5
18 October 2013 | CIPR NewsleƩer P ù-Ý-ùÊç-Ù®ò-Ä-ùÊç-Ýò IÄÝçÙÄ: PÊãÄ㮽 BÄ¥®ãÝ Ä IÝÝçÝ By Allen Greenberg, Manager, Non-Toll Pricing IniƟaƟves, Federal Highway AdministraƟon This arƟcle expresses the opinions of the author and is not meant to represent the posiƟon or opinions of the NAIC or its members, nor is it the ocial posiƟon of any stamembers. By converƟng all or some porƟon of xed insurance costs to per-mile or per-minute-of-driving charges, pay-as-you- drive-and-you-save (PAYDAYS) insurance—also commonly known as usage-based insurance—has the potenƟal to encourage voluntary reducƟons in driving and related de- creases in congesƟon. TradiƟonal raƟng factors (e.g., residenƟal locaƟon, gender, age, and driving record) are directly incorporated into usage -based rates, with such rates also reecƟng the specic cov- erage a driver chooses. PAYDAYS insurance is likely to result in charges that more accurately reect crash risk, based, as they are, on usage. By contrast, tradiƟonal insurance rates vary liƩle, if at all, based on mileage, even though few claims are made for damages, such as theŌ, that may hap- pen when a vehicle is not being driven. With convenƟonal insurance, consumers have liƩle oppor- tunity to save by driving fewer miles despite the fact that insurance claims are directly related to miles driven. In ex- change for reducing xed insurance costs, many drivers— especially lower income ones—would readily accept mile- age premiums that they can reduce by driving less. They could do so through voluntary trip consolidaƟon, carpool- ing, alternaƟve transportaƟon use, and forfeiƟng of low- value trips. The potenƟal benets of PAYDAYS insurance, discussed be- low, would principally be a result of reduced mileage by con- sumers in response to facing higher variable costs of driving. Reduced driving levels are projected using observed results from previous before-aŌer studies where consumers experi- enced a change in their per-mile cost of driving and adjusted their driving habits in response. These studies derive what is called a price elasƟcity, which expresses the change in mile- age as a funcƟon of the change in price. Major studies on PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elasƟci- ty gure of -0.15, based on nding a “conservaƟve average” of results from previous price elasƟcity studies (Edlin, 1996, Bordoand Noel, 2008, Ferreira and Minikel, 2010). That is, if the per-mile cost of driving (including fuel costs and insur- ance premiums that are Ɵed directly to mileage, but general- ly excluding vehicle wear and tear because drivers may not consider it) doubles, drivers are expected to cut their vehicle -miles traveled (VMT) by 15%. F®Ä®Ä¦ ã« AÖÖÙÊÖÙ®ã B½Ä BãóÄ F®ø Ä VÙ®½ PÙîçÃÝ There is a debate as to whether it is appropriate to convert all xed insurance costs to mileage charges. Since, as noted above, benets are principally a result of consumers reduc- ing their mileage due to higher variable costs of driving, benets will be reduced if not all insurance costs are made variable. Researchers at the MassachuseƩs InsƟtute of Technology (MIT) matched claims data that insurance com- panies are required to report to the State of MassachuseƩs with mileage data from annual vehicle inspecƟons. The data included $502 million in reported claims corresponding to almost 3 million cars driven about 3.4 billion miles. The pe- riod recorded for insurance claims and mileage tended to match fairly closely (within months), but not precisely. The study concluded that—when also accounƟng for territory and class (reecƟve of years of driving experience)—the “best t” premium pricing model included a xed fee that covered the rst 2,000 miles of driving, plus a fee for addi- Ɵonal miles (with both the xed and per-mile prices varying by individual risk factors). The projected result for Massa- chuseƩs, a high-cost insurance state, was that applying the “best t” model to premium pricing would yield a 5.0% re- ducƟon in driving, versus a 9.5% reducƟon with a fully varia- ble pricing model (Ferreira and Minikel, 2010). Because for a variety of reasons higher mileage drivers tend to present a lower per-mile risk than lower mileage drivers, and vice versa, a PAYDAYS pricing model that fails to dier- enƟate customers based on a mulƟtude of demographic factors will invariably overesƟmate the “xed risk” of an individual driver and underesƟmate his or her per-mile driv- ing risk. As researcher Todd Litman from the Victoria Transport Policy InsƟtute has pointed out on many occa- sions, if a pricing model were sophisƟcated enough to dierenƟate the risk of every driver, it could then reect the likelihood that if an individual curtails his or her driving by a certain percentage, that driver's probability of geƫng into a crash should be cut by the same percentage, assum- ing that the nature of driving (mixture of Ɵme and place, plus the condiƟon of the driver) that he or she does remains similar despite reduced mileage. A more sophisƟcated “best t” model would almost certainly yield a lower xed premi- um and higher variable premium than what was developed through the MIT research. PÊÝÝ®½ BÄ¥®ãÝ Studies esƟmate VMT would drop between 8 and 20% if all xed automoƟve insurance costs were converted to usage- based, with the more recent esƟmates tending to be on the (Continued on page 19) © Copyright 2013 NaƟonal AssociaƟon of Insurance Commissioners, all rights reserved.

P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    6

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

18 October 2013 | CIPR Newsle er

P - - - - - - I : P B I

By Allen Greenberg, Manager, Non-Toll Pricing Ini a ves, Federal Highway Administra on This ar cle expresses the opinions of the author and is not meant to represent the posi on or opinions of the NAIC or its members, nor is it the official posi on of any staff members. By conver ng all or some por on of fixed insurance costs to per-mile or per-minute-of-driving charges, pay-as-you-drive-and-you-save (PAYDAYS) insurance—also commonly known as usage-based insurance—has the poten al to encourage voluntary reduc ons in driving and related de-creases in conges on. Tradi onal ra ng factors (e.g., residen al loca on, gender, age, and driving record) are directly incorporated into usage-based rates, with such rates also reflec ng the specific cov-erage a driver chooses. PAYDAYS insurance is likely to result in charges that more accurately reflect crash risk, based, as they are, on usage. By contrast, tradi onal insurance rates vary li le, if at all, based on mileage, even though few claims are made for damages, such as the , that may hap-pen when a vehicle is not being driven. With conven onal insurance, consumers have li le oppor-tunity to save by driving fewer miles despite the fact that insurance claims are directly related to miles driven. In ex-change for reducing fixed insurance costs, many drivers—especially lower income ones—would readily accept mile-age premiums that they can reduce by driving less. They could do so through voluntary trip consolida on, carpool-ing, alterna ve transporta on use, and forfei ng of low-value trips. The poten al benefits of PAYDAYS insurance, discussed be-low, would principally be a result of reduced mileage by con-sumers in response to facing higher variable costs of driving. Reduced driving levels are projected using observed results from previous before-a er studies where consumers experi-enced a change in their per-mile cost of driving and adjusted their driving habits in response. These studies derive what is called a price elas city, which expresses the change in mile-age as a func on of the change in price. Major studies on PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of results from previous price elas city studies (Edlin, 1996, Bordoff and Noel, 2008, Ferreira and Minikel, 2010). That is, if the per-mile cost of driving (including fuel costs and insur-ance premiums that are ed directly to mileage, but general-ly excluding vehicle wear and tear because drivers may not consider it) doubles, drivers are expected to cut their vehicle-miles traveled (VMT) by 15%.

F A B B F V P

There is a debate as to whether it is appropriate to convert all fixed insurance costs to mileage charges. Since, as noted above, benefits are principally a result of consumers reduc-ing their mileage due to higher variable costs of driving, benefits will be reduced if not all insurance costs are made variable. Researchers at the Massachuse s Ins tute of Technology (MIT) matched claims data that insurance com-panies are required to report to the State of Massachuse s with mileage data from annual vehicle inspec ons. The data included $502 million in reported claims corresponding to almost 3 million cars driven about 3.4 billion miles. The pe-riod recorded for insurance claims and mileage tended to match fairly closely (within months), but not precisely. The study concluded that—when also accoun ng for territory and class (reflec ve of years of driving experience)—the “best fit” premium pricing model included a fixed fee that covered the first 2,000 miles of driving, plus a fee for addi-

onal miles (with both the fixed and per-mile prices varying by individual risk factors). The projected result for Massa-chuse s, a high-cost insurance state, was that applying the “best fit” model to premium pricing would yield a 5.0% re-duc on in driving, versus a 9.5% reduc on with a fully varia-ble pricing model (Ferreira and Minikel, 2010). Because for a variety of reasons higher mileage drivers tend to present a lower per-mile risk than lower mileage drivers, and vice versa, a PAYDAYS pricing model that fails to differ-en ate customers based on a mul tude of demographic factors will invariably overes mate the “fixed risk” of an individual driver and underes mate his or her per-mile driv-ing risk. As researcher Todd Litman from the Victoria Transport Policy Ins tute has pointed out on many occa-sions, if a pricing model were sophis cated enough to differen ate the risk of every driver, it could then reflect the likelihood that if an individual curtails his or her driving by a certain percentage, that driver's probability of ge ng into a crash should be cut by the same percentage, assum-ing that the nature of driving (mixture of me and place, plus the condi on of the driver) that he or she does remains similar despite reduced mileage. A more sophis cated “best fit” model would almost certainly yield a lower fixed premi-um and higher variable premium than what was developed through the MIT research. P B Studies es mate VMT would drop between 8 and 20% if all fixed automo ve insurance costs were converted to usage-based, with the more recent es mates tending to be on the

(Continued on page 19)

© Copyright 2013 Na onal Associa on of Insurance Commissioners, all rights reserved.

Page 2: P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

October 2013 | CIPR Newsle er 19

P - - - - - - I : P B I (C )

lower side of this range (Litman, 2004; Barre , 1999; Parry, 2005; Bordoff and Noel, 2008; Ferreira and Minikel, 2010). The Brookings Ins tu on has calculated that between $50 and $60 billion in net benefits would accrue in the U.S. from reduced driving related externali es if fully-variable PAY-DAYS premiums became the standard insurance product offering (Bordoff and Noel, 2008). Conges on reduc on had been shown in many instances to be dispropor onately greater than the reduc on in traffic. For example, the Oct. 22, 2008 INRIX report, The Impact of Fuel Prices on Consumer Behavior and Traffic Conges on, concluded that the price spikes led to a 26% reduc on of peak-hour conges on, resul ng from a much smaller reduc-

on (i.e., around 3%) in VMT. University of California Professor of Law and Professor of Economics, Aaron Edlin, has also researched the insurance-costs-to-others externality of driving in traffic-dense states. His research in California concluded that an addi onal in-sured driver causes between a $1,725 and $3,239 increase in total statewide insurance costs to other drivers com-pared to only $10 in North Dakota (Edlin, 1996). The report, Moving Cooler: An Analysis of Transporta on Strategies for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions, a joint effort of mul ple Federal agencies, environmental organiza-

ons, and Shell Oil, shows the importance of implemen ng various packages of policy measures in reducing VMT and related greenhouse gas emissions in mee ng reduc on tar-gets. Significantly, when fully-variable PAYDAYS insurance was added to a bundle of land use/transit/non-motorized transporta on measures (one of a number of policy bundles evaluated), it led to a 44% increase in the reduc on of transporta on-related greenhouse gas emissions through 2050 than without the inclusion of such insurance (Cambridge Systema cs, Inc., 2009). By providing affordable insurance to low-income motorists who are willing to limit their mileage, PAYDAYS could re-duce the number of uninsured motorists (Litman, 2004). It has been projected that 63.5% of households with insured vehicles (63.7% of urban households, 62.9% of rural house-holds, and approaching 80% for the poorest of households) would save an average of 28% on their total premiums, or about $496 annually for households that do save for fully variable PAYDAYS premiums (Bordoff and Noel, 2008). Another issue to consider when projec ng the benefits of PAYDAYS insurance is the degree to which behavioral eco-nomics strategies are deployed in concert with the new pricing to encourage reduc ons in driving beyond what

would be realized without the use of such strategies. Behav-ioral economics, a discipline combining economics and psy-chology to explain consumer decision making, offers in-sights on marke ng and designing PAYDAYS insurance prod-ucts to maximize consumer acceptance and benefits. Gen-eral behavioral economics research findings strongly sug-gest that different product offerings among the myriad of PAYDAYS insurance product possibili es would result in substan al differences in VMT and in the magnitude of re-lated benefits. For PAYDAYS insurance, the following prod-uct features and related communica ons protocols have been iden fied as most likely to increase consumer re-sponse (i.e., lead to greater reduc ons in driving) at all lev-els of premium: • Direct and transparent per-mile charges (no rebates or

requirements to purchase miles in large use-or-lose bundles);

• Frequent billing emphasizing tangible (check or even cash) as opposed to less tangible (credit card) payment forms;

• Reinforce pricing through e-mail reminders and taxi-like in-vehicle meters;

• Nego ate transit pass discounts and matching funds to buy down prices of alterna ve transporta on modes;

• Provide individualized assistance to customers to re-duce driving by iden fying alterna ve transporta on, trip consolida on, and trip elimina on (e.g., through Internet shopping) op ons; and

• Establish reasonable driving-reduc on goals for par ci-pants and provide, con ngent upon achieving such goals, frequent-flyer-program-like status-related desig-na ons and rewards and “regret lo ery” rewards, where par cipants would regret it if they had to forfeit a lo ery award for failing to meet a goal (Greenberg 2010).

The benefits discussed earlier in this sec on presumed that PAYDAYS insurance would be offered as a pure per-mile premium without the “bells-and-whistles” product features suggested immediately above that would likely enhance driver responsiveness to PAYDAYS pricing. The addi onal benefits from the above strategies is something insurance commissioners may want to consider if faced with a rate filing request that includes product features like these. S - L -T P The combina on of consumer acceptance and the ability of insurance companies to use telema cs in an affordable way to offer PAYDAYS insurance products suggest that the pa ern of market development in the short term may be

(Continued on page 20)

Page 3: P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

20 October 2013 | CIPR Newsle er

P - - - - - - I : P B I (C )

rela vely straigh orward. Insurance companies have a very compelling reason to use telema cs for market segmenta-

on and to offer consumers some incen ves, perhaps through “PAYDAYS insurance lite” policies (where some mi-nor discounts are offered in exchange for drivers sharing telema cs data), to gain their coopera on. Companies that fail to use telema cs for segmenta on face fairly extreme adverse selec on risk. (For example, one firm that facilitates insurance companies in offering usage-based insurance as-serted the following benefits of its driver evalua on scoring at a recent industry conference: when insurance companies with sophis cated, but not telema cs-informed, premium-se ng models use its usage-based score to recalculate pre-miums, 10% of drivers had an expected loss ra o of 30% or less of the average-driver loss ra o and another 10% of driv-ers, at the other extreme, had an expected loss ra o that was 250% greater than the average (Harbage, 2013). Clearly, adverse selec on will occur if some companies have this data, and price accordingly, while others do not, and the la er will likely be unable to price in a way that will both retain market share and enable con nued profitability.) The Na onal Associa on of Insurance Commissioners, CIPR Key Issues webpage cites industry experts projec ng that 20% of insurance plans will incorporate PAYDAYS features within five years (Detroit News, 2013). A recent Towers Watson survey provides an upper-range es mate of con-sumer interest. Fully 79% of respondents would at least consider purchasing a usage-based product, rising to 89% if they were guaranteed that their premiums would not rise (Towers Watson, 2013). The benefits of having consumers appreciate how their driv-ing affects their rates and then being provided an oppor-tunity to change behavior to save on premiums may be lost if “black box” pricing becomes the norm. (“Black box” pric-ing refers to where an insurance company gathers and ap-plies usage-based data in premium se ng primarily for im-proved market segmenta on—to offer the most a rac ve rates to the lowest-risk drivers within any rate class—but without the consumer having any detailed knowledge as to how their usage characteris cs affect their rates.) This con-cern is not just theore cal since the majority of the almost two million people who have signed up for telema cs-enabled insurance products are not provided by their insur-ance carriers significant personalized guidance about reduc-ing their crash exposure and earning premium savings as a result. For any benefits to be conveyed, consumers would need to have access to their own driving data that is linked to crash risk—including about driving amounts, condi ons (e.g., related to conges on and me of day), and vehicle handling (e.g., prevalence of hard braking)—and be provid-

ed the opportunity to alter their driving to further reduce their premiums and crash risk. It is uncertain whether or when the marketplace, without market interven on (whether through regula ons or incen ves), will provide consumers such an opportunity. Interes ngly, separate from insurance product offerings, there are a number of sophis cated smartphone applica-

ons that score drivers on their safety and green-driving performance, coach drivers on improving their perfor-mance, and even in some cases facilitate social media inter-ac on (comparing scores with friends) and the provision of rewards—such as with par cipa ng retailers—for good driving. While there is much discussion and some experi-menta on within the industry of using the smartphone to provide data for PAYDAYS pricing, this approach has not taken off in part because insurance companies cannot be sure that they are ge ng all of the relevant data. Various technology fixes are being tested to address this challenge. Over the longer term, premiums under tradi onal insurance plans would have to rise to reflect that the drivers with the lowest risk exposure will have moved into telema cs-informed insurance plans, leaving the tradi onal plans to cover drivers with somewhat higher average risk exposure. Among the drivers who remain in the tradi onal plans, those with the lowest risk exposure will—like those who le tradi onal insurance plans before them—then have an in-cen ve to move into PAYDAYS insurance plans, too, and tradi onal plans will again need to raise their rates as this phenomenon repeats itself. The key unknown, though, is whether the PAYDAYS insur-ance products that are to become prevalent in the market-place will provide transparent and variable pricing that en-courages motorists to reduce their risk exposure in order to secure a lower rate, or instead whether the products will improve driver segmenta on without offering such incen-

ves (and, thus, without yielding benefits). Of those inter-ested in PAYDAYS insurance, 60% said they would change their driving habits to reduce their premiums, rising to 76% of drivers between the ages of 18 and 34 (Towers Watson, 2013). The ques on remains whether drivers will be afford-ed this opportunity. The most significant voluntary reduc ons in driving re-sul ng from PAYDAYS pricing would be expected for prod-ucts that offer both a reasonable amount of pricing trans-parency and pricing that is presented and structured in a way that empowers consumers to secure a be er rate by reducing their risk exposure over me.

(Continued on page 21)

Page 4: P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

October 2013 | CIPR Newsle er 21

P - - - - - - I : P B I (C )

Many people, especially young adults, are beginning to rely on “shared economy” services in lieu of car ownership to meet their “automobility” needs. Two types of “shared economy” transporta on services are becoming available—peer-to-peer (P2P) carsharing and dynamic ridesharing (both described below)—where new PAYDAYS insurance products could be especially helpful. While the prevalent carsharing model (of a company like Zipcar owning or leasing vehicles that are made available to rent by the hour for its members) lends itself to coverage under exis ng insurance structures, where a commercial insurance product covers all members (who are required to be pre-qualified by the insurance company), insurance offerings may need to be reinvented to accommodate P2P carsharing. P2P carsharing entails individual vehicle owners making their cars available—through a company that han-dles scheduling, payment, insurance, and modifying own-ers’ vehicles to allow authorized third-party access—to rent by the hour. While a tradi onal carsharing firm will only acquire and supply vehicles for specific loca ons where rental income is expected to cover fixed lease/ownership costs, monthly parking charges, and insurance premiums, P2P carsharing instead takes advantage of an underu lized asset (the personally owned vehicle) that has already been acquired and for which the owner typically has reserved parking. Such carsharing requires a usage-based insurance product in order to be economically viable for vehicle own-ers just star ng to share their cars, where insurance premi-ums that are not usage-based could easily exceed rental income. One possibility is an insurance product that meshes a personal and commercial policy into one, which would provide vehicle owners a further incen ve to limit their own driving (beyond the opportunity cost of poten ally forgone rental income), while also charging fairly for insurance cov-erage for other users. In addi on to sharing of vehicles, people are sharing rides in new ways, typically enabled by smartphone applica ons, and where money changes hands as part of such rideshar-ing, the nature of its effects on insurance coverage some-

mes becomes murky. Like with P2P carsharing, usage-based premiums for shared rides when considered com-mercial (typically where the payment to drivers exceed mileage costs) could be especially helpful, when vehicle owners/drivers are only offering their services occasionally. References • Barre , James P. Conference Report: The Benefits of Mileage Based

Auto Insurance Policies. Economic Policy Ins tute, Washington, D.C., March 1999.

• Bordoff, Jason and Noel, Pascal J. “Pay-As-You-Drive Auto Insurance: A Simple Way to Reduce Driving-Related Harms and Increase Equity,” The Brookings Ins tu on, Washington, D.C., July 2008.

• Cambridge Systema cs, Inc. “Moving Cooler: An Analysis of Trans-porta on Strategies for Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions.” Urban Land Ins tute, Washington, D.C., Aug. 2009.

• Detroit News. “Pay-as-you-drive insurance catching on.” Available at DetroitNews.com, Detroit, Aug., 29, 2013.

• Edlin, Aaron S. and Mandic, Pinar Karaca. “The Accident Externality from Driving,” Journal of Poli cal Economy 114.5, University of Chica-go Press, Chicago, 1996.

• Ferreira, Joseph and Minikel, Eric. “Pay-as-you-drive Auto Insurance in Massachuse s: A Risk Assessment and Report on Consumer, In-dustry and Environmental Benefits.” Conserva on Law Founda on, Boston, November 2010.

• Greenberg, Allen. “Applying Behavioral Economics Concepts in De-signing Usage-Based Car Insurance Products.” Appearing in “Sec on 4: Transporta on Structures and Behavior” within People-Centered Ini a ves for Increasing Energy Savings. Edited by Karen Ehrhardt-Mar nez and John A. “Skip” Laitner, American Council for an Energy-Efficient Economy, Washington, DC, Nov. 2010.

• Greenberg, Allen. “Comparing the Benefits of Mileage and Usage Pricing Incen ves with Other Government Transporta on Incen-

ves,” Transporta on Research Board, available at www.ltrc.lsu.edu/TRB_82/TRB2003-001805.pdf, Washington, D.C., Nov. 15, 2002.

• Harbage, Robin. “Market Update and Key Drivers for 2013.” Presen-ta on at Insurance Telema cs USA 2013, Chicago, Sept. 4, 2013.

• Litman, Todd. Distance-Based Vehicle Insurance Feasibility Costs and Benefits: Comprehensive Technical Report, Victoria Transport Policy Ins tute, Victoria, B.C., July 8, 2004.

• Parry, Ian W.H. “Is Pay-As-You-Drive Insurance a Be er Way to Re-duce Gasoline than Gasoline Taxes?” Resources for the Future, Wash-ington, D.C., April 2005.

• Towers Watson. “Drivers Are Overwhelmingly Recep ve to Usage-based Auto Insurance, According to Towers Watson Survey.” New York. Sept. 4, 2013 (press release).

A A

Allen Greenberg has over 20 years of experi-ence in analyzing and advoca ng for sus-tainable U.S transporta on policy at the na onal and regional levels from both inside and outside of government. For the last thirteen years, Allen has been employed as a senior policy analyst at the Federal Highway Administra on, where he plays a leadership role with the Value Pricing Pilot Program

and the Urban Partnership Program, including solici ng and man-aging transporta on pricing pilot ini a ves related to usage-based auto insurance, variable and transparent demand-based parking pricing, and new forms of vehicle-use pricing and services (including car sharing and priced dynamic ridesharing, both of which entail insurance-related challenges). Allen has authored seven peer-reviewed research papers covering a very broad array of issues related to pay-as-you-drive insurance. Allen holds a Masters in Urban and Regional Planning from the University of Virginia and a Bachelor of Science in Public Policy and Manage-ment from Carnegie Mellon University.

Page 5: P ù Ý ùÊç Ù®ò Ä ùÊç Ý ò I : P B Ä I · PAYDAYS insurance have converged on a consensus elas ci-ty figure of -0.15, based on finding a “conserva ve average” of

October 2013 | CIPR Newsle er 27

© Copyright 2013 Na onal Associa on of Insurance Commissioners, all rights reserved. The Na onal Associa on of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) is the U.S. standard-se ng and regulatory support organiza on created and gov-erned by the chief insurance regulators from the 50 states, the District of Columbia and five U.S. territories. Through the NAIC, state insurance regulators establish standards and best prac ces, conduct peer review, and coordinate their regulatory oversight. NAIC staff supports these efforts and represents the collec ve views of state regulators domes cally and interna onally. NAIC members, together with the central re-sources of the NAIC, form the na onal system of state-based insurance regula on in the U.S. For more informa on, visit www.naic.org. The views expressed in this publica on do not necessarily represent the views of NAIC, its officers or members. All informa on contained in this document is obtained from sources believed by the NAIC to be accurate and reliable. Because of the possibility of human or mechanical error as well as other factors, however, such informa on is provided “as is” without warranty of any kind. NO WARRANTY IS MADE, EXPRESS OR IM-PLIED, AS TO THE ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PARTICULAR PURPOSE OF ANY OPINION OR INFORMATION GIVEN OR MADE IN THIS PUBLICATION. This publica on is provided solely to subscribers and then solely in connec on with and in furtherance of the regulatory purposes and objec ves of the NAIC and state insurance regula on. Data or informa on discussed or shown may be confiden al and or proprietary. Further distribu on of this publica on by the recipient to anyone is strictly prohibited. Anyone desiring to become a subscriber should contact the Center for Insur-ance Policy and Research Department directly.

NAIC Central Office Center for Insurance Policy and Research 1100 Walnut Street, Suite 1500 Kansas City, MO 64106-2197 Phone: 816-842-3600 Fax: 816-783-8175

http://www.naic.org http://cipr.naic.org To subscribe to the CIPR mailing list, please email [email protected] or [email protected]