60
Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa A Labor Market Perspective on What Works, What Does Not, and Why THE WORLD BANK Christophe Lemiere Christopher H. Herbst Negda Jahanshahi Ellen Smith Agnes Soucat WORLD BANK WORKING PAPER NO. 209 AFRICA HUMAN DEVELOPMENT SERIES Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers inSub-Saharan AfricaA Labor Market Perspective on What Works,What Does Not, and Why

THE WORLD BANK

Christophe LemiereChristopher H. HerbstNegda JahanshahiEllen SmithAgnes Soucat

W O R L D B A N K W O R K I N G P A P E R N O . 2 0 9

A F R I C A H U M A N D E V E L O P M E N T S E R I E S

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

wb370910
Typewritten Text
58443
Page 2: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 3: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

W O R L D B A N K W O R K I N G P A P E R N O. 2 0 9

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan AfricaA Labor Market Perspective on What Works, What Does Not, and Why

Christophe Lemiere, Christopher H. Herbst, Negda Jahanshahi, Ellen Smith, and Agnes Soucat

Page 4: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Copyright © 2011 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank1818 H Street NWWashington DC 20433Telephone: 202-473-1000Internet: www.worldbank.org

All rights reserved

printed on recycled paper

1 2 3 4   13 12 11 10

World Bank Working Papers are published to communicate the results of the Bank’s work to the development community with the least possible delay. The manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally-edited texts. Some sources cited in this paper may be informal documents that are not readily available. This volume is a product of the staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. The fi ndings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this volume do not necessarily refl ect the views of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

Rights and PermissionsThe material in this publication is copyrighted. Copying and/or transmi ing portions or all of this work without permission may be a violation of applicable law. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank encourages dissemination of its work and will normally grant permission to reproduce portions of the work promptly. For permission to photocopy or reprint any part of this work, please send a request with complete information to the Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; telephone: 978-750-8400; fax: 978-750-4470; Internet: www.copyright.com. All other queries on rights and licenses, including subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Offi ce of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2422; e-mail: [email protected].

ISBN: 978-0-8213-8599-9eISBN: 978-0-8213-8600-2ISSN:1726-5878       DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8599-9

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data has been requested

Page 5: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

iii

Contents

List of Abbreviations .....................................................................................................................vIntroduction ..................................................................................................................................... 1Chapter 1. What Is Wrong with the Current Policy Perspective on Urban-Rural

Imbalances? .............................................................................................................................. 3Chapter 2. Urban-Rural Imbalances: Extent and Consequences ........................................... 5

National level imbalances ....................................................................................................... 5Urban-rural imbalances by country, profession, and gender ............................................ 6Eff ect of urban-rural health worker imbalances on achieving health MDGs, reducing poverty, and improving health system effi ciency ............................................... 9

Chapter 3. Explaining Urban-Rural Imbalances from a Labor Market Perspective: Theory and Evidence ............................................................................................................ 11Urban-rural diff erences in demand for labor ..................................................................... 12Urban-rural diff erences in the supply of labor .................................................................. 12Urban-rural diff erences in compensation ........................................................................... 14

Chapter 4. Policy Options for Addressing Urban-Rural Imbalances: Theory and Evidence ............................................................................................................ 16Increasing health worker demand ....................................................................................... 17Reducing the opportunity cost of rural employment: incentive policies ....................... 17Transferring urban health workers to rural areas through compulsory policies (bonding) ................................................................................................................... 22Increasing the overall supply of health workers by scaling up HRH education .......... 23Improving the rural orientation of the HRH education system ...................................... 23Creating alternative skill mixes in rural clinics .................................................................. 24A racting health workers from abroad (immigration policies) ...................................... 26

Chapter 5. Conclusion: A Roadmap for Policymaking .......................................................... 29Appendix A. Countries Reviewed ............................................................................................. 33Appendix B. The Lorenz Curve, the Concentration Index, and the Gini Coeffi cient ...... 34

The Lorenz curve .................................................................................................................... 33The Concentration index ....................................................................................................... 34The Gini coeffi cient................................................................................................................. 34

Appendix C. Applying Labor Economics to Health Care ..................................................... 37Market-clearing equilibrium, unemployment, and labor shortages ............................... 38

Appendix D. Health Labor Market Analysis ........................................................................... 43References ....................................................................................................................................... 45

Page 6: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

iv World Bank Study

BoxesBox 2.1 Overview of methods to apply to the measurement of geographical

imbalances of HRH .................................................................................................................. 6Box 4.1 Using discrete choice experiments to elicit health workers’ preferences

regarding rural jobs ................................................................................................................ 18Box 4.2 Using incentives to recruit rural doctors in Mali and Zambia .................................. 20

FiguresFigure 1.1 Policymaking and health labor markets..................................................................... 3Figure 2.1 Doctor, nurse, midwife per 1,000 population ratio in Sub-Saharan Africa ........... 6Figure 2.2 Concentration indices for doctors and nurses .......................................................... 7Figure 2.3 Distribution of health workers per capita by cadre in all districts of Tanzania ... 8Figure 2.4 Male : female ratios among health workers in rural

and urban areas of Zambia ..................................................................................................... 9Figure 3.1 Urban employment and rural shortage situation ................................................... 12Figure 3.2 Reasons Ethiopian healthcare workers prefer working in urban areas .............. 14Figure 3.3 Compensation for doctors and nurses across regions in Ethiopia ....................... 15Figure 4.1 Eff ect of various incentives on probability of doctors and nurses

accepting a post in a rural area ............................................................................................. 17Figure 4.2 Reasons for migration in Cameroon, South Africa, Uganda, and Zimbabwe .... 27Figure 4.3 Growth trend of Cuban brigade doctors present in Ghana .................................. 27Figure 5.1 Policy roadmap for addressing urban-rural health workers imbalances ............ 29Figure B.1 Sample Lorenz curve .................................................................................................. 34Figure B.2 Lorenz curve for under-fi ve mortality rate in India and Mali .............................. 36Figure C.1 Market-clearing equilibrium ..................................................................................... 39Figure C.2 Unemployment ........................................................................................................... 40Figure C.3 Labor shortage............................................................................................................. 40Figure C.4 Urban employment and rural shortage situation .................................................. 41Figure C.5 Urban and rural HRH markets with improved information ............................... 41Figure D.1 Health labor market analysis: a country example (for doctors) .......................... 43

TablesTable 2.1 Number of doctors and nurses per 1,000 people in rural and urban

regions of Sub-Saharan Africa ................................................................................................ 7Table 2.2 Poverty indicators by region in Mozambique in 2000.............................................. 10Table 4.1 Policy options for reducing urban-rural imbalances in HRH ................................. 16Table 4.2 Examples of incentive programs implemented in Sub-Saharan Africa ................. 19Table 4.3 Compulsory programs implemented in selected

Sub-Saharan Africa countries ............................................................................................... 22Table 4.4 Skill mix programs in selected countries in Sub-Saharan Africa ............................ 25Table 5.1 Policy options for reducing urban-rural gaps in HRH ............................................ 31

Page 7: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

List of Abbreviations

DRC Democratic Republic of the CongoHRH Health human resourcesMDG Millennium Development Goals (United Nations)MGI Medecine General IntegralSNNPR Southern Nations, Nationalities, and Peoples’ Region (Ethiopia)SSA Sub-Saharan AfricaUN United NationsUSAID United States Agency for International DevelopmentWB World BankWHO World Health OrganizationZHWRS Zambian Health Workers Retention Scheme

v

Page 8: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 9: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

1

Introduction

The human resources crisis in the health sector has been gathering a ention on the global stage. To date, however, most of this a ention has focused on shortages of health

human resources (HRH) at the national level. At least as important are problems at the sub-national level. Massive geographic and skill mix imbalances are refl ected in the perilous undersupply of HRH in most rural areas. Virtually all Sub-Saharan African countries suff er from signifi cant geographic imbalances.

Very li le substantive information or documentation exists on the problem. Even less is known about the lessons from policies aimed at addressing urban-rural human resource imbalances, let alone experiences of Sub-Saharan Africa countries, with such policies.

There also appears to be a disconnect between the objectives and eff orts of policymakers on the one hand and the functioning of national health labor markets and labor market behavior on the other hand. This disconnect hinders policy eff ectiveness and the effi cient utilization of resources intended to narrow urban-rural inequities. In Sub-Saharan Africa, government policies, o en limited to the management of public sector vacancies, appear to be elaborated, prescribed, and implemented independently of labor market considerations. Partly as a result, they are unable to eff ectively address urban-rural imbalances, which are an outcome of labor market dynamics.

This report discusses and analyzes labor market dynamics and outcomes (including unemployment, worker shortages, and urban-rural imbalances of categories of health workers) from a labor economics perspective. It then uses insights from this perspective as a basis for elaborating policy options that incorporate the underlying labor market forces.

The goal of the study is to address undesirable outcomes (including urban-rural HRH imbalances) more eff ectively. The study draws on an extensive inventory of policy options relevant to urban-rural labor force imbalance in Sub-Saharan Africa and the experiences with these imbalances to date. Given the limited documentation available on this topic through formal channels, the review relies heavily on “gray literature” from policymakers in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization (WHO). The report is divided into fi ve main sections. The fi rst section focuses on economic policies related to HRH objectives. It argues that policymaking has ignored health labor market dynamics. The second section provides data showing the extent of urban-rural imbalances and describes how these imbalances aff ect health system outcomes. The third section uses a health labor market framework to explain these imbalances. The fourth section outlines policy options relevant to Sub-Saharan Africa for addressing market distortions and aff ecting labor market outcomes. It also reviews evidence on the policies, strategies, and programs designed to address geographic imbalances in Sub-Saharan Africa, highlighting what has been done, what has worked, and what has not. The last section provides a roadmap for policymakers.

Page 10: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 11: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

3

C H A P T E R 1

What Is Wrong with the Current Policy Perspective

on Urban-Rural Imbalances?

Policymakers set health policy objectives (such as, for example, achieving the Millennium Development Goals for health). These health policy objectives are measured and

monitored using health policy indicators.Reaching the Millennium Development Goals requires that adequate numbers of

health workers be in place to serve the population in urban and rural areas. Two indicators are generally used to monitor urban-rural health worker imbalances. The main indicator is a regional health worker density indicator (the number of health workers per person). The vacancy rate of rural health worker positions is a second policy outcome indicator. Even if an adequate number of rural positions are funded, it is likely that some of them will remain vacant.

Both indicators depend on the dynamics of the health labor market. Within these markets, the supply of human resources for health (HRH) (that is, the number of health workers willing to work at various compensation levels) equals the demand for HRH (that is, the number of employers able and willing to recruit health workers at various compensation levels). When labor market outcomes need to be adjusted, the government uses policy instruments to infl uence the supply of or demand for labor, changing the market outcome (fi gure 1.1).

Figure 1.1 Policymaking and health labor markets

Health Labor Market COMPONENTS

Government HRH Policy

Available INSTRUMENTS

HRH demand

HRH supply Health Labor Market

OUTCOMES

(Levels of hired HRH & average HRH compensation)

Private health sector:

households and private health

care facilities

Other economic sectors

Health Policy INDICATORS

(HRH density in rural areas & vacancy rates in rural areas)

Health Policy OBJECTIVE

(Health care system utilization and quality)

Foreign countries

Source: Authors

Page 12: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

4 World Bank Working Paper

To date most policymakers have mistakenly assumed that they have complete control over labor market demand and supply and hence on labor market outcomes. Based on this assumption, they have relied on the following policies to address urban-rural health worker imbalances:

Allocating more budget funds in order to create additional health worker positions, especially in rural areas (that is, increasing HRH demand)

Increasing capacity for training more health workers (that is, increasing HRH supply)

Forcing health workers to work in rural areas (a practice known as bonding) Providing fi nancial incentives for health workers accepting work in rural areas

Most of these policies have failed to deliver sustained results, because they have assumed that health workers have only two alternatives: working for the government or being unemployed. Although governments in most Sub-Saharan Africa countries probably did have monopsony power until the 1980s, other employers now compete for health workers who can (legally or illegally) work in the private sector, move to other economic sectors, or emigrate. Failing to take account of the fact that governments are no longer the sole source of demand for health workers leads to fl awed policies.

Considering health labor market behavior helps policymakers identify (and measure) not only constraints but also opportunities for be er policymaking. Health labor markets can also help identify key success (or failure) factors for some policies.

Page 13: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

5

C H A P T E R 2

Urban-Rural Imbalances:Extent and Consequences

Health Worker imbalances and regional inequities in distribution can be measured and are evident at the national and particularly the sub-national level. Several methods

have been applied to capture the uneven distribution of health works. One popular method is the ratio of health workers to population, o en used to measure HRH imbalances. Other methods to analyze and compare imbalances of health workers is through economic tools such as the Concentration index, alongside the Gini index and Lorenzo Curve (see Box 2.1 and more detailed description in Annex B).

National level imbalances

Although the majority of countries have health worker ratios below the 2006 WHO benchmark, seven countries have a combined density of physicians, nurses and midwives that is above the 2006 benchmark of 2.28 (see fi gure 2.1). These countries are Botswana (3.05), Gabon (5.45), Mauritius (4.79), Namibia (3.36), Sao Tome and Principe (2.70), Seychelles (9.44) and South Africa (4.85). Interestingly, a lot more countries reach the pre-2006 benchmark of 0.4 professionals per 1000 population. This would suggest that many countries in SSA are actually not as badly off in terms of health worker availability as o en suggested. However, examining HRH to population ratios only at the national level can produce a misleading

Figure 2.1: Doctor, nurse, midwife per 1,000 population ratio in Sub-Saharan Africa

02

46

810

Phy

sici

an, N

urse

& M

idw

ifeD

ensi

ty p

er 1

0,00

0 P

opul

atio

n

Sey

chel

les

(200

5)G

abon

(200

5)S

outh

Afri

ca (2

005)

Mau

ritiu

s(20

05)

Nam

ibia

(200

5)B

otsw

ana

(200

5)S

ao T

ome

and

Prin

cipe

(200

8)Za

mbi

a (2

005)

Cap

e V

erde

(200

8)N

iger

ia (2

008)

Sw

azila

nd (2

009)

Ken

ya (2

007)

Ang

ola

(200

5)S

udan

(200

7)M

aurit

ania

(200

9)G

hana

(200

8)C

ongo

(200

8)Zi

mba

bwe

(200

8)B

enin

(200

8)D

RC

(200

9)E

quat

oria

l Gui

nea

(200

5)E

ritre

a (2

008)

Uga

nda

(200

7)B

urki

na F

aso

(200

8)C

omor

os (2

008)

Rw

anda

(200

7)G

uine

a (2

005)

Gui

nea-

Bis

sau

(200

9)Le

soth

o (2

005)

Gam

bia

(200

8)M

adag

asca

r (20

05)

Cam

eroo

n (2

009)

Mal

i (20

08)

Cot

e d'

Ivoi

re (2

008)

Sen

egal

(200

8)M

ozam

biqu

e (2

007)

Togo

(200

8)Ta

nzan

ia (2

007)

Cen

tral A

frica

n R

epub

lic (2

009)

Eth

iopi

a (2

008)

Libe

ria (2

009)

Mal

awi (

2008

)C

had

(200

9)B

urun

di (2

005)

Som

alia

(200

6)S

ierr

a Le

one

(200

9)N

iger

(200

9)

y

Source: WHO/Global Atlas

Page 14: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

6 World Bank Working Paper

picture. Countries that have acceptable national level HRH to population ratios may be experiencing health worker shortages or surplus in certain geographical areas.

Urban-rural imbalances by country, profession, and gender

A disaggregated analysis of HRH to population ratios o en exposes signifi cant diff erences between urban and rural areas. In Kampala for example, by far the largest urban area in Uganda, the number of doctors is 4.5 times the minimum benchmark—and 45 times that of rural Kamuli district. In Sudan, the doctor to population ratio in urban areas is 24 times that of rural areas, and the nurse to population ratio is 20 times higher than in rural areas (table 2.1).

And stark and yet diverse inequities in the distribution of health workers in several countries in SSA can also be illustrated using a concentration index. Figure 2.2 reveals the

Box 2.1: Overview of methods to apply to the measurement of geographical imbalances of HRH

HRH to pop ratioOne common HRH benchmark to measure HRH imbalances was proposed by the WHO following several studies carried out with the Joint Learning Initiative (WHO 2006). This benchmark indicates that there should be at least 2.28 health workers (doctors, nurses, and midwives) per 1,000 people to achieve the MDGs. This followed earlier pre-2006 WHO benchmarks of 0.1 doctors, 0.2 nurses, and 0.1 midwives per 1,000 people and about 0.4 health professionals per 1,000 people. Many countries have developed their own benchmarks, usually based on a standard skill mix for each type of health care facility. In Benin, for example, a district hospital is supposed have three doctors and a primary health care center is supposed to have one. Standards like these are very rigid and do not take into account the local burden of disease (especially HIV/AIDS). More sophisticated benchmarks have been designed, using clinical guidelines (see, for instance, Kurowski and others 2004). Yet, those also do not take into account the labor market determinants that may infl uence the fi nal HRH outcome

The Lorenz curve The Lorenz curve is a graphical representation of the proportionality of a distribution (the cumulative percentage of the values). To build the Lorenz curve, all the elements of a distribution must be ordered from the most important to the least important. Then, each element is plotted according to their cumulative percentage of X and Y, X being the cumulative percentage of elements and Y being their cumulative importance. For instance, out of a distribution of 10 elements (N), the fi rst element would represent 10% of X and whatever percentage of Y it represents (this percentage must be the highest in the distribution). The second element would cumulatively represent 20% of X (its 10% plus the 10% of the fi rst element) and its percentage of Y plus the percentage of Y of the fi rst element.

The Gini coeffi cient The Gini coeffi cient was developed to measure the degree of concentration (inequality) of a variable in a distribution of its elements. It compares the Lorenz curve of a ranked empirical distribution with the line of perfect equality. This line assumes that each element has the same contribution to the total summation of the values of a variable. The Gini coeffi cient ranges between 0, where there is no concentration (perfect equality), and 1 where there is total concentration (perfect inequality).

The Concentration indexThe concentration index summarizes the information presented by the Lorenz curve. The distance between the Lorenz curve (the observed distribution of the indicator) and the “ideal distribution line” represents the degree of inequality. The number measuring the area between the two lines thus summarizes the degree to which the distribution is equitable.

The concentration index formula calculates twice the area between the Lorenz curve and the line of inequality (Wagstaff 2008). It ranges in value from –1 to 1. By convention the concentration index is negative when the Lorenz curve is above the ideal distribution line (representing an undesirable indicator variable) and positive when the Lorenz curve is below the ideal distribution line (representing a desirable indicator).

Page 15: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 7

Figure 2.2: Concentration indices for doctors and nurses

0.600

0.500

0.400

0.300

Con

cent

ratio

n In

dexe

s

0.200

0.100

0.000

Doctors

Nurses

Seneg

alMoz

ambiq

ue

Chad

Congo

DRC

Benin

Niger

Maurita

nia Mali

Kenya

Source: Authors

Table 2.1 Number of doctors and nurses per 1,000 people in rural and urban regions of Sub-Saharan Africa

Country Doctors Nurses

rural region

urbanregion

rural region

urban region

Chad 0.222 0.549 ND’jamena 0.885 0.685

Congo, Dem. Rep.

0.175 1.449 4.762 10.101

Ethiopia 0.167 Amhara 0.769 Addis 0.909 Amhara 0.752 Addis

Guinea 0.714 Moyenne Guinee

3.774 Conakry 0.952 Moyenne Guinnee

3.333 Conakry

Mali 0.196 Koulikouro 1.852 Bamako 0.909 0.806 Bamako

Mauritania 0.303 Gorgol 1.031 Nouadhibou 2.632 Gorgol 0.794 Nouadhibou

Mozambique 0.154 2.564

Niger 0.056 Tillabery 1.429 Niaey 0.556 Tillabery 0.833 Niamey

Rwanda 0.034 Gikongoro 0.588 Kigali 0.541 Gikongoro 0.617 Kigali

Senegal 0.069 Kolda 2.326 Dakar 0.800 Dakar

Sudan 0.143 South 3.497 Khartoum 0.615 South 12.594 North

Kenya 0.006 Turkana 2.000 Nairobi

Uganda 0.100 Kamuli 4.545 Kampala

Source: Author’s calculations based on country status reports.

Page 16: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

8 World Bank Working Paper

degree of geographical imbalance of doctors and of nurses across seven SSA countries. The closer the concentration index is to zero, the more equal the distribution of a given resource (doctors or nurses in this context). Conversely, the closer a concentration index is to 1, the less equal is the distribution of a given resource. As the concentration indices reveal, in the majority of countries, the distribution of doctors is more and fairly equally skewed towards urban areas, whereas the distribution of nurses is much more variant and diverse.

Figure 2.3: Distribution of health workers per capita by cadre in all districts of Tanzania

Source: Munga and Maestad 2009.

The disproportionate allocation of doctors in urban areas can be generalized by speaking in terms of highly- and lowly-trained (or qualifi ed) health workers. Health workers with more years of formal education, such as doctors, are heavily concentrated in urban areas and especially sparse in rural areas, while cadres with fewer years of education, such as nurses or auxiliary nurses, have a higher concentration (relative to population) in rural areas. An interesting example (see fi gure 2.3) is provided by the Tanzania case, where the density of health workers, by cadres, has been analyzed using concentration curves1).

As shown in the fi gure, about 80% of the population in Tanzania (mostly in rural areas) is served by only 20% of the doctors (named “medical offi cers” in Tanzania). Rural areas have a higher proportion of mid-level cadres such as Clinical Offi cers2 (see the green line in graph) than urban areas. The Figure also shows that there is no cadre of which the

Page 17: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 9

Figure 2.4 Male : female ratios among health workers in rural and urban areas of Zambia

Source: Herbst 2007

Rural areas Urban areas

disadvantaged districts have a larger share of the health workers than is suggested by their relative population levels (i.e. all concentration curves in Fig. 2.4 fall below the diagonal).

Furthermore, rural areas tend to have a higher proportion of health workers without formal training. These health workers include community health workers, health extension workers, and traditional health workers, and are predominantly found largely in poorer, rural areas. For instance, Lesotho, where more than 75 percent of the population is rural, has 8,600 healthcare workers. Only 44 percent of them have a formal education. The other workers—4,800—are community health workers, most of whom work in rural areas. Sierra Leone is home to only 3,736 conventional workers but also to 10,723 traditional birth a endants, who are mostly found in more districts.

Urban and rural healthcare workers also tend to have diff erent gender profi les, with females more heavily concentrated in urban areas than in rural areas. For instance, of all healthcare workers in Zambia, 64.7 percent are female. Nonetheless, all cadres except nurses are majority male in rural areas. All cadres have a large female contingent in urban areas. This gender imbalance further exacerbates the discussed defi cits of nurses and midwives in rural areas, since these cadres are largely made up of females.

Effect of urban-rural health worker imbalances on achieving health MDGs, reducing poverty, and improving health system effi ciency

One reason why rural ratios below benchmarks are especially troublesome is that they signal a double burden on the poorest of the poor, many of whom live in rural areas and face greater public health needs than people in urban areas (table 2.2).

The most severe public health problems are o en found in rural and remote areas, where mortality levels are higher. Yet, the lack of health workers in these areas greatly decreases the likelihood that the sick obtain treatment or that the healthy prevent infection. Greater exposure to health risks and inadequate access to healthcare in rural areas reduce the likelihood of achieving the MDGs, which depend on the expansion of coverage of key, high-impact interventions. It is diffi cult for rural areas without adequate access to the providers of these interventions to achieve the MDGs. A case-in-point is maternal mortality. Strong evidence points to a high coverage rate of skilled birth a endants as a critical input for reducing maternal mortality rates (Anand and Baernighausen 2004). The lack of specifi c professionals, such as midwives, in rural areas is strongly associated with the failure to achieve the maternal mortality MDG.

Page 18: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

10 World Bank Working Paper

A frequent contention is that higher-level professionals (for example, doctors) are not in demand in rural areas. And that the urban-rural imbalance of higher-level professionals may actually refl ect this apparent lack of demand for them. Community and traditional health providers may be more trusted and respected than formal health workers in some remote areas and, thus, considered a more appropriate solution. Furthering this argument is the apparently diff erent utilization pa ern of higher-level professional health workers by rural populations. When doctors are made more accessible in rural areas, however, the utilization pa ern is not signifi cantly diff erent from that of the non-poor (Ouendo 2005). Many demographic and health surveys fi nd that the poor have lower overall utilization rates of health workers, but when they do seek out health services, they choose the same combination of services and health professionals as do the non-poor. Thus, the apparent lower utilization of higher-level health workers may refl ect the poor’s limited access to higher-level and qualifi ed health workers rather than diff erent preferences (for Tanzania, see Leonard, Mliga, and Haile Mariam 2003; Klemick 2007).

Urban-rural imbalances in health workers hinder the development of primary health care services, reducing the effi ciency of the health system. Using urban referral centers rather than rural centers dramatically increases the costs of health care services for the poor for two main reasons. First, rural people incur costs in traveling to an urban area.1 Second, when they reach their destination, they pay more for health care services, because urban health care services are usually more expensive than rural services. Sanders and others (1998) show that for the same medical case (that is, acute malaria fever), the length of stay and number of lab tests may be 10 times as great in an urban area than in a rural one.

Notes1 This cost includes both the direct cost for transportation and the opportunity cost of taking a half-day or a day off . 2 A cadre that commonly has a skill set somewhere between that of doctors and that of nurses.

Table 2.2 Poverty indicators by region in Mozambique in 2000

Region Prevalence of poverty Depth of poverty Doctor to population ratio

Rural 71.25 29.92 0.154

Urban 62.01 26.67 2.564

North 66.28 26.62 -

Center 73.81 32.71 -

South (including Maputo city) 65.8 6.8 -

South (excluding Maputo city) 71.67 30.17 -

National 69.37 29.26 -

Source: Ministério do Plano e Finanças 2000.

Page 19: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

11

C H A P T E R 3

Explaining Urban-Rural Imbalances from a Labor Market

Perspective: Theory and Evidence

Labor economics theory provides an insightful framework to be er understand the reasons behind this unequal distribution in HRH (see Appendix C for a detailed

description). It off ers two diff erent types of explanations, which are basically related to the two key features of a labor market. These explanations are not exclusive and a given country can experience both.

(i) A fi rst explanation is the reduced demand for HRH in rural areas. Such demand does not refl ect needs-based demand for HRH, but the demand expressed by employers to hire health workers or by individuals willing to buy health services. It is important to note that there are always two kinds of employers: public ones (government-run health care facilities) and private ones (private health care facilities and patients paying user fees). Yet, demand for HRH in rural areas is usually not adequately funded, which contributes to the rural-urban imbalances of health workers.

(ii) A second explanation centers on reduced supply for rural areas. Indeed, even if there is enough funding and a signifi cant rural demand for HRH, health workers may not be suffi cient in number and or have some preferences and characteristics that make them reluctant to work in rural areas. Health worker numbers, preferences and characteristics lead therefore to a limited number of health workers in rural areas.

In many instances in Sub-Saharan Africa, the urban market is in unemployment or at best at a market-clearing equilibrium (although occasionally also in a shortage situation); whilst rural areas are o en in shortage situations. As a result, the urban and rural markets together are usually in one of three diff erent situations: urban unemployment equals rural shortage, urban unemployment is greater than rural shortage, or urban unemployment is less than rural shortage. Vujicic and Zurn (2006) fi nd that Malawi experienced high vacancy rates and high underemployment of health workers, even in urban markets, although HRH needs are far from being met. Data from health facilities in Zambia in 2006 reveal health worker shortages throughout the country, albeit one that is much worse in rural than urban areas (table 3.1). The Republic of Congo suff ers from twin urban unemployment and rural health worker shortages. A 2008 assessment of health worker distribution and urban-rural vacancy rates there fi nds that “a severely unequal distribution of human resources between urban and rural se ings caused by a variety of problems has resulted in 302 rural clinics closing and an over-supply of workers in urban facilities” (Crigler, Boniface, and Shannon 2008). Rates of underemployment are high in urban areas in other countries as well. In Côte d’Ivoire, for instance, about 35 percent of doctors were underemployed while vacancy rates in rural areas remained signifi cant (Loukou and others 2006). Comparable rates have been found in Mali and Madagascar.

Figure 3.1 below illustrates how urban employment versus rural labor shortages can be explained by the economics of demand and supply side behavior of actors within the rural and

Page 20: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

12 World Bank Working Paper

urban health labor markets. The diff erences in demand and supply, as well as compensation in rural versus urban areas, are discussed in the remainder of this chapter.

Urban-rural differences in demand for labor

Evidence shows that demand for HRH is lower in rural areas than in urban ones. This means that, all other things equal, at any given compensation level, rural employers will employ fewer healthcare workers than their urban counterparts. One of the reasons for this situation is, that because of low employer income and limited progress in fi scal decentralization in many Sub-Saharan Africa countries, rural health facilities are struggling to receive adequate funding. In Benin, for example, less than 40 percent of regional credits allocated for rural health centers actually reached them; the balance remained at regional levels (World Bank 2003). Disproportionate allocation of public funds to district health authorities has also been observed in Zambia. This fi scal centralization, coupled with the abolishment of user fees in several countries, has limited the income of local health facilities and decreased their ability to hire healthcare workers. Such limitations on rural health facilities’ budgets means that the demand curve, representing the number of HRH that employers want and can aff ord, is farther to the le in rural markets than in urban markets. HRH funding shortages in rural areas are probably signifi cant factors explaining urban-rural imbalances.

Urban-rural differences in the supply of labor

The evidence suggests that the supply of labor is larger in urban areas than in rural areas, although not necessarily for all professionals. Some health workers are willing to work in rural areas given suffi cient compensation. Others (for example, doctors, people with children, and people originally from urban areas) are less willing to relocate to rural areas, even with a comprehensive incentive package. The motivation for working in rural areas is thus diff erent across subgroups of health workers. Graphically, this implies that the rural

Figure 3.1 Urban employment and rural shortage situation

Source: Authors.

Page 21: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 13

supply curve may be slightly to the le of the urban supply curve, especially for health workers that are less sensitive to compensation levels.

There is some evidence that lower-level professionals are more amenable to working in rural areas than higher-level professionals. A study in Ghana fi nds that some lower-level professionals appreciate the exposure to a wide range of pathologies that comes with rural service. The reasons cited for preferring rural areas include the fact that they are given duties above their skill level; bond more tightly with staff , facilitate on-the-job learning skills (such as surgery); have more opportunities to manage teams, allowing them to develop management and leadership skills; and have higher social recognition in villages (they are sometimes called doctor) and receive gi s (Lievens and others 2007).

Evidence also suggests that younger health workers may be more willing to work in rural areas than older workers. A study in Ethiopia tracking the graduating nursing class of 2004 fi nds that 34 percent of graduating nurses were willing to accept a rural placement in 2004; by 2007, this proportion had declined to 18 percent (Serneels et al. 2005). In Niger, young doctors cite lack of opportunities for postgraduate training as a key reason for not accepting rural positions (Souleymane et al. 2005). In contrast, older doctors cite weak remuneration as their main reason for not considering rural positions. Older doctors face a higher opportunity cost for moving to rural areas, as the reputation they have built in the city o en allows them to run a private practice. Anecdotal evidence from Benin and Niger indicates that doctors can more than double their salary by accepting private clients a er hours. Given that moonlighting can make up a signifi cant proportion of doctors’ incomes, moving to a rural area may indeed represent a considerable income decrease.

Evidence also points to a gender diff erence in willingness to work in rural areas, with men more willing to do so than women. Dussault and others (2006) suggest that female doctors are likely to live near their husband’s place of employment. In the Republic of Congo, as in many Sub-Saharan Africa countries, married couples are required by law to live together; providers assigned to rural areas, therefore, o en marry and move to the city to be with their spouses (Crigler, Boniface, and Shannon 2008). There is anecdotal evidence that once a woman is assigned to a rural job, she tries to get married quickly in order to move back to the capital.

For nonnative women without family or friends in the region, locating to a rural area without support or protections can also create safety concerns. A 2008 HRH assessment of the Republic of Congo fi nds that “rural se ings are also considered too dangerous for unaccompanied women, as they cannot ride buses by themselves or feel comfortable leaving their homes to work in the villages at night if needed. As more than 61 percent of health workers are women, this further complicates staffi ng rural regions” (Crigler, Boniface, and Shannon 2008). The fact that many female healthcare professionals come from more educated, elite, or urban backgrounds also makes them less likely to accept positions in rural or remote areas.

Evidence shows that health workers with rural or poor backgrounds are o en more willing to work in rural areas than those from urban or wealthier backgrounds. Data from Ethiopia indicates that health workers from rural areas or less well-off backgrounds are more motivated and willing to work in rural areas (Serneels et al. 2008). Some of the willingness of lower level or alternative professionals may stem from the fact that a greater proportion of such people have rural backgrounds.2 Some health workers may be willing to work in rural areas for altruistic reasons. Among both nursing and medical students in Ethiopia, the most frequently cited reason for seeking a rural placement is “to provide healthcare where it is needed most” (this reason was cited more o en by nursing students than by medical students; Serneels et al. 2005)—see fi gure 3.2. At the same time a follow-up cohort study three years later fi nds that altruism diminishes once workers gain experience and begin working as healthcare professionals (Serneels et al. 2008).

Page 22: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

14 World Bank Working Paper

Urban-rural differences in compensation

There is strong evidence that urban areas off er higher monetary and non monetary compensation than rural areas. A study on Ethiopia illustrates this and fi nds that monetary compensation levels for doctors and nurses in the capital city (Addis) and rural regions (Tigray and SNNPR) are signifi cantly diff erent (Jack 2008), with compensation much higher in urban areas (fi gure 3.1).

Various studies, including the World Health Report 2006 (WHO 2006), also document the lack of career-related incentives, such as professional development and training opportunities, in rural areas. Lower rural net incentives also refl ect the higher costs associated with working in rural areas. Inadequate management, lack of supplies, and

Figure 3.2 Reasons Ethiopian healthcare workers prefer working in urban areas

Source: Serneels et al. 2005

Figure 3.3 Compensation for doctors and nurses across regions in Ethiopia

Doctors Nurses

Source: Jack 2008

Page 23: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 15

heavy workloads are only some of the factors disproportionately evident in rural facilities. A study of the Republic of Congo fi nds that “this [urban-rural] imbalance has many causes, not the least [of which] is the diffi cult working conditions providers encounter in rural areas, such as lack of infrastructure, roads, electricity, water, and housing” (Crigler, Boniface, and Shannon 2008). Opportunities for education and jobs for spouses are also limited, increasing the costs of living in a rural area. Workers who transfer to rural areas also may have to rent a house in the city for their children who remain there.

Notes1 This low demand will depend on the employment arrangement in place in rural areas. This phenomenon will, of course, be present in decentralized systems, where rural health care facilities can directly recruit and pay some of their staff but have diffi culties doing so because of limited (or delayed) budget and revenues. Conversely, in countries where recruitment and payment of salaries are still fully centralized, there is no public rural employer as such. 2 A large body of evidence indicates that professionals from rural area are more likely than professionals from urban areas to se le in remote areas (see Rolfe and others 1995; Dunbabin and Levi 2003; Vries and Reid 2003). Easterbrook and others (1999) fi nd that Canadian physicians who were raised in rural communities were 2.3 times more likely than those from non-rural communities to choose to practice in a rural community immediately a er graduation.

Page 24: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

16

C H A P T E R 4

Policy Options for Addressing Urban-Rural Imbalances:

Theory and Evidence

A number of policies and interventions are available to policy makers to impact labor market dynamics and reduce geographical imbalances of health workers (table 4.1).

This chapter focuses on the supply side policy options to address rural/urban imbalances and includes a review of the experience of countries with policies and their impact on the rural/urban distribution of health workers in countries in SSA. For each policy category except increasing demand for health workers in rural areas— a detailed discussion of which is beyond the scope of this study—it reviews theoretical insights and the evidence of success and failure, including key factors for explaining possible impacts. The chapter shows that many SSA have a empted to correct the rural urban imbalance - some with success-, by directly infl uencing key labor market dynamics.

Table 4.1 Policy options for reducing urban-rural imbalances in HRH

Policy category Policy options

Increasing health worker demand in rural areas

Policy 1: Increase funding available to health centers so that they can hire more health workers (fi scal decentralization)

Reducing opportunity costs associated with rural jobs (through incentives)

Policy 2: Increase net compensation in rural areas (with a package consisting of both monetary and nonmonetary incentives)

Transferring urban health workers to rural areas through compulsory policies

Policy 3: Require graduates to complete a placement in rural areas (“bonding”)

Increasing the overall supply of health workers by scaling up education

Policy 4: Scale up education (by increasing the number of health graduates per institution or creating more institutions)

Improving rural orientation of existing education system (creating a “rural pipeline”)

Policy 5: Establish local schools for doctors and nurses in order to attract students from rural areasPolicy 6: Change curricula to better train students regarding clinical situations often experienced in rural areasPolicy 7: Implement a preferential admission policy in health schools in order to select more health workers with rural backgrounds (“rural pipeline”)

Creating alternative skill mixes for rural areas

Policy 8: Create alternative groups of professionals, such as midlevel professionals

Attracting health workers from abroad (through immigration policies)

Policy 9: Provide incentives or facilitate immigration for specifi c professions

Source: Authors.

Page 25: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 17

Increasing health worker demand

Although demand side policy options are not discussed in detail here, they do warrant a brief mention. A fi rst approach to strengthening the demand for health workers in rural areas is to increase the funding going to rural districts and facilities. This is increasingly done throughout SSA as more and more countries adopt and implement fi scal decentralization. Depending on the model adopted, funding for rural health workers wages is transferred to local governments in the form of block grants –as in Ethiopia and temporarily in Zambia- or earmarked transfers –as in Benin, Uganda and Mali -. In other countries funding for wages is directly transferred to facilities as in Rwanda. When the funds transferred are calculated in function of needs and poverty –needs based or equity formula- this contributes further to increasing demand for rural workers. (see Vujicic et al). A further and more extensive discussion of country experience with increasing demand in rural areas and information on some of the key successes and failures with doing so is beyond the scope of this study and will have to be addressed in future research.

Reducing the opportunity cost of rural employment: incentive policies

Increasing monetary and nonmonetary incentives is one of the most important policy options available to facilities or districts facing a shortage of HRH because they are unable to a ract health workers from urban areas. Direct fi nancial incentives include salaries, bonuses, hardship allowances, and any other monetary benefi ts. Indirect fi nancial incentives include loan repayment schemes; scholarships; allowances for childcare, housing, and children’s schooling; health insurance; benefi ts; travel subsidies; and the right to moonlight or maintain a private practice. Nonfi nancial incentives fall into three main categories: career-related incentives, such as professional development opportunities, training, and job security; incentives to improve the working environment, such as improved management, fl exibility, availability of supplies and equipment, and reduced workloads; and family and lifestyle incentives, such as increased vacation time, provision of housing, and spousal employment.

In many environments, changing the wage rate (direct fi nancial incentive) can be diffi cult, because wages may be set by the central ministry of health, frozen by budget constraints, or slow to respond to market forces. If wages cannot be changed, rural clinics must compensate by improving nonwage benefi ts, such as be er working conditions,

Figure 4.1 Effect of various incentives on probability of doctors and nurses accepting a post in a rural area

Doctors Nurses

Source: Jack 2008

Page 26: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

18 World Bank Working Paper

Box 4.1 Using discrete choice experiments to elicit health workers’ preferences regarding rural jobs

Stated preference methodologies include conjoint analysis, contingent valuation, and other techniques for assessing the utility of alternatives for individuals. These increasingly popular methodologies have been used in several countries, including Ethiopia, Indonesia, Malawi, and Niger, to elicit health workers’ preferences regarding rural jobs

In a discrete choice experiment, a sample of health workers is asked to choose between simple job descriptions, usually arranged in about 15 pairs (box table). Collected observations are then analyzed using econometric models. Figure 4.1 was produced through such a process.

Box table. Sample discrete choice set

Source: Mangham 2007

The effects of such incentive policies vary signifi cantly across professions (fi gure 4.1). Doubling pay increases the probability that a doctor accepts a rural job from 7 percent to 57 percent; doubling the pay of nurses increases the probability of accepting a rural job from 4 percent to 27 percent. Provisions of basic housing, reduced payback time, and (for nurses) improved supervision also have positive, albeit smaller, effects on the likelihood of choosing a rural post. These analytical results were obtained from a discrete choice experiment (box 4.1).

A discrete choice experiment is more powerful than a normal questionnaire for two reasons. First, people are not good at assessing their own preferences. They can rank them (to some extent) along an ordinal scale, but they have diffi culties assigning cardinal values to these preferences. For instance, given the choice among jobs located in the capital, 100 kilometers from the capital, and 200 kilometers from the capital, an individual could rank the choices ordinally; however, a mere ranking does not reveal the utility associated with each distance.

Second, even if individuals can estimate their utility on a cardinal scale, they will still have diffi culties assessing the tradeoffs between alternatives. A discrete choice experiment replicates actual choices and does not assume any ability of individuals to precisely estimate their preferences. It is currently the most reliable method for measuring tradeoffs and eliciting preferences.

Source: Authors

Page 27: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health W

orkers in Sub-Saharan Africa 19

Table 4.2 Examples of incentive programs implemented in Sub-Saharan Africa

Country Type of monetary IncentivesType of nonmonetary incentive

Health workers targeted Impact

Quality of evidence/source

Ghana Additional monthly allowance of 20–30 percent of base salary paid to health workers working in one of 55 deprived areas

None All health workers Unknown Low

(Dolea et al. 2008)

Mali Doctors setting up and maintaining a rural private practice receive fi nancial aid for purchasing housing and basic medical supplies, retain 50 percent of user fees, and receive a base salary from local communities of $200 a month

Private doctors receive technical support for preparing their business plans and strong clinical mentoring

Young and unemployed doctors

Strong Medium(Coulibaly et al. 2007)

Mauritania Additional monthly allowance equal to about half the base salary None All health workers Unknown Low(Sy and Hamed 2006)

Niger Additional monthly allowance of $40–$160 (7–30 percent of base salary)

None Doctors who are already civil servants

Weak High(Souleymane and others 2005, 2008)

Senegal Additional monthly allowance of $370 for doctors (equivalent to 75 percent of base salary) and $290 for nurses (equivalent to 100 percent of base salary)

Motorcycles given to nurses in some rural provinces

All doctors and nurses

Medium Low [[AQ: source for Senegal info?]]

South Africa Additional monthly allowance of 8–22 percent of base salary None Doctors and nurses Medium Medium(Vujicic and Lindelow forthcoming)

Tanzania Since 2005, all health workers willing to spend at least one year in a rural area may apply for a Mkapa fellowship

None All health workers Unknown Low(Merkle and Prytherch 2007)

Zambia Under the Zambian Health Workers Retention Scheme (ZHWRS), program participants receive additional monthly allowance of $250–$300 (equal to about half of base salary); end-of-contract bonus of $2,000–$2,500, paid upon satisfactory completion; allowance for purchasing basic medical supplies and equipment; $3,000 bonus for renovating a house; $1,500 annual subsidy for each child attending school; and preferred access to home and car loans

Preferred access to postgraduate education (if a doctor spends at least three years in a rural area) and clinical mentoring during installation of young doctors in rural areas

Doctors Strong Medium(Koot and Martineau 2005)

Source: Authors.

Page 28: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

20 World Bank Working Paper

Box 4.2 Using incentives to recruit rural doctors in Mali and Zambia

Rural private practices in MaliMali implemented a very innovative strategy to support young doctors in setting up rural private practices (Coulibaly and others 2007). Madagascar also recently implemented a similar program, about which little information is available. With the support of an NGO (Santé-Sud) and the Bamako medical faculty, young doctors interested in working in rural areas are identifi ed before graduation. Those that are interested receive help in preparing a business plan that is in line with the incomes of the targeted population. Once they start their business, these doctors benefi t from regular mentoring by seasoned doctors. They receive a small, fi xed amount of money ($200 a month) and, sometimes, a house from the community; most of their revenues come from user fees, half of which they are allowed to keep. Very active rural doctors can earn about $1,000 a month, not much less than they would earn in urban areas. Since 2000, more than 100 doctors have been attracted to and retained in rural areas thanks to this program.

The Zambian Health Workers Retention SchemeTo address the issue of uneven distribution of doctors throughout the country, Zambia developed a new policy in 2003 based on a comprehensive incentive package. The package, known as the Zambian Health Workers Retention Scheme (ZHWRS), includes both monetary and nonmonetary incentives. Monetary incentives included a monthly allowance of $250–$300 (equivalent to roughly 50 percent of base salary); an end-of-contract bonus of $2,000–$2,500, paid upon satisfactory completion; an allowance for purchasing basic medical supplies and equipment; a $3,000 bonus for renovating a house; a $1,500 annual subsidy for each child attending school; and preferred access to home and car loans. Nonmonetary incentives consisted of preferred access to postgraduate education (if a doctor stayed at least three years in a rural area) and clinical mentoring during installation. Even though some of these incentives were not fully implemented, the ZHWRS attracted more than 50 doctors in rural areas within the fi rst 14 months after implementation (Koot and Martineau 2005). The success of the program has prompted some hospital doctors to complain about the medical “brain drain” from urban to rural areas. The program, which was heavily subsidized by USAID, may not be sustainable, however.

Source: Authors

training opportunities, or lifestyle factors. Although the value of these a ributes is more diffi cult to quantify than wage a ributes, they are important levers in shaping workers’ satisfaction (Vujicic and Lindelow forthcoming).

The incentive package must be carefully selected for each country, profession, profi le, and circumstance. In Ghana, a focus group discussion reveals that a policy requiring a limited period of rural service together with rural incentives and a fi rm commitment to promotion a er rural service would be a strong incentive to some health workers (Lievens and others 2007). A study in Ethiopia (Jack 2007) fi nds that proportionate wage bonuses for rural service would probably increase rural labor supply (the eff ects appeared to be much larger for doctors than for nurses). For both doctors and nurses, superior housing and equipment signifi cantly increase the probability that a worker accepts a rural job (fi gure 4.1).

Country experiencesMost Sub-Saharan Africa countries that have implemented incentive policies have used both monetary and nonmonetary incentives. Incentive policies aiming at reducing the opportunity cost associated with rural employment are the most frequently used, with almost all Sub-Saharan Africa having tested at least one such type of incentive policy. The range of experiences is wide, ranging from very simple incentive schemes (in Niger or Mauritania) to comprehensive packages (in Zambia); see table 4.2.

Experience with incentives—which increasingly mix monetary and nonmonetary incentives—has generally been mixed, with successes occurring in Mali, South Africa, and

Page 29: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 21

Zambia (box 4.2).1 Niger’s fi nancial incentive program for doctors, for example, where one of the few truly prospective evaluations of an incentive program was carried out, had no signifi cant impact. The distribution of doctors remaining highly skewed to the benefi t of the capital city, with the percentage of all doctors working in the capital remaining virtually constant before and a er implementation of an incentive scheme (34 percent doctors in 2005, before the program was implemented, and 35 percent in 2008, a er it was implemented) (Souleymane et al. 2005, 2008).

Key success and failure factorsThe lack of success has generally been a ributed to the level of monetary and nonmonetary incentive, which was insuffi cient to outweigh the opportunity costs associated with se ling in rural areas. At a minimum, monetary incentives should off set the loss of private practice revenues (which are more diffi cult to generate in rural areas); the added cost of children’s education (as children usually live in the capital city, which entails transportation and lodging costs); and the loss of the spouse’s salary. Few programs analyzed these opportunity costs before se ing the level of fi nancial incentive, thus greatly increasing the chances of failure.

Younger doctors, who are usually unmarried, have no children, and lack enough experience to a ract private clients, may face lower opportunity costs. They also highly value opportunities for learning, including clinical mentoring and preferred access to postgraduate training. Such nonmonetary incentives have not been included in most incentive packages.

More research is needed to evaluate the outcomes of incentive programs on rural shortages. The best policies may well be those that successfully combine monetary and nonmonetary incentives. Most incentive programs have targeted only doctors; li le is known about their eff ect on other types of health workers. In situations where health workers are unresponsive to both monetary and nonmonetary incentives, other solutions (such as compulsory placement) may have to be considered.

Where incentives succeeded, their success was generally a ributed to the fact that the incentive packages comprehensively addressed the needs and opportunity costs of doctors. In Mali, the needs and constraints of the targeted group of doctors were well researched and understood. In Zambia, the incentive package was not only fi nancially a ractive, it also took into account all the various opportunity costs faced by rural staff (technical support, children’s education, housing, transportation, and so forth) and included nonmonetary incentives for expanding learning opportunities for young doctors. In both cases, preparatory analysis was conducted to evaluate the specifi c types of incentives needed to motivate specifi c subgroups of health workers before the programs were put into place.

Neither country used sophisticated techniques for eliciting health workers’ preferences. Instead, they adjusted their policy through a long process of trial and error. Other countries could avoid this costly and lengthy process by using state-of-the-art techniques, such as discrete choice experiment.

Success is also related to some contextual factors, notably the dynamics between urban and rural labor markets. A racting health workers to rural areas is easier when there is unemployment in urban labor markets—this factor may explain part of the success of the Malian experience. Because of fi scal constraints, the Malian government is able to hire only a small proportion of new medical graduates. As a consequence, there is a large pool of unemployed doctors in the capital city, Bamako. These underemployed doctors were explicitly targeted by the incentive program; many of them reacted favorably to the proposal to set up a private practice in a rural area.

Another contextual factor is the degree of decentralization in a given country. The Malian experience could not have been successful without the high degree of decentralization already achieved in the country. Local communities in Mali have substantial experience managing and outsourcing local services. Contracting private doctors was, thus, not a major challenge for these communities.

Page 30: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

22 World Bank Working Paper

Another possible issue relates to civil service regulation of compensation. In many Sub-Saharan African countries, governments are still the main employer of health workers, whose remuneration is usually defi ned by national and multisectorial salary scales. Ministries of fi nance are leery of rural incentives for health workers, fearing the risk of spillover eff ects. In Niger, for instance, as soon as the government agreed to implement incentives for doctors, other health workers asked for (and obtained) similar advantages. Spillover can also extend beyond the health sector, especially to education, as teachers share health workers’ reluctance to work in rural areas. Several countries are trying to overcome this constraint by creating health worker categories outside the civil service system (delinkage). Evidence on this policy is mixed, with successes in Rwanda and failures in Benin and Zambia.

Transferring urban health workers to rural areas through compulsory policies (bonding)

Health workers can be moved from urban areas to rural areas through compulsory placement policy, also known as bonding. Creating a period of obligatory rural service for graduating health workers is one way of bonding. This option falls outside of labor market theory, as labor is no longer a commodity that health workers are free to off er or not off er according to the compensation level.

Country experiencesMany Sub-Saharan Africa countries have implemented compulsory placement programs (table 4.3). Although such policies may temporarily reduce short-term shortages, they have had li le or no impact on long-term rural retention. Anecdotal evidence suggests that these programs are also diffi cult to enforce.2

Key success and failure factorsInteractions between policies and incentives may backfi re on bonding policies. In the early years of Thailand’s compulsory placement program, young doctors used the fi nancial benefi ts received from working in rural areas to pay the fi nes associated with not completing their obligatory rural service time (Wibulpolprasert and others 2003a). The unintended—and paradoxical—consequence of this rural policy package was that a signifi cant number of doctors le remote rural areas thanks to rural fi nancial incentives. Another fundamental factor in the failure of bonding policies is the fact that they do not compensate for the fi nancial and nonfi nancial opportunity costs borne by doctors serving in rural areas.

Sub-Saharan African countries that have this kind of policy have not been able to enforce it consistently. Most “displaced” health workers returned illegally to the capital city, sometimes a er bribing ministry of health offi cials. Such a policy cannot be easily implemented if there is no shortage of health workers in the urban market. Conversely, when a health worker surplus is experienced in urban markets, the opportunity cost of “displaced” health workers is signifi cantly lower.

Table 4.3 Compulsory programs implemented in selected Sub-Saharan Africa countries

Country Requirement

Ethiopia Compulsory periods of work in rural areas as a condition for obtaining medical degree

Ghana Compulsory two-year service in rural areas for new doctors entering civil service

Niger Compulsory three-year service in rural areas for new doctors entering civil service

Zambia Compulsory one-year placement of young doctors in rural areas

Zimbabwe Compulsory program for entering civil service

Source: Authors.

Page 31: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 23

Failure can also be a ributed to the lack of support of key stakeholder groups, associations, and health workers themselves. Doctors in Zimbabwe, for example, went on strike in response to compulsory placement policies requiring medical students to work two years in rural stations (Mutizwa-Mangiza 1998).

Increasing the overall supply of health workers by scaling up HRH education

Increasing the overall supply of health workers does not target urban-rural imbalances as such, and is thus not discussed in detail here. It may however increase the numbers of health workers working in rural areas. Indeed, increasing the overall supply of health workers may address the problem that even if there is suffi cient rural demand, and a potential willingness of some health workers to work in rural areas, the number of available health workers to spread into rural areas is simply too low. In theory, the more health workers there are, the larger the proportion willing to work in rural areas. To scale up the number of health workers, the capacity of the institutions that produce them must be scaled up as well. First assessments of current institutional and organization capacity must take place. To increase cost eff ectiveness relevant existing resources should be maximized. This includes faculty, material and infrastructural resources and systems that are currently producing well-qualifi ed health workers. However, it is important to examine innovative approaches and lessons learned from other health systems to help improve national health worker production capacity. Finally, many countries may fi nd that signifi cant investment in physical, information and communication infrastructures as well as in knowledge management systems is necessary and cost-eff ective in the long run. Governments might also fi nd that building partnerships across, institutions, sectors and borders is required to maximize the use of scarce resources and take advantage of learning from relevant experiences. (GHWA, 2008). On the whole thus, increasing the overall supply of health workers does not address rural-urban imbalances as such, but may increase the number of health workers that are available and willing to work in rural areas. It may thus be a policy option at least worth exploring as a requirement before designing other policies for addressing urban-rural imbalances.

Improving the rural orientation of the HRH education system

Rural pipeline policies combine several features to create a sustainable rural health workforce. Two education-related policy options address geographic imbalances. The fi rst involves targeting potential students with the profi le most likely to be amenable to rural postings (especially those with rural backgrounds)—by, for example, admi ing many more rural students to existing institutions or establishing new institutions in rural areas. The second involves changing the health education curriculum so that it is more relevant to rural healthcare and exposes students to rural environments as a part of their formal education.

Several countries have designed curricula that are more rural-friendly. Such curricula include compulsory internships in rural areas, more training on community or rural medicine, and general surgery. Equatorial Guinea launched a postgraduate program—Medecine General Integral (MGI)—in 2000, in cooperation with Cuba. Students receive in-depth training in all necessary fi elds to face the most commonly found situations in rural areas (pediatrics, internal medicine, general surgery, gynecology-obstetrics).

Rural pipeline policies can be made up of a combination of the following elements:

Admissions policies giving preference to or allo ing a specifi c number of slots to applicants from rural regions

Creation of regional rural medical and nursing schools Development of curricula with strong emphases on family or community medicine Compulsory rural internships Financial aid and scholarships for rural students Mentoring by experienced rural doctors for new health workers in rural areas.

Page 32: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

24 World Bank Working Paper

Country experiencesA few Sub-Saharan African countries have implemented rural pipeline programs. Benin created a regional medical school in 2001 that trains only general practitioners. Niger established two nursing schools in rural areas in 2006 and Mali xx schools since xxx. Senegal created a regional branch of the medical school in Dakar in 2008. Ethiopia has established nursing schools not just in the capital Addis Ababa, but also in the south and west of the country. South Africa experienced good results from a scholarship program that required rural students to return to their districts a er graduating.

Almost all empirical studies of such programs are from non-African programs (in Australia, Japan, Norway, Thailand, and the United States) where evidence of a strong impact is clear. Overall, rural pipeline programs in these countries have been very eff ective in a racting and retaining doctors in rural areas (see Murray and others 2006 and Rolfe and others 1995 for Australia; Rabinowitz 1999 and 2001 for the United States; Hsueh and others 2004 for Norway and Japan). Except in Thailand, none of these programs included a mechanism for obligating or creating special incentives to ensure that rural students returned to rural areas to work. Instead, most of the rural graduates chose to se le in rural areas, underscoring the potential power of the rural pipeline tool. South Africa has tested a rural scholarship program in the Mosvold district where scholarships are given to rural students on the condition that they return to their district a er graduation. Rural students receiving the scholarship were three to eight times more likely to practice in rural areas a er graduation. Such cross-national studies provide evidence that people with rural backgrounds are, indeed, not only more willing to work in rural areas but also more likely to do so voluntarily. Policies to recruit and train students from rural backgrounds are potentially a low-cost and sustainable part of the solution to the urban-rural gap in HRH.

Key success factorsResults from the most in-depth study of a rural pipeline program (Rabinowitz and others 2001) fi nd that a preferred admissions policy and a revised curriculum are the most relevant factors in a racting rural students and infl uencing their decision to later se le in rural areas of Pennsylvania, in the United States. Rural internships and fi nancial aid had li le impact on student decisions.

Creating alternative skill mixes in rural clinics

Highly trained health workers with many years of formal education, such as doctors, are the most diffi cult to recruit and retain in rural health clinics. Consequently, rural clinics and ministries of health are now training lower level professionals to take on some roles of doctors and nurses. Because they are recruited locally, such professionals are more likely to stay (Dovlo 1994). Such task shi ing does not increase the number of health workers in rural areas; rather, it increases the capacity to perform health interventions, which lies at the heart of the health worker shortage. Shi ing some tasks to lower or midlevel health workers, such as auxiliary professionals, nurses, or community health workers, through in-service training is increasingly hailed as a potential way to increase the number of personnel qualifi ed to carry out key health interventions in rural areas.

In principle, delegating additional tasks to lower level health workers is a feasible response to rural skills shortage. It can also serve as a key motivator by giving lower level workers more responsibility and scope for professional development, which may increase productivity and quality. Medical care knowledge and technology have evolved rapidly in recent years, allowing health workers without full medical training to perform some diagnoses and treatments that would have needed medical skills a few years ago.

There is much divergence across countries regarding which tasks it is acceptable for health workers of diff erent levels to carry out. It is imperative that strategies focus on

Page 33: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 25

Table 4.4 Skill mix programs in selected countries in Sub-Saharan Africa

Country Task shiftedTargeted professionals

Training and supervision arrangements Reference

Botswana Management of antiretroviral therapy

Nurses In-service training Miles and others (2007)

Cameroon Prevention of maternal-to-child HIV transmission services, including counseling, testing, and administration of nevirapine

Rural birth attendants

Ongoing supervision by nurses

Wanyu and others(2007)

Ethiopia Counseling and testing Community health workers

6-week in-service training

Mengistu (2008)

Ghana Management of childhood diseases

Community health nurses

11-day in-service training

WHO (2006)

Kenya Management of obstetrical complications

Nurses and clinical offi cers

In-service training Thairu and Schmidt (2003)

Malawi General surgery, including Caesarian sections (district-level)

Clinical offi cers 3 years Chilopora and others (2007)

Antiretroviral therapy initiation Nurses and community health workers

3-week intensive training

Philips (2008)

Mozambique General surgery, including Caesarian sections (district-level)

Medical assistants 3 years Vaz (1999); Pereira and others (1996)

Evaluation of patient eligibility for highly active antiretroviral therapy

Basic level nurses Standardized training on staging HIV–positive patients using CD4 counts and WHO criteria

Gimbel-Sherr and others (2007)

Rwanda HIV/AIDS services, including prescription of antiretroviral therapy

Nurses Ivers (2008)

HIV/AIDS services, including diagnosis of opportunistic infections associated with HIV/AIDS

Community health workers

Tanzania General surgery, including Caesarian sections (district-level)

Assistant Medical Offi cers

Mbaruku and Bergström (1995)

Source: Authors.

Page 34: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

26 World Bank Working Paper

matching the skills of workers to the local profi le of health needs. Although the objective of training lower and midlevel professionals to deliver health care at the community level is to eventually delegate to them work normally reserved for high-level professionals, all professionals should continue to provide care they are uniquely equipped to provide.

Country experiencesSeveral types of skills-expansion policies have been observed in Sub-Saharan Africa (table 4.4). These activities focus on increasing the skill sets of lower and midlevel professionals as well as higher-level professionals, such as general practitioners.

The experience with shi ing higher-skill tasks to lower-level professionals in rural areas has generally been successful. Alternative skill mixes can deliver positive results when they focus on a specifi c procedure, such as obstetrics or antiretroviral therapy. In Mozambique, the lack of doctors combined with the urgent need for emergency surgical care and skills for maternal health necessitated a reorientation of the training of health staff . A comparison of 1,000 consecutive Caesarean sections conducted by medical assistants, with the same number conducted by obstetricians and gynecologists, showed no diff erences in quality (Pereira and others 1996). In Malawi a 2007 study of more than 2,000 emergency obstetric operations performed by clinical offi cers found that postoperative outcomes were comparable to those performed by medical offi cers (Philips, Zachariah, and Venis 2008).

Key success and failure factorsAdequate training, monitoring, and support are key success factors of any alternative skill mix policy. Although concerns have been raised about the safety of services provided by lower and midlevel health workers, most of the evidence shows that, with appropriate training and support, such health workers can respond eff ectively to most emergency problems in general surgery and obstetrics.

There is li le empirical evidence of precisely how much support, monitoring, and supervision are required in alternative skill mix schemes. Some observers argue that the new task distribution must be institutionalized in order for the programs to be sustained or expanded. If, for example, nurses are given the task of managing antiretroviral therapy, as in Botswana, their new position should be clearly defi ned so that there is no ambiguity, and their performance should be closely monitored (Miles and others 2007).

Some observers argue that an alternative skill mix initiative that permits treatment where people otherwise would get none at all should be viewed positively (Philips, Zachariah, and Venis 2008). The overall, but limited, picture from studies to date indicates that alternative skill mix is a viable option to provide support to the overstretched healthcare systems in many African countries; although, it cannot complete solve the region’s human resources problem.

Another factor in determining the success of alternative skill mix initiatives is the choice of which professionals take on which tasks. Two considerations are crucial: the professional must be able to take on the additional workload, and the professional should be considered appropriate to taking on the task in view of the local community’s features and potential clients. The fi rst consideration demands that the current workload and potential for its increase be analyzed before deciding if an individual is able to take on the new task. In Lesotho, a focus group study found that many people with HIV/AIDS had had unsatisfactory experiences with nursing staff , which aff ected their willingness to receive treatment (Pa erson and others 2007). The participants in the study acknowledged that these experiences had occurred largely because the nurses were overworked and underpaid. The participants stated that they would be happy with nurses taking on additional tasks, such as prescribing antiretroviral treatment, as long as they received adequate clinical training and anti-stigma training.

Page 35: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 27

The clients’ perceived view of the nurses’ a itudes underscores the second consideration: the importance of taking account of local social factors when assigning roles to specifi c workers. In some communities, women may prefer to receive treatment from women.

Goodman and others (2006) raise the idea that, for simple public health interventions, tasks may even be shi ed to nonmedical professionals. Their study fi nds that a program that trained shopkeepers in Kenya to treat childhood fevers was both cost-eff ective and sustainable.

These fi ndings are consistent with those of other studies on the cost-eff ectiveness of alternative skill mix for the delivery of health services in both high-income and resource-constrained countries. Much of that evidence is from high-income countries; however, more work needs to be done to develop a clearer picture of these experiences in Sub-Saharan Africa. More studies are needed on the performance of lower-level professionals recently trained in higher-level interventions.

Attracting health workers from abroad (immigration policies)

Country-level shortages can be eliminated by encouraging the infl ow of foreign health workers. Sometimes, this can be a political arrangement or exchange. When giving them a choice, however, workers tend to go where working conditions are be er. Although income is an important motivation for migration, it is not the only one (fi gure 4.2). Other incentives include working conditions, career and training opportunities, and management quality. Political instability, war, and the threat of violence are also strong drivers of migration in many Sub-Saharan African countries. The reasons behind their migration serve as basis for creating contracts and incentive packages aimed at a racting health workers from abroad.

Several countries in SSA are already a racting immigrant health workers, formally and informally. Within Africa, migration is already common in some countries, particularly migration to Southern Africa (i.e., migration of Ethiopian and Cameroonian doctors to South Africa and Botswana). Furthermore, many West African countries have contracts with Cuba

Figure 4.2 Reasons for migration in Cameroon, South Africa, Uganda, and Zimbabwe

Page 36: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

28 World Bank Working Paper

for organizing extended stays of Cuban health workers in rural areas. Figure 4.3 shows that the number of Cuban doctors presently employed in Ghana has grown steadily since 1982, and today hovers around the 200 mark. Very li le is known on the impact of these contracts (Dussault and others 2006); however, Ghana emphasizes the commitment and dedication, as well as low cost, of Cuban health workers. Other countries hire immigrant health workers on a case-by-case basis.

An advantage that immigration policies have over education is their time frame. Immigration polices allow a much quicker response to national shortages than education policies, at least for most categories of health workers.

Notes1 In Mali, more than 100 doctors agreed to start private practices in rural areas (Coulibaly and others 2007). Under the South African Rural Allowance and Scarce Skills Allowance, 28–35 percent of rural health workers who received the 8–22 percent salary bonus believed it aff ected their career plans for the following year (Vujicic and Lindelow forthcoming). The Zambian Health Workers Retention Scheme a racted and retained more than 50 doctors in rural areas in less than two years (Koot and Martineau 2005).2 Zambia’s compulsory one-year placement of young doctors in rural areas was not strictly enforced; when it was, many doctors resigned rather than work in rural areas (Koot and Martineau 2005). One exception to enforcement failure can be found outside the African region: Thailand was successful in enforcing a comprehensive package of benefi ts and incentives for rural health workers as well as a rural pipeline program (Wibulpolprasert and others 2003b).3 In Nepal, a nationwide health worker surplus was intentionally created to overwhelm health labor markets. The underlying assumption was that such a policy would entail high unemployment in urban areas, which would create a natural incentive for health workers to move in rural areas. Evidence on results is scarce and, in most cases, disappointing.

Figure 4.3 Growth trend of Cuban brigade doctors present in Ghana

Page 37: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

29

C H A P T E R 5

Conclusion: A Roadmap for Policymaking

The eff ectiveness of a given policy option depends strongly on the country context and the way in which the policy is designed. A roadmap for policymakers can nevertheless

be proposed that may help them avoid major and costly blunders (fi gure 5.1).The fi rst step is to evaluate and address any imbalance caused by insuffi cient resources

(referred to here as a funding shortage). It is useless to try to a ract more health workers to rural areas if adequate budgetary allocations and fi nancial and management processes are not already in place with which to remunerate them. This step, which would increase

Figure 5.1 Policy roadmap for addressing urban-rural health workers imbalances

Is there a HW surplus on the urban labor market ?

2. Incentives (monetary and/or

non monetary)

YES

NO 4. Pre - service training

scaling up

9. Migration from abroad

5. Local medical and

nursing schools

3. Bonding

8. Alternative skill - mix

1. Strengthening rural demand

(fiscal decentralization)

7. Preferential admission policy

for rural candidates (rural pipeline)

6. Curriculum changes

toward rural needs

Is there a funding shortage in rural areas ?

YES

NO

STEP 1

STEP 2

SHORT - TERM OPTIONS

LONG - TERM OPTIONS

Is there a HW surplus on the urban labor market ?

2. Incentives (monetary and/or

non monetary)

YES

NO 4. Pre - service training

scaling up

9. Migration from abroad

5. Local medical and

nursing schools

3. Bonding

8. Alternative skill - mix

1. Strengtheningrural demand

(fiscal decentralization)

7. Preferential admission policy

for rural candidates (rural pipeline)

6. Curriculum changes

toward rural needs

Is there a funding shortage in rural areas ?

YES

NO

STEP 1

STEP 2

SHORT - TERM OPTIONS

LONG - TERM OPTIONS

Source: Authors

Page 38: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

30 World Bank Working Paper

rural demand for health workers, must be prioritized. This can be done through increased resources from governments as well as from users. Fiscal decentralization helps increase public resources for peripheral providers whether channeled directly to providers and combined with providers’ autonomy or as subsidies to demand side fi nancing, including health insurance or cash transfers. Private resources can also be used more effi ciently, for example, by pooling user payments into rural health insurance mechanisms that can contribute to increased utilization and, thus, resources for rural providers.

The second step is to address health workers’ willingness to work in rural areas. Choosing the right policy mix strongly depends on the labor market situation. Incentive and bonding policies are likely to be more eff ective if there is a surplus of health workers on the urban market and a pool of unemployed or underemployed health workers to draw from in urban areas. Consequently, an analysis of labor supply, rural and urban, is highly recommended before selecting the mix of policy options. (Appendix D provides a brief presentation of such an analysis.)

If health workers are available and underemployed and incentives or bonding policies emerge as promising options, policymakers must carefully estimate the opportunity costs associated with rural jobs. Many countries carry out feasibility studies in a very traditional way (that is, by administering a simple questionnaire). Stated preferences techniques (especially discrete choice experiment) are not more expensive and provide much more insight than traditional surveys. They should be carried out systematically before designing the package to a ract health workers to rural areas.

If there is no health worker surplus on the urban labor market, incentives and bonding is unlikely to work. In this case, education and alternative skill mix policies are probably the best solutions. Rural pipelines are o en needed to serve particularly remote and poor areas. Evidence from industrial countries suggests that this set of policies can have a strong impact. However, when alternative skill mix is implemented through in-service training, these policies are longer-term options. Creating midlevel professionals, such as medical or clinical offi cers, for example, requires waiting three or four years before the fi rst class graduates. As health workers will live in the system for many years, this also has long-term consequences on the type of health system that is developed.

Most policy options can be combined, especially to take into account the fact that some are short-term and others longer-term solutions. Niger started to prepare its policy in 2004–05, when it decided to scale up the production of surgeons. Given that the fi rst class would not graduate until 2008, two additional (short-term) policies were implemented: an incentive scheme for doctors and fast-track (one year) training in district surgery for a group of general practitioners. In Ethiopia, the recent scaling up eff orts supports a combination of short-term solutions. The rapid training of 30,000 health extension workers trained in one year is associated with the increase in production of medical offi cers trained in four years as well as the creation of new medical schools in rural areas.

Policy options can be evaluated on the basis of two criteria: ease of implementation and potential impact (table 5.1).

Because country-specifi c conditions o en dictate how policies work in practice, learning by doing is the best approach. Learning from experience requires the regular evaluation of the impact of implemented policies. Evidence on policy impact remains very limited in Sub-Saharan Africa. Enhancing data collection and analysis is a key priority for improving the geographical distribution of health workers within the region’s countries.

Page 39: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 31

Table 5.1 Policy options for reducing urban-rural gaps in HRH

Policy category Ease of implementation Potential impactIncreasing demand for health workers in rural areas

Requires an adequate fi scal space and, possibly, some fi scal decentralization

Strong if rural shortage is caused largely by funding shortage

Reducing opportunity costs associated with rural jobs (incentive)

May require some changes in civil service system (including delinkage); otherwise quickest policy to implement

Limited evidence; can have signifi cant impact if opportunity costs and preferences associated with rural jobs are correctly measured and there is health worker surplus in urban markets.

Transferring urban health workers to rural areas through compulsory policies

Stakeholders’ resistance is usually weak, because young health workers are targeted

Requires high governance level to ensure enforcement

Easier to implement if there is health worker surplus in urban markets

No success story in Africa, probably because of weak capacity for enforcement.

Increasing the overall supply of health workers by scaling up education

Adequate fi scal space needed, as well as detailed assessment of needs for HRH education capacity

Evidence lacking; impact on rural shortage possible if funding shortage is large and addressed at same time. Because of cohort effects, impact appears slowly.

Improving the rural orientation of the existing education system (“rural pipeline”)

Stakeholders may view policy as a “two-tier” system (urban health worker professionals versus rural health worker professionals); otherwise easy to implement

Evidence on success limited, but potential impact is probably strong, given experiences in industrial countries.

Creating alternative skill mixes for rural areas

Stakeholders may view policy as “two-tier” system

Evidence on impact compelling; can emerge quickly if alternative skill mix is created through in-service training.

Attracting health workers from abroad (immigration policies)

Usually the last-resort policy No evidence available; impact probably small.

Source: Authors.

Page 40: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 41: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

33

A P P E N D I X A

Countries Reviewed

Forty-six Sub-Saharan Africa countries were analyzed.

Some quantitative data on rural incentives found

Only anecdotal evidence on rural incentives found

No data on rural incentives found Not reviewed

Benin

Ethiopia

Ghana

Côte d’Ivoire

Madagascar

Malawi

Mali

Mauritania

Mozambique

Niger

Rwanda

Senegal

South Africa

Tanzania

Zambia

Angola

Equatorial Guinea

Lesotho

Namibia

Swaziland

Zimbabwe

Botswana

Burundi

Cape Verde

Djibouti

Eritrea

Gambia

Guinea Bissau

São Tome and Principe

Somalia

Uganda

Burkina Faso

Cameroon

Chad

Comoros

Congo, Dem. Rep. of

Congo, Rep. of

Gabon

Guinea

Kenya

Liberia

Mauritius

Nigeria

Seychelles

Sierra Leone

Sudan

TogoSource: Authors.

Page 42: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

34

A P P E N D I X B

The Lorenz Curve, the Concentration Index, and the Gini Coeffi cient

Economists use a variety of indicators to measure the concentration or equitable distribution of resources, including the Gini coeffi cient, the concentration index, and

the Lorenz curve. All three measures are used to measure equity, concentration, and the adequacy of targeted policy interventions.

The Lorenz curve

The Lorenz curve, generally used by economists to assess the equity of income distribution, is a cumulative frequency curve associated with the distribution of a specifi c variable (for

Figure B.1 Sample Lorenz curve

equal

distrib

ution

last 25%has 70% ofnationalincome

third 25%has 25% ofnationalincome

second 25%has 10% ofnationalincome

first 25%has 5% ofnationalincome

Cum

ulat

ive

% o

f inc

ome

Cumulative % of population

equal

distrib

ution

last 25%has 70% ofnationalincome

third 25%has 25% ofnationalincome

second 25%has 10% ofnationalincome

first 25%has 5% ofnationalincome

Cum

ulat

ive

% o

f inc

ome

Cumulative % of population Source: Authors

Page 43: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 35

example, income). It shows the proportion of the distribution of a variable associated with the bo om X percent of values over which it is distributed (for example, population) (fi gure B.1).

The equal distribution is represented by a diagonal line. On this line, 20 percent of the population receives 20 percent of income, 40 percent of the population receives 40 percent of the income, and so forth. This line represents the most equitable distribution of income across population. The more the Lorenz curve deviates from this line, the greater the inequity.

The Lorenz curve can be below or above the diagonal, depending on the variable. When the variable is valuable to the population—as, for example, in the case of income, expenditure on health or education, access to health services or to water—the curve is below the diagonal line. When the variable is detrimental to the population, as in the case of accidents, injuries, or deaths, the curve falls above the diagonal line.

The Concentration index

The concentration index summarizes the information presented by the Lorenz curve. The distance between the Lorenz curve (the observed distribution of the indicator) and the “ideal distribution line” represents the degree of inequality. The number measuring the area between the two lines thus summarizes the degree to which the distribution is equitable.

The concentration index formula calculates twice the area between the Lorenz curve and the line of inequality. It ranges in value from –1 to 1. By convention, the concentration index is negative when the Lorenz curve is above the ideal distribution line (representing an undesirable indicator variable) and positive when the Lorenz curve is below the ideal distribution line (representing a desirable indicator).

The Gini coeffi cient

The Gini coeffi cient is an index that ranges from 0 to 1. It can be calculated in various ways. A simple formula was elaborated by Brown (1994):

G X X Y Yk k k kk

n

= − − −− −=

∑| ( )( )|11 1

1

The fi rst step in calculating the Gini coeffi cient for HRH is to sort the geographic units by the health variable (for example, infant mortality rate) from the worst to the best situation (highest to lowest rate). The rates are then transformed into continuous variables and the cumulative proportion calculated for both variables. A fi gure showing the cumulative proportion for the health variable (Y-axis) and the cumulative proportion of the population (X-axis) is then prepared.

The Gini coeffi cient refl ects the level of equity of the distribution of a variable. Comparing Gini coeffi cients of diff erent distributions (say, over time) o en provides useful interpretation.

To estimate the Gini coeffi cient and graph the Lorenz curve, it is fi rst necessary to sort the health variable (infant mortality rate in India and Mali in fi gure B.2) from the worst situation (highest rate) to the best situation (lowest rate). The following steps are then taken for each country (or region within a country):

Estimate the under-fi ve mortality and live birth rates Calculate the percentage of the under-fi ve mortality rate and the percentage of

total live births observed in each population group ranked by wealth Calculate the cumulative percentage of each of the two variables for each group Calculate the Gini coeffi cient using the formula Graph the curve, using the X-axis for cumulative shares of live births by population

groups and the Y-axis for the cumulative shares of under-fi ve mortality rate

Page 44: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

36 World Bank Working Paper

If the under-fi ve mortality rate were completely independent of wealth, the lowest-earning 20 percent of the population of India would account for 20 percent of India’s under-fi ve mortality rate. In this case, the Lorenz curve for India would fall along the equal distribution line.

The concentration index approach can be used to measure the unequal distribution of health workers in urban versus rural areas. As the variable of interest is the distribution of healthcare workers, the number of healthcare workers is the indicator variable. Because of data availability, and because doctors and nurses are usually the most educated and skilled health professionals, the analysis was limited to doctors and nurses (analyzed separately). The regions of the country are ranked on a rural-urban scale, as approximated by the population density (population divided by area of the region); the lower the population density, the less urban the region.

The steps for estimating a Gini-like coeffi cient for the distribution of doctors across regions are as follows. First, the regions of the country are sorted on a rural-urban scale, as approximated by the population density (population divided by area of the region). Second, the following steps are taken for each region of the country:

Estimate the population Estimate the percentage of all doctors and the percentage of the population

observed in each region (ranked by population density) Estimate the cumulative percentage of each of the two variables for each region Use the Brown formula to estimate the Gini coeffi cient Graph the Lorenz curve, using the X-axis for cumulative population and the Y-axis

for the cumulative number of doctors

Figure B.2 Lorenz curve for under-fi ve mortality rate in India and Mali

Source: Wagstaff 2008

Page 45: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

37

A P P E N D I X C

Applying Labor Economics to Health Care

This appendix elaborates on the underlying analytical framework and the formalization of the dynamics behind labor market outcomes in three labor market situations. It then

focuses on urban versus rural labor market forces and dynamics.What is presented here is a generic and basic model built on a set of simplifying

assumptions. In practice, country- and case-specifi c labor market characteristics need to be taken into account in determining the menu of policy options. For example, if, for certain categories of health workers, the public sector is the sole employer, this should be taken into account, especially in any reservation wage analysis (that is, analysis of workers’ next best alternatives). In practice, there are cases in which it is diffi cult to get simple general results from purely theoretical models. In such cases, conclusions regarding the menu of policy options must rely on empirical analysis. The main objective here is not to provide policy recipes but to illustrate the interconnectedness between government measures and labor market outcomes (that is, who works where and under what conditions).

Economists view the functioning of labor markets as similar to any other market, in that the dynamics of supply and demand determine price (the wage, remuneration, or compensation rate) and quantity (the number of people employed or the number of hours worked). The framework used in this appendix is a basic classical labor market model suitable for policy design and analysis. In these models, labor markets are assumed to clear, either through a simplifying assumption that markets always converge to a situation in which the quantity of labor supplied equals the quantity of labor demanded, or, given enough time, through a phased process of adjustments in remuneration, which presumes that wages are free to change. In simple terms, this means that markets tend to move toward wages or compensation levels that balance the quantities of labor supplied and the quantities demanded, such that the market will eventually be cleared of all labor surpluses (excess supply) and shortages (excess demand).

In principle, when there is excess demand for doctors in rural areas (which creates a shortage), doctors’ wages or remuneration packages in rural areas should increase. This increase results in doctors already practicing in rural areas working more in the short run and new doctors entering the rural labor market in the longer run. In the short run, the adjustment mechanism clears the shortage, establishing a new equilibrium in the rural labor market. A similar mechanism operates when there is a labor market surplus. In this case, the wage (or the value of the remuneration package) declines to end the excess supply. As a result of the decline, doctors in rural areas work fewer hours or days of work in the short run and some of them exit the rural labor market in the longer run.

This model assumes freely operating labor markets without imperfections or rigidities. Without these assumptions, “sticky” wages might be observed and markets will not necessarily clear. Some economists a ribute what appear to be labor market imbalances to factors such as government policy, labor unions, and the like. Although not all economists adhere to the classical labor market model, many economists consider wage fl exibility as

Page 46: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

38 World Bank Working Paper

a plausible assumption for policy design and analysis, arguing that wages are not sticky forever.

In the health sector, the labor market is the economic space in which health workers sell their skilled labor and employers buy skilled labor. This market is made up of the supply of health workers (the number of health workers willing to work at various compensation levels) and the demand for health workers (the number of workers employers are willing and able to hire at various compensation levels). The interplay between supply and demand should determine the compensation level within a labor market.

Compensation is a multidimensional concept that takes into account many monetary and nonmonetary factors. Monetary compensation may be direct or indirect. Direct fi nancial or monetary compensation is paid as a wage or salary, a fi nancial bonus (for good performance or as an incentive to serve in a rural area), or as part of a supplementary income scheme. Indirect fi nancial compensation off ers goods and services that would otherwise have to be paid for. Examples include scholarships and loan repayments, childcare, housing, cars and motorcycles, health insurance, and education. Nonfi nancial compensation refers to benefi ts that could not be paid for but are nonetheless considered valuable. Such compensation can be related to career (on-the-job training, experience, professional development opportunities, job security, career advising, networking); the working environment (availability of supplies, equipment, technology, be er infrastructure, reduced workload, a fl exible schedule); or lifestyle and family life (vacation time, opportunities for spousal employment). Keeping in mind these many forms of compensation is vital when reviewing policy options.

Compensation refers to net compensation—the diff erence between the gross (monetary plus nonmonetary) compensation and the costs associated with a particular job that are borne by the employed individual. For example, doctors in rural areas may bear additional monetary and nonmonetary costs—such as having to pay for children’s private schooling (because rural public schools are of a lower quality than urban schools) or having to pay both their own rural housing and urban housing for children who remain in the city to study; forgone opportunities for professional development; and forgone amenities available only in urban areas and proximity to family in the city. Net compensation compares costs and benefi ts, creating a more accurate picture of the choices facing health workers.

Economists argue that the supply side of the health labor market is determined by the number of health workers available (the health labor force) and their willingness to work at various compensation levels. Because many workers are willing to work at a high compensation levels and few are willing to work at low compensation levels, the market supply curve is always upward sloping.

The demand for health labor is determined by the number and the size of employers and their willingness to hire health workers at various compensation levels. Because employers hire only a few workers at a high compensation level but many workers at a low compensation level, the demand curve is always downward sloping (demand in the economic sense is distinct from demand in the social welfare sense, where it refers to the number or healthcare workers needed to address all health care concerns). Demand is determined by the desire, ability, and willingness of employers to pay for providers of health-related services. Healthcare that is desired but cannot be paid for is not considered part of demand and does not aff ect the health labor market.

Market-clearing equilibrium, unemployment, and labor shortages

The classical labor market model assumes that all markets ultimately clear. Key assumptions underlying this model are that compensation levels are allowed to fl uctuate (for example, they are not fi xed by the government or trade unions); that people are free to work or not; and that accurate information is available to both employers and workers about labor market conditions. Failure to meet these conditions must be taken into account in cra ing policy.

Page 47: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 39

At the market-clearing equilibrium, the quantity of labor supplied equals the quantity of labor demanded. In other words, employers are willing to employ LaborMC units of labor, and employees are willing to off er LaborMC units of labor at CompMC level of compensation (fi gure C.1).

The situation in which the quantity of labor supplied exceeds the quantity of labor demanded is referred to as unemployment. If the compensation level were higher, the quantity of labor supplied would exceed the quantity of labor demanded, as more people would be willing to work for a high compensation level but employers would be willing to hire fewer employers.

A situation in which more labor is demanded than is supplied is called a labor shortage. When the compensation level is set below the market-clearing level—say, at, CompLS—employers will want to hire workers, but only be willing to work for such a low compensation (fi gure C.3).

When the assumptions of the classical labor market model are met, the unemployment and labor shortage situations will move to the market-clearing situation over the long run. When compensation is higher than the market-clearing compensation level, some unemployed workers in the labor market will begin to off er their labor for a lower compensation level, which is benefi cial to employers; in this way, the compensation level will be driven downwards toward CompMC. When the compensation level is lower than the market-clearing compensation level, employers will off er a higher compensation in order to a ract workers unwilling to work for CompLS. People previously unwilling to work at CompLS or people entering the labor market will increase the supply of labor until the market-clearing situation is reached.

The economics of urban versus rural labor marketsNon-market-clearing labor markets can persist in the long run when the classical labor market model assumptions are not met. Market distortions take diff erent shapes. Trade unions, minimum wage regulation, government pay policies, multinational corporations’

Figure C.1 Market-clearing equilibrium

Source: Authors

Page 48: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

40 World Bank Working Paper

Figure C.2 Unemployment

Source: Authors

Figure C.3 Labor shortage

Source: Authors

Page 49: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 41

pay policies, and labor codes may keep compensation levels higher than CompMC. Both unemployment and labor shortages are undesirable. Unemployed workers represent a major ineffi ciency in a country’s labor market. Shortages in rural areas mean that clients do not receive the health services they are willing to pay for.

In most instances in Sub-Saharan Africa, the urban market is in unemployment or at best at a market-clearing equilibrium (although, occasionally, in a shortage situation); rural areas are o en in shortage situations. As a result, the urban and rural markets together are

Figure C.4 Urban employment and rural shortage situation

Source: Authors

Figure C.5 Urban and rural HRH markets with improved information

Source: Authors

Page 50: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

42 World Bank Working Paper

usually in one of three diff erent situations: urban unemployment equals rural shortage (fi gure C.4), urban unemployment is greater than rural shortage, or urban unemployment is less than rural shortage.

Market distortions of all kinds can cause markets to fail to clear. An urban surplus of health workers may not equilibrate in the long run with a rural defi cit of health workers because of market imperfections, such as lack of information. In practice, most urban workers remain uninformed about compensation and vacancies in rural areas, making them less likely to move there. A more eff ective system to communicate information regarding vacancies would increase the rural supply of labor. Increased information translates into an outward shi in the rural supply curve, along with an inward shi in the urban supply curve, which would increase the rural labor force and employment while decreasing urban unemployment (fi gure C.5).

Page 51: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

43

A P P E N D I X D

Health Labor Market Analysis

Vujicic and Zurn (2006) provide a useful framework for analyzing the supply of labor. The main idea is that HRH density can be seen as the outcome of a complex process

that begins with the education of high school students and ends in the employment of health workers (fi gure D.1). Many possible leakages prevent a country with an adequate education system from obtaining the needed density of health workers.

Until recently, most HRH country analyses focused on only two boxes in fi gure D.1: HRH education capacity and the number of health workers employed in the public sector. For be er understanding of the HRH situation of a given country, leakage sources—particularly migration trends, underemployed workers, and private sector workers—have to be measured and, if possible, addressed. Exploring these categories of health workers is especially diffi cult, but some rigorous analyses have been conducted (see Côte d’Ivoire for underemployment and private sector; see Ghana for migration trends).

Figure D.1 Health labor market analysis: a country example (for doctors)

Source: Vujicic and Zurn 2006

Page 52: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 53: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

45

References

Adkins, . 1987. “Geographic and Specialty Distributions of WAMI Program Participants and on Participants.” Journal of Medical Education 62: 810–17.

Anand, S., and T. Baernighausen. 2004. “Human Resources and Health Outcomes: Cross-Country Econometric Study.” Lancet 364 (9445): 1603–9.

Bergström, S. 2005. “Who Will Do the Caesareans When There is No Doctor? Finding Creative Solutions to the Human Resource Crisis.” BJOG: An International Journal of Obstetrics and Gynaecology 112 (9): 1168–69.

Black, Richard. 2003. “Where and Why Are 10 Million Children Dying Every Year?” Child Survival Series. Lancet 361: 2226–34.

Bolduc, Denis. 1996. “The Eff ect of Incentive Policies on the Practice Location of Doctors: A Multinomial Probit Analysis.” Journal of Labor Economics 14 (4): 703–32.

Butera, Damascene, John Vincent Fieno, Suzanne Diarra, Gilbert Kombe, Catherine Decker, and Soumahoro Oulai. 2005. Assessment of Human Resource Requirements to Deliver the President’s Emergency Plan for AIDS Relief and Other Basic Health Services in Côte d’Ivoire. July. Partners for Health Reformplus Project, Abt Associates, Inc. Bethesda, MD.

Chilapora, G. 2007. “Postoperative Outcome of Caesarean Sections and Other Major Emergency Obstetric Surgery by Clinical Offi cers and Medical Offi cers in Malawi.” Human Resources for Health 5 (17).

Chomitz, Kenneth. 1998. “What Do Doctors Want? Developing Incentives for Doctors to Serve in Indonesia’s Rural and Remote Areas.” Policy Research Working Paper 1888, World Bank Washington, DC.

Coulibaly, S.. 2007. “Une médecine rurale de proximité: l’expérience des médecins de campagne au Mali.” Education for Health 20 (2):

Courtney, M., H. Edwards, S. Smith, and others. 2002. “The Impact of Rural Clinical Placement on Student Nurses’ Employment Intentions. “ Collegian 9: 12–18.

Crigler, Lauren, Sebikali Boniface, and Salentine Shannon. 2008. “Human Resource and Quality Rapid Assessment.” Republic of Congo, March 27.

Dambisya, Yoswa. 2007. A Review of Non-Financial Incentives for Health Worker Retention in East and Southern Africa. Equinet Discussion Paper 44,

Desplats, D., Y. Koné, and C. Razarkisan. 2004. “Pour une médecine communautaire en première ligne.” Med Trop 64: 539–44.

Dolea, Carmen. 2009. “Increasing Access to Health Workers in Remote and Rural Areas Through Improved Retention.” Background paper for the fi rst expert meeting to develop evidence-based recommendations to increase access to health workers in remote and rural areas through improved retention, World Health Organization, Geneva, February 2-4.

Dovlo, Delanyo. 2004. “Using Mid-Level Cadres As Substitutes for Internationally Mobile Health Professionals in Africa. a Desk Review.” Human Resources for Health 2: 7.

Dunbabin, J. S., and L. Levi L. 2003. “Rural Origin and Rural Medical Exposure: Their Impact on the Rural and Remote Medical Workforce in Australia. Rural Remote Health 3: 212.

Page 54: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

46 World Bank Working Paper

Dussault, G. 2006. “Not Enough There, Too Many Here: Understanding Geographical Imbalances in the Distribution of the Health Workforce.” Human Resources for Health 4: 12.

Easterbrook, Mark. 1999. “Rural background and clinical rural rotations during medical training: eff ect on practice location.” Canadian Medical Association Journal 160: 1159–63.

Ferrinho, Paolo. 2007. “Human Resources Function in the Health Sector in Guinea-Bissau.”

Fileds, Gary, and Mabel Andalón. 2008. “A Toolkit for Analyzing Labor Markets in the Health Care Sector in Africa.” January.

Freedman, L. P. 2002. “Shi ing Visions: “Delegation” Policies and the Building of a ‘Rights-Based’ Approach to Maternal Mortality.” Journal of the American Medical Women’s Association 54 (3): 154–58.

Fryer, George. 2002. “The Association of Title VII Funding to Departments of Family Medicine with Choice of Physician Specialty and Practice Location.” Family Medicine 34 (6): 436–40

Furth, R. 2006. “Zambia Performance-Based Incentives Pilot Study.” Initiatives Inc. and USAID.

Gimbel-Sherr, Sarah. 2007. “Using Nurses to Identify HAART Eligible Patients in the Republic of Mozambique: Results of a Time Series Analysis.” Human Resources for Health 5: 7.

Goodman, Catherine. 2006. “The Cost-Eff ectiveness of Improving Malaria Home Management: Shopkeeper Training in Rural Kenya.” Health Policy and Planning 21 (4): 275–88.

Herbst, C., and D. Gij sbre ts. 2007. Comprehensive and Accurate Information on Health Worker Stock, Profi les and Distribution in Zambia: Analysis of the JICA Data. Dra report.

Hounye, F. 2007. Mécanismes incitatifs a l’exercice du personnel de santé en zone déshéritées et/ou enclavées. January, fi nal report, Ministry of Health, .

Hsueh, Wayne. 2004. “What Evidence-Based Undergraduate Interventions Promote Rural Health?” New Zealand Medical Journal 117 (1204).

Ivers, Louise. 2008. “Task-Shi ing in Delivery of HIV Care.” December. Jack, William. 2008. Human Resources for Health in Ethiopia. Summary Report, February. Kakwani Nanak, Adam Wagstaff , and Eddy Van Doorslaeff . 1997. “Socioeconomic

Inequalities in Health: Measurement, Computation, and Statistical Inference.” Journal of Econometrics 77 (1): 87–103.

Klemick Heather. 2007. “Doctor Quality, Roads and Patient Access to Health Care in Rural Tanzania.” Working paper, University of Maryland.

Koot, J., and T. Martineau. 2005. Mid-Term Review of the Zambian Health Workers Retention Scheme. ZHWRS) 2003–2004.

Koot J., V. Mukonka, J. Oosterhoff , and C. Simutowe. 2003. Supplementation Programme Dutch Medical Doctors 1978–2003: Lessons Learned and Retention Scheme Zambian Medical Doctors 2003–2006.

Kotzee, T., and I. D. Couper. 2006. “What Interventions Do South African Qualifi ed Doctors Think Will Retain Them in Rural Hospitals of the Limpopo Province of South Africa?” Rural and Remote Health 6: 581.

Kruk, M. 2007. “Economic Evaluation of Surgically Trained Assistant Medical Offi cers in Performing Major Obstetric Surgery in Mozambique.” British Journal of Obstetrics and Gynecology 114: 1253–60.

Kurowski, Christoph, Kaspar Wyss, Salim Abdulla, and Anne Mills. 2004. “Human Resources for Health: Requirements and Availability in the Context of Scaling-Up Priority Interventions in Low-Income Countries. Case Studies from Tanzania and Chad.” HEFP Working Paper 01/04, Health Economics and Financing Programme, Department of Public Health and Policy, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine.

Page 55: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 47

Lee, S., and L. Mackenzie. 2003. “Starting Out in Rural New South Wales: The Experiences of New Graduate Occupational Therapists.” Australian Journal of Rural Health 11: 36-43.

Lehmann, Utah. 2008. “Staffi ng Remote Rural Areas in Middle and Low-Income Countries: A Literature Review of A raction and Retention.” BMC Health Services Research 8: 19.

Lemiere Christophe. 2008. “The Benin Health Workforce: A Labor Market Analysis.” Leonard, Kenneth, G. R. Mliga, and D. Haile Mariam. 2003. “Bypassing Health Centers

in Tanzania: Revealed Preferences for Quality.” Journal of African economies 11 (4): 441–71.

Lin, Y., and L. M. Franco. 2000. Assessing Malaria Treatment and Control at Peer Facilities in Malawi. Quality Assurance Project: Case Study. U.S. Agency for International Development. (USAID) by the Quality Assurance Project (QAP) Bethesda, MD.

Lievens, Tomas. 2007. Ghana Health Worker Study.Loukou, Dia. 2006. “Recensement du personnel médical au chômage en Côte d’Ivoire.”

November. Maestad, O. 2006. Human Resources for Health in Tanzania: Challenges, Policy Options and

Knowledge Gaps. CMI ReportMangham, Lindsay. 2007. “Addressing the Human Resource Crisis in Malawi’s Health

Sector: Employment Preferences of Public Sector Registered Nurses.” ESAU Working Paper 18, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Mbaruku, G. , and S Bergström. 1995. “Reducing Maternal Mortality in Kigoma, Tanzania.” Health Policy and Planning 10 (1): 71–8.

Mengistu, Samuel. 2008. “Task Shi ing in HIV Counseling and Testing: Experience from Ethiopia.” January 22, JHPIEGO/Ethiopia,

Merkle, Ricarda, and Helen Prytherch. 2007. “Initiatives Addressing Human Resource for Health in the United Republic of Tanzania.” Bulletin von Medicus Mundi Schweiz 104 (May).

Miles, K. 2007. “Antiretroviral Treatment Roll-Out in a Resource-Constrained Se ing: Capitalizing on Nursing Resources in Botswana.” WHO Bulletin 85: 557.

Miti, S. K. 2006. “Migration, Retention and Return of Health Professionals. The Zambian Case. The Challenge of Managing a Health Care System in Crisis.” Presentation at the Health in Foreign Policy Forum.

Mullan, F. and S. Frehywot. 2007. “Non-Physician Clinicians in 47 sub-Saharan African Countries.” Lancet 370 (9605): 2158–63.

Munga, A Michael, and Masetad, O ar. 2009. Measuring inequalities in the distribution of health workers: The case of Tanzania. Human Resources for Health, 2009, 7:4.

Murray, Richard, and Ian Wronski. 2006. “When the Tide Goes Out: Health Workforce in Rural, Remote and Indigenous Communities.” Medical Journal of Australia 185 (1): 37–38.

Pa erson, Jacqueline. 2007. “Building Healthy Communities: The Views of People Living with HIV in ‘Task Shi ing’ and Health Systems Strengthening. Findings from a Five-Country Consultation.” Health Global Access project, November 26.

Pereira, C. 1996. “A Comparative Study of Caesarean Deliveries By Assistant Medical Offi cers and Obstetricians in Mozambique.” British Journal of Obstetrics and Gynecology 103 (6): 508–12.

Pereira, C., A. Cumbi, R. Malalane, F. Vaz, C. McCord, A. Bacci, and S. Bergström. 2007. “Meeting the Need for Emergency Obstetric Care in Mozambique: Work Performance and Histories of Medical Doctors and Assistant Medical Offi cers Trained for Surgery.” British Journal of Obstetrics and Gynecology.

Philips, M., R. Zachariah, and S. Venis. 2008. “Task Shi ing for Antiretroviral Treatment Delivery in Sub Saharan Africa: Not a Panacea.” Lancet 371 (9613): 682–84.

Page 56: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

48 World Bank Working Paper

Picazo, Oscar. 2008. “Struggling and Coping to Serve: The Zambian Health Workforce as Depicted in the Public Expenditure Tracking and Quality of Service Delivery Survey, 2006.” World Bank, Africa Region, Human Development 1, Country Department 2, Washington, DC.

Playford, D., A. Larson, and B. Wheatland. 2006. “Going Country: Rural Student Placement Factors Associated with Future Rural Employment in Nursing and Allied Health.” Australian Journal of Rural Health 14 (1): 14–19.

Rabinowitz, Howard. 1999. “A Program to Increase the Number of Family Physicians in Rural and Underserved Areas: Impact a er 22 years.” Journal of the American Medical Association 281 (3): 255–60.

Rabinowitz, Howard. 2001. “Critical Factors for Designing Programs to Increase the Supply and the Retention of Rural Primary Care Physicians.” Journal of the American Medical Association 286 (9).

Reid, S. 2004. Monitoring the Eff ect of the New Rural Allowance for Health Professionals. Health Systems Trust, Durban, South Africa.

Rolfe, I. E., S. A. Pearson, D. L. O’Connell, and J. Dickinson. 1995. “Finding Solutions to the Rural Doctor Shortage: the Rules of Selective Versus Undergraduates Medical Education at Newcastle.” Australia and New Zealand Journal of Medicine 5: 512–7.

Sanders, D. J. , S. Kravitz, S. Lewin, and M. McKee. 1998. “Zimbabwe’s Hospital Referral System: Does It Work?” Health Policy and Planning 13 (4): 359–70.

Serneels, Peter. 2005. “For Public Service or Money: Understanding Geographical Imbalances in the Health Workforce.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3686, Washington, DC.

Serneels, Peter. 2008. Discovering the Real World: Health Workers’ Early Work Experience and Career Choice.

Souleymane. 2005. Etude sur la motivation des personnels de santé à servir en périphérie in Niger. July.

Souleymane. 2008. “Impact des mesures d’incitation fi nancière accordées aux médecins, pharmaciens et chirurgiens dentists in Niger.” Impact of Financial Incentives for Doctors, Pharmacists and Dentists in Niger July.

Sy, Aly, and Mohamed Hamed. 2006. “Etude sur les primes de zone et de technicité.” Ministry of Health and World Bank.

Thairu, A., and K. S midt. 2003. “Training and Authorizing Mid-Level Providers in Life-Saving Skills in Kenya.” In Sandra Crump, ed., Shaping Policy for Maternal and Newborn Health: A Compendium of Case Studies. Baltimore, MD: JHPIEGO.

Van Dormael, Monique. 1997. “La médecine coloniale, ou la tradition exogène de la médicine moderne dans le Tiers Monde.” Studies in Health Services Organisation & Policy 1.

Vaz, F. , S. Bergström, M. Vaz, J. Langa, and A. Bugalho. 1999. “Training Medical Assistants for Surgery. Policy and Practice.” Bulletin of the World Health Organization 77(8): 688–91.

Vries, Elma De, and Steve Reid. 2003. “Do South African Rural Origin Medical Students Return to Rural Practice?” Health System Trust Paper, May.

Vujicic, Marko, and Magnus Lindelow. Forthcoming. Approaches to Reduce Health Worker Shortages in Remote Areas: A Global Review of Recruitment and Retention Policies. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Vujici Marko, and Pascal Zurn. 2006. “The Dynamics of Health Labor Market.” International Journal of Health Planning and Management 21 (2): 101–15.

Wanyu, B. . “Birth A endants Trained in Prevention of Mother-to-Child HIV Transmission Provide Care in Rural Cameroon, Africa.” Journal of Midwifery and Women’s Health 52 (4).

Wibulpolprasert, Suwit. 2003a. “Inequitable Distribution of Doctors: Can It Be Solved?” Human Resources Development Journal 3 (1): 2–22.

Page 57: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa 49

———. 2003b. “Integrated Strategies to Tackle the Inequitable Distribution of Doctors in Thailand: Four Decades of Experience.” Human Resources for Health I: 12.

World Bank. 2003. Benin: Pour une plus grande effi cacité de la dépense publique: Examen de trois secteurs clés. Report 29656-BEN, December 20.

WHO (World Health Organization). 2006. The World Health Report 2006: Working Together for Health. Geneva: WHO.

———. 2008. Task Shi ing: Rational Redistribution of Tasks among Health Workforce Teams: Global Recommendations and Guidelines. Geneva: WHO.

Page 58: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

50 World Bank Working Paper

Eco-AuditEnvironmental Benefi ts Statement

The World Bank is commi ed to preserving Endangered Forests and natural resources. We print World Bank Working Papers and Country Studies on postconsumer recycled paper, processed chlorine free. The World Bank has formally agreed to follow the recommended standards for paper usage set by Green Press Initiative—a nonprofi t program supporting publishers in using fi ber that is not sourced from Endangered Forests. For more information, visit www.greenpressinitiative.org.

In 2008, the printing of these books on recycled paper saved the following:

Trees* Solid Waste Water Net Greenhouse Gases Total Energy

289 8,011 131,944 27,396 92 mil.*40 feet in height and

6–8 inches in diameter

Pounds Gallons Pounds CO2 Equivalent BTUs

Page 59: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization
Page 60: Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub ... · in Sub-Saharan Africa and their development partners, especially the World Bank and the World Health Organization

Reducing Geographical Imbalances of Health Workers in Sub-Saharan Africa

is part of the World Bank Working Paper series. These papers are published to

communicate the results of the Bank’s ongoing research and to stimulate public

discussion.

This paper discusses and analyzes labor market dynamics in Sub-Saharan Africa

and outcomes (including unemployment, worker shortages, and urban-rural

imbalances of categories of health workers) from a labor economics perspective.

This analysis reviews the experience of many Sub-Saharan African countries

and is the basis for elaborating policy options that incorporate the underlying

labor market forces to address undesirable outcomes such as the urban-rural

imbalance more effectively. The conclusions are relevant to researchers, policy

analysts, and policy makers with an interest in understanding and improving the

allocation of human resources for health in the developing world.

This working paper was produced as part of the World Bank’s Africa Region

Health Systems for Outcomes (HSO) Program. The Program, funded by the

World Bank, the Government of Norway, the Government of the United

Kingdom and the Global Alliance for Vaccines and Immunization (GAVI),

focuses on strengthening health systems in Africa to reach the poor and achieve

tangible results related to Health, Nutrition and Population. The main pillars

and focus of the program center on knowledge and capacity building related to

Human Resources for Health, Health Financing, Pharmaceuticals, Governance

and Service Delivery, and Infrastructure and ICT. More information as well

as all the products produced under the HSO program can be found online at

www.worldbank.org/hso.

World Bank Working Papers are available individually or on standing order. The

World Bank Working Papers series is also available online through the World

Bank e-library (www.worldbank.org/elibrary).

SKU 18599

ISBN 978-0-8213-8599-9

THE WORLD BANK1818 H Street, NW

Washington, DC 20433 USA

Telephone: 202 473-1000

Internet: www.worldbank.org

E-mail: [email protected]