45
Option Pricing using Integral Transforms Peter Carr NYU Courant Institute joint work with H. G´ eman, D. Madan, L. Wu, and M. Yor

Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    10

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Option Pricing using Integral Transforms

Peter Carr

NYU Courant Institute

joint work with H. Geman, D. Madan, L. Wu, and M. Yor

Page 2: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Introduction

Callvalues

are oftenobtained by integ-

rating their payoff againsta risk-neutral probability density

function. When the characteristic functionof the underlying asset is known in closed form,

call values can also be obtained by a single integration.

2

Page 3: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

A Brief History of Sines

• The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in1747.

• D’Alembert proposed using a superposition of sine functionsto describe the oscillations of a violin string.

• The recipe for computing the coefficients, later associated withFourier’s name, was actually formulated by Euler in 1777.

• Fourier proposed using the same idea for the heat equation in1807.

• Since the introduction of periodic functions, mathematics hasnever been the same...

3

Page 4: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Fourier Frequency in Finance

• McKean (IMR 65) used Fourier transforms in his appendix toSamuelson’s paper.

• Buser (JF 86) noticed that Laplace transforms with real argu-ments give present value rules.

• Shimko (92) championed the use of Laplace transforms in hisbook.

• Beaglehole (WP 92) used Fourier series to value double barrieroptions.

• Stein & Stein (RFS 91) and Heston (RFS 93) started the ballrolling with their use of Fourier transforms to analytically valueEuropean options on stocks with stochastic volatility.

• While not necessary, Fourier methods simplify the developmentof option pricing models which reflect empirical realities suchas jumps (Ait-Sahalia JF 02), volatility clustering (Engle 81),and the leverage effect (Black 76).

• A bibliography at the end of this presentation lists 76 papersapplying integral transforms to option pricing.

4

Page 5: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

My Fast Fourier Talk (FFT)

• To survey integral transforms for option pricing in one hour,I restrict the presentation to the use of Fourier transforms tovalue European options on a single stock.

• Here’s an overview of my FFT:

1. What is a Fourier Transform (FT)?

2. What is a Characteristic Function (CF)?

3. Relating FT’s of Option Prices to CF’s

4. Pricing Options on Levy Processes

5. Pricing Options on Levy Processes w. Stochastic Volatility

5

Page 6: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Fourier Transformation and Inversion

• Let f(x) be a suitably integrable function

• Letting δ(·) be Dirac’s delta function:

f(x) =

∫ ∞

−∞f(y)δ(y − x)dy.

• The next page shows that δ(y − x) = 12π

∫ ∞−∞ eiu(y−x)du.

• Substituting in this fundamental result implies:

f(x) =

∫ ∞

−∞f(y)

1

∫ ∞

−∞eiu(y−x)dudy

=1

∫ ∞

−∞e−iux

∫ ∞

−∞f(y)eiuydydu.

• Define the Fourier transform (FT) of f(·) as:

Ff(u) ≡∫ ∞

−∞eiuyf(y)dy.

• Thus given the FT of f , the function f can be recovered by:

f(x) =1

∫ ∞

−∞e−iuxFf(u)du.

• It is sometimes necessary to make u complex. When Im(u) ≡ui 6= 0, the FT is referred to as a generalized Fourier transform.

f(x) =1

∫ iui+∞

iui−∞e−iuxFf(u)du.

6

Page 7: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

No Potato, One Potato, Two Potato, Three...

• Note that:

1. the average of 1 and 1 is 1

2. the average of 1 and eiπ = −1 is 0.

1. The average of 1 and 1 and 1 is 1

2. The average of 1 and e2π3 i and e

4π3 i is 0.

3. The average of 1 and e4π3 i and e

8π3 i is 0.

1. The average of 1 and 1 and 1 and 1 is 1

2. The average of 1 and eπ2 i and eπi and e

3π2 i is 0.

3. The average of 1 and eπi and e2πi and e3πi is 0.

4. The average of 1 and e3π2 i and e3πi and e

9π2 i is 0.

• As financial engineers, we conclude that for all d = 2, 3, 4 . . .:

1

d

d−1∑

k=0

e2πid jk = 1j=0,

for j = 0, 1, . . . , d − 1.

7

Page 8: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Yes, but...

• Recall our engineering style proof that for d = 2, 3, . . . ,:

1

d

d−1∑

k=0

e2πid jk = 1j=0, j = 0, 1, . . . , d − 1.

• A mathematician would note that if we define r = e2πid j, then

the LHS is 1d

d−1∑k=0

rk. If j = 0, then r = 1 and the LHS is clearly

1, while if j 6= 0, then the sum is a geometric series:

1

d

d−1∑

k=0

rk =1

d

rd − 1

r − 1= 0, since rd = e2πij = 1.

• Multiplying the top equation by d implies d1j=0 =d−1∑k=0

e2πid jk.

• Putting our engineering cap back on on, letting d ↑ ∞ andj = y − x:

δ(y − x) =

∫ ∞

−∞ei2πω(y−x)dω.

• Letting u = 2πω:

δ(y − x) =1

∫ ∞

−∞eiu(y−x)du.

• Fortunately, this can all be made precise.

8

Page 9: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Basic Properties of Fourier Transforms

• Recall that the (generalized) FT of f(x) is defined as:

Ff(u) ≡∫ ∞

−∞eiuxf(x)dx,

where f(x) is suitably integrable.

• Three basic properties of FT’s are:

1. Parseval Relation:Define the inner product of 2 complex-valued L2 functionsf(·) and g(·) as 〈f, g〉 ≡

∫ ∞−∞ f(x)g(x)dx. Then:

〈f, g〉 = 〈Ff(u),Fg(u)〉.

2. Differentiation:

Ff ′(u) = −iuFf(u)

3. Modulation:

Fe`xf(u) = Ff(u − i`)

9

Page 10: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

What is a Characteristic Function?

• A characteristic function (CF) is the FT of a PDF.

• If X has PDF q, then:

Fq(u) ≡∫ ∞

−∞eiuxq(x)dx = EeiuX.

• For u real and fixed, the CF is the expected value of the loca-tion of a random point on the unit circle. Hence the norm ofthe CF is never bigger than one:

|Fq(u)| ≤ 1.

• The bigger the absolute value of the real frequency u, the wideris the distribution of uX . Hence, if the PDF of uX is wrappedaround the unit circle, larger |u| leads to more uniform distri-bution of probability mass on the circle, and hence smallernorms of the CF.

• Symmetric PDF’s centered about zero have real CF’s.

• When the argument u is complex with non-zero imaginarypart, the PDF is wrapped around a spiral rather than a circle.The larger is Im(u), the faster we spiral into the origin.

10

Page 11: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

From Fourier to Finance

• Suppose we interpret the function f as the final payoff to aderivative security maturing at T .

• Recall that f(FT ) =∫ ∞−∞ f(K)δ(FT − K)dK.

• This is a spectral decomposition of the payoff f into the payoffsδ(·) from an infinite collection of Arrow Debreu securities.

• From Breeden & Litzenberger, ∂2

∂K2(FT − K)+ = δ(FT − K).

• Hence, static positions in calls can create any path-indep. pay-off including er1x sin(r2x) & er1x cos(r2x), r1, r2 real. The pay-offs from these sine and cosine claims are created model-free.

• As we saw, δ(FT − K) = 12π

∫ ∞−∞ eiu(FT−K)du.

• When u is complex and u = ur + iui:

eiux = eurx cos(uix) + ieurx sin(uix).

• Hence, the payoff from each A/D security can in turn be repli-cated by a static position in sine claims and cosine claims.

• Just as the payoffs from A/D securities may be a more conve-nient basis to work with than option payoffs, the payoffs fromsine and cosine claims may be an even more convenient basis.

• The use of complex numbers is even more convenient. After all,it is a lot easier to evaluate i2 than sin(u1 +u2) or cos(u1 +u2).

11

Page 12: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Parsevaluation

• Let g(k) be the Green’s function (a.k.a the pricing kernel, but-terfly spread price, and discounted risk-neutral PDF).

• Letting V0 be the initial value of a claim paying f(XT ) at T ,risk-neutral valuation implies:

V0 =

∫ ∞

−∞f(k)g(k)dk = 〈f, g〉,

where for any functions φ1(x) and φ2(x), the inner product is:

〈φ1, φ2〉 ≡∫ ∞

−∞φ1(x)φ2(x)dx.

• By the Fourier Inversion Theorem f(k) = 12π

∫ ∞−∞ e−iukFf(u)du:

V0 =

∫ ∞

−∞

1

∫ ∞

−∞e−iukFf(u)dug(k)dk

=1

∫ ∞

−∞Ff(u)

∫ ∞

−∞g(k)e−iukdkdu

=1

∫ ∞

−∞Ff(u)Fg(u)du.

• Hence V0 = 〈f, g〉 = 12π〈Ff ,Fg〉 by a change of basis.

• Note that Fg(u) = B0(T )Fq(−u), i.e. discount factor × CF.

• By restricting the payoff, more efficient Fourier methods canbe developed.

12

Page 13: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Breeden Litzenberger in Logs

• Let C(K, T ) relate call value to strike K and maturity T

• The Green’s f’n G(K, T ) is B0(T )Q{FT ∈ d(K, K + dK)}.• From Breeden & Litzenberger (JB 78), G(K,T ) = ∂2

∂K2C(K, T ).

• Let k ≡ ln(K/F0) measure moneyness of the T maturity call.

• Let γ(k, T ) ≡ C(K, T ) relate call value to k and T .

• Let Xt ≡ ln(Ft/F0) be the log price relative.

• Let g(k, T ) ≡ G(K, T ) be the Green’s function of XT .

• How are g and γ related?

• By no arbitrage, the call value is related to g by:

γ(k, T ) = F0

∫ ∞

k

(ey − ek)g(y, T )dy.

• To invert this relationship, differentiate w.r.t. k:∂

∂kγ(k, T ) = −F0

∫ ∞

k

ekg(y, T )dy.

Hence:e−k

F0

∂kγ(k, T ) = −

∫ ∞

k

g(y, T )dy.

• Differentiating w.r.t. k again gives the desired result:

g(k, T ) =∂

∂k

e−k

F0

∂kγ(k, T ).

13

Page 14: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Relationship Between Fourier Transforms

• Recall that Green’s function g of XT = ln(FT/F0) is relatedto the call price as a function γ of moneyness k ≡ ln(K/F0):

g(k, T ) =∂

∂k

e−k

F0

∂kγ(k, T ).

• Multiply both sides by eiθk where θ ∈ C and integrate out k:

F [g](θ, T ) ≡∞∫

−∞

eiθkg(k, T )dk = F[

∂k

e−k

F0

∂kγ

](θ, T ).

• The differentiation and modulation rules for FT’s imply:

F [q](θ, T ) = (−iθ)F[e−k

F0

∂kγ

](θ, T )

=(−iθ)

F0F

[∂

∂kγ

](θ + i, T )

=−θ(θ + i)

F0F [γ](θ + i, T ).

• Letting u = θ + i, solving for F [γ](θ + i, T ):

F [γ](u, T ) =F0F [g](u − i, T )

(i − u)u.

• Carr Madan (JCF 98) compute this (generalized) FT via FFT.

14

Page 15: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

More on the FFT Method

• Since γ(k) is not integrable, its generalized FT is only definedon a subset of the complex plane that excludes the real line.

• If we invert an FT for call value at n strikes, the work is O(n2)since each inversion is a numerical integration.

• Using the FFT to invert the FT of the call value reduces thework to O(n ln n), a considerable improvement.

• The formula is only for European options. However, Lee (03)extends it to a bigger class of path-independent payoffs andDempster & Hong (WP 02) extend it to spread options.

• Lee (03) develops error bounds for the FFT method.

• Inversion returns option prices as a function of (log) strike,which is useful for calibrating to market option prices.

• Alternatively, one can calibrate directly in Fourier space relyingon Parseval to ensure that errors do not magnify on inversion.

• If call values are homogeneous in spot and strike, one also getsoption prices in terms of spot (hedging/risk management).

• When the CF is available in closed form, both Parsevaluationand the FFT method give closed form expressions for the gen-eralized FT of a claim value. But where do we get closed formexpressions for CF’s?

15

Page 16: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Options on Levy Processes

• Fortunately, an important class of stochastic processes calledLevy processes are specified directly in terms of the CF of arandom variable.

• Levy processes are right continuous left limits processes withstationary independent increments.

• Important examples include arithmetic brownian motion (ABM)and compound Poisson processes.

• The only continuous Levy process is ABM:

dAt = bdt + σdWt, t ≥ 0.

• Note that the Black Scholes model assumes that the log priceis ABM. Thus, if we are going to go beyond Black Scholes andwe want to price options on assets whose log price is a Levyprocess, then we are going to have to make our peace withpricing options in the presence of jumps.

• Work on this issue is also motivated by Hakansson’s catch 22and Sandy Grossman’s crack on ketchup economics.

16

Page 17: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Complete Markets

• The Black Scholes model prices all stock price contingent claimsuniquely by no arbitrage using just a bond and the underlyingstock in the replicating portfolio.

• The basic intuition comes from seeing Black Scholes as a con-tinuous time limit of the binomial model, where at each discretetime the increment in the stock price is Bernoulli distributed.

• Some SV models and jump models have all of the above fea-tures of Black Scholes, eg. CEV model or Cox Ross (JFE 76)fixed jump model (also see Rogers & Hobson (MF 98) andDritschel & Protter (MF 99)).

• However, these models are still limits of discrete time modelsin which the local movement in the stock price process is stillconditionally binary.

17

Page 18: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Pricing Options on Assets which Jump

• Rejecting the conditionally binary assumption on empiricalgrounds, we can still price claims by using some subset of:

1. Restricting the target claim space

2. Restricting the underlying price process

3. Increasing the basis asset space

4. Assuming more than no arbitrage

5. Giving up on unique pricing.

• For example, suppose the target claim space is restricted toarbitrary European options & the underlying price process isrestricted to an arbitrary Levy process. Suppose dynamic trad-ing is restricted to stock & bond, but static positions are al-lowed in N < ∞ options with different strikes &/or maturities.

• Then we can still uniquely price options by assuming more thanno arbitrage. For example, we can assume that asset marketsare in equilibrium and hence is using this criterion to selectone arbitrage-free pricing rule from the many that reprice theoptions and their underlying stock.

• To learn this pricing rule, we may specify ex ante a family ofLevy processes with M < N parameters. Then the parametersare determined from market option prices by say a least squaresfit. But how do we specify a Levy process?

18

Page 19: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Levy Khintchine Theorem

• Once one specifies the distribution of an infinitely divisiblerandom variable at time 1, the corresponding Levy process is

determined by Xtd= tX1.

• The Levy Khintchine theorem characterizes all infinitely divis-ible random variables in terms of their CF.

• For simplicity, I will only present the theorem for Levy processesstarted at 0 and whose jump component has sample paths offinite variation.

• By the Levy Khintchine theorem, all such processes have a CF:

EeiuXt = et

[ibu−σ2u2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)

]

, t ≥ 0.

• The Levy process is specified by the drift rate b, the diffusioncoefficient σ, and the so-called Levy measure `(dx).

• Loosely speaking, the Levy measure `(dx) specifies the arrivalrate of jumps of size (x, x+dx). Hence, it must be nonnegativeand no measure is assigned to the origin. So that the processhas well-defined quadratic variation, the Levy measure mustalso integrate x2 around the origin i.e.∫

<−{0}

x21(|x| < 1)`(dx) < ∞.

19

Page 20: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Applying Levy Khintchine

• Recall the Levy Khintchine theorem:

EeiuXt = et

[ibu−σ2u2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)

]

.

• If the Levy process is ABM (dAt = bdt + σdWt, t ≥ 0), then:

EeiuAt = et[ibu−σ2u2

2

].

• For Black Scholes with constant interest rate r and dividendyield q, the drift of the log stock price relative is b = r−q− σ2

2and we are done.

• Merton’s jump diffusion model assumes that the log price rel-ative is the sum of an ABM and an independent compoundPoisson process. The conditional distribution of the jump sizeis normal with mean α and standard deviation σj. The Levy

measure is `(dx) = λe−1

2

(x−ασj

)2

√2πσj

dx. Hence, the CF is:

EeiuXt = e

t

ibu−σ2u2

2 + λ√2πσj

∫<−{0}

(eiux−1)e−1

2

(x−ασj

)2

dx

.

• The last integral can be done in closed form. Once one relatesthe risk-neutral drift b to the parameters r, q, σ, λ, α, and σj,European option pricing is straightforward.

20

Page 21: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

An Interpretation of Levy Khintchine

• All Levy processes arise as limits of compound Poisson processes.

• To see why, recall the Levy Khintchine theorem:

EeiuXt = et

[ibu−σ2u2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)

]

. (1)

• A Poisson process jumping by k with arrival rate λ has CF:

EeiukNt(λ) =∞∑

n=0

eiukne−λt(λt)n

n!= et(eiuk−1)λ. (2)

• (1) and (2) are the same if b = σ = 0 and the Levy measureis:

`(dx) = λδ(x − k)dx.

• The term ibu in (1) is arising from cumulative drift bt. Now:

limk↓0

eiuk − 1

k= iu.

• Hence, this term can come from (2) by letting λ = bk and

letting k ↓ 0.

21

Page 22: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Diffusions as Jumps

• Recall the Levy Khintchine theorem:

EeiuXt = et

[ibu−σ2u2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)

]

. (3)

and the CF for a Poisson process jumping by k with arrivalrate λ:

EeiukNt(λ) = et(eiuk−1)λ. (4)

• The difference of 2 IID Poissons jumping by k has CF:

Eeiuk[N1t(λ)−N2t(λ)] = et[(eiuk−1)+(e−iuk−1)]λ. (5)

• The term σ2u2

2in (3) is arising from the CF of σWt, where W

is SBM. Now:

limk↓0

(eiuk − 1) + (e−iuk − 1)

k2= −u2.

• Hence, this term can come from (4) by letting λ = σ2

2k2 andletting k ↓ 0.

• Where does the term∫

<−{0}

(eiux − 1

)`(dx) in (3) come from?

22

Page 23: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Poisson Processes as Building Blocks

• Recall the Levy Khintchine theorem:

EeiuXt = et

[ibu−σ2u2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)

]

. (6)

• Suppose that a Poisson process Pt jumps by the fixed size xand has an infinitessimally small arrival rate `(dx):

Pt = xNt(`(dx)).

• Its CF is:EeiuPt = et(eiux−1)`(dx). (7)

• Now consider a continuum of such processes where each processis independent of every other.

• The integral in (6) can be thought of as arising from a calcu-lation of the CF of a superposition of these processes:

It ≡∫

<−{0}

xNt(`(dx)).

The rareness of jumps ensures that at every time, there areeither no jumps or only one.

• Since drift and diffusion also come from limiting linear com-binations of standard Poisson processes, we see that theseprocesses are the building blocks of Levy processes.

23

Page 24: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

You Say Tomato

• Many Levy processes can go negative while futures prices oflimited liability assets must be nonnegative.

• Suppose we assume that the log of the futures price relative isa Levy process started at zero:

Xt = ln(Ft/F0).

• No arbitrage implies that the futures price Ft = F0eXt is a

positive martingale under a risk-neutral measure Q.

• Since the exponential function is convex, Jensen’s inequalityforces the process X to have negative drift.

• For example in the Black model, the log futures price relativeis ABM and the drift of the log futures price relative is −σ2/2.

• This negative drift is often termed a convexity correction, butit should be called a concavity correction if the log is concave.

24

Page 25: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Convexity Correction

• To determine the convexity correction when the log futuresprice relative is a Levy process, let Lt be a Levy process withzero drift whose jump component has sample paths of finitevariation. We term L the driver of the futures price process.

• By the Levy Khintchine theorem, we have:

EeiuLt = et[−u2σ2

2 +∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx)]

= e−tΨ(u),

where Ψ(u) ≡ − ln EeiuL1 = u2σ2/2−∫

<−{0}(eiux − 1)`(dx) is

called the characteristic exponent of the driver.

• Assuming that expectations are finite, evaluating the top equa-tion at u = −i:

EeLt = e−tΨ(−i) and hence EetΨ(−i)+Lt = 1.

Let:

b ≡ Ψ(−i) = −σ2/2 −∫

<−{0}

(ex − 1)`(dx).

• Then Xt ≡ bt + Lt is a Levy process with the property thateXt is a positive martingale started at 1.

• Hence, St ≡ S0e(r−q)t+Xt has the desired risk-neutral dynam-

ics, since:ESt = S0e

(r−q)t, t ≥ 0.

25

Page 26: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

The thigh bone’s connected to the..

• Recall from way back when that γ(k) is a function relating thecall price to the moneyness k ≡ ln(K/F0).

• Carr Madan relate the FT of γ to the CF of XT ≡ ln(

FTF0

):

Fγ(u, T ) =F0B0(T )Fq(u − i, T )

(i − u)u,

where q(k, T ) ≡ Q {XT ∈ (k, k + dk)} is the risk-neutral PDFof XT and B0(T ) is the price of a bond paying $1 at T .

• The CF of Xt = ln(

FtF0

)is det’d by the char. exponent Ψ(u):

F [q](u, T ) = EeiuXT = eiubT−TΨ(u), where b = Ψ(−i).

• The characteristic exponent is det’d by the Levy measure `(dx):

Ψ(u) = u2σ2/2 −∫

<−{0}

(eiux − 1)`(dx).

• If `(dx) is chosen so that∫

<−{0}(eiux−1)`(dx) can be evaluated

in closed form, then the CF and FT of γ are also closed form.

• The table on the next page gives several popular Levy measuresand closed form expressions for the corresponding characteris-tic exponents.

26

Page 27: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Levy Measures & Characteristic Exponents

Table 1:

Driver’s Levy Measure Characteristic ExponentName `(dx)/dx Ψ(u) ≡ − ln EeiuL1

Purely Continuous Levy Driver

ABM µt + σWt 0 −iµu + 12σ2u2

Finite Activity Pure Jump Levy components

Merton Jump Part λ 1√2πσ2

j

exp(− (x−α)2

2σ2j

(1 − eiuα− 1

2σ2

j u2)

Kou’s Double Exp’l λ 12η

exp(− |x−k|

η

(1 − eiuk 1−η2

1+u2η2

)

Eraker (2001) λ 1η

exp(−x

η

(1 − 1

1−iuη

)

Infinite Activity Pure Jump Levy Driver

Normal Inv. Gauss eβx δαπ|x|K1(α|x|) −δ

[√α2 − β2 −

√α2 − (β + iu)2

]

Hyperbolic eβx

|x|

[∫ ∞0

e−√

2y+α2|x|

π2y(J2|λ|(δ

√2y)+Y 2

|λ|(δ√

2y))dy − ln

[ √α2−β2√

α2−(β+iu)2

]λ [Kλ

(δ√

α2−(β+iu)2)

(δ√

α2−β2)

]

+1λ≥0λe−α|x|)

CGMY

{Ce−G|x||x|−Y −1, x < 0,Ce−M |x||x|−Y −1, x > 0

CΓ(−Y )[MY − (M − iu)Y + G − (G + iu)Y

]

Variance Gammaµ2±

exp(−µ±

v±|x|)

|x| λ ln(1 − iuα + 1

2σ2

j u2)

(µ± =

√α2

4λ2 +σ2

j

2± α

2λ, v± = µ2

±/λ)

FiniteMomLogStbl c|x|−α−1, x < 0 −cΓ(−α) (iu)α

27

Page 28: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Stochastic Volatility and Timex

• By definition, Levy processes have stationary independent in-crements.

• As a consequence, squared returns are independent i.e. volatil-ity does not cluster.

• However, there is much empirical evidence to the contrary.

• Fortunately, one can capture volatility clustering by time-changing a Levy process. If a Levy process is run on a stochas-tic clock whose increments are correlated, then the incrementsin the Levy process inherit this correlation.

• Mathematically, a stochastic clock (technically a subordinator)is a right continuous increasing stochastic process started at 0.

• Intuitively, think of it as a $5 Rolex.

• If the Levy process is standard Brownian motion and the sto-chastic clock is τ (t) ≡

∫ t

0 σ2t dt, then:

dBτ(t)d= σtdBt,

by the Brownian scaling property. If σt is a random continuousprocess, then the increments of Bτ(t) become correlated.

28

Page 29: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

FT of Time Changed Levy Process

• Let X be a Levy process started at 0 and whose jump compo-nent has sample paths of finite variation. Then its CF is:

FXt(u) ≡ EeiuXt = e−tΨx(u), t ≥ 0,

where Ψx(u) ≡ −ibu + σ2u2

2 −∫

<−{0}

(eiux − 1

)`(dx) is the

characteristic exponent of Xt.

• Let τ be a subordinator which is independent of X and letYt ≡ Xτt, t ≥ 0. Then the CF of Y involves expectations over2 sources of randomness:

FYt(u) ≡ EeiuYt = EeiuXτt = E[E

[eiuXτt|τt = u

]].

• If τt is independent of X , then the randomness due to the Levyprocess can be integrated out using the top equation:

FYt(u) = Ee−τtΨx(u) ≡ Lτt(Ψx(u)),

where Lτt(λ) ≡ Ee−λτt is the Laplace Transform (LT) of τt,λ ∈ C, Re(λ) ≥ 0.

• Thus, the CF of Yt is just the LT of τt evaluated at the char-acteristic exponent of X .

• Clearly, if the LT of τt and the characteristic exponent of Xare both available in closed form, then so is the CF of Yt.

29

Page 30: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Laplace Transforms and Bond Prices

• Consider specifying the clock in terms of an activity rate vt:

τt =

∫ t

0

vs−ds, vs ≥ 0.

• Then the Laplace transform of the clock has form:

Lτt(λ) ≡ E[e−λτt

]= E

[e−λ

∫ t0 vs−ds

].

• This formulation arises in the bond pricing literature if weregard λvt as the instantaneous interest rate.

• If the Levy process being time changed is Brownian motion,then v is the variance rate.

• The instantaneous interest rate and the instantaneous activityrate are both required to be non-negative and are commonlythought to be mean reverting.

• Thus, one can adopt the vast literature on bond pricing toobtain Laplace transforms in closed form.

• In particular, one can apply 2 tractable bond pricing classes,namely affine and quadratic interest rate models.

• These classes are summarized in the table on the next page.

• See CGMY (MF 03) and Carr & Wu (JFE 03) for variouspairings of Levy processes and stochastic clocks.

30

Page 31: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Activity Rate Processes & LT of Clock

Under each class of activity rate processes, the entries summarize the specification of the activity rate andthe corresponding Laplace transform of the random time.

Activity Rate Specification Laplace Transformvt LTt(λ) ≡ E

[e−λTt

]

Affine: Duffie, Pan, Singleton (2000)

vt = b>v Zt + cv,

µ(Zt) = a − κZt,[σ(Zt)σ(Zt)

>]ii

= αi + β>i Zt,[

σ(Zt)σ(Zt)>]

ij= 0, i 6= j,

γ(Zt) = aγ + b>γ Zt.

exp(−b(t)>z0 − c(t)

),

b′(t) = λbv − κ>b(t) − 12βb(t)2

−bγ ( Lq(b(t)) − 1) ,c′(t) = λcv + b(t)>a − 1

2b(t)>αb(t)

−aγ ( Lq(b(t)) − 1) ,b(0) = 0, c(0) = 0.

Generalized Affine: Filipovic (2001)

Af(x) = 12σ2xf ′′(x) + (a′ − κx)f ′(x)

+∫R+

0(f(x + y) − f(x) + f ′(x) (1 ∧ y))

(m(dy) + xµ(dy)) ,a′ = a +

∫R+

0(1 ∧ y) m(dy),∫

R+0

[(1 ∧ y)m(dy) + (1 ∧ y2) µ(dy)] < ∞.

exp (−b(t)v0 − c(t)) ,b′(t) = λ − κb(t) − 1

2σ2b(t)2

+∫R+

0

(1 − e−yb(t) − b(t)(1 ∧ y)

)µ(dy),

c′(t) = ab(t) +∫R+

0

(1 − e−yb(t)

)m(dy),

b(0) = c(0) = 0.

Quadratic: Leippold and Wu (2002)

µ(Z) = −κZ, σ(Z) = I,vt = Z>

t AvZt + b>v Zt + cv.

exp[−z>0 A (t) z0 − b (t)> z0 − c (t)

],

A′(t) = λAv − A (t) κ − κ>A (τ) − 2A (t)2 ,

b′(t) = λbv − κb(t) − 2A (t)> b (t) ,c′(t) = λcv + trA (t) − b(t)>b(t)/2,A(0) = 0,b(0) = 0, c(0) = 0.

31

Page 32: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Correlation and the Leverage Effect

• To capture the well documented volatility clustering phenom-enon, we time-changed a Levy process using an independentsubordinator.

• It is also well documented that percentage changes in the un-derlying’s price and volatility are correlated, typically nega-tively.

• Whether or not this correlation is due to leverage, it is com-monly referred to as the leverage effect.

• Carr and Wu (JFE 03) show how to calculate the CF of a Levyprocess time-changed by a correlated subordinator.

• Monroe (1978) showed that any semi-martingale can be char-acterized as Brownian motion time-changed by a possibly cor-related subordinator.

• Hence, the entire class of processes used in derivatives pricingcan now be captured by Fourier methods.

32

Page 33: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Motivating Complex Measure

• Recall that if the Levy process X and the clock τt are inde-pendent, then the CF of Yt ≡ Xτt is given by:

φYt(u) = Lτt(Ψx(u)) = EQ[e−Ψx(u)τt

],

where Ψx(u) is the characteristic exponent of X .

• Suppose for simplicity that the PDF of X is symmetric (eg.SBM). Then the PDF of Y is also symmetric and the charac-teristic functions and exponents of both X and Y are real.

• One can introduce skewness into the distribution of Y by in-troducing correlation between increments in τ and X . Then,the CF of Y takes on a non-zero imaginary part.

• Suppose we still want to relate CF’s to LT’s and to character-istic exponents, as in the top equation.

• As the characteristic exponent of X and the clock τt are bothreal, the only way to accomplish this is to allow the probabilitymeasure Q used in the expectation to become complex.

33

Page 34: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Changing to Complex Measure

• Let Q be the usual risk-neutral measure under which a Levyprocess X has characteristic exponent Ψx(u).

• Let τt be a stochastic clock and let Mt(u) ≡ eiuXτt+τtΨx(u).

• Carr and Wu use the Optional stopping theorem to showthat Mt(u) is a well-defined complex-valued Q-martingale andhence can be used to change the real valued probability mea-sure Q into a complex valued measure Q(u):

EQ[eiuYt

]= EQ

[eiuYt+τtΨx(u)−τtΨx(u)

]= EQ

[Mt(u)e−τtΨx(u)

]

= EQ(u)[e−τtΨx(u)

]≡ Lu

τt(Ψx(u)) .

• Thus, the generalized CF of the time-changed Levy processYt ≡ XTt under measure Q is just the (modified) Laplacetransform of τ under the complex-valued measure Q(u), eval-uated at the characteristic exponent Ψx(u) of Xt.

• Just as Cox-Ross (JFE 76) show that correct valuation arises ifa risk-neutral investor uses Q in place of statistical measure, weshow that correct valuation arises if an investor who believesin independence uses Q(u) in place of Q. For this reason, weterm Q(u) the leverage-neutral measure. We illustrate manyold models (eg. Heston (RFS 93)) and many new models fromthe perspective of this generalized framework.

34

Page 35: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Summary and Future Research

• After reviewing the meanings of FT and CF, we showed howoptions can be priced by a single integration once one knowsthe CF of the underlying log price in closed form.

• To obtain this CF in closed form, we can time-change a Levyprocess using a stochastic clock whose increments are in generalcorrelated with returns.

• This allows us to rapidly develop and test a wide variety ofoption pricing models, which reflect empirical realities such asjumps, volatility clustering, and the leverage effect.

• A quick glance at my bibliography should convince you thatFourier methods are already being applied to many areas offinance besides option pricing.

• Judging from the enormity of the applications of harmonicanalysis in mathematics and the hard sciences, it is not toohard to predict that much work remains to be done.

• Copies of these transparencies can be downloaded from:www.petercarr.net (and clicking on Papers) orwww.math.nyu.edu\research\carrp\papers\pdf

35

Page 36: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

References

[1] Andreas, A., B. Engelmann, P. Schwendner, U. Wystup, 2002,“Fast Fourier method for the valuation of options on sev-eral correlated currencies”, Foreign Exchange Risk 2, ed. J.Hakala, U. Wystup, Risk Books.

[2] Bakshi, G. and Chen, Z. (1997), “An Alternative ValuationModel for Contingent Claims,” Journal of Financial Eco-nomics, 44, 1, 123-165.

[3] Bakshi G., and D. Madan), 2000, “Spanning and Derivative-Security Valuation”, Journal of Financial Economics, 55(2), 205-238.

[4] Ball C., and A. Roma, 1994, “Stochastic Volatility OptionPricing”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,29, 4, December.

[5] Bates D., 2000, “Post-’87 Crash Fears in S&P 500 Futures Op-tions”, Journal of Econometrics 94:1/2, January/February,181–238.

[6] Bates, David (1996), “Jumps and Stochastic Volatility: Ex-change Rate Processes Implicit in Deutschemark Options,”Review of Financial Studies, 9, 69-108.

[7] Beaglehole, D., 1992, “Down and Out, Up and In Options”,University of Iowa working paper.

36

Page 37: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[8] Beaglehole, D., 1993, “Down and Out, Up and Out Options”,University of Iowa working paper.

[9] Benhamou E., 2002,“Fast Fourier transform for discrete Asianoptions”, Journal of Computational Finance, Fall.

[10] Berger, E., 1995, “Barrier Options”, Chapter 8 ofHandbook of Exotic Options ed. by I. Nelken, Probus Pub-lishing, Chicago IL.

[11] Bhagavatula, R., and P. Carr, 1997, “Valuing Double Knock-out Options with Fourier Series”, Morgan Stanley workingpaper.

[12] Broadie M., and Y. Yamamoto, 2002, “Application of theFast Gauss Transform to Option Pricing” Columbia Univer-sity working paper.

[13] Buhlmann H., F. Delbaen, P. Embrechts, 1998, “On EsscherTransforms in Discrete Finance Models”.

[14] Buhlmann H., F. Delbaen, P. Embrechts, A. Shiryaev, 1996,“No-Arbitrage, Change of Measure and Conditional EsscherTransforms”.

[15] Buser S. 1986, “Laplace Transforms as present Values Rules”,Journal of Finance, 3.

[16] Carr, P. and D. Madan, 1998, “Option Valuation using the fastFourier transform,” Journal of Computational Finance, 2,61-73.

37

Page 38: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[17] Carr P. and M. Schroder, 2002, “On the Valuation ofArithmetic-Average Asian Options:the Geman-Yor LaplaceTransform Revisited”, NYU working paper.

[18] Carr P. and L. Wu, 2002, “The Finite Moment LogstableProcess And Option Pricing”, forthcoming in Journal of Fi-nance.

[19] Carr P. and L. Wu, 2002, “Time-Changed Levy ProcessesAnd Option Pricing”, (with L. Wu), forthcoming in Journalof Financial Economics.

[20] Carr P., H. Geman, D. Madan, and M. Yor, “StochasticVolatility for Levy Processes”, forthcoming in MathematicalFinance.

[21] Carr P., H. Geman, D. Madan, and M. Yor, “The Fine Struc-ture of Asset Returns: An Empirical Investigation”, Journalof Business, 75, 2002, 2, 305–32.

[22] Carr P.,“Randomization and the American Put,” 1998, Re-view of Financial Studies, 11, 3, 597–626.

[23] Carverhill, A. and L. Clewlow, 1990, “Flexible Convolution”,Risk 3, Apr. 25–29.

[24] Cathcart L., 1998, “The pricing of floating rate instruments”,Journal of Computational Finance, 1, 4, Summer.

[25] Chiarella C.,N. El-Hassan, 1997, “Evaluation of Derivative Se-curity Prices in the Heath-Jarrow-Morton Framework as Path

38

Page 39: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

Integrals Using Fast Fourier Transform Techniques”, Journalof Financial Engineering.

[26] Chiarella C.,N. El-Hassan, A. Kucera, 1999, “Evaluation ofAmerican Option Prices in a Path Integral Framework us-ing Fourier-Hermite Series Expansions” Journal of EconomicDynamics and Control, 23.

[27] Craddock M.,D. Heath, E. Platen, 2000, “Inversion of LaplaceTransforms in Mathematical Finance” U.Tech Sydney work-ing paper.

[28] Craddock M.,D. Heath, E. Platen, 2000, “Numerical Inver-sion of Laplace Transforms: Survey of Techniques with Ap-plications to Derivative Pricing”, Journal of ComputationalFinance, Fall.

[29] Dempster M. and S. Hong, 2002, “Spread Option Valuationand the Fast Fourier Transform”, Cambridge University work-ing paper.

[30] DeSchepper A.,M. Goovaerts, and F. Delbaen, 1993 “TheLaplace Transform of Certain Annuities with Random Inter-est Rates” Applied Stochastic Models and Data Analysis,v 1.

[31] DeSchepper A.,M. Teunen, and M. Goovaerts, 1994, “An An-alytic Inversion of a Laplace Transform Related to AnnuitiesCertain”, Insurance:Math and Economics.

39

Page 40: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[32] Duffie D., J. Pan, and K. Singleton, 2000, “Transform Analysisand Asset Pricing for Affine Jump-Diffusions”, Econometrica11.

[33] Dufresne, D., 2001, “The integrated square-root process”,University of Melbourne working paper.

[34] Ebenfeld S., M. Mayr and J. Topper, 2002, “An Analysis ofOnion Options and Double-no-Touch Digitals”, Wilmott Sept2002, 68–77.

[35] Engelmann B., P. Schwendner, 1998, “The pricing of multi-asset options using a Fourier grid method”, Journal of Com-putational Finance 1 (4).

[36] Eraker B., 2001, “Do Stock Prices and Volatility Jump? Rec-onciling Evidence from Spot and Option Prices”, Duke Uni-versity working paper.

[37] Eraker B., M. Johannes, and N. Polson, 2000, “The Impactof Jumps in Volatility and Returns”, University of Chicagoworking paper.

[38] Filipovic, D., 2001, ”A General Characterization of OneFactor Affine Term Structure Models”, Finance andStochastics,5,3,389–412

[39] Fu M.,D. Madan,T. Wang, 1999, “Pricing Continuous TimeAsian Options: Comparison of Analytical and Monte CarloMethods”, Journal of Computational Finance, Winter.

40

Page 41: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[40] Geman H.,A. Eydeland 1995, “Domino Effect”, Risk, 4.

[41] Geman H. 2001, “Time Changes, Laplace Transforms andPath-Dependent Options” Computational Economics, 2.

[42] Gerber H.,E. Shiu, 1994, “Option Pricing by Esscher Trans-forms” Transactions of the Society of Actuaries, XLVI.

[43] Heston, Stephen, 1993, Closed-Form Solution for Options withStochastic Volatility, with Application to Bond and CurrencyOptions, Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327–343.

[44] Heston S., “A Simple New Formula for Options with Stochas-tic Volatility”, Washington University of St. Louis workingpaper.

[45] Hoogland J.,D. Neumann, 2000, ”Exploiting Symmetries inPricing Theory with Applications to Asian and Cash Divi-dends”

[46] Hui C., C. Lo, P. Yuen, 2000, “Comment on Pricing Dou-ble Barrier Options using Laplace Transforms” Finance andStochastics, 4.

[47] F. Jamshidian, 1997, “A note on analytical valuation of doublebarrier options,” Sakura Global Capital working paper.

[48] Jiang G. and J. Knight, 2002, “Efficient estimation ofcontinuous-time stochastic volatility process via empiricalcharacteristic function,” York University Working Paper.

41

Page 42: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[49] Ju N. 1997, “Fourier Transformation, Martingale and Pricingof Average-Rate Derivatives”.

[50] Kou, S., G. Petrella, 2002, “A Laplace Transform Method forPricing Discrete Barrier and Lookback Options”, ColumbiaUniversity working paper.

[51] Lee R. 2003, “Option Pricing by Transform Methods: Ex-tensions, Unification and Error Control”, Stanford Universityworking paper.

[52] Lewis, A., 2001, “A Simple Option Formula for General Jump-Diffusion and other Exponential Levy Processes”, FinancePress.

[53] Lewis, A., 2000, Option Valuation under Stochastic Volatility,Finance Press.

[54] Lipton A., 2002, “Assets with jumps”, Risk, 15 9.

[55] Mancino M., and P. Malliavin, 2002 “Fourier series methodfor measurement of multivariate volatilities”, Finance andStochastics, 6 (1) 49–61.

[56] Mallier R., and G. Alobaidi, 2000, “Laplace Transforms andAmerican Options”, Applied Mathematical Finance, 12.

[57] Merino S. and M. Nyfeler, 2002, “Calculating portfolio loss”,Risk, August 15 8.

[58] Negrea, B., 2002, “Option Pricing with Stochastic Volatility:A Closed-Form Solution Using the Fourier Transform”.

42

Page 43: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[59] Paulson V., 2001, “The h-Transformation and Its Applicationto Mathematical Finance”.

[60] Pelsser A. 2000, “Pricing Double Barrier Options usingLaplace Transforms”, Finance and Stochastics,4.

[61] Prause K. 1999, “The Generalized Hyperbolic Model: Esti-mation, Financial Derivatives and Risk Measures”.

[62] Rebonato R., and I. Cooper, 1998, ”Coupling Backward In-duction with Monte Carlo Simulations:A Fast Fourier Trans-form(FFT) Approach’ Applied Mathematical Finance, 6.

[63] Reiner E., 1999, “Convolution Methods for Exotic Options”,Warburg Dillon Read working paper.

[64] Sbuelz A., 1997, “Barrier Contingent Claims: Laplace Trans-forms and Financial Intuition”. Tilburg University workingpaper.

[65] Schroder M., 2000, “On the Valuation of Arithmetic-AverageAsian Options: Laguerre Series and Theta Integrals”, U.Mannheim working paper.

[66] Schroder M., 2000, “The Laplace Transform Approach toValuing Exotic Options:the Case of the Asian Option”, U.Mannheim working paper.

[67] Schroder M., 1999, “Fact and Fantasy in Recent Applicationsof Transform Methods to the Valuation of Exotic Options”,U. Mannheim working paper.

43

Page 44: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[68] Schroder M., 1999, “The Characteristic Functions ApproachTo Valuing Contingent Claims: Pleading The Case For TheForward Measure”, U. Mannheim working paper.

[69] Scott, L. (1997), “Pricing Stock Options in a Jump-DiffusionModel with Stochastic Volatility and Interest Rates: Applica-tion of Fourier Inversion Methods,” Mathematical Finance,7, 413-426.

[70] Shephard N., 1991, “From Characteristic Function to Dis-tribution Function: A Simple Framework for the Theory”,Econometric Theory, 7, 4, 519–29.

[71] Sidenius J., 1998, “Double barrier options: valuation by pathcounting”, Journal of Computational Finance, 1 3, Spring.

[72] Skachkov I., 2002, “Black-Scholes Equation in Laplace Trans-form Domain”, available at www.wilmott.com

[73] Stein, E., and J. Stein, 1991, “Stock Price Distributions withStochastic Volatility: An Analytic Approach”, Review of Fi-nancial Studies, 4, 4, 727–752.

[74] Sudler G., 1999, ”Asian Options:Inverse Laplace Transformsand Martingale Methods Revisited”. Virginia PolytechnicUniversity master’s thesis.

[75] Underwood R. and J. Wang, 2000, “An integral representationand computation for the solution of American options”, Pro-ceedings of the Third World Congress of Nonlinear Analysis,July 19-26, 2000, Catania, Sicily, Italy.

44

Page 45: Option Pricing using Integral Transformspages.stern.nyu.edu/~dbackus/GE_asset_pricing...A Brief History of Sines • The history of integral transforms begins with d’Alembert in

[76] Zhu. J., 2000,Modular pricing of options: an application of Fourier analysis,Springer-Verlag, New York.

45