41
Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism for Shifting Risk? Frederick L. Bereskin Assistant Professor Department of Finance Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716 [email protected] Helen Bowers Associate Professor Department of Finance Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716 [email protected] September 8, 2015 Abstract A poison put, also referred to as an event-risk or change-in-control covenant, gives the bondholder the option of redeeming the bond before maturity if a specified event occurs, such as a change in control. We investigate the association of poison puts with corporate governance and their effects on firms’ merger activity. We do not find evidence that poison puts are associated with weaker governance. Rather, our evidence is most consistent with poison put issuance being driven by efficient contracting for bondholders, as opposed to managerial entrenchment. However, we also find that firms that issue poison puts are less likely to be either acquirers or targets, even though these firms are more likely to be in industries with acquisition activity. Other findings are consistent with an explanation based on efficient contracting issues with poison puts exhibit other characteristics that we would also expect for bondholders who are concerned about potential risk-shifting such as shorter maturity, higher treasury spreads, and significantly more covenants.

Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

Poison Puts:

Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism for Shifting Risk?

Frederick L. Bereskin

Assistant Professor

Department of Finance

Lerner College of Business & Economics

University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716

[email protected]

Helen Bowers

Associate Professor

Department of Finance

Lerner College of Business & Economics

University of Delaware, Newark, DE 19716

[email protected]

September 8, 2015

Abstract

A poison put, also referred to as an event-risk or change-in-control covenant, gives the

bondholder the option of redeeming the bond before maturity if a specified event occurs,

such as a change in control. We investigate the association of poison puts with corporate

governance and their effects on firms’ merger activity. We do not find evidence that poison

puts are associated with weaker governance. Rather, our evidence is most consistent with

poison put issuance being driven by efficient contracting for bondholders, as opposed to

managerial entrenchment. However, we also find that firms that issue poison puts are less

likely to be either acquirers or targets, even though these firms are more likely to be in

industries with acquisition activity. Other findings are consistent with an explanation based

on efficient contracting – issues with poison puts exhibit other characteristics that we would

also expect for bondholders who are concerned about potential risk-shifting – such as

shorter maturity, higher treasury spreads, and significantly more covenants.

Page 2: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

1

1 Introduction

Poison puts (also referred to as proxy puts, change in control, or event risk covenants)

give bondholders the right, but not the obligation, to redeem their bonds if a change in control

occurs. These covenants give bondholders a put option requiring the issuer to offer to purchase

all of the bonds (typically at 101% of par), when changes in control occur.1 Poison puts have

traditionally been seen as the result of efficient contracting by bondholders to minimize their

agency costs by protecting against risk-shifting from highly levered transactions or being

acquired by firms with lower debt ratings. The effectiveness of covenants in this context has

been studied by Asquith and Wizman (1990). They found that even though, on average, the

bondholders of successful leveraged buyouts and restructurings over the period 1980-1988

experienced negative returns, bonds with relatively strong covenant protection gained value.

Asquith and Wizman’s (1990) results also show that the covenants that were most effective in

increasing bond value during this period functioned similarly to poison puts because the increase

in bond value was related to those bonds being more likely to be called than unprotected bonds.

The 2014 acquisition of Tim Hortons Inc. by Burger King Worldwide Inc. is a more

recent example of the use of poison puts for efficient contracting by bondholders. Burger King’s

debt was rated five levels below Tim Hortons’ investment grade debt. However, instead of

experiencing a loss due to a ratings downgrade resulting from the acquisition, Tim Hortons’

1 Specifically, changes in control are generally defined as one or more of the following events: 1) any person or

group acquires 50% or more the issuer’s voting stock; 2) any time the majority of the board of directors ceases to be

those who were directors at the time of issuance (continuing directors) or directors whose election was approved by

a majority of the continuing directors (related to this are the notion of “dead hand” proxy puts; without the “dead

hand” feature, board can approve the dissident slate of directors to avoid triggering the put – see Reindel (2015) for

more detail); 3) the merger or consolidation of the company into another entity; 4) the sale, in one or a series of

related transactions, of all or substantially all of the company’s assets; or 5) the adoption of a plan to dissolve or

liquidate the company. Some poison put covenants include a “double trigger” where the change in control event

must be associated with a ratings downgrade.

Page 3: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

2

bondholders were protected by poison puts that allowed them to redeem their issues at a slight

premium to par.2

However, poison puts, like any anti-takeover defensive measure can also serve to

entrench management. A recent New York Times article suggests that management is active in

placing poison put covenants in indenture agreements for the purpose of entrenchment

(Solomon, 2014). Poison puts are described as “tools companies use to forestall shareholder

activists and hostile takeovers.” This argument places poison puts in the corporate governance

arena as a mechanism of circumventing shareholder rights. Poison puts cause an additional

concern because they are debt covenants and therefore, unlike poison pills, sidestep scrutiny as a

takeover defense that could impinge on the shareholder franchise. Inclusion of a poison put in a

debt covenant entails less conflict among shareholders than putting poison pill provisions in

place – and are generally implemented without shareholder votes. Consequently, poison puts are

an example of an “unregulable” takeover defense (Arlen and Talley, 2003) in that they can be

imposed through contractual arrangements, and difficult to pinpoint as purely entrenching.

Moreover, in contrast to poison pills, poison puts have the potential to significantly harm the

firm, and not merely the acquirer. As a result of their potential for significant damage to the firm,

their ability to be imposed without shareholder scrutiny, and their widespread and increasing use,

it is important to understand their implications in greater detail.

Decisions in two seminal cases in the Delaware Chancery Court, San Antonio Fire &

Police Pension Fund v. Pharmaceuticals, Inc.3 and Kallick v. SandRidge Energy,4 dealt with

2 C. Gutscher, “Tim Hortons poison put leaves creditors with indigestion”, BloombergBusiness, Aug 27, 2014,

Retrieved http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-08-27/tim-hortons-put-leaves-holders-with-indigestion-

canada-credit on Mar 2, 2015. 3 San Antonio Fire and Police Pension Fund v. Amylin Pharms., Inc. 983 A.2d 304 (Del. Ch. 2009). 4 Kallick v. Sandridge Energy, Inc.68 A.3d 242 (Del. Ch. 2013).

Page 4: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

3

boards of directors’ responsibilities to protect stockholders from possible entrenchment effects

around triggering events in poison put covenants. Both cases were decided on narrow grounds,

but Byeff (2015) argues that because those poison puts that were triggered by the replacement of

the majority of the company’s continuing directors, that poison puts can “have both the motive

and effect of entrenching incumbent directors” and “that board entrenchment purposes had

trumped potential agency cost reduction.”5 Although not endorsing the argument that poison

puts exist solely to entrench management, the Delaware Chancery Court’s 2013 decision in

Kallick recognizes that management can adopt them solely for that purpose. The Kallick

decision states that, in light of the potential entrenching effects of poison puts, companies should

strenuously bargain to exclude puts and accept them only in exchange for significant economic

benefits and charges independent directors to monitor poison puts to ensure that they are not

being adopted solely as entrenchment devices.

Another avenue through which poison puts may entrench management is by discouraging

activist investors. Reporting on bank loans, Hoffman (2015) states that “nearly 200 companies

have struck new loan agreements since the beginning of 2014” that include poison put

provisions. He argues that the increase in activist investors, particularly hedge funds,

necessitates poison puts to protect lenders from the debt-financed buybacks, dividends, and

restructurings, favored by such investors, which deteriorate credit. Poison puts are a unique

means of entrenchment, because debtholders can argue that it is in their economic interest to

know their borrowers and have faith that the business plan at the time of the issue will continue

for the life of the loan. The increased focus given to poison puts in the courts and the popular

press is understandable – despite their widespread attention in the early 1990s, their use has

5 See Byeff (2015) pp. 375 and 415.

Page 5: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

4

become significantly more common in recent years. For example, poison puts were included in

over half of our sample debt issues in 2012, compared to a range of 8.1%-27.4% of debt issues in

our sample in the 1990s.

The purpose of our study is to investigate the association of poison puts with corporate

governance and their effects on acquisition activity. We examine these two, non-mutually

exclusive motivations for the inclusion of the poison put covenants. Poison puts could: (1)

increase the agency costs associated with acquisitions, by potentially enhancing managerial

entrenchment; or (2) protect bondholders from risk-shifting and associated wealth transfers that

could result from acquisitions (i.e., efficient contracting).

We do not find evidence that poison puts are associated with weaker governance.6 In

particular, firms with bonds that have poison puts are more likely to have the characteristics of

firms with strong corporate governance. Firms with bonds that have poison put covenants have

slightly higher levels of institutional ownership, are less likely to have poison pills, and are no

more or less likely to have classified boards. However, we also find that firms with bonds that

have poison puts are more likely to be incorporated outside of Delaware7 and are less likely to be

either acquirers or targets, even though these firms are more likely to be in industries with

acquisition activity. Consistent with an explanation based on efficient contracting, issues with

poison puts exhibit other characteristics that we would also expect for bondholders who are

concerned about potential risk-shifting. In particular, issues with poison put covenants tend to

have shorter maturities and higher treasury spreads (thus reflecting the risk), and significantly

more covenants – both bondholder-protective covenants and issuer-restrictive. Our multivariate

6 We define governance as “weak” or “strong” from the shareholder’s perspective, in terms of shareholder rights. 7 Daines (2001) notes that firms incorporated in Delaware are more vulnerable to takeovers.

Page 6: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

5

results confirm these findings, in that firms with more contracting-issues (both issue-specific and

firm-specific) are more likely to include poison puts in their bonds. In contrast, we find no

evidence of these firms having weaker corporate governance or being more prone to managerial

entrenchment aside from entrenchment caused by the poison put itself. It is worth stressing that

the additional covenants that are present among bonds with poison puts are particularly

consistent with protection to bondholders from acquisition-related risk-shifting (as one would

expect from the contracting-based explanation), as opposed to manager-specific and board-

specific restrictions on their investment activity and dividend policy.

An alternative explanation for the generally strong governance of firms with poison puts

is that these covenants could be one of the few means of entrenchment for these types of firms.

Poison puts are not voted on by shareholders, and their effects are not widely understood,

compared to other means of entrenchment.

We then examine the effects of poison puts, in contrast to their motivation, and analyze

our data in the context of acquisition activity. Poison puts appear to matter in that firms that had

bonds with poison puts are less likely to be either acquirers or targets. Similarly, our regression

results confirm that these firms are more likely to be in industries with acquisition activity.

Together, these results suggest that bonds are more likely to contain poison puts if the issuing

firms are more prone to acquisitions and in industries experiencing consolidation. Combined

with our earlier results on governance and these firms’ contracting environments, our findings

are consistent with these firms’ use of poison puts being driven by bondholders’ risk-shifting

concerns. The effects of the firms experiencing fewer acquisition activity are also consistent with

poison puts having an entrenchment effect.

Page 7: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

6

Nonetheless, we are unable to find consistent evidence that firms without poison puts

experience more risk-shifting. This is not to say that poison puts are not effective at mitigating

risk-shifting. One may expect that other firms mitigate risk-shifting and protect bondholders in

other ways, whereas the type of firm that adopts poison puts does so out of limited alternative

mechanisms.

Our results have a number of interesting implications. First, we contribute to the literature

by focusing on the governance implications and determinants of poison puts, which are not

widely studied despite their widespread use and potential agency problems. Given our findings

that firms issuing bonds with poison puts have reasonable shareholder governance and no

significantly higher levels of managerial entrenchment (beyond the poison puts themselves), our

results help explain why poison puts remain so prevalent. Moreover, their increased use may in

part be driven by improved shareholder protection, to the degree that bondholders are more

concerned about risk-shifting occurring.

Our paper also presents evidence that firms are not opportunistically employing poison

puts to position themselves as stronger acquirers. In contrast, poison puts are used by firms in

consolidating industries that wish to avoid acquisition activity in general, which admittedly could

also reflect an entrenchment effect. Poison puts are a manifestation of an environment in firms

that have a unique contracting environment with bondholders, managers, and other parties.

Finally, our lack of evidence of risk-shifting occurring is consistent with poison puts not being

detrimental to bondholders. At the very least, they appear to offer a mechanism to protect

bondholders who would otherwise not have credible forms of commitment.

Page 8: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

7

Our study also contributes to the broader literature of creditors’ role in corporate

governance, and the mechanism by which their involvement occurs.8 Moreover, whereas other

studies may focus on how particular covenants alleviate the bondholder-shareholder conflict,

poison puts also highlight the shareholder-manager conflicts as well.

Our paper continues as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the related literature, and build

on it to develop our hypotheses. We review our data set and results in Section 3. Concluding

remarks follow in Section 4.

2 Literature Review

2.1 Pricing and value effects of poison puts on stockholders and bondholders

The seminal work on poison put bonds dates to Crabbe (1991) and Cook and Easterwood

(1994). Crabbe (1991) finds that over the period 1983-1988, the inclusion of event-risk

protection reduced borrowing cost by approximately 20 to 30 basis points. Although his

evidence is consistent with bondholders valuing these covenants, he also finds evidence that this

effect declined with the reduction in corporate restructurings towards the end of his sample

period.9 Cook and Easterwood (1994) compare the wealth effects on the existing debt and equity

of firms issuing debt with poison put covenants with firms issuing debt without poison puts

during 1988 and 1989. For issuers of poison put debt, stockholders experience an abnormal

8 For example, recent studies have examined creditors’ role on the board of directors (Santos and Rumble, 2006),

information intermediation (Ivashina et al., 2009), or focused on creditors’ role among firms experiencing financial

distress (Baird and Rasmussen, 2006; Chava and Roberts, 2008; Ayotte and Morrison, 2009; Roberts and Sufi,

2009; Nini, Smith, and Sufi, 2012). 9 Crabbe (1991) restricts his sample to bond issues with “super poison put” covenants. In the more recent literature

this type of put is usually described as having a “double trigger” where the change in control event must be

associated with a ratings downgrade.

Page 9: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

8

return of negative 70 basis points, while existing bondholders experience a positive abnormal

return of 52 basis points. There is no wealth reaction for stockholders and existing bondholders

associated with non-poison put debt. Cook and Easterwood’s (1994) evidence is consistent with

the “mutual interest” hypothesis that poison puts protect both managers and bondholders, at the

expense of shareholders.

Torabzadeh, Roufagalas and Woodruff (2000) find, in a sample spanning 1986 through

1990, that the inclusion of a poison put reduced yields by 58 to 79 basis points. Using a case

study approach, Okamoto, Pedersen, and Pedersen (2011) exploit court decisions regarding the

buyout of Bell Canada Enterprises to show that poison puts are, indeed, priced by the market.

2.2 Returns for change of control events and risk-shifting

Billett, Jiang, and Lie (2010) study the effect of poison puts on leveraged buyouts over

the period 1980-2006. In particular, they show that upon the announcement of a leveraged

buyout, bondholders with poison puts experience average wealth effects of 2.3%; this compares

to -6.8% for bonds without poison puts. Additionally, they find that poison puts reduce the

probability of being targeted in both LBO and non-LBO takeovers. Their results are also

consistent with Asquith and Wizman’s (1990) results concerning LBOs occurring between 1980

and 1988. They found that the buyout announcement return for bonds with strong covenant

protection is 2.6%; this compares to announcement returns of -0.7% for bonds with weak

protection and -5.2% for those with no protective covenants.

Billett, King, and Mauer (2004) study acquisitions between 1979 and 1997; although the

magnitude of their results is not as large as those found for leverage buyouts, they conclude that

there is a coinsurance effect or risk-shifting associated with acquisitions. They find that returns

Page 10: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

9

for target bondholders are significantly higher when the target’s debt rating is below the

acquirer’s, when the combination is expected to decrease leverage for the target, and when the

target’s maturity is shorter. Overall, they find an abnormal return on announcement for target

bondholders of 1.09%. However, for targets’ debt rated below investment grade, the

announcement return the announcement abnormal return is 4.30%. The abnormal announcement

return for acquirer bondholders is -0.17%, and there is no significant difference between

investment grade and non-investment grade debt.

Lehn and Poulsen (1991) conclude that the use of event-risk covenants, such as poison

puts, was the response to the risk-shifting and consequent large losses experiences by target

firms in LBOs. They found that alternative defenses against risk-shifting, such as hedging and

the use of convertible debt, did not increase after the buy-outs and restructurings of the 1980s.

2.3 Firm characteristics of issuers with poison puts

Nash, Netter, and Poulsen (2003) find that firms with high-investment opportunities were

more likely to issue bonds with poison puts in 1989 than in 1996. Their results show that firms

that have bond issues with poison put covenants tend to have lower interest coverage ratios, and

that non-investment grade debt is not driven by firms’ investment opportunities – rather, it is

largely driven by the likelihood of financial distress. Their evidence is consistent with bond

contracts being carefully negotiated, depending on the firm’s and investors’ goals, as opposed to

being “boilerplate” documents.

The use of covenants (such as poison put covenants) is positively associated with growth

opportunities, debt maturity, and leverage, consistent with firms using covenants to address

potential conflicts between stockholders and bondholders over growth option exercise (Billett,

Page 11: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

10

King, and Mauer, 2007) or bondholder risk driven by strong shareholder control (Cremers, Nair,

and Wei, 2007).

In contrast, Chava, Kumar, and Warga (2010) note the role of managerial agency costs,

and emphasize the degree that these agency issues can mitigate the bondholder-shareholder

conflict, to the degree that managerial entrenchment can occasionally benefit bondholders at the

expense of shareholders. Their evidence is consistent with the important role of agency issues;

although entrenchment increases the use of covenants to control for inefficient investment, it is

negatively associated with covenants on dividend payouts and accepting takeover offers. Qi,

Roth, and Wald (2011) use international data to establish results similar to Chava et al. (2010);

firms in countries with stronger shareholder control may have more severe shareholder-

bondholder conflicts, and thus prefer to use more covenants.

There are other reasons that firms may wish to employ poison put covenants. For

instance, Hege and Hennessy (2010) contribute to the literature examining why firms may wish

to issue debt with poison puts. They present evidence that the use of poison put covenants,

among other strategies, help an incumbent capture more of the surplus in the event of an

acquisition. In summary, the aforementioned papers present evidence that the effect of

entrenchment on the use of poison puts is unclear.

3 Data and Results

3.1 Data and sample statistics

Our data is collected from a number of sources. In particular, we use Mergent FISD as

our primary source of data for poison puts. We complement this data with Compustat for

Page 12: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

11

financial and accounting data, Thomson for institutional ownership data, RiskMetrics for certain

corporate governance measures, and SDC for acquisition data.

Given the low frequency of poison put issues prior to the 1990s, we begin our sample in

1990 and continue to 2012. In Panel A of Table 1, we provide the distribution of poison puts by

the percentage of bond issues and firm-years (of firms that issue bonds and with matching

Compustat data). This table reflects the large frequency of poison puts among our sample firms,

whether by bond-issuance activity or by firm-year. Our results highlight the relative resurgence

in the use of poison puts. For example, although their popularity diminished in the late 1990s

(i.e., to 8.1% of issues in 1998 and 11.3% of issues in 1999), their use significantly rebounded in

the later part of the last decade – by 2012, 56.8% of bond issues had poison put covenants. In

unscaled terms, 2012 was a record year, with 239 poison put issues and 172 firm-years where at

least one poison put was present in a bond. This is consistent with the use and prevalence of

poison puts not being diminished, despite more vigilant corporate governance over that period

that weakened many other aspects of entrenchment. The prominence of poison puts despite the

more rigorous recent governance environment would be consistent with poison puts reflecting

bondholders’ contracting demands, as opposed to a means of managerial entrenchment.

Alternatively, it is also plausible that poison puts are one of the few mechanisms of entrenchment

for otherwise well-governed firms – potentially due to shareholders’ limited ability to vote on

these covenants, or due to less shareholder scrutiny.

In Panel B of Table 1, we continue examining the characteristics of the sample poison put

firms by evaluating their relative prominence by Fama-French 48 industry group. This table

highlights the significant heterogeneity among firms’ industries, and reflects the importance of

industry characteristics in determining whether a firm is inclined to issue a bond with a poison

Page 13: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

12

put. Not surprisingly, among firms that are in industries with already prominent anti-takeover

protections – such as banking firms and utilities, due partly to government regulation – issuance

of bonds with poison puts is rare; for example, only 9.5% of issues in the financial industry and

15.1% in the utility industry contain poison puts. In contrast, among firms in industries with less

apparent anti-takeover protections (such as healthcare firms, construction firms, and business

services firms), issues with poison puts account for the majority of bond issues and of sample

firm-years; for example, poison puts are present in 76.3% of sample healthcare firms’ issues. The

results in this table are consistent with firms issuing poison puts if they are relatively more

vulnerable to a hostile acquisition, and not issuing these types of bonds when consolidation in the

industry is less frequent.

In Panel C, we examine the prevalence of poison puts by credit ratings. This table

highlights the weaker credit quality of firms that issue poison puts. Whereas highly-rated firms

seldom issue bonds with poison puts, their use becomes very common among firms with poorer

credit quality. For example, of firms A-rated and higher, our sample contains 208 issues with

poison puts, out of 2,723 total issues; in contrast, firms rated BB+, BB, or BB- issued 476 bonds

with poison puts, out of 652 total issues. This finding potentially reflects some of the contracting

regularities among lower-rated firms, and the notion that these firms’ creditors value the poison

puts (and, similarly, that issuing poison puts is less damaging to shareholder value for these firms

than for more highly-rated firms).

In conclusion, our results indicate that poison puts are common in general, and remain

prevalent in current bond issues. Firms appear more likely to issue poison puts if they are in

industries commonly associated with acquisition activity, and are less likely if they have other

safeguards in place to protect themselves and their bondholders from potentially risk-shifting

Page 14: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

13

acquisitions. Additionally, poison puts’ concentration among low-rated and non-investment

grade firms is consistent with contracting-based explanations for their use, as opposed to

governance-based explanations, since governance is not thought to be reliably associated with

credit ratings.

In Figure 1 and Table 2, we evaluate the percentage of firms’ issues represented by

poison puts, compared to non-poison put bonds. This is especially relevant for us to understand

whether firms’ poison put issuance reflects a more significant change in firms’ behavior, as

opposed to the decision to issue a bond with a poison put being a one-time decision unrelated to

the firm’s other bond issues. In Figure 1, we show that firms appear to establish a policy decision

of always issuing bonds with poison puts (851 firms) or never issuing bonds with poison puts

(847 firms). In contrast, there are a smaller number of firms (344 firms) with some, but not all,

issues containing a poison put – for 112 of those firms, poison put issues account for between

40% and 60% of their bond issues.

To examine whether those firms issuing only certain bonds with poison puts experienced

a policy shift when they began issuing these types of bonds, we study their issuance activity in

Panel B of Table 2. In this Panel, we show that there are a large number of issues that occur prior

to the firm’s first poison put issue, and a smaller number of issues that occur following the firm’s

last poison put issue. In contrast, during the time between the first and last issues with poison

puts, 76.7% of firms’ issues included bonds with poison puts. This is consistent with the decision

to issue bonds with poison puts as one that is deliberate and reflective of a general decision by

the firm to increase its anti-takeover protections. Additionally, the relatively small number of

issues that occur following the “last” poison put issue in our sample is consistent both with

firms’ reluctance to reduce their takeover protections once those protections are already in place,

Page 15: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

14

as well as new bondholders’ reluctance to accept covenants less favorable than those of prior

bondholders. Finally, the issuing activity that we note in this table supports the subsequent use in

our paper of an indicator variable equal to one if the firm had issued bonds with poison puts in

the prior five years – in general, use of poison puts in bonds tend to reflect a policy shift in firms’

covenants, as opposed to being temporary events that are not repeated.

In Table 3, we evaluate the sample statistics of our firms, to compare firm-years and bond

issues with poison puts to those without poison puts. In Panel A, we evaluate the differences in

means and medians of firm-years with at least one poison-put issue to those without a poison-put

issue (all firm-years are in our Mergent sample, and thus include firms that issued at least one

bond, to make the comparisons similar). Our results suggest that firms issuing bonds with poison

puts tend to be smaller (median sales of $1.7 billion, compared to $4.9 billion for the control

sample), have a higher market-to-book (median of 1.4, compared to the control sample’s 1.2),

and have more leverage (37%, compared to the control sample’s 31%). The differences in means

and medians for these two groups’ values of sales, market-to-book, and leverage are statistically

significant. The differences in these characteristics are consistent with the notion that firms with

poison puts are more prone to information asymmetries, thus helping explain why they are more

likely to use poison puts: their greater levels of information asymmetries would naturally

increase the need for bondholders to receive contractual assurances of protection from a risk-

shifting or otherwise damaging takeover event.

We also study the presence of four important governance variables: institutional

ownership, an indicator variable for firms incorporated in Delaware, a dummy for firms with

poison pills, and an indicator variable for firms with classified boards. Poison-put firms have

significantly higher levels of institutional ownership (64%, compared to 59% for other firms).

Page 16: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

15

This is consistent with these firms having, if anything, stronger external monitors – again, an

explanation that is consistent with a governance structure complemented by contractual

protections for bondholders (given these firms’ information asymmetries), and inconsistent with

weak governance and/or managerial entrenchment leading to the issuance of poison puts. Firm-

years with poison puts are significantly less likely to be from firms incorporated in Delaware.

Given the increased exposure of Delaware firms to acquisitions (Daines, 2001) and evidence that

Delaware firms are not more or less likely to replace CEOs due to poor performance

(Jagannathan and Pritchard, 2013), this finding is not consistent with firms issuing poison puts

having weaker governance.

Interestingly, poison put firms are significantly less likely to have a poison pill – it is

present in 35% of those sample firms, compared to 45% among the control firms. This, too,

ought to be expected, as poison put firms’ investors have a need to protect themselves from

takeovers. Finally, we do not find any evidence that poison put firms are more likely to have

classified boards; the similar prevalence of classified boards across the two groups of firms is

again consistent with any weaker governance among poison put firms.

In Panel B of Table 3, we evaluate characteristics of issues with poison puts, compared to

other issues. Our results are consistent with these firms experiencing greater information

asymmetries – the treasury spread is significantly higher for issues with poison puts (a median

spread that is 83 basis points higher than issues that do not have poison puts) and maturity is

significantly shorter than non-poison put issues (mean maturity is 11.0 years for poison put

issues and 13.1 for other issues). The offering amount is not reliably different between the

samples – poison put issues exhibit a significantly smaller mean and a significantly larger

median, compared to other issues.

Page 17: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

16

The number of covenants in poison put issues is consistent with bondholders demanding

stronger contractual protections. The mean and median number of bondholder protective

covenants in the issues (excluding poison put covenants) is significantly larger for issues with

poison puts than those without. Similarly, the difference in mean and median is significantly

present in issuer restrictive covenants as well; the mean number of these covenants is 3.95

among issues with poison puts, compared to 2.40 among other issues. This evidence is consistent

with poison puts being reflective of bondholders’ desires for optimal contracting, in contrast to

them being reflective of managerial opportunism. Managers seeking to entrench themselves

would be particularly reluctant to issue bonds that have significantly higher amounts of

covenants (and especially issuer restrictive covenants).

3.2 Results

In Table 4, we confirm these results with regressions on the determinants of poison puts.

The dependent variable is equal to one if the issue has a poison put, and is zero otherwise. Our

regression results are consistent with our univariate analysis. In particular, we find that the

number of covenants is positively and significantly associated with the presence of poison puts.

We also find that treasury spreads are positively associated with the presence of poison puts.

Larger issues are positively associated with poison puts, consistent with the median of poison put

issues being larger than other issues and in contrast to the mean of poison put issues being

smaller. Shorter maturity is also positively and significantly associated with the presence of

poison puts. In short, these issue-specific variables are consistent with our univariate tests.

With the exception of market-to-book, the firm-specific variables are also consistent with

our univariate tests. Lower levels of sales (i.e., firm size) are associated with a greater likelihood

Page 18: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

17

of a poison put issue. Additionally, leverage is positively and significantly associated with the

presence of a poison put when controlling for year fixed effects, reflecting the distinct

contracting environment for firms at risk of financial distress. In contrast, market-to-book is

negatively associated with the presence of a poison put, suggesting that the firms with fewer

growth options are more likely to acquiesce to limiting their vulnerability to being taken over.

In Table 5, we continue from our earlier result by examining the characteristics

associated with a firm-year having a poison put issue, conditional on the firm issuing bonds in

that year. Similar to our results in Table 4, the likelihood of a firm-year experiencing the

issuance of at least one bond issue with a poison put is greater in firms that are smaller, firms

with more leverage, and firms with lower market-to-book. Our other variables are also as

expected, and are inconsistent with poison puts being driven by poorly governed firms. In

particular, we find that (1) institutional ownership is higher for these firms, reflecting stronger

external monitoring coinciding with the use of poison puts; (2) an inconsistent effect of being

incorporated in Delaware; (3) depending on the fixed-effects, poison pills are either

insignificantly associated or negatively associated with the firm’s propensity to issue bonds with

poison puts; and (4) the use of classified boards is not significantly associated with the use of

poison puts. In conclusion, we do not find any evidence that the issuance of bonds with poison

puts is driven by these firms having weaker governance.

One way to study how the use of poison puts corresponds with other aspects of the firms’

contracting environment is to test what bond covenants are associated with poison puts. In Panel

A of Table 6, we show the percentage of bonds with given covenants, conditional on them

having poison puts. In this table, we find that the use of poison puts corresponds with other,

related covenants – likely reflecting bondholders with legitimate concerns related to acquisitions

Page 19: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

18

and risk shifting. For example, the covenants most frequently seen in bonds with poison puts

relate to consolidations/acquisitions, asset sales, and cross-acceleration. In Panel B of Table 6,

we examine corresponding statistics of the proportion of poison put covenants present in bonds

that have certain types of covenants. Again, our results are broadly consistent with poison puts

being associated with protecting bondholders from the types of events that would occur in

somewhat risky firms. For example, whereas poison puts would be common among bonds that

have ratings decline triggers and asset sale clauses, they are less sensitive where bondholders’

concerns are less clear. As an example, only 22.2% of bonds with defeasance covenants contain

poison puts.

We continue by examining how poison puts are associated with subsequent acquisition

activity in particular industries. In Panel A of Table 7, we compare acquisition activity of firms

with poison puts with those that do not have poison puts. Consistently, we find that firms with

poison puts are less inclined to be involved in acquisitions, either as acquirers or targets. For

example, an average of 15% of sample poison put firm-years experience a year as an acquirer,

compared to 21% for firms without poison puts. Similarly, 7% of firm-years where the firm

issued poison puts are acquisition targets, compared to 10% of other firm-years.10 This is

consistent with poison puts reflecting a desire by the firm to avoid being involved in acquisitions,

as opposed to it using poison puts opportunistically to aggressively acquire firms while being a

less likely target itself. Interestingly, we also find that industries less prone to acquisition activity

(either as acquirers or as targets) are also more likely to have firms with poison puts. In

particular, for poison put firms, the industry-average percentage of acquisitions that occur are 6%

10 Our results are very similar when omitting withdrawn deals.

Page 20: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

19

of acquisitions and 3% of targets, values that are significantly lower than 8% of firm-years and

4% of targets for non-poison put firms.

Given the earlier results, we also examine how acquisitions of poison put targets compare

to other firm-years. Our results in Panel B of Table 7 present mixed evidence regarding potential

risk-shifting occurring at acquisitions in which the target has a poison put.11 First, these

transactions are not significantly more likely to be hostile. Although this is not particularly

surprising given the paucity of hostile transactions, fewer hostile transactions would suggest that

poison puts work to deflect hostile takeovers. The transaction value is significantly larger for

firms with poison puts, with a median value of $72 billion compared to $53 billion for other

sample firms; admittedly, this partly reflects our inclusion of typically smaller firms without

public debt issues in our sample of non-poison put targets. The median market-to-book of poison

put targets is not significantly different than targets without poison puts, although the mean value

is significantly less, at 1.58, compared to 1.93 for non-poison put firms. The market-to-book of

the acquiring firm is not significantly different across subsamples. This is not consistent with

risk-shifting occurring.

We find broadly similar results for other variables related to risk-shifting. In particular,

although leverage is significantly higher for firms with poison puts (for example, the median

book and market value of leverage for these firms is 40% and 35%, respectively), the leverage of

acquirers is lower than that of the targets – for example, the median market value of leverage for

these firms is 20%, compared to 19% for non-poison put targets. This difference is significant at

the 10% level, and the difference in mean values of leverage are insignificantly different between

11 Our sample size here is larger since we are also including non-Mergent firms in the sample as “non-poison put

targets.” Our results are robust to limiting both samples to firms that are in Mergent.

Page 21: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

20

the two subsamples. Although the mean and median of the book value of leverage of acquirers of

poison put firms (32% and 30%, respectively) are significantly higher than the corresponding

values for non-poison put firms (23% and 21%, respectively), the differences are not as

surprising when considering that they are comparable to the differences in book leverage

between the target firms. Moreover, the acquiring firm’s leverage is consistently below that of

the target’s for poison put firms – something that is inconsistent with risk-shifting occurring.

Finally, we consider earnings volatility. We find that poison put firm targets have significantly

lower earnings volatility compared to non-poison put firm targets (i.e., a mean value of 3%

compared to 9%), as do their acquirers (i.e., a mean value of 2%, compared to 10%).

Additionally, among targets with poison puts, the earnings volatility of the acquirers is less than

that of the targets (i.e., 2% compared to 3%), whereas this is not the case with non-poison put

targets (i.e., 10% compared to 9%). If anything, risk-shifting in favor of poison put target

bondholders seems to be occurring. This is consistent with the types of firms that issue poison

puts being particularly aware of the potential damage associated with risk-shifting, and inclined

to protect their bondholders more than otherwise comparable firms not issuing poison puts.

In Table 8, we regress the recent issuance of poison put bonds against other firm and

industry-specific characteristics. Firms in industries that are more acquisition-intensive (based on

the acquisition activity in the prior year) are more likely to issue bonds with poison puts. In

economic significance, a one-standard deviation increase in the industry’s acquisition intensity as

targets (acquirers) is associated with a 14.5% (17.5%) increase in the likelihood of the firm

issuing poison puts. This is consistent with these firms endeavoring simply to be less involved in

acquisition activities, and their issuance of poison puts is likely driven by being in a

consolidating industry; it is inconsistent with the sample statistics, and reflects the effect of the

Page 22: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

21

year and industry fixed-effects. Additionally, as before, leverage and institutional ownership are

both positive and significant, and firm size is negative and significant.

For our other variables, market-to-book is less significant than before, likely having much

of its effect subsumed by our variable for the intensity of consolidation in the industry-year.

Additionally, earnings volatility is insignificant, indicating that, when controlling for all other

factors, firms particularly concerned about risk-shifting occurring are not more likely to issue

poison puts.

In Table 9, we examine the risk-shifting hypothesis in more detail, and find no consistent

evidence of risk-shifting occurring. The aspects that we consider for risk-shifting are the

acquirer’s market-to-book, leverage, and earnings volatility. Model (5) for leverage and Model

(7) for earnings volatility are the only regressions where the coefficient associated with poison

puts is significant. In these regressions, we find that the leverage or earnings volatility of the

acquirer are slightly lower when the target has a poison put – in contrast to what would be

expected from risk-shifting. However, these results are not robust to including year fixed-effects.

4. Conclusion

In this study, we examine the prevalence and determinants of firms’ use of poison put

covenants. Given the potential for these covenants to entrench management, and their continued

popularity (particularly in certain industries), it is important to understand how they interact with

other governance mechanisms that firms face.

Our evidence is consistent with poison put covenants being reflective of efficient

contracting. We do not find evidence of firms that issue these covenants experiencing weaker

governance, and present evidence that poison puts are driven by risk-shifting concerns. We also

Page 23: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

22

find that firms with poison puts are less likely to be involved in acquisitions as either acquirers or

targets, even though these firms are in industries experiencing consolidation. Our evidence is

consistent with poison puts being employed in a manner consistent with firms’ contracting

environments, although their effect on mergers would increase entrenchment as well.

The increased prominence of poison put covenants and potential scrutiny from regulators,

combined with the potential for poison puts to facilitate managerial entrenchment, shows the

importance of understanding their role. Our results provide an example of a corporate finance

decision that seems to be primarily driven by contracting considerations, as opposed to

governance failures.

Page 24: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

23

References

Arlen, J. and E. Talley, 2003. Unregulable defenses and the perils of shareholder choice.

University of Pennsylvania Law Review 152(2), 957-1023.

Armstrong, C.S., K. Balakrishnan, and D. Cohen, 2012. Corporate governance and the

information environment: Evidence from state antitakeover laws. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 53(1&2), 185-204.

Asquith, P. and T. Wizman, 1990. Event risk, covenants, and bondholder returns in leveraged

buyouts. Journal of Financial Economics 27(1), 195-213.

Ayotte, K.M. and E.R. Morrison, 2009. Creditor control and conflict in chapter 11. Journal of

Legal Analysis 1(2), 511-551.

Baird, D.G. and R.K. Rasmussen, 2006. Private debt and the missing lever of corporate

governance. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 154(5), 1209-1251.

Billett, M.T., Z. Jiang, and E. Lie, 2010. The effect of change-in-control covenants on takeovers:

Evidence from leveraged buyouts. Journal of Accounting and Economics 16(1), 1-15.

Billett, M.T., T.-H. King, D.C. Mauer, 2004. Bondholder wealth effects in mergers and

acquisitions: New evidence from the 1980s and 1990s. Journal of Finance 59(1), 107-

135.

Byeff, S., 2015. Note: The spirit of Blasius: Sandridge as an antidote to the poison put. Columbia

Law Review, 115, 375-415. http://www.lexisnexis.com/hottopics/lnacademic/

Chava, S., P. Kumar, A. Warga, 2010. Managerial agency and bond covenants. Review of

Financial Studies 23(3), 1120-1148.

Chava, S. and M.R. Roberts, 2008. How does financing impact covenants? The role of debt

covenants. Journal of Finance 63(5), 2085-2121.

Chemmanur, T.J. and K. Simoyan, 2010. What drives the issuance of putable convertibles: Risk-

shifting, asymmetric information, or taxes? Financial Management 39(3), 1027-1067.

Cheng, A.F. and T.-H. King, 2006. An empirical examination of poison puts in U.S. corporate

debt. Working paper, UNC Charlotte.

Cook, D.O. and J.C. Easterwood, 1994. Poison put bonds: An analysis of their economic role.

Journal of Finance 49(5), 1905-1920.

Corporate Bonds: Control Freaks, 16 Mar 2006. The Economist. 21 Feb 2015.

http://www.economist.com/node/5637646.

Crabbe, L., 1991. Event risk: An analysis of losses to bondholders and “super poison put” bond

covenants. Journal of Finance 46(2), 689-706.

Cremers, K.J.M., V.B. Nair, and C. Wei, 2007. Governance mechanisms and bond prices.

Review of Financial Studies 20(5), 1359-1388.

Daines, R., 2001. Does Delaware law improve firm value? Journal of Financial Economics

62(3), 525-558.

Page 25: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

24

De Franco, G. and Vasvari, F. P. and Vyas, D. and Wittenberg-Moerman, R., 2013. Sticky

covenants. Chicago Booth Research Paper No. 13-61; Rotman School of Management

Working Paper No. 2288723. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2288723.

Fabozzi, F. J. and S. Mann, 2012. The Handbook of Fixed Income Securities 8th ed., (New York:

McGraw Hill).

Feldhütter, P., E. Hotchkiss, and O. Karakaş, 2015. The value of creditor control in corporate

bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

Francis, B.B., I. Hasan, K. John, and M. Waisman, 2010. The effect of state antitakeover laws on

the firm’s bondholders. Journal of Financial Economics 96(1), 127-154.

Gutscher, C. 27 Aug 2014. Tim Hortons poison put leaves creditors with indigestion.

BloombergBusiness. 2 Mar 2015. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2014-08-

27/tim-hortons-put-leaves-holders-with-indigestion-canada-credit.

Hege, U. and C. Hennessy, 2010. Acquisition values and optimal financial (in)flexibility. Review

of Financial Studies 23(7), 2866-2899.

Hoffman, L., 28 Apr 2015, Lenders feel heat as suits ramp up. Wall Street Journal. 29 Apr 2015.

http://www.wsj.com/articles/banks-feel-the-heat-from-lawsuits-1430259260.

Ivashina, V., V.B. Nair, A. Saunders, N. Massoud, and R. Stover, 2009. Bank debt and corporate

governance. Review of Financial Studies 22(1), 41-77.

Jagannathan, M., and A.C. Pritchard, 2013. Do Delaware CEOs get fired? Working paper,

Binghamton University and University of Michigan.

Kallick v. Sandridge Energy, Inc.68 A. 3d 242. Del. Ch. 7 Mar 8 2013. LexisNexis Academic.

Web. 24 Jun 2015.

Kahan, M. and M. Klausner, 1993. Antitakeover provisions in bonds: Bondholder protection or

management entrenchment? UCLA Law Review 40, 931-981.

http://www.lexisnexis.com/hottopics/lnacademic/

Katz, D. A., 15 Mar 2013. Delaware court raises bar for use of “poison put” provisions. Harvard

Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation. 2 Mar 2015.

http://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2013/03/15/delaware-court-raises-bar-for-use-of-poison-

put-provisions/.

Lehn, K. and A. Poulsen, 1991. Contractual resolution of bondholder-stockholder conflicts in

leveraged buyouts. Journal of Law and Economics, 34(2-2), 645-673.

Levine, M., 17 Dec 2014. Oil company finds gusher in bond indenture. Bloomberg View. 21 Feb

2015. http://www.bloombergview.com/articles/2014-12-16/oil-company-finds-gusher-in-

bond-indenture.

Mansi, S.A., W. F. Maxwell, and J. K. Wald, 2009. Creditor protection laws and the cost of debt.

Journal of Law and Economics 52(4), 701-717.

McGee, P. and M. Wirz, 3 Feb 2013.New worry for bondholders: LBOs. The Wall Street

Journal. 21 Feb 15.

http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424127887324761004578281660084115812.

Page 26: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

25

Nash, R.C., J.M. Netter, and A.B. Poulsen, 2003. Determinants of contractual relations between

shareholders and bondholders: Investment opportunities and restrictive covenants.

Journal of Corporate Finance 9(2), 201-232.

Nini, G., D.C. Smith, and A. Sufi, 2012. Creditor control rights, corporate governance, and firm

value. Review of Financial Studies 25(6), 1713-1761.

Okamoto, K., D. Pedersen, and N. Pedersen, 2011. The price effects of event-risk protection: The

results from a natural experiment. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 8(3), 878-903.

Petitt, B., J. E. Pinto, and W. L. Pirie, 2015. Fixed Income Analysis 3rd ed., (Hoboken, NJ:

Wiley).

Qi, Y., L. Roth, and J. K. Wald, 2011. How legal environments affect the use of bond covenants.

Journal of International Business Studies 42(2), 235-262.

Qi, Y. and J. K. Wald, 2008. State laws and debt covenants. Journal of Law and Economics

51(1), 179-207.

Reindel, F.W., 2015. “Dead hand proxy puts” – what you need to know. Harvard Law School

Corporate Governance Forum. June 10.

Roberts, M.R. and A. Sufi, 2009. Control rights and capital structure: An empirical investigation.

Journal of Finance 64(4), 1657-1695.

San Antonio Fire and Police Pension Fund v. Amylin Pharms., Inc. 983 A. 2d 304. Del. Ch. 12

May 2009. LexisNexis Academic. Web. 12 May 2009.

Santos, J.A.C. and A.S. Rumble, 2006. The American keiretsu and universal banks: Investing,

voting and sitting on nonfinancials’ corporate boards. Journal of Financial Economics

80, 419-454.

Solomon, S. D., 26 Nov 2014. A defense against hostile takeovers develops a downside. New

York Times. 29 Nov 2014. http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2014/11/25/a-defense-against-

hostile-takeovers-develops-a-downside/?_r=0.

Torabzadeh, K., J. Roufagalas, and C. Woodruff, 2000. Self-selection and the effects of poison

put/call covenants on the reoffering yields of corporate bonds. International Review of

Economics and Finance 9(2): 139-156.

Wargo, A. and I. Welch, 1993. Bondholder losses in leveraged buyouts. Review of Financial

Studies 6(4), 959-982.

Page 27: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

26

Figure 1: Histogram of percentage of firms’ issues containing poison puts

For each sample firm, this figure provides the proportion of the firm’s total issues that have

poison put covenants.

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900 847

71

164

79

30

851

Axis

Tit

le

Percent of Issues with Poison Puts

Number of Firms

Page 28: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

27

Table 1: Sample statistics

This table provides the number and proportion of poison put issues that occur, by various firm

characteristics. Panel A provides the distribution by firm-year, Panel B provides the distribution

by Fama-French 48 industry group, and Panel C provides the distribution by the bond’s S&P

credit rating (where available).

Panel A: Distribution by year

Year

Number of

Poison Put

Issues

Number of Poison

Put firm-years

% Poison Put

Issues

% Poison Put

Firm-Years

Number of

Issues in

Sample

Number

of Firms

in

Sample

1990 48 34 25.4% 27.9% 189 122

1991 55 47 15.3% 22.1% 359 213

1992 111 89 19.9% 27.6% 558 322

1993 176 151 25.4% 38.8% 692 389

1994 77 73 27.4% 38.2% 281 191

1995 40 65 10.7% 24.9% 375 261

1996 49 109 16.7% 38.8% 293 281

1997 31 70 9.9% 27.8% 312 252

1998 26 63 8.1% 23.8% 320 265

1999 27 46 11.3% 22.0% 239 209

2000 16 55 9.9% 33.1% 162 166

2001 23 66 8.5% 28.1% 271 235

2002 18 42 7.0% 19.9% 258 211

2003 31 109 11.5% 37.8% 270 288

2004 20 73 11.5% 39.9% 174 183

2005 16 29 9.1% 19.1% 175 152

2006 35 58 16.5% 32.4% 212 179

2007 155 135 56.2% 61.6% 276 219

2008 108 97 47.0% 58.4% 230 166

2009 195 175 50.1% 60.3% 389 290

2010 205 164 53.8% 61.2% 381 268

2011 176 128 50.4% 59.3% 349 216

2012 239 172 56.8% 57.3% 421 300

Page 29: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

28

Panel B: Distribution by industry-group

Industry Group

Number of

Poison Put

Issues

Number of

Poison Put

firm-years

% Poison Put

Issues

% Poison Put

Firm-Years

Number of

Issues in

Sample

Number of

Firms in

Sample

Coal 9 10 100.0% 100.0% 9 10

Fabricated Products 3 6 100.0% 85.7% 3 7

Real Estate 11 12 91.7% 85.7% 12 14

Agriculture 9 7 90.0% 87.5% 10 8

Healthcare 58 67 76.3% 77.9% 76 86

Non-Metallic and Industrial Metal Mining 22 15 73.3% 68.2% 30 22

Measuring and Control Equipment 30 24 68.2% 64.9% 44 37

Construction 74 81 66.7% 73.6% 111 110

Precious Metals 8 8 66.7% 50.0% 12 16

Electrical Equipment 23 17 53.5% 53.1% 43 32

Rubber and Plastic Products 18 14 51.4% 51.9% 35 27

Steel Works Etc 35 39 50.0% 56.5% 70 69

Recreation 12 12 48.0% 57.1% 25 21

Apparel 9 9 45.0% 45.0% 20 20

Restaraunts, Hotels, Motels 38 43 43.7% 55.8% 87 77

Entertainment 29 40 43.3% 61.5% 67 65

Construction Materials 37 41 42.5% 56.9% 87 72

Wholesale 51 66 40.5% 50.0% 126 132

Business Services 69 114 40.1% 62.0% 172 184

Textiles 6 6 40.0% 46.2% 15 13

Communication 123 159 37.7% 56.4% 326 282

Business Supplies 69 48 36.3% 37.2% 190 129

Retail 176 150 35.7% 48.9% 493 307

Petroleum and Natural Gas 163 179 34.8% 48.8% 468 367

Tobacco Products 16 7 34.8% 38.9% 46 18

Electronic Equipment 45 95 34.6% 63.3% 130 150

Chemicals 81 58 34.5% 37.4% 235 155

Almost Nothing 8 13 33.3% 50.0% 24 26

Personal Services 6 12 33.3% 63.2% 18 19

Pharmaceutical Products 59 85 33.0% 51.8% 179 164

Food Products 65 51 32.8% 39.8% 198 128

Medical Equipment 21 33 31.3% 49.3% 67 67

Shipbuilding, Railroad Equipment 3 4 30.0% 57.1% 10 7

Consumer Goods 29 27 29.6% 36.0% 98 75

Machinery 40 47 28.8% 40.5% 139 116

Shipping Containers 11 11 28.2% 40.7% 39 27

Transportation 64 71 26.8% 40.8% 239 174

Computers 33 41 25.6% 45.6% 129 90

Aircraft 20 14 20.0% 26.9% 100 52

Printing and Publishing 11 9 19.0% 21.4% 58 42

Insurance 86 66 18.2% 17.1% 473 387

Candy & Soda 10 6 16.9% 17.6% 59 34

Automobiles and Trucks 14 20 15.7% 28.6% 89 70

Defense 3 4 13.0% 40.0% 23 10

Utilities 91 82 10.9% 15.1% 838 543

Beer & Liquor 11 9 10.5% 18.4% 105 49

Trading 39 70 8.8% 19.4% 443 361

Banking 29 48 3.2% 9.5% 916 507

Page 30: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

29

Panel C: Distribution by credit rating

Credit rating

Number of

Poison Put

Issues

Number of Poison

Put firm-years

%

Poison

Put

Issues

%

Poison

Put

Firm-

Years

Number of

Issues in

Sample

Number of

Firms in

Sample

AAA - - 0.0% 0.0% 100 65

AA+ - 1 0.0% 4.0% 33 25

AA 10 7 3.3% 4.1% 299 169

AA- 12 8 3.0% 3.7% 399 216

A+ 76 45 10.3% 11.4% 737 396

A 110 83 9.5% 12.7% 1,155 654

A- 166 94 22.9% 20.5% 726 459

BBB+ 202 156 24.6% 28.3% 821 551

BBB 262 207 26.4% 29.6% 993 699

BBB- 225 199 37.6% 40.2% 599 495

BB+ 123 128 58.0% 63.7% 212 201

BB 179 194 71.0% 78.5% 252 247

BB- 174 235 92.6% 89.0% 188 264

B+ 173 220 94.0% 92.1% 184 239

B 59 94 93.7% 91.3% 63 103

B- 18 60 100.0% 89.6% 18 67

CCC+ 6 17 85.7% 89.5% 7 19

CCC 2 6 100.0% 66.7% 2 9

CCC- 1 1 50.0% 50.0% 2 2

CC 1 2 100.0% 66.7% 1 3

C - 1 0.0% 100.0% - 1

Page 31: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

30

Table 2: Proportion of poison put issuance across sample

This table examines the proportion of issues that contain poison put covenants. Panel A, which

corresponds to Figure 1, provides the distribution by firm, for our sample period. Panel B

provides the distribution of issues for the subsample of firms that issued at least one bond with a

poison put, and for which less than 100% of its bonds contain poison puts.

Panel A: Proportion of sample firms’ issues containing poison put covenants

% of issues with a

poison put

Number of

firms

x=0% 847

0< x ≤5% 5

5%< x ≤10% 9

10< x ≤15% 14

15%< x ≤20% 24

20< x ≤25% 19

25%< x ≤30% 13

30< x ≤35% 33

35%< x ≤40% 21

40< x ≤45% 15

45%< x ≤50% 82

50< x ≤55% 3

55%< x ≤60% 12

60< x ≤65% 7

65%< x ≤70% 29

70< x ≤75% 28

75%< x ≤80% 8

80< x ≤85% 8

85%< x ≤90% 11

90< x ≤95% 3

95%< x <100% 0

x =100% 851

Page 32: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

31

Panel B: Proportion of sample firms’ issues containing poison put covenants

Number of

issues

Number of

poison put

issues

% of

poison put

issues

% of poison

put issues

(dollar

weighted)

(1): Prior to first poison put

issue 917

(2): During the time that the

firm issues its first poison put

issue 1,595 1,224 76.7% 83.4%

(3): After final poison put

issue 389

Page 33: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

32

Table 3: Differences in means and medians; issue and issuer characteristics

This table examines the differences in means and medians of firm-years where the firm issues at

least one issue with a poison put covenant in the firm-year (Panel A), or issue characteristics of

issues with poison put covenants (Panel B). Variables are defined as follows: Revenue (Firm’s

sales in that year, in millions), Market to Book (the market value of assets, scaled by the book

value of assets), Leverage (book value of total debt, scaled by the book value of assets),

Institutional Ownership (the proportion of the firm owned by institutional investors), Delaware

(an indicator variable equal to one if the firm is incorporated in Delaware, and zero otherwise),

Poison Pill (an indicator variable equal to one if the firm has a poison pill, and zero otherwise),

Classified Board (an indicator variable equal to one if the firm has a classified board, and zero

otherwise), Treasury Spread (the treasury spread of the bond issue, in basis points), Offering

Amount (the par value of the debt originally issued, in thousands), Maturity (the maturity of the

issue, in years), Number of BP Covenants (the number of bondholder protective covenants in the

same issue, excluding the poison put), and Number of IR Covenants (the number of issuer

restrictive covenants in the same issue). *, **, and *** denote significant differences in means

and medians at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels respectively.

Panel A: Firm-year characteristics

Poison put firm-year Non-poison put firm-year

N Mean Median N Mean Median

Revenue 2,050 6,413 1,674 3,328 13,548*** 4,882***

Market to Book 2,050 1.67 1.37 3,328 1.48*** 1.19***

Leverage 2,050 0.41 0.37 3,328 0.31*** 0.31***

Institutional Ownership 2,050 0.55 0.64 3,328 0.54 0.59***

Delaware 831 0.42 0.0 1,259 0.46** 0.0**

Poison Pill 831 0.35 0.0 1,259 0.45*** 0.0***

Classified Board 831 0.51 1.0 1,259 0.52 1.0

Panel B: Issue characteristics

Poison put bond Non-poison put bond

N Mean Median N Mean Median

Treasury Spread 1,877 216.62 183.00 5,309 123.20*** 100.00***

Offering Amount 1,877 409,892 300,000 5,309 415,592 250,000***

Maturty 1,877 10.99 10.02 5,309 13.13*** 10.02

Number of BP Covenants 1,877 3.46 4.00 5,309 2.54*** 3.00***

Number of IR Covenants 1,877 3.95 3.00 5,309 2.40*** 3.00***

Page 34: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

33

Table 4: Determinants of poison put covenants in an issue

This table presents the results of logistic regressions, in which the dependent variable is equal to

one if the issue contains a poison put covenant, and zero otherwise. Explanatory variables

include: LogBP (the natural log of one plus the number of bondholder protective covenants,

excluding poison puts), LogIR (the natural log of one plus the number of issuer restrictive

covenants), TreasurySpread (the treasury spread of the bond issue), LogOffAmount (the natural

log of one plus the offering amount), LogMaturity (the natural log of one plus the number of

days to maturity), LogRevenue (the natural log of one plus the firm’s sales), MarketToBook (the

market to book value of assets), Leverage (total debt scaled by total assets). Year and Fama-

French 12 industry fixed effects are included, where applicable. Firm-clustered standard errors

are provided in parentheses; *, **, and *** denote significant differences in means and medians

at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels respectively.

(1) (2)

LogBP 0.477*** 0.240**

(4.570) (2.004)

LogIR 1.209*** 1.304***

(10.983) (11.086)

TreasurySpread 0.005*** 0.004***

(18.730) (9.441)

LogOffAmount 0.012*** 0.011***

(15.368) (12.617)

LogMaturity -0.148*** -0.098

(-2.793) (-1.539)

LogRevenue 0.001 -0.353***

(0.030) (-9.119)

MarketToBook -0.277*** -0.511***

(-4.854) (-6.919)

Leverage -0.154 1.266***

(-0.652) (4.581)

Constant -2.703*** 7.274***

(-2.982) (6.574)

Observations 7,186 7,186

Pseudo R2 30.58% 45.63%

Year fixed-effects No Yes

Industry fixed-effects Yes Yes

Page 35: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

34

Table 5: Determinants of firm-year with at least one poison put covenant issued

This table presents the results of logistic regressions, in which the dependent variable is equal to

one if the firm-year is associated with the issuance of a bond with a poison put covenant, and

zero otherwise. Explanatory variables are as defined in Table 4, with the exception of:

InstitutionalOwn (the percentage of ownership by institutional investors), Delaware (an indicator

variable equal to one if the firm was incorporated in Delaware, and zero otherwise), PoisonPill

(an indicator variable equal to one if the firm had a poison pill, and zero otherwise),

ClassifiedBoard (an indicator variable equal to one if the firm had a classified board, and zero

otherwise). Year and Fama-French 12 industry fixed effects are included, where applicable.

Firm-clustered standard errors are provided in parentheses; *, **, and *** denote significant

differences in means and medians at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels respectively.

(1) (2) (3) (4)

LogRevenue -0.367*** -0.622*** -0.452*** -0.772***

(-17.798) (-23.269) (-10.847) (-14.406)

MarketToBook -0.133*** -0.149*** -0.239*** -0.220**

(-2.839) (-2.744) (-2.980) (-2.274)

Leverage 1.822*** 2.396*** 1.047*** 1.857***

(9.113) (10.551) (2.912) (4.356)

InstitutionalOwn 0.321*** 0.671*** 2.057*** 1.071***

(2.857) (4.483) (8.886) (4.099)

Delaware -0.186* 0.523***

(-1.749) (3.644)

PoisonPill -0.835*** -0.149

(-7.270) (-1.065)

ClassifiedBoard -0.135 0.059

(-1.222) (0.456)

Constant 7.402*** 14.587*** 9.270*** 18.034***

(15.365) (21.981) (9.190) (13.507)

Observations 5,378 5,378 2,090 2,090

Pseudo R2 19.27% 32.54% 19.66% 36.69%

Year fixed-effects No Yes No Yes

Industry fixed-effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 36: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

35

Table 6: Covenants associated with poison puts

This table presents a description of the covenants associated with a poison put issue. In Panel A,

we provide the proportion of issues with poison puts that also have certain covenants. In Panel B,

we provide the prevalence of poison puts among issues that have certain covenants. The other

covenants are defined as follows: After_acquired_property_clause (property that is acquired after

the sale of current debt issues will be used in the current mortgage), Asset_sale_clause

(requirement that the issuer uses sale proceeds of certain assets to redeem bonds),

Consolidation_merger (restriction of a consolidation or merger with another entity),

Covenant_defeas_wo_tax_conseq (provides issuer the right to defease the indenture covenants

without tax consequences to the bondholder), Cross_acceleration (enables bondholders to

accelerate their debt, if any other debt of the firm has been accelerated due to default),

Cross_default (activates an act of default if any other debt of the firm experiences default),

Declining_net_worth (triggers certain bond provisions when the issuer’s net worth falls below a

certain level), Defeasance_wo_tax_conseq (provides issuer the right to defease the issue’s

monetary portion without tax consequences to the bondholder), Dividends_related_payments

(limits to some ratio the payments made to shareholders or other entities), Economic_cov_def

(provides issuer the right to defease indentures), Fixed_charge_coverage (requirement that issuer

has a minimum amount of earnings available for fixed charges), Funded_debt (restriction from

issuing additional “funded debt,” defined as any debt with a maturity of at least one year),

Indebtedness (restriction on incurring additional debt beyond a given dollar amount or as a

percentage of total capital), Investments (restriction on the issuer’s investment policy),

Legal_defeasance (provides the issuer the right to defease the security’s monetary portion);

Leverage_test (restricts the issuer’s total indebtedness), Liens (provides bondholders with unpaid

obligations the right to sell mortgaged property in the event of bankruptcy),

Maintenance_net_worth (requirement of issuer to maintain a minimum net worth),

Negative_pledge_covenant (requirement to secure current issue on a pari passu basis if the firm

issues secured debt), Net_earnings_test_issuance (requirement of certain profitability levels for

firm to issue additional debt), Rating_decline_trigger_put (triggers a bondholder put provision in

the event of a rating decline), Restricted_payments (restriction on issuer for making payments

not related to dividends to shareholders and other parties), Sale_assets (restriction on the issuer’s

ability to sell assets or on using the proceeds from asset sales), Sales_leaseback (restriction on

the type or amount used in sale-leaseback transactions), Senior_debt_issuance (restriction on the

amount of senior debt that may be issued), Stock_issuance_issuer (restriction on issuing common

stock), Stock_transfer_sale_disp (restriction on transferring or selling its own common stock),

Subordinated_debt_issuance (restriction on the issuance of subordinated or junior debt),

Transaction_affiliates (restriction on certain types of transactions with subsidiaries).

Page 37: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

36

Panel A: Issues with poison puts – proportion of other covenants that are also present

Covenant Proportion

Consolidation_merger 92.8%

Sale_assets 92.6%

Cross_acceleration 80.7%

Defeasance_wo_tax_conseq 76.2%

Covenant_defeas_wo_tax_conseq 73.7%

Negative_pledge_covenant 70.3%

Sales_leaseback 54.7%

Indebtedness 34.7%

Restricted_payments 30.2%

Transaction_affiliates 30.2%

Fixed_charge_coverage 21.7%

Asset_sale_clause 14.9%

Dividends_related_payments 9.4%

Legal_defeasance 9.2%

Subordinated_debt_issuance 7.7%

Cross_default 7.0%

Economic_cov_def 6.1%

Rating_decline_trigger_put 6.1%

Liens 5.1%

Investments 4.3%

Stock_transfer_sale_disp 3.5%

Stock_issuance_issuer 3.0%

Maintenance_net_worth 2.6%

Declining_net_worth 1.8%

Funded_debt 1.5%

Senior_debt_issuance 0.5%

After_acquired_property_clause 0.2%

Net_earnings_test_issuance 0.1%

Leverage_test 0.0%

Page 38: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

37

Panel B: Issues with certain covenants – proportion that also has poison puts

Covenant Proportion

Asset_sale_clause 99.3%

Rating_decline_trigger_put 99.1%

Restricted_payments 91.9%

Transaction_affiliates 90.0%

Investments 83.3%

Declining_net_worth 82.9%

Subordinated_debt_issuance 75.9%

Indebtedness 64.6%

Fixed_charge_coverage 58.2%

Stock_issuance_issuer 55.9%

Senior_debt_issuance 47.4%

Dividends_related_payments 43.6%

Cross_acceleration 37.9%

Maintenance_net_worth 33.3%

Funded_debt 33.3%

Liens 32.8%

Covenant_defeas_wo_tax_conseq 31.7%

Sales_leaseback 31.0%

Defeasance_wo_tax_conseq 30.7%

Sale_assets 29.1%

Consolidation_merger 29.1%

Negative_pledge_covenant 28.8%

Economic_cov_def 28.5%

Cross_default 24.0%

Legal_defeasance 22.2%

Stock_transfer_sale_disp 19.6%

After_acquired_property_clause 1.9%

Net_earnings_test_issuance 0.9%

Leverage_test 0.0%

Page 39: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

38

Table 7: Differences in means and medians; poison puts and mergers

This table examines the differences in means and medians for firms that had recently issued

poison puts. In Panel A, we examine the propensity of firms to experience M&A-related

activities, depending on their past issuance of poison puts. In Panel B, we examine deal

characteristics where the target has a poison put. We distinguish a firm as having a poison put if

it issued at least one bond with a poison put within the prior five years; all other firms are

regarded as non-poison put firms. Our other variables in Panel A are: Acquirer (an indicator

variable equal to one if the firm was an acquirer in that firm-year, and zero otherwise),

Acquirer_year_mean (the average of firm-years in the industry where firms have Acquirer equal

to one), Target (an indicator variable equal to one if the firm was a target in that firm-year, and

zero otherwise), Target_year_mean (the average of firm-years in the industry where firms have

Target equal to one). In Panel B, our variables are: Hostile (an indicator variable equal to one if

the deal is hostile, and zero otherwise), Transaction Value (the deal’s transaction value), Market

to Book (the market to book value of assets of the acquirer or target, as specified in the table),

Book Leverage (the book value of leverage of the acquirer or target, as specified in the table),

Market Leverage (the market value of leverage of the acquirer or target, as specified in the table),

Earnings Volatility (the earnings volatility based on the prior five years of income before

extraordinary items scaled by the book value of assets, for the acquirer or target). *, **, and ***

denote significant differences in means and medians at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels respectively.

Panel A: M&A activity for firms with and without poison put covenants

Poison put firm Non-poison put firm

N Mean Median N Mean Median

Acquirer 2,416 0.15 0.00 2,962 0.21*** 0.00***

Acquirer_year_mean 2,416 0.06 0.07 2,962 0.08*** 0.09***

Target 2,416 0.07 0.00 2,962 0.10*** 0.00***

Target_year_mean 2,416 0.03 0.03 2,962 0.04*** 0.04***

Panel B: Deal characteristics for firms with and without poison put covenants

Poison put targets Non-poison put targets

N Mean Median N Mean Median

Hostile 222 0.02 0.00 7,833 0.02 0.00

Transaction Value 193 183.91 72.00 6,961 141.60** 53.00***

Market to Book (target) 222 1.58 1.36 7,833 1.93*** 1.28

Market to Book (acquirer) 162 1.99 1.52 5,874 2.23 1.48

Book Leverage (target) 222 0.42 0.40 7,833 0.26*** 0.22***

Book Leverage (acquirer) 162 0.32 0.30 5,874 0.23*** 0.21***

Market Leverage (target) 222 0.39 0.35 7,833 0.29*** 0.24***

Market Leverage (acquirer) 162 0.26 0.20 5,874 0.25 0.19*

Earnings Volatility (target) 222 0.03 0.01 7,833 0.09*** 0.01*

Earnings Volatility (acquirer) 162 0.02 0.01 5,874 0.10*** 0.01

Page 40: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

39

Table 8: Determinants of poison put issuance, merger characteristics

This table provides the results of logistic regressions on the firm having issued a bond with a

poison put covenant within the prior five years. All variables are as defined in Tables 4 and 7.

Firm-clustered standard errors are provided below in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote

significant differences in means and medians at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels respectively.

(1) (2)

Target_year_mean 14.738***

(4.155)

Acquirer_year_mean 9.645***

(3.649)

LogRevenue -0.513*** -0.513***

(-11.220) (-11.218)

MarketToBook -0.118 -0.127*

(-1.635) (-1.765)

BookLeverage 2.157*** 2.140***

(6.196) (6.182)

EarningsVolatility -0.041 -0.057

(-0.072) (-0.101)

InstitutionalOwn 0.951*** 0.938***

(3.821) (3.794)

Constant 12.904*** 12.923***

(11.629) (11.637)

Observations 5,378 5,378

Pseudo R2 29.33% 29.32%

Year fixed-effects Yes Yes

Industry fixed-

effects Yes Yes

Page 41: Poison Puts: Corporate Governance Structure or Mechanism

40

Table 9: Effects of poison puts on risk-shifting

This table provides the results of regressions for the risk-shifting hypothesis. The dependent

variables are of the acquirer’s (1) market to book value of assets; (2) market leverage; (3)

earnings volatility, as defined in Table 7. The independent variables are: PoisonPut (an indicator

variable equal to one if the firm issued a bond with a poison put covenant within the last five

years), LogRevenue (the natural log of one plus the target’s sales), MarketToBook (the target’s

market to book value of assets), BookLeverage (the target’s book value of leverage), and

EarningsVolatility (the target’s earnings volatility based on the prior five years of income before

extraordinary items, scaled by assets). Year and Fama-French 12 fixed-effects are provided

where applicable. Firm-clustered standard errors are provided below in parentheses. *, **, and

*** denote significant differences in means and medians at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels

respectively.

Market to Book Market Leverage Market Leverage Earnings Volatility

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

PoisonPut -0.131 -0.043 -0.031 -0.034 -0.039* -0.039 -0.009* -0.010

(-0.431) (-0.199) (-1.299) (-1.485) (-1.652) (-1.624) (-1.652) (-1.646)

LogRevenue 0.040 0.038 0.006 0.003 0.000 -0.003 -0.001 -0.002

(0.522) (0.352) (1.042) (0.400) (0.012) (-0.366) (-0.754) (-0.862)

MarketToBook 0.035 -0.123 -0.016 -0.012 0.017 0.015 -0.003 -0.004

(0.208) (-1.040) (-1.247) (-1.224) (1.109) (1.004) (-1.091) (-1.680)

BookLeverage -0.145 -0.299 0.228*** 0.221*** -0.007 -0.007

(-0.180) (-1.197) (3.632) (2.973) (-0.462) (-0.612)

MarketLeverage 0.284*** 0.247***

(4.753) (3.258)

EarningsVolatility 0.088 0.058

(0.877) (0.694)

Constant 0.941 0.664 0.020 0.121 0.094 0.219 0.040 0.048

(0.470) (0.244) (0.130) (0.697) (0.637) (1.190) (1.036) (0.910)

Observations 494 494 494 494 494 494 494 494

R2 5.27% 10.58% 21.64% 26.00% 23.11% 26.55% 3.43% 5.75%

Year fixed-effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

Industry fixed-effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes