43
PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CITE WITHOUT THE EXPRESS WRITTEN CONSENT OF THE AUTHORS EXIT, VOICE, AND LOYALTY WITH MULTIPLE EXIT OPTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE U.S. FEDERAL WORKFORCE Andrew B. Whitford Professor Department of Public Administration and Policy The University of Georgia 204 Baldwin Hall Athens, GA 30602-1615 Phone: 706.542.2898 Fax: 706.583.0610 [email protected] Soo-Young Lee Assistant Professor Graduate School of Public Administration Seoul National University 599 Gwanak-ro, Gwanak-gu Seoul, Korea 151-742 Phone: 82.2.880.5575 Fax: 82.2.882.3998 [email protected]

PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: PLEASE DO NOT ... assess Hirschman’s theory of exit, voice and loyalty in the context of voluntary exit from organizations in the public workforce when

  • Upload
    ledung

  • View
    214

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR CITE WITHOUT

THE EXPRESS WRITTEN CONSENT OF THE AUTHORS

EXIT, VOICE, AND LOYALTY WITH MULTIPLE EXIT OPTIONS:

EVIDENCE FROM THE U.S. FEDERAL WORKFORCE

Andrew B. Whitford Professor

Department of Public Administration and Policy The University of Georgia

204 Baldwin Hall Athens, GA 30602-1615

Phone: 706.542.2898 Fax: 706.583.0610

[email protected]

Soo-Young Lee Assistant Professor

Graduate School of Public Administration Seoul National University

599 Gwanak-ro, Gwanak-gu Seoul, Korea 151-742 Phone: 82.2.880.5575 Fax: 82.2.882.3998 [email protected]

2

EXIT, VOICE, AND LOYALTY WITH MULTIPLE EXIT OPTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM THE U.S. FEDERAL WORKFORCE

Abstract

We assess Hirschman’s theory of exit, voice and loyalty in the context of voluntary exit from

organizations in the public workforce when respondents have multiple exit options. Specifically,

we follow other studies that have tested the effects of loyalty and voice on the likelihood a

person states their intention to leave. However, using data from the Federal Human Capital

Survey, we are able to assess the impact of loyalty, voice, and other factors (including

assessments of pay) on the likelihood that a respondent will retire, leave for another federal

agency, or leave for another sector. Our data come from two years of large-scale survey evidence

from the federal workforce. Our statistical analysis provides evidence that perceptions about

voice and loyalty limit exit. Yet, the effect of voice, loyalty and pay vary with exit option.

3

INTRODUCTION

In 1970, Albert O. Hirschman argued in Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline

in Firms, Organizations, and States that response to a decline in the quality of an organization by

causes people to choose from the actions of exit, voice, and loyalty. Loyalty keeps one from

leaving an organization going in the “wrong direction”; exit and voice are alternatives to loyalty

(Hirschman 1970, 78). Unfortunately, “empirical studies have not been as extensive or as

thorough as the number of citations to Hirschman (1970) would lead one to expect” (Dowding et

al. 2000, 469). In contrast, most of the over 1,500 general studies on turnover have been on

private sector organizations (Muchinsky and Morrow 1980). Researchers often mix voluntary

turnover (e.g., quits) and involuntary turnover (e.g., discharges) (Shaw et al. 1998). Yet, a

person’s stated intention to leave helps predict actual turnover (Hom et al. 1984; Mobley 1977;

Steel and Ovalle 1984; Steers and Mowday 1981; Van Breukelen et al. 2004).

Historically there were few public sector studies of intent to leave (Cotton and Tuttle

1986; Selden and Moynihan 2000; Tett and Meyer 1993), though this has changed recently. Core

themes remain the organizational traits of agencies losing employees (Kellough and Osuna

1995), the characteristics of those who exit (Lewis 1991; Lewis and Park 1989) and the role of

voluntary turnover (Kellough and Osuna 1995; Lewis 1991; Lewis and Park 1989; Selden and

Moynihan 2000).

In 2009, Lee and Whitford argued that the exit, voice, and loyalty framework was useful

for understanding turnover in the case of the public sector. That paper offered statistical evidence

showing exit varies with perceptions about voice and loyalty. Yet, dissatisfaction with pay is also

a substantial cause of intention to leave. Finally, the article showed evidence for “motivation

crowding” when pay-based motivation is emphasized.

4

This paper fills a gap in the literature on public sector turnover by moving beyond the

study of “intent to leave” in broad terms. Instead, we focus attention on the intent to leave when

there are multiple exit options. Realistically, employees do not just leave organizations: they go

somewhere else. This “else” is the focus of our paper. Specifically, we test whether an

individual’s intention to leave (exit) for a specific option depends on the organization’s

commitment to responding to voice and organizational attempts to build loyalty. Turnover

intention is a conscious and deliberate determination to leave the organization (Tett and Meyer

1993). However, because employees face multiple options, intention could be “to leave to

retire”, “intention to leave to take another job within the federal government”, or “intention to

leave to take another job outside the federal government”, instead of just the choice of leaving or

not leaving.

This study addresses two research questions. First, what are the differences among the

federal employees who choose the four different exit options? For this question, we describe and

compare the federal employees across their four types of responses to the exit option question in

terms of their empowerment, commitment, and satisfaction with the organization and pay. We

will analyze this question by using descriptive statistics and analysis of variance. Second, what

are the relationships among the four kinds of exit choices, voice, loyalty, and pay? To address

this question, we use the “no intention to leave” response as a base group for comparison to test

whether an individual’s exit choices depend on the organization’s commitment to responding to

voice and organizational attempts to build loyalty.

We also ask whether the exit intention depends on the individual’s hierarchical status as

non-supervisor or team leader, supervisor or manager, and/or executive. In contrast to Hirschman,

we test whether exit depends on the use of extrinsic incentives like pay. Last, we ask whether the

5

specific exit intention depends on the respondent’s time horizon – whether it depends on their

place in the age strata.

We provide evidence for this position using a statistical model of data from the 2008

Federal Human Capital Survey; a future version of this paper will also include the 2010 version,

the new Federal Employee Viewpoint Survey. Our dependent variable is the respondent’s stated

intention to leave for a specific exit option, and so is an unordered polychotomous variable;

using a multinomial logit model, we estimate effects across individuals working at different

levels the organization’s hierarchy, and accounting for structural aspects of the sampling frame.

We show direct effects for both voice and loyalty on exit. We show that pay also

motivates these individuals. Finally, we show that these effects are different for different exit

options.

Our article proceeds as follows. In the next section, we discuss Hirschman’s approach to

understanding exit in organizations, and we offer our specification of a model of the intention to

leave when there are multiple exit options. After that, we estimate the effects of voice, loyalty,

pay, and several other alternative causes of the intention to leave and assess the results of our

statistical model. Finally, we discuss the results of our theory and test for understanding the

intention to leave in the public workforce.

THEORY

To exit means to leave an organization; expressing voice means bringing one’s

dissatisfaction with the organization directly to management (or through a process that makes

management subordinate) (Hirschman 1970, 4). Exit, voice, and loyalty are substitutes, though

exit is a “reaction of last resort” (1970, 37). Loyalty is allegiance – in groups or organizations;

and “loyalty makes exit less likely” (Hirschman 1970, 77). For instance, voice for workers may

6

come through a trade union if unionization enhances negotiated relations with management

(Freeman 1976, 1980; Freeman and Medoff 1984), but voice is usually more than just union

membership (Dowding et al. 2000, 486). More broadly, studies added to this triumvirate the

concept of neglect, which is similar to “shirking” in Brehm and Gates (1997) (see also Farrell

1983; Rusbult and Farrell 1982; Rusbult and Lowery 1985; Rusbult et al. 1982; Withey and

Cooper 1989). Most studies offer the EVLN (exit, voice, loyalty, and neglect) components as

dependent variables (e.g., Daley 1992).

In this paper, our claim is that the likelihood of exit depends on the access to mechanisms

that support exercising voice, or that enhance obligations like loyalty. The role of unionization in

supporting voice is less relevant in the federal workforce because of limited variation in

unionization status. But managers regularly try to enhance voice in organizations without relying

on unionization – witness the growth of “employee empowerment” during the 1990s. Likewise,

managers try to build commitment among the members of their workforce to the organization

where they work.

As noted, numerous scholars in public administration and public management have

studied employee turnover in the public sector because turnover increases the costs of hiring and

training new employees and lowers productivity (Kim 2005; Lee and Whitford 2008). Table 1

summarizes previous studies on employee turnover in the public sector. These focused on actual

turnover rates or public employees’ turnover intentions, usually to explain factors causing actual

turnover or intentions.

[Insert Table 1 about here.]

As Table 1 shows, little previous research, especially with regard to the public sector, has

focused on employees having several alternatives when they decide to leave their organizations.

7

The broader management literature has considered this possibility. For instance, Carruthers and

Pinder (1983) and Mueller and Price (1989) argued that employees consider and create

alternatives (or job choices) across organizations as well as within the same organizations when

they decide to leave their current job. Yet, “Most turnover models predicting job change

decisions concentrate on employee’s leaving an organization and rarely take into account the

employee’s destination choice” (Kirschenbaum and Weisberg 2002, 109). No large-scale

statistical studies have paid attention to alternative forms of turnover destinations.

This is the case even though, as Miller (1996, 24) argued, turnover is “any voluntary

movement out of a job” and most studies define it as “movement across the boundaries of an

organization – or quitting.” He even includes in his definition movement within organizational

boundaries such as quits, transfers, and promotions – aspects overlooked in a traditional

definition of turnover as movement across organizational boundaries. In other words, turnover

incorporates the mobility out of a job within the organization as well as any movement leaving

their organization. Therefore, researchers should realize that employees can have a set of

turnover options such as quits, transfers and promotions within the organization, or planned

retirement and “it is important to examine turnover by contrasting homogeneous groups of

employees, based on their having experienced similar types of turnover” (Miller 1996, 24). For

this reason, Miller (1996) identified four types of turnover: no turnover (staying), promotion,

transfer, and resignation (quitting). Exit happens in all organizations (Kellough and Osuna 1995;

Tett and Meyer 1993), including retirements, quits, transfers, reductions in force, death, and

terminations after temporary appointments (Lewis 1991).

Kirschenbaum and Weisberg (2002, 110-111) argued that “Employees’ movements from

their current job or position could be within the same organization or crossing boundaries to

8

another organization, or even withdrawing totally from the labor market,” which implies three

types of turnover options such as quits, internal organizational destination options (e.g., another

job in the same department, the same job in a different department, or a different job in a

different department), and external destination choices involving inter-organizational movements

(e.g., the same job in a different organization or a different job in a different organization).

According to Hom, et al. (1992), these turnover options depend on the nature of the labor

market and employees’ perception of their organization. In other words, employees’ perceptions

of specific factors in their work environment affect their turnover choices. “Those employees,

whose career aspirations are best met by moving across or within their work organization … will

be more sensitive to signs at their work place that will either reinforce or dampen their

destination options” (Kirschenbaum and Weisberg 2002, 110).

Doeringer and Piore (1970) also pointed out that these turnover options come from the

nature of the labor market in which work conditions and work-related behaviors are different

according to career pathways. That is, the innate dynamics of labor markets provide different

opportunity structures and working conditions for different career options (Spilerman 1977) and

employees will be respond to contrasting conditions between their present status and available

opportunities (Kirschenbaum and Weisberg 2002). From this perspective, Kirschenbaum and

Weisberg (1994) stated that intentions to improve employment conditions (including working

conditions) and perceptions of other organization-related factors may decide a choice of one

turnover option over another. In their view, it is natural for employees to try to move up to a

better position and move out of a current organization for a better job in order to match their

improved skills and knowledge with alternative job opportunities involving career and residential

changes.

9

We argue that attempts to alter the psychological states of employees occur against the

backdrop of an employee’s overall satisfaction with the organization – the employee’s perception

that the organization is in decline or improving. In Hirschman’s view, a person’s choice of exit,

voice, or loyalty occurs within the context of that person’s assessment of an organization (e.g., a

consumer’s assessment of a product supplier, or an employee’s assessment of an employer). We

begin our analysis of the intention to leave by building on the employee’s perception of

organizational satisfaction. This forms a baseline for the employee’s calculus for exit: we control

for the employee’s satisfaction with the organization in our models below in order to control for

the employee’s overall psychological state of affect toward the organization. Our hypothesis is:

H1: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when her satisfaction with the organization is high.

Our approach is different from that followed by other studies. Typical studies define job

satisfaction as an employee’s affective reaction to a job based on their comparison of desired

outcomes and actual outcomes (e.g., Cranny et al. 1992); studies show that job satisfaction

reduces an employee's intention to leave a firm (Gray-Toft and Anderson 1981; Mobley 1977;

Murphy and Gorchels 1996; Ostroff 1992;). Yet, multiple aspects of an employee’s job may

make them dissatisfied; for example, Rosse and Miller (1984) identify aspects of a lack of

satisfaction (such as salary or career opportunities) that are associated with an employee’s intent

to leave.

This is different from Hirschman’s argument, which centers on organizational

satisfaction and not job satisfaction per se (see Driscoll 1978). We measure key aspects of a lack

10

of satisfaction (such as voice, loyalty, pay, physical conditions, and benefits), but control for the

employee’s overall organizational satisfaction. We do not include a broad measure of

“leadership”, mainly because many models of leadership are built on enhancing voice and

loyalty (Ashour 1982; Larson 1986; Locke and Latham 1990; Mumford 1986; O’Driscoll and

Beehr 1994; Tjosvold 1984; Williams and Hazer 1986). Instead, we test propositions derived

from Hirschman’s work.

Do organizational attempts to increase voice (to empower employees) reduce the

likelihood of exit? As noted, other studies use unionization as a coarse proxy for mechanisms

that increase an employee’s ability to use voice in an organization (Freeman 1976, 1980;

Freeman and Medoff 1984). Given unionization, what other mechanisms are available to

increase voice?

Hirschman sees voice as “any attempt at all to change, rather than to escape from, an

objectionable state of affairs” (1970, 30). In firms, employees can use voice to express their

dissatisfaction with management or to bring those views to others who have the power to change

the state of affairs. Specifically, to resort to voice is to “make an attempt at changing the

practices, policies, and outputs of the firm from which one buys or of the organization to which

one belongs” (1970, 30). Hirschman’s theory sees parallel relationships: between customers and

firms, and between employees and organizations. The “consumer revolution” (part of a larger

“participation explosion”) provides consumers with a new channel for “making their voice

heard” (1970, 42). In general, voice is the attempt to achieve change “from within” (1970, 38).

Hirschman’s exercise of voice connects directly to the empowerment of employees in

organizations. Specifically, empowerment is the “process of enhancing feelings of self-efficacy

among organizational members through the identification of conditions that foster powerlessness

11

and through their removal by both formal organizational practices and informal techniques of

providing efficacy information” (Conger and Kanungo 1988, 474). Empowerment is itself

“based on the assumption that individuals can have a high level of ‘voice’ in shaping and

influencing organizational activities” (Spreitzer 1996, 484). Employees exercise Hirschman’s

voice when they choose to attempt to change the organization; empowerment is an “active, rather

than a passive, orientation to a work role” (Spreitzer 1995, 1444). The empowerment literature is

lengthy and broad, traversing the power of participatory management in enhancing

empowerment, its impact on both affective reactions, and workplace outcomes like turnover and

absenteeism (Eby et al. 1999; Liden et al. 2000; Thomas and Velthouse 1990;). Our

measurement strategy (discussed below) for identifying “voice” is connected to the measurement

of empowerment. Because Hirschman argues that voice can be a substitute for exit (1970, 37),

our second hypothesis is:

H2: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when she perceives increased opportunities to express voice.

Third, does the presence of loyalty make exit less likely? For Hirschman, loyalty is

neither exit nor voice; in contrast, loyalists “suffer in silence, confident that things will soon get

better” (1970, 38). Loyalty is the willingness to trade off the certainty of outcome that would

result from exit and the uncertainty from remaining in an organization and hoping things will get

better. Of course, loyalty also can be a defense against outside forces; loyalty can be a stand on

behalf of an organization facing outside criticism (Daley 1992).

12

Loyalty is directly related to the employee’s expression of commitment to an

organization (even a declining one). Employees are committed when they strongly believe in and

accept the organization’s goals and values, they exert effort for the organization, and they

maintain membership in the organization (Mowday et al. 1979). Studies have tried to describe all

the ways commitment can operate (e.g., Angle and Perry 1981), but “in a very broad sense,

organizational commitment refers to an individual’s loyalty or bond to his or her employing

organization” (Bozeman and Perrewé 2001); indeed, a main way of conceptualizing commitment

as a normative concept is that an employee “should be loyal to his organization, should make

sacrifices on its behalf, and should not criticize it” (Wiener and Vardi 1980, 86). Previous

research shows that organizational commitment underpins a number of organizational constructs,

including turnover intention (Mathieu and Zajac 1990). Of course, managers may try to increase

an employee’s loyalty/commitment to the group by inducing a psychological state in employees

(Menon 2001). The measurement strategy we discuss below for loyalty takes advantage of this

literature on the measurement of commitment. Our hypothesis is:

H3: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when she perceives the organization as attempting to foster loyalty among

members of the workforce.

Together these hypotheses are consistent with the Hirschman framework and attempt to test the

framework by connecting it to multiple literatures with long traditions in organizational behavior

(e.g., Mathieu and Zajac 1990; Steers 1977).

13

We also want to test a claim about the power of voice and loyalty on the likelihood a

person expresses their intention to exit an organization. Specifically, recent studies argue that the

use of monetary incentives may undermine more “intrinsic” types of motivation that mostly

drive the decisions of employees – even employees in firms. To be specific, financial incentives

can be a substitute (not a complement) for social motivation in a hierarchical/principal-agent

relationship (Miller and Whitford 2002). The power of monetary incentives may be at odds with

the power of intrinsic motives like voice and loyalty – motives that social psychologists have

shown to operate in many organizations. Bertelli (2007) shows that increased accountability

increases turnover among subordinates only; supervisors facing paybanding are less likely to

leave than those who do not.

We test for a direct effect of satisfaction with pay on intention to leave. It is important to

note that despite the possible relative decline in federal wages compared to private sector wages,

voluntary turnover has been relatively stable (Lewis 1991), suggesting at least at the aggregate

level that turnover does not move with pay. However, many scholars contend pay is an important

determinant of turnover (Blau and Kahn 1981; Kim 1999; Leonard 1987; Utgoff 1983) and

studies confirm the importance of pay in reducing quit rates (Park et al. 1994; Powell et al. 1994;

Shaw et al. 1998). Our hypothesis is:

H4: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when her pay is satisfactory.

We also address a few other probable causes of turnover intention in order to make our

model robust. We assess the hypotheses listed H5 to H10 below because they represent probable

14

causes of turnover intention that other studies have addressed. In our approach these are mostly

included as control variables since our primary focus is on the impact of voice, loyalty, and pay

on the likelihood of intending to exit the organization. The alternative – not including these

variables and ignoring these other possible causes – would represent a form of excluded variable

bias; we also would not be able to infer what is the relative contribution of voice, loyalty, and

pay in a process like turnover intention when compared to other traditional concerns that studies

have centered on. This approach also allows us to “bridge” Hirschman’s approach with other

traditional approaches to understanding turnover.

For example, using meta-analysis, Cotton and Tuttle (1986) categorize some of the

correlates of turnover into external (union presence, unemployment rate), work-related (pay,

overall job satisfaction, role clarity), and personal (age, education, gender) correlates. Kellough

and Osuna (1995) show that voluntary turnover is a function of organizational factors (size,

unionization), work force characteristics (professional/administrative proportion) and individual

factors (age, gender, race). Selden and Moynihan (2000) examine the impact of environmental

factors (unemployment, region), organizational factors (size, unionization), and human resource

management practices (pay, training) on voluntary separation in state government. We also

recognize that external labor market prospects, which will depend on broader economic growth,

may cause a person to leave the public sector workforce; of course, the data we use here are from

a single point in time and are not geo-coded so we are unable to address such dynamic effects in

our data.

Research indicates that investments in human capital such as benefits reduce voluntary

turnover (Osterman 1987) and that policies that support worker flexibility and those with

15

families can increase retention (Durst 1999; Ezra and Deckman 1996; Newman and Mathews

1999). We assess the hypothesis:

H5: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when she is more satisfied with family-friendly benefits.

Private sector research indicates that training predicts involuntary turnover but not voluntary

turnover: firms with more training had significantly higher discharge rates (Shaw et al. 1998).

However, we also expect that this relationship is less powerful for the exit option of retirement.

Other research indicates that businesses without attractive career development programs

lose good workers to competitors (Rita and Kirschenbaum 1999). We assess the hypothesis:

H6: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave when training is present.

In addition, past analysis by meta-analysis shows a moderate, negative relationship between

satisfaction with promotion opportunity and turnover (Cotton and Tuttle 1986). We assess the

hypothesis:

H7: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave for any given exit option

when promotion is merit-based.

Past research found that, in the case of clerical staff, conditions like office darkness were

significantly and negatively correlated with turnover (Oldham and Fried 1987), although there is

16

no consistent, negative relationship between poor physical work conditions and intent to leave

(Koh and Goh 1995). We assess the hypothesis:

H8: An employee is less likely to state her intention to leave when physical conditions

in the workplace are acceptable.

Finally, we also assess the role of the respondents’ racial and gender characteristics. Blau

and Kahn (1981) note that quit rates are lower for minority employees than for whites, once

personal and job characteristics are held constant; other studies also find that blacks have lower

quit rates (Datcher 1983; Haber et al. 1983; Weiss 1984). Other studies show higher quit rates

due to a number of factors, including commuting time, local unemployment, and at-work racial

harassment (Shields and Price 2002; Zax 1989). Our hypothesis is:

H9: Minority employees are less likely to state their turnover intention for any given

exit option.

Previous private sector studies report gender is strongly correlated with turnover (women are

more likely to leave than men), especially for professional jobs, probably due to different job-

matching processes for women and men (Cotton and Tuttle 1986; Meitzen 1986). Aggregate

statistics usually show turnover to be much higher for women than for men (Kellough and Osuna

1995). The hypothesis is:

H10: Women are more likely to state their intention to leave for any given exit option.

17

We discuss the full specification of our hypotheses in terms of the measurement of

concepts below, but we first turn to a key design element of our study. Rather than take the

position of other studies intent to leave is a single exit option, we argue that the intent to leave

varies across exit options: e.g., retirement, for another agency, or outside the federal workforce.

Accordingly, we move beyond previous studies that use federal workforce data to account for a

peculiar potential cause of exiting through retirement: the respondent’s age. In this case we

account for the respondent’s location in four age strata. We discuss these strata below. We

expect that the likelihood of selecting retirement increases with movement through these age

strata. At a minimum, not accounting for age is a form of omitted variable bias.

We also account for the respondent’s work status: e.g., non-supervisor/team leader,

supervisor/manager, and executive. Knowledge of a person’s hierarchical level helps us

understand perceived exit options. We expect that those inhabiting the lowest of the three

hierarchical tiers – non-supervisors and team leaders – are least likely to state intent to leave.

Those in the higher tiers are more likely to respond as intending to leave. Such intent would

suggest position-specific retention methods. Differences exist between top-level and lower-level

workers in terms of their time horizon for the organization, with lower-level workers less

affected by long-term strategic considerations (Brinkerhoff 1972).

Model Specification

Our data on employees’ perceived intention to quit come from two sources: the 2008

Federal Human Capital (FHC) Survey; future versions of this paper will also discuss its 2010

counterpart: the Federal Employee Viewpoint (FEV) Survey (the results for that survey are

available from the authors). Both were conducted by the U.S. Office of Personnel Management.

18

More than 210,000 Federal employees responded to the 2008 FHCS, for a government-wide

response rate of 51 percent (Office of Personnel Management 2008).1

We start with a brief discussion of our dependent variable. Typically, the dependent

variable Intention to leave is measured as a dichotomous response (1 for yes, 0 for no) to the

survey item “Are you considering leaving your organization?” For example, in the 2004 FHC,

the proportions of respondents responding “yes” are: 36.1 percent (non-supervisors and team

leaders), 33.5 percent (supervisors and managers), and 38.7 percent (executives); the overall

turnover intention is 35.4 percent.

In this paper, we recognize that our dependent variable mixes a number of different kinds

of turnover, including different types of intentional separations. To the degree that other reasons

for turnover are mixed in with the individual responses (e.g., planned retirement), those factors

could bias effects toward zero or inflate standard errors. The dependent variable in our paperis

federal employees’ exit choices (i.e., types of turnover), measured by an item asking “Are you

considering leaving your organization within the next year, and if so, why?” The response

categories of this question are “no”, “yes, to retire”, “yes, to take another job within the federal

government”, and “yes, to take another job outside the federal government”. The original survey

item also includes another response category (“yes, other”); we omit since we cannot interpret

what this clearly means.

As Table 2 shows, the number of respondents of the dependent variable by response

categories (i.e., exit choices) in the original survey. In the 2008 FHC, the proportions of

respondents responding “no” are 74.6 percent, “to retire” 6.1 percent, “for another agency” 17.0

percent, and “to leave federal government” 2.3 percent. In contrast, in the 2010 FEV, the

1 Details on the FEV survey are available from: http://www.fedview.opm.gov/2010/.

19

proportions of respondents responding “no” are 75.4 percent, “to retire” 6.8 percent, “for another

agency” 16.0 percent, and “to leave federal government” 1.8 percent.2

[Insert Table 2 about here.]

We note that we do not address actual exit in this study, but instead concentrate a

person’s stated intention to exit the organization. We address the stated intent for a number of

important reasons. First, there remains little research on federal employees’ intent to leave; most

research has examined actual turnover rates. One recent study of intent to leave centers on recent

attempts to make federal employees more fiscally accountable (Bertelli 2007), rather than

assessing the Hirschman framework, and does so in the case of only two agencies. Second,

studies of turnover rates examine measures usually calculated some time after employees’

separation from their organizations, and such rates are organizational-level data. Third, turnover

intention is an immediate and accurate predictor of actual turnover (Hom et al. 1984; Mobley

1977; Steers and Mowday 1981; Stell and Ovalle 1984; Van Breuklen et al. 2004).

Our variable Organizational Satisfaction is by the following single item: “Considering

everything, how satisfied are you with your organization?” This item was measured by a Likert-

type five-point scale from “strongly disagree” (1) to “strongly agree” (5). This variable taps into

our first key concept – the respondent’s perception of the ascent or decline of the organization.

Again, this forms the baseline of the employee’s calculus for exit.

Voice is constructed from four items by dividing the sum of the responses to the items by

the number of the items. Hirschman’s exercise of voice connects directly to the empowerment of

employees in organizations (Lee and Whitford 2008) and empowerment is the ‘‘process of

2 The responses in this table may be different from those in our model since some items for the independent variables have ‘Do not know’ or ‘No basis to judge’ response categories that we removed for this analysis and some respondents did not answer this question.

20

enhancing feelings of self-efficacy among organizational members” (Conger and Kanungo 1988,

474). The Cronbach’s α for the scale is 0.87. The items are: “employees have a feeling of

personal empowerment and ownership of work processes”, “I feel encouraged to come up with

new and better ways of doing things”, “My talents are used well in the workplace”, and

“supervisors/team leaders in my work unit provide employee(s) with the opportunities to

demonstrate their leadership skills.” This variable taps into our second key concept – the

respondent’s perception of their ability to express voice.

Our third variable Loyalty is constructed from two items by dividing the sum of the

responses to the items by the number of the items. It is directly related to the employee’s

expression of commitment to an organization (even a declining one). Bozeman and Perrewe

(2001, 161) defined organizational commitment as an individual’s loyalty or bond to his or her

employing organization in a very broad sense. The Cronbach’s α for the scale is 0.77. The items

are: “in my organization, leaders generate high levels of motivation and commitment in the

workforce”, and “I recommend my organization as a good place to work.”

We want to be clear that our measures of Voice and Loyalty are not perfect or direct – that

they are coarse representations of the range of considerations that Hirschman packaged into

theoretical framework. Of course, this is not unusual in empirical research that bridges past

theoretical work with specific cases drawn from the world of public management. However, we

note that this problem is frequently encountered when using existing data like the Merit

Principles Survey or Federal Human Capital Survey, which was specifically constructed for

purposes other than the illumination of academic concerns about human motivation. We

recognize that these two variables might be improved upon, and we hope that other approaches

21

that follow this paper will move the measurement of exit, voice, and loyalty in new and fruitful

directions.

We measure a respondent’s perception of the pay component of their work relationship

(Pay) by their response to the question: “considering everything, how satisfied are you with your

pay?” This item is measured on a five-point scale from “strongly disagree” (1) to “strongly

agree” (5). We attempt to examine a claim about the power of voice and loyalty on the likelihood

a person expresses their intention to exit their organization by testing for a direct effect of

satisfaction with pay on intention to leave. In our previous study, we found that extrinsic

motivation such as pay in the Senior Executive Service crowds out other important intrinsic

motivating factors like voice and loyalty. We try to investigate this motivation crowding-out

effect, given several kinds of exit destination choices.

This study includes six control variables. We constructed our variable Benefits from two

items by dividing the sum of the responses to the items by the number of the items. The

Cronbach’s α for the scale is 0.73. The four items are: “how satisfied are you with child care

subsidies?” and “how satisfied are you with work/life programs (for example, health and

wellness, employee assistance, eldercare, and support groups)?”3

Training addresses whether an employee’s professional development makes the

individual more likely to stay (Huselid, 1995). Our scale is constructed following two items

(Cronbach’s alpha = 0.80): “how satisfied are you with the training you receive for your present

job?”; and, “my training needs are assessed”.

3 Eldercare includes services like assisted living, day care, and long-term care that the Federal

Government offers to those employees who are caregivers for senior relatives. See U.S. Office of

Personnel Management (2006).

22

Merit Promotion represents perceptions of merit-based promotion and is measured by the

employees’ response to the statement “promotions in my work unit are based on merit.” We

measure the respondents’ perceptions of the physical conditions of the workplace by their

response to the statement “physical conditions (for example, noise level, temperature, lighting,

cleanliness in the workplace) allow employees to perform their jobs well” (Physical Conditions).

Finally, in our analysis Race is recorded “0” for white and non-Hispanic, non-Latino, and

non-Spanish respondents, and “1” for others. Women are coded “1” for the variable Gender.

Respondents’ positions are also divided into three categories: non-supervisor and/or team

leader, supervisor and/or manager, and executive. A non-supervisor does not supervise other

employees. Team leaders provide employees with day-to-day guidance in conducting work

projects, but do not have supervisory responsibilities and are not official supervisors. Supervisors

oversee employees but not other supervisors; managers oversee one or more supervisors. Finally,

an executive is a member of the Senior Executive Service (SES) or its equivalent.

Our age strata come from responses to the following question: “what is your age group?”.

Age stratum 1 is composed of those responding “29 and under”; 2 is “30-39”; 3 is “40-49”; 4 is

“50-59”; and 5 is “60 or older”. Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics.

[Insert Table 3 about here.]

MODEL ESTIMATION AND RESULTS

For the analysis, we will use multinomial logit model because our dependent variable

(i.e., exit destination choices) is an unordered polychotomous variable with four response

categories (Long and Freese 2006, 223). We are interested in the effects for the variables

Organizational Satisfaction, Voice, Loyalty, Pay, Benefits, Training, Merit Promotion, Physical

23

Conditions, Race, Gender, Age, and Status. Table 4 shows the model for the 2008 FHC data in

three columns. The baseline effect is for the option of “do not leave”. The entry for each variable

in the column “retirement” indicates the relative risk ratio for that variable for the exit option of

retiring, and so on; below we interpret these option-specific effects in relation to the option of

not leaving. We also account for the fact that some groups were under-sampled by including

survey weights in our estimation.

[Insert table 4 about here]

All of the effects are represented as relative risk ratios. Multinomial logit is a nonlinear

estimation routine, so the effect of an independent variable on the probability a person expresses

a specific intent to leave varies across the range of that variable. Because of this, the effects of a

variable in terms of the probability of the dependent variable taking a specific, unordered value

“1” are better expressions of the variable’s explanatory power. The relative risk ratio approach

helps make such a probability statement, but it only does so at the mean value of that variable.

In future versions of this paper, we will interpret these effects in terms of the change in

probability of a person stating an exit-specific intent to leave, when evaluated across the range of

the independent variable. To provide a complete picture, we will represent the explanatory power

of an independent variable across its entire range graphically by using King et al.’s stochastic

simulation approach (2000). We also estimate our models with agency-specific fixed effects to

account for heterogeneity that depends on unobservable agency-level characteristics. Generally,

the model fits well, with the proportional reduction in error being in the 20 percent range. Note

that pseudo-R2 as a fit measure is bounded at some point below 1; upper bounds must be

calculated for each individual application.

24

First, we find that satisfaction with the organization reduces the likelihood of stating

intention to leave for all three exit options. Indeed, high organizational satisfaction translates into

a much lower risk of leaving for a position outside government than in leaving for a position in

another agency. A Wald test of the equality of the coefficients for the satisfaction variable in the

“leave agency” and “leave government” equations shows that the latter is more negative (lower

in terms of relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 10.15). Similarly, a Wald test of the equality of the

coefficients for the satisfaction variable in the “retire” and “leave agency” equations shows that

the latter is more negative (lower in terms of relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 8.55). This is robust

evidence for the dependence of exit on perceptions of the ascent or decline of the organization.

Given the effect of this perception, what are the roles of voice and loyalty in reducing the

use of exit in organizations? We find compelling evidence for the reduction in the likelihood of

exit based on individual-level perceptions of management’s dedication to both expanding the use

of voice and enhancing employees’ sense of loyalty to the organization. With regard to

Hypothesis 2 above, Table 4 also shows that the effects of voice are the same for both the “leave

agency” and “leave government” equations, although the effect is not significant for the

“retirement” equation. A Wald test of the equality of the coefficients for the voice variable in the

“leave agency” and “leave government” equations shows that the latter is more negative (lower

in terms of relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 21.26). Similarly, a Wald test of the equality of the

coefficients for the voice variable in the “retire” and “leave agency” equations shows that the

latter is more negative (lower in terms of relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 73.39).

Table 4 shows that the effects of loyalty are also in the predicted direction and

significantly different from zero, and that the effects vary across exit option. The magnitudes of

these effects are smaller than for satisfaction with the organization, but are important when one

25

considers which factors are more available to managers concerned about exit from the

organization. Interestingly, a Wald test of the equality of the coefficients for the loyalty variable

in the “leave agency” and “leave government” equations shows that we can only distinguish

between the two at the 0.10 significance level (that they are not so different in terms of relative

risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 3.52). Similarly, a Wald test of the equality of the coefficients for the

loyalty variable in the “retire” and “leave agency” equations shows that the two are statistically

equivalent (the same in terms of relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 0.07).

Table 4 show unusual variation in the effects of pay – that pay satisfaction reduces the

likelihood a respondent reports an intention to leave, except in the case of retirement. Pay

satisfaction increases the likelihood of planning retirement (though this could be due to the

higher pay status of those people who are planning retirement). Table 4 shows that the effect is

significant at the 0.001 level (two-tailed test). In contrast, pay satisfaction reduces the odds of

leaving the agency or leaving the government for another position.

A Wald test of the equality of the coefficients for the pay variable in the “leave agency”

and “leave government” equations shows that the latter is more negative (lower in terms of

relative risk ratios) (Wald χ2 = 93.12). Not surprisingly, a Wald test of the equality of the

coefficients for the pay variable in the “retire” and “leave agency” equations shows that the latter

is more negative (Wald χ2 = 318.82). This is robust evidence for the dependence of exit outside

government on pay satisfaction. No study has ever modeled all three exit options together and

assessed the role of pay on intent to leave using this kind of nonlinear model. It is possible that

other papers fail to find similar effects due to differences in modeling strategies.

We next address our subsidiary Hypotheses 5 through 10 and show that other effects are

also present. Increases in the benefits index reduce the odds of exit to another agency or outside

26

government (but curiously increase the probability of retirement). Increases in the training index

increase the odds of retirement or exit outside of government (but reduce it for exit to another

agency). Merit-based promotion reduces exit (except for retirement, in which case there is no

effect); better physical conditions reduce the odds of exit to another agency or outside

government (but curiously increase the odds of retirement). Minorities have a greater odds of

exit to other agencies (but lower risk to leaving the government) than do white employees.

Women’s risks of exit are lower in the case of retirement and leaving government employment.

We also note that significant differences remain even after we account for status-level

motivations for exit, with those in the second stratum more likely to retire, to leave for another

agency, and to leave government employment. Age strata effects are also present in the case of

leaving for other agencies and leaving government (but not for retirement; in that case, while the

estimated effects are huge, we have great uncertainty about their magnitudes).

What can we say about the relative performance of voice, loyalty, and pay as

explanations for exit? The variables are measured so that they have the same support or range

[1,5], so we can test the coefficients directly.4 Is the coefficient for loyalty larger than that for

voice? The Wald test of the estimated parameters can reject the null hypothesis of no difference

in the effects of voice and loyalty in the exit option of leaving government (Wald χ2(1) = 47.16)

and in the exit option of leaving for another agency (Wald χ2(1) = 26.02). Is the coefficient for

voice larger than that for pay satisfaction? For the exit option of leaving government, the

coefficient for voice is more negative than that for pay at the 0.001 level (Wald χ2(1) = 17.75);

4 The total explanatory power also depends on the standard error of the estimate and the

descriptive characteristics of the variable. The latter are roughly similar across the groups, but

the variables have different means and standard deviations.

27

for the case of the leaving government employment, the coefficient is more negative than that for

pay only at the 0.10 level (Wald χ2(1) = 3.45).

Is the coefficient for loyalty larger than that for pay satisfaction? For the case of the

leaving government employment, we can reject the null that the coefficients are the same at a

conventional level (Wald χ2(1) = 65.90); the same is in the case of leaving for another agency

(Wald χ2(1) = 11.22). Together these results suggest that in aggregate, voice and loyalty are

more important than pay.

DISCUSSION

Hirschman’s theory narrows the gap between study environment and causal mechanism.

A distinct contribution of this study may be in the realization that the effects of exit, voice, and

loyalty are similar for different exit options. Lee and Whitford (2009) called for additional

research into how programs like the SES affect the long-term development of perceptions of

voice and loyalty, and what the potential costs are of pay mechanisms dictated by politicians for

such cohorts. What is interesting is that the effect of pay and the EVL components have different

effects for the likelihood of leaving government versus moving to other agencies. Our study also

helps show the relative performance of pay vis-à-vis loyalty and EVL components of motivation,

considerations currently lacking in principal-agency theory.

20

Table 1: Summary of Previous Studies on Employee Turnover in the Public Sector

Author(s) Independent Variables (*Control Variables) Dependent Variable(s)

Data Unit of Analysis

Lewis & Park

(1989)

Sex (Are women more likely to quit than men?) *Control Variable: Age, Education, Experience, Salary

Exit (the employee

either did or did not exit federal

service)

1% random sample of the

Central Personnel Data File (US)

Individual

Lewis (1991) General Schedule (GS1-GS3, GS4-GS6, GS7-GS9, GS10-GS12, GS13 and above) *Control Variable: Gender, Age, Years of service, Years of education

Exit rates Central Personnel Data File (1973-1989, US)

Individual

Kellough & Osuna (1995)

% of the young workers, Gender (% of female), Race (% of minority), Occupational characteristics (professional/administrative proportion, clerical proportion), Agency size, Union strength, % of the temporary employment

Quit rates

Pooled data from the U.S. OPM (1986, 1988, 1990,

and 1992)

Agency

Selden & Moynihan

(2000)

Unemployment rates, Unionization, Internal opportunity structure, Pay, Family-friendly policies (Child care on site), Training *Control Variable: Geographical region & Size (Median state annual income)

Turnover rates

Data from the 1998 Government Performance

Project, the National Association of State Personnel Executive

(1999), the Book of State, the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and the US Bureau of the Census

State

Kim

(2005)

Job characteristics (Work exhaustion, Role clarity, Role conflict), Work environment (Participatory management, Resources), Human resource management (Advancement opportunities, Training & development, Pay & rewards satisfaction) *Control Variable: Perceived job alternatives, Gender, Age, Years of work education

Turnover

intentions (of IT employees)

Survey of central IT department employees (State governments of

Nevada and Washington, 2003, US)

Individual

Bertelli (2007)

Functional preferences (JIM: Job Involvement and Intrinsic Motivation), Friendly workplace, Quality of workgroup output, Poor performance is addressed, Quality of pay, Quality of immediate supervisor, Managerial review of goals and evaluation, Supervisors receptive to change, Hold leaders in high regard, Reasonable workload, Work-life balance supported, Promotions are merit based, Timely rewards for high performance, Appraisal reflects performance, Awards incentivize high performance, Accountability for results, Information regarding benefit changes *Control Variable: Gender, Minority

Turnover intention

2002 Federal Human Capital Survey (US)

Individual

Bright (2008)

PSM(Public Service Motivation) & P-O fit(Person-Organization fit) *Control Variable: Age, Minority status, Gender, Education, Years of public sector

Turnover intention & Job

Their own survey of public employees in Indiana,

Individual

21

experience satisfaction Kentucky, & Oregon (US) Lee &

Whitford (2008)

Organizational satisfaction, Voice, Loyalty, Pay *Control Variable: Benefits, Training, Merit promotion, Physical conditions, Race, Gender

Turnover intention

2002 Federal Human Capital Survey (US)

Individual

Meier & Hicklin (2008)

Teachers’ turnover rates *Control Variable: Resources (Teacher pay, Class size, State aid, Percentage of Noncertified teachers, Teachers with advanced degrees, Experienced teachers), Constraints (Poverty, Race)

Students’ Performance (test score)

Texas school districts’

survey (1994 – 2002, US)

School

Districts

Moynihan & Landuyt

(2008)

Individual characteristics (Primary earner, Household size, Age, Years in state of Texas, Agency experience, Education, Gender, Race), Job characteristics (Job satisfaction, Workload, Supervisor), HRM practices (Salary, Perception of fair pay, Benefits, Merit promotion, Family-friendly work practices, Diverse workforce practices, Employee development), Work environment (Loyalty, Empowerment, Voice)

Turnover Intention

Survey of state employees in Texas (2004, US)

Individual

Moynihan & Pandey

(2008)

Internal Social Network (Obligation toward coworkers, Coworker support), External Social Network, Person-Organization value fit *Control Variable: Job satisfaction, Age, Years in position, Nonprofit status

Turnover intention

(Short-term & Long-term)

Their own survey of 12 organizations in the

northeastern US (2005)

Individual

Choi (2009)

Race diversity, Sex diversity, Age diversity, Diversity management, Equal Employment Opportunity (EEO) complaints, Job satisfaction *Control Variable: Size, Tenure, Gender, Minority, Supervisory status

Turnover intention

Central Personnel Data File & 2004 Federal Human

Capital Survey (US)

Individual

Jung (2010)

Goal ambiguity, Pay satisfaction, Interpersonal relationship, Merit promotion, Diversity policy, Workload satisfaction, Benefit satisfaction *Control Variable: Organizational size, Minority rates, Female rates

Turnover rates & Turnover

intention rates

Federal Human Capital Survey (2006, US)

Agency

Lee & Jimenez (2011)

Performance-based rewards system & Performance-supporting supervision *Control Variable: Work-related variables (job satisfaction, training, job position, year of employment, salary, union membership) & Socio demographic variables (gender, age, race)

Turnover Intention

2005 Merit Principles

Survey (US)

Individual

Lee & Hong

(forthcoming)

Paid Leave for Family Care, Child Care Subsidy, Telecommuting, Alternative Work Schedule *Control Variable: Pay Satisfaction, Training Satisfaction, Physical Conditions Satisfaction

Turnover rates

Federal Human Resources Data (OPM, 2005, 2007), Federal Human Capital

Survey (2004, 2006, US)

Agency

22

23

Table 2: Intent to Leave (Weighted)

Intent 2008 2010 Do Not Intend to Leave 74.63 75.42 Intend to Retire 6.07 6.81 Intend to Leave for Another Agency 17.01 16.03 Intend to Leave Federal Government 2.29 1.75

24

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics (Weighted)

2008 2010 Mean SD Mean SD

Organizational Satisfaction 3.510 1.074 3.721 1.010 Voice 3.502 0.902 3.601 0.892 Loyalty 3.436 1.000 3.651 0.942 Pay 3.564 1.070 3.646 1.082 Merit Promotion 2.969 1.183 3.049 1.161 Physical Conditions 3.679 1.076 3.722 1.073 Benefits 3.223 0.725 3.255 0.729 Training 3.480 0.910 3.513 0.962 Race 0.138 0.391 Gender 0.337 0.413 Age Stratum 1 0.042 0.061 Age Stratum 2 0.177 0.167 Age Stratum 3 0.303 0.291 Age Stratum 4 0.397 0.349 Age Stratum 5 0.081 0.132 Status Stratum 1 0.759 0.799 Status Stratum 2 0.236 0.126 Status Stratum 3 0.005 0.075 N 120547

494292

22

23

Table 4: Model of Intention to Leave (Exit) for 2008 Data (Weighted): Comparison of Effects by Exit Option

Retirement Inside Federal Government Outside Federal Government RRR SE RRR SE RRR SE

Organizational Satisfaction 0.738 0.014 *** 0.690 0.011 *** 0.623 0.019 *** Voice 0.966 0.022 0.759 0.014 *** 0.639 0.022 *** Loyalty 0.895 0.020 *** 0.888 0.017 *** 0.954 0.034 Pay 1.088 0.014 *** 0.828 0.008 *** 0.687 0.012 *** Merit Promotion 0.987 0.014 0.860 0.010 *** 0.881 0.021 *** Physical Conditions 0.948 0.011 *** 1.071 0.010 *** 1.046 0.019 * Benefits 1.061 0.021 ** 0.960 0.014 ** 0.786 0.021 *** Training 1.137 0.020 *** 0.906 0.013 *** 1.013 0.026 Race 1.004 0.041 1.466 0.047 *** 0.417 0.035 *** Gender 0.692 0.019 *** 1.031 0.026 0.610 0.031 *** Age Stratum 2 1.41x107 1.09x1010 0.849 0.038 0.882 0.086 *** Age Stratum 3 2.56x107 1.98x1010 0.520 0.023 *** 0.417 0.041 Age Stratum 4 3.46x108 2.68x1011 0.264 0.012 *** 0.365 0.036 *** Age Stratum 5 1.04x109 8.05x1011 0.130 0.010 *** 0.232 0.031 *** Status Stratum 2 1.262 0.033 *** 1.249 0.032 *** 1.426 0.071 *** Status Stratum 3 1.186 0.162 0.774 0.226 9.172 1.567 *** Agency-Specific Effects Included N 120547 LR χ2 36552.26 *** Log-Likelihood -73338.0 Pseudo R2 0.1995

*** indicates significant at better than 0.001 (two-tailed test) ** indicates significant at better than 0.01 (two-tailed test) * indicates significant at better than 0.05 (two-tailed test)

22

23

REFERENCES

Angle, Harold L., and James L. Perry. 1981. An empirical assessment of organizational commitment and organizational effectiveness. Administrative Science Quarterly 26:1–13.

Ashour, Ahmed Sakr. 1982. A framework of a cognitive-behavior theory of leader influence and

effectiveness. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 30 (3): 407-430. Bertelli, Anthony. M. 2007. Determinants of bureaucratic turnover intention: Evidence from the

Department of the Treasury. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 17 (2): 235-258.

Blau, Francine D. and Kahn, Lawrence M. 1981. Race and sex differences in quits by young

workers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 34 (4): 563-577. Bozeman, Dennis P. and Pamela L. Perrewé. 2001. The effect of item content overlap on

organizational commitment questionnaire - turnover cognitions relationships. Journal of Applied Psychology 86 (1): 161-173.

Brehm, John and Scott Gates. 1997. Working, Shirking, and Sabotage: Bureaucratic Response to

a Democratic Public. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Brinkerhoff, Merlin B. 1972. Hierarchical status, contingencies, and the administrative staff

conference. Administrative Science Quarterly 17(3): 395-407. Burgess, Simon. 1998. Analyzing firms, jobs, and turnover. Monthly Labor Review 121 (7): 55-

57. Conger, Jay A. and Rabindra N. Kanungo. 1988. The empowerment process: Integrating theory

and practice. Academy of Management Review 13 (3): 471-482. Cooper, M. R., B. S. Morgan, P. M. Foley, and L. B. Kaplan. 1979. Changing employee values:

Deepening discontent? Harvard Business Review 57 (1): 117-125. Cotton, John L. and Jeffrey M. Tuttle. 1986. Employee turnover: A meta-analysis and review

with implications for research. Academy of Management Review 11 (1): 55-70. Cranny, C. J., Patricia Cain Smith, and Eugene F. Stone. 1992. Job satisfaction: How people feel

about their jobs and how it affects their performance. San Francisco, CA: New Lexington Press.

Daley, Dennis. M. 1992. When bureaucrats get the blues: A replication and extension of the

Rusbult and Lowery analysis of federal employee responses to job dissatisfaction. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 2 (3): 233-246.

24

Datcher, Linda. 1983. The impact of informal networks of quit behavior. Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (3): 491-495.

Deci, Edward L. 1975. Intrinsic Motivation. New York: Plenum. Dowding, Keith, Peter John, Thanos Mergoupis, and Mark Van Vugt. 2000. Exit, voice and

loyalty: Analytic and empirical developments. European Journal of Political Research 37 (4): 469-475.

Driscoll, James W. 1978. Trust and participation in organizational decision making as predictors

of satisfaction. Academy of Management Journal 21 (1): 44-56. Durst, Samantha L. 1999. Assessing the effect of family-friendly programs on public

organizations. Review of Public Personnel Administration 19 (3): 19-33. Eby, Lillian T., Deena M. Freeman, Michael C. Rush, and Charles E. Lance. 1999. Motivational

biases of affective organizational commitment: A partial test of an integrative theoretical model. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology 72 (4): 463-483.

Ezra, Marni and Melissa Deckman. 1996. Balancing work and family responsibilities: Flextime

and childcare in the federal government. Public Administration Review 56 (2): 174-179. Farrell, Dan. 1983. Exit, voice, loyalty, and neglect as responses to job dissatisfaction: A

multidimensional scaling study. Academy of Management Journal 26 (4): 596–607. Fehr, Ernst, Simon Gächter, and Georg Kirchsteiger. 1997. Reciprocity as a contract

enforcement device. Econometrica 65 (4): 833-860. Freeman, Richard B. 1976. Individual mobility and union voice in the labor market. American

Economic Review 66 (2): 361–368. Freeman, Richard B. 1980. The exit-voice tradeoff in the labor market: Unionism, job tenure,

quits and separations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 94 (4): 643–673. Freeman, Richard B. and James L. Medoff. 1984. What do Unions Do? New York: Basic Books. Frey, Bruno S. 1997. Not Just For the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation.

Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Frey, Bruno S. and Reto Jegen. 2001. Motivation crowding theory. Journal of Economic Surveys

15 (5): 589-611. Frey, Bruno S. and Margit Osterloh, Eds. 2002. Successful Management by Motivation -

Balancing Intrinsic and Extrinsic Incentives. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

25

Frey, Bruno S. and Margit Osterloh. 2005. Yes, managers should be paid like bureaucrats. Journal of Management Inquiry 14 (1): 96-111.

Gray-Toft, Pamela and James G. Anderson. 1981. Stress among hospital nursing staff: Its causes

and effects. Social Science and Medicine 15 (5): 639-647. Golembiewski, Robert T. 1986. OD perspectives on high performance: Some good news and

some bad news about merit pay. Review of Public Personnel Administration 7 (1): 9-26. Haber, Sheldon E., Enrique J. Lamas, and Gordon Green. 1983. A new method for estimating job

separations by sex and race. Monthly Labor Review 106 (6): 20-27. Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,

Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hom, Peter W., Rodger W. Griffeth and C. Louise Sellaro. 1984. The validity of Mobley’s

(1977) model of employee turnover. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 34 (2): 141-174.

Huselid, Mark A. 1995. The impact of human resources management practices on turnover,

productivity, and corporate financial performance. Academy of Management Journal 38 (3): 635-672.

Ingraham, Patricia W. 1984. The Civil Service Reform Act of 1978: Its design and legislative

history. In Legislative Bureaucratic Change: The Civil Service Reform Act of 1978, ed. P.W. Ingraham and C. Ban. Albany: State University of New York Press.

Ingraham, Patricia W. and Peter W. Colby. 1982. Political reform and government management:

The case of the Senior Executive Service. Policy Studies Journal 11 (2): 304-317. Ingraham, Patricia Wallace, Selden, Sally Coleman, and Moynihan, Donald P. 2000. People and

performance: Challenges for the future public service - the report from the Wye river conference. Public Administration Review 60 (1): 54-60.

Kellough, J. Edward and Will Osuna. 1995. Cross-agency comparisons of quit rates in the

federal service: Another look at the evidence. Review of Public Personnel Administration 15 (4): 58-68.

Kim, Marlene. 1999. Where the grass is greener: Voluntary turnover and wage premiums.

Industrial Relations 38 (4): 584-603. King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg. 2000. Making the most of statistical analyses:

Improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science 44 (2): 341-355.

26

Koh, Hian Chye. and Chye Tee Goh. 1995. An analysis of the factors affecting the turnover intention of non-managerial clerical staff: A Singapore study. The International Journal of Human Resource Management 6 (1): 103-125.

Larson Jr., James R. 1986. Supervisors’ performance feedback to subordinates: The role of

subordinate performance valence and outcome dependence. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 37 (3): 391-408.

Lawler, Edward E. 1971. Pay and Organizational Effectiveness: A Psychological View. New

York: McGraw-Hill. Leonard, Jonathan S. 1987. Carrots and sticks: pay, supervision, and turnover. Journal of Labor

Economics 5 (4): s136-s152. Lewis, Gregory B. 1991. Turnover and the quiet crisis in the federal civil service. Public

Administration Review 51 (2): 145-155. Lewis, Gregory B. and Kyungho Park. 1989. Turnover in federal white collar employment: Are

women more likely to quit than men? American Review of Public Administration 19 (1): 13-28.

Liden, Robert C., Sandy J. Wayne, and Raymond T. Sparrowe. 2000. An examination of the

mediating role of psychological empowerment on the relations between the job, interpersonal relationships, and work outcomes. Journal of Applied Psychology 85 (3): 407-416.

Locke, Edwin A. and Gary P. Latham. 1990. A Theory of Goal Setting and Task Performance.

Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Lyman, Elizabeth L. 1955. Occupational differences in the value attached to work. American

Journal of Sociology 61 (2): 138-144. Mathieu, John E. and Dennis M. Zajac. 1990. A review and meta-analysis of the antecedents,

correlates, and consequences of organizational commitment. Psychological Bulletin 108 (2): 171–194.

Meitzen, Mark E. 1986. Differences in male and female job-quitting behavior. Journal of Labor

Economics 4 (2): 151-167. Menon, Sanjay T. 2001. Employee empowerment: An integrative psychological approach.

Applied Psychology: An International Review 50 (1): 153-180. Meyer, Herbert H. 1975. The pay-for-performance dilemma. Organizational Dynamics 3 (3): 39-

50.

27

Miller, Gary J. and Andrew B. Whitford. 2002. Trust and incentives in principal-agent negotiations: The insurance-incentive trade-off. Journal of Theoretical Politics 14 (2): 231-267.

Miller, Gary J. and Andrew B. Whitford. 2007. The Principal’s Moral Hazard: Constraints on the

Use of Incentives in Hierarchy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory. 17 (2): 213-233.

Mobley, William H. 1977. Intermediate linkages in the relationship between job satisfaction and

employee turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology 62 (2): 237-240. Mowday, Richard T., Richard M. Steers, and Lyman W. Porter. 1979. The measurement of

organizational commitment. Journal of Vocational Behavior 14 (2): 224–247. Muchinsky, Paul M. and Paula C. Morrow. 1980. A multidimensional model of voluntary

employee turnover. Journal of Vocational Behavior 17 (3): 263-290. Mumford, Michael D. 1986. Leadership in the organizational context. Journal of Applied social

Psychology 16 (6): 508-531. Murphy, William H. and Linda Gorchels. 1996. How to improve product management

effectiveness. Industrial Marketing Management 25 (1): 47-58. Newman, Meredith and Kay Mathews. 1999. Federal family-friendly work-place policies.

Review of Public Personnel Administration 19 (3): 34-48. O’Driscoll, Michael P. and Terry A. Beehr. 1994. Supervisor behaviors, role stressors and

uncertainty as predictors of personal outcomes for subordinates. Journal of Organizational Behavior 15 (2): 141-155.

Oldham, Greg R. and Yitzhak Fried. 1987. Employee reactions to workspace characteristics.

Journal of Applied Psychology 72 (1): 75-80. Osterman, Paul. 1987. Turnover, employment security, and the performance of the firm. In M.

M. Kleiner, R. N. Block, M. Roomkin, and S. W. Salsburg (Eds.), Human Resources and the Performance of the Firm. Madison, WI: Industrial Relations Research Association.

Ostroff, Cheri. 1992. The relationship between satisfaction, attitudes, and performance: An

organizational level analysis. Journal of Applied Psychology 77 (6): 963-974. Perrow, Charles. 1986. Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay. New York: Random House. Perry, James L. 2003. Compensation, merit pay, and motivation. In S. W. Hays and R. C.

Kearney (Eds.), Public Personnel Administration: Problems and Prospects. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

28

Park, Hong Y., Joseph Jo Ofori-Dankwa, and Deborah R. Bishop. 1994 “Organizational and environmental determinants of functional and dysfunctional turnover: Practical and research implications. Human Relations 47 (3): 353-366.

Pierce, Jon L., Stephen A. Rubenfield, and Susan Morgan. 1991. Employee ownership: A

conceptual model of process and effect. Academy of Management Review 16 (1): 121-144. Powell, Irene, Mark Montgomery, and James Cosgrove. 1994. Compensation structure and

establishment quit and fire rates. Industrial Relations 33 (2): 229-248. Price, James L. 1977. The Study of Turnover. Ames: The Iowa State University Press. Rainey, Hal G. 2003. Understanding & Managing Public Organizations. Third edition. San

Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Rita, Mano-Negrin and Alan Kirschenbaum. 1999. Push and pull factor in medical employees’

turnover decisions: The effect of a careerist approach and organizational benefits on the decision to leave the job. The International Journal of Human Resource Management 10 (4): 689-702.

Rosse, Joseph G., and Howard E. Miller. 1984. Relationships between absenteeism and other

employee behaviors. In P.S. Goodman and R.S. Atkin (Eds.), Absenteeism. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

Rousseau, Denise M. 1978. Characteristics of departments, positions, and individuals: Contexts

for attitudes and behavior. Administrative Science Quarterly 23(4): 521-540. Rousseau, Denise M. 1995. Psychological Contracts in Organizations: Understanding Written

and Unritten Agreements. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Rusbult, Caryl E. and Dan Farrell. 1983. A longtitudinal test of the investment model: The

impact on job satisfaction, job commitment, and turnover of variations in rewards, costs, alternatives and investments. Journal of Applied Psychology 68 (3): 429-438.

Rusbult, Caryl E. and David Lowery. 1985. When bureaucrats get the blues. Journal of Applied

Social Psychology 15 (1): 80-103. Rusbult, Caryl E., Isabella M. Zembrodt, and Lawanna K. Gunn. 1982. Exit, voice, loyalty, and

neglect: responses to dissatisfaction in romantic involvements. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 43 (6): 1230-1242.

Selden, Sally Coleman and Donald P. Moynihan. 2000. A model of voluntary turnover in state

government. Review of Public Personnel Administration 20 (2): 63-74.

29

Shaw, Jason D., John E. Delery, G. Douglas Jenkins, Jr., and Nina Gupta. 1998. An organization-level analysis of voluntary and involuntary turnover. Academy of Management Journal 41 (5): 511-525.

Shields, Michael A. and Stephen Wheatley Price. 2002. Racial harassment, job satisfaction and

intentions to quit: Evidence from the British nursing profession. Economica 69 (274): 295-326.

Spreitzer, Gretchen M. 1995. Psychological empowerment in the workplace: dimensions,

measurement, and validation. Academy of Management Journal 38 (5): 1442-1465. Spreitzer, Gretchen M. 1996. Social structural characteristics of psychological empowerment.

Academy of Management Journal 39 (2): 483-504. Steel, Robert P., and Nestor K. Ovalle II. 1984. A review and meta-analysis of research on the

relationship between behavioral intentions and employee turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology 69 (4): 673-686.

Steers, Richard M. 1977. Antecedents and outcomes of organizational commitment.

Administrative Science Quarterly 22(1): 46-56. Steers, Richard M. and Richard T. Mowday. 1981. Employee turnover and post-decision

accommodation processes. In L. L. Cummings and B. M. Staw (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 1. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Stillman, Richard J. 2004. The American Bureaucracy: The Core of Modern Government.

Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Thomson Learning. Tett, Robert P. and John P. Meyer. 1993. Job satisfaction, organizational commitment, turnover

intention, and turnover: Path analyses based on meta-analytic findings. Personnel Psychology 46 (2): 259-293.

Thomas, Kenneth W. and Betty A. Velthouse. 1990. Cognitive elements of empowerment: An

interpretive model of intrinsic task motivation. Academy of Management Review 15 (4): 666-681.

Tjosvold, Dean. 1984. Effects of leader warmth and directiveness on subordinate performance on

a subsequent task. Journal of Applied Psychology 69 (3): 422-427. U.S. Office of Personnel Management. 2006. The Handbook of Elder Care Resources for the

Federal Workplace. Available at: http://www.opm.gov/Employment_and_Benefits/WorkLife/OfficialDocuments/HandbooksGuides/ElderCareResources/index.asp

Utgoff, Kathleen Classen. 1983. Compensation levels and quit rates in the public sector. The

Journal of Human Resources 18 (3): 394-406.

30

van Breukelen, Wim, René van der Vlist, and Herman Steensma. 2004. Voluntary employee

turnover combining variables from the traditional turnover literature with the theory of planned behavior. Journal of Organizational Behavior 25 (7): 893-914.

Waterman, Richard W and Kenneth J. Meier. 1998. Principal-agent models: An expansion?

Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 8 (2): 173-202. Weiss, Andrew. 1984. Determinants of quit behavior. Journal of Labor Economics 2 (3): 371-

387. Wiener, Yoash and Yoav Vardi. 1980. Relationships between job, organization, and career

commitments and work outcomes: An integrative approach. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 26 (1): 81-96.

Williams, Larry J. and John T. Hazer. 1986. Antecedents and consequences of satisfaction and

commitment in turnover models: A reanalysis using latent variable structural equation methods. Journal of Applied Psychology 71 (2): 219-231.

Withey, Michael J. and William H. Cooper. 1989. Predicting exit, voice, loyalty and neglect.

Administrative Science Quarterly 34 (4): 521–539. Zax, Jeffrey S. 1989. Quits and race. Journal of Human Resources 24 (3): 469-493.