27
POST CRISIS SECURITIES REGULATION AND MARKET DISCIPLINE Kashif Ghani 1 Abstract This paper describes how our ideals of financial regulation failed to prevent yet another financial crisis. It lays emphasis on the lessons we have learnt from the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and the realization that our new measures aimed at preventing a crisis might fail to prevent the next crisis. It has been argued that market discipline and regulation must be balanced in a manner that they complement each other in order to achieve the objectives of regulation. The paper discusses the changes required to be made in the financial regulations framework that may help reduce the likelihood and impact of future crises, the degree to which market discipline and disclosure regime can be relied upon to achieve the objectives of regulation and the type of crises that are likely to challenge the stability of our financial systems in future. JEL Classification: G01, G18, G28, Key words: Global Financial Crisis, Financial Regulation, Securities Regulation, Market Discipline, Financial Stability, Disclosure 1 Kashif Ghani is Deputy Director at Securities & Exchange Commission of Pakistan (SECP). The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not represent the position of the author’s employer. Email: [email protected]

Regulation, Transparency and Market Discipline (Kashif Ghani)

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

This paper describes how our ideals of financial regulation failed to prevent yet another financial crisis. It lays emphasis on the lessons we have learnt from the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and the realization that our new measures aimed at preventing a crisis might fail to prevent the next crisis. It has been argued that market discipline and regulation must be balanced in a manner that they complement each other in order to achieve the objectives of regulation. The paper discusses the changes required to be made in the financial regulations framework that may help reduce the likelihood and impact of future crises, the degree to which market discipline and disclosure regime can be relied upon to achieve the objectives of regulation and the type of crises that are likely to challenge the stability of our financial systems in future.

Citation preview

  • POST CRISIS SECURITIES REGULATION

    AND MARKET DISCIPLINE

    Kashif Ghani1

    Abstract

    This paper describes how our ideals of financial regulation failed to prevent yet another financial

    crisis. It lays emphasis on the lessons we have learnt from the Global Financial Crisis (GFC)

    and the realization that our new measures aimed at preventing a crisis might fail to prevent the

    next crisis. It has been argued that market discipline and regulation must be balanced in a

    manner that they complement each other in order to achieve the objectives of regulation. The

    paper discusses the changes required to be made in the financial regulations framework that

    may help reduce the likelihood and impact of future crises, the degree to which market discipline

    and disclosure regime can be relied upon to achieve the objectives of regulation and the type of

    crises that are likely to challenge the stability of our financial systems in future.

    JEL Classification: G01, G18, G28,

    Key words: Global Financial Crisis, Financial Regulation, Securities Regulation, Market

    Discipline, Financial Stability, Disclosure

    1 Kashif Ghani is Deputy Director at Securities & Exchange Commission of Pakistan (SECP). The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not represent the position of the authors employer. Email: [email protected]

  • 2 | P a g e

    1. INTRODUCTION

    The Great Recession now ranks as the most serious financial crisis we have

    seen since the great depression. It has shaken publics confidence in the

    financial systems considered extremely robust only a couple of years back.

    The crisis brought the world financial system almost to the brink of collapse.

    Financial markets were only able to continue performing their functions as a

    result of expensive rescue of public sector banks.

    IMFs Global Financial Stability Report (2011) point out that despite some

    signs of improvement in economic growth, the global financial stability is yet

    to be achieved. According to IMF, although the financial markets have shown

    signs of stability, risks and challenges still remain that need to be addressed. In

    advanced economies, governments continue to be indebted and the financial

    institutions are struggling to recover from shocks.

    Indeed the Great Recession has reminded us of many forgotten lessons. The

    most important being the need to rethink our financial regulations framework.

    One thing that the crisis has not changed is the basic objectives of regulation.

    Even after the crisis, the objectives of securities regulation remain unchanged.

    Regulators still need to focus on maintenance of investor confidence,

    promoting fair and transparent markets and minimizing risks threatening the

    stability of the financial system. However, much rethinking is required for

    determining which tools and techniques must be employed in order to achieve

    the objectives of securities regulation.

    For the purposes of this paper, securities regulation is meant to include the

    regulation of equities, bonds, collective investment schemes, derivatives and

    other similar financial products.

    Existing Literature

    A large amount of literature exists on the causes of financial crises, the role of

    market discipline and disclosure; on how regulation should respond to the

  • 3 | P a g e

    financial crisis and how the financial crises have changed the way regulators

    must design and implement rules and standards.

    An important study in this context is one by Zingales (2009) who advocates a

    series of reforms directed toward improving corporate governance, putting

    renewed emphasis on protecting unsophisticated investors and development of

    set of rules aimed at minimizing the regulatory gap between private and public

    equity markets. This study is unique as it gives an historical account of how

    securities regulation has evolved over time and how present day regulators

    may benefit from regulatory success stories of the past.

    Another significant contribution was made by Poser (2009) in his study that

    highlights how regulators lost sight of their basic objectives of regulation and

    failed to respond to the changing market dynamics in the period leading up to

    the financial crisis. Specifically, it gives a history of SEC USA, its evolving

    focus over time, the debacles that are termed SECs failures and the reasons

    why SEC failed to prevent two major crises in 2008. Poser (2009) argues that

    the regulators were unable to prevent these crises primarily due to their

    obsession with market deregulatory philosophy. He proposes that SEC USA

    needs to restore its activism of the 1930s and 1960s along with keeping itself

    familiar with new financial instruments and entities through in depth studies of

    particular segments, activities and players in the market.

    A recent study by Erskine (2010) focuses on the changes required in the

    regulatory mindset and the financial regulation framework in the post crisis

    period. Erskine (2010) provides a detailed review of policies and principles

    that were conventional wisdom before the crisis and that eventually turned

    out to be contributors to the crisis. This study also proposes a shift from a

    deregulatory mindset and stresses the need for avoiding over-relying on

    financial markets to self-stabilize. The author further argues that the need of

    the hour is the adoption of a wider view that takes account of systemic risks to

    financial stability.

  • 4 | P a g e

    A very important study with reference to the crisis in banking is the FSAs

    report called The Turner Review (2009), which covers in great detail the

    causes of global banking crisis and how bank regulators should respond to the

    changing scenario after the lessons learnt from the crisis. It proposes a large

    set of reforms aimed at averting a future crisis in banking, including

    improvements to the capital adequacy framework, institutional and

    geographical coverage of regulations, changes to the regulation of gatekeepers

    (e.g. credit rating agencies) and changes in the regulators supervisory

    approach, among other things. There are a number of other studies on various

    areas of securities regulations, market discipline and the impact financial crisis

    is likely to have on financial regulation.

    This paper attempts to add to the existing literature on financial regulation in

    the post-crisis-era by focusing on how our ideals of financial regulation failed

    to prevent a crisis. What lessons we have learnt from the Global Financial

    Crisis (GFC), the changes in regulatory framework that may reduce the

    likelihood - and more importantly, the impact of future crises and the

    realization that our new measures aimed at preventing a crisis might also fail

    to prevent the next crisis. An effort has been made to emphasize that financial

    regulation and market discipline should be thought of as complementing each

    other, rather than being substitutes. Hence, this work stresses the need to strike

    the right balance between regulation and the measures to promote market

    discipline. The limitations and benefits of market discipline as a regulatory

    tool are touched upon. The major focus is on the changes required to be made

    in the financial regulations framework, the degree to which market discipline

    and disclosure regime may be relied upon to achieve the objectives of

    regulation and what type of crises are likely to challenge the stability of our

    financial systems in future.

    The remaining part of this paper is structured as follows: Section 2 discusses

    the lessons learnt from the financial crises and how they have changed our

    thinking about the ways markets should be regulated. Section 3 highlights the

    uses and limitations of market discipline and disclosure as an aid to financial

    regulation. Section 4 describes the shifting focus of financial regulations to

  • 5 | P a g e

    meet the needs of the post crisis scenario. Section 5 gives a brief description of

    the types of crises we are likely to face in the future despite our best efforts.

    Section 6 concludes the discussion.

    2. LESSONS WE HAVE LEARNED (OR NOT LEARNED)

    What went wrong?

    Financial crises are centuries old phenomena and the first crises are traced

    back to the beginning of capitalism (Bordo, 2007). Various explanations have

    been presented as to the causes of the present crisis; including overrating the

    value of market deregulatory and self-stabilizing approach, over-reliance on

    disclosure for achieving market efficiency, the failure to assess systemic risk

    etc (Erskine 2010). It must be understood here that the great recession was

    primarily caused by a credit shock that eventually resulted in a banking crisis

    and recession. However, securities markets being part of the interconnected

    financial system could not be insulated from the effects of the crisis. The

    ultimate outcome was increasing defaults on corporate bonds and decline in

    equity prices. The securities markets also played their part in the present crisis

    as Credit Default Obligations (CDOs) and Credit Default Swaps (CDSs) (a

    type of derivative product) are considered to have made a significant

    contribution to the present crisis. It may be noted that derivatives are generally

    supposed to be regulated by securities regulators, though CDOs and CDSs

    were largely unregulated.

    Many attempts have been made to analyze the factors and circumstances

    leading up to the GFC. One theory suggests that macro imbalances played a

    significant role in the factors leading to the GFC as the oil exporting countries

    and Asian giants like China and Japan had huge current account surpluses in

    the period leading up to the GFC and countries like UK and USA had large

    current account deficits (The Turner Review, 2009). Very high saving rates

    existed in countries having current account surpluses while some developed

    countries like UK and USA had very low real risk free rate of interest. This

    meant that in USA and UK the investment avenues promising higher expected

    rates of return became very attractive for the investors. This led to an increase

  • 6 | P a g e

    in demand for innovative products offering higher yields and as a result

    emerged a large number of structured products that offered the investors

    varying levels of risk, return and liquidity options compared with traditional

    fixed return instruments. The development of a large number of structured

    products that were largely unregulated; combined with growing size of the

    financial sector, increasing leverage, increasing interconnectedness of

    financial intermediaries and inability of these structured products to insure

    against the risk of default, eventually led to the emergence of current financial

    crisis on a global scale.

    Similar views have been expressed by others such as Martin (2009) who

    observes that securitization of subprime mortgages, the decline in real estate

    prices, the complexity of the products that were being introduced (with

    accompanying lack of information) and mark-to-market accounting issues

    contributed significantly to the credit crisis.

    Lessons we learnt from the crisis

    In the pre-crisis period markets were considered to be self-equilibrating and

    rational and it was believed that economic efficiency and stability could be

    ensured by market completion (Turner, 2010). Innovation in finance and

    increase in trading activity were to be always welcome as these were

    considered pro-growth.

    Various reasons for failure of national regulators have been elaborated. For

    instance, staff conflict of interests, lack of training, budgetary constraints and

    fragmented regulatory system have been cited as the reasons for the failure of

    SEC USA to prevent major debacles. But the most important factor that stands

    out is the anti-regulatory climate (Poser, 2009). It was widely believed that a

    pro-market, deregulatory mindset had led to fluctuations in growth and

    inflation being moderate. The existence of relative financial stability was seen

    as evidence that the deregulatory approach was indeed working effectively

    (Erskine, 2010). It is said that SEC in USA had moved, in the pre-crisis

    period, from an investor protection approach to protecting the companies and

    investment firms that it regulated. Regulation was thought to be hampering

  • 7 | P a g e

    growth of financial markets and considered costlier than the benefit it

    provided (Poser, 2009).

    Lack of trained and experienced staff of the regulatory organizations is

    another reason cited for spread of crisis situation. Regulatory staff often lacks

    the required incentives to pursue in depth investigations. The relations with

    market players (some of them are seen as potential future employers) are also

    at stake providing further disincentive to the staff working with the apex

    watchdog. Frequent hopping of jobs between the regulator and the institutions

    being regulated also works against effective regulation of these entities due to

    the so called revolving door problem. Shortage of training for staff members

    of the regulatory agencies and higher remuneration in the private sector also

    hinder the regulators ability to develop and retain valuable human resources.

    3. MARKET DISCIPLINE, FINANCIAL STABILITY AND

    DISCLOSURE

    Market discipline is the mechanism (constituting information, incentives and

    controls) to monitor and discipline excessive risk taking behavior of market

    participants. Market discipline is considered complementary to, rather than a

    substitute of, supervision and regulation in present times. Information

    asymmetries between regulator and the financial institutions, combined with

    the problem of political considerations or weak legal systems augments the

    need for market discipline as an aid to regulation. Other factors enhancing the

    need for market discipline include increasing complexity, innovation and

    globalization of financial institutions. Regulations, among other things, should

    be aimed at enhancing the power of markets to discipline themselves.

    Financial stability may be achieved through the formulation of sound policies

    and institutions in order to prevent, manage and resolve financial crises. It

    must be understood that we cannot eliminate the possibility of crises; we must

    accept there would be failures but failures should not lead to a systemic

    collapse.

  • 8 | P a g e

    It is widely believed now that market discipline failed to limit risk taking

    behavior of market participants within acceptable parameters during the GFC.

    In the pre-crisis period disclosure framework and a set of rules were thought to

    be sufficient to prevent excessive risk taking and encourage banks and other

    intermediaries to act in a way that promoted confidence of their customers

    (investors) in their services and in financial markets generally. Market

    gatekeepers were expected to adhere to highest professional standards as their

    reputations were supposed to be at stake; however, this was essentially a

    simplistic view which the crisis has proved to be incorrect. Some scholars hold

    that market discipline did work but its effect was too little too late to avert a

    disaster. Even in that case, there would still be need for taking further steps for

    strengthening the mechanics for stronger market discipline.

    The regulators now face the challenge of restructuring financial markets in a

    way that promotes financial stability, without compromising on efficiency.

    Regulators must make efforts to limit the undesirable, destructive competition

    and excessive risk taking by market participants. However, to promulgate

    countless new rules and regulations in an attempt to cover every possible

    aspect of the behavior of financial institutions would be inefficient as well as

    ineffective. Inefficient because doing so will also require increase in the staff

    required for enforcement of those rules; and inefficient because covering each

    possible aspect is humanly impossible, especially in this era of financial

    innovation and ingenuity. Thus such detailed rules would ultimately fail to

    prevent the next crisis and all efforts in designing those detailed rules will

    prove fruitless. In this context, putting in place a robust system of market

    discipline is likely to prove more beneficial.

    On the other hand, the idea of banning every product that is considered evil,

    dangerous or vaguely suspicious for the unsuspecting investors and for the

    financial markets at large, is impractical. Regulators, therefore, need to place

    more emphasis on the discipline coming from within the market

    (Shanmugaratnam, 2001).

  • 9 | P a g e

    Thus market discipline needs to be strengthened (by adopting means such as

    improved disclosure requirements) but it should not be solely relied upon to

    avert a future crisis. Regulation should strengthen and reinforce market

    discipline. As argued by Shanmugaratnam (2001) there ought to be a system

    of laws, rules and regulations to aid and assist the market disciplining

    mechanism. Rules should be framed in favor of companies that follow high

    corporate governance standards and adopt adequate disclosure policies.

    Whereas those who adopt suspicious practices and are involved in market

    manipulation should be punished. Conflict of interest situations need to be

    handled carefully to ensure they do not work to the detriment of market

    discipline.

    Stephanou (2010) has proposed a framework2 based on four pillars:

    1) Information and disclosure

    2) Market participants

    3) Discipline mechanisms

    4) Internal governance

    The first pillar stresses the need for availability of adequate and reliable

    information on the financial performance and risk exposures of financial

    institutions for making timely and informed decisions.

    The second pillar underlines the need for existence of independent market

    participants possessing the ability to accurately process the information and

    the right incentives to monitor the risk exposures of the financial institution.

    The third pillar stresses the need for existence of disciplining mechanisms/

    instruments that may be used by market participants to exercise discipline or

    penalize excessive risk taking. Ideally, the market should provide sufficient

    solvency signals for instrument holders or creditors to demand change of

    management or for the regulators to intervene.

    2 A similar model has been proposed by Crocket (2001)

  • 10 | P a g e

    Finally, the organizational and governance structure, remuneration of

    executives, board composition, independence and qualifications are crucial for

    the effective functioning of market discipline.

    These pillars serve to outline the pre-requisites for existence of an effective

    market disciplining mechanism. However, a more pertinent question now is

    what practical steps can be taken from a regulatory perspective to increase the

    effectiveness of market discipline for averting a crisis. The steps that can be

    taken to improve the market discipline framework include:

    - lowering the cost of monitoring by market participants, by putting in

    place additional, carefully thought out disclosure requirements and by

    provision of reliable and timely information

    - Encouraging the monitoring by market participants, by ensuring that

    required incentives are in place. This may include redesigning safety

    nets and assuring that executives of poorly managed financial

    institutions will not go unpunished (the least amount of punishment

    being loss of jobs). On the other hand, investors must share some

    burden for their poor investment decision.

    - Improving the corporate governance environment at the financial

    institutions to ensure that management has sufficient interest and

    incentive to respond to market signals effectively

    The merits and limitations of disclosure as a regulatory technique

    Inadequate disclosure has been termed as one of the major contributors to the

    global financial crisis. It has been argued that investors failed to understand

    the risks involved in investing in structured securities primarily due to

    insufficient disclosures. Furthermore, common investors often lacked enough

    information about the functioning of the credit rating agencies and

    repercussions of excessive executive compensation.

  • 11 | P a g e

    The basic premise behind the presumed effectiveness of disclosure as a

    regulatory instrument was that investors are primarily rational, who, when

    provided with sufficient information, make optimal resource allocation

    decisions aimed at wealth maximization. Being a part of the deregulatory

    mindset, framing rules for disclosure of plenty of information was a major

    focus of regulators as it would result in investors making informed, rational

    decisions and markets essentially regulating themselves. An important

    question that needed to be addressed was whether investors would be able to

    process (i.e. make sense of) the mass of information being disclosed and be

    able to make rational decisions? The quality and relevance of information and

    the ability of the investors to process that information are important

    considerations (Avgouleas 2009).

    It is argued that many of the risk factors that eventually led to the advent of

    financial crisis were disclosed in considerable detail in various documents;

    however, the users of information were unable to understand the true

    implications of such risk factors and the effect these were likely to have on

    their investments. Even more difficult it would have been for an investor to

    fully comprehend the combined effect of these factors on the financial

    markets.

    Product complexity also contributes to diminishing the utility of disclosure as

    the quantity of documents required to be read and understood by the investors

    keeps increasing with increasing complexity (Schwarcz, 2008). Innovation in

    financial markets and products makes their understanding much more

    cumbersome. Other socio-psychological factors such as performance

    pressures, herd behavior and cognitive biases also play their part in reducing

    the effectiveness of disclosure as a regulatory technique.

    It is important that Regulators understand disclosures inherent limitations.

    One of the limitations is the way information is presented to the prospective

    users of information. Framing of information in a leading manner may serve to

    defeat the very purpose of a disclosure regime. The less sophisticated, less

    informed users of information are at greater risk of being mislead due to

  • 12 | P a g e

    framed disclosures (Tversky and Kahneman 1986). Even sophisticated

    institutional investors may struggle to free themselves from the effects of such

    framed information and the regulators have limited control over such framing.

    Despite its limitations, disclosure as a regulatory technique offers many

    benefits including allowing market participants to battle market abuses and

    aiding decision making. Regulators need to consider the timing, frequency,

    content and format of such disclosures keeping in view the limitations of

    disclosure and the objectives to be achieved. These considerations regarding

    disclosure need to be guided by experimental and empirical studies that test

    and measure the impact and effectiveness of information disclosed, as

    suggested by Gerding (2006) and Avgouleas (2009). However, there have

    been experiments that have shown that changing the volume of information

    disclosed may have minimal effect on investors decisions (Choi et al, 2010).

    More experimental evidence is essential to further our understanding of the

    subject.

    The issue of product complexity is already being tackled by the regulators by

    focusing on product standardization and improvement of clearing and

    settlement systems. Further considerations include whether complex financial

    products should be allowed to be market to the less sophisticated investor. An

    important reflection in this respect would be the use of soft paternalism

    mechanism (Avgouleas, 2009).

    Conflicts of interest (CoI)

    Eliminating all conflict of interest situations may not be practically possible

    for any regulator. However, conflicts of interest are to be managed in a way

    that their effects are minimized. Complete elimination of conflicts of interest

    situations would only be possible under the theoretical perfect competition and

    absence of asymmetric information. COIs are of special interest to regulators

    because exploitation of conflicts of interest situations by market players may

    have negative consequences for the confidence investors have in the financial

    markets.

  • 13 | P a g e

    Regulators have been criticized for being too lenient on market intermediaries

    and failing to properly deal with conflict of interest situations. They are now

    faced with the task of devising regulations to address conflict of interest

    situations that endanger the health of our financial system. Market

    intermediaries are naturally at an advantage in terms of access to information.

    Market imperfections and asymmetric information are the key reasons which

    may lead the intermediaries to exploit such situations. The regulators are again

    faced with the uphill task of balancing regulations as too lenient regulations

    would permit exploitation by market intermediaries at the cost of their clients.

    On the other hand, too harsh regulations run the risk of inhibiting growth by

    disallowing activities that may otherwise be appropriate. Regulations should

    ideally focus on encouraging the development of internal controls that help

    control such conflicts of interest (Emerging Markets Committee of IOSCO,

    2010).

    Moreover, as with any set of rules and standards; the implementation and strict

    enforcement of laws is as important from regulatory point of view as the

    regulations themselves. Regulators also need to develop required capabilities

    and technical expertise to carry out investigations and take effective

    enforcement action with reference to COI situations. Rules and regulations

    should be primarily aimed at changing the behavior of firms concerned as

    avoidance of COI situations inevitably involves exercise of best judgment by

    the management of these intermediaries. As conflict of interest situations can

    take many different forms; it is practically not possible to devise a set of rules

    for each type of COI situation. Thus rules should be targeted at developing

    higher level rules for guiding the behavior of management of financial

    intermediaries, combined with strong monitoring by the regulators. The

    methodology to be adopted by the regulators may include encouraging firms

    to engage senior management of the entities in the decisions involving COI

    situations.

  • 14 | P a g e

    4. THE REGULATION OF SECURITIES MARKETS POST

    CRISIS?

    Regulators have started rethinking securities regulations after the lessons

    learnt from the financial crisis. Thus many of the measures proposed in this

    paper are currently under consideration of regulators or already in the process

    of being implemented. However, a pertinent consideration at this point in time

    the formulation of plans that are well thought-out and the willingness to stick

    to those plan during the times of resistance and criticism.

    i) Focus on Principles based regulations

    Principles based regulations (PBR) are the need of the time. Principles based

    regulations means broad set of standards focusing on the final goal to be

    achieved rather the mechanics of it. These standards would be aided by set of

    guidelines on how to achieve the desired outcomes. PBRs mean focusing less

    on chalking out detailed rules and prescriptions on how firms should operate.

    Instead the PBR give the firms more independence to operate within the set

    regulatory principles.

    Principles based regulations are preferable over the more detailed rule based

    regulations on the grounds that prescriptive standards have not been effective

    in complete prevention of market misconduct (Committee on Capital Markets

    Regulation, 2009). Detailed rules and regulations are burdensome for the

    regulators to devise and cumbersome to follow for the regulated entities.

    Detailed rules also fail to capture the changing nature of the financial sector

    and regulations often struggle to keep pace with innovations in products and

    range of services offered. Regulations based on principles are more likely to

    create an environment conducive to such innovations and advancements. The

    expectation that rules and regulations would always keep pace with these

    innovations is unrealistic and is likely to create hindrance to novelty in

    products and services. As the complexity of financial market and products

    increases, so will the complexity of rules to be followed.

  • 15 | P a g e

    Detailed rules and regulations make compliance more difficult especially for

    the smaller companies that lack dedicated resources having expertise in legal

    and regulatory matters (The Financial Services Authority, 2007). Sometimes

    elaborating such details may also have negative effect of both regulator and

    the regulated entity being engrossed in ensuring compliance with the law in

    letter, but unable to follow its true spirit.

    The risk-based regulation focusing on principles rather than detailed rules, is

    likely to contribute to better understanding and compliance of law in its true

    spirit and would also contribute towards the reduction in human resources

    employed in framing of laws and ensuring compliance.

    However, it must be understand that this shift of focus does not mean

    complete elimination of rules and regulations. There will always be need for

    detailed rules in some areas which will be required to be in place. This

    approach aligns well with the participatory role of the regulator as it makes

    following the law less cumbersome for the regulated entities.

    In this context, the concept of cost-benefit analysis of regulations needs more

    emphasis from regulators. Regulators need to focus on the accurate

    measurement of the costs that institutions have to incur in order to comply

    with regulations for the reason that most of these compliance costs would

    eventually be passed on to the clients/ shareholders of those institutions.

    ii) Reducing Systemic Risk

    Instruments such as Credit Default Swaps (CDS) have been blamed as

    contributors to the GFC. However, the proponents of these instruments opine

    that the instruments are not evil by substance and changes in the way these

    instruments are traded may magnify their utility as tools for diversifying credit

    risk. However, the current CDS market has potential to destabilize the

    financial system as it is susceptible to a chain of counterparty defaults

    (Committee on Capital Market Regulation, 2009).

  • 16 | P a g e

    The recent financial crisis has indeed exposed the credit, operational and

    systematic risks inherent in an unregulated CDS market. Some of these

    inherent risks can be mitigated by making CDS instruments subject to

    centralized clearing.

    Anabtawi and Schwarcz (2011) have proposed a three-pronged approach for

    dealing with systemic risks. The authors argue that in order to manage

    systemic risks, three inter-related factors must be controlled; namely conflicts,

    complacency and complexity. These are considered to be factors that the

    market participants cannot be expected to address by themselves.

    Regulations directed towards managing systemic risks must take into account

    behavioral factors that lead market players to take decisions that would not

    pass the test of rationality. Behavioral biases lead individuals to make errors of

    judgment regarding the risks involved in their investments thus contributing to

    enhanced systemic risk. Encouraging companies to provide their risk

    managers with reasonable degree of independence and authority to question

    excessive risk taking behaviors by decisions makers is one way of handing this

    problem. Furthermore, companies may be encouraged to perform qualitative

    analysis of risks, in addition to the use of quantitative models.

    Agency problems lead managers to take excessive risks or the risks that

    shareholders do not want the company to undertake. Regulators can play their

    part by encouraging companies to align executives remuneration with

    companys long-term performance. Furthermore, regulators must also consider

    the ability and willingness of market participants to appreciate risks inherent

    in their investments. Complex financial products sometimes make it difficult

    for decision makers to fully appreciate the risks involved in their investments.

    This leads to enhanced threat to the stability of the financial system.

    iii) Need for enhanced International Cooperation

    Enhanced international cooperation among regulator would be required in the

    post-crisis period as the financial markets become global and more inter-

  • 17 | P a g e

    connected. This cooperation will reduce the opportunities for regulatory

    arbitrage available to some financial firms. Regulators would also benefit from

    exchange of information and insights gained from local regulatory experiences

    which will aid in devising policies.

    iv) Other considerations

    Carvajal and Elliott (2007) argue that:

    a combination of factors, including insufficient legal authority, a lack of

    resources, political will and skills, has undermined the regulators capacity to

    effectively execute regulation. This weakness is more acute in areas of

    increased technical complexity such as standards for and supervision of the

    valuation of assets and risk management practices.

    The regulators need to re-adopt the policy of active regulation with strong

    regulations focusing on investor protection and market stability. Regulators

    must keep themselves abreast of developments taking place in the financial

    markets, train and equip their staff members to better regulate complex and

    innovative financial products being introduced from time to time. Regulators

    need to strike the right balance between promoting growth of financial

    markets and achievement of market discipline and stability. The staff members

    at the securities regulators must be provided proper training along with a

    career path that incentivizes them to pursue a long term career with the

    regulator. This will reduce likely conflicts of interest caused by the fact that

    market participants could be possible future employers for staff members. This

    may also mean grooming of staff members and preparing them for

    appointment at senior most positions (e.g. Commissioners) in the regulatory

    bodies.

    The regulators need to rediscover their focus on optimal corporate disclosure,

    corporate governance and auditing & accounting oversight. The regulatory

    framework must be made less complicated in order to minimize the room for

    regulatory arbitrage or the possibility that a specific type of market player or

    product could evade the ambit of regulation. This will lessen the likelihood

  • 18 | P a g e

    that one particular area would remain unregulated owing to unclear

    demarcation of responsibility between regulators.

    The regulators must appreciate their roles in restoring public confidence in

    financial markets and institutions. Necessary steps for restoration of that

    confidence include not only development but strict enforcement of rules that

    assure the investing public that necessary controls have been put in place and

    anyone who defrauds investors will be taken to task.

    It has also been proposed that in order to achieve the goal of investor

    protection; the regulators should consider aiming to dissuade unsophisticated

    investors from investing directly in the security markets (instead encourage

    investment through mutual funds). This may done, for instance, by including a

    disclaimer similar to ones given by mutual funds, in the broker contract that

    investing directly in securities markets involves considerable risk and is

    suitable for well knowledgeable investors only (Zingales, 2009). This will

    allow regulators to focus more on asset managers and mutual funds and

    possibly eliminate the need for detailed rules intended to protect unsuspecting

    individual investors. Removal of some of the tedious rules may also encourage

    more companies to offer their securities to the market.

    The conventional goal of educating investors must be brought to the fore-front

    with the increasing complexity and innovation of in financial markets and

    products. Investors must be made aware of the risks involved in different type

    of financial products keeping in view the ultimate goals of investor protection

    and controlling systemic risk. The drawbacks of the present system of investor

    education must be assessed and current investor education programs revamped

    to make them more effective in the post-crisis environment. The focus should

    go beyond fraud education to include education on risky investment avenues,

    risk assessment mechanism, functioning of credit rating agencies and rights of

    shareholders etc.

  • 19 | P a g e

    5. WHAT KIND OF CRISES CAN WE EXPECT IN FUTURE?

    HOW CAN WE DEAL WITH THEM?

    It needs to be emphasized that no set of financial or macro regulations can

    completely eliminate the possibility of occurrence of financial crises. By

    improving the regulatory framework, however, we aim to reduce the impact of

    these crises as and when they occur and also decrease the likelihood of such

    crisis leading to complete financial turmoil by not being able assess or manage

    the systemic risk.

    Price bubbles have been at the forefront of many of the crises in recent times

    and excessive risk taking and herd mentality will probably continue to produce

    price bubbles in years to come. Gerding (2006) has done extensive work on

    the financial crises, price bubbles and on the decay of securities regulations.

    His argument revolves around two basic premises. First, a period of financial

    growth generally creates or strengthens political pressure in the favor of a

    framework inclined towards deregulation. In a period of financial growth

    culminating in a bubble, market players lobby for less stringent securities laws

    citing prevailing financial stability and growth. Rules and regulations

    restricting excessive risk taking are portrayed as impediments to the growth of

    the financial sector. Thus policy makers are persuaded to consider diluting

    securities regulations with an aim to promote growth. The resistance by

    market participates may also include resistance against new proposals that

    address excessive speculation and risk taking. A period of growth and relative

    financial stability thus becomes non-conducive to imposition of limits on the

    risk taking of institutions. Secondly, bubbles tend to enfeeble even those

    regulations that remain unaffected by political pressures. This can be caused

    by several factors, including increased work load and pressures to finalize

    impending deals - performance pressures that may lead to industry wide

    decline in professional norms and weakening status of compliance with laws

    and rules.

    Many different theories aimed at preventing asset price bubbles and

    minimizing the systemic effects of bursting of price bubbles have surfaced.

  • 20 | P a g e

    One of the possible solutions could be, as suggested by Gerding (2006), to

    politically insulate the regulators so that the impact of political pressures on

    the decisions of regulators would be minimal. However, practically insulating

    regulators from political pressures is not an easy task. Allen and Gale (199)

    have proposed a theory that emphasizes the relationship of credit availability

    and asset price bubbles. This theory proposes that central banks should try to

    avoid unnecessary expansion of credit as well as the uncertainty regarding

    future credit expansion. The authors suggest that if central banks can control

    the level and volatility of credit, it is likely to help prevent asset price bubbles

    as, according to this theory, high current credit levels as well as expectations

    of higher future credit levels can contribute to price bubbles.

    Financial institutions and their managers are under pressure during periods of

    sustained economic growth to report profits, comparable or better than

    competition. These performance pressures lead managers to assume excessive

    risks in anticipation of higher profits which results in greater systemic risks.

    Managers unable to keep pace with competition are considered under-

    performers and often end up getting below par remuneration. Companies that

    succumb to this performance pressure often expand at a faster pace using

    higher leverage. This works without much trouble during the periods when

    asset prices are on the rise, stock markets are performing well and there are

    few defaults on the bond market with sufficient liquidly in the system.

    However, as the boom nears its end, liquidity dries up especially for highly

    leveraged firms who have already started experiencing higher defaults partly

    due to lower standards of credit assessments used during the period of

    aggressive growth. Thus booms and busts follow each other in a cycle and

    prohibiting the use of particular products would do little to prevent the next

    crisis (Goodhart, 2009).

    Liquidity, credit and banking crises might continue to occur every now and

    then in one part of the world causing trouble elsewhere in this increasingly

    interconnected financial world. The task for regulators is tough as they battle

    to find the right policy response to these recurring crisis situations.

  • 21 | P a g e

    The reliance on complex mathematical models and theorems is already being

    criticized as some experts believe that a broader understanding of macro

    economy may prove more beneficial for stabilizing our financial markets

    (ALDE Workshop, 2008).

    6. CONCLUSION

    Securities markets regulations can greatly benefit from the increasing

    emphasis and focus on relevant research. Regulatory authorities need to

    realign their research budgets so that in-depth research on the issues affecting

    the stability of our financial system is conducted and appropriate policy

    recommendations are formulated. Dedicated human resources specializing in

    research on regulations and policy issues should be developed for this purpose.

    The recommendations from these researchers should be given due weight-age.

    One of the lessons learned from the financial crises experience over the years

    is that regulators must discontinue being over-reactive to market events.

    Sarbanes Oxley Act was enacted in 2002 in response to major corporate

    scandals such as Enron and Worldcom. Checks on executive remuneration

    were introduced immediately after expensive bailouts of troubled banks; and

    there have been calls for complete banning of CDS after credit crisis. Far from

    commenting on the merit of some of these actions, this paper argues that

    regulators need to stick to the principles of regulations during the periods of

    growth and during crises, rather than being lax during a bubble and over-

    stringent after a bust.

    As suggested by Barr et al (2009); regulations must be behaviorally

    informed. Regulators must consider the limitations of disclosure and market

    discipline due to behavioral factors and the design of all future policies should

    take into account the complex mix of rational choice and behavioral biases

    which inherently reduce the predictability of these regulatory choices. Policy

    makers must have the realization that market players do not always act in their

    own interest (i.e. due to complexity, complacency and conflict as suggested by

    Anabtawi and Schwarcz, 2011). Thus market players cannot be expected to,

    automatically take into account the collective interest of the whole market.

  • 22 | P a g e

    This is due in part their inability to see the complete picture (as also suggested

    by Gorton (2009)).

    Regulators would also contribute to improving the stability of our financial

    system by renewing their focus on investor education. We have seen time and

    again that the complexities and conflicts of modern day financial markets

    make it hard for even the sophisticated investors to make rational decisions.

    This further amplifies the need for enhanced efforts for carrying out

    comprehensive investor awareness programs that warn unsuspecting investors

    of the real risks of entering the financial markets. These efforts will go a long

    way towards reduction of systemic risk and hence achievement of the

    objectives of financial regulation.

    The history of financial crises over the last two centuries enlightens us that the

    causes common to most crises were excessive risk taking, failure to limit

    systemic risk, imprudent lending, lack of understanding of complex financial

    products (a more recent phenomenon) and conflicts of interests (ALDE

    Workshop, 2008). Regulators must realize that crises have occurred despite

    our best efforts and this fashion is likely to continue in years to come. The

    belief that future crises are likely to possess similar characteristics to the ones

    we have seen in the past, is indeed a silver lining as it provides guidance to

    regulators and policy makers in their quest to minimize the likelihood and

    impact of such crises.

  • 23 | P a g e

    References

    Allen, F. and Gale, D. (1999); Bubbles, Crises and Policy; Oxford Review of

    Economic Policy; Vol. 15, No.03

    Alliance for Liberals and Democrats for Europe (ALDE) (2008); Workshop

    titled International Financial Crisis: Its causes and what to do about it;

    Liberals and Democrats Workshop, February 27th

    , 2008

    Anabtawi, I. and Schwarcz, S. L. (2011); Regulating Systemic Risk: Towards

    An Analytical Framework; Duke Law Faculty Scholarship; Paper 2305.

    http://scholarship.law.duke.edu/faculty_scholarship/2305 (accessed on May

    12, 2011)

    Avgouleas, E. (2009); What Future for Disclosure as a Regulatory Technique?

    Lessons from the Global Financial Crisis and Beyond; Available at:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1369004 (accessed on May 19, 2011)

    Barr, M.S., Mullainathan, S. and Shafir, E. (2009); The Case for Behaviorally

    Informed Regulation, in New Perspectives In Regulation; David Moss & John

    Cisternino ed. 2009.

    Bordo, M.D. (2007); Growing Up To Financial Stability; Working Paper

    12993, March 2007; JEL No. N00, N2 (available at

    http://www.nber.org/papers/w12993; accessed on: April 20, 2011)

    Carvajal, A. and Elliott, J. (2007); Strengths and Weaknesses in Securities

    Market Regulation: A Global Analysis; IMF Working Paper No. 07/259,

    2007; Available at:

    http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2007/wp07259.pdf; (accessed on May

    15, 2011)

    Choi, J. J., Beshears, J., Laibson, D. and Madrian, B. C. (2010); How Does

    Simplified Disclosure Affect Individuals Mutual Fund Choices?, available at

    http://www.som.yale.edu/faculty/jjc83/summaryprospectus.pdf; (accessed on

    May 10, 2011).

  • 24 | P a g e

    Committee on Capital Markets Regulation; (2009) The Global Financial

    Crisis: A plan for regulatory reform; available at:

    http://www.capmktsreg.org/pdfs/TGFC-CCMR_Report_(5-26-09).pdf;

    accessed on May 19, 2011)

    Crockett, A. (2001), Market Discipline and Financial Stability, BIS

    speeches, 23 May 2001 (Available at:

    http://www.bis.org/speeches/sp010523.htm : accessed on: May 07, 2011)

    Emerging Markets Committee of IOSCO (2010); Guidance for Efficient

    Regulation of Conflicts of Interest Facing Market Intermediaries (October

    2010), International Organization of Securities Commissions; (available at:

    http://www.iosco.org/library/pubdocs/pdf/IOSCOPD342.pdf; accessed on:

    May 07, 2011)

    Erskine, A. (2010); Rethinking Securities Regulation After The Crisis: An

    Economics Perspective, (9 July 2010); Available at:

    http://www.asic.gov.au/asic/pdflib.nsf/LookupByFileName/RethinkingSecuriti

    esRegulation-20100709.pdf/$file/RethinkingSecuritiesRegulation-

    20100709.pdf; (accessed on May 11, 2011)

    Enders, Z. and Hakenes, H. (2010); On the Existence and Prevention of Asset

    Price Bubbles; available at: www.coll.mpg.de/pdf_dat/2010_44online.pdf;

    (accessed on: May 15, 2011)

    Gerding, E.F. (2006); The Next Epidemic: Bubbles and the Growth and Decay

    of Securities Regulation; (February 2006); Connecticut Law Review 38(3), pp.

    393-453

    Goodhart, C, et al (2009), The Fundamental Principles of Financial

    Regulation, Geneva Reports on the World Economy 11; (available at:

    www.princeton.edu/~markus/research/papers/Geneva11.pdf; accessed on:

    May 13, 2011)

  • 25 | P a g e

    Gorton, G. (2009); Slapped in the Face by the Invisible Hand: Banking and the

    Panic of 2007 (May 09, 2009); available at:

    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1401882; accessed on:

    May 07, 2011)

    International Monetary Fund - IMF (2011); Global Financial Stability Report

    (April 2011); (available at:

    http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2011/01/index.htm; accessed on May

    07, 2011)

    Martin, J. D. (2009); A Primer on the Role of Securitization in the Credit

    Market Crisis; (January 7, 2009) (available at:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1324349; accessed on May 07, 2011)

    McCarthy, C. (2006) Speech by Chairman, FSA (31 October 2006) at

    Financial Services Skills Council 2nd Annual Conference (Available at:

    http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/Library/Communication/Speeches/2006/1031_c

    m.shtml; accessed on: April 18, 2011)

    Moshirian, F. (2010); The Global Financial Crisis and the Evolution of

    Markets, Institutions and Regulation; (August 29, 2010). Journal of Banking

    and Finance, Vol. 36, No. 1, 2011; available at:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1667824

    Poser, N. S, (2009); Why the SEC Failed: Regulators Against Regulation;

    Brooklyn Journal of Corporate, Financial & Commercial Law, Vol. 3, Spring

    2009; Brooklyn Law School, Legal Studies Paper No. 132. (Available at:

    http://ssrn.com/abstract=1348612; accessed on May 07, 2011)

    Shanmugaratnam (2001); Regulating the capital markets: making market

    discipline work; Speech by Tharman Shanmugaratnam, Deputy Managing

    Director of the Monetary Authority of Singapore at the StanChart-Reuters-

    Business Times Investment Awards ceremony, Singapore (16 Feb 2001)

  • 26 | P a g e

    (available at: http://www.bis.org/review/r010220b.pdf accessed on: May 10,

    2011)

    Stephanou, C. (2010) Rethinking Market Discipline in Banking - Lessons

    from the Financial Crisis World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series,

    (available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1565988; accessed on: April 20, 2011)

    Schwarcz, S. L. (2008); Disclosures Failure In The Subprime Mortgage

    Crisis; Utah Law Review, p.1109, 2008; Duke Law School Legal Studies

    Paper No. 203; (available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1113034; accessed on:

    May 10, 2011)

    The Financial Services Authority (2007); Principles based regulation

    focusing on the outcomes that matter; (Available at:

    http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/principles.pdf; accessed on: April 18, 2011)

    Turner, A. (2010), Economics, Conventional Wisdom and Public Policy, UK

    Financial Services Authority, Speech to the Institute for New Economic

    Thinking, Inaugural Conference, Cambridge, (April 9, 2010); (available at:

    http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pages/Library/Communication/Speeches/2010/0409_at.

    shtml; accessed on: April 18, 2011)

    Turner Review, The (2009); A regulatory response to the global banking

    crisis; March 2009 (The Financial Services Authority (FSA) United

    Kingdom); (available at: www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/other/turner_review.pdf;

    accessed on: April 25, 2011)

    Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1986) Rational Choice and the Framing of

    Decisions The Journal of Business, Vol. 59, No. 4, (Available at:

    http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0021-

    9398%28198610%2959%3A4%3CS251%3ARCATFO%3E2.0.CO%3B2-C;

    accessed on May 07, 2011)

  • 27 | P a g e

    Zingales, L. (2009); The Future of Securities Regulation; Chicago Booth

    School of Business Research Paper No. 08-27; FEEM Working Paper No.

    7.2009; (available at:

    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1319648; accessed on:

    April 19, 2011)