Public Economies

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    1/30

    Public Economics

    Paper 7

    Lecture 3

    Multi-dimensional policy spaces and the

    Probabilistic Voting Model

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    2/30

    Outline

    Critique of the median voter model

    The probabilistic voting model

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    3/30

    The Median Voters Theorem

    The two parties will propose the same platform

    and that platform is equal to the

    most-preferred policy of the median voter.

    A Condorcet Winner

    A policy that beats all others in

    a pair-wise comparison.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    4/30

    When does a Condorcet winner

    exist? The policy space has one dimension.

    Voters have single peaked preference

    over policy along that one dimension.

    Each voter has a most-preferred policy and the

    further the policy is away from this ideal point

    the worse.

    g

    )(gWi

    (size of government)Ideal point

    Single peaked.

    Not single peaked.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    5/30

    More policy dimensions

    A Condorcet winner will not exist in

    general.

    Policy instability and cycles.

    Chaos

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    6/30

    The logic of chaos

    Two public goods, g and h.

    Each voter has an ideal point ),(**

    ii hg

    g

    h

    *

    ig

    *

    ih

    Ideal point

    Indifference

    curve

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    7/30

    g*

    1g

    *

    1

    *

    2hh

    h

    *

    2g

    *

    3h

    *

    3g

    A

    Win set 12

    1

    3

    2

    B

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    8/30

    The Chaos Theorem(McKelvey, Journal of Economic Theory, 1976)

    When there are at least two issues and at least three

    voters every platform can be defeated.

    Political instability => incumbents are always defeated.

    The median voter model has no predictive power

    in the realistic case where the policy space is complex

    Reinstated domain assumption =>

    collective rationality has to give

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    9/30

    Why so much stability?

    Institutions prevent instability

    Legislative bargaining (next week)

    Uncertainty about voter preferences

    restores predictability

    Probabilistic voting (now)

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    10/30

    Probabilistic voting

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    11/30

    The Idea Voters care about two things:

    Policy platforms

    Fixed characteristics of the parties that are unrelated totheir platform endorsements; they have a bias towardsone of the parties:

    Ideology

    Charisma or competency of leaders

    Voters tend to vote for party that offers the bestplatform but only if the difference is big enough to overturntheir bias.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    12/30

    The Idea Let ibe the ideological bias if voters i

    Each voter knows i

    The parties dont know i but they know thedistribution of the biases.

    The parties therefore perceive that there only is

    a probability that voter i will support itsplatformeven it is better for that voter thanthe one proposed by the other party.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    13/30

    Deterministic vs. probabilistic voting

    Voters vote for sure for the platform

    that comes closest to their ideal point.

    Let

    iiWWiff1 BAAip

    be the probability that voter i votes for party A.Aip

    i

    B

    i

    A

    WWiff0 Ai

    pi

    B

    i

    A2

    1 WWiff Aip

    g

    h

    *

    ig

    *

    ih

    Party A

    Party B

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    14/30

    Deterministic vs. probabilistic voting

    Voters dont vote for sure for the platform

    that comes closest to their ideal point.

    i

    BAAip ii

    WWiff1

    i

    Aip i

    B

    i

    A WWiff0

    i

    Aip i

    B

    i

    A2

    1 WWiff

    g

    h

    *

    ig

    *

    ih

    Party A

    Party B?

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    15/30

    Assumptions

    Two parties, A and B

    Platforms are xA and xB (many dimensions, e.g.

    x={g,h,t}) Different ideologies (or other fixed characteristics).

    Two types of voters, J=1,2

    WJ(x) is strictly concave in x (single-peaked).

    xJ* is the most-preferred policy of a voter of type J

    nJ voters of type J with n1 n2.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    16/30

    Assumptions

    The ideological bias of voter i in favour of

    party B is i

    iBAAi xxp )(W)(Wiff1

    ii

    The distribution of the biases is type

    specific

    i is distributed uniformly between

    [lJ

    ,hJ

    ] for J=1,2.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    17/30

    17

    Distribution of ideological biases

    i

    0

    Type 1

    l1 h1

    1/(h1+ |l1|)

    Type 2

    l2 h2

    1/(h2+ |l2|)

    2211 lhlh

    0)()( 21 ii EE

    )(0)(21 ii EE

    Swing versus committed voters:

    Equally popular parties:

    Type 1 (2) is faithful to party B (A):

    i

    BAAi xxp )(W)(Wiff1ii

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    18/30

    The timing

    Politiciansannounce platforms

    Citizens vote Elected politicianimplements his platform

    {xA, xB}

    Citizens learn their

    ideological bias

    i

    BAAi xxp )(W)(Wiff1ii

    Simple majority

    Proportional representation

    First-past-the-post in multiple districts

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    19/30

    Objectives of the parties

    Maximize the probability of winning a

    majority in the election:

    )2

    1Prob(

    21

    2211

    nn

    nn AA

    JA (JB) is the share of voters of type J that

    votes for party A (B)

    Common popularity shock in favour of

    party A: .

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    20/30

    The political Equilibrium

    1. Express the vote shares as a function of theplatforms.

    2. Find the platform that maximise the probabilityof winning for each party

    3. Find the Political (Nash) equilibrium by solvingthe resulting first order conditions

    A pair of platforms that maximise eachparties chance of winning given the platform

    choice of the other party and the voting rule

    followed by voters.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    21/30

    The vote shares Step 1: Express share of votes for party A (and B) amongst

    type 1 voters (A

    1 and B

    1) as a function of xA

    and xB

    Fix two platform proposals xA and xB Find the voter of type 1 who is indifferent between the two parties

    when these platforms are proposed

    W1(xA

    ) = W1(xB

    ) + s1

    s1

    = W1

    (xA)W

    1

    (xB)

    This voter, indexed by s, is the swing voter of type 1.

    Who is the swing voters depends on xA and xB

    All voters in group 1 with i1< s1 vote for party A

    All voters in group 1 with i1s1 vote for party B

    Step 2: Calculate the vote share for party A and party B

    respectively:

    Step 3: Repeat step 1 and 2 for voters of type 2 to get A

    2

    and B

    2

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    22/30

    22

    Shares of votes for party A and B among type 1 voters

    Voting rule: vote for A ifW1(xA) > W1(x

    B) + i

    i

    0l1

    1/(h1+ |l1|)

    s1(xA, xB)

    h1

    11

    11

    1

    hl

    ls

    A

    11

    111)'()'(

    hl

    xWxWlBA

    11

    111

    11)'()'(

    1

    hl

    xWxWhAB

    AB

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    23/30

    The platform choice

    Party A proposes the platform xA that maximisesits probability of winning given the platform

    proposed by party B xB

    2

    1nnProbmax

    21

    2211

    nn

    AAxA

    2211nnmax AAxA

    22

    222

    2

    11

    111

    1)()()()(

    maxhl

    xWxWln

    hl

    xWxWln

    BABA

    xA

    for given xB

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    24/30

    22

    222

    2

    11

    111

    1)()()()(

    maxhl

    xWxWln

    hl

    xWxWln

    BABA

    xA

    for given xB

    First order condition:

    02

    2

    22

    1

    1

    11

    A

    A

    A

    A

    x

    W

    Wn

    x

    W

    Wn

    0

    112

    22

    2

    1

    11

    1

    AA x

    W

    hlnx

    W

    hln

    Similarly for party B

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    25/30

    011

    2

    22

    21

    11

    1

    AA x

    W

    hln

    x

    W

    hlnParty A:

    Party B: 011

    2

    22

    2

    1

    11

    1

    BB x

    W

    hln

    x

    W

    hln

    Equilibrium exists: Even if the policy space is bigand complex.

    Policy convergence: The two parties propose the

    same platform xA

    =xB

    =x*

    Policy compromise: The equilibrium policy is a

    compromise between what type 1 and type 2

    voters want.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    26/30

    The Representation Theorem

    The equilibrium platform maximizes

    2

    1

    )(maxJ

    J

    Jx

    xWq

    A representative democracy with probabilistic voting

    behaves as ifthe government is maximizing a weighed

    social welfare function, where the weights represent

    the voters responsiveness to marginal platform changes

    and group sizes.

    JJ

    J

    Jhl

    nq

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    27/30

    Result overview

    Groups whose vote decision is mostly

    influenced by policy as opposed to ideology

    get a bigger weight.Policy caters to the swing voters as opposed to

    the median voter.

    Large groups of voters get bigger weight.

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    28/30

    What is Next?

    Probabilistic voting model and electoral

    systems

    Legislative Bargaining

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    29/30

    g*

    1g

    *

    1

    *

    2hh

    h

    *

    2g

    *

    3h

    *

    3g

    Pareto set

  • 7/31/2019 Public Economies

    30/30

    g*

    1g

    *

    1

    *

    2hh

    h

    *

    2g

    *

    3h

    *

    3g

    A

    Win set 32

    Win set 31

    Win set 12

    1

    3

    2