦)𝑘,𝑡 0.045∗∗ 0.038∗ 0.043∗ 0.052∗∗ 0.051∗∗

(0.023) (0.023) (0.023) (0.023) (0.023)

𝑙𝑛(𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟𝑜𝑓𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠)𝑘,𝑡 0.083∗∗∗ 0.079∗∗∗ 0.080∗∗∗ 0.084∗∗∗ 0.075∗∗∗

(0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022)

𝑆𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑘,𝑡 0.010 0.005 0.003 0.007 0.005

(0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027) (0.027)

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡 0.019 0.026 0.020 0.010 0.011

(0.047) (0.047) (0.047) (0.047) (0.047)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 0.128 -0.765 -0.816 -0.281 -0.043

(1.336) (1.331) (1.328) (1.332) (1.329)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 0.151 0.264 0.547∗∗ 0.584∗∗ 0.663∗∗∗

(0.254) (0.253) (0.254) (0.257) (0.256)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.228∗∗∗ -0.246∗∗∗ -0.246∗∗∗ -0.229∗∗∗ -0.237∗∗∗

(0.055) (0.055) (0.055) (0.055) (0.055)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑆𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.005 -0.007 -0.007 -0.005 -0.008

(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.563∗∗∗ -0.561∗∗∗ -0.564∗∗∗ -0.562∗∗∗ -0.548∗∗∗

(0.069) (0.068) (0.068) (0.068) (0.068)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 -0.013 -0.013 -0.015 -0.013 -0.016

(0.027) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026)

𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 0.054∗∗∗ 0.062∗∗∗ 0.109∗∗∗ 0.113∗∗∗

(0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019)

Observations 35219 35219 22595 22595 22595 22595 22595

R2 0.901 0.902 0.893 0.894 0.894 0.893 0.894

Adjusted R2 0.901 0.902 0.892 0.893 0.894 0.893 0.893

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 51: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

50

Table 5

Two-Stage Least Square Regressions: Underidentification Test and Exogeneity Test

Table 5 reports the Anderson LM test statistic for tests of identification and Sargan statistics for test of exogeneity

for the 2SLS regressions. The null hypothesis for the test of identification is that the instruments and endogenous

variables are not correlated and, in addition, that the overidentifying restrictions are valid. Sargan’s chi-square statistic

tests the joint null hypothesis that the excluded instruments are valid instruments (i.e., uncorrelated with the error

term) and correctly excluded from the estimated equation. Each column corresponds to the column of same number

in Table 5 and Table 6.

I II III IV V VI VII

Underidentification Test (Anderson’s LM Statistic)

33.326 33.203

29.124

29.029

28.867

29.112

29.296

Chi-square P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

Sargan Statistic

(Instrument Exogeneity Test)

0.006

0.012

0.438

0.434

0.509

0.386

0.329

Chi-square P-value 0.936 0.913 0.501 0.510 0.476 0.534 0.566

Page 52: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

51

Table 6

Two-Stage Least Square Regressions: First Stage

Table 6 reports the coefficients estimates from the first stage of the two-stage lease square regressions. The dependent

variable is 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡, defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in last 5 years over

the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years. The two instrument variables are geographic distance and

number of banks in the state of the borrower. Geographic distance measured as the distance in thousand kilometers

between the location of the firm and the location of the financial top holder of the lending bank at the quarter of loan

origination. The number of banks is measured as the number of financial institutions that filed Call Report during the

quarter of loan origination in the borrower’s state. Each column in Table 5 corresponds to the column with same number

in Table 6, which presents the second stage of the two-stage least square regressions. Standard errors are in parentheses.

*, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 53: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

52

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡

I

II

III

IV

V

VI

VII

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑖,𝑗 -0.031∗∗∗ -0.030∗∗∗ -0.029∗∗∗ -0.029∗∗∗ -0.029∗∗∗ -0.029∗∗∗ -0.029∗∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

𝑁𝑜. 𝑜𝑓𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑠𝑖 -0.037 -0.036 -0.022 -0.022 -0.023 -0.023 -0.023

(0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.025)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.005 -0.004 -0.005 -0.004 -0.009 -0.004 -0.011∗

(0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.005) (0.010) (0.005) (0.006)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 0.007∗∗ 0.007∗ 0.006∗ 0.006∗ 0.005 0.006 0.006∗

(0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.000 0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000 -0.000

(0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)

𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 -0.007 -0.005 -0.017

(0.013) (0.013) (0.023)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 0.002

(0.003)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.005

(0.009)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.078

(0.073)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 0.008

(0.007)

𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 -0.025

(0.046)

𝑙𝑛(𝐷𝑒𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡)𝑘,𝑡 0.029∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗

(0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010)

𝑙𝑛(𝑀𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦)𝑘,𝑡 -0.027∗∗ -0.027∗∗ -0.027∗∗ -0.028∗∗ -0.027∗∗

(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012)

𝑙𝑛(𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟𝑜𝑓𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠)𝑘,𝑡 -0.123∗∗∗ -0.123∗∗∗ -0.123∗∗∗ -0.123∗∗∗ -0.123∗∗∗

(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012)

𝑆𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑘,𝑡 -0.023 -0.023 -0.023 -0.023 -0.023

(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.020 -0.020 -0.020 -0.021 -0.020

(0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑆𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 0.022∗∗∗ 0.021∗∗∗ 0.021∗∗∗ 0.022∗∗∗ 0.022∗∗∗

(0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 0.027 0.028 0.027 0.026 0.026

(0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036) (0.036)

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡 -0.052∗∗ -0.052∗∗ -0.053∗∗ -0.052∗∗ -0.054∗∗

(0.026) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 -0.294 -0.297 -0.292 -0.288 -0.303

(0.648) (0.648) (0.648) (0.649) (0.648)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.170 -0.168 -0.163 -0.181 -0.149

(0.123) (0.124) (0.124) (0.125) (0.125)

𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.002

(0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009)

Observations 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909

𝑅2 0.110 0.110 0.135 0.135 0.135 0.135 0.136

Adjusted 𝑅2 0.093 0.093 0.116 0.116 0.116 0.116 0.116

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 54: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

53

Table 7

Two-Stage Least Square Regressions: Second Stage

Table 7 reports the coefficients estimates from the second stage of the two-stage lease square regressions. The dependent

variable is 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 , the borrower’s distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination.

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 is the fitted value from the first stage regression presented in Table 6. All other variables are

defined the same as Table 4, and their definition can be found in appendix. Standard errors are in parentheses. *, **, and

*** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 55: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

54

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I

II

III

IV

V

VI

VII

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.192∗∗∗ -0.101∗∗∗ -0.195∗∗∗ -0.107∗∗∗ -0.200∗∗∗ -0.199∗∗∗ -0.137∗∗∗

(0.021) (0.023) (0.022) (0.023) (0.047) (0.023) (0.032)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.018 -0.037∗∗ -0.014 -0.033∗ -0.048∗∗∗ -0.016 -0.030∗

(0.018) (0.017) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019) (0.018)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.949∗∗∗ 0.952∗∗∗ 0.937∗∗∗ 0.940∗∗∗ 0.941∗∗∗ 0.939∗∗∗ 0.940∗∗∗

(0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.007)

𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 -0.555∗∗∗ -0.540∗∗∗ -0.748∗∗∗

(0.061) (0.062) (0.109)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 0.033∗∗

(0.014)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.059

(0.042)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.788∗∗

(0.358)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 0.015

(0.035)

𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 -0.745∗∗∗

(0.219)

𝑙𝑛(𝐷𝑒𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡)𝑘,𝑡 -0.070 -0.062 -0.060 -0.073 -0.059

(0.053) (0.052) (0.051) (0.053) (0.052)

𝑙𝑛(𝑀𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦)𝑘,𝑡 0.178∗∗∗ 0.156∗∗ 0.155∗∗ 0.193∗∗∗ 0.173∗∗∗

(0.063) (0.061) (0.061) (0.063) (0.062)

𝑙𝑛(𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟𝑜𝑓𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠)𝑘,𝑡 0.388∗∗∗ 0.366∗∗∗ 0.360∗∗∗ 0.396∗∗∗ 0.372∗∗∗

(0.124) (0.121) (0.121) (0.125) (0.122)

𝑆𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑘,𝑡 -0.018 -0.010 -0.012 -0.021 -0.024

(0.071) (0.069) (0.069) (0.071) (0.070)

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡 -0.029 0.020 0.004 -0.038 0.003

(0.132) (0.129) (0.129) (0.133) (0.132)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 0.205 -0.211 -0.139 -0.244 0.490

(3.095) (3.022) (3.006) (3.120) (3.059)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.062 0.174 0.251 0.125 0.036

(0.600) (0.586) (0.583) (0.612) (0.598)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.356∗∗∗ -0.384∗∗∗ -0.383∗∗∗ -0.359∗∗∗ -0.373∗∗∗

(0.136) (0.133) (0.132) (0.137) (0.134)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑆𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.087∗∗ -0.089∗∗ -0.088∗∗ -0.088∗∗ -0.092∗∗

(0.042) (0.041) (0.041) (0.043) (0.042)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.650∗∗∗ -0.633∗∗∗ -0.635∗∗∗ -0.636∗∗∗ -0.634∗∗∗

(0.172) (0.168) (0.167) (0.174) (0.170)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 2.299∗∗∗ 2.163∗∗∗ 2.413∗∗∗ 2.260∗∗∗ 2.215∗∗ 2.477∗∗∗ 2.348∗∗∗

(0.817) (0.800) (0.889) (0.869) (0.867) (0.896) (0.876)

𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 0.141∗∗∗ 0.105∗∗ 0.123∗∗∗ 0.189∗∗∗

(0.044) (0.043) (0.043) (0.044)

Observations 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909 4909

R 2 0.845 0.852 0.844 0.851 0.853 0.842 0.848

Adjusted R 2 0.842 0.849 0.841 0.848 0.850 0.838 0.844

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 56: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

55

Table 8

Lead-lag Effect Analysis

Table 8 reports the coefficients estimates from the lead-lag effect regressions. The dependent variable in Column I, II,

III, and IV is 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡, the borrower’s distance-to-default at the quarter of loan origination, and the

dependent variable in Column V, VI, VII, and VII is 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡, bank’s systemic risk at the quarter of loan origination.

Standard errors are in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡

I

II

III

IV

V

VI

VII

VIII

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.113∗∗∗ -0.085∗∗∗ -0.121∗∗∗ -0.093∗∗∗ 0.559∗∗∗ 0.373∗∗∗ 0.586∗∗∗ 0.403∗∗∗

(0.007) (0.009) (0.007) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.965∗∗∗ 0.965∗∗∗ 0.946∗∗∗ 0.945∗∗∗ -0.001 0.004 0.001 0.006∗∗

(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003)

𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 -0.175∗∗∗ -0.176∗∗∗ 1.170∗∗∗ 1.166∗∗∗

(0.027) (0.027) (0.030) (0.029)

𝑙𝑛(𝐷𝑒𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡)𝑘,𝑡 0.021 0.023 -0.008 -0.019

(0.017) (0.017) (0.019) (0.018)

𝑙𝑛(𝑀𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦)𝑘,𝑡 0.051∗∗ 0.045∗ -0.097∗∗∗ -0.054∗∗

(0.023) (0.023) (0.026) (0.025)

𝑙𝑛(𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟𝑜𝑓𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠)𝑘,𝑡 0.096∗∗∗ 0.093∗∗∗ -0.043∗ -0.025

(0.023) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024)

𝑆𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑘,𝑡 0.001 0.005 0.036 0.005

(0.027) (0.027) (0.030) (0.029)

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡 -0.034 -0.029 0.305∗∗∗ 0.276∗∗∗

(0.049) (0.048) (0.054) (0.052)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 1.369 1.061 -0.803∗∗∗ -8.764∗∗∗

(1.263) (1.263) (1.397) (1.350)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 1.213∗∗∗ 1.287∗∗∗ -5.169∗∗∗ -5.660∗∗∗

(0.246) (0.246) (0.272) (0.263)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.132∗∗ -0.134∗∗ -0.008 0.008

(0.056) (0.056) (0.062) (0.059)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑆𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.026∗ -0.025∗ 0.033∗∗ 0.025∗

(0.013) (0.013) (0.015) (0.014)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.843∗∗∗ -0.847∗∗∗ 0.072 0.097

(0.064) (0.064) (0.071) (0.069)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 0.008 0.006 -0.039 -0.029

(0.027) (0.027) (0.030) (0.029)

𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 0.092∗∗∗ 0.086∗∗∗ -0.461∗∗∗ -0.427∗∗∗

(0.020) (0.020) (0.022) (0.022)

Observations 22464 22464 22464 22464 22464 22464 22464 22464

R 2 0.889 0.889 0.890 0.890 0.622 0.647 0.637 0.662

Adjusted R 2 0.888 0.889 0.890 0.890 0.620 0.645 0.636 0.660

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 57: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

56

Table 9

Within-loan Regressions

Table 9 reports the coefficients estimate from the within-loan regressions:

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑘 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 + 𝛼2Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦 + 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 +

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼3𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 +𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡,(10)

Panel A reports the package level regressions, and Panel B reports the facility level regressions. In each panel, Columns

I, II, and III report the coefficients of regressions using contemporaneous systemic risk, while Columns IV, V, VI report

the coefficients of regression using lagged systemic risk. Subscript i, j, k, and t indicate the borrowing firm, the bank,

the packages/facilities, and the time (quarter) respectively, and 𝛼𝑘 denotes the package/facility fixed effects. Standard

errors are clustered by bank. The dependent variable in all regressions is the bank allocation share in percentages at

either package or facility level. 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦 denotes how extreme a borrower’s default risk is compared with

other borrowers in the same year. It can be 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 , 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 , or 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 . 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1

equals 1 if the borrower’s distance-to-default falls into the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th quantiles (risky), and 0 if it falls into

the 6th, 7th, 8th, 9th, and 10th quantiles (less risky). 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 equals 1 if the borrower’s distance-to-default falls into

the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, and 4th quantiles (risky), and 0 if it falls into the 7th, 8th, 9th, and 10th quantiles (less risky). 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3

equals 1 if the borrower’s distance-to-default falls into the 1st, 2nd, and 3rd quantiles (risky), and 0 if it falls into the 8th,

9th, and 10th quantiles (less risky). 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 and 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 only focus on borrowers whose default risks are

either very high or very low. Columns I and IV interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1, Columns II and V interact

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 , and Columns III and VI interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 .

𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 equals 1 if bank j is a lead lender in the package/facility k. I define a bank as a lead lender if

its lender credit variable is “Yes” in Dealscan. 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 controls for the intensity of past lending

relationships between borrower i and bank j. It is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in the

last 5 years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 includes an array of

bank control variables including the natural logarithm of bank total assets (in millions), bank capital ratio, bank

return on equity, bank liquidity, bank loan charge-offs, bank loan loss allowance, and bank risk-weighted assets.

All bank control variables are lagged by one quarter. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸 denotes bank fixed effects. Standard errors are in

parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 58: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

57

Panel A: Package Level 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV V VI

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.096∗ -0.122∗∗ -0.189∗∗∗

(0.050) (0.059) (0.060) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.129∗∗ -0.133∗∗ -0.180∗∗

(0.050) (0.058) (0.067)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 0.204∗∗∗

(0.053) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 0.245∗∗∗

(0.063) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 0.387∗∗∗

(0.078) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 0.204∗∗∗

(0.053) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 0.227∗∗∗

(0.061) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 0.348∗∗∗

(0.074)

𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 5.909∗∗∗ 6.137∗∗∗ 6.399∗∗∗ 5.908∗∗∗ 6.136∗∗∗ 6.401∗∗∗

(0.451) (0.436) (0.513) (0.451) (0.438) (0.515)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 0.709∗∗∗ 0.637∗∗∗ 0.772∗∗∗ 0.705∗∗∗ 0.633∗∗∗ 0.766∗∗∗

(0.105) (0.115) (0.096) (0.104) (0.114) (0.096)

ln(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡−1 0.570∗∗ 0.654∗∗ 0.723∗∗ 0.572∗∗ 0.662∗∗ 0.735∗∗

(0.280) (0.280) (0.334) (0.279) (0.279) (0.333)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡−1 -3.785 -4.343 -3.041 -3.774 -4.449 -3.197

(4.380) (4.478) (5.675) (4.453) (4.496) (5.761)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.696 0.639 0.464 -0.826 0.507 0.361

(1.316) (1.433) (1.770) (1.308) (1.420) (1.810)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -2.752∗ -3.260∗ -2.785 -2.676 -3.216∗ -2.773

(1.591) (1.835) (2.186) (1.600) (1.846) (2.198)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑒 − 𝑂𝑓𝑓𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 7.419 31.068 49.596 9.400 33.031 52.783

(29.020) (29.913) (33.254) (28.611) (29.510) (33.243)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐿𝑜𝑠𝑠𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑗,𝑡−1 1.236 -0.308 1.337 2.826 0.734 1.528

(23.152) (24.910) (30.013) (23.078) (25.021) (30.085)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 −𝑊𝑒𝑖𝑔ℎ𝑡𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 3.235∗ 3.571∗ 4.505∗ 3.222∗ 3.548∗ 4.492∗

(1.614) (1.910) (2.267) (1.641) (1.931) (2.287)

Observations 12647 10065 7513 12647 10065 7513

R 2 0.855 0.853 0.850 0.855 0.853 0.850

Adjusted R 2 0.821 0.818 0.812 0.821 0.818 0.812

Package fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 59: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

58

Panel B: Facility Level 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV V VI

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.153∗∗∗ -0.151∗∗∗ -0.218∗∗∗

(0.047) (0.055) (0.069) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.176∗∗∗ -0.183∗∗∗ -0.217∗∗

(0.051) (0.063) (0.082)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 0.212∗∗∗

(0.045) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 0.268∗∗∗

(0.054) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 0.340∗∗∗

(0.067) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦1 0.202∗∗∗

(0.041) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦2 0.254∗∗∗

(0.049) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦3 0.284∗∗∗

(0.057)

𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 6.065∗∗∗ 6.275∗∗∗ 6.513∗∗∗ 6.064∗∗∗ 6.275∗∗∗ 6.514∗∗∗

(0.436) (0.432) (0.472) (0.436) (0.433) (0.474)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 0.944∗∗∗ 0.887∗∗∗ 0.872∗∗∗ 0.940∗∗∗ 0.883∗∗∗ 0.863∗∗∗

(0.108) (0.102) (0.146) (0.108) (0.100) (0.146)

ln(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡−1 0.181 0.311 0.261 0.189 0.319 0.273

(0.322) (0.308) (0.324) (0.322) (0.308) (0.322)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡−1 -11.684∗∗ -12.397∗ -15.468∗∗ -11.504∗∗ -12.374∗ -15.210∗∗

(5.694) (6.425) (6.872) (5.714) (6.354) (6.856)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -2.127 -1.380 -1.504 -2.262 -1.563 -1.578

(1.767) (1.800) (2.211) (1.777) (1.813) (2.265)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -3.581∗ -3.380∗ -3.044 -3.505∗ -3.293 -2.982

(1.847) (1.954) (2.212) (1.838) (1.962) (2.243)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑒 − 𝑂𝑓𝑓𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 9.996 32.834 48.991 14.141 36.790 56.327∗

(28.346) (29.436) (32.808) (27.758) (28.913) (31.239)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐿𝑜𝑠𝑠𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑗,𝑡−1 5.139 7.437 18.002 5.762 9.442 18.053

(28.904) (32.261) (35.329) (28.921) (32.118) (35.152)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 −𝑊𝑒𝑖𝑔ℎ𝑡𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 4.378∗∗ 5.008∗∗ 7.022∗∗∗ 4.375∗∗ 4.993∗∗ 7.034∗∗∗

(1.777) (1.984) (2.270) (1.798) (2.014) (2.302)

Observations 15785 12556 9383 15785 12556 9383

R 2 0.843 0.844 0.839 0.843 0.844 0.839

Adjusted R 2 0.807 0.807 0.800 0.807 0.807 0.800

Facility fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 60: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

59

Table 10

Within-loan Regressions: Robustness Check

Table 10 reports the coefficients estimate from the within-loan regressions:

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼𝑘 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 + 𝛼2Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

+ 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼3𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 +𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡,(11)

where subscripts i, j, k, and t indicate the borrowing firm, the bank, the packages/facilities, and the time (quarter)

respectively, and 𝛼𝑘 denotes the package/facility fixed effects. The dependent variable in all regressions is the bank

allocation share in percentages at either package or facility level. Panel A reports the package level regressions, and

Panel B reports the facility level regressions. In each panel, Columns I and II report the coefficients of regressions using

contemporaneous systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡, while Columns III and IV report the coefficients of regression using lagged

systemic risk, Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1. In Columns I and III, I interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with contemporaneous borrower distance-to-

default, 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡

, while in Columns II and IV, I interact Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 with 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 −

𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1

. 𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 equals 1 if bank j is a lead lender in the package/facility k. A bank is defined

as a lead lender if its lender credit variable is “Yes” in Dealscan. 𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 controls for the intensity

of past lending relationships between borrower i and bank j. It is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by

bank j in the last 5 years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in last 5 years. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 includes

an array of bank control variables including the natural logarithm of bank total assets (in millions), bank capital

ratio, bank return on equity, bank liquidity, bank loan charge-offs, bank loan loss allowance, and bank risk-

weighted assets. All bank control variables are lagged by one quarter. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸 denotes bank fixed effects.

Standard errors are clustered by bank and are shown in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%,

and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 61: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

60

Panel A: Package Level 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 0.125∗∗∗ 0.171∗∗∗

(0.026) (0.030)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 0.064∗ 0.078∗∗

(0.033) (0.033)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 -0.021∗∗∗

(0.005) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 -0.024∗∗∗

(0.005) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 -0.022∗∗∗

(0.006) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 -0.023∗∗∗

(0.005)

𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 5.914∗∗∗ 5.915∗∗∗ 5.915∗∗∗ 5.917∗∗∗

(0.452) (0.452) (0.452) (0.452)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 0.710∗∗∗ 0.714∗∗∗ 0.705∗∗∗ 0.706∗∗∗

(0.105) (0.105) (0.103) (0.103)

ln(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡−1 0.589∗∗ 0.594∗∗ 0.585∗∗ 0.585∗∗

(0.278) (0.276) (0.278) (0.276)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡−1 -3.571 -3.561 -3.354 -3.470

(4.242) (4.230) (4.272) (4.233)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.704 -0.792 -0.876 -0.985

(1.249) (1.263) (1.254) (1.255)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -2.878∗ -2.966∗ -2.685∗ -2.721∗

(1.527) (1.514) (1.543) (1.538)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑒 − 𝑂𝑓𝑓𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 6.116 6.451 12.241 11.693

(29.829) (30.116) (28.913) (29.293)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐿𝑜𝑠𝑠𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑗,𝑡−1 3.440 2.170 4.444 4.614

(23.746) (24.336) (23.620) (24.088)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 −𝑊𝑒𝑖𝑔ℎ𝑡𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 3.099∗ 3.013∗ 3.202∗ 3.125∗

(1.573) (1.559) (1.600) (1.600)

Observations 12647 12647 12647 12647

R 2 0.855 0.855 0.855 0.855

Adjusted R 2 0.821 0.821 0.821 0.821

Package fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 62: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

61

Panel B: Facility Level 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 0.061∗ 0.112∗∗∗

(0.036) (0.040)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 0.009 0.027

(0.039) (0.039)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 -0.018∗∗∗

(0.004) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 -0.022∗∗∗

(0.004) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 -0.019∗∗∗

(0.006) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 × 𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 -0.022∗∗∗

(0.006)

𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝐷𝑢𝑚𝑚𝑦𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 6.070∗∗∗ 6.071∗∗∗ 6.071∗∗∗ 6.072∗∗∗

(0.437) (0.437) (0.437) (0.436)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 0.940∗∗∗ 0.945∗∗∗ 0.934∗∗∗ 0.936∗∗∗

(0.106) (0.106) (0.107) (0.106)

ln(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡−1 0.203 0.211 0.203 0.205

(0.321) (0.321) (0.322) (0.322)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡−1 -11.480∗∗ -11.466∗∗ -11.141∗∗ -11.234∗∗

(5.528) (5.484) (5.511) (5.435)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -2.136 -2.195 -2.271 -2.361

(1.712) (1.710) (1.734) (1.723)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑑𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡−1 -3.712∗∗ -3.800∗∗ -3.530∗ -3.569∗

(1.793) (1.788) (1.788) (1.789)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑒 − 𝑂𝑓𝑓𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 9.042 9.416 16.804 16.405

(28.962) (29.210) (28.052) (28.274)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐿𝑜𝑠𝑠𝐴𝑙𝑙𝑜𝑤𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑗,𝑡−1 7.622 6.492 7.720 7.806

(29.299) (29.945) (29.405) (29.900)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑖𝑠𝑘 −𝑊𝑒𝑖𝑔ℎ𝑡𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑗,𝑡−1 4.227∗∗ 4.130∗∗ 4.334∗∗ 4.257∗∗

(1.745) (1.733) (1.759) (1.759)

Observations 15785 15785 15785 15785

R 2 0.843 0.843 0.843 0.843

Adjusted R 2 0.807 0.807 0.807 0.807

Facility fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 63: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

62

Table 11

Dynamic Panel GMM Regressions

Table 11 reports the results from dynamic panel GMM regressions. The dependent variable,

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡, is the equal-weighted average borrower distance-to-default for all

loans originated by bank j in quarter t. 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑣𝑔𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1 is the equal-weighted average distance-to-default in

quarter t-1 of borrowers who borrowed from bank j in quarter t. For space reasons, only the coefficients on systemic

risks, 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑣𝑔𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1, and interaction terms are reported. The estimation of the dynamic panel GMM estimator

consists of four steps: First, I convert my regression equation to a bank-quarter panel regression. For each bank j

in quarter t, I calculate the average borrower distance-to-default of all loans originated by this bank in this quarter.

For this calculation, I don’t put any restriction on whether the bank act as a lead lender or non-lead participant.

As long as a bank participates in a loan, this loan is included to the average borrower distance-to-default

calculation. I name this average distance-to-default Bank Portfolio Distance-to-Default. Following the same

methodology, I generate the average borrower characteristics and loan characteristics for each bank in each

quarter. In this way, the regression is converted to a panel regression using quarterly Bank Portfolio Distance-to-

Default as the dependent variable, quarterly systemic risks as the main independent variables, and quarterly bank,

average borrower, and average loan characteristics as control variables. Second, I rewrite the regression equation

as a dynamic model, adding three lags of Bank Portfolio Distance-to-Default (𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 −

𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡−𝑝, p=1,2,3) as explanatory variables. Note that 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡−1is

different from 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑣𝑔𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1. 𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑣𝑔𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1 controls for the borrower’s lagged credit risk one

quarter before their borrowing activity, while 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑃𝑜𝑟𝑡𝑓𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑜𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 − 𝑡𝑜 − 𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑗,𝑡−1 is the average

credit risk the lender actually took in quarter t-1. Third, I first difference all variables, which allows me to control

for unobserved heterogeneity and eliminate potential omitted variable bias. Fourth, I estimate the model by

dynamic panel GMM and use lagged (t-3 to t-8) explanatory variables as instruments. As suggested by Saunders,

Schmid, Walter (2016), using lagged variables as instruments for the present values of these variables controls

for potential simultaneity and reverse causality. In addition, this estimation procedure allows all the explanatory

variables to be treated as endogenous. AR(1) and AR(2) are tests for first-order and second-order serial correlation in

the first differenced residuals with the null hypothesis of no serial correlation. Standard errors are in parentheses. *, **,

and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 64: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

63

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV V VI VII

𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.174∗∗∗ -0.142∗∗∗ -0.193∗∗∗ -0.146∗∗∗ -0.293∗∗ -0.229∗∗ -0.372∗∗∗

(0.023) (0.022) (0.062) (0.043) (0.125) (0.103) (0.088)

𝐿𝑎𝑔𝑔𝑒𝑑𝐴𝑣𝑔𝐷𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑗,𝑡−1 0.897∗∗∗ 0.869∗∗∗ 0.931∗∗∗ 0.864∗∗∗ 0.904∗∗∗ 0.882∗∗∗ 0.976∗∗∗

(0.059) (0.054) (0.096) (0.102) (0.103) (0.079) (0.098)

𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 -0.161∗∗∗ -0.361∗∗∗ -0.513∗∗∗

(0.042) (0.095) (0.158) 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐶𝐴𝑇𝐹𝐼𝑁𝑡 0.034

(0.031) 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -1.533∗∗

(0.713)

𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.217∗∗

(0.084)

𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 -0.729

(0.497) 𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑦𝑊𝑎𝑟𝑛𝑡 0.061

(0.101)

Observations 1550 1550 1505 1505 1505 1505 1505

Controls Variables No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

P-value of AR(1) test 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.007 0.010 0.004 0.001

P-value of AR(2) test 0.940 0.943 0.320 0.943 0.811 0.401 0.565

Page 65: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

64

Table 12

Credit Risk Sensitivity on Systemic Risk: Regressions by Single Banks

Table 12 reports the estimates for coefficients 𝛼1 and 𝛼3 in equation (9), where 𝛼3 is coefficient for the interaction of

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅 and the recession dummy. 𝛼1 measures a bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity during normal periods, while

𝛼1 + 𝛼3 measures the bank’s credit risk-taking sensitivity during recession periods.

RSSD ID Name 𝜶𝟏 𝜶𝟑

3587146 BANK OF NEW YORK MELLON CORPORATION, THE -0.8075 0.5444

1199611 NORTHERN TRUST CORPORATION -0.6599 0.9219

1119794 U.S. BANCORP -0.5555 0.4678

1068294 BANK ONE CORPORATION -0.4345 0.5565

1068762 MELLON FINANCIAL CORPORATION -0.4312 0.5588

1113514 FLEETBOSTON FINANCIAL CORPORATION -0.4136 0.5251

1069778 PNC FINANCIAL SERVICES GROUP, INC., THE -0.4126 0.4209

1068025 KEYCORP -0.4112 0.3281

1070345 FIFTH THIRD BANCORP -0.3796 0.0214

1199844 COMERICA INCORPORATED -0.2985 0.1329

1073551 WACHOVIA CORPORATION -0.2878 0.1362

1039502 JPMORGAN CHASE & CO. -0.2854 0.0514

1120754 WELLS FARGO & COMPANY -0.2383 0.1793

1131787 SUNTRUST BANKS, INC. -0.2303 0.1421

1073757 BANK OF AMERICA CORPORATION -0.1906 0.0780

1951350 CITIGROUP INC. -0.1774 0.0857

1069125 NATIONAL CITY CORPORATION -0.0990 0.0137

Page 66: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

65

Table 13

Bank Executives Innovation Dimensions and Styles – Factor Analysis

Panel A and Panel D show the factor analysis for manager and bank fixed effects. The manager and bank fixed effects

are estimated from a set of three-way fixed effects regressions (executives, bank, and year fixed effects) which use a

connectedness sample constructed based on Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) that includes all banks that have

employed at least one manager who has worked for two or more banks during the sampling period of 1992 -2013:

𝑃𝑗(𝑚,𝑡+1) = 𝐵𝑗(𝑚,𝑡)𝛾 + 𝐸𝑡𝛽 + Σ𝑗=1𝐽 𝐷𝑚,𝑗,𝑡𝜃𝑗 + 𝜙𝑚 + 𝜇𝑡 + 𝜀𝑗,𝑡 (13)

where 𝑃𝑗(𝑚,𝑡+1) are eight business policy variables (non-interest income, loans over assets, MBS, derivatives, lending

diversifications, Gap12, loans over deposits, non-deposit funding) following Hagendorff et al. (2017) for bank j at time

t+1. Definition of business policy variables are listed in Appendix II. Executives included are CEOs, CFOs, COOs, and

executive directors. Position and tenure data are obtained from Execucomp. The dependent variable is explained by

bank characteristics 𝐵𝑗(𝑚,𝑡), macroeconomic conditions 𝐸𝑡−1, bank fixed effects 𝜃𝑗, manager fixed effects 𝜙𝑚, and time

fixed effects 𝜇𝑡. The regression results are omitted, and estimated bank and manager fixed effects are utilized to conduct

factor analysis. Panel B (Panel E) extracts four major factors that summarizes the correlation matrix of managerial (bank)

styles, and based on factors’ loadings on the business model variables, I define an executive’s (a bank’s) score on Factor

1 as the asset-side innovation dimension score, and an executive’s (a bank’s) score on Factor 2 as the liability-side

innovation dimension score. Panel C (Panel F) shows four manager (bank) styles: (1) Asset Innovators are executives

(banks) with score on Factor1 higher than the mean level (0.012) and score on Factor 2 lower than the mean level (-

0.149); (2) Asset and Liability Innovators are executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 and Factor2 both higher than

the mean levels; (3) Traditionalists are executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 and Factor 2 lower than the mean

levels; (4) Liability Innovators are those executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 lower than the mean level and scores

on Factor 2 higher than the mean level. The number of executives (banks) for each type are included in the parenthesis.

Page 67: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

66

Panel A: Factor Analysis – Executive Fixed Effects

Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative

Factor1 3.91806 2.43493 0.6988 0.6988

Factor2 1.48313 1.19896 0.2645 0.9633

Factor3 0.28417 0.08931 0.0507 1.014

Factor4 0.19486 0.13989 0.0348 1.0487

Panel B: Factor Loadings on Manager Fixed Effects

Variable Factor1 Factor2 Factor3 Factor4

Non-interest income 0.8382 0.3239 -0.2053 0.0577

Loans -0.9371 -0.1502 0.1326 0.1015

MBS 0.7556 0.0463 -0.0058 -0.2273

Derivatives 0.8718 -0.0785 0.1615 0.1846

Lending Diversification 0.7602 0.0465 0.3115 0.1300

Gap12 -0.1735 0.3591 -0.2458 0.2685

Loans/Deposits -0.6270 0.6639 0.1963 -0.0177

Non-deposit funding 0.0732 0.8806 0.0486 -0.0785

Panel C: Average Factor Loadings, by Executive Style

Factor 1 (Asset

Innovation Dimension)

Factor 2 (Liability

Innovation Dimension)

Asset Innovator (79) 0.7329 -0.3559

Asset and Liability

Innovator (113) 1.0624 0.2237

Traditionalist (156) -0.6219 -0.3919

Liability Innovator (79) -0.9586 0.0054

Page 68: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

67

Panel D: Factor Analysis – Bank Fixed Effects

Factor Eigenvalue Difference Proportion Cumulative

Factor1 2.6757 1.7168 0.6658 0.6658

Factor2 0.9589 0.3982 0.2386 0.9045

Factor3 0.5607 0.1883 0.1395 1.0440

Factor4 0.3724 0.3448 0.0927 1.1367

Panel E: Factor Loadings on Bank Fixed Effects

Variable Factor1 Factor2 Factor3 Factor4

Non-interest income 0.7124 0.1372 -0.211 0.3175

Loans -0.8774 -0.2048 -0.0236 0.2255

MBS 0.6518 0.1669 -0.3193 -0.1829

Derivatives 0.5916 -0.1165 0.3425 0.1054

Lending Diversification 0.6002 -0.2281 0.2531 0.2555

Gap12 -0.174 0.3251 -0.3369 0.2933

Loans/Deposits -0.4639 0.4666 0.2351 0.1361

Non-deposit funding 0.1336 0.6937 0.252 -0.0795

Panel F: Average Factor Loadings, by Bank Style

Factor 1 (Asset

Innovation Dimension)

Factor 2 (Liability

Innovation Dimension)

Asset Innovating Bank

(25) 0.5385 -0.4280

Asset and Liability

Innovation Bank (18) 0.8483 0.6589

Traditional Bank (19) -0.5318 -0.5427

Liability Innovating Bank

(23) -0.8099 0.3978

Page 69: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

68

Figure 1: Clustering of Executive Styles

The figure presents the graphical clustering of managerial patterns in styles. Using factor analysis, I extract two factors (Factor1 and

Factor2) that summarize a relevant portion of the correlation matrix of managerial styles. The styles are derived from a k-median

clustering algorithm. The managers types are defined as: (1) Asset Innovators are executives with score on Factor1 higher

than the mean level (0.012) and score on Factor 2 lower than the mean level (-0.149); (2) Asset and Liability Innovators

are executives with scores on Factor 1 and Factor2 both higher than the mean levels; (3) Traditionalists are executives

with scores on Factor 1 and Factor 2 lower than the mean levels; (4) Liability Innovators are those executives with scores

on Factor 1 lower than the mean level and scores on Factor 2 higher than the mean level.

-2-1

01

23

Score

s for

facto

r 1

-1 -.5 0 .5 1Scores for factor 2

Asset Innovator Asset and Liability Innovator

Traditionalist Liability Innovator

Page 70: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

69

Table 14

Systemic Risk-taking and Manager Style – Correlation Matrix

Table 14 reports the correlation matrix for systemic risk, executive and bank innovation dimensions for the period of

1992 to 2013. Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡99 (Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡

95) is the bank-level systemic risk for bank j in quarter t estimated at the 99% (95%)

quantile. 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the equal average executive asset-side innovation dimension scores (scores on

Factor 1) for all executives working for bank j in quarter t. 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the equal average

executive liability-side innovation dimension scores (scores on Factor 2) for all executives working for bank j in quarter

t. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 is bank j’s asset-side time-invariant innovation score (score on Factor 1).

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 is bank j’s liability-side time-invariant innovation score (score on Factor 2).

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

(1) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡99 1

(2) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡95 0.8517 1

(3) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡+199 0.8534 0.7336 1

(4) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡+195 0.7275 0.8627 0.8543 1

(5) 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.3690 0.3942 0.3714 0.3958 1

(6) 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.0642 0.0624 0.0635 0.0611 0.2166 1

(7) 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.1580 0.1258 0.1605 0.1285 0.0452 0.0420 1

(8) 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 -0.0089 -0.0408 -0.011 -0.0430 0.0189 -0.2033 -0.0744 1

Page 71: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

70

Table 15

Credit Risk-taking Sensitivity on Systemic Risk – The Effect of Manager Asset Innovation and Liability

Innovation

Table 15 reports the coefficient estimates from the following fixed effects regression for the connectedness sample:

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

= 𝛼0 + 𝛼1Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼3Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑆𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑗,𝑡 + 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑆𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑗,𝑡

+ 𝛼4Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 + 𝛼5𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝛼3Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 + 𝛼2𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡

+ 𝛼6𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜l𝑠𝑘,𝑡 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑗,𝑡 + 𝛼8𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛼9𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡

+ 𝛼10𝑀𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑜𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙𝑡 + 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟𝐹𝐸 + 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦𝐹𝐸 + 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐹𝐸 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡 ,(9)

where subscript i, j, k, and t indicate the borrowing firm, the bank, the package, and the time (quarter), respectively. The

regressions are run at the package level and observations are by package-lender pairs, where lenders include both lead

lenders and non-lead participants, and are identified at the bank holding company level. The dependent variable,

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡 , is borrower’s distance-to-default in the quarter of loan origination.

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑆𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑒𝑗,𝑡 is either 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 or 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 .

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the equal average executive asset-side innovation dimension scores (scores on Factor

1) for all executives working for bank j in quarter t. 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the equal average executive

liability-side innovation dimension scores (scores on Factor 2) for all executives working for bank j in quarter t. The

vectors of variables Loan Controls, Bank Controls, and Borrower Controls contain loan, bank, and firm-specific

control variables from the quarter of loan origination. 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 is a dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the

loan is originated at an economic recession quarter defined by National Bureau of Economic Research, and 0 otherwise.

Standard errors are clustered by bank and shown in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%,

and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 72: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

71

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.217∗∗∗ -0.251∗∗∗ -0.217∗∗∗ -0.287∗∗∗

(0.008) (0.012) (0.008) (0.014)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.031∗∗∗ 0.065∗∗∗

(0.009) (0.010)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 -0.041∗∗∗ -0.095∗∗∗

(0.013) (0.016)

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 -0.200∗∗ -0.295∗∗∗

(0.099) (0.103)

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.224∗∗ 0.515∗∗∗

(0.107) (0.117)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.021∗∗∗ -0.022∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗ -0.022∗∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗

(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.113∗∗∗ 0.111∗∗∗ 0.110∗∗∗ 0.105∗∗∗

(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.890∗∗∗ -0.866∗∗∗ -0.866∗∗∗ -0.793∗∗∗

(0.129) (0.130) (0.129) (0.130)

𝑙𝑛(𝐷𝑒𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡)𝑘,𝑡 -0.000 -0.001 -0.000 -0.001

(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)

𝑙𝑛(𝑀𝑎𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑖𝑡𝑦)𝑘,𝑡 0.057∗∗∗ 0.057∗∗∗ 0.056∗∗∗ 0.055∗∗∗

(0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020)

𝑙𝑛(𝑁𝑢𝑚𝑏𝑒𝑟𝑜𝑓𝐿𝑒𝑎𝑑𝑠)𝑘,𝑡 0.068∗∗∗ 0.068∗∗∗ 0.069∗∗∗ 0.069∗∗∗

(0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.019)

𝑆𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑘,𝑡 -0.014 -0.015 -0.015 -0.015

(0.028) (0.028) (0.028) (0.028)

𝑙𝑛(𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑇𝑜𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑗,𝑡 -0.026 -0.035 -0.020 -0.050

(0.044) (0.047) (0.045) (0.047)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡 1.344 1.170 1.558 1.301

(1.312) (1.318) (1.337) (1.336)

𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑢𝑟𝑛𝑜𝑛𝐸𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 0.593∗∗ 0.613∗∗∗ 0.612∗∗∗ 0.702∗∗∗

(0.237) (0.237) (0.238) (0.237)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑇𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑖𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑗,𝑡 -0.187∗∗∗ -0.186∗∗∗ -0.186∗∗∗ -0.185∗∗∗

(0.050) (0.050) (0.050) (0.050)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝑆𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.002 -0.001 -0.002 -0.002

(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012)

𝐵𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑒𝑟𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 -0.693∗∗∗ -0.690∗∗∗ -0.694∗∗∗ -0.690∗∗∗

(0.094) (0.094) (0.094) (0.094)

𝐿𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑖𝑛𝑔𝑅𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑗,𝑡 -0.016 -0.017 -0.015 -0.017

(0.026) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026)

𝐺𝐷𝑃𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ𝑡 0.163∗∗∗ 0.161∗∗∗ 0.164∗∗∗ 0.159∗∗∗

(0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017)

Observations 24098 24098 24098 24098

R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Adjusted R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 73: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

72

Table 16

Credit Risk-taking Sensitivity on Systemic Risk – The Effect of Bank Asset Innovation Score and Liability

Innovation Score

Table 16 presents the fixed effects regressions on borrower distance-to-default for the connectedness sample. Both bank

innovation scores and executive innovation scores are included in the regressions. 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the

equal average executive asset-side innovation dimension scores (scores on Factor 1) for all executives working for bank

j in quarter t. 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 is the equal average executive liability-side innovation dimension scores

(scores on Factor 2) for all executives working for bank j in quarter t. 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 is bank j’s asset-side time-

invariant innovation score (score on Factor 1). 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 is bank j’s liability-side time-invariant

innovation score (score on Factor 2). Control variables include loan, bank, firm-specific, and macroeconomic control

variables in the quarter of loan origination. Standard errors are clustered by bank and shown in parentheses. *, **,

and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Page 74: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV V VI VII

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.217∗∗∗ -0.213∗∗∗ -0.247∗∗∗ -0.218∗∗∗ -0.217∗∗∗ -0.213∗∗∗ -0.306∗∗∗

(0.008) (0.009) (0.013) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009) (0.016)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 -0.008 -0.009 -0.008 0.014∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.007)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐵𝑎𝑛𝑘𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗 0.027 0.015 0.027 -0.034∗

(0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.019)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.032∗∗∗ 0.075∗∗∗

(0.009) (0.011)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 -0.039∗∗∗ -0.122∗∗∗

(0.013) (0.020)

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 -0.190∗ -0.347∗∗∗

(0.099) (0.105)

𝐸𝑥𝑒𝑐𝑢𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑗,𝑡 0.208∗ 0.680∗∗∗

(0.109) (0.136)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.021∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗ -0.022∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗ -0.022∗∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗

(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.113∗∗∗ 0.112∗∗∗ 0.111∗∗∗ 0.112∗∗∗ 0.110∗∗∗ 0.111∗∗∗ 0.105∗∗∗

(0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.890∗∗∗ -0.887∗∗∗ -0.862∗∗∗ -0.882∗∗∗ -0.863∗∗∗ -0.879∗∗∗ -0.788∗∗∗

(0.129) (0.129) (0.130) (0.130) (0.130) (0.130) (0.130)

Observations 24098 24098 24098 24098 24098 24098 24098

R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Adjusted R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 75: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, and The Effect of Managerial ... ANNUAL... · * I thank Linda Allen, Armen Hovakimian, Ayako Yasuda, Ayan Bhattacharya, Dexin Zhou, Gayle Delong, Lin Peng,

74

Table 17

Credit Risk-taking Sensitivity on Systemic Risk - How Do Manager Styles Matter?

Table 17 reports the coefficient estimates from the baseline regression adding interaction of Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 with manager

style dummy as defined in Panel C in Table 1. The managers types are defined as: (1) Asset Innovators are executives

(banks) with score on Factor1 higher than the mean level (0.012) and score on Factor 2 lower than the mean level (-

0.149); (2) Asset and Liability Innovators are executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 and Factor2 both higher than

the mean levels; (3) Traditionalists are executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 and Factor 2 lower than the mean

levels; (4) Liability Innovators are those executives (banks) with scores on Factor 1 lower than the mean level and scores

on Factor 2 higher than the mean level.

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑗,𝑘,𝑡

I II III IV V VI

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 -0.243∗∗∗ -0.255∗∗∗ -0.238∗∗∗ -0.241∗∗∗ -0.240∗∗∗ -0.224∗∗∗

(0.009) (0.010) (0.011) (0.009) (0.009) (0.011)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 0.030∗∗∗

(0.010) Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑑𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 -0.008 -0.023∗∗

(0.009) (0.010)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑇𝑟𝑎𝑑𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑗,𝑡 -0.079∗∗∗ -0.099∗∗∗

(0.025) (0.026)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 -0.093∗∗∗ -0.110∗∗∗

(0.032) (0.032)

𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 -0.231∗∗∗

(0.073) 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑑𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 0.115 0.204∗∗∗

(0.072) (0.074)

𝑇𝑟𝑎𝑑𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑗,𝑡 0.337∗∗∗ 0.009

(0.130) (0.324)

𝐿𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦𝐼𝑛𝑛𝑜𝑣𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑗,𝑡 0.275∗ 0.002

(0.159) (0.334)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡−1 -0.019∗∗∗ -0.019∗∗∗ -0.019∗∗∗ -0.020∗∗∗ -0.019∗∗∗ -0.021∗∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

𝐷𝑖𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑡𝑜𝐷𝑒𝑓𝑎𝑢𝑙𝑡𝑖,𝑡−1 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.954∗∗∗ 0.953∗∗∗ 0.954∗∗∗

(0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

Δ𝐶𝑜𝑉𝑎𝑅𝑗,𝑡 × 𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 0.115∗∗∗ 0.112∗∗∗ 0.115∗∗∗ 0.114∗∗∗ 0.109∗∗∗ 0.106∗∗∗

(0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016)

𝑅𝑒𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.836∗∗∗ -0.803∗∗∗ -0.833∗∗∗ -0.819∗∗∗ -0.771∗∗∗ -0.736∗∗∗

(0.155) (0.155) (0.155) (0.155) (0.156) (0.156)

Observations 20819 20819 20819 20819 20819 20819

R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Adjusted R 2 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896 0.896

Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Lender fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes