18
This article was downloaded by: [Uniwersytet Warszawski] On: 17 October 2014, At: 06:05 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Scandinavian Economic History Review Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/sehr20 Organising affluence: the Norwegian Consumer Council and comparative product testing in the 1950s and 1960s. Technocratic roots and practices Christine Myrvang a a Centre for Business History, BI Norwegian Business School , Oslo, Norway Published online: 09 Jun 2011. To cite this article: Christine Myrvang (2011) Organising affluence: the Norwegian Consumer Council and comparative product testing in the 1950s and 1960s. Technocratic roots and practices, Scandinavian Economic History Review, 59:2, 149-165, DOI: 10.1080/03585522.2011.572583 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03585522.2011.572583 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms- and-conditions

Organising affluence: the Norwegian Consumer Council and comparative product testing in the 1950s and 1960s. Technocratic roots and practices

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

This article was downloaded by: [Uniwersytet Warszawski]On: 17 October 2014, At: 06:05Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registeredoffice: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Scandinavian Economic History ReviewPublication details, including instructions for authors andsubscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/sehr20

Organising affluence: the NorwegianConsumer Council and comparativeproduct testing in the 1950s and 1960s.Technocratic roots and practicesChristine Myrvang aa Centre for Business History, BI Norwegian Business School , Oslo,NorwayPublished online: 09 Jun 2011.

To cite this article: Christine Myrvang (2011) Organising affluence: the Norwegian ConsumerCouncil and comparative product testing in the 1950s and 1960s. Technocratic roots and practices,Scandinavian Economic History Review, 59:2, 149-165, DOI: 10.1080/03585522.2011.572583

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03585522.2011.572583

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the“Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis,our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as tothe accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinionsand views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors,and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Contentshould not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sourcesof information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims,proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever orhowsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arisingout of the use of the Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Anysubstantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms &Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Organising affluence: the Norwegian Consumer Council andcomparative product testing in the 1950s and 1960s.Technocratic roots and practices

Christine Myrvang*

Centre for Business History, BI Norwegian Business School, Oslo, Norway

The work of the Consumer Council, established in 1953, can be regarded asthe first overall attempt in Norway to organise the capitalist marketplace fromthe consumers’ point of view. As a source of counter-information to seductivecommercial marketing techniques that appealed to people’s hidden desires, theCouncil aimed to enlighten the consumer with objective expert advice on buyingthe best value-for-money goods according to their ‘true needs’. The idea of thegood and functional market was based neither on planning nor on the completeautonomy of market forces, nor was it opposed to an abundant commodityculture as such. In fact, publishing results from scientific product tests for certainitems could be seen as a major contribution to the spread and legitimisation of amodern consumer culture. The article discusses this attempt to organise affluencethrough the construction of a context-free, objective reality by a scientificbureaucracy of consumption and looks into the historical roots of such practices.

Keywords: consumer culture; consumer politics; comparative product testing;technocracy; Norway

Organising consumers

As a mass market of consumer goods developed during the nineteenth century, the

question of organising consumer interests came to attention in industrialising parts of

the world. Small-scale consumer cooperation flourished through wholesaling and

retailing networks, making room for exchange of goods outside the predominant

market institutions. The consumer co-operative movement exerted a powerful appeal

as a counterforce against profit-seeking capitalists and as a way of protecting

consumers. This heterogeneous movement was, in short, aiming at a more democratic

control of the means of consumption and securing the needs of its members.

Historically, there have been profound struggles regarding the political and

ideological meaning of consumer co-operatives’ potential of rearranging the economy

and society. By the beginning of the twentieth century, consumer co-operation was

both regarded as a ‘third way’ between free-competition capitalism and socialist

planning, and simultaneously � within the labour movement � presented as a ‘third

pillar of socialism’, along with trade unionism and political labour parties.1 In

Norway the co-operative movement grew strong during the first half of the twentieth

century, while it was also struggling for its ideological and organisational indepen-

dency in relation to the powerful labour movement. However, the country � as

*Email: [email protected]

Scandinavian Economic History Review

Vol. 59, No. 2, June 2011, 149�165

ISSN 0358-5522 print/ISSN 1750-2837 online

# 2011 Taylor & Francis

DOI: 10.1080/03585522.2011.572583

http://www.informaworld.com

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

Scandinavia in general � lacked other powerful consumer advocacy groups that could

raise consumption as an issue of civic engagement and promote general consumer

interests.2

In most countries, the co-operative way of organising consumer interests was

severely challenged in the decades after the Second World War. A new affluent and

pleasure-oriented consumer culture was a powerful force, and the post-war consumer

politics in countries such as the Social Democratic Norway put an emphasis on the

need for empowering individual buyers to navigate the dizzying array of marketplace

choices. In Scandinavian countries, state-sponsored consumer institutions emerged

after the war; the Danish Danske husmødres forbrugerrad (the Danish Housewives’

Consumer Council) in 1947, the Norwegian Forbrukerradet (the Consumer Council)

in 1953 and the Swedish Statens Konsumentrad (the State Consumer Council) in

1957. Such advocacy bodies soon became an important supplement to the co-

operative movement, and in the case of Norway, one can argue that the Council,

rather than the consumer co-operative union, NKL, in fact was given a ‘third pillar’

function inside the mixed market economy of the Social Democratic post-war state.

Today, the Consumer Council is regarded as the master voice of Norwegian

consumers.As Iselin Theien has pointed out, the Norwegian Consumer Council established in

1953 was mainly a result of joint efforts of the women of the consumer co-operative

movement and housewives’ organisations, in combination with the Norwegian

Price Directorate request for a consumer advisory body in matters regarding price

regulations.3 The women strongly demanded governmental quality control of goods

on the post-war market where nearly ‘anything’ could be sold. The ‘ashtray industry’

was the contemporary concept describing the production results of the powerful

demand pressure.4 The housewives’ initiative appeared at a time when Norwegian

politics went through an intense struggle on the issue of a planned economy. The

implementation of a new Price and Rationalisation Act would have given the

government an important tool for resource allocation, production control and market

regulations. However, the work on the Act was set aside by the Labour Party after

major confrontations with business and industry. A more moderate Price Act was

passed in Parliament while the attempt to increase the productivity of industrial

production was intensified through a new Productivity Institute.5

Post-war consumption was regulated in part by import restrictions, by price

and tax policy, and by a system of wage adjustments. Yet, the new Consumer Council

had ambitions to make further improvements on the market through white-coated

scientists and technical expertise bridging the information gap between sellers and

users of branded goods. This faith in science was a distinct feature of post-war

consumerist activism in many countries.6 The Norwegian Consumer Council was

politically neutral, but could still be regarded as the Labour Party’s baby during the

first decades of its existence. Both chairpersons of the Consumer Council during the

period examined by this paper were members of the Labour Party.7 The actual

Council was a body of seven individuals, who represented various housewives’

organisations, the consumer cooperative movement, and the Norwegian Confedera-

tion of Trade Unions (LO), in addition to the chairperson appointed by Parliament.

A key issue was mobilising each individual consumer in the capitalist marketplace

through knowledge production and distribution, whereby the imbalances between

business and consumers was meant to be confronted and altered. In fact, in 1954, the

150 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

OEEC recommended an increase of organised consumer research and consumer

guidance as a way of creating more efficient markets in Europe.8 However, Norwegianbusiness and industry were hostile to the idea of a Consumer Council as they

considered it to be just another planning tool in the hands of social democrats.9

The Consumer Council was to embody various experiences and interests of the

consumers put forward by the housewives’, co-operatives, and labour organisations

who were represented on the Council. Here, different types of competencies were

gathered and re-institutionalised. Yet, in the 1950s and 1960s, these experiences were

of secondary importance compared with the Council’s extensive use of external,

technical expertise. One of the Council’s main activities was product testing. As latershown in this article, this meant systematically revealing and comparing the technical

qualities of different brands of consumer commodities primarily through laboratory

experiments. Subsequently, the test results were presented in the Council’s magazine

Forbruker-rapporten (Consumer Report), where consumers could study the results

carefully and then � in the marketplace � buy the products that corresponded to their

‘true’ and ‘rational’ needs.

However, as a point of departure I will first discuss the historical roots of the

Norwegian Consumer Council by focusing on three main legacies: first, thecorporatist heritage of obtaining consumer representation in an economic democracy,

and then two technocratic motivated sources of inspiration: the home economics

movement and the technocratic consumer activism, which focused on the construc-

tion of a rational consumer operating in the institutions of the market with the help of

science and technical expertise. This article mainly addresses the practices of product

testing and the publishing of these tests in the Council’s magazine, Consumer Report,

for informing purchase decisions. This was a time and labour-consuming practice

firmly stressed by the Council itself. My aim is to show that the state sponsoredConsumer Council was not just a distinct post-war Social Democratic institution. By

putting an emphasis on the historical roots, I investigate the impact of the inter-war

debate on economic democracy and stress the inspiration from the American

technocratic movement. The article explores the Consumer Council’s notion of

ultimate markets, ranging from its historical legacy to the construction of an affluent

market economy through the help of expert advice as a meaningful, rational system in

the 1950s and 1960s.

The corporatist heritage

When the Labour government, along with the price director, considered setting up a

Consumer Council in the early 1950s, the main task was to establish a body that

would allow for the representation of the interests of the consumer ‘in a rational

way’.10 The Council was seen as an important part of a corporatist structure based

on market regulation and economic democracy. Ever since the First World War, the

powerful Norwegian price director and liberal leftist Wilhelm Thagaard called fororganising consumer interests and representation regarding public control over

trusts, cartels, and the price mechanism.11 In the marketplace, consumers � not

workers � were considered to embody the true counter-interests of corporate power.

After the Second World War, the problem of representation became even more

urgent and the category of consumers became increasingly visible in the political

debate.12 The extensive system of price control established during the war was

Scandinavian Economic History Review 151

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

redeveloped in the subsequent years. In a wide range of Price Panels consumer

representation was achieved through workers, white-collar employees, ‘or others

representing consumer interests’.13 In some cases unionists had been appointedas consumer representatives, in others housewives, but none of these arrangements

was fully satisfactory. At times it was quite obvious that the unionists’ identity was

based more on their role as employees of companies than as consumers.

The consuming public was, of course, everyone. But when reflecting the problem

of proper representation, price director Thagaard was addressing the economic

function of consumers. This division of interests based on different functions and

roles in the economic system was important in the corporate planning tradition.

Ideologically the Norwegian labour movement became revolutionary during

the First World War, inspired by uprisings in Russia and Germany. The following

debate on socialisation put forward visions of an economic democracy organised

with the help of a vertical and horizontal council structure at a local/enterprise level,

a district/branch level, and a national level.14 And even though it was obvious that

the focus was primarily on the so-called productive part of the population (consumers

were not considered among them), consumers were supposed to be given a small role

in the socialist economy both through representation in the council system andthrough the notion that a democratic, socialised economic system’s main objective

was to effectively supply the needs of the population, in contrast to the capitalist

system that was geared towards maximising profit. The socialisation theorists

suggested the control of production by ‘the working and consuming people’.15 Yet it

was highly unclear who the consumer was and how this economic function should be

given representation. At the same time it was clear that technical and scientific

expertise was to be given a far more powerful position than both workers and

consumers, and that technocracy would precede democracy in the actual manage-

ment of a socialised economy.16 When it came to organising the future socialised

production based on consumers’ ‘true’ needs, the vision of the 1920s’ socialisation

theorists was that the Riksøkonomiradet (National Economic Council), comprised of

representatives of producers, consumers and scientists, would seek complete

harmony between production and consumption. In order to achieve this, they

would compile national statistics on both needs and recourses, which would be the

starting point for managed production in order to satisfy consumer needs and to

promote the efficient utilisation of production forces.17

Gradually the Labour Party left the revolutionary programme and became

reformist. During the depression years of the early 1930s, the ideas for handling the

capitalist crisis were, to a large extent, put in concrete terms in The Norwegian Three-

Year Plan: The Road Towards a Socialistic Planned Economy in Norway, published by

the economist Ole Colbjørnsen and agronomist Axel Sømme in 1933. The

Colbjørnsen and Sømme Plan was even more producerist than the socialisation

theories of the 1920s when it came to forming a corporatist council structure. In their

advisory National Economic Council there was no room for consumer representa-

tion at all.18 The Three-Year Plan � which was pragmatic state-capitalist rather than

utopian socialist in orientation � addressed the issue of purchasing power and the

raising of a standard of living on a broad scale, but was still more focused on a push

of supply rather than a pull of demand.19 The plan had hardly anything to say about

the satisfaction of human needs and how to decide what to produce, if not through

the market mechanism. In fact, the plan did not undermine private industry and

152 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

retailing; this would exist along with new state enterprises just as the market

mechanism would exist side by side with public price regulations. The task of theoverall planning of economic life was to be put in the hands of a National Planning

Commission, which was a body of economic and technical experts who worked

alongside politicians.20

A socialist revolution never occurred in Norway, although the Labour Party

became the leading political party after the Second World War. The party set aside its

most ambitious plans for regulating economic life, but the corporatist inheritance

was of great importance at the time when the Consumer Council was established.

In 1953, general consumer interests were for the first time given some type oforganised form in Norway, while the Labour Party simultaneously abandoned

its radical planning ambitions. The hierarchal corporatist ambitions were trans-

formed into a ‘corporative pluralism’, in which representatives of organised interests

were brought into the sphere of public administration in great numbers.21 After ten

years of its existence, the Consumer Council was represented on 27 different panels

and committees, both publicly and privately organised.22 Yet, even though the

Council played a specific role in representing the consumer’s voice in a post-war

capitalist corporative state, I will argue that this was not its only main task in the1950s and 1960s. The Council was just as focused on directly addressing consumer

behaviour on the markets and, through its practical activity, on laying the

groundwork for what was considered to be both an affluent and a rational economic

order.

The technocratic heritage

Along with the corporatist legacy, I will point out two other important roots ofthe Norwegian Consumer Council, namely the home economics movement and

consumer activism. The corporatist tradition was also related to technocracy by

pushing for governance by competent elites.23 Still, these two movements held the

conviction that expertise could change the relations of the marketplace, especially by

changing the behaviour of the individual consumer.

First, the Council’s activities in the 1950s and 960s were based on the legacy of

the home economics movement. Throughout the progressive era in the USA at the

end of the nineteenth and the beginning of the twentieth century, there had been aprofound focus on professionalising the housewife by making housework more

scientific and rational. At the turn of the century, this movement was highly

influenced by the spirit of the organisation engineer Frederick W. Taylor. The gospel

of Taylorism, and of efficient housekeeping in general, spread to many countries,

including the Scandinavian ones.24 Home economists were educated to become

experts of the domestic household in a broad sense. They became teachers and

lecturers, presenting to housewives the modern scientific methods for doing

housework, for buying the right goods, and for running an efficient household. Inaddition, many of them became consultants, selling expert knowledge to business.25

Especially in the USA, but also in Scandinavia, home economists actively promoted

a commodity culture through their participation in business marketing practices. Of

particularly great importance throughout the twentieth century was their contribu-

tion to the diffusion of household durables such as electric cookers, washing

machines, vacuum cleaners, refrigerators and other technical appliances for the

Scandinavian Economic History Review 153

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

home. These household experts were seen in advertisements as well as in sales

demonstrations. They performed an interpreting function, framing the commodities

according to the lives of the housewives. However, they were also hired bycorporations to test and develop products, thereby providing expert advice on the

needs and desires of modern housewives. In this way, many household experts looked

upon themselves as mediators of the market, organising the relations between

consumers and producers.26

At the end of the nineteenth century, courses in home economics penetrated the

curriculum of North American high schools, women’s colleges, and state universities.

By the turn of the century, departments of home economics had been established in

30 colleges.27 Even though this was far from the case in Norway, the creation of

Statens lærinneskole i husstell (the National School for Domestic Science Teachers) in

1909 laid an important foundation for spreading the home economics message

through local housewife schools. Many of these Norwegian, middle-class domestic

science teachers promoted consumer products for business, just like their American

colleagues.28 During the period 1936�1939, Statens forsøksvirksomhet i husstell (the

National Research Unit for Domestic Science) was established, which among other

things specialised in the testing of consumer products, from the 1950s also oncommission for the Consumer Council. In 1940, Statens opplysningskontor i husstell

(the National Information Office for Domestic Science) was created. The chemist

Bergliot Quiller, who headed the research unit, was sent to study home economics in

the USA where she found that the Americans were at least 15 years ahead of Norway

when it came to domestic science research and education.29

Although they were primarily based on nutrition, hygiene and housework

discourses, the new domestic science institutions were also rooted in the idea that

housewives could be made into rational buyers. A corresponding programme could

be found among American consumer activists. During the progressive era, the first

wave of consumer activism occurred in the USA which among other things

contributed to the creation of protective food and drug legislation at the start of

the twentieth century. This first wave played an important role in placing consumer

exploitation and the issue of the standard of living on the political agenda. The

second wave of American consumer activism started at the end of the 1920s and

reached its peak during the depression years and New Deal in the 1930s. The focal

points here were mainly branded goods, advertising, and the confusion ofmisinformed consumers.30 The politics and practises of the Norwegian Consumer

Council in the 1950s and 1960s drew on the heritage from the second wave’s private

American watchdog organisations: Consumers’ Research Inc. (CR, established in

1929) and the Consumers Union (CU, 1936).31 There was a short-lived attempt to

establish an equivalent non-government consumer advocacy group in Norway in

1939, called Forbrukernes Kontroll-lag (the Consumer’s Control Association), but the

troubled wartime economy brought this to an end.32

The founders of the American Consumers’ Research were the accountant Stuart

Chase and the engineer Frederick Schlink, both of whom were influenced by

Thorstein Veblen’s critique of the business enterprise and by the Taylorist debates on

efficiency and waste, and both had the commitment to improve technical rationality

in an economy of abundance.33 In the book The Tragedy of Waste from 1925, Stuart

Chase discussed waste in consumption, which was a form of waste caused by the

affluent production of goods that had no root in real human needs. He regarded

154 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

these commodities as illth (a concept he borrowed from the English artist and writer

John Ruskin), which was the opposite of wealth. Chase called for a more functional

society in which the satisfaction of human needs, not the maximisation of profit, wasthe criterion for an efficient and successful economic system.34 This perspective was

followed up by the book Your Money’s Worth (1927), which Chase wrote together

with Frederick Schlink. The engineer Schlink had discovered the consumer issue

while working at the Bureau of Standards in the 1910s, and later as assistant

secretary to the American Engineering Standards Committee. The Bureau of

Standards had been testing the quality of products for the government and had

amassed information on a vast number of brands. Schlink thought that this

information should ideally be handed over to the consumers so that they could get

the most value for their money.35 In Your Money’s Worth the authors described the

consumer as a helpless victim in a war of adjectives generated by the advertising

industry.36 However, not all the products could simply be ‘the best’, and there was

therefore a great need for scientific methods that could reveal the true qualities of the

products. ‘The great bulk of things which we consumers buy are not reviewed by any

impartial testing body’, Chase and Schlink wrote. ‘Most of them advance upon us

from behind a great smoke screen of advertising. Given time enough, and trial and

error enough, quality will in many cases make itself felt. But consider the waste ofthis trial and error method against a permanent source to which we might turn for

the results of scientific tests and the setting of impartial standards.’37 They summed

up their plea for scientific buying as follows: ‘If science could displace magic in

salesmanship, the whole curve of consumption would change. Science has taught the

manufacturer how to plan for mass production, but there is as yet no science, broadly

speaking, in consumption.’38

The book Your Money’s Worth was not directly anti-capitalist or hostile to the

market as such. It can rather be regarded as an attempt to create the neoclassical

perfect market with full information. The authors identified modern salesmanship,

especially the institution of advertising, as the main reason for existing dysfunction-

alities.39 Salesmanship created artificial desires and made people buy things

they could do without. According to the neoclassical concept of the ‘economic

man’, which had been developed before the making of modern marketing insti-

tutions, consumers possess full information about the qualities and prices of the

commodities and they are able to make rational choices. What Chase and Schlink

were asking for was objective counter-information to advertisement based onscientific methods so that the consumers were fully able to perform their function

in the market. This was the laboratory path to a functional economy � fair, just, safe

and efficient.

Within a few months Your Money’s Worth became a Book-of-the-Month best

seller. Shortly after, the two authors established the New York based Consumers’

Research Incorporated, financed by patrons of liberal magazines.40 Consumers’

Research organised impartial scientific tests of different types of branded goods and

published the results in the magazine Consumers’ Research Bulletin. The organisation

stated that its aim was to readjust the ‘rapidly increasing power of the manufacturer

and seller over the mind and judgment of the consumer’.41 However, after a strike hit

Consumers’ Research in 1935, some of the most active members left the organisation

and formed Consumers Union, Inc. in 1936. This new organisation addressed the

living conditions of the consumers and the standard of living issue in a broad sense,

Scandinavian Economic History Review 155

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

but Consumers Union continued in the footsteps of Chase and Schlink by specialising

in impartial product testing as well. The results were distributed by a new publication,

Consumers Union Reports, which later took the name Consumer Reports. After the

Second World War, the Consumers Union was the major consumer organisation in

America, with a growth of registered members from 55,000 in 1945 to close to 900,000

in 1960.42

Un/dressing consumers and commodities

It was these product testing practices in particular that were adopted by the

Norwegian Consumer Council. In fact, this state-financed body established in 1953

was the closest one got to the ‘second wave consumer activism’ in Norway. Quality

control, product labels and consumer guidance were considered to be important

tools. When the Consumer Council was established, the ambition was also to develop

certain standard products of good quality at low prices. The Council managed to get

one ‘People’s washing machine’ on the market, the relatively low-cost ‘Evalet

Populær’. However, in general such standardisation efforts were not very successful

due to lack of interest from manufacturers.43

Throughout the first decades, one of the Council’s main activities was conducting

various technical tests of consumer products carried out by external experts in

laboratories. First, the tests were made available as information for media in the

rather modest leaflet F-rapporten (the F-report) established in 1954. But the Council

was soon aiming for a more direct contact with consumers. From 1958 and onward,

the test results were published in the Council’s new magazine, Consumer Report,

edited by the economist Bjørn Gulbrandsen. This was the first Scandinavian

magazine that systematically presented advisory consumer product tests, and as

Jannike Wehn Hegnes has shown, it was highly inspired by the American Consumer

Reports.44 In 1957, the Council’s chairman Ragnar Christiansen had actually visited

CR and CU and other institutions on a trip organised by the post-Marshall agency

International Cooperation Administration (ICA). Christiansen was highly impressed

with the work of the American comparative testing organisations.45

In an increasingly abundant post-war economy these Consumer Reports were

meant to guide the confused consumer. ‘Think before you act’,46 was the Council’s

message to the shopping public. Consumer Report was soon to become a great

success, with nearly 80,000 subscribers in 1963 and close to 200,000 by the end of the

decade. This made it one of the largest consumer magazines in the world, taking into

account the country’s population (3.9 million in 1970).

As already mentioned, the neoclassical assumption of the perfect market was

based on rational choice of a fully informed consumer. However, the Consumer

Council’s critique of the affluent market was based on the consumer continuously

being misinformed through the corporations’ marketing activities. In this way, the

Consumer Council framed its mission along the same lines as Chase and Schlink. The

bureaucracy of the firm was occupied with designing markets, and through marketing

research the producers invented more and more sophisticated forms of ‘dressing up’

commodities. The techniques of advertising and product branding were based on

cultural and social connotations of the objects. Critics would claim that consumers

were persuaded to buy things on false pretences by the corporations’ construction of

156 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

‘false’ needs through appealing to people’s vanity and other irrational feelings.

Therefore, the Consumer Council’s task was to strip these commodities from the same

connotations constructed by commercial interests. Only then could the ‘real’ but

hidden qualities of the goods be exposed. Through such professional guidance the

consumers would have actual freedom of choice, and only then would the market

experience healthy price and quality competition. ‘True’ needs of consumers would be

met and the standard of living lifted.47

In the 1930s, the marketing institutions, especially in America, intensified their

knowledge production. The ambition was that business should know as much about

efficiency in distribution as industry knew about efficiency in production.48 Market-

ing researchers aimed to develop scientific tools for mapping consumers’ wants, where

and when they were likely to buy an item, and at what price, as well as how to promote

commodities. During the next decades there was extensive discussion of how to

improve the marketing techniques and make them more reliable and effective. These

discussions challenged the statistical methods and problems of representation, as well

as psychological questions in connection with questionnaires and interviewing

techniques.

The first institute for measuring public opinion in Norway was called ‘Fakta’ �Facts � and was established in 1944. In 1946, the competing company Norsk Gallup

(Norwegian Gallup) was established based on the techniques of the American

psychologist George Gallup. For both Fakta and Norwegian Gallup, market research

was a central activity. In addition to measuring public opinion on commodities

through different surveys, the quantitative mapping of brand diffusion on the market

became an important task. Soon, the tools became more specialised. In the mid-

1960s, the company bought a bus, which it used as a mobile laboratory for conducting

advertisement and product tests; the latter measuring people’s reactions to actual

commodities to which they were exposed.49

The 1960s was, in general, a decade when Norwegian Gallup and other marketing

institutions developed more and more sophisticated qualitative methods, for example

motivation studies became a part of the portfolio.50 This had been one of the major

innovations of the market research discipline in the 1950s, especially in the USA.

Motivation research was considered to be an in-depth method for penetrating

underneath the surface of the consumer’s consciousness to the sub-conscious sphere

with the help of psychological techniques. Instead of asking what, when and where

consumers were buying, motivation researchers began to ask the question of why

they buy. Psychological techniques for commercial use in the advertisement industry

had been under development in America and Germany since the beginning of the

twentieth century. But motivation research took it even further, and even deeper. It

was based on the assumption that people often do not really mean what they say,

that they do not necessarily act in the ways they say they were going to act, and that

they often want other things than they actually express in interviews. Knowledge of

these hidden aspects of human nature was music to the ears of industry and business.

This meant that the marketing strategy, from product development to advertising

material, could be tailored to consumers’ hidden, emotional desires. Sociological

analyses of status systems according to social groups, as well as research on market

segmentation in the late 1950s, were of great importance when producers and

distributors targeted specific potential customers through advertising.51

Scandinavian Economic History Review 157

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

Organising affluence through comparative product testing

In general, the 1950s and 1960s were decades when large parts of the empirical social

sciences were developed in close contact with industrial and commercial interests,

especially in the USA. This gave fuel to an extensive critique of both researchers and

business: through their contribution to making marketing techniques more and more

sophisticated, psychologists and sociologists were accused of running errands for

forces that often were in direct opposition to common people’s interests. Although

commercial interests were largely convinced that they only gave people what they

truly desired, social scientists were criticised for lending business a helping hand by

persuading consumers to buy products they did not really need. As a counter-attack,

organised consumers arranged their own scientific, comparative product tests,

‘unwrapping’ the commodities from the social and cultural connotations that

business had packaged them in. As in the case of motivation research, this activity

also aimed at revealing something hidden; not the hidden wants of the consumers,

but the hidden qualities and facts of the commodities. The idea of the good and

efficient market was based neither on planning nor on the complete freedom of

market forces, nor was it opposed to the affluent economy as such, since publishing

the test results on certain brand-items, such as washing machines, refrigerators,

vacuum cleaners, cars, televisions and stereos, could be regarded as a major

contribution to the spread and legitimisation of a modern consumer culture.

The procedures for conducting an average commodity test were presented in an

edition of Consumer Report in 1967.52 According to this (normative) description of

techniques, the first step was how to decide on which type of product was going to be

tested. This selection, the magazine stated, was mainly a result of complaints received

from the public based on their personal experiences with the items, but it could also be

initiated by individuals within or outside the Council. The next step was for the

Council’s secretariat to find an independent research institute or laboratory to carry

out the test. This institution formulated a test programme on questions such as ‘What

type of qualities will be tested?’, ‘Which brands and how many samples are needed?’,

‘What type of procedures should be undertaken during the test?’ and so on. After

that, the plan was presented to producers and importers of the commodity, who were

invited to comment on the technical aspects of the test programme. Comments of a

more principled character were to be addressed directly to the Consumer Council.

The next step was for the Council to grant its approval for the test to be carried out.

Then a representative of the Council would buy the products anonymously in the

shop � ‘just like a regular consumer’ � or in special cases he or she would borrow the

items from the producer or the importer. The commodities were handed over to

the research institute, and then the lab experiments begun. The magazine write-up

emphasised in a scientific manner that one should be able to reproduce the same test

again under exactly the same circumstances. After completing the laboratory tests, the

results were translated into a report that was handed over to the Consumer Council.

Then the manufacturers or importers were invited to comment on the test performed

on their product or, in some cases, to challenge the results. Challenges on a technical

basis were again dealt with by the research institution, whereas the challenges based

on principle were considered by the Council. If necessary, new tests could be

conducted. The next step was another translation, namely the process in which the

report was popularised and published in Consumer Report. The final manuscript was

158 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

controlled by technical and legal experts before being sent back to the research

institution for approval. Finally, the Council, the editorial committee and the editorwould decide on whether or not the results would be published. If so, the article was

printed with corresponding illustrations � and then it would be up to the consumer to

choose the best value-for-money commodity!

One striking aspect of this procedure for impartial, comparative scientific testing

is that it created a considerable bureaucracy of consumption, especially if it was seen

as a permanent, institutionalised practice that was crucial for a functional market.

Another is the amount of interpretation and representation that was carried out on

behalf of the consumer. By choosing the types of commodities and brands and byfocusing on certain types of qualities, the tests also produced certain frameworks

within which the ideal consumer and his or her needs were constructed. In the

following section, I will give an example of how the product of the test, namely the

final presentation in Consumer Report, also contained various types of interpreta-

tions. To make this small case study more complete, I will also show how the same

commodities were presented in advertising. The motivation for this is the fact that the

commodity tests were established as objective counter-information to advertising

messages. But, as we will see, both of them were in the business of defining situationsand framing objects and consumer practices through simultaneously created cultural

images of how people should live their lives. As pointed out by the Swedish sociologist

Boel Berner, experts have had a strong power in the making and maintenance of social

orders throughout these decades.53 Their special social position of authority has, for

example, naturalised the gendered division of labour in the household, but at the same

time changed routines of housework.

Buying the good cooker: two framings of ‘Rex’

The example I have chosen is based on a commodity test presented in a lengthy article

in Consumer Report, no. 6, 1963. Here, engineers from the Norwegian Control Agency

of Electrical Equipment, NEMKO, tested the technical qualities of 12 cookers. First,

however, I will describe how these products were presented in contemporary

advertisements. This is an example of a commercial marketing message targeting

the consumer, which the Consumer Council was trying to counter-balance.

In general, cooker advertisements in woman magazines contained technicalinformation, illustrations of the commodities and exclusive details, as well as

commercial slogans. The overall framings were often that housewives would both

become more efficient and be given more freedom with the new equipment. For

example, the ‘Elektra’ cooker from the company Per Kure was presented with a

‘thinking hotplate’, which could ‘regulate itself ’ with a thermostat mechanism. The

illustration was divided in three parts, showing the cooker, a hotplate surrounding

the housewife’s head in a ‘science fictional’ style, and a woman holding up her arms

as if she was liberated.54 Other advertisements stressed the look of the cookers. Forexample, ‘Beha de Luxe’ had ‘NEW elegance � clean modern lines’55 and ‘Let the

new KPS Super-T adorn your kitchen’.56 In addition, the overall focus on technology

as ‘automatic’ was strong in these advertisements. Scientific progress had reached the

kitchen.

I will now further examine the results for one of the brands presented in Consumer

Report: the ‘Rex’ cooker manufactured by the Norwegian company Elektrisk Bureau.

Scandinavian Economic History Review 159

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

An earlier advertisement of this cooker prior to the Council’s commodity test is highly

interesting as it contains expert advice from a home economist.57 The rather large

advertisement contains the headline ‘Automatic cooking and barbeque frying in athousand homes’ and the slogan ‘Tomorrow’s cooker’. We see a picture of the Rex

cooker, with a close-up of the control panel complete with a timer, and next to it we

find the consultant of home economics, Rigmor Holth. This also tells us that the

manufacturer is relying on the authority of expertise when addressing the consumer.

The advertisement may be viewed as an example of the phenomenon mention earlier,

whereby housekeeping experts spread a consumer culture by selling their names and

skills to companies’ marketing strategists.

Throughout the text, Rigmor Holth speaks in a direct tone to the consumers � or

more precisely, to the housewives. Relying on her knowledge of housework and

housewives, she draws on her authority as she makes a statement in favour of the Rex

cooker. She not only presents the many technical qualities of the commodity, she also

places them in a context that forms a cultural framework for the Rex cooker. The

narrative tells us that housewives are always very busy, whether or not they work

outside the home. The Rex cooker, however, is the solution to the problem. With the

help of the ‘beautiful and practical’ control panel you can leave the house while thecooker works for you. And with the barbeque technique � the ‘frying method of

the future’ � the nutrients and vitamins of the food are well preserved. The Rex

cooker was built on 40 years of experience and deserved the label ‘Tomorrow’s

cooker’, Holth concludes.

Moving on to the Consumer Report, the article on the Rex cooker was presented

in the same scientific spirit as the ad. The comparative cooker test was front page

material, containing a large colour photo of two white-coated male engineers baking

a cake at the NEMKO kitchen lab. These men were about to test the ovens of

12 different cookers by making identical cakes according to standardised procedures.

This type of focus on the specific practices of the commodity tests was very common

in the Consumer Report. But how was the actual commodity described?

The narrative of the Rex cooker comes in two versions: a table of technical results

and a descriptive text followed by a simple photo of the cooker. In the descriptive

text, the various functions as well as the volume, height, breadth and depth

are presented. The diameter of each of the hotplates and the regulating stages for theheat are also pointed out. The oven is equipped with a light and has a ‘heat guard’.

There is also a short statement about the baking test: ‘The cake was cooked through

and had a normal height. The baking evenness was completely satisfactory on both

the top and the underside of the cake.’58

The technical results of the test were presented in a simplified table so that

the different cookers could be easily compared. Here, the technical facts of size,

space, time and energy efficiency measured by the NEMKO engineers are shown in

the smallest detail. The table shows, among other things, that the actual temperature

measured in the oven was 1968C when the thermostat was set at 2008C, that the

boiling time of the largest hotplate was 8.76 minutes (for boiling 2 litres of water),

and that the efficiency of this plate was measured to be 65%.59 Neither the table, nor

the descriptive text or the general magazine article on the cooker tests said anything

about the life situations of the persons who would use this type of cooker. The

commodity is apparently de-gendered and the cultural context is removed, unlike

the narrative in the advertisement. But like the ad, the test article has a gender. The

160 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

male engineers in their white laboratory coats provide the results with the necessary

authority, and maybe their voices seem to be more objective and scientific than thevoice of the female home economist. Of course, a major difference is that Rigmor

Holth was paid by Elektrisk Bureau to promote the cooker. There is no doubt she

was representing business interests. At the same time, however, the ad tries to connect

her to consumer interests, i.e. the housewives. The NEMKO engineers were paid by

the Consumer Council to perform the test; yet they are not associated directly with

the consumers. We notice that the home economist relies on a different type of

experience than the engineers. She uses her knowledge of women’s life situations,

while NEMKO’s men are more closely connected to the practices of objective science.While the home economist in the narrative of the ad can be regarded as an ally of the

producer and the consumer, the engineers seem to be more independent of the market

actors: the test was about their authority, the test situation and the test object.

From the Consumer Council’s point of view, the idea behind the comparative

product tests was not that they directly would state which brand was ‘best in test’. The

test results were presented in a way that enabled each consumer to find the best

product according to their individual needs. But at the same time, the professionals

performing and presenting the tests had to have some idea of what these needs mightrefer to. The inner core of this engineer-inspired organisation of the market is

connected to a correspondence between the consumer’s ‘real’ needs and the physically

measurable features of the cooker. Although the price of the cooker and the

evaluation of the baking results are also mentioned in the text, the article does not pay

much attention to it. The ‘automatic cooking’ emphasised in the advertisement is not

tested or commented on. In fact, the test results do not mention anything about how

modern the cooker is or if it could help people in their busy, daily activities. They do

not say whether it will look good in the kitchen or impress the next-door neighbour.The consumer had no need for such subjective pieces of information. However, the

commodity test article also says something about how the modern Norwegian

consumer should perform his or her duties. ‘Think before you act’ was the slogan of

the Consumer Council, but it was obvious that the proper type of thinking was strictly

engineer-oriented. The facts about commodities that the consumer should look at

before buying were highly detailed and technical. It was hard work finding the right

commodity. All this stood in sharp contrast to the light-hearted, easy-going and

leisurely consumer culture beginning to dominate mass media in the 1950s and 1960s.Expert advice was considered to be a guarantor of both a healthy affluent economy

and an economic democracy, but at the end of the 1960s voices were finally being

raised: did this strategy really work?

The ultimate market in a reform technocracy

The Norwegian sociologist Rune Slagstad has described the social democratic post-

war state as a ‘reform technocracy’.60 This was the great era of an engineeringmentality, and the Government was leaning heavily on a combination of scientific

paternalism and technocratic management at the state level. According to Slagstad,

social economists were the avant-garde of this social democratic reform technocracy

and the Labour Party aimed for an overall governance of the economy on a macro

level. When Slagstad made no room for the Consumer Council in this picture, it

might have been because it appeared on a different level of analysis and it was not a

Scandinavian Economic History Review 161

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

direct political instrument in the hands of the Labour Party. Still, the efforts of the

Norwegian Consumer Council in the 1950s and 1960s can largely be interpreted

as the pragmatic and practical side of a social democratic consumer policy. Aproducerist macro-political-economy level was supplemented by a consumerist

micro-market-economy level. The Consumer Council’s notion of the ultimate market

can be regarded as a consumer-driven production orientation. Competent consumers

were the ‘road to a higher standard of living’, as the editorial of the first edition of

Consumer Report stated. Consumers with a critical, alert and active attitude would

‘get an immediate raise in standard of living, and they will encourage sound price

and quality competition and thereby lay the groundwork for rational production of

commodities at reasonable prices’.61

However, at the end of the 1960s, this rather optimistic vision of the rational

consumer’s influence on production faded. Critique arose from within the organisa-

tion, from the subscribers of Consumer Report, and from a growing discussion abroad

on consumer policy issues in general. Increasingly, the international movement

questioned its own preoccupation with the rational, individualist, value-for-money,

choice-based consumerism.62 As the Swedish academic and consumer activist Brita

Akerman put it in a profound attack on the ambitions of testing more and moreproducts with increasingly sophisticated methods; the consumer activist would just be

‘running around in a hamster wheel’. Industry was constantly feeding consumers’

laboratories with testing objects and consumers felt powerful when sorting bad goods

from good ones. But industry would always be the initiating force, and there-

fore consumer activists would have to devise a whole new plan for influencing

production.63

This feeling of constantly lagging behind the forces of production was also

growing in the Norwegian Consumer Council. Commodity testing was an expensive

and labour-demanding business. As long as there was a continuous flow of new

products into the market, the job of testing was like housework � it was never done.

But the factor that really made the Council disillusioned was the results of a survey

conducted by the Norwegian Statistical Bureau in 1969 of the readers of Consumer

Report. The survey showed that the vast majority of readers belonged to a rather

wealthy and enlightened middle class, which was considered to be the segment of the

population that least needed guidance.64 This was indeed a democratic problem, and

along with growing dissatisfaction over the work of the Consumer Council, a debateon consumer research in general had arisen.65 An increasingly common belief was

that there was a need for more knowledge on the consumer, rather than on the

commodities. To speak in terms used in marketing research: not only business but

also consumer politicians and activists had to ask the question ‘why’. Why did

consumers prefer certain commodities? What social and cultural factors influenced

their choices? Commodity testing did not disappear from the agenda, but had to be

supplemented with psychological and sociological investigations on consumer

behaviour and problems. Therefore, social science had to become a tool in the

hands of the consumer, not only the commercial interests. In 1970, Statens institutt

for forbruksforskning og vareunderssøkelser (the National Institute for Consumer

Research and Product Testing) was established. The institute is today called Statens

institutt for forbruksforskning (SIFO) (the National Institute for Consumer

Research) and it conducts both comparative-testing in labs as well as broader forms

of political, economical, social and cultural consumer research.

162 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

At the beginning of the 1970s, the Norwegian Consumer Council was also

reorganised in order to direct more of its activity toward the local level.

Simultaneously, the focus turned from the duties of the rational ‘think before you

act’-consumer in the marketplace to the juridical rights of a citizen consumer. Instead

of the time-consuming task of gathering technical information prior to making a

purchase, the consumer could now strike back through the use of the Act of

Consumer Purchases after a dissatisfactory acquisition. If you are not happy with the

cooker, complain and get your money back. The Consumer Council today points out

that consumers must be aware of their rights in order to be proven correct.

Educational efforts and comparative product testing are still carried out, but the

strong belief in organising an ultimate market through a continuous flow of highly

technical counter-information has been set aside as the authority of the scientific

experts has also been transformed. The Council’s current slogan, ‘Balanced

markets’66 is more a matter of countervailing power through protective legislation

than directly changing consumer practices in the marketplace through scientific

paternalism.

Today, the Norwegian magazine Consumer Report has ceased to exist due to an

ongoing decrease in the number of subscribers. In February 2010 the last paper issue

was published; from now on comparative product test results will be available on the

Council’s home page ‘Forbrukerportalen.no’. At the same time, the abundance of

tests and ‘best buy’ advice is a striking side of consumer information and journalism

on the internet and in other media. Some of these ‘tests’, often equipped with scores

represented by numbers on dices or smiley/grumpy faces, are conduced by consumers

themselves, others are in fact a part of the marketing strategies of commercial

interests. There is no guarantee of an interest-free source of information or that the

tests are being conducted in a scientific way. For ‘rational’ consumers trying to be

enlightened through the internet, the problem is then not a lack of tests but sorting

out impartial, ‘objective’ information on the one hand, and advertising on the other.

Acknowledgements

Many thanks to my former colleagues Tian Sørhaug and Ketil Gjølme Andersen for thediscussions we had in relation to our joint project ‘Knowledge, meaning and economic order’,financed by the Norwegian Research Council.

Notes

1. Even Lange, ed., Organisert kjøpekraft: Forbrukersamvirkets historie i Norge (Oslo: PaxForlag, 2006), part 2; Ellen Furlough and Carl Strikwerda, ‘Economics, ConsumerCulture, and Gender: An Introduction to the Politics of Consumer Cooperation’, inConsumers against Capitalism? Consumer Cooperation in Europe, North America, andJapan 1840�1990, ed. Ellen Furlough and Carl Strikwerda (Landham: Rowman &Littlefield, 1999), 3.

2. Iselin Theien, Shopping for the ‘People’s Home’: Consumer Planning in Norway andSweden after the Second World War, in The Expert Consumer: Associations andProfessionals in Consumer Society, ed. Alain Chatriot et al. (Hampshire: Ashgate, 2006),139.

3. Iselin Theien, Shopping for the ‘People’s Home’, 144�5; Lange, Organisert kjøpekraft,253�62.

Scandinavian Economic History Review 163

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

4. Einar Lie, Ambisjon og tradisjon: Finansdepartementet 1945�1965 (Oslo: Universitetsfor-laget, 1995), 131.

5. Gunnar Yttri, Pris- og rasjonaliseringslova: Ordskiftet i og ikring DNA-regjeringa 1952�1953. Major subject dissertation in history (Oslo: University of Oslo, 1993).

6. Matthew Hilton, Consumerism in 20th-Century Britain: The Search for a HistoricalMovement (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), chapter 7.

7. Ragnar Christiansen (1953�1960) and Ebba Lodden (1960�1977).8. Instilling om forbruksforskning. The Consumer Research Committee, Committee report.

Oslo 1960, 58�59 (The Norwegian National Library Collection).9. Parliamentary records: St.prp. 1/11 1953, Om opprettelsen av Forbrukerradet. Printed in

Stortingsforhandlinger 1953, part 1b (Oslo: The Parliament, 1953), 31�6; Jannike WehnHegnes, Forbruksforskning som forbrukerpolitikk 1939�1984 (Oslo: SIFO, 2006), 55.

10. Parliamentary records: St.prp. 1/11 1953, 1.11. Parliamentary records: St.prp. 1/11 1953, 37.12. Theien, Shopping for the ‘People’s Home’, 142.13. Parliamentary records: St.prp. 1/11 1953, 37.14. Christine Myrvang, Sosialistiske produksjonsidealer � ‘dagen derpaa’. Storskala og

teknokrati i norsk sosialiseringsdebatt og -teori 1917�1924. TMV report no. 18 (Oslo:TMV/Pensumtjeneste, 1996).

15. Haavard Langseth, Omkring Socialiseringen (Kristiania: Det norske arbeiderpartis forlag,1921), 21.

16. Myrvang, Sosialistiske produksjonsidealer, 123, 133�7.17. Myrvang, Sosialistiske produksjonsidealer, 121.18. Ole Colbjørnsen and Axel Sømme, En norsk 3-arsplan: Veien frem til en socialistisk

planøkonomi i Norge (Oslo: Det norske arbeiderpartis forlag, 1933), 122�7.19. Kjetil Jakobsen, ‘Efter oss kommer overfloden’: Teknokratisk moderniseringsideologi i norsk

politikk og samfunnsvitenskap 1917�1953 (Dissertation, University of Oslo, 1994), 21�6,36�40.

20. Colbjørnsen and Sømme, En norsk 3-arsplan, 36 and 122.21. Francis Sejersted, Sosialdemokratiets tidsalder: Norge og Sverige i det 20. arhundre (Oslo:

Pax Forlag, 2005), 337.22. 10 ar for forbrukerne: Forbrukerradet 1953�1963 (Oslo: Forbrukerradet, 1963), 26.23. Myrvang, Sosialistiske produksjonsidealer, 133�9.24. Boel Berner, Sakernas tillstand: Kon, klass, teknisk expertis (Stockholm: Carlsson, 1996),

246.25. Carolyn M. Goldstein, ‘Part of the Package: Home Economists in the Consumer Products

Industries, 1920�1940’, in Rethinking Home Economics: Women and the History of aProfession, ed. Sarah Stage and Virginia B. Vincenti (Ithaca and London: CornellUniversity Press, 1997).

26. Goldstein, ‘Part of the Package’, 276.27. Emma Seifrit Weigley, ‘It Might Have Been Euthenics: The Lake Placid Conferences and

the Home Economics Movement’, in American Quarterly, vol. 26, 1974:1, 80�83.28. Myrvang, Christine, Forbruksagentene: Slik vekket de kjøpelysten (Oslo: Pax Forlag,

2009), chapter 7.29. Hegnes, Forbruksforskning som forbrukerpolitikk, 35�7.30. Lizabeth Cohen Cohen, ‘Citizens and Consumers in the United States in the Century of

Mass Consumption’, in The Politics of Consumption: Material Culture and Citizenship inEurope and America, ed. Martin Daunton and Matthew Hilton (Oxford and New York:Berg, 2001), 204�5; Inger L. Stole, Advertising on Trial: Consumer Activism and CorporatePublic Relations in the 1930s (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2006), 22�3.

31. The so-called third wave consumer movement developed in America in the 1960s and1970s, and was, to a large extent, focused on the protection and legal rights of consumers.

32. Hegnes, Forbruksforskning som forbrukerpolitikk, 32�40.33. Robert B. Westbrook, ‘Tribune of the Technostructure: The Popular Economics of Stuart

Chase’, in American Quarterly 32 (1980): 4, 388; Charles McGovern, Sold American:Consumption and Citizenship, 1890�1945 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press,2006), chapter 4.

164 C. Myrvang

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4

34. Stuart Chase, The Tragedy of Waste (New York: Workers Education Bureau of America,1926 [1925]), 30�1; Westbrook, ‘Tribune of the Technostructure’, 396�7.

35. Kathleen G. Donohue, Freedom from Want: American Liberalism and the Idea of theConsumer (Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2003), 175.

36. Stuart Chase and F. J. Schlink, Your Money’s Worth: A Study in the Waste of theConsumer’s Dollar (New York: Macmillan, 1927), 2.

37. Chase and Schlink, Your Money’s Worth, 4.38. Chase and Schlink, Your Money’s Worth, 258.39. Donohue, Freedom from Want, 176�8.40. Norman Isaac Silber, Test and Protest: The Influence of Consumers Union (New York:

Holmes & Meier, 1983), 17�18.41. Hayagreeva Rao, ‘Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Consumer Watch-

dog Organizations’, in The American Journal of Sociology 103, no. 4 (1998): 930.42. Silber, Test and Protest, 20�7. Rao, Caveat Emptor, 935�7; Brita Akerman, Makt at

konsumenten (Stockholm: Raben & Sjogren, 1968), 96.43. 10 ar for forbrukerne, 17�19; Aftenposten 30 October 1954; Hegnes, Forbruksforskning som

forbrukerpolitikk, 63�4.44. Hegnes, Forbruksforskning som forbrukerpolitikk, 85.45. Hans Georg Lindbom, Forbruksvareforskning og �opplysning I U.S.A.: Rapport fra en

studiereise februar � mars 1957 (Oslo, 1957).46. The Norwegian expression ‘Tenk før du handler’ actually has two meanings: ‘Think

before you act’ and ‘Think before you shop’.47. Forbruker-rapporten no. 1 (1958), 3.48. Ferdinand C. Wheeler, ed., The Technique of Marketing Research (New York: McGraw-

Hill, 1937), vii.49. Svend A. Eggen, Norsk gallup institutt gjennom femti ar: Menigmanns meninger og maktens

redskap (Oslo: Norsk Gallup, 1996), 48.50. Eggen, Norsk gallup institutt, 46.51. Sissel Myklebust, ‘Farlig kunnskap? Manipulasjon, kommunikasjon og livsstil’, in

Temmet eller uhemmet: Historiske perspektiver pa konsum, kultur og dannelse, ed. ChristineMyrvang, Sissel Myklebust and Brita Brenna (Oslo: Pax Forlag, 2004); Myrvang,‘Forbruksagentene’, chapter 4.

52. Forbruker-rapporten no. 6 (1967).53. Boel Berner, ‘Housewives’ films and the modern housewife. Experts, users and household

modernization: Sweden in the 1950s and 1960s’, in History and Technology no. 3 (2002),158�61.

54. Alle kvinner no. 10 (1963), 68.55. Alle kvinner no. 36 (1963), 62.56. Alle kvinner no. 38 (1963), 55.57. Alle kvinners blad no. 47 (1958), 80.58. Forbruker-rapporten no. 6 (1963), 13.59. Forbruker-rapporten no. 6 (1963), 9�15.60. Rune Slagstad, De nasjonale strateger (Oslo: Pax Forlag, 1998), 277.61. Forbruker-rapporten no. 1 (1958), 3.62. Hilton, Consumerism in 20th-Century Britain, 242.63. Akerman, Makt at konsumenten, 107�8.64. Innstilling om forbrukerradets arbeidsoppgaver, sammensetning og organisasjon m.v. (Oslo:

Dep. for familie- og forbrukersaker. (St.meld. nr. 65 (1971�72)), 1971), 31�2, 44.65. See Berit As, Forbrukeren i det moderne samfunn. En orientering om psykologisk og

sosiologisk forbrukerforskning (Oslo: Universitetsforlaget, 1966).66. Balanced Markets. The Consumer Council of Norway’s strategic plan for 2002 through

2005, http://forbrukerportalen.no/engelsk_fransk/1023793458.07 (accessed 11 May 2010).

Scandinavian Economic History Review 165

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

wer

syte

t War

szaw

ski]

at 0

6:05

17

Oct

ober

201

4