24
Static Games of Incomplete Information .

Static Games of Incomplete Information.. Mechanism design Typically a 3-step game of incomplete info Step 1: Principal designs mechanism/contract Step

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Static Games of Incomplete Information

.

Mechanism design• Typically a 3-step game of incomplete info

Step 1: Principal designs mechanism/contract

Step 2: Agents accept/reject the mechanism

Step 3: Agents that have accepted, play the game specified by mechanism

• Constant theme: Incomplete information and binding individual rationality constraints prevent efficient outcomes

Nonlinear pricing• A monopolist produces good at marginal cost c

and sells quantity q • Consumer transfers T to seller and has utility

u1(q, T, θ)= θV(q)-T, V(0)=0, V/>0, V//<0

• θ is private knowledge for buyer• Seller knows that θ= w.p. and θ= w.p. • The game:

1. Seller offers tariff T(q): specifies a price for qty q

2. Consumer accepts/rejects• If seller knows θ, she will charge T= θV(q), her

profit, θV(q)-cq. This is maximized at some q given by θV/(q)=c

p p

Nonlinear pricing• Let be bundle for type and for type• Seller’s expected profit:• Seller faces two constraints:

1. Individual Rationality (IR): Consumer should be willing to purchase

2. Incentive Compatibility (IC): Consumer should consume the bundle intended for his type

• IR1: ; and IR2:

• IC1: ; and IC2:

• First step: To show that only IR1 and IC2 are binding

) ,( Tq ) ,( Tq

)()(0 qcTpqcTpEu

0)( TqV 0)( TqV

TqVTqV )()( TqVTqV )()(

Nonlinear pricing

• First note: IR1 and IC2 imply IR2

• IR2 can’t be binding unless =0

• However, IR1 must bind. Else seller can increase

by same amount and increase revenue

• Also, IC2 must be binding, else seller can increase

, satisfy all constraints and increase revenue• The high-type’s indifference curve is always

steeper than the low type’s for any allocation• This implies that high type consumes more than

low type:

q

TT &

T

qq

Nonlinear pricing• Eliminating transfers, principal’s objective function is:

• FOC wrt

• FOC wrt

• Check that IC1 is satisfied

• Note: Quantity purchased by high-type is optimal

Quantity purchased by low-type is sub-optimal

• Seller sacrifices efficiency for rent-extraction!

))(

1/()( : /

p

pcqVq

cqVq )( : /

)})(())()]({([max,

qcqVpqcpqVppqq

Auctions• Seller has unit of good and there are two bidders• Each bidder can have types , with < • Corresponding probabilities are and• Buyer’s expected probability of getting the good are

and payments are• The constraints are:

IR1: ; IR2:

IC1: ; IC2:

• What is seller’s optimal contract?

p p

XX & TT &

0 TX 0 TX

TXTX TXTX

Auctions • Seller’s expected profit is: • Again, IR1 and IC2 are binding. The seller’s profit:

• Also, ex-ante prob of a player getting good,• Moreover,

• Case 1: . The seller sets and Optimal mechanism: Not to sell if both announce low-type; sell to high-type if they announce different types; sell wp ½ to each if both announce high type

• Case 2: . The seller sets and Optimal mechanism: Sell to high-type if bidders announce different types, and sell wp ½ to each if they both announce high-type or low-type

TpTp

XpXpEu )(0

2

1 XpXp

2

ppX

p 0X2

ppX

p 2/pX 2

ppX

Moral Hazard

•Consider a Principal and an agent who can exert costly effort, e

•Let e {0, 1}, with costs: ψ(0)=0, ψ(1)= ψ

•Agent receives transfer, t, and has utility;

U=u(t)- ψ(e), with u/>0, u//<0.

•Production is stochastic, and production level,

,

• Stochastic influence of effort on production:

,

},{~ qqq qq

10 }1~Pr{ ;}0~Pr{ eqqeqq 01

Moral Hazard• Principal can offer a contract, {t( )}, that depends

on observed, random output• With two possible outcomes, contract is: if output

is and if output is• Let Principal’s profit with qty q be S(q)• His profit when agent expends effort e=0 is:

• His profit when agent expends effort e=1 is:

q~

q~

tq t q

])()[1(])([ 000 tqStqSV

])()[1(])([ 111 tqStqSV

Incentive Feasible Contracts

• Induce positive effort and ensure participation

• Incentive constraint:

• Participation constraint:

0)()1()( 11 tutu

)()1()()()1()( 0011 tutututu

Complete Information Benchmark• Complete info or First-Best: Principal observes effort• Principal’s problem is:

subject to:• Using Lagrangian, μ, and from FOCs we have,

• From the above equations, we have that:• Thus, Agent obtains full insurance!• The optimal transfer is: t*= u-1(ψ)=h(ψ), where h=u-1

))(1()(max 11)},{(

tStStt

0)()1()( 11 tutu

0)(

1

)(

1*/*/

tutu

*** ttt

First Best Case• When there is complete information• Principal’s profit from inducing effort e=1:

V1=

• If agent exerted 0 effort, principal would earn:

V0=

• Inducing effort is optimal for principal if: , where

• Principal’s First-Best cost of inducing effort is: h(ψ)

)()1( 11 hSS

SS )1( 00

)( hS SSS ;01

Second-Best: In terms of transfers

• Agent is risk-averse• Principal’s problem, P, is:• (P):

subject to: , and

• First ensure concavity of (P): Let

))(1()(max 11)},{(

tStStt

0)()1()( 11 tutu

)( );( tuutuu

)()1()()()1()( 0011 tutututu

Second-Best: In terms of utilities

• The Principal’s program can be rewritten in terms of utilities

• (P/):

• Principal’s objective function is concave in

because h(.) is convex, and the constraints are linear• The KKT conditions are necessary and sufficient

0)1(

)1()1( :

))()(1())((max

11

0011

11)},{(

uu

uuuutosubject

uhSuhSuu

),( uu

Both IR and IC are binding• Let λ & μ be Lagrange multipliers for IC & IR• The FOCs, upon rearranging terms, are:

where, are second-best optimal transfers

• From these, , so IR is binding

• Also, , so IC is binding

1/

1/ 1)(

1 ;

)(

1

SBSB tutu

SBSB tt ,

0)()(

1/

1/

1

SBSBtutu

0))(

1

)(

1(

)1(//

11

SBSB tutu

Second-Best Solution

• The variables ( , λ, μ ) are solved simultaneously from two FOCs, IC and IR

• The second-best optimal transfers are:

• : contract does not provide full insurance• 2nd Best cost of inducing effort: CSB=• Clearly, for the Principal, CSB> CFB. So Principal

induces high effort (e=1) less often than in first-best• There is under-provision of effort in the second-best

SBSB tt ,

)( );)1(( 11

htht SBSB

SBSBtt

SBSBtt )1( 11

Mechanism design with a single agent• Agent’s type with distribution/density • Type-contingent allocation is fn.• Defn: A decision function is implementable if

there exists a transfer t(.) such that allocation y(.) is incentive-compatible, i.e.

• Theorem: A piecewise C1 decision fn x(.) is implementable only if

whenever and x is differentiable at θ

] ,[ )(/)( pP

))( ),(()( txy

X:x

],[],[)ˆ,( ),),ˆ(()),(( 11 yuyu

0)/

/(

1 1

1

d

dx

tu

xu kn

k

k

)( t),( txx

Mechanism design with a single agent• Sketch of proof: Type θ announces to maximize

The FOC and SOC are

Totally differentiating the first equation,

The (local) SOC becomes or,

Rewrite the FOC we get,

Eliminating, dt/dθ,

)),ˆ(),ˆ((),ˆ( 1 txu

),( ,0

ˆ),(

2

2

),(ˆ

),( 2

2

2

01

1

1

d

dt

t

u

d

dx

x

u kn

k k

01

1

1

d

dt

t

u

d

dx

x

u kn

k k

0}/]{[ 1111

1

1

d

dx

t

u

x

u

t

u

t

u

x

u k

k

n

k k

),(2

Mechanism design with a single agent• The sorting/ single crossing/ constant sign (CS) condition is:

• Note that is agent’s marginal rate of substitution

between decision k and transfer t• Consider x to be output supplied by agent, i.e.,• Then sorting condition means that the agent’s indifference

curve in (x, t) space, , is decreasing in θ

• If θ2> θ1 , y(θ1)=(x(θ1), t(θ1)), y(θ2)=(x(θ2), t(θ2)), then y(θ2)>y(θ1)

• Theorem: If decision space is 1-dim and CS holds, then a necessary condition for x(.) to be implementable is that it is monotonic.

• What about sufficiency?

0/

/

1

1

tu

xu k

01 x

u

tu

xu k

/

/

1

1

tu

xu

/

/

1

1

Optimal mechanisms for one agent • The assumptions:

A1: Reservation utility independent of type

A2: Quasi-linear utilities:

Principal: u0(x, t,θ)= V0(x, θ)-t; Agent: u1(x, t,θ)= V1(x, θ)+t

A3: n=1, i.e., decision is 1-dim and CS holds.

A4:

A5:

A6:

u

012

xV

01 V

002

xV

0 & ,02

13

21

3

x

V

x

V

Optimal mechanisms for one agent• The problem: Principal maximizes his expected utility

subject to: (IR) u1(x(θ), t(θ), θ)≥ =0, for all θ

(IC) u1(x(θ), t(θ), θ)≥

• From A1 & A4, if IR satisfied at , it is satisfied everywhere • IR binding at . Thus, • Let

• From Envelope theorem,• This implies that,

) ),( ),((max 0)}(),({

txuE

tx

u

)ˆ ,( ) ),ˆ( ),ˆ((1 txu

0) ),( ),((1 utxu

111 Vu

d

dU

) ),( ),(() ),ˆ( ),ˆ((max)( 11ˆ1

txutxuU

~~

)~

,~

(()( 1

1 dxV

uU

Optimal mechanisms for one agent• Further, u0= V0+ V1- U1≡ Social surplus-Agent’s utility• Principal’s objective function:

• Since monotonicity is necessary and sufficient for implementability, Principal’s optimization program becomes

s.t. x(.) is monotonic

dpxV

p

PxVxV )(]

),(

)(

)(1),(),([ max 1

10{x(.)}

dpxV

p

PxVxV

dpdxV

xVxV

)(])),((

)(

)(1)),(()),(([

)(]~

~)

~),

~((

)),(()),(([

110

110

Optimal mechanisms• We solve the principal’s program ignoring monotonicity• The solution to the relaxed program is

• The principal faces a trade-off between maximizing total surplus (V0+ V1) and appropriating the agent’s info rent (U1)

• When is it legit to focus on relaxed program?

When solution x*(θ) to above eq is monotonic. Differentiating,

When Hazard rate is monotone:

x

V

p

P

x

V

x

V 12

10

)(

)(1

21

30

21

2

*

21

3

21

2

20

2

)(

)(1]1)

)(

)(1([

))(

)(1(

x

V

p

P

x

V

p

P

d

d

x

V

d

dx

x

V

p

P

x

V

x

V

0)(1

)(

P

p

d

d